Lecture 6 Search and matching theory

Similar documents
Lecture 3: Employment and Unemployment

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Third Edition

Macroeconomics of the Labour Market Problem Set

SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment

7 Unemployment. 7.1 Introduction. JEM004 Macroeconomics IES, Fall 2017 Lecture Notes Eva Hromádková

Employment, Unemployment and Turnover

Lecture 3 Shapiro-Stiglitz Model of Efficiency Wages

Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr, Prat, Schmerer (2011)

Workers and Firms sorting into Temporary Jobs

Online Appendix for Revisiting Unemployment in Intermediate Macro: A New Approach for Teaching Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides

Collective bargaining, firm heterogeneity and unemployment

New Business Start-ups and the Business Cycle

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 7 - Labor markets: Introduction & the search model March. Sciences Po

Unemployment and Matching in the Labor Market. A Model of Search and Matching in the Labor Market

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model

PERMANENT UNEMPLOYMENT, A REFLECTION OF CHANGING THE BASIC STRUCTURE OF ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES

1 The Solow Growth Model

Chapter II: Labour Market Policy

Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations

Lecture 24 Unemployment. Noah Williams

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

14 Unemployment. Why unemployment? So far we have studied models where labor market clears. Is that a good assumption? Why is unemployment important?

Lecture Notes. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University

Practice Problems for the DMP Model

Aggregate Demand and the Dynamics of Unemployment

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

1 Dynamic programming

The long term unemployed have a harder time finding jobs than the short term

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

ECONOMY IN THE LONG RUN. Chapter 6. Unemployment. October 23, Chapter 6: Unemployment. ECON204 (A01). Fall 2012

The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models. European Summer Symposium in International Macroeconomics, May 2015 Tarragona, Spain

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Dynamic Macroeconomics

TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Unemployment, tax evasion and the slippery slope framework

SUMMER TERM 2017 ECON1604: ECONOMICS I (Combined Studies)

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Keynesian Inefficiency and Optimal Policy: A New Monetarist Approach

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Chapter 3. National Income: Where it Comes from and Where it Goes

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Gross Worker Flows and the Great Recession in the United Kingdom: Examining the Theory and Evidence. Andrew J. Sutton

Staggered Wages, Sticky Prices, and Labor Market Dynamics in Matching Models. by Janett Neugebauer and Dennis Wesselbaum

Chapter 6 Classical Theory of. Unemployment

CHAPTER 13. Duration of Spell (in months) Exit Rate

9 D/S of/for Labor. 9.1 Demand for Labor. Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009

ECON 442:ECONOMIC THEORY II (MACRO) 8 1: W/C

Lecture Notes # 4 Tito Boeri

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Econ 223 Lecture notes 2: Determination of output and income Classical closed economy equilibrium

Market Reforms in a Monetary Union: Macroeconomic and Policy Implications

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ABSTRACT. Alejandro Gabriel Rasteletti, Ph.D., Prof. John Haltiwanger and Prof. John Shea, Department of Economics

Chapter 6 : Unemployment

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

Chapter 7. Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth (The Very Long Run) CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I. slide 0

Reducing Supply-Side Disincentives

1 No capital mobility

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Unemployment and the Labor Market

Chapter 3: Productivity, Output, and Employment

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Examination Period 3: 2016/17

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

LABOR-MARKET VOLATILITY IN A MATCHING MODEL WITH WORKER HETEROGENEITY AND ENDOGENOUS SEPARATIONS

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries

Keynes in Nutshell: A New Monetarist Approach (Incomplete)

Outline for ECON 701's Second Midterm (Spring 2005)

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

Macroeconomics. Part Two: Unemployment and Money. Dr. Ali Moghaddasi Kelishomi. Warwick Economics Summer School 2016

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Final Exam Solutions

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Dynamic Models Of Labor Demand

Theory of the rate of return

Online Appendix: Extensions

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Labor Economics. Basic Job Search Model. Winter 2014/2015. Bonn University

Answers To Chapter 14

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

1 Unemployment Insurance

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters

Tax Wedge and Job Distribution in a Directed Search Model

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

6/16/2008. Unemployment. In this chapter, you will learn. Assumptions: Natural rate of unemployment. A first model of the natural rate

Transcription:

Lecture 6 Search and matching theory Leszek Wincenciak, Ph.D. University of Warsaw

2/48 Lecture outline: Introduction Search and matching theory Search and matching theory The dynamics of unemployment Job creation by firms Wage determination Steady state Comparative statics

Introduction 3/48 Introduction Even in the absence of marked changes in overall employment, there are simultaneous processes of job creation and destruction, reaching 20% of total employment in manufacturing during a year Workers are searching for the best jobs Firms are looking for the best workers Searching for job or a worker and matching takes time and is costly This leads to frictional unemployment

Search and matching theory 4/48 Search and matching theory Search and matching theory

Search and matching theory 5/48 Search and matching theory Frictional unemployment Firms create job openings (vacancies) Workers search for jobs Match of a worker and a vacancy results in a productive job Matching is not coordinated (workers and firms dedicate time and resources to find a suitable match) Probability that a firm or a worker find the partner depends on a relative number of vacant jobs and unemployed workers labour supply (L) = unemployed + employed labour demand = filled jobs + vacancies

Search and matching theory 6/48 Search and matching theory Total number of unemployed workers ul Total number of vacancies vl Total number of matches between unemployed workers and vacant firms in each unit of time ml The process of matching is summarized by a matching function, which expresses the number of newly created jobs (ml) as a function of the number of unemployed workers (ul) and vacancies (vl): ml = m(ul, vl) (1)

Search and matching theory 7/48 Search and matching theory The matching function, assumed to be increasing in both arguments, can be thought of as similar to aggregate production function. Workers and vacant jobs can be viewed as productive inputs which produce a match, which results in a productive job. Creation of employment requires presence of both unemployed workers and vacant jobs m(0, 0) = m(0,vl)=m(ul, 0) = 0. Typically it is assumed that matching function exhibits a constant returns to scale (empirical evidence seems to support this assumption).

Search and matching theory 8/48 Search and matching theory In case of CRS matching function, we can write: m(ul, vl) m = = m(u, v). (2) L The function m( ) determines the flow of workers who find a job and who exit the unemployment pool within each time interval. Consider the case of an unemployed worker: at each moment in time, the worker will find a job with probability p = m( )/u. With constant returns to scale for m( ) we may thus write: m(u, v) u ( = m 1, v ) p(θ), (3) u where θ = v/u is called the labour market tightness.

Search and matching theory 9/48 Search and matching theory The instantaneous probability p that a worker finds a job is positively related to the tightness of the labour market which is measured by θ, the ratio between the number of vacancies and unemployed workers. An increase in θ, reflecting a relative abundance of vacant jobs relative to unemployed workers, leads to an increase in p.

Search and matching theory 10/48 Search and matching theory The average length of an unemployment spell is given by 1/p(θ), and is thus inversely related to θ. Similarly, the rate at which a vacant job is matched to a worker may be expressed as: m(u, v) v ( = m 1, v ) u u v = p(θ) q(θ), (4) θ a decreasing function of the vacancy/unemployment ratio. An increase in θ reduces the probability that a vacancy is filled and 1/q(θ) measures the average time that elapses before a vacancy is filled. The dependence of p and q on θ captures the dual externality between agents in the labour market: an increase in the number of vacancies relative to unemployed workers increases the probability thataworkerfindsajob(dp( )/dv > 0), but at the same time it reduces the probability that a vacancy is filled (dq( )/dv < 0).

Search and matching theory 11/48 The dynamics of unemployment The dynamics of unemployment

Search and matching theory 12/48 The dynamics of unemployment The dynamics of unemployment Changes in unemployment result from a difference between the flow of workers who lose their job and become unemployed, and the flow of workers who find a job. The inflow into unemployment is determined by the separation rate which we take as given for the moment: at each moment in time a fraction s of jobs (corresponding to a fraction 1 u of the labour force) is hit by a shock that reduces the productivity of the match to zero: in this case the worker loses her job and returns to the pool of unemployed, while the firm is free to open up a vacancy in order to bring employment back to its original level. Given match destruction rate s, jobs therefore remain productive for an average period of 1/s.

Search and matching theory 13/48 The dynamics of unemployment Given these assumptions we can now describe the dynamics of the number of unemployed workers. Since L is constant, d(ul)/dt = ul and hence: ul = s(1 u)l p(θ)ul u = s(1 u) p(θ)u. (5) The dynamics of the unemployment rate depend on the tightness of the labour market θ: at a high value for the ratio of vacancies to unemployed workers, workers easily find a job leading to a large flow out of unemployment.

Search and matching theory 14/48 The dynamics of unemployment From equation (5) we can immediately derive the steady state relationship between the unemployment rate and θ: u = s s + p(θ). (6) Since p ( ) > 0, the properties of the matching function determine a negative relation between θ and u. To obtain job creation and destruction rates, we may divide the flows into and out of employment by the total number of employed workers (1 u)l. The rate of destruction is simply equal to s, while the rate of job creation is given by p(θ)[u/(1 u)].

Search and matching theory 15/48 The dynamics of unemployment θ v v = θ 0 u θ 0 v 0 u 0 u =0 u θ 0 u 0 u =0 u Figure 1. Dynamics of the unemployment rate

Search and matching theory 16/48 The dynamics of unemployment The steady-state relationship (6) is illustrated graphically in the left panel of Figure 1: to each value of θ corresponds a unique value for the unemployment rate. Moreover, the same properties of m( ) ensure that this curve is convex. For points above or below u =0, the unemployment rate tends to move towards the stationary relationship: keeping θ constant at θ 0,avalueu>u 0 causes an increase in the flow out of unemployment and a decrease of the flow into unemployment, bringing u back to u 0.

Search and matching theory 17/48 The dynamics of unemployment Moreover, given u and θ, the number of vacancies is uniquely determined by v = θu, wherev denotes the number of vacancies as a proportion of the labour force. The picture on the right hand side of the figure shows the curve u =0in (v, u) space. This locus is known as the Beveridge curve, and identifies the level of vacancies v 0 that corresponds to the pair (θ 0,u 0 ) of the left hand panel of the Figure 1. It is important to note that variations in the labour market tightness are associated with a movement along the curve u =0, while changes in the separation rate s or the efficiency of the matching process (captured by the properties of the matching function) correspond to movements of the curve u =0.

Search and matching theory 18/48 The dynamics of unemployment 4 2001 Jan 2016 Jul 2015 Apr Jul 2016 Jan 2015 Apr 2015 Oct Job vacancy rate 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 2001 Apr 2007 Apr 2007 2001 2006 Jan Jul Apr 2006 Oct 2006 20072005 Jan Jul 2005 Oct JulApr 2007 20062008 Oct Jul Jan 2008 Apr 2004 Jul 2004 2002 2003 OctJan Jan 2005 20012004 Jan Oct 2008 AprJul 2004 2002 2002 Jan Oct 2008 AprAug 2002 2003 JulApr 2014 2015 Oct Jan 2003 2003 Oct 2008 Jul Oct 2014 Jul 2014 Apr 2014 Jan 2013 Oct 2013 2013 Jul Apr 2009 Jan 2012 2013 Oct 2012 JanApr Jul Jan 2009 Apr Jan 2001 Jul 2008 Aug 2008 Jul 2009 Aug 2009 Jul 2016 2011 Jul 2011 Oct 2009 Jul 2011 Apr 2010 Oct 20112010 Jan Jul 2010 Apr 2010 Jan 2009 Aug 2009 Oct 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Unemployment rate Figure 2. Beveridge curve for USA, 2001-2016 (BLS)

Search and matching theory 19/48 The dynamics of unemployment Equation (6) gives a first steady state relationship between u and θ. To find the actual equilibrium values, we need to specify a second relationship between these variables. This second relationship can be derived from the behavior of firms and workers on the labour market.

Search and matching theory 20/48 Jobcreationbyfirms Job creation by firms

Search and matching theory 21/48 Jobcreationbyfirms Jobcreationbyfirms The crucial decision of firms concerns the supply of vacancies on the labour market. The decision of a firm whether to create a vacancy depends on the expected future profits over the entire time horizon of the firm, which we assume to be infinite. Formally, each individual firm solves an intertemporal optimization problem taking as given the aggregate labour market conditions which are summarized by θ, the labour market tightness. Individual firms therefore disregard the effect of their decisions on θ, and consequently on the matching rates p(θ) and q(θ). To simplify the analysis, we assume that each firm can offer at most one job. If the job is filled, the firm receives a constant flow of output equal to y. Moreover, it pays a wage w to the worker and it takes this wage as given. The determination of this wage will be described later on.

Search and matching theory 22/48 Jobcreationbyfirms On the contrary, if the job is not filled, the firm incurs a flow cost c, which reflects the time and resources invested in the search for suitable workers. Firms therefore find it attractive to create a vacancy as long as its value, measured in terms of expected profits, is non-negative; in the opposite case, the firm will not find it attractive to offer a vacancy and will exit the labour market. The value that a firm attributes to a vacancy (denoted by V )andto a filled job (J) can be expressed using the asset equations. Given a constant real interest rate r, we can express these values as: rv (t) = c + q(θ(t))(j(t) V (t)) + V (t), (7) rj(t) =(y w(t)) + s(v (t) J(t)) + J(t). (8)

Search and matching theory 23/48 Jobcreationbyfirms (7) and (8) are explicit functions of time. The flow return of a vacancy is equal to a negative cost component ( c), plusthe capital gain in case the job is filled with a worker (J V ), which occurs with probability q(θ), plus the change in the value of the vacancy itself ( V ). Similarly, (8) defines the flow return of a filled job as the value of the flow output minus the wage (y w), plus the capital loss (V J) in case the job is destroyed, which occurs with probability s, plus the change in the value of the job ( J).

Search and matching theory 24/48 Jobcreationbyfirms Subtracting (7) from (8) yields the following expression for the difference in value between a filled job and a vacancy: r(j(t) V (t)) =(y w(t)+c) [s + q(θ(t))](j(t) V (t)) +( J(t) V (t)). (9)

Search and matching theory 25/48 Jobcreationbyfirms Now, if we focus on steady state equilibria we can impose V = J =0in equations (7) and (8). Moreover, we assume free entry of firms and as a result V =0: new firms continue to offer vacant jobs until the value of the marginal vacancy is reduced to zero. Substituting V =0in (7) and (8) and combining the resulting expressions for J, weget: J = c/q(θ) J =(y w)/(r + s) } y w =(r + s) c q(θ). (10) Equation (7) gives us the first expression for J. According to this condition the equilibrium value of a filled job is equal to the expected costs of a vacancy, that is the flow cost of a vacancy c times the average duration of a vacancy 1/q(θ).

Search and matching theory 26/48 Jobcreationbyfirms The second condition for J can be derived from (8): the value of a filled job is equal to the value of the constant profit flow y w. These flow returns are discounted at rate r + s to account for both impatience and the risk that the match breaks down. Equating these two expressions yields the final solution (10), which gives the marginal condition for employment in a steady state equilibrium: the marginal productivity of the worker (y) needs to compensate the firm for the wage w paid to the worker and for the flow cost of opening a vacancy. The latter is equal to the product of the discount rate r + s and the expected costs of a vacancy c/q(θ).

Search and matching theory 27/48 Jobcreationbyfirms This last term is just like an adjustment cost for the firm s employment level. It introduces a wedge between the marginal productivity of labour and the wage rate. However, in this model the size of the adjustment cost is endogenous and depends on the aggregate conditions on the labour market. In equilibrium, the size of the adjustment costs depend on the unemployment rate and on the number of vacancies, which are summarized at the aggregate level by the value of θ. If, for example, the value of output minus wages (y w) increases, then vacancy creation will become profitable (V > 0) and more firms will offer jobs. As a result, θ will increase, leading to a reduction in the matching rate for firms and an increase in the average cost of a vacancy and both these effects tend to bring the value of a vacancy back to zero.

Search and matching theory 28/48 Jobcreationbyfirms Finally, notice that equation (10) still contains the wage rate w. This is an endogenous variable. Hence the job creation condition (10) is not yet the steady state condition which together with (6) would allow us to solve for the equilibrium values of u and θ. To complete the model we need to analyze the process of wage determination, to which we now turn.

Search and matching theory 29/48 Wage determination Wage determination

Search and matching theory 30/48 Wage determination Wage determination The process of wage determination that we adopt here is based on the fact that the successful creation of a match generates a surplus. That is, the value of a pair of agents that have agreed to match (the value of a filled job and an employed worker) is larger than the value of these agents before the match (the value of a vacancy and an unemployed worker). This surplus has the nature of a monopolistic rent and needs to be shared between the firm and the worker during the wage negotiations. Here we shall assume that wages are negotiated at a decentralized level between each individual worker and her employer. Since workers and firms are identical, all jobs will therefore pay the same wage.

Search and matching theory 31/48 Wage determination Wage determination Let E and U denote the value that a worker attributes to employment and unemployment, respectively. The joint value of a match (given by the value of a filled job for the firm and the valueofemploymentfortheworker)canthenbeexpressedas J + E, while the joint value in case the match opportunity is not exploited (given by the value of a vacancy for a firm and the value of unemployment for a worker) is equal to V + U. The total surplus of the match is thus equal to the sum of the firm s surplus, J V, and the worker s surplus, E U: (J + E) (V + U) (J V )+(E U). (11)

Search and matching theory 32/48 Wage determination Wage determination The match surplus is divided between the firm and the worker through a wage bargaining process. We take their relative bargaining strength to be exogenously given. Formally, we adopt the assumption of Nash bargaining. This assumption is common in models of bilateral negotiations. It implies that the bargained wage maximizes a geometric average of the surplus of the firm and the worker, each weighted by a measure of their relative bargaining strength (Nash maximand). In our case the assumption of Nash bargaining gives rise to the following optimization problem: max (J V w )1 β (E U) β, (12) where 0 β 1 denotes the relative bargaining strength of the worker.

Search and matching theory 33/48 Wage determination Wage determination Given that the objective function is a Cobb-Douglas one, we can immediately express the solution (the first order conditions) of the problem as: E U = β (J V ) E U = β[(j V )+(E U)]. (13) 1 β The surplus that the worker appropriates in the wage negotiations (E U) is thus equal to a fraction β of the total surplus of the job.

Search and matching theory 34/48 Wage determination Similar to what is done for V and J in (7) and (8), we can express the values E and U using the relevant asset equations (reintroducing the dependence on time t): re(t) =w(t)+s(u(t) E(t)) + Ė(t) (14) ru(t) =z + p(θ)(e(t) U(t)) + U(t). (15) For the worker the flow return on employment is equal to the wage plus the loss in value if the worker and the firm separate, which occurs with probability s, plus any change in the value of E itself; the return on unemployment is given by the imputed value of the time that a worker does not spend working, denoted by z, plus the gain if she finds a job and the change in the value of U. Parameter z includes the value of leisure and/or the value of alternative sources of income including possible unemployment benefits. It is assumed to be exogenous and fixed.

Search and matching theory 35/48 Wage determination Restricting attention to steady state equilibria, so that Ė = U =0, we can derive the surplus of the worker E U directly from (14) and (15). E U = w z r + s + p(θ). (16) According to (16) the surplus of a worker depends positively on the difference between the flow return during employment and unemployment (w z) and negatively on the separation rate s and on θ: an increase in the ratio of vacancies to unemployed workers increases the exit rate out of unemployment and reduces the average length of an unemployment spell.

Search and matching theory 36/48 Wage determination Using (16) and noting that in steady state equilibrium J V = J = y w r + s, we can solve the expression for the outcome of the wage negotiations given by (13) as: w z r + s + p(θ) = β y w 1 β r + s. Rearranging terms, and using (10), we obtain the following equivalent expressions for the wage: w z = β[(y + cθ w)+(w z)] (17) w = z + β(y + cθ z). (18)

Search and matching theory 37/48 Wage determination From equation (17) it follows that the flow value of the worker s surplus, i.e. the difference between the wage (w) and alternative income z, isafractionβ of the total flow surplus. The term (y w + cθ) represents the flow surplus of the firm, where cθ denotes the expected cost savings if the firm fills a job. If we eliminate the wage payments in (17) we obtain the flow value of the total surplus of a filled job (y + cθ z), which is equal to the sum of the value of output and the cost saving of the firm minus the alternative costs of the worker. Finally, equation (18) expresses the wage as the sum of the alternative income and the fraction of the surplus that accrues to the worker.

Search and matching theory 38/48 Wage determination It can easily be verified that the only influence of aggregate labour market conditions on the wage occur via θ, the ratio of vacancies to unemployed workers. The unemployment rate u does not have any independent effect on wages. The explanation is that wages are negotiated after a firm and a worker meet. In this situation the match surplus depends on θ, as we saw above. This variable determines the average duration of a vacancy, and hence the expected costs for the firm if it would continue to search. The determination of the equilibrium wage completes the description of the steady state equilibrium.

Search and matching theory 39/48 Steady state Steady state

Search and matching theory 40/48 Steady state Steady state The steady state equilibrium can be summarized by equations (6), (10) and (18) which we shall refer to as BC (Beveridge curve), JC (job creation condition)andw (wage equation): s u = s + p(θ) (BC) (19) c w = y (r + s) q(θ) (JC) (20) w =(1 β)z + β(y + cθ) (W ) (21)

Search and matching theory 41/48 Steady state For a given value of θ, the wage is independent of the unemployment rate. The system can therefore be solved recursively for the endogenous variables u, θ and w. Using the definition for θ wecanthensolveforv. The last two equations jointly determine the equilibrium wage w and the ratio of vacancies/unemployed θ, as is shown in the left panel of Figure 5. Given θ, wecanthen determine the unemployment rate u, and consequently also v, which equate the flows into and out of unemployment (the right hand panel of the figure).

Search and matching theory 42/48 Steady state w v JC + W W w 0 v 0 θ 0 JC θ θ 0 u 0 BC u Figure 3. Equilibrium of the labour market with frictional unemployment

Search and matching theory 43/48 Comparative statics Comparative statics

Search and matching theory 44/48 Comparative statics Comparative statics This dual representation facilitates the static comparative analysis, which is intended to analyze the effect of changes in the parameters on the steady state equilibrium. Scenario 1: Assume, that we observe an increase in unemployment benefits, a component of z, oranincreaseintherelative bargaining strength of workers β.

Search and matching theory 45/48 Comparative statics Comparative statics, z or β w W v JC + W w 1 w 0 θ 1 θ 0 W JC θ v 0 v 1 θ 0 θ 1 u 0 u 1 JC + W BC u Figure 4. Theeffectsofanincreaseinz or β

Search and matching theory 46/48 Comparative statics Interpretation As a result of an increase in unemployment benefits (captured by z) or an increase in the bargaining power of the workers (captured by β) the wage curve defined by (21) shifts upwards. This causes an increase in the wage and a reduction in the labour market tightness, θ. This reduction, along the Beveridge Curve (BC), is accompanied by an increase in u and a reduction in v. Scenario 2: Consider now a reallocative shock, i.e. the increase in the separation rate s.

Search and matching theory 47/48 Comparative statics Comparative statics, s w W v JC + W w 0 w 1 JC + W θ 1 θ 0 JC JC θ? θ 0 θ 1 u 0 u 1 BC BC u Figure 5. The effects of an adverse reallocative shock

Search and matching theory 48/48 Comparative statics In the case of a reallocative shock we observe an inward shift of JC along W schedule. This results in a joint decrease of the wage and the labour market tightness θ, as in the case of the aggregate shock. At the same time, however, the Beveridge Curve BC shifts to the right. Hence, while the unemployment rate increases unambiguously, it is in general not possible to determine the effect on the rate of vacancies. In reality, however, v appears to be procyclical and this suggests that an increase of the separation rate will reduce the rate of vacancies.