A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets

Similar documents
ARBITRAGE POSSIBILITIES IN BESSEL PROCESSES AND THEIR RELATIONS TO LOCAL MARTINGALES.

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term.

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

On Utility Based Pricing of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets

Yuri Kabanov, Constantinos Kardaras and Shiqi Song No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

Applications to Mathematical Finance

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

ON THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ASSET PRICING. Dedicated to the memory of G. Kallianpur

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Pricing and hedging in the presence of extraneous risks

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES

Risk Neutral Measures

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

Hedging under Arbitrage

The Notion of Arbitrage and Free Lunch in Mathematical Finance

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

Hedging of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

Hedging under arbitrage

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Arbitrage and Asset Pricing

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Markets with convex transaction costs

Non replication of options

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

A note on sufficient conditions for no arbitrage

Arbitrage Theory. The research of this paper was partially supported by the NATO Grant CRG

Risk Neutral Pricing. to government bonds (provided that the government is reliable).

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires

Enlargement of filtration

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

The Notion of Arbitrage and Free Lunch in Mathematical Finance

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Stochastic Integral Representation of One Stochastically Non-smooth Wiener Functional

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

The super-replication theorem under proportional transaction costs revisited

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

arxiv: v4 [q-fin.pr] 10 Aug 2009

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing under Proportional Transaction Costs in Finite Discrete Time

Spot and forward dynamic utilities. and their associated pricing systems. Thaleia Zariphopoulou. UT, Austin

SÉMINAIRE DE PROBABILITÉS (STRASBOURG)

Optimal Dividend Policy of A Large Insurance Company with Solvency Constraints. Zongxia Liang

Shifting Martingale Measures and the Birth of a Bubble as a Submartingale

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

Ross Recovery theorem and its extension

Class Notes on Financial Mathematics. No-Arbitrage Pricing Model

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1.

Interest rate models in continuous time

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

Optional semimartingale decomposition and no arbitrage condition in enlarged ltration

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics

arxiv: v13 [q-fin.gn] 29 Jan 2016

On an optimization problem related to static superreplicating

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Valuing power options under a regime-switching model

The Azema Yor embedding in non-singular diusions

CAPITAL BUDGETING IN ARBITRAGE FREE MARKETS

Asset Price Bubbles in Complete Markets

Transcription:

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets FREDDY DELBAEN 1 Department of Mathematics Vrije Universiteit Brussel and HIROSHI SHIRAKAWA 2 Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering Tokyo Institute of Technology Abstract: We consider an international financial market model that consists of N currencies. The purpose is to derive a no arbitrage condition which is not affected by the choice of numéraire between the N currencies. As a result, we show that a finiteness condition for an arbitrary chosen currency and the no arbitrage condition for the basket currency are necessary and sufficient for the no arbitrage property of all the N currencies. Keywords: Multi-currency, Basket currency, No arbitrage, Numéraire, Martingale measure. 1 Introduction After the pioneering work by Harrison Kreps [12], many researchers have studied the relationship between the existence of an equivalent martingale measure and the no arbitrage property. In this setting most authors use a fixed asset as numéraire. But in the case of an international economy model, an a priori choice of numéraire poses some problems to characterize the no arbitrage property. Suppose that an international financial market consists of N currencies. Then from the viewpoint of economic efficiency, we should require that if we take any of the N currencies as numéraire and express the others in function of this choice, the so obtained price process should not allow arbitrage profits. This problem is not trivial. Delbaen Schachermayer [5] and [7] have given an example of a two currency model with the property that when the first is chosen as numéraire, there is no arbitrage but on the contrary there is an arbitrage profit when the second is chosen as numéraire. The purpose of this note is to derive a compact condition which guarantees the no arbitrage property, regardless of the currency chosen as numéraire. In particular we show that if a finiteness condition with respect to an arbitrary chosen currency holds, then the no arbitrage property with respect to a basket currency is necessary and sufficient for the no arbitrage property to hold, regardless which of the N currencies is chosen as numéraire. The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we summarize the fundamental results from Delbaen Schachermayer [5] [11] used in this note. In section 3, we explain the multi- 1 Research supported in part by Nomura Foundation for Social Science and by the European Community Stimulation Plan for Economic Science contract Number SPES-CT91-89 2 This research was supported in part by Nomura Foundation for Social Science. 1

currency international financial market model. In section 4, we investigate the finiteness condition, which turns out to be invariant for the choice of numéraire and for the choice of equivalent probability measure. Finally in section 5, we derive the compact no arbitrage condition. Without loss of generality, we use the interval [, 1] as the time interval for the finite time horizon model. Let (Ω, F, (F t ) t 1, P ) be a filtered probability space satisfying the usual conditions. The bold face characters denote column vectors, and the denotes the transpose. We introduce the notation H S for the vector stochastic integral and we refer to Jacod [15] for details. 2 Summary of Results on Arbitrage Theory We consider a financial market consisting of N assets numbered from 1 to N. Asset number 1 is chosen as numéraire. The price of asset k, 2 k N, at time t is denoted by St k, of course we have St 1 = 1. The process S=(S 1,,S N ) is supposed to be a continuous, vector-valued semi-martingale such that each coordinate is strictly positive. Definition 2.1 Let a be a positive real number. An S-integrable predictable vector-valued process H=(H 1,,H N ) is called a-admissible if H = and (H S) t a, P-a.s. for all t 1. The predictable process H is called admissible if it is a-admissible for some a R. Definition 2.2 We say that the vector-valued semi-martingale S satisfies the no arbitrage condition, (NA), for general admissible integrands, if for all H admissible we have that (H S) 1, a.s. implies (H S) 1 =, a.s.. (2.1) For the history and the use of this condition we refer to Delbaen Schachermayer [6] and Harrison Pliska [13]. If M is a continuous d-dimensional vector-valued local martingale, then the bracket process M, M is defined as a continuous process taking values in the space of d d matrices. The elements are described by the usual brackets M i,m j where M i denotes the i-th coordinate of M. The Kunita Watanabe inequality states that the process M, M takes values in the cone of positive definite symmetric matrices and the process is increasing in the sense that M, M t M, M s is a positive definite symmetric matrix for s<t. Using a control measure λ, we can describe M, M as a process having a Radon Nykodim derivative with respect to λ. Forλ we can take the predictable increasing process λ t = trace M, M t = d i=1 M i,m i t. The process M, M can then be written as M, M t = t L udλ u where L is a predictable process having values in the cone of positive definite symmetric matrices. There is an easy way to see this, by using the following construction of the Radon Nykodim derivative. For each n 1, we define the process L n as follows. L n u = M, M k M, M k 1 2n 2 n λ λ k 2 n k 1 2 n, k k +1 <u 2n 2, 1 k n 2n 1 L n u =, u 1 2 n 2

One shows that dλ a.e., L n L on [, 1] Ω, and Ln u L u dλ u, in probability, for any matrix norm. The Kunita Watanabe inequality shows that each L n u is a positive definite symmetric matrix and hence the same remains true for L u. Using power series, we define the processes I d exp ( nl). These processes are still predictable and when n, the limit of I d exp ( nl) tends to the projection P on the range of L, P is therefore predictable, see also lemma 4.2 below. Remark that the kernel of P is also the kernel of L. For a continuous semi-martingale S, the following was proved in Delbaen Schachermayer [1]. Theorem 2.3 If S is a continuous vector-valued semi-martingale decomposed as ds t = dm t + da t where M is a continuous local martingale and A is a continuous process of bounded variation, (the Doob Meyer decomposition of S), then (a) if S satisfies NA for general admissible integrands, there is a predictable vector process h such that da t = d M, M t h t, (2.2) where d M, M is the matrix measure and h is a vector-valued predictable process. (b) Under the same hypothesis, { τ = inf t t } h u d M, M uh u = >, a.s. (2.3) (c) The continuous semi-martingale S admits an equivalent local martingale measure, i.e. satisfies EMM, if and only if the following two conditions hold (i) S has the NA property for general admissible integrands. (ii) S satisfies the finiteness property h u d M, M uh u <, a.s., (2.4) where h is defined by (2.2) Remark 2.4 The local martingale process ( t L t = exp h u dm u 1 t ) h u 2 d M, M h u (2.5) is not necessarily a martingale and hence the obvious Girsanov Maruyama transformation does not give an equivalent local martingale measure for S (see Delbaen Schachermayer [9] and Schachermayer [16]). Remark 2.5 Under the hypothesis of the theorem, H is S-integrable if and only if and (1) (2) H ud M, M u H u = H uda u = H ul u H u dλ u <, H ul u h u dλ u <, a.s. It is clear that in such expressions, we may replace h by its projection Ph and we see that H is S-integrable if and only if PH is S-integrable. This follows easily from the fact that ker(p) =ker(l) and Range(P) =Range(L). 3 a.s.

If S is a continuous vector-valued semi-martingale, then we denote by M e (P ) the set of all equivalent probability measures Q under which S becomes a (vector-valued) Q-local martingale. We will also make us of the following sets: K 1 = {(H S) 1 H is 1-admissible}, (2.6) K = {(H S) 1 H is admissible}. (2.7) We can easily see that K 1 Kand K = a> K a = λ> λk 1. The following theorems are proved in Delbaen Schachermayer [8] and [11] (see also Jacka [14], Ansel Stricker [3]). It makes use of the set of maximal elements defined as follows Definition 2.6 We say that f K 1 is maximal in K 1 if g K 1 and g f imply g = f. The element f Kis maximal in K if g Kand g f imply g = f. Remark 2.7 The (NA) property is equivalent to the statement that the zero function is maximal in K (or in K 1 ). If S satisfies the (NA) property with respect to general admissible integrands, then f K 1 is maximal in K 1 if and only if f is maximal in K. Theorem 2.8 If S satisfies EMM, i.e. admits an equivalent local martingale measure, then for an element f K 1 the following are equivalent : (a) f is a maximal element in K 1. (b) f is a maximal element in K. (c) There is an equivalent local martingale measure Q M e (P ) such that E Q [f] =. (d) There is a 1-admissible integrand H and there is an equivalent local martingale measure Q M e (P ) such that f =(H S) 1 and the process H S is a Q-uniformly integrable martingale. Theorem 2.9 If S satisfies EMM, i.e. admits an equivalent local martingale measure, then for an admissible integrand H such that V = c + H S satisfies V t >, a.s., for t 1, the following are equivalent : (a ) f =(H S) 1 is a maximal element in K. (b ) There is an equivalent local martingale measure Q M e (P ) such that sup{e R [V 1 ] R M e (P )} = E Q [V 1 ] <. (c ) There is an equivalent local martingale measure Q M e (P ) such that V is a Q- uniformly integrable martingale. (d ) The process S V has an equivalent local martingale measure. Theorem 2.1 Suppose that S satisfies EMM, i.e. admits an equivalent local martingale measure. If f 1,,f n are maximal in K, then f 1 + + f n is maximal in K. Corollary 2.11 Suppose that S satisfies EMM, i.e. admits an equivalent local martingale measure. If f 1,,f n are elements in K such that for each j n, there is Q j M e (P ) with E Q j[f j ]=, then there is Q M e (P ) such that E Q [f j ]=for each j n. 4

Proof. By the theorem, each f j, j n is maximal and hence f 1 + + f n is maximal. This implies the existence of Q M e (P ) such that E Q [f 1 + + f n ] =. Since the elements f j are in K and since Q M e (P ), we necessarily have E Q [f j ]. But this implies that E Q [f j ] = for each j. From Theorem 2.9 2.1 and Corollary 2.12, it follows that Corollary 2.12 If V j = c j + H j S >, j =1,,J < are stochastic integrals such that for each j, there is an equivalent probability measure Q j M e (P ) for which V j is a Q j -uniformly integrable martingale, then there is an equivalent probability measure Q M e (P ) such that for all j J, V j is a Q-uniformly integrable martingale. 3 An International Financial Market Model We consider an international financial market model consisting of N currencies numbered from 1 to N. For each currency k there is a positive (mostly stochastic) interest rate r k such that rudu k <, a.s., 1 k N. (3.1) Without loss of generality, we assume that the currency 1 is the domestic currency which is used as numéraire to express the other values. The exchange rate of currency k for the domestic currency 1 is described by Et k. From the definition, we have Et 1 =1. E k and r k are supposed to be adapted processes and each E k is a continuous, strictly positive semi-martingale. Following e.g. Harrison Kreps [12] and Artzner Delbaen [1], we define the following discounted exchange rates St 1 = 1, (3.2) ( t ) ( t ) St k = exp rudu 1 exp rudu k Et k, 2 k N. (3.3) The process S k describes, in terms of currency 1, the relative value of one unit of currency k, deposited at time and continuously compounded at interest rate r k. From the definition it follows that S k >, a.s., 1 k N. If we choose currency k as the numéraire, the discounted vector-valued process becomes ( S1,, SN ). More generally, for a positive S k S k constant weight vector α=(α 1,,α N ), α j >, we may define the basket currency B by N B t = α k St k. (3.4) k=1 When the basket currency is used as numéraire, the discounted vector-valued process is expressed by the process ( S1,, SN ). Notice that an admissible strategy H for S, i.e. B B with respect to the domestic currency, is not necessarily admissible when currency k is used as numéraire. That is, H is not necessarily admissible for the vector-valued process 1 S. It follows that the NA-property depends on the currency used as numéraire. S k 4 Finiteness Property As stated in Section 2 in general the NA property is not sufficient to guarantee the existence of an equivalent local martingale measure. Stronger conditions are needed. For 5

general locally bounded semi-martingales, such a condition is the so-called No Free Lunch with Vanishing Risk (or NF LV R) property. However in the case of a continuous price process, we can relax the assumption and split the NF LV R condition in two separate conditions. The first is the already mentioned (NA) property, the second is the finiteness condition, which can be seen as the integrability of the risk premium process h. As will be shown below, the finiteness condition does not depend on the choice of the probability measure. In other words, if the probability measure P is replaced by an equivalent probability measure Q, then the Doob Meyer decomposition under Q again satisfies the finiteness condition. We start with some obvious results from linear algebra. Lemma 4.1 If A : R d R d is a symmetric linear operator, then the Moore Penrose inverse is given by A 1 = lim na exp ( (I d + A 2 n)x ) dx (4.1) n Proof. Since A is a symmetric linear operator, there exists an orthogonal basis of R d in which A is represented by a diagonal matrix. In this basis, we have λ 1 λ 1 1...... A = λ r and A 1 = λ 1 r. (4.2)...... Now observe that nλ exp ( x(1 + nλ 2 ) ) dx = nλ { 1 1+nλ, if λ, 2 λ, if λ =. (4.3) Lemma 4.2 If φ :(E,E) S(R d ) is a measurable mapping from a measurable space (E,E) into the vector space of symmetric operators on R d. Then (a) φ 1 : E S(R d ) is still measurable (b) P : E S(R d ), where P is projection on Range(φ), is measurable. Proof. (a) φ 1 = lim nφ exp ( x(i d + nφ 2 ) ) dx (4.4) n expresses φ 1 as a limit of measurable expressions of φ, hence φ 1 is measurable. (b) P = φ 1 φ is the product (matrix product) of two measurable mappings and hence is measurable. In the same way, we can show the following corollary. Corollary 4.3 If Ax = b is a linear system then the couple (x, y) such that Ax + y = b and x 2 + y 2 is minimal, depends in a measurable way on A and b. 6

Proof. Take normal equations and apply Lemma 4.2. Lemma 4.4 If S is a vector-valued continuous semi-martingale and if S satisfies the finiteness condition under P, then for each probability measure Q, equivalent to P, the process S still satisfies the finiteness condition under Q. [ Proof. Let Z be the martingale defined by Z t = E dq P F ] dp t. We, of course, can take a cadlag version for Z (we remark that we did not make a continuity assumption on the filtration (F t ) t 1 and we therefore cannot state that Z is continuous). Suppose that under P, the semi-martingale S is decomposed as ds t = dm t + d M, M t h t. Because S satisfies the finiteness property under P, we have that h d M, M h <. The Girsanov Maruyama formula says that under Q, the martingale part becomes t 1 M t d M,Z u Z u and the predictable part is given by da t = d M, M t h t + 1 d M,Z t (4.5) Z t Because M is continuous, we may decompose the martingale Z as dz = φ dm + dn, where N is a local martingale, strongly orthogonal to the continuous martingale M and where φ is M-integrable, i.e. φ d M, M φ <. We consequently obtain d M,Z t = d M, M t φ t. The process Z is bounded away from zero (see Dellacherie Meyer [4]) and therefore the finiteness property under Q follows from the finiteness property under P and from the M-integrability of φ. Lemma 4.5 The finiteness condition does not depend on the choice of numéraire, i.e. if S satisfies the finiteness condition and if = c + H S > is a stochastic integral, then S also satisfies the finiteness condition. Proof. By definition we have that d = H ds. Then from the generalized Itô s lemma and from ds = dm + da, we deduce: ( ) 1 d = 1 d + 1 2 3 (d)2 = 1 2 H ds + 1 3 H d M, M H. (4.6) Hence d ( ) S = 1 ds + Sd ( 1 ) + d S, 1 = 1 dm + 1 d M, M h 1 2 SH ds + 1 3 SH d M, M H 1 d M, M H 2 = 1 dm 1 2 SH dm 1 2 SH d M, M h + 1 d M, M h + 1 3 SH d M, M H 1 d M, M H. (4.7) 2 7

The martingale part N t of (4.7) is given by dn = 1 dm 1 2 SH dm = 1 (I 1 SH )dm. (4.8) From this we can calculate d N, N : d N, N = 1 ( I 1 ) 2 SH d M, M (I 1 ) HS. The bounded variation part B t of (4.7) is given by db = 1 2 SH d M, M h + 1 d M, M h + 1 3 SH d M, M H 1 d M, M H. (4.9) 2 Since >, U = 1H is well defined. By the exponential formula we know that t is given by ( t t = exp U dm 1 t ) U d M, M U. (4.1) 2 The equation (4.9) can be rewritten as db = 1 SU d M, M h + 1 d M, M h + 1 SU d M, M U 1 d M, M U = (I SU ) d M, M h (I SU ) d M, M U ( ) h U = (I SU ) d M, M. (4.11) Next we shall show that db can be written as (I SU ) d M, M (I SU ) g, for some predictable process g. As shown in Section 2, we can write d M, M = Ldλ for some control measure λ. Substitute this for (4.11), we have ( ) h U db =(I SU ) L dλ. (4.12) To simplify notation let C=I SU. We then have the following trivial inclusion on the ranges of different operators, Range(CLC ) Range(CL). However we also have Range(CL) Range(CLC ). Indeed if y Range(CLC ), we have y CLC =. Then y CLC y = and C y ker(l) =Range(L). This means that y CL = and hence y Range(CL). Therefore Range(CL) =Range(CLC ). Let D=(I SU )L (I U S). The projection P on Range(D) is predictable and D is bijective on the Range(D) =Range(P ). The Moore Penrose inverse D 1 is predictable and D 1 D = DD 1 = P. By taking g = D 1 (I SU )L h U, we have a predictable process g such that db = 8

d N, N g. We should check the finiteness property for g. g d N, N g = g CLC gdλ ( ) h U = g CL dλ [( ) ( (g CLC g) 1 h U h U 2 L The last inequality follows from the Cauchy Schwarz inequality for positive definite bilinear forms. Hence, again by the Cauchy Schwarz inequality, we have ( ) 1 ( ) g s d N, N hs U s hs U s sg s L s dλ s s ( ) 1 ( ) hs U s hs U s = d M, M s 1 2 s s s )] 1 2 dλ. (h s d M, M sh s + U s d M, M su s ). (4.13) Since inf t 1 t >, we have 1 U 2 s s d M, M su s < from (4.1) and from 1 >. This together with the finiteness property (2.4) yields the desired result. Remark 4.6 From Lemma 4.4 and 4.5, the finiteness condition is invariant for the choice of numéraire and for the choice of equivalent probability measure. Hence from Theorem 2.3 (c), if the finiteness condition is satisfied under P, the NA property becomes equivalent to the existence of an equivalent local martingale measure for the process S. 5 The Main Theorem We show that under the finiteness condition for an arbitrary chosen currency, the no arbitrage condition for a basket currency is necessary and sufficient for the no arbitrage property to hold with respect to all the N currencies. Theorem 5.1 If S is a continuous vector-valued semi-martingale that satisfies the finiteness condition, then the following are equivalent: (a) For all j, 1 j N, there is an equivalent probability measure Q j M e (P ) such that S j is a Q j -uniformly integrable martingale. (b) There is an equivalent probability measure Q M e (P ) such that S is a Q-uniformly integrable vector martingale. (c) For all j, 1 j N, S S j integrands. satisfies the NA property with respect to general admissible (d) If B is a basket currency, B = α 1 S 1 + + α N S N, where the α i are strictly positive constants, then S satisfies the NA property with respect to general admissible B integrands. 9

Proof. (a) (b): Follows from Corollary 2.12. (a) (c): Follows from (c ) (d ) in Theorem 2.9 and Remark 4.6. (b) (d): Suppose now that there is an equivalent measure Q M e (P ) such that B is a Q-uniformly integrable martingale. Hence from Theorem 2.3 (c) and (c ) (d ) in Theorem 2.9, S satisfies NA. (d) (a): If S B B satisfies NA, from Theorem 2.3 (c), Remark 4.6 and (c ) (d ) in Theorem 2.9, there exists Q M e (P ) such that B is a Q-uniformly integrable martingale. Since each S k is a Q-local martingale and S k B min 1 j N, S k is a Q-uniformly integrable martingale. α j Remark 5.2 Theorem 5.1 shows how important the existence of a martingale measure (instead of a local martingale measure) is when dealing with different currencies and numéraires. Another application of the theorem is that of different stocks and the use of an index as numéraire. We also want to point out that the N financial assets were interpreted as currencies. They can also represent arbitrary financial assets. The model is therefore much more general than the title indicates. The NA properties for general admissible integrands follow, in the continuous case, from the no free lunch with vanishing risk NF LV R property for simple admissible integrands (see Delbaen Schachermayer [6]). So the theorem can also be stated using N F LV R for simple admissible integrands. In this case, the finiteness property follows from NF LV R. References [1] Artzner, P. and Delbaen, F., Term Structure of Interest Rates : The Martingale Approach, Advances in Applied Mathematics, vol. 1, 95 129, 1989. [2] Ansel, J.-P. and Stricker, C., Unicité et Existence de la Loi Minimale, Séminaire de Probabilités, Lecture Notes in Mathematics. Springer-Verlag, 1994. [3] Ansel, J. P. and Stricker, C., Couverture des actifs contingents, working paper, 1993. [4] Dellacherie, C. and Meyer, P. A., Probabilities and Potential, North-Holland, 1978. [5] Delbaen, F. and Schachermayer, W., Arbitrage and Free Lunch with Bounded Risk for Unbounded Continuous Processes, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 4, 343 348, 1994. [6] Delbaen, F. and Schachermayer, W., A General Version of the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing, Mathematische Annalen, Vol. 3, 463 52, 1994. [7] Delbaen, F. and Schachermayer, W., Arbitrage Possibilities in Bessel Processes and their Relations to Local Martingales, submitted, 1994. [8] Delbaen, F. and Schachermayer, W., The No-Arbitrage Property under a Change of Numéraire, Stochastics and Stochastics Reports, 1995. [9] Delbaen, F. and Schachermayer, W., A Simple Example of Two Non Uniformly Integrable Continuous Martingale whose product is a Uniformly Integrable Martingale, submitted, 1994. 1

[1] Delbaen, F. and Schachermayer, W., The No Arbitrage Property for Continuous Processes, submitted, 1994. [11] Delbaen, F. and Schachermayer, W., The Set of Maximal Admissible Elements in Arbitrage Theory, in preparation, 1994. [12] Harrison, M. and Kreps, D., Martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod securities markets, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 2, 381 48, 1979. [13] Harrison, M. and Pliska, S., Martingales and Stochastic Integrals in the Theory of Continuous Trading, Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, Vol. 11, 215 26, 1981. [14] Jacka, S. D., A Martingale Representation Result and an Application to Incomplete Financial Markets, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 2, 239 25, 1992. [15] Jacod, J., Calcul Stochastique et Problèmes de Martingales, Springer-Verlag, 1979. [16] Schachermayer, W., A Counterexample to Several Problems in the Theory of Asset Pricing, to appear in Mathematical Finance, 1994. 11