Taxation and Subsidies for Housing and Land: Market Impacts and Economic Efficiency Implications

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Taxation and Subsidies for Housing and Land: Market Impacts and Economic Efficiency Implications"

Transcription

1 Taxation and Subsidies for Housing and Land: Market Impacts and Economic Efficiency Implications Peter Abelson Macquarie University Abstract This paper quantifies the major subsidies and taxes separately for the homeowner and rental sectors, analyses the effects of these fiscal measures on house prices and housing consumption in the owner-occupier and investor/renter sectors, and quantifies the efficiency effects. The paper estimates that the private housing sector receives a net subsidy of $7.0 billion per annum. Almost the whole subsidy accrues to homeowners, who receive about a 10 per cent subsidy on imputed gross rentals. There is minimal net subsidy to the rental sector. On plausible demand and supply assumptions, a 10 per cent subsidy to homeowners raises housing consumption by about 3.4 per cent and raises house prices also by an estimated 3.4 per cent. The housing subsidy produces an estimated deadweight loss from expenditure on renovations of about $100 million per annum. However, contrary to previous work, the paper finds that the housing subsidy produces welfare gains from expenditure on new housing in the order of $150 million a year. This arises because the subsidy offsets the over-regulated supply of new housing. However, transaction taxes on housing have a separate deadweight cost on asset exchange of $375 million per annum. Also, the unequal treatment of homeowners and renters has a small annual deadweight cost. JEL classification H20, H21, R31 Acknowledgements I thank Roselyne Joyeux for her assistance in the preparation of this paper. Any errors are my responsibility. Note: Paper to be presented to the 34 th Australian Conference of Economists in Melbourne in September Any comments on the paper are welcome.

2 Taxation and Subsidies for Housing and Land: Market Impacts and Economic Efficiency Implications 1 Introduction Residential property attracts concurrently numerous taxes and substantial subsidies. Governments typically view property as an irresistible sitting target for taxation. In Australia, taxes on housing include land taxes, local council rates, stamp duties on property transfers, numerous developer charges, the goods and services tax (GST) on sales of new dwellings and renovations of existing dwellings, and capital gains taxes on rental property and second homes. On the other hand governments recognise that housing is a fundamental component of household welfare. Many households spend a quarter or more of their income on housing. Housing is also a major vehicle for household saving. Thus, in Australia there is no income taxation of imputed rent, no expenditure taxes on rents, and no capital gains tax for owneroccupied housing. There are grants to assist first home buyers and rent subsidies for low income households in private and public housing. In this paper I analyse the market impacts and efficiency implications of these fiscal measures. Section 2 describes and quantifies the main taxes and subsidies that affect housing. Section 3 analyses the impacts of these fiscal provisions on house prices and housing consumption in both the owner-occupier and investor/renter sectors. Section 4 analyses the efficiency effects. 2 Housing Taxes and Subsidies in Australia Table 1 shows the main taxes and subsidies relating to housing in Australia. The taxes include local government rates and developer charges that may be regarded as user payments, which is an issue discussed further below. The subsidies are divided into tax concessions and public expenditure subsidies. As will be discussed, some tax concessions are economy-wide concessions, but they have a particularly strong impact on the housing sector. Before quantifying these measures, two general points should be noted. First, the notion and size of a tax concession depends critically on the definition of an appropriate tax base or benchmark. For example, to quantify capital gains tax concessions, most commentators compare the revenue in the concessionary case (nil for owner-occupiers) with the potential revenue from a tax on all nominal capital gains. Arguably, a preferred benchmark would be revenue from a tax on real capital gains. Similar issues arise with estimates of the magnitudes of other tax concessions. Second, the effects of tax concessions depend on various factors such as marginal income tax rates and inflation rates. The higher are marginal tax rates, the greater are the effects of the concessions. Also the effects of fiscal measures like capital gains tax concessions and negative gearing depend on the rate of inflation. 2

3 Table 1 Tax or subsidy Tax concessions Non-taxation of imputed rents Non-taxation of rental services Concessional capital gains taxes Tax treatment of losses on rental property (negative gearing) Public expenditure subsidies Major Australian taxes and subsidies affecting housing Main features Imputed rental income is not assessed as part of taxable income. There is no consumption tax on imputed or actual housing rents. (a) Home owner-occupiers pay no capital gains tax. (b) Property investors pay tax on half the nominal capital gains. Investors can deduct 100 per cent of nominal losses from rental property against other taxable income. First home owner grants Grants of $7000 to first home owner purchasers since 1 July Assistance to private renters Assistance to public housing tenants Main taxes on land and housing State land taxes Local government land taxes Stamp duties on transfers of land and housing GST on home maintenance and renovations, land sales and new buildings Infrastructure developer charges Australian Government provides rental subsidies to low income persons, who comprise about one quarter of all private renters. State governments provide public housing to 5 per cent of all Australian households - in most cases at below market rents. States taxes on value of land used for rental properties and second homes. Some land taxes on premium value owner-occupied property. Local governments levy land taxes (rates) on most residential properties. Most state governments levy stamp duty on value of property when it is transferred. 10% GST applies to (a) maintenance and renovation expenditure for existing housing and (b) sales of land and new buildings. Most state and local governments levy infrastructure charges on developers. Tax provisions that assist housing Four tax provisions substantially assist housing. They are the exclusion of imputed rents from the income tax base, the exclusion of all housing rents from any expenditure tax base, the exemption of owner-occupied housing from the capital gains tax (CGT), and the asymmetric income tax treatment of losses and gains by investors in rental housing. The exclusion of imputed rents from the income tax base is part of the general exclusion of imputed rents from consumer durables, such as motor vehicles, from the income tax base. However, housing is overwhelmingly the most important exclusion. Moreover, the rental income of investor landlords is taxed. Both Wang et al. (2004) and the Productivity Commission (2004) estimate that the non-taxation of imputed rents is worth a net $8 billion per annum to homeowners. 1 Wang et al. provide more detail. For 2001, they estimated that, with household equity averaging 81 per cent and a marginal tax rate on average income of 31.5 per cent, the non-taxation of net imputed rent (gross imputed rent less housing expenses) provided an after-tax benefit of $13 billion to owner-occupier households. Partially offsetting this is the non-deductibility of mortgage interest payments, which costs homeowners an estimated $5.0 billion after tax. The net result of $8.0 billion is sensitive to the marginal tax rate and gearing rate. Wang et al (2004) estimate that in 2000, when the marginal tax rate on 1 This Wang et al estimate applies to 2001; the Productivity Commission estimate to

4 average income was 35.5 per cent, the value to homeowners of the imputed rent exemption after tax was $10 billion. Of course, if net imputed rents were taxed, the benefit of equity financed housing would fall and households would likely reduce their equity in housing. Thus the value of the tax concession exceeds the revenue that government would collect by abolishing the concession. Secondly, existing housing services are not taxed as part of the consumption tax base. There is no GST or other tax on imputed or actual rents. Given an estimated gross annual rental of $91 billion on Australian housing stock (see Table 2 below), a 10 per cent GST would raise tax revenues of $9.1 billion per annum (assuming no change in the quantity, price or rental of the housing stock). 2 However, GST is charged on new houses and on inputs to house renovations and maintenance. If GST were charged on rents, presumably these taxes, valued below at $6.0 billion per annum, would be deductible. The net cost of excluding existing housing services from the tax base is in the order of $3.1 billion per annum. Turning to taxation of capital gains, home owners are exempt from CGT whereas, since September 1999, most investors in other assets pay CGT on half the nominal capital gains when the gains are realised. The Productivity Commission (2004) estimated that the value of this concession to homeowners was $10 billion in This result is sensitive to annual house price inflation, the marginal tax rate, and the benchmark. Wang et al (2004, Table A2) estimate that, between 1990 and 2001, the value of the CGT concession to homeowners compared with a CGT on 50 per cent of nominal gains (the present CGT) varied from $1 billion to $13 billion per annum and averaged $8.8 billion per annum in 2001 prices. Whether investors in rental housing receive a tax concession from the present CGT depends on the benchmark. Investors receive a concession (along with owners of most other forms of capital) if all nominal capital gains should be taxed. But taxation of nominal changes in value is hard to justify. There is a widespread view that the 50 per cent CGT on realised nominal capital gains is concessionary compared with the 100 per cent tax on realised real capital gains that it replaced. However, this is true only when the inflation rate (π) is less than the real rate of increase in house prices (r). If π > r, which it usually is (Abelson and Chung, 2004), the new CGT regime increases capital gains taxes. In practice, the current CGT is generally not a tax concession compared with a CGT on real gains. 3 The issue is further complicated by the treatment of borrowing costs. Australian income tax provisions allow investors generally to deduct losses from one activity, inclusive of borrowing costs, against income from another activity in the same period. When the losses arise from borrowing costs, the practice is known as negative gearing. In the rental property 2 Yates (2000) estimated that the subsidy from the non-taxation of rental services from all housing was about one-third higher than the subsidy from non-taxation of imputed rents. Neither Wang et al (2004) nor the Productivity Commission (2004) discuss this tax expenditure. 3 Suppose that the real percentage increase in house prices is r, the inflation rate isπ, and the capital gains tax rate is t. The nominal gain (n) equals (1+r) (1+π) -1. Thus n can be approximated by r+π. If the CGT is on real gains, the tax payable is P h rt, where P h is the price of the house at the start of the period and t is the tax rate. If the CGT is on half the nominal gains, the tax payable is approximately P h (r+π) 0.5t. If r =π, then tr = 0.5t ( r+ π). If r >π, the new CGT reduces tax payable. If r <π, the new CGT increases tax payable. Wang et al (2004, Table A.2) show that between 1990 and 2001 tax would have been lower with the CGT discount method introduced in 1999 than they were with the previous CGT based on taxes of real gains. 4

5 market it is common practice to deduct losses against other taxable income in the same period. Of the 17 per cent of taxpayers who report rental income, nearly half report losses on rental investment and in many years reported losses from rental property exceed reported incomes (Productivity Commission, 2004). Because negative gearing is an economy-wide practice, the Australian Treasury does not consider negative gearing to be a tax expenditure and the Productivity Commission (ibid) did not estimate an associated tax concession. However the combination of allowing investors to deduct 100 per cent of the cost of borrowing (whether making a loss of not) while taxing only 50 per cent of the capital gains is a substantial tax concession. Suppose that an investor borrows $100,000 at 7 per cent, the real rate of return on investment is 4 per cent, annual inflation is 3 per cent which is translated into a nominal increase in capital value, and the investor s marginal tax rate is 40 per cent. The investor records an operating loss of $3000 and reduces his tax payment by $1200. On the other hand, if he realises the nominal capital gain of $3000, he pays tax on only half that gain. The net gain is $600 or 0.6 per cent of the capital value. If he defers the capital gain, the present value of the gain is greater. The asymmetrical treatment of nominal costs and gains provides investors with an annual tax concession that equals (borrowing for rental investment the inflation rate the marginal tax rate) less the present value of the tax on realised nominal capital gains. Allowing for an estimated capital value of rental stock of $597 billion (see Table 2) and average investor gearing of 40 per cent, borrowing by rental investors is currently about $239 billion. Working with the same parameters as before, the tax concession is worth $1.43 billion (0.006 $239 billion). The present value of the gain will be larger in so far as the gain is deferred and the investor s discount rate exceeds the inflation rate. These benefits to investors arise from the general asymmetric treatment of nominal gains and costs and not just because investors can deduct losses against other taxable income. 4 Although the concession is an economy-wide one, households access the concession predominantly via investment in rental housing. A similar asymmetry occurs with depreciation allowances. Investors can deduct construction costs on new buildings at a rate of 2.5 per cent a year. When deductions for capital works are claimed for income tax purposes, the CGT cost base is reduced. However, investors can claim 100 per cent deduction from taxable income for depreciation and pay CGT on only half of this amount and later. Again there is an effective tax concession although a much smaller one than with negative gearing. But again similar concessions exist across the economy. Other housing subsidies Governments support home purchase in several ways, including the first home owner grant (FHOG) scheme, direct lending, deposit assistance, interest rate assistance measures, mortgage relief, and home purchase advisory services (Australian Institute of Health and Welfare, 2005a). Of these schemes, the FHOG has been by far the most substantial form of assistance to home purchase since its inception in July By January 2004, the Australian government had provided $4.3 billion to over 550,000 first home owners (Productivity Commission, 2004), which equates to a subsidy of about $1.2 billion per annum. 4 The estimated value of this tax concession is based on the benchmark assumption that only real income should be taxed and only real costs should be tax deductible. This is quite different from arbitrary policy proposals related to negative gearing that all costs should be tax deductible so long as the investor makes a profit and that no costs contributing to a loss should be tax deductible. 5

6 The Australian Government provides rental assistance directly to about one-quarter of all renters via means tested cash benefits. Wang et al. (2004) report that the Commonwealth provided over $1.8 billion in rent assistance to 943,000 income units in 698,000 households in for an average annual benefit of $2470 per household. 5 Public housing is a third major vehicle of housing assistance. About 5 per cent of households in Australia live in public housing with most receiving a rental subsidy. Drawing on a sample from the Australian Housing Survey (ABS, 2000), Wang et al. (2004) estimate that at end- June 2002, 342,500 households lived in public housing and 302,500 households received a subsidy. Comparing public housing rents with market rents, Wang et al. estimate the subsidy to be worth $1.25 billion per annum or about $4150 per household per annum. However, they note that some data on market rents are based on tenant estimates, which may not be reliable. Taxes on land and housing All States and Territories in Australia, except the Northern Territory, levy taxes on the value of land used for rental investments. The tax base is the value of improved land, which includes improvements produced by adding capital to land. Thus the land tax is also a tax on capital, albeit a much smaller tax on capital than is a full property tax. Land tax rates are usually progressive with marginal rates on high value property at around 5 per cent. Land tax is generally not imposed on owner-occupied residences though there are exceptions for second homes and for high priced properties. In 2004, land tax yielded state and territory jurisdictions about $3 billion per annum of which about 60 per cent was tax on residential land. On the other hand, the Productivity Commission (2004) estimated that the value of the home owner exemption from land taxes on their principal homes was $7 billion per annum. Evidently the land taxes can be viewed from two different perspectives. From the perspective of the tax system as a whole, given that other forms of household wealth are not taxed, land taxes are an impost on wealth held in the form of land. Alternatively, the exemption of home owners from land taxes can be regarded as a tax subsidy. The former more general position in adopted in this paper. In addition, most local governments in Australia raise rates via a tax on (improved) land values. These taxes are usually proportional to land value, but some jurisdictions levy a minimum amount per property regardless of land value. Nineteenth century British economists, such as Cannan and Marshall, tended to view local government rates as a benefit tax because the payments reflected services mainly to property owners. A more modern view, emanating from the United States and associated with the Tiebout hypothesis, is that the value of local services and taxes are capitalised into property values. This implies that households choose and pay for the local service/tax package that they want. It follows that even though local rates are a compulsory payment, they may be viewed as a user fee rather than as a tax. However, these perspectives have little current relevance to most Australian households. Most local services today are provided to people rather than to property. Moreover, services and local taxes do not vary a great deal across local governments within the cities. There is little 5 The Australian Government provides separately about another $80 million a year in various forms of private rental assistance, such as interest free loans for bonds, help with temporary problems and relocation expenses (Australian Institute of Health and Welfare, 2005b). 6

7 connection between local government rates paid and services received and no marginal relationship. In short, most Australian households would regard local rates as a tax to fund services rather than as a payment for particular services. In 2004, local government in Australia raised about $8.0 billion in land taxes. For the reasons just given, in this analysis these payments are treated as a tax on land rather than a payment for services. However investors can deduct land taxes, whether levied by the states or local jurisdictions, from their taxable rental income. Thus the after-tax cost of land taxes (LT) to investors is LT (1-mtr), where mtr is the marginal investor tax rate which we assume is 40 per cent in this analysis. All States and Territories traditionally charged stamp duty on transfers of land and housing. The tax base is the purchase price of the land or home. In 2003, stamp duty rates varied by jurisdiction from one per cent of sale value for low-priced properties to over 5 per cent of sale value for high-price properties. 6 Most jurisdictions provide stamp duty relief for first home owners. The NSW Government also levies a 2.25% vendor tax on sale of housing. Total revenue from stamp duty on all property related transactions rose from $4 billion in the mid s to over $10 billion in the early 2000 s. Of this, about $9 billion was collected on conveyancing of residential properties (Productivity Commission, 2004). 7 These stamp duties are not tax deductible against income. Another fiscal measure affecting housing is the GST. 8 This tax is imposed on vacant land sold by registered enterprises, new dwellings erected on vacant land, renovation expenditures, and inputs to home maintenance. Gross capital formation for private dwellings is currently about $50 billion per annum, inclusive of about $30 billion on new dwellings and $20 billion on renovations. This expenditure attracts GST of about $5.0 billion per annum. In addition, land development and repairs and maintenance each attract GST of about $0.5 billion per annum (Productivity Commission, 2004). Thus total GST on housing is about $6.0 billion per annum. However, as argued below, the GST on land and new dwellings is borne almost entirely by landowners rather than by the consumers (or the building industry). Most state and local governments in Australia levy developers of new housing for public provision of related economic and social infrastructure. Economic infrastructure includes water, sewerage, drainage, roads, public transport and other utilities. Social infrastructure includes open spaces and parks, libraries, community centres and sports facilities. The charges are mostly for services external to the development site and may serve several subdivisions, for example trunk water mains or major roads. Within sub-divisions, the developer organises and pays directly for most facilities. Development charges vary greatly with jurisdiction (Housing Industry Association, 2003). Charges are usually much higher for houses on the urban fringe than for units in established areas. Allowing an average state and local government charge of $ per new house, and new houses in a year, developer charges total some $2.0 billion per annum. Although the charges are levied as a capital charge on developers rather than as a recurrent charge on 6 The Housing Industry Association (2003, p.63) provides details of stamp duty rates by jurisdiction. 7 These figures do not include stamp duties on financial instruments (mortgages) associated with property purchase. 8 The 10% GST applies to about 55% of purchases in Australia. Thus GST is part of the general tax system rather than a specific tax on housing. 7

8 homeowners, they are generally designed to reflect costs and intended as payments for services provided. Housing subsidies and taxes: a summary To place the value of housing subsidies and taxes in perspective, Table 2 provides estimated capital and annual values of the housing stock in2004, by owner-occupied and investor/rental sectors. The estimates of housing stock are based on 2001 Census figures (Kennedy and Robertson, 2003) plus an average net increase of 100,000 dwellings per annum to 2004 that allows for demolitions. The same report shows that 70 per cent of private housing stock is in home ownership. Wang et al (2004) report that there are nearly 390,000 publicly rented dwellings. 9 Our estimates of average capital values are based on average house and unit prices from Abelson and Chung (2004) along with 2001 Census data showing that owner-occupiers occupy 81 per cent of separate houses and 30 per cent of units (with the balance rented). Our rental values are based gross rentals at 4 per cent of capital values (Reserve Bank, 2003). Table 2 Estimated capital and annual values of housing in 2004 Unit Owneroccupied housing a Private rental housing All private housing b Public rental housing No. of dwellings No mn Average (mean) value $ 300, , , ,000 Capital value $bn Rental value 4% $bn Investment in housing p.a. $bn Na Na 50 c Na (a) (b) (c) These include dwellings that are not occupied or rented, eg. second homes. Excluding caravans, cabins and houseboats. A trend figure that includes expenditure on new houses and alterations and additions. It does not include land development and home maintenance costs that total about another $10 billion. The estimated capital value of the private housing stock in mid-2004 was $2272 billion, including $1674 billion in owner-occupied housing and $598 billion in private rental housing. Annual investment in housing (including land development, building, renovation and maintenance) is about $60 billion per annum. Allowing a 4 per cent gross rental rate, the gross rental value of all private housing is $91 billion per annum, including $67 billion in imputed rent for owner-occupied housing and $24 billion in private rental housing. Table 3 summarises the estimated after tax value of housing subsidies and taxes per annum. As emphasised, the estimates depend on definitions of a benchmark tax regime. For example, the size of the negative gearing concession is estimated relative to a symmetric tax treatment of real gains and losses. Table 3 includes estimates of GST foregone by the lack of a consumption tax on imputed or actual rents, but this is offset to a large extent by GST paid on capital improvements and maintenance. Local government rates are included because they are viewed here as a tax rather than a user charge. Developer infrastructure charges are not included because they are primarily a user charge. 9 As Wang et al (2004) note, administration figures for public housing are higher than their survey figures. 8

9 Subsidies and taxes are estimated separately for homeowners and to investors/renters. Where attribution is not clear, the subsidy or tax is attributed approximately proportional to the value of the homeowner or rental stock. But I have used some judgement. For example I estimate that homeowners/landowners would bear a slightly greater proportion of GST on new homes than on renovations. For all private housing, estimated subsidies total $30.4 billion per annum and taxes total $23.4 billion per annum, making a net subsidy of $7.0 billion per annum. This net subsidy is equivalent to 7.7 per cent of estimated gross annual rental value of housing and just under about 0.9 per cent of GDP. The subsidy accrues almost entirely to the homeowner sector, which inclusive of landowners receives an estimated net subsidy of $6.9 billion per annum. If, as argued below, original landowners pay the $3.0 billion GST on new homes, homeowners receive a subsidy of $9.9 billion per annum. Allowing for second homes, this is equivalent to about $2000 per homeowner per annum. Investors and renters of private rental properties jointly receive an estimated net subsidy of only $0.1 billion per annum. This rises to $0.6 billion if GST on new homes is borne by the landowner, which equates to an estimated net subsidy of $250 per rental property per annum. 10 In addition, public housing tenants receive a subsidy of $1.25 billion, which translates to just over $4000 per subsidised household. Table 3 Estimated average value (after tax) of subsidies and taxes per annum Subsidy / tax Owner-occupied housing Private rental housing All private housing a Subsidies $bn % annual housing value $bn % annual housing value $bn % annual housing value Imputed rent tax concession Na Na No GST on imputed / actual rents Capital gains tax concession Na Na Asymmetric tax treatment of losses and gains Na Na First home owner grant Na Na Private rent subsidies Na Na Total subsidies Taxes Land taxes (state governments) Land taxes (local government) Na Na 1.2 b b Stamp duties GST on land / new houses GST on renovations and house maintenance c Total taxes Subsidies - Taxes (a) Excluding caravans, cabins and houseboats. (b) Estimated land tax payable by investors is $2.0 billion per annum. After Australian Government tax deduction, net tax payable is $1.2 million per annum. (c) A small part of this may be allowed as a tax deduction. 10 Because investor supply of rental housing is competitive, most of this subsidy accrues to renters. 9

10 3 Fiscal Measures and the Housing Market We now examine the impacts of these fiscal measures in the owner-occupied and rental sectors on house prices and housing consumption in the two sectors and across the market. As usual, outcomes depend on price elasticities of demand and supply for the taxed or subsidised commodity. In lieu of authoritative estimates of Australian house price elasticities, I start by assuming unitary elasticities and then review implications of other assumptions. The assumption of unitary supply price elasticity is probably more contentious than the assumption of unitary demand price elasticity, for which there is some evidence ( ). Much tax incidence literature assumes that the supply price elasticity of commodities is high because capital is mobile and capital markets are competitive. This could apply to housing renovations. It may also apply to the supply of new houses in marginal urban areas where land values for housing are close to values for other uses. However, most new houses in Australia are constructed in or close to major urban areas where land values far exceed land opportunity costs. Here, planning regulations determine the supply of land for new housing and the number of new houses constructed. Planners are influenced only weakly by house prices. The Berger-Thompson and Ellis (2004) study of the Australian housing market suggests that the price elasticity of new housing supply is low. Effects of fiscal measures affecting owner occupied housing Equilibrium in the market for owner-occupied houses requires that owners earn the same marginal rate of return on their housing investment as on other possible investments. This equilibrium relationship can be expressed as: R h / P h = ρ = i + m + t h - π h (1) where R h is the value of the rental services per period in owner-occupied homes, P h the price of existing houses, ρ the nominal after-tax rate of return on non-housing investment, i the weighted nominal rate of interest after tax, m house maintenance cost as a percentage of house price, t h the tax on housing as a percentage of house cost, and π h is nominal rate of house price inflation (which is not taxed for owner-occupiers). If housing is subsidised, t h is negative. In this equation, R h is determined by household demand in conjunction with the housing stock. All the right-hand side variables are exogenous. Note that i = (w.mr) + (1-w)ρ, where w denotes the proportion of debt in the house and mr the mortgage rate. Note also that tax is expressed here as a percentage of house price rather than of gross rental. 11 Thus the price of housing has to adjust to bring the owner-occupier (investor) market into equilibrium with other assets. This implies: P h = R h / (i + m + t h - π h ) (2) Holding housing constant, taxes on owner-occupiers directly reduce house prices. Conversely, subsidies increase prices. 11 Equation (1) can be expressed in terms of consumption instead of investment: as R h = (i + m + t h - π h ) P h. In this case, the real value of consumption in any period must equal the user cost of the asset. 10

11 For our purposes, it is more convenient to express Equation (2) in terms of changes in net rent: P h = (R h - T h ) / (i + m - π h ) (3) where T h is the amount of tax paid. If a subsidy or tax is permanent, and the owner-occupied housing stock is constant, house prices rise/fall pro rata with the proportion of subsidies/taxes to imputed gross rental values. A 10 per cent subsidy would raise house prices by 10 per cent. We now introduce interaction with rental housing and total housing supply. These effects will likely occur over one or two years rather than instantly. The relationship between the owneroccupied and rental market is complicated because houses are heterogeneous and owneroccupiers tend to own houses whereas most renters occupy apartments. However, to illustrate the impacts of subsidies for homeowners, houses are assumed to be equivalent units. Also, for ease of illustration, we take the current price/quantity relationship to be the initial equilibrium and estimate the impact of changes from this equilibrium. Thus Figure 1 shows an initial equilibrium in homeowner and rental markets with a house price of $300,000. As in Table 3, there are 5.58 million owner-occupied dwellings and 2.39 million private renter dwellings. 12 A homeowner subsidy of 10 per cent of gross rent raises the demand curve of homeowners from D o to D os and owner-occupier dwelling prices would rise by 10 per cent to $330,000. The renter demand curve for housing is assumed to be independent and unchanged. It slopes down because lower house prices imply lower rents and increased housing consumption. At a market price of $330,000 and with a demand price elasticity of -1.0, rental household consumption would fall by 10 per cent to 2.15 million housing units. However, this would result in 0.24 million unoccupied housing units. With unitary demand elasticity also in the owner-occupied market and no increase in overall supply, the new equilibrium market price is $321,000 per housing unit. Owner-occupier dwellings would increase from 5.58 million to 5.74 million and renter dwellings fall from 2.39 million to 2.23 million. Figure 1 Effects of 10 per cent subsidy to home owners on home owner and rental markets with fixed total supply of housing 12 These numbers include unoccupied dwellings. 11

12 Figure 2 introduces a housing supply response. It shows the total market demand curve for owner-occupiers and renters (D o + D R ) along with the market supply curve. The higher demand curve (D os + D R ) allows for a 10 per cent subsidy to homeowners. With unitary demand and supply elasticities, the new equilibrium price is $310,320. The housing stock increases to 8.24 million dwellings, including 5.93 owner-occupied dwellings and 2.31 investor owned dwellings. In this new equilibrium, both housing consumption and house prices rise by 3.4 per cent. However house ownership has risen by 6.3 per cent and rental dwellings have fallen by 3.3 per cent. The above estimates are based on solving for the following four equations where the β coefficient is the demand or supply price elasticity respectively. Initial owner housing demand: lnh od1 = 7.42 βlnp (4) Subsidised owner housing demand a : lnh 0d2 = 7.52 βlnp (5) Rental housing demand: lnh rd = 6.58 βlnp (6) Housing supply: lnh s = βlnp (7) (a) Allowing for a 10 per cent homeowner subsidy. Figure 2 Effects of subsidy to home owners with unit elasticity supply response Table 4 shows estimated market outcomes with various homeowner subsidies and demand and supply elasticities. For a given homeowner subsidy and supply price elasticity, the greater is the price elasticity of demand, the greater is the increase in owner-occupied dwellings and the higher the rise in prices. Holding demand price elasticity constant, a high supply elasticity increases housing consumption but reduces the rise in house prices. It should also be noted that, in percentage terms, estimated changes in housing consumption and house prices are not very sensitive to adoption of a different initial equilibrium price. 12

13 Table 4 Market outcomes from fiscal measures for home owners Market assumptions Owner subsidy / tax (%) a Demand elasticity Supply elasticity Market outcomes New house price ($) % change in house price Total housing (mn) Owner housing (mn) Rental housing (mn) % change: all housing % change owner housing % change rental housing (a) A + denotes a subsidy; is a tax. Effects of fiscal measures affecting investor / rental housing The effects of fiscal measures in the rental market depend on whether the subsidy or tax is targeted on investors or renters. Investors face a similar asset choice to homeowners. In equilibrium the return from housing must equal the return on other assets. Because they operate with different tax rules, the values of the variables may be different for investors, but the principle is the same. Figure 3 depicts a shift in the investor supply curve from S to S t as a result of a new 10 per cent tax on rental incomes. Given that homeowners own 70 per cent of dwellings and an assumed price elasticity of demand in homeowner and rental markets of -1, the equilibrium price for houses would fall by 3 per cent to $291,000. To recover the 10 per cent increase in costs, investors raise rents by 7 per cent and pay 3 per cent less for the properties. The rise in rentals reduces rental property consumption by 7.2 per cent, so rental properties fall from 2.39 million to 2.22 million. On the other hand, owner-occupied dwellings increase by 3.1 per cent from 5.58 million to 5.75 million. Note that this assumes no contraction of housing supply. Figure 3 Effects of 10 per cent tax on rental income with fixed housing supply 13

14 On the other hand, a 10 per cent reduction in taxes on investors in rental properties would lead initially to a 3 per cent increase in property prices, which would in turn induce some increase in supply. With unitary demand and supply price elasticities, the estimated final equilibrium price would be $304,460. Rental property consumption would rise by 8.4 per cent and owner-occupied housing would fall by 1.5 per cent. Table 5 Market outcomes from fiscal measures for investors Market assumptions Owner subsidy / tax (%) a Demand elasticity Supply elasticity Market outcomes New house price ($) % change in house price Total housing (mn) Owner housing (mn) Rental housing (mn) % change: all housing % change owner housing % change rental housing (a) A + denotes a subsidy; is a tax. Turning to the impact of monetary subsidies for renter households, the key point here is that the average rent subsidy of $2500 per annum per household ($50 per week) is less than the rent that most households pay. In these circumstances the rent subsidy is effectively an untied income cash benefit. Suppose, as shown in Figure 4, that a low income household has a disposable annual income of $16,000 from which it allocates one quarter to housing ($4000) and the rest to other goods. Even if a grant of say $2400 were tied to housing, the household could consume the same amount of housing as it would without the grant and consume an extra $2400 of other goods. With a unitary income elasticity of demand for housing, the household would increase its housing consumption by $600 per annum (or by just $12 per week). This scenario is depicted in Figure 4, where a utility maximising household moves from E 1 to E 2 as a result of the outward shift in the budget line and expenditure on housing rises by 15 per cent (in proportion with the increase in disposable income) from $4000 per annum to $4600 per annum. If all rent subsidies are in effect untied general grants and households spend a quarter of the subsidy on housing, a subsidy of $1.8 billion to private renters increases expenditure on private rental housing by $0.45 billion, which is only 1.9 per cent of estimated gross private rentals of $24 billion. Assuming unitary demand and supply elasticities, the estimated equilibrium house price across the market would rise by only 0.28 per cent from $300,000 to $300,850 and there would be a similar rise in gross rents. Renter dwellings would rise from 2.39 million to 2.43 million and there would be a very small fall in owner-occupier dwellings from 5.58 million to 5.56 million dwellings. 14

15 Expenditure on general goods ($ 000) E 2 E 1 I 2 I Expenditure on housing ($ 000) Figure 4 Housing expenditure with a private rental subsidy of $2400 per annum Effects of fiscal measures on new houses The Housing Industry Association (HIA, 2004) contends that new home buyers are inappropriately facing massive bills for upfront contributions to social and community infrastructure as well as GST and stamp duties and that the taxation of housing is impacting severely on housing affordability. The implication is that all such taxes on new houses are passed forward to the consumer. This would occur only if the demand for new housing were perfectly inelastic and supply perfectly elastic. Market conditions for new housing are almost the exact opposite of this. The demand for new houses is almost perfectly price elastic because existing houses are a very close substitute for new houses. Moreover, in any period sales of existing houses usually far outnumber sales of new houses. On the other hand, the supply of new houses is determined principally by planning regulation and is highly price inelastic. This is illustrated in Figure 5. The imposition of a tax on new housing would shift the supply curve only marginally, if at all, to the left. Accordingly, there would be would be minimal, if any, increase in the price of new houses. In these market conditions, nearly all taxes are passed backwards to housing suppliers, or more specifically to original land owners, rather than forwards to consumers. The HIA (2003) reports that infrastructure charges, GST and stamp duties range from $50,000 to over $100,000 per new house in But it also reports that the price of a typical greenfield building site ranged from $25,000 in Perth to $60,000 in Melbourne, $67,500 in Brisbane, and $110,000 in Sydney. These non-urban land values indicate that market forces have little effect on the supply of new houses. If housing supply responded to house prices, greenfield prices for housing would be a fraction of these values. 15

16 $ S t S P 1 P 2 D Q 2 Q 1 New houses Figure 5 The effect of a tax on new houses In a regulated market for new houses, taxes and subsidies for development affect raw land values, not house prices. Taxes reduce the price that developers are willing to pay for the land; subsidies increase it. Taxes and subsidies affect new house prices only when building land prices are close to opportunity cost and fiscal measures affect the supply of housing. 4 Fiscal Measures and Economic Efficiency There has long been concern that housing subsidies cause excess resources to be allocated to housing and too few resources to be allocated to allegedly more productive activities. In a major review of the topic, Henderson and Bourassa (1992) argued that that there were significant incentives to over invest in owner-occupied housing, but did not quantify the alleged distortion. The Reserve Bank (2003. p.5) expressed concern that tax incentives were causing excess investment in rental housing: When we observe the results (of current tax arrangements) resources and finance are being disproportionately channelled into this area. On the other hand, in reviewing various quantitative estimates of the welfare effects of potential excess investment in housing in relation to GDP, Yates (2000, p.515) concluded that there is little evidence to suggest that any efficiency costs (from housing tax expenditures) are large. A second efficiency concern is the use of the housing stock. Transaction taxes such as stamp duties affect not only amount of housing but also how it is used. In addition, unequal fiscal treatment between owned and rented property may distort the tenure choice decision. I examine below the possible deadweight costs of housing subsidies and taxes, inclusive of some important second best considerations. However, the paper does not attempt to estimate the value of possible positive externalities of house ownership or occupation. 16

17 Efficiency costs and gains from fiscal measures affecting investment in housing To estimate the efficiency implications of investment in housing, the paper adopts the classic public finance / cost-benefit approach and examines what consumers are willing to pay for housing compared with the real opportunity costs of the resources used to provide housing. Figure 6 exemplifies this approach for a competitive housing market, where the supply curve is also a marginal cost schedule. Subsidies to housing shift the demand curve for new housing from D to D s. Housing supplied increases from Q 1 to Q 2 and the price for housing rises from P 1 to P s. Housing producers gain the benefit of area P s BCP 1. However, the net price to house purchasers is only P c. Housing consumers gain the surplus area P 1 CFP c. Government pays the difference between P s and P c, which amounts to a total payment of area P s BFP C. The difference between government (taxpayer) subsidies and the sum of producer and consumer surpluses is the area BCF, which is the deadweight loss. $ S P S P 1 P C A C E F B D S deadweight loss D Q 1 Q 2 New housing per period Figure 6 Effects of a housing subsidy on housing quantity and price with competitive housing and land markets As shown in the public finance literature 13, this deadweight loss (DWL) is estimated by DWL = 0.5t 2 Q h P h / ((1/η d ) +(1/η s )) (8) Where t = the marginal tax (or subsidy) rate Q h = the number of new dwellings constructed with no subsidy P h = the initial price of housing η d = the demand price elasticity for housing η s = the supply price elasticity for housing If Q h equals 150,000 new dwellings per annum, P h is $300,000, the subsidy is 10 per cent, and there are unitary demand and supply elasticities, the deadweight loss from construction of new housing would be $225 million per annum. 13 For derivation of Equation (8), see for example Rosen (2002, p.292) 17

18 DWL NH =[0.5 (0.10) 2 $300, ,000 houses] / 2 = $225 million per annum The deadweight loss would rise to $450 million if the supply of new houses were perfectly price elastic. On the other hand, the loss tends to zero as the supply price elasticity for new houses tends to zero. However, we three other significant issues need to be considered. The first is expenditure on housing renovations. Second, the above estimates assume that the average initial house price of $300,000 represents the real opportunity cost of resources used in housing. Third, the estimates make no allowance for the deadweight cost of raising tax revenue. As will be seen, the second issue is fundamental and dealing with it radically affects the outcome. Annual capital expenditure on housing is about $55 billion per annum, which includes about $20 billion on renovations, $30 billion on construction of new housing and $5 billion on land development. To estimate the deadweight cost of renovations in the absence of convenient housing units, we substitute expenditure on housing renovation for Q h P h in Equation (8). The supply price elasticity of renovations is likely to be high and is assumed here to be infinite. Assuming again a subsidy of 10 per cent and a demand price elasticity of 1, the deadweight cost associated with expenditure on renovations is: DWL R = 0.5 (0.10) 2 $20 billion = $100 million per annum Returning to construction of new houses, what is the real opportunity cost? Obviously costs vary greatly. However, the widespread difference between the land price for housing and the opportunity cost of land indicates that the real opportunity cost of housing supply is generally below the price of housing. The following costs per housing are fairly typical. Private land development expenditure applies mainly to about 100,000 new houses on the urban fringe and is about $50,000 per house. However, some housing requires little land development, and the overall average cost per housing unit is assumed here to be $40,000. Public infrastructure costs are also higher on the urban fringe than for developments in established areas. These costs may average out at about $20,000 per housing unit. Building cost is assumed to be $150,000 per unit. Allowing $10,000 for the opportunity cost of raw land, the total land and building package is $220,000. Add $40,000 for management and sales, and the total opportunity cost of a house would average around $260,000 compared with the price of $300,000. The social surplus would be $40,000 per dwelling. In a study of a development of over 10,000 houses in south-west Sydney, I estimated that after allowing for all public and private costs there was a social surplus of about $20,000 per new dwelling unit. This was in an area of moderately priced houses and estimated costs included expensive public transport and negative externalities from private motor vehicles. Evidently, the supply curve in Figure 6 is not a marginal cost curve. Figure 7 shows the housing market with a marginal cost curve below the market price reflecting the regulation of new housing. In this case, a housing subsidy increases investment in housing from Q 1 to Q 2 and there is an efficiency gain equal to area ABCD. This is the difference between the price that consumers are willing to pay for housing and the real cost of providing the housing. 18

Analysis of capital gains tax changes

Analysis of capital gains tax changes COMMERCIAL IN CONFIDENCE F I N A L R E P O R T Analysis of capital gains tax changes Prepared for Housing Industry Association Limited 6 December 2017 The Centre for International Economics is a private

More information

CHANGING THE TAXATION REGIME FOR INVESTORS IN THE HOUSING MARKET

CHANGING THE TAXATION REGIME FOR INVESTORS IN THE HOUSING MARKET CHANGING THE TAXATION REGIME FOR INVESTORS IN THE HOUSING MARKET BRIEFING REPORT FOR MASTER BUILDERS AUSTRALIA APRIL 2018 SUMMARY REPORT Housing affordability, particularly for first home buyers, is an

More information

Melbourne Economic Forum, 13 April Lower Personal Income Tax Rates. John Freebairn. University of Melbourne

Melbourne Economic Forum, 13 April Lower Personal Income Tax Rates. John Freebairn. University of Melbourne Melbourne Economic Forum, 13 April 2016 Lower Personal Income Tax Rates John Freebairn University of Melbourne Current personal income taxation Collect $170 b in 2013-14, and 40% of total government taxation

More information

Implementing Foreign Investment Reforms

Implementing Foreign Investment Reforms 17 July 2015 Manager International Investment & Trade Unit Foreign Investment & Trade Policy Division The Treasury Langton Crescent PARKES ACT 2600 By email: ForeignInvestmentConsultation@treasury.gov.au

More information

A Review of Funding Measures for Urban Infrastructure with Special Reference to Developer Charges, Betterment (Value Uplift) Taxes and Turnover Taxes

A Review of Funding Measures for Urban Infrastructure with Special Reference to Developer Charges, Betterment (Value Uplift) Taxes and Turnover Taxes A Review of Funding Measures for Urban Infrastructure with Special Reference to Developer Charges, Betterment (Value Uplift) Taxes and Turnover Taxes Peter Abelson Department of Economics, University of

More information

Budget Summary of Tax and Other Issues. Prepared by:

Budget Summary of Tax and Other Issues. Prepared by: Budget 2017-18 Summary of Tax and Other Issues Prepared by: Contents For Business... 3 $20k immediate deduction extended for another year... 3 Contractors in the courier and cleaning industries face greater

More information

Application: The Costs of Taxation

Application: The Costs of Taxation Application: The Costs of Taxation Chapter 8. Application: The Costs of Taxation Welfare economics is the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. Buyers and sellers receive

More information

Master Builders Association of SA Stamp Duty and State Government Taxation Review

Master Builders Association of SA Stamp Duty and State Government Taxation Review Master Builders Association of SA Stamp Duty and State Government Taxation Review Executive Summary The Master Builders Association of SA has commissioned Hudson Howells to undertake a review of South

More information

Chapter 12 TAXES AND TAX POLICY Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.)

Chapter 12 TAXES AND TAX POLICY Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.) Chapter 12 TAXES AND TAX POLICY Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.) Chapter Summary This chapter starts out with a theory of taxes using the supply-and-demand model. Referring back to the

More information

Housing tax reform: What will make a difference?

Housing tax reform: What will make a difference? Housing tax reform: What will make a difference? Brendan Coates, Grattan Institute National Housing Conference 2017, Sydney 30 November 2017 Housing tax reform Worsening housing affordability is really

More information

Paper for New Agenda for Prosperity, the University of Melbourne, 28 March 2008 Reforming State Taxes John Freebairn The University of Melbourne

Paper for New Agenda for Prosperity, the University of Melbourne, 28 March 2008 Reforming State Taxes John Freebairn The University of Melbourne Paper for New Agenda for Prosperity, the University of Melbourne, 28 March 2008 Reforming State Taxes John Freebairn The University of Melbourne 1. Introduction While much of the discussion on the reform

More information

[01.01] Owner Occupied Housing. An Exploration of Alternative Treatments of Owner- Occupied Housing in a CPI. Keith Woolford

[01.01] Owner Occupied Housing. An Exploration of Alternative Treatments of Owner- Occupied Housing in a CPI. Keith Woolford International Comparison Program [01.01] Owner Occupied Housing An Exploration of Alternative Treatments of Owner- Occupied Housing in a CPI Keith Woolford To be presented at the TAG Meeting Global Office

More information

Housing Taxation for Stability and Growth

Housing Taxation for Stability and Growth Housing Taxation for Stability and Growth ECFIN Workshop European Commission Property taxation and enhanced tax administration in challenging times 24 November 2011 Dan Andrews Economics Department 1 Organisation

More information

Review of the Lease Variation Charge

Review of the Lease Variation Charge 25 October 2018 Mr David Nicol Under Treasurer Canberra Nara Centre 1 Constitution Avenue Canberra City ACT 2601 Review of the Lease Variation Charge Thank you for the opportunity to comment on the Review

More information

Economic influences on the Australian mortgage market

Economic influences on the Australian mortgage market Economic influences on the Australian mortgage market Presentation to Choice Aggregation Services Saul Eslake Chief Economist ANZ Burswood Resort Perth 3 rd October 7 www.anz/com/go/economics Capital city

More information

Impact of removing stamp duties on insurance. Insurance Council of Australia

Impact of removing stamp duties on insurance. Insurance Council of Australia Impact of removing stamp duties on insurance Insurance Council of Australia October 2015 Contents Executive Summary... i 1 Background... 1 1.1 This report... 2 2 Assessing the efficiency of taxes... 2

More information

Tenants guide to tax reform

Tenants guide to tax reform Tenants' Union of NSW Suite 201 55 Holt Street Surry Hills NSW 2010 ABN 88 984 223 164 P: 02 8117 3700 F: 02 8117 3777 E: tunsw@clc.net.au tenantsunion.org.au tenants.org.au Tenants guide to tax reform

More information

Tax & Property Seminar Property development and tax a practical guide...1

Tax & Property Seminar Property development and tax a practical guide...1 Property development and tax a practical guide...1 1. Understanding the tax treatment of a property development business...2 1.1 When will land held by a taxpayer in the business of property development

More information

Session three: Revenue Raising and Base Broadening 16 September 2009

Session three: Revenue Raising and Base Broadening 16 September 2009 VICTORIA UNIVERSITY TAX WORKING GROUP Session three: Revenue Raising and Base Broadening 16 September 2009 The day: The framework in which to consider tax reform; Presentations from Len Burman, Arthur

More information

INVESTMENT IN AUSTRALIAN REAL ESTATE BY A FOREIGN INVESTOR

INVESTMENT IN AUSTRALIAN REAL ESTATE BY A FOREIGN INVESTOR INVESTMENT IN AUSTRALIAN REAL ESTATE BY A FOREIGN INVESTOR PREPARED BY: Chartered Accountants Business Advisers and Consultants Suite 201, Level 2 65 York Street Sydney NSW 2000 Australia Telephone: 61+2+9290

More information

Maximising growth potential of housing providers through title transfer

Maximising growth potential of housing providers through title transfer Maximising growth potential of housing providers through title transfer Prepared for Community Housing Council of SA Inc. Date 22 November 2013 Prepared by Emilio Ferrer 0412 251 701 eferrer@sphere.com.au

More information

The Australia Taxation reflects legislation in place at 1 November Exam questions will be based upon the tax year.

The Australia Taxation reflects legislation in place at 1 November Exam questions will be based upon the tax year. AUSTRALIA TAXATION CPA Program subject outline First edition A professional accountant is required to possess fundamental tax law knowledge and skills. Australia Taxation introduces fundamental concepts

More information

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY Institute of Business and Economic Research Fisher Center for Real Estate and Urban Economics PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY WORKING PAPER SERIES WORKING PAPER NO. W06-001B HOUSING POLICY IN THE UNITED

More information

Intermediate Microeconomics

Intermediate Microeconomics Intermediate Microeconomics Fall 018 - M Pak, J Shi, and B Xu Exercises 1 Consider a market where there are two consumers with inverse demand functions p(q 1 ) = 10 q 1 and p(q ) = 5 q (a) Suppose there

More information

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership Kamila Sommer Paul Sullivan August 2017 Federal Reserve Board of Governors, email: kv28@georgetown.edu American

More information

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS University of Victoria Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS Martin Farnham Problem Set #5 Note: Answer each question as clearly and concisely as possible. Use of diagrams, where appropriate, is strongly

More information

An exploration of alternative treatments of owner-occupied housing in a CPI

An exploration of alternative treatments of owner-occupied housing in a CPI An exploration of alternative treatments of owner-occupied housing in a CPI (Paper presented at the 9 th meeting of the Ottawa Group London, 14 16 May 2006.) Keith Woolford Australian Bureau of Statistics

More information

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium 2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium Partial equilibrium tax incidence misses out on a lot of important aspects of economic activity. Among those aspects : markets are interrelated, so that prices of

More information

Property tax reform A Contribution To Home Ownership And Challenges For Government In Australia

Property tax reform A Contribution To Home Ownership And Challenges For Government In Australia Property tax reform A Contribution To Home Ownership And Challenges For Government In Australia Peer-reviewed paper Vince Mangioni University of Technology, Sydney Vincent.mangioni@uts.edu.au Abstract:

More information

ESTIMATES OF PRIVATE SECTOR WEALTH. Tim Callen. Research Discussion Paper October Economic Analysis Department. Reserve Bank of Australia

ESTIMATES OF PRIVATE SECTOR WEALTH. Tim Callen. Research Discussion Paper October Economic Analysis Department. Reserve Bank of Australia ESTIMATES OF PRIVATE SECTOR WEALTH Tim Callen Research Discussion Paper 9109 October 1991 Economic Analysis Department Reserve Bank of Australia I am grateful to my colleagues at the RBA for helpful comments,

More information

Incidence of Taxation

Incidence of Taxation Incidence of Taxation Taxes are not always borne by the people who pay them in the first instance. They are often shifted to other people. Tax incidence means the final placing of a tax. Incidence is on

More information

Submission to the Federal Tax Discussion Paper. Prepared by the Urban Development Institute of Australia (UDIA)

Submission to the Federal Tax Discussion Paper. Prepared by the Urban Development Institute of Australia (UDIA) Submission to the Federal Tax Discussion Paper Prepared by the Urban Development Institute of Australia (UDIA) June 2015 Contents Contents... 2 UDIA in Brief... 3 Introduction... 4 Recommendations... 5

More information

Recitation #6 Week 02/15/2009 to 02/21/2009. Chapter 7 - Taxes

Recitation #6 Week 02/15/2009 to 02/21/2009. Chapter 7 - Taxes Recitation #6 Week 02/15/2009 to 02/21/2009 Chapter 7 - Taxes Exercise 1. The government wishes to limit the quantity of alcoholic beverages sold and therefore is considering the imposition of an excise

More information

CHAPTER 3 - NON-CONCESSIONARY OPTIONS. 3.1 Taxed/Taxed/Exempt

CHAPTER 3 - NON-CONCESSIONARY OPTIONS. 3.1 Taxed/Taxed/Exempt - 17 - CHAPTER 3 - NON-CONCESSIONARY OPTIONS 3.1 Taxed/Taxed/Exempt The Consultative Document proposed that contributions to superannuation schemes should be from tax paid income, rather than being deductible

More information

The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)) Taxation and economic efficiency

The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)) Taxation and economic efficiency The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)) Taxation and economic efficiency 1 Taxation and economic efficiency Most taxes introduce deadweight losses because they alter relative

More information

Tax Time Monthly OCTOBER 2017 INCOME TAX SUPERANNUATION STATE TAXES Williams Hall Chadwick

Tax Time Monthly OCTOBER 2017 INCOME TAX SUPERANNUATION STATE TAXES Williams Hall Chadwick Tax Time Monthly OCTOBER 2017 INCOME TAX SUPERANNUATION STATE TAXES +61 7 3221 2416 www.wpca.com.au Williams Hall Chadwick CONTENTS 1 INCOME TAX pg 3 pg 3 pg 3 pg 4 Bill Introduced to limit deduction for

More information

The Victorian economy and government financial position

The Victorian economy and government financial position The n economy and government financial position Presentation to n Council of Social Service 26 Congress Saul Eslake Chief Economist ANZ RACV Centre Melbourne th August 26 4 th www.anz.com/go/economics

More information

Transitioning from a transaction to a recurrent tax on property

Transitioning from a transaction to a recurrent tax on property 23 RD ANNUAL PACIFIC RIM REAL ESTATE SOCIETY CONFERENCE SYDNEY, NEW SOUTH WALES, AUSTRALIA 15 TH 18 TH JANUARY 2017 Transitioning from a transaction to a recurrent tax on property Vince Mangioni University

More information

Country note: housing finance in Switzerland

Country note: housing finance in Switzerland Country note: housing finance in Switzerland Martin Brown. Overview. Characteristics and developments The majority of Swiss households live in rented apartments or houses. Nevertheless, the housing market

More information

june 07 tpp 07-3 Service Costing in General Government Sector Agencies OFFICE OF FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT Policy & Guidelines Paper

june 07 tpp 07-3 Service Costing in General Government Sector Agencies OFFICE OF FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT Policy & Guidelines Paper june 07 Service Costing in General Government Sector Agencies OFFICE OF FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT Policy & Guidelines Paper Contents: Page Preface Executive Summary 1 2 1 Service Costing in the General Government

More information

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. 1 Market Demand Assume that there are only two goods (x and y)

More information

Effective Tax Rates on Different Corporate Investments. John Freebairn. University of Melbourne

Effective Tax Rates on Different Corporate Investments. John Freebairn. University of Melbourne Effective Tax Rates on Different Corporate Investments John Freebairn University of Melbourne Abstract An effective tax rate is measured by the difference between the pre-tax return earned by the company

More information

2007 Thomson South-Western

2007 Thomson South-Western Application: The Costs of Taxation Welfare economics is the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic wellbeing. Buyers and sellers receive benefits from taking part in the market. The

More information

Investing in Perth. Understanding the drivers of the property market in Western Australia

Investing in Perth. Understanding the drivers of the property market in Western Australia Investing in Perth Understanding the drivers of the property market in Western Australia 01 Investing in Perth Perth shares a business time zone with 60% of the world Investing in Perth Perth s Property

More information

INTRODUCTORY TAXATION

INTRODUCTORY TAXATION INTRODUCTORY TAXATION SUBJECT OUTLINE A professional accountant is required to possess fundamental tax law knowledge and skills. Introductory Taxation introduces fundamental concepts of income tax law,

More information

The problem with the current VAT treatment of immovable property. Christine Peacock, Graduate School of Business and Law, RMIT University

The problem with the current VAT treatment of immovable property. Christine Peacock, Graduate School of Business and Law, RMIT University 1 The problem with the current VAT treatment of immovable property Christine Peacock, Graduate School of Business and Law, RMIT University Abstract There has been a fundamental shift from other forms of

More information

Exploring the Personal Income Tax System

Exploring the Personal Income Tax System www.pwc.com.au 22 October 2018 Exploring the Personal Income Tax System Paper Two Separate taxation of labour and capital income Paper Two Separate taxation of labour and capital income Exploring the Personal

More information

MACROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH. 6 - INTRODUCTION TO TAXES.

MACROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH. 6 - INTRODUCTION TO TAXES. !! www.clutchprep.com CONCEPT: INTRODUCING TAXES AND TAX INCIDENCE Taxes allow the government to provide public services. Taxes can either be imposed on the buyer or the seller of a good. The tax shifts

More information

Housing affordability the deposit gap

Housing affordability the deposit gap Housing affordability the deposit gap Summary Housing affordability forms part of the ALP s justification for changing 70 years of taxation law and outlawing negative gearing on all investments apart from

More information

Any book of Microeconomics can be useful: Microeconomics and Behavior, R. H. Frank Microeconomic Analysis (H. Varian) 2/22/2016 1

Any book of Microeconomics can be useful: Microeconomics and Behavior, R. H. Frank Microeconomic Analysis (H. Varian) 2/22/2016 1 Any book of Microeconomics can be useful: Microeconomics and Behavior, R. H. Frank Microeconomic Analysis (H. Varian) 2/22/2016 1 Basics of the economics of taxation Taxation in competitive market Commodity

More information

Victorian State Budget

Victorian State Budget Victorian State Budget 2014-15 Contents Commentary 1 The Government s reliance on State taxes revenue 2 Metropolitan planning levy 4 Payroll tax 5 Land tax and stamp duty 6 First home owner stamp duty

More information

The Finance Act 1998: Can the owners of Agricultural land continue to Gain from their Capital disposals? Roger Gibbard November 1998

The Finance Act 1998: Can the owners of Agricultural land continue to Gain from their Capital disposals? Roger Gibbard November 1998 The Finance Act 1998: Can the owners of Agricultural land continue to Gain from their Capital disposals? Roger Gibbard November 1998 Abstract This paper seeks to analyse and discuss, from the perspective

More information

Gehrke: Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13. Exercises

Gehrke: Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13. Exercises Gehrke: 320.120 Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13 Questions #1 (National accounts) Exercises 1.1 What are the differences between the nominal gross domestic product and the real net national income? 1.2

More information

Lecture 8. Application: the cost of taxation

Lecture 8. Application: the cost of taxation Lecture 8 Application: the cost of taxation By the end of this lecture, you should understand: how taxes reduce consumer and producer surplus the meaning and causes of the deadweight loss from a tax why

More information

Sample Exam Questions/Chapter 7

Sample Exam Questions/Chapter 7 Sample Exam Questions/Chapter 7 1. A tax of $20 on an income of $200, $40 on an income of $300, and $80 on an income of $400 is: A) progressive. B) proportional. C) regressive. D) constant-rate. 2. A tax

More information

Website:

Website: Monday, 1 June 2015 Tax White Paper Task Force The Treasury Langton Crescent PARKES ACT 2600 Website: http://bettertax.gov.au/have-your-say/discussion-paper-submissions/ Dear Sir/Madam, The Motor Trades

More information

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand Background paper for Session 5 of the Victoria University of Wellington Tax Working Group October 2009 Prepared by the New Zealand Treasury

More information

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH. 6 - INTRODUCTION TO TAXES AND SUBSIDIES

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH. 6 - INTRODUCTION TO TAXES AND SUBSIDIES !! www.clutchprep.com CONCEPT: INTRODUCING TAXES AND TAX INCIDENCE Taxes allow the government to provide public services. Taxes can either be imposed on the buyer or the seller of a good. The tax shifts

More information

FINANCIAL REPORT THE ROYAL AUTOMOBILE CLUB OF QUEENSLAND LIMITED AND ITS CONTROLLED ENTITIES FOR THE YEAR ENDED 31 DECEMBER 2011

FINANCIAL REPORT THE ROYAL AUTOMOBILE CLUB OF QUEENSLAND LIMITED AND ITS CONTROLLED ENTITIES FOR THE YEAR ENDED 31 DECEMBER 2011 RACQ ANNUAL REPORT 2011 31 THE ROYAL AUTOMOBILE CLUB OF QUEENSLAND LIMITED AND ITS CONTROLLED ENTITIES FINANCIAL REPORT FOR THE YEAR ENDED 31 DECEMBER 2011 Statement of comprehensive income 32 Balance

More information

AMP Tax Report Message from the Chief Financial Officer. 2. Introduction

AMP Tax Report Message from the Chief Financial Officer. 2. Introduction AMP Tax Report 2017 1. Message from the Chief Financial Officer Our purpose is to help customers own their tomorrow by helping them take control of their money and achieve their financial goals. Whether

More information

The study expands and delves deeper into an earlier presentation in Ekonomisk Debatt 2015, nos. 7 and 8. 7

The study expands and delves deeper into an earlier presentation in Ekonomisk Debatt 2015, nos. 7 and 8. 7 Summary Introduction This study presents a box model for uniform capital income and property taxation. 6 What, then, is a box model? The name is taken from the Dutch model for standard taxation of financial

More information

STATE BY STATE ANALYSIS N E W H O M E B U I L D I N G

STATE BY STATE ANALYSIS N E W H O M E B U I L D I N G HALF YEARLY REVIEW STATE BY STATE ANALYSIS STATE RANKINGS N E W H O M E B U I L D I N G A state by state performance review of residential construction Summer 2018 STATES STAMP DUTY DEPENDENCE: WORST IN

More information

THE UNDERGROUND ECONOMY AND AUSTRALIA S GDP

THE UNDERGROUND ECONOMY AND AUSTRALIA S GDP FEATURE ARTICLE: INTRODUCTION THE UNDERGROUND ECONOMY AND AUSTRALIA S GDP A publication titled Measuring the Non-Observed Economy: A Handbook, was released in 2002. It was jointly authored by the Organisation

More information

Lecture 3: Tax incidence

Lecture 3: Tax incidence Lecture 3: Tax incidence Economics 336/337 University of Toronto Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 1 / 18 Tax incidence in competitive markets What is the economic incidence of a tax on a single

More information

A Clear Direction Financial Planning Level 19, 10 Eagle Street, Brisbane QLD 4000 (07) ABN:

A Clear Direction Financial Planning Level 19, 10 Eagle Street, Brisbane QLD 4000 (07) ABN: A Clear Direction Financial Planning Level 19, 10 Eagle Street, Brisbane QLD 4000 scottk@acleardirection.com.au (07) 3379 6068 ABN: 85 147 572 870 The budget has provided a number of significant changes

More information

Tax Design. Professor David Bell University of Stirling

Tax Design. Professor David Bell University of Stirling Tax Design Professor David Bell University of Stirling Fundamentals of tax design Relying heavily on the Mirrlees Review (Institute for Fiscal Studies) Key concerns are the effect of tax system on: Distribution

More information

Efficiency of the Tax System: a marginal excess burden analysis

Efficiency of the Tax System: a marginal excess burden analysis Presentation to 2017 Australian Conference of Economists Efficiency of the Tax System: a marginal excess burden analysis preliminary and not for quotation Chris Murphy, Visiting Fellow, ACDE, ANU Chris.Murphy@anu.edu.au

More information

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001 AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001 1. Yes, the allocation will be efficient, since the tax in this question is a tax on the value of people s endowments. This is a lump sum tax. In an

More information

ASX INVESTMENT SECTOR PERFORMANCE REPORT

ASX INVESTMENT SECTOR PERFORMANCE REPORT ASX INVESTMENT SECTOR PERFORMANCE REPORT Investments Report December 2003 An investment sector performance report prepared for the Australian Stock Exchange by Towers Perrin. Fair Comparison of Investment

More information

Spurious Deadweight Gains

Spurious Deadweight Gains Spurious Deadweight Gains Giovanni Facchini Peter J. Hammond Hiroyuki Nakata Stanford University Stanford University Stanford University July 28, 2000 Abstract Marshallian consumer surplus (MCS) is generally

More information

April 2018 Adviser use only. Aged care guide

April 2018 Adviser use only. Aged care guide April 2018 Adviser use only Aged care guide Table of contents Welcome to the aged care guide 1 Residential aged care 2 Advising your clients about residential aged care 3 Before entering residential aged

More information

Wellington Management Portfolios (Australia) Global Strategic Equity Portfolio ARSN Annual report - 30 June 2010

Wellington Management Portfolios (Australia) Global Strategic Equity Portfolio ARSN Annual report - 30 June 2010 Wellington Management Portfolios (Australia) Global Strategic Equity Portfolio ARSN 116 524 255 Annual report - Wellington Management Portfolios (Australia) Global Strategic Equity Portfolio ARSN 116524255

More information

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies Prepared on behalf of the Organization for International Investment June 2015 (Page intentionally left

More information

Perth, January 1998 SOME IMPACTS OF RECENT BUDGETARY POLICY UPON THE PROPERTY INDUSTRY IN AUSTRALIA. Mervyn Fiedler, M.Com., Ph.D.

Perth, January 1998 SOME IMPACTS OF RECENT BUDGETARY POLICY UPON THE PROPERTY INDUSTRY IN AUSTRALIA. Mervyn Fiedler, M.Com., Ph.D. 1 4 th Pacific Rim Real Estate Society Conference Perth, 19-21 January 1998 SOME IMPACTS OF RECENT BUDGETARY POLICY UPON THE PROPERTY INDUSTRY IN AUSTRALIA Mervyn Fiedler, M.Com., Ph.D., Dip FP, FCPA Adjunct

More information

Tax Related Issues. Presented by: Louisa Andreucci, Hood Sweeney

Tax Related Issues. Presented by: Louisa Andreucci, Hood Sweeney Tax Related Issues Presented by: Louisa Andreucci, Hood Sweeney Today s session GST the basics Applying the margin scheme Capital gains tax Other taxes GST the basics Introduction A broad based tax on

More information

Price Changes and Consumer Welfare

Price Changes and Consumer Welfare Price Changes and Consumer Welfare While the basic theory previously considered is extremely useful as a tool for analysis, it is also somewhat restrictive. The theory of consumer choice is often referred

More information

Commonwealth Budget : what does it mean? Economic Society of Australia (Victoria) Danielle Wood, Fellow Grattan Institute 16 May 2017

Commonwealth Budget : what does it mean? Economic Society of Australia (Victoria) Danielle Wood, Fellow Grattan Institute 16 May 2017 Commonwealth Budget 2017-18: what does it mean? Economic Society of Australia (Victoria) Danielle Wood, Fellow Grattan Institute 16 May 2017 Commonwealth Budget 2018 Budget repair recedes over the horizon

More information

AMP Tax Report Message from the Chief Financial Officer. 2. Introduction

AMP Tax Report Message from the Chief Financial Officer. 2. Introduction AMP Tax Report 2016 1. Message from the Chief Financial Officer Our purpose is to help customers own their tomorrow by helping them take control of their money and achieve their financial goals. Whether

More information

PERPETUAL SECURED PRIVATE DEBT FUND NO.1

PERPETUAL SECURED PRIVATE DEBT FUND NO.1 PERPETUAL SECURED PRIVATE DEBT FUND NO.1 Financial Report 1 July 2014 to ARSN 147 155 020 Perpetual Investment Management Limited ABN 18 000 866 535 AFSL 234426 ARSN 147 155 020 Financial Report for the

More information

Australian demographic trends and implications for housing assistance programs PEER REVIEWED EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Australian demographic trends and implications for housing assistance programs PEER REVIEWED EXECUTIVE SUMMARY PEER REVIEWED EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Australian demographic trends and implications for housing assistance programs FOR THE AUTHORED BY Australian Housing and Urban Research Institute Gavin Wood RMIT University

More information

Aspects of Financial Planning

Aspects of Financial Planning Aspects of Financial Planning Taxation implications of overseas residency More and more of our clients are being given the opportunity to live and work overseas. Before you make the move, it is worthwhile

More information

CHAPTER 17: PUBLIC CHOICE THEORY AND THE ECONOMICS OF TAXATION

CHAPTER 17: PUBLIC CHOICE THEORY AND THE ECONOMICS OF TAXATION CHAPTER 17: PUBLIC CHOICE THEORY AND THE ECONOMICS OF TAXATION Introduction As we have seen, government plays an important role in addressing market failures. But it also plays a significant role in taxation

More information

The Economy Wide Benefits of Increasing the Proportion of Students Achieving Year 12 Equivalent Education

The Economy Wide Benefits of Increasing the Proportion of Students Achieving Year 12 Equivalent Education January 2003 A Report prepared for the Business Council of Australia by The Economy Wide Benefits of Increasing the Proportion of Students Achieving Year 12 Equivalent Education Modelling Results The

More information

Revised exposure draft law on stapled structures and foreign investor tax concessions

Revised exposure draft law on stapled structures and foreign investor tax concessions TaxTalk Insights Global Tax Revised exposure draft law on stapled structures and foreign investor tax concessions 31 July 2018 Explore more insights In brief On 26 July 2018, Treasury released for public

More information

In understanding the behavior of aggregate demand we must take a close look at its individual components: Figure 1, Aggregate Demand

In understanding the behavior of aggregate demand we must take a close look at its individual components: Figure 1, Aggregate Demand The Digital Economist Lecture 4 -- The Real Economy and Aggregate Demand The concept of aggregate demand is used to understand and measure the ability, and willingness, of individuals and institutions

More information

AP Microeconomics Chapter 16 Outline

AP Microeconomics Chapter 16 Outline I. Learning objectives In this chapter students should learn: A. The main categories of government spending and the main sources of government revenue. B. The different philosophies regarding the distribution

More information

Outlook for Australian Property Markets Brisbane

Outlook for Australian Property Markets Brisbane Outlook for Australian Property Markets 2009-2011 Brisbane Update August 2009 Outlook for Australian Property Markets 2009-2011 Brisbane Residential Update August 2009 Population growth continues to surge

More information

2013 Omnibus Tax Bill

2013 Omnibus Tax Bill Tax Incidence Analysis Prepared by the Tax Research Division, Minnesota Department of Revenue June 24, 2013 2013 Omnibus Tax Bill Chapter 143 (H.F. 677 as enacted on May 23, 2013) The 2013 Omnibus Tax

More information

Application: The Costs of Taxation

Application: The Costs of Taxation Application: The Costs of Taxation Chapter 8 Copyright 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of the work should be mailed to: Permissions Department,

More information

Social and Affordable Housing Projections for Australia

Social and Affordable Housing Projections for Australia Social and Affordable Housing Projections for Australia 2016-2026/36 Dr Judy Yates Honorary Associate, School of Economics, University of Sydney. 1 Social and Affordable Housing Projections for Australia

More information

REFORM OF INCOME TAX IN AUSTRALIA: A LONG-TERM AGENDA

REFORM OF INCOME TAX IN AUSTRALIA: A LONG-TERM AGENDA DEMOGRAPHY AND SOCIOLOGY PROGRAM RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES REFORM OF INCOME TAX IN AUSTRALIA: A LONG-TERM AGENDA Peter McDonald Rebecca Kippen Working Papers in Demography No. 95 March 2005 Working

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

Auditor s Independence Declaration

Auditor s Independence Declaration Financial reports The Directors Eumundi Group Limited Level 15, 10 Market Street BRISBANE QLD 4000 Auditor s Independence Declaration As lead auditor for the audit of Eumundi Group Limited for the year

More information

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries Munich Discussion Paper No. 2006-30 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität

More information

Retirement Villages An Institutional Asset Class?

Retirement Villages An Institutional Asset Class? Author Affiliations University of Technology Sydney, Sydney, Australia Abstract Globally the world is facing an ageing trend and while this trend has been global, seniors housing has remained a local asset

More information

A-level Economics 7136/3

A-level Economics 7136/3 SPECIMEN MATERIAL SECOND SET A-level Economics 7136/3 Paper 3 Economic principles and issues Specimen 2015 Morning 2 hours Materials For this paper you must have: the source booklet a calculator. Instructions

More information

The impact of interest rates and the housing market on the UK economy

The impact of interest rates and the housing market on the UK economy The impact of interest and the housing market on the UK economy....... The Chancellor has asked Professor David Miles to examine the UK market for longer-term fixed rate mortgages. This paper by Adrian

More information

Consolidated statement of comprehensive income

Consolidated statement of comprehensive income Consolidated statement of comprehensive income Notes 2017 Revenue from continuing operations 5 24,232 23,139 Other income Net gain on fair value adjustment investment properties 13 80 848 Total revenue

More information

Module 10. Lecture 37

Module 10. Lecture 37 Module 10 Lecture 37 Topics 10.21 Optimal Commodity Taxation 10.22 Optimal Tax Theory: Ramsey Rule 10.23 Ramsey Model 10.24 Ramsey Rule to Inverse Elasticity Rule 10.25 Ramsey Problem 10.26 Ramsey Rule:

More information

CHAPTER 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

CHAPTER 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes CHAPTER 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes A PowerPoint Tutorial To Accompany MACROECONOMICS, 7th. Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Tutorial written by: Mannig J. Simidian B.A. in Economics

More information