SUBMISSION FROM JOHN MCLAREN, FISCAL AFFAIRS SCOTLAND

Similar documents
Adjusting Scotland s Block Grant

Scotland's Fiscal Framework: Assessing the agreement

Economic Perspectives

Guide to the new Scottish budget process

Social Security (Scotland) Bill Financial Memorandum Briefing David Eiser, Committee Adviser

Active Scottish Economy in recession over 2016

PUBLIC SPENDING IN SCOTLAND: RELATIVITIES AND PRIORITIES

The referendum and prospects for public expenditure in. John McLaren, Centre for Public Policy for Regions

Scotland s new Budget Framework

Reflections on the SNP s Sustainable Growth Commission Report

Economic aspects of Scottish independence: public spending and revenue

The Economic and Fiscal Issues Facing Scotland,

The Autumn Statement. Implications for Scotland. November: 2016

A primer on the Scottish Parliament s new fiscal powers: what are they, how will they work, and what are the challenges?

Timing of the Draft Scottish Budget 2017/18

Spending Review Overview

Income Tax in Scotland: 2017 update

SCOTLAND S FISCAL DEFICIT

Consultation and decision paper CP17/44. PSR regulatory fees

The (Dis)United Kingdom? Ed Poole Cardiff University, Wales

Outlook for Scotland s Public Finances and the Opportunities of Independence. May 2014

AFFORDABILITY: EXPENDITURE DRIVERS. No Control. Largely Fixed Commitments. Policy Commitments. Partial Control

Adjusting the Scottish block grant abatement: the algebra of CM and IPC 1

Working paper No.14. Devolved income tax: forecasting by tax bands

The Fiscal Framework and the Scottish Budget Process: Some Thoughts

Grant to Welsh Government, and Wales Office funding

Understanding Scotland s Budget Graeme Roy, Fraser of Allander Institute David Hume Institute 11 th May 2017

What Costs would an Independent Scotland Bear in its First Year?

Intergovernmental relations and Scotland s constitutional debates

UK Autumn Budget impact on Scotland

SCOTLAND S FISCAL DEFICIT

Government spending priorities

SOCIAL SECURITY (SCOTLAND) BILL [AS AMENDED AT STAGE 2]

Research Briefing Budget Series 1: Funding Welsh devolution

The New Monetary Policy Strategy of the ECB 1. Anne Sibert, Birkbeck College, London and CEPR. May 2003

Draft Budget : Taxes

Grant to Northern Ireland Government, and Northern Ireland Office funding

Joint Consultation Paper

Bruce Crawford MSP Convener Finance and Constitution Committee The Scottish Parliament. By February Dear Convener,

THE SCOTTISH GOVERNMENT S BUDGET GROWTH PROSPECTS AND BUDGET OPTIONS

Contents Paragraph Introduction 1-3. Who we are 4-6. Key point summary Major points 17-36

CHALLENGES FOR THE SNP GROWTH COMMISSION

COMMON FRAMEWORKS NFU SCOTLAND EVIDENCE

The agreement between the Scottish Government and the United Kingdom Government on the Scottish Government s fiscal framework

Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals

Re: Position Paper Means Test Rules for Lifetime Retirement Income Streams

PAY GROWTH SCOTLAND S MISSING THE ECONOMIC AND FISCAL IMPACTS OF WEAK WAGES SINCE THE FINANCIAL CRISIS REPORT

Recovering the costs of the Office for Professional Body Anti-Money Laundering Supervision (OPBAS): fees proposals

LOCALISING COUNCIL TAX SUPPORT: A BRIEFING NOTE ON LOCAL AUTHORITIES PLANS Sam Popper and Peter Kenway

Comments on the Revised Discussion Draft on Transfer Pricing Aspects of Intangibles*

The Swedish NDC system - A critical assessment

A review of the surplus target, SOU 2016:67

1. Context i/ Scottish parliament support to look at differentiation:

The Swedish Fiscal Framework and the Fiscal Policy Council. Lars Calmfors Workshop on Fiscal Rules and Institutions OECD, 22 March, 2010

Fiscal Policy, Budget Deficits and the Economic Crisis. Lars Calmfors Intermediate macroeconomics Stockholm, 30 March 2010

Response to the Scottish Parliament s Finance and Constitution Committee Call for Evidence

Finance Committee. Inquiry into methods of funding capital investment projects. Submission from PPP Forum

SUNDAY TIMES REPORT. Analysis of the fiscal balance of an independent or fiscally autonomous Scotland.

DRIVING RELATIVE REGIONAL CONSUMER PRICE LEVELS OUT OF THE UK PURCHASING POWER PARITIES

Borrowing powers in the Scotland Bill Scottish Government. Summary. June 2011

REVIEW OF DOUBLE TAXATION TREATIES AND DOUBLE CONTRIBUTION AGREEMENTS

EFFECT OF PUBLIC EXPENDITURES ON INCOME DISTRIBUTION WITH SPECIAL REFERENCE TO VENEZUELA

NHS Finances The challenge all political parties need to face. Charts and tables. Chart update, May Chart update, May 2015

Financial Scrutiny Unit Briefing The Economic Implications of Brexit

Sanctions and Anti-Money Laundering Bill

Light at the end of the fiscal tunnel? Scotland s public spending pressures

Designing a European Fiscal Union: Lessons from the Experience of Fiscal Federations Fiscal Affairs Department IMF

Strengthening Scotland s Future

EU Exit. Long-term economic analysis November Cm 9741

Calling Time on the Alcohol Duty Escalator. Budget Submission 2014 The Scotch Whisky Association

A PROGRESSIVE FUTURE FOR INCOME TAX IN SCOTLAND?

The Commission s Study on Company

Welsh budgetary trade offs to Ian Mitchell

Survey. Local Government Finance & Treasury Current Affairs. Lead Sponsor

" (Briefing Note - Immediate Release - 15th March 2017)

Comments on THE CURRENT STATE OF LITHUANIAN PENSION SYSTEM AND DISCUSSIONS ON IT S REFORM

Income Tax and Small Businesses in Scotland

Spring Budget IFS Director Paul Johnson s opening remarks

The South Staffordshire/Cambridge water merger. The case of South Staffordshire/ Cambridge: is clearer water emerging?

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION 2014 DRAFT BUDGETARY PLANS OF THE EURO AREA: OVERALL ASSESSMENT OF THE BUDGETARY SITUATION AND PROSPECTS

Thomson Reuters response to CESR consultation Transparency of corporate bond, structure finance product and credit derivatives markets (CESR/O8-1014)

MAKE SURE YOU RE IN THE KNOW

Empowerment and Responsibility: Financial Powers to Strengthen Wales

HMRC consultation: Alternative method of VAT collection split payment Response by the Chartered Institute of Taxation

Submission from the FAI to Inquiry into Economic Statistics

Financial scrutiny uncovered. A guide for Members by the Committee Office Scrutiny Unit

National Budgeting for European Convergence Eduardo Zapico Goñi Associate Professor, EIPA

WRITTEN SUBMISSION TO THE HMRC BUSINESS INTERNATIONAL TAX TREATY TEAM ON THE ANNUAL REVIEW OF DOUBLE TAXATION TREATIES

The Economic Situation of the European Union and the Outlook for

Usable Productivity Growth in the United States

Suggested answers to Problem Set 5

REVIEW OF DOUBLE TAXATION TREATIES AND DOUBLE CONTRIBUTION AGREEMENTS

An assessment of the recent review of the ECB's monetary policy strategy. Peter Bofinger, Universität Würzburg and CEPR

1 Payrolling of benefits

Scottish Policy Foundation. Economic Commentary. Exports a background note. April Vol 41 No 3

Autumn Budget 2018: IFS analysis

Tax Brief. 16 November Exposure Draft on Share Buybacks. Off-market buybacks

BBPA Local impact of the beer and pub sector 2010/11

Public Sector Statistics

26/10/2016. The Euro. By 2016 there are 19 member countries and about 334 million people use the. Lithuania entered 1 January 2015

Transcription:

SUBMISSION FROM JOHN MCLAREN, FISCAL AFFAIRS SCOTLAND Finance Committee - pre attendance written submission with regards to the questions outlined in the Committee s call for written evidence on Chapter 2 of the Command Paper Scotland in the United Kingdom: An enduring settlement. What needs to be included within a revised funding framework for Scotland and how do we ensure that it is fair, transparent, effective and mechanical rather than requiring regular negotiations? Detailed points on the proposed framework are outlined below. Whether the current proposal is what should be included in any revised framework is a very different question and not one that is addressed here. However, it is worth commenting on the fair, transparent, effective and mechanical rather than requiring regular negotiations aspect of the question above. First, in order to know whether these requirements are being met, each one needs to be clearly defined. Having done so, it is debatable whether each can be met at the same time, or at least to the same degree. It seems inevitable that there will be some degree of trade off involved. Consequently some degree of prioritisation across the requirements may be needed. Second, there is the question of whether each requirement is actually desirable, in particular with respect to the frameworks being mechanical. Barnett is highly mechanical in nature but this has brought its own problems. It may be better to accept that a degree of adaptability and an element of negotiation (which occurs even with Barnett) is probably inevitable, and welcome. If not, then introducing a funding mechanism that is transparent and mechanical may require softening the requirement for being fair (or at least what is considered fair by one or other of the two government s). What fiscal rules should be applied in order to ensure fiscal responsibility and debt sustainability? As the last recession showed, no fiscal rules are bullet proof and the consequences of their being broken are not automatic. For example, with regards to debt positions, Japan, Greece and Ireland each started the recession with debt as a share of GDP ratios of 180%, 118% and 29% respectively, but now find themselves in very different places. Hence, fiscal rules need to be adaptable to local conditions. Nevertheless there appears to be a growing consensus across OECD countries that good fiscal rules should incorporate (i) an annual borrowing limit or date-related target for reaching some form of balanced budget, and (ii) a limit or date-related target for debt as a % of GDP. However, it should be noted that any such benchmarks are not rooted in any well evidenced research or in any widely accepted theory of optimal debt.

It is also interesting to note that, pre recession, such rules tended to apply to maximums for annual borrowing limits (e.g. the EU s 3% of GDP) and for debt as a % of GDP (e.g. the UK s 40% limit). However, post recession, with such rules largely abandoned, the new rules apply to turning round the current, unsustainable positions. So we get the UK s current debt target as simply that it is falling, but with no sign as to what level it should fall to. On balancing the budget the target relates to the timing of reaching a such a balance, but with little indication of the longer term desired position. Inevitably the current UK fiscal rules will change in the medium term to take into account the current targets having been reached, but it remains unclear what these future targets might be. Furthermore, changes over time are also likely to occur, in line with the changing UK political discourse. It may well be that, due to the relative sizes involved, any such UK changes will take the lead on this, with Scotland being expected to follow suit. Despite the somewhat random nature of these targets, setting fiscal rules may still prove to be a worthwhile exercise. Academic research (1) suggests that such rules, along with supporting institutions, can help to achieve greater fiscal discipline, as the combination tends to force governments to better address unsustainable fiscal positions. Equally it gives markets confidence in the direction of travel and so allows for market borrowing without penalising costs. In general terms, and regardless of the actual targets, consistency of fiscal rules across the UK would be beneficial in terms of transparency and coherency and in terms of improving the likelihood of a mood of co-operation over effective management between government s. What mechanisms are required to ensure the transparency and effective scrutiny of how the block grant is calculated including the operation of the Barnett formula? What mechanisms are required to ensure the transparency and effective scrutiny of adjustments to the block grant to reflect the tax revenues foregone by the UK Government? What mechanisms are required to ensure the effective working of the no detriment principle? (Taken together) On the assumption that the system outlined by the Smith Commission and in the Command Paper is what is going to be put in place then the key questions concern how the actual workings of the Barnett formula will be revised and, in particular, how it is adjusted over time. The original Barnett system is very simple, contrary to popular belief, and that is one of the reasons it was introduced and has lasted so long. As soon as you move away from this simplicity (including to the 2012 Act) then anomalies and difficulties start to emerge.

The Command Paper offers two worked examples (see para 2.4.14) of how the adjustment process will work. However, these examples are somewhat opaque and less than comprehensive. As an alternative Annex 1, here, expands on how the adjustment process works in practice and, hopefully, clarifies the outcomes. The results are not always intuitively obvious. For this reason it may take some time for government s and the public to become comfortable with such adjustments. This means that there may be, initially at least, considerable scope for discontent over the adjustment process, from either side. With regards to the no detriment principle, one key issue relates to the position where the raising of existing taxes is not equally spread across the UK. For example, Scotland s share of Income Tax (IT) is notably lower than its population share (7.3% vs 8.3%) and this is largely down to fewer tax payers in the higher rate bracket. This has two major implications. First, any adjustment to the UK higher tax rate could disproportionately benefit or cost Scotland, depending on which share is used. Second, it means that, based on recent experience, Scottish IT revenues are likely to grow more slowly than the UK s. Furthermore, if the UK population continues to rise faster than that of Scotland then IT is also likely to rise faster and so Scotland could, again, lose out. To compensate for this, any adjustment process may want to move in line with changes in UK IT per capita. The downside to this is that it does not allow Scotland to benefit from any net migration rise through being seen as a more attractive place to live and work. Although, as the Smith recommendations do not include powers over immigration, the scope to achieve this may be limited. Furthermore, the IT tax base will alter over time as a result of different demographics, either through ageing or through net migration patterns. This could affect what is seen as fair in terms of the no detriment principle. Complexity over time - Individual taxes may come and go, specific benefits are even more likely to come and go. As a result, over time it will be very difficult to follow what is the correct adjustment is for a change in Scottish or UK policy. Even without the introduction of new taxes and benefits, over time the complexity will inevitably grow as rates and thresholds change and the calculation of the no detriment compensation amount will become less precise. On the assumption that such imprecision will not be biased one way or the other it may be easiest to simply accept that this will be the case and that the swings and roundabouts will balance out. Second round impacts - While Scotland will keep any above UK trend increase in IT, such an outcome suggests higher economic growth which should also result in higher growth in VAT (and other) receipts. At present, Scotland would receive a share of this increase, but not its full, higher than UK growth, share. Whether any attempt will be made to incorporate such second round effects into the adjustment process is not clear at present.

A revised Barnett formula will also heighten awareness of the existing faults within the formula. The IFS have already highlighted one such issue, with regards to the treatment of business rates income. Another relates to the fact that the formula was originally designed to reduce the spending per head advantage seen for Scotland (and Wales and NI) over time. This convergence feature will remain as part of a revised Barnett formula, with no lower limit over how close the spending per head levels can get. A third concern relates to how differential population growth rates affect the fairness of Barnett, as historical spending levels are maintained but new funds are allotted purely on an, annually updated, population basis. What additional borrowing powers for current spending and for capital spending should the Scottish Government have? What fiscal rules should be applied to these additional borrowing powers? (Taken together) A number of basic issues arise in relation to the correct approach to borrowing powers. - First, whether any limit applies and if it does whether it is fixed or variable. Some degree of adjustment to the economic and fiscal conditions that apply at the time is likely to be warranted, but it is difficult to be precise in such matters. The comments made above re fiscal rules in general are again relevant here. With regards to the borrowing for current versus capital spending issue, it is unclear whether such limits can be strictly applied in practice. This also brings up the issue of whether it is still necessary for Barnett to distinguish between current and capital consequentials. Given the extra responsibility being given to the Scottish government in a number of new areas, it seems odd that this restriction on the Scottish Parliament is still in place. - Second, whether borrowing is undertaken indirectly via the UK government or directly, or both. This is likely to have a bearing on the cost of future borrowing. - Third, how any borrowing responsibility/limits are split between local and central government in Scotland. What is the role that should be played by elected Scottish local authorities in agreeing borrowing limits and rules? - Fourth, the ability of the Scottish government to top up any existing UK benefit brings into question what borrowing limit applies as it could, in practice, put an effective ceiling on the scope for such adjustments. There is much scope for further discussion of each of these points although the final decisions are likely to result from political negotiation rather than from reference to academic research findings, such as they are.

How should inter-governmental machinery including the Joint Exchequer Committee be strengthened and made more transparent? What mechanisms should there be for reviewing the Statement of Funding Policy? What should be the role and remit of an enhanced Scottish Fiscal Commission and who should be responsible for generating the economic and fiscal forecasts? (Taken together) It is likely that the current nature of the JEC meetings, which are occasional and involve senior politicians, makes them unsuitable for a leading role in the future. Although such a body will no doubt need to continue, in order to give final approval to negotiations taking place at a lower level. The existing Scottish Fiscal Commission will need to be expanded in terms of its funding and staffing levels to undertake the work it will need to do. It s remit is likely to be similar to that for the OBR, as, like the OBR, its most important role will be to bring neutral information and analysis to the table, in order to enhance clarity and minimise the room for dispute. Similarly the Finance Department of the Scottish government will need to be expanded and better staffed. The overall result should be something akin to a Scottish Treasury and OBR, though on smaller in scale. As at the UK level, these two bodies will need to work closely with each other in order to fulfil their new roles. A better model of the Scottish economy and its finances is essential. It should be provided by either the OBR or its Scottish equivalent. This will not be easy as the current quality and breadth of economic and fiscal data available for Scotland is relatively poor. What lessons can we learn from the experience of other fiscal federations? There are always inconsistencies and quirks with regards to any regional or federal funding system but many other countries manage to survive them. Nevertheless, the UK s asymmetry of powers in the existing quasi federal system is almost unique, Spain may be the closest to it (2). This makes the ability to attain a fair, transparent, effective and mechanical system all the more difficult. In Scotland s case it will also be highly devolved in the sense of full autonomy over setting of some taxes, as opposed to the use of assigned tax revenues. No other country has fully devolved IT to a region (save the Basque region of Spain), usually it is assigned rather than fully devolved e.g. Germany. Hence, it may well be that few international lessons are available, as all systems are different. Notes (1) See for example: Fiscal Rules: Theoretical Issues and Historical Experiences, NBER Working Paper No. 17884, 2012; and Fiscal Rules in Response to the Crisis - Towards the Next-Generation Rules, IMF Working Paper, WP/12/187.

(2) See for example: Fiscal Devolution - some comparative examples, SPICe Briefing Paper 14/88; and Designing a European Fiscal Union: Lessons from Experience of Fiscal Federations, IMF, 2014.

Annex 1 - Mechanics of (Rest of) UK Income Tax change example. If the UK government raises the Income Tax (IT) rate post Smith, then more IT is raised in the RUK but the amount raised in Scotland is unchanged. This extra revenue could be used a number of ways: - to offset reductions in other taxes, keeping overall (R)UK revenues the same - to be spent on services that are devolved (like the NHS) - to be spent on services that are not devolved (like Defence) - to be spent on reducing borrowing (and so debt levels and future debt interest related payments) If the extra RUK IT revenues were spent on devolved services then Scotland s block budget would rise, through the continued use of the Barnett formula, even though Scots were not paying any more in tax. To adjust for this, it is assumed there would be a further, offsetting, cut in the Scottish block to return it to its previous position. Hence, if Scotland wanted the extra spending seen in the RUK then it too would need to raise the IT rate in order to access this extra funding. In each of the other cases outlined above the argument is slightly different but the appropriate outcome is the same. For example, if the rise in UK IT was spent on reserved areas like Defence or Pensions then Scotland also benefits from increased expenditure on these shared resources. Hence, a cut in the Scottish block might be considered appropriate, with Scotland then also having to raise the IT rate in order to pay for its share of this extra spend on shared services. Otherwise it could be seen as a free lunch scenario. Clearly a similar situation would happen if the reverse were true. If RUK reduced the rate of IT, this would feed through to lower spending in Scotland, either directly via the Barnett formula working, or indirectly through lower spend on public services in relation to Scotland. This in turn implies an increase in the Scottish block to adjust for this i.e. Scotland is still paying at the higher rate of income tax but is receiving less of a service (of some kind) and so needs to be compensated, i.e. it is neither receiving the new benefit of a lower tax rate nor the old benefit of the higher spend on the NHS/Defence/Pensions etc. Scotland could then choose whether to reduce the IT rate by a similar amount in order to benefit from a similar tax cut (and cut in its budget) or to continue to spend the extra, transferred, money on services. If this impact were in relation to devolved spending, like the NHS, then the increase in the Block grant would be to offset the Barnett related cut to the Block.

If it was in relation to reserved spending, like Pensions, then the increase would be to allow for higher pensions in Scotland, although this may need to be done indirectly e.g. through a huge increase in pensioner winter allowance or the introduction of a new benefit. Effectively the higher rate of Scottish IT (than in the RUK) would be paying for this.