The impact of arbitrage on market liquidity

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The impact of arbitrage on market liquidity"

Transcription

1 The impact of arbitrage on market liquidity Dominik M. Rösch a a Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University First draft: May 2013 Abstract The notion that arbitrageurs improve liquidity is based on the assumption that arbitrage opportunities arise because of demand shocks. If, however, arbitrage opportunities reflect informational differences, arbitrageurs create adverse selection and deteriorate liquidity. I test these competing hypotheses in the Depositary Receipts market, where arbitrage is frequent and almost risk-free. As inverse measures of arbitrage activity I use price deviations across both markets based on simultaneous trades, and quotes, and further the velocity at which deviations increase before simultaneous trades. Using 16 years of international tick-by-tick data I find that (i) 70% of all arbitrage opportunities arise because of demand shocks, and (ii) greater arbitrage activity predicts a decrease in order imbalance and an increase in liquidity. These findings suggest that arbitrageurs trade against market order imbalance, and thereby improve market integration and liquidity. Keywords: liquidity, efficiency, fragmentation, arbitrage, market integration I thank Dion Bongaerts, Tarun Chordia, Ruben Cox, Nicolae Gârleanu, Amit Goyal, Andrew Karolyi, Albert Kyle, Pamela Moulton, Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, Raman Uppal, Dimitrios Vagias, Mathijs van Dijk, Manuel Vasconcelos, Kumar Venkataraman, Axel Vischer, Avi Wohl, and participants at the 2013 Liquidity Conference (Rotterdam), and at seminars at Erasmus University, and Cornell for valuable comments. This work was carried out on the National e- infrastructure with the support of SURF Foundation. I thank SURFsara, and in particular Lykle Voort, for technical support, and OneMarket-Data for the use of their OneTick software. I also gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Vereniging Trustfonds Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam. address: drosch@rsm.nl (Dominik M. Rösch) November 4, 2013

2 Abstract The impact of arbitrage on market liquidity The notion that arbitrageurs improve liquidity is based on the assumption that arbitrage opportunities arise because of demand shocks. If, however, arbitrage opportunities reflect informational differences, arbitrageurs create adverse selection and deteriorate liquidity. I test these competing hypotheses in the Depositary Receipts market, where arbitrage is frequent and almost risk-free. As inverse measures of arbitrage activity I use price deviations across both markets based on simultaneous trades, and quotes, and further the velocity at which deviations increase before simultaneous trades. Using 16 years of international tick-by-tick data I find that (i) 70% of all arbitrage opportunities arise because of demand shocks, and (ii) greater arbitrage activity predicts a decrease in order imbalance and an increase in liquidity. These findings suggest that arbitrageurs trade against market order imbalance, and thereby improve market integration and liquidity.

3 Inefficiencies in financial markets can have effects on the real economy. For example, in a financial market in which the law of one price is violated perhaps the purest indication that the financial market is less than perfectly efficient prices do not reflect fundamentals hampering efficient resource allocation and the ability to learn from prices for market-makers and decision makers alike. While liquidity encourages arbitrage activity, which enforces the law of one price, there are good reasons to believe that arbitrageurs can also impact liquidity. According to the limits of arbitrage literature the role of the arbitrageur is to eliminate mispricings and provide liquidity (Gromb and Vayanos, 2010). However, the assumed impact arbitrage has on liquidity is opposite in the Depositary Receipts literature where with arbitrage present, the adverse selection costs of domestic dealers increase, so that... liquidity falls (Domowitz, Glen, and Madhavan, 1998) and trading costs are higher... due to greater adverse selection associated with arbitrageurs (Bacidore and Sofianos, 2002). Indeed, theoretical models suggest that the impact of arbitrage on market liquidity depends on the underlying reason for the arbitrage opportunity to arise. The notion that arbitrageurs provide liquidity is mainly based on the assumption that arbitrage opportunities arise due to non-fundamental demand shocks, such as fire sales by mutual funds, and hence arbitrageurs increase market-making capacity by trading against net market demand (Grossman and Miller, 1988; Holden, 1995; Gromb and Vayanos, 2010; Rahi and Zigrand, 2012; Foucault, Pagano, and Röell, 2013). But in informationally fragmented markets, where arbitrage opportunities can reflect informational differences, arbitrageurs might create adverse selection and deteriorate liquidity (Kumar and Seppi, 1994; Domowitz, Glen, and Madhavan, 1998). Several papers provide evidence that information production varies 1

4 across markets (e.g. Grossman (1988)) which can lead to predictabilities across both markets (Chan, Chan, and Karolyi, 1991; Cremers and Weinbaum, 2010). The impact of arbitrageurs on market liquidity does not need to be contemporaneous alone, but could have persistent effects. O Hara and Oldfield (1986) and Comerton-Forde, Hendershott, Jones, Moulton, and Seasholes (2010) provide theoretical and empirical evidence that overnight inventories affect future liquidity. If arbitrageurs trade against net market order imbalance, a decrease in arbitrage activity might lead to higher order imbalance, which could predict future illiquidity. So far the literature mainly focused on the important impact of high frequency trading (HFT) and algorithmic trading (AT) on market quality. While the general impact of HFT and AT is important, it is equally important to understand the impact of particular trading strategies that require HFT or AT. For example, while Chaboud, Chiquoine, Hjalmarsson, and Vega (2013) show that increased AT decreases arbitrage opportunities, and improves price efficiency in the foreign exchange market, they do not find a relation between the correlation of algorithmic traders actions and market efficiency, and interpret this to provide support for Foucault (2012): The effect of algorithmic trading on the informativeness of prices may ultimately depend on the type of strategies used by algorithmic traders, not on the presence of algorithmic trading per se. One such particular trading strategy is arbitrage, which so far has been mainly investigated in the content of the limits-of-arbitrage literature (e.g. Mitchell, Pulvino, and Stafford (2002); De Jong, Rosenthal, and van Dijk (2009); Gagnon and Karolyi (2010b); Ben-David, Franzoni, and Moussawi (2012).) The limitsof-arbitrage literature can explain why arbitrage opportunities persist, but not why arbitrage opportunities arise. Similarly, the limits-of-arbitrage literature can 2

5 explain how liquidity impacts arbitrage activity, but not how arbitrage impacts liquidity. Schultz and Shive (2010) do provide first empirical evidence that arbitrage opportunities between shares issued by the same company and trading on the same exchange mainly arise from non-fundamental demand shocks and Lou and Polk (2013) look at arbitrage activity in momentum strategies and ask whether arbitrageurs can have a destabilizing effect, but both papers do not investigate the impact on liquidity. Roll, Schwartz, and Subrahmanyam (2007) and Choi, Getmansky, and Tookes (2009) empirically investigate liquidity and arbitrage activity directly. Choi, Getmansky, and Tookes (2009) find empirical evidence in favour of a positive impact of arbitrageurs on liquidity. However, this evidence of a positive impact of arbitrage on liquidity is based on measures of the hedging activity of arbitrageurs, rather than on measures of the actual arbitrage activity itself. Hedging clearly has less possible information than the arbitrage trade itself, and the above mentioned tension, between cross-sectional market making (Holden, 1995) and adverse selection does not arise. Roll, Schwartz, and Subrahmanyam (2007) find opposite evidence, that arbitrageurs in the futures-cash basis deteriorate liquidity. It remains an open empirical question whether the notion that arbitrage activity improves liquidity is supported by empirical evidence. Motivated by these observations, in this paper, I investigate why arbitrage opportunities arise and the impact of arbitrageurs on market liquidity. Of course, the effects of cross-sectional market making (Holden, 1995) and adverse selection are not exclusive. If, for example, both effects are equally strong, and cancel each other out, arbitrage activity will not have a visible effect on the spread set by local market-makers. This forms the null hypothesis. Alternatively, if the 3

6 effect of increased adverse selection dominates, arbitrageurs deteriorate liquidity. This forms the first alternative hypothesis. But if arbitrage opportunities arise because of demand shocks, arbitrageurs trade against local net market demand, and increase the market-making capacity. If this effect is stronger than potential adverse selection arbitrageurs should improve liquidity. This forms the second alternative hypothesis. My focus is the American Depositary Receipts (ADR) market. As laid out by Gagnon and Karolyi (2010b) ADR s represent claims against the home-market shares, and offer identical cash-flows as the ordinary share in the home market (albeit in USD), and hence should trade at the same price. Further, the authors state that in the ADR market, institutions exist to facilitate arbitrage (making arbitrage almost risk-free) and elaborate on the mechanics of arbitrage. Especially the feature of conversion, in which the ADR can be converted to the home market share, and the other way around, makes the ADR market particular suitable to study arbitrage. Despite this the authors provide comprehensive empirical evidence that arbitrage opportunities occur frequently and can be sizeable. Conversations with employees of BNY Mellon (the world s largest depositary for ADR s) confirm that arbitrage is frequent in the ADR market. I examine intraday bid and ask quotes and trade prices for 69 ADRs and currency adjusted prices for the home market stock from Brazil, England, France, Germany, and Mexico over a long time frame from 1996 till I construct two measures of price deviations. First, the difference between the best bid and the best ask prices across both markets, which measures opportunity profits. Second, the difference between simultaneous trade prices, which measures traded profits. Inspired by Schultz and Shive (2010), I first investigate if arbitrage opportunities 4

7 arise due to a non-fundamental demand shock where the asset that creates the arbitrage is also the asset that closes down the arbitrage. I then compare opportunity profits and liquidity around simultaneous trades across both markets. I distinguish between simultaneous trades that occur during (18 million trades) and outside (11 million) positive opportunity profits. I then construct two (inverse) proxies for daily arbitrage activity, namely the daily maximum opportunity profit and the average daily traded profit. I extend the analysis by a third (inverse) measure of arbitrage activity, the velocity at which opportunity profits increase before a simultaneous trade occurs. Using these three stock-day measures of arbitrage activity I estimate vector autoregressions and impulse response functions from detrended and expunged from other calendar regularities arbitrage activity, and both home market and ADR liquidity. I further estimate impulse response functions using net market order imbalance (absolute difference between buyer- and seller-initiated trades), in addition to liquidity measures. To address the concern of an omitted variable bias, I estimate a fixed-effect panel vector autoregression and further the effect of opportunity profits on the difference between illiquidity during and outside overlapping trading hours, i.e. when both the ADR and the home market share are trading. The intraday analysis reveals that in the ADR market more than 70% of all arbitrage arise due to a non-fundamental demand shock. And for simultaneous trades that occur during positive opportunity profits I find that opportunity profits peak at the time the trade occurs with on average 21% higher opportunity profits than its two minute average around the trade. This provides justification for interpreting these trades as motivated by arbitrage. 5

8 Using the daily measures I find that the average daily maximum opportunity profit is around 0.9% (as a percentage of the home-market share price) and the average daily traded profit is around 0.6%, both similar to the cost-adjusted, absolute end-of-day price deviations reported by Gagnon and Karolyi (2010b) of 1.12%. The velocity at which opportunity profits increase before a simultaneous trade occurs is 5BP per minute, on average. Impulse response functions indicate that a positive shock to arbitrage activity predicts an increase in liquidity and a decrease in net market order imbalance. And further that an increase in arbitrage activity does not predict a general improvement in liquidity, but rather that it predicts a stronger increase in liquidity when arbitrageurs are active, i.e. during overlapping trading times, than outside, i.e. when arbitrageurs are not active. The main contribution is to provide empirical evidence that arbitrageurs improve liquidity. I provide empirical evidence that most arbitrage opportunities arise because of a demand shock and that an increase in arbitrage activity predicts a decrease in net market order imbalance. Both indicates that arbitrageurs trade against net market demand, and hence improve international market integration by shifting excess demands across markets. Further I provide evidence that an increase in arbitrage activity predicts an increase in liquidity. A likely explanation is that because net market order imbalance has a persistent effect on liquidity, and arbitrageurs trade against net market order imbalance, arbitrageurs do improve liquidity. My secondary contribution is to extend the ADR literature. First, I use intraday data over a long time span from both the ADR and the home market stock from five different exchanges and document large opportunity profits of almost 1% 6

9 averaged over the whole sample. Second, by showing that an increase in arbitrage activity decreases the gap between liquidity during and outside overlapping trading times I join two distinct research streams in the Depositary Receipts literature, where one focuses on explaining deviations from the law of one price (e.g. Gagnon and Karolyi (2010b)) and the other explains liquidity differences during and outside overlapping trading hours (e.g. Werner and Kleidon (1996); Moulton and Wei (2009)). I consider the finding that arbitrageurs improve liquidity important for at least four reasons. First, the findings provide empirical justification for the assumption underlying the limits of arbitrage theory. Especially, that the benefits of arbitrageurs trading against net market demand outweigh a potential increase in adverse selection, even in emerging markets which are in general less informationally integrated (Bacidore and Sofianos, 2002). Second, the findings help to understand how policy changes that hinder arbitrage activity (e.g. short-sell bans, or transaction taxes), negatively impact not only the efficiency of the financial market, but also its liquidity. For example, in January 2014 eleven European member states plan to introduce a transaction tax on financial instruments of at least 0.1%. The results of this paper suggest that the transaction tax will negatively impact liquidity, because of a decrease in arbitrage activity, which will increase the cost of capital for firms (Amihud and Mendelson, 1986). Third, the results add to the debate about how recent changes to the trading environment, seemingly helping arbitrageurs, affect market quality. Markets are not only more fragmented than ever before allowing arbitrage opportunities to arise, it is also possible to trade on these opportunities in milliseconds using computer based algorithms with very low transaction costs. Looking at all four changes (i.e. fragmentation, high frequency 7

10 trading, algorithmic trading, and liquidity) individually improves market liquidity and informational efficiency (O Hara and Ye, 2011; Menkveld, 2012; Hendershott, Jones, and Menkveld, 2011; Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam, 2008). This paper indicates that arbitrageurs might play an important role in these findings. Fourth, the results can provide an explanation for time-variation in liquidity differences during and outside overlapping trading times. Where Werner and Kleidon (1996) find that quoted spreads of ADR s in 1991 are higher during than outside overlapping trading times, using data from 2003 Moulton and Wei (2009) find the opposite. The increase in arbitrage activity provides one explanation for these different findings. This paper is organized as follows. In section 1 I discuss data and sample construction. Section 2 discusses the construction of the intraday price deviations based on trade and quote data and provides evidence that arbitrage opportunities arise because of demand shocks, and that simultaneous trades around positive opportunity profits are driven by arbitrage motivations. Section 3 discusses the construction of three daily measures of arbitrage activity, and measure of liquidity, and order imbalance. Section 4 shows that an increase in arbitrage activity predicts an increase in liquidity on an individual stock-level using time-series and panel vector autoregressions. Section 5 provides evidence that arbitrage activity predicts liquidity and net market order imbalance at a market level. Section 6 concludes. 1. Data, and sample construction I focus on arbitrage opportunities in the American Depositary Receipts market (ADR), because here arbitrage is frequent and almost risk-free as outlined by (Gagnon and Karolyi, 2010b). For a detailed explanation and a comprehensive in- 8

11 troduction to the ADR market I refer to Karolyi (1998). For a survey about recent developments in the ADR market I refer to Gagnon and Karolyi (2013), chapter 11, which is based on Gagnon and Karolyi (2010a). The feature of convertibility in the ADR market, where an ADR can be converted to the home market share, and the other way around, makes the ADR a particular suitable setting to study arbitrage. Convertibility is a rare feature that distinguishes the ADR arbitrage from many other arbitrage opportunities, for example from arbitrage on Exchange Traded Funds, which can only be converted by authorized participants (Ben-David, Franzoni, and Moussawi (2012)) or from arbitrage on price differences between (cash-settled) derivatives and spot prices, which profit at expiry depends on the difference of the final settlement price of the derivative and the price the underlying could be traded at (which not necessarily needs to be the same, see e.g. Aulerich, Fishe, and Harris (2011)). As the following example shows, convertibility allows to interpret price differences between bid and ask prices at the time an arbitrageur opens the arbitrage position as profits an actual arbitrageur could make. For example, if the currency adjusted bid price of the home market stock is higher than the ask price of the ADR an arbitrage opportunity exists to simultaneously short sell the home market stock at the bid price, convert the proceeds from the short-sale into USD, and buy the ADR at the NYSE at the ask price. 1 After that the ADR can be converted into the home-market stock either through a broker (e.g. Interactive Brokers), a crossing platform (e.g. ADR Max, or ADR 1 Note that this example is for illustrative purposes only. In real markets short-selling is capital intensive, and an initial margin requirement of 150% is required (in the US, Regulation T), which then also creates exchange rate risk. 9

12 Navigator), or the actual depositary bank, which (in general) is obliged to provide the home market share for the ADR and vice-versa. According to Interactive Brokers such conversion takes around one to two business days, and according to wallstreetandtech.com costs 2 to 3 cents a share in After the conversion the home-market share can be delivered to close down the short position, resulting in a USD profit equal to the difference between the bid of the home market and the ask of the ADR at the time the arbitrage position was opened. This indicates that actual realized profits (excluding fixed costs) after the arbitrage position is closed cannot be lower than profits at the time the arbitrage position was opened. To construct my sample of ADR s and their respective home market shares I use standard sources in the DR literature: Datastream, Bank of New York Complete Depositary Receipt Directory ( and Deutsche Bank Depositary Receipts Services (adr.db.com). Details about the sample construction can be found in the appendix. I focus on the NYSE as the cross-listed market as it is and was the world leading exchange in terms of listed Depositary Receipts (DR) and together with NASDAQ captures almost 90% of the worldwide total trading in the DR market of USD 3.5 trillion in 2010 (Cole-Fontayn, 2011). I identify matched home-market/adr pairs and construct my sample based on the five home-market exchanges with the most identified ADR/home-market pairs, and with overlapping trading times to the NYSE. This results in 69 ADR/home-market pairs across the following five exchanges: the London Stock Exchange (England, with 27 stocks), Sao Paolo Stock Exchange (Brazil, 12 stocks), Bolsa Mexicana de Valores (Mexico, During a meeting BNY Mellon mentioned that conversion often takes place within the same day and that conversion costs range from 0 to 5 cents a share. 10

13 12 stocks), XETRA (Germany, 9 stocks), and Euronext Paris (France, 9 stocks). For all matched ADR/home-market pairs I obtain intraday data on quotes and trades (time-stamped with microsecond precision) as well as their respective sizes from Thomson Reuters Tick History (TRTH) over the sample period Jan-1996 (the earliest date available in TRTH) till the end of Similarly, I obtain intraday quotes on the currency pairs required to convert local prices into USD, the currency in which the ADR is quoted in. Quote and trade data is filtered as described in the Appendix (Data filters). After the filtering 5,620,997,653 quotes remain, with roughly 50% from ADRs. Further 804,602,677 trades remain, with around 25% on ADRs. Most of the analysis requires comparing prices across the ADR and the homemarket stock. To have valid, tradable quotes for both the ADR and the homemarket stock most of the analysis is based on overlapping trading times, i.e. when both the home-market as well as the NYSE are in their continuous trading session. Figure 1 shows the continuous trading times for all five exchanges in the sample on The opening and closing time at the NYSE is indicated by the left and right vertical line, respectively. The area within the vertical lines, in which the home-market is open, refers to the overlapping trading hours for this specific exchange. 3 Day light saving time (DST) does not follow the same rule in the USA and the other countries in the sample. Hence, overlapping trading hours between the NYSE and the other exchanges are varying within the year, but in general are 2, 6, and 6.5 hours between Europe, Brazil, and Mexico and the NYSE, respectively (as depicted in Figure 1). 11

14 2. Intraday arbitrage opportunities and simultaneous trades 2.1. Do arbitrage opportunities arise due to demand shocks or information differences? If arbitrage opportunities arise because of non-fundamental demand shocks arbitrageurs will act as cross-sectional market makers (Holden, 1995) and improve liquidity. However, if arbitrage opportunities arise because of different information sets, arbitrageurs will likely be perceived as informed traders, increasing adverse selection costs and deteriorating liquidity. Because the reason behind an arbitrage opportunity to arise partly determines the impact arbitrageurs have on liquidity I first follow Schultz and Shive (2010) and study how arbitrage opportunities arise. To measure opportunity profits profit i,s of stock i in second s I calculate the relative difference between the bid on the home-market (ADR) and the ask on the ADR (home-market), i.e. profit i,s is calculated as: profit i,s = max( bid.home i,s ask.adr i,s, bid.adr i,s ask.home i,s, 0) (1) mid.home i,s mid.home i,s where, mid.home i,s is the last mid-quote price of stock i in second s, and bid.home i,s (ask.home i,s ) is the last bid (ask) of stock i in second s converted to USD using the prevailing bid (ask) of the respective currency pair, i.e. BRL for Brazil, GBP for England, EUR for Germany and France (after 1-Jan-1999, and before DEM and FRF, respectively), and MXN for Mexico. Further bid.adr i,s (ask.adr i,s ) is the last bid (ask) in second s of the ADR trading at the NYSE associated to stock i, adjusted for the respective bundling ratio as described in the Appendix (Data filters). To make results comparable among stocks I scale each second s arbitrage 12

15 profit by the mid-quote of the home-market share. 4 If for one particular stock i at time x 1 opportunity profits are zero, but at time x opportunity profits are positive, at least one bid or ask quote of at least one asset had to change from time x 1 to time x (this asset is denoted the First mover, either the ADR, the home-market stock, or the respective currency pair). Similar, if opportunity profits are positive till time y 1 > x, but zero at time y at least one bid or ask quote of at least one asset had to change. In this case I say that an arbitrage opportunity arises for stock i at time x and disappears at time y (to reduce potential noise I ignore any arbitrage opportunity that last less than one second, so that y > x.) 5 For each stock i, and for each arbitrage opportunity a I consider the maximum opportunity profit within the arbitrage opportunity as the profit opportunity of a. The first three rows of Panel A of Table 1 report the average across all 69 stocks in the sample of the daily average number of arbitrage opportunities, their daily average (time-weighted) maximum opportunity profit in per cent, and the daily average time the arbitrage opportunity persists in seconds. The rest of Panel A report these statistics by exchange. Panel B of Table 1 report these three statistics over two different time intervals, namely 1996 to 2000 and 2001 to The time intervals are chosen as in later parts I focus on data from 2001 to 2011 to mitigate issues arising from infrequent trading and stocks entering the sample. 4 Because this might lead to spurious results in later regressions, where both the independent as well as the dependent variable are scaled by the mid-quote, I also use opportunity profit in USD, which qualitatively yields the same result (unreported). 5 In case the day opens with an arbitrage opportunity, I consider the asset which market opened last as the First mover. On the other hand if an arbitrage opportunity exists and either of the markets closes I drop this arbitrage opportunity from the analysis in this section, as I do not know which asset closes down the arbitrage. Both cases are infrequent and do not impact the main results in this section. 13

16 Following Schultz and Shive (2010) I consider an arbitrage opportunity to arise because of a non-fundamental demand shock if the same asset is responsible for the arbitrage opportunity to arise and to disappear. However, if any of the other two assets moves and the arbitrage opportunity disappears, the shock to the First mover was persistent, reflecting potential differences in information. The table reports all statistics across which asset created the arbitrage opportunity (First mover), namely the respective currency in which the home-market stock is quoted in (Forex), the ADR (ADR), the home-market ordinary stock (ORD), and if both the ADR and the home-market stock move together (BOTH ). 6 For each First mover I distinguish between arbitrage opportunities that arise because of a transitory change in the asset (Transitory), potentially due to a non-fundamental demand shock, or because of a persistent change in the asset (Persistent), potentially due to information. On average around 61 arbitrage opportunities arise per day, of which 43 (over 70%) arise because of price pressure, over the whole sample but also with similar ratios in each of the five exchanges reported in Panel A of Table 1, and in each of the two time periods reported in Panel B of Table 1. On average arbitrage opportunities profits decreased from 0.50% in the early years to 0.24% in the later years of the sample. Also the time arbitrage opportunities last decreased from around 10 minutes to 5 minutes in the later years. Arbitrage opportunities are particular short lived if the arbitrage opportunity arises because of a transitory change in the currency pair (81 seconds), with particular low opportunity profits (0.05%). This indicates that demand shocks in the currency market do not play 6 In the case that the currency pairs moves together with any of the other assets, the arbitrage opportunity is considered to arise or to disappear, because of a movement in the other asset. 14

17 a major role in explaining the ADR arbitrage. However, on average, three times a day, the currency market does seem to lead the other markets creating sizeable opportunity profits of 0.20%, on average. Table 1 provides evidence that the majority of all arbitrage opportunities arise because of a demand shock in either the ADR or the home-market stock, and hence that arbitrageurs trade against net market demand and act as cross-sectional market makers (Holden, 1995) most of the time Are simultaneous trades during positive opportunity profits driven by arbitrage? I now turn to estimate absolute price differences between simultaneous trades and provide empirical evidence that during positive opportunity profits these trades are motivated by arbitrage and behave like arbitrage trades. In particular I show that opportunity profits increase (decrease) before (after) simultaneous trades during positive opportunity profits. To measure trade profits trade.profit i,t of stock i for simultaneous trade t I calculate the relative difference between the trade prices of the ADR and the home market stock, i.e. trade.profit i,t is calculated as: trade.profit i,t = trade.home i,t trade.adr i,t1 mid.home i,t (2) where, trade.home i,t is the currency adjusted trade price for trade t of the homemarket stock, and trade.adr i,t1 is the bundling adjusted trade price for trade t 1 of the ADR, such that t 1 minimizes the distance to t and both trades occur within two seconds, i.e. t t 1 < 2. With 27 million simultaneous trades in total they occur frequently over the 15

18 whole sample, and explain a large fraction of all ADR trades during the overlapping trading times (27%). Further, despite that I match trades that can be up to 2 seconds apart, the average time between trades on the ADR and homemarket share is just 0.27 seconds. The number of simultaneous trades increased significantly from 1996 to 2011 and is not only driven by the increase in total trades in later years. For example, in 2000 the average number of ADR trades per stock-month for German stocks (during the overlapping trading times) is 900, and in 2001 it is 1300 (i.e. on average one ADR trade every two minutes), but the amount of simultaneous trades increased from 200 to over 600 per month (more than tripled), so that for Xetra in 2001 almost half of all trades on ADR s occur within two seconds of a trade on the home market. In the spirit of an event study (where the event is a simultaneous trade) I now look at opportunity profits before and after the event. For each stock-day I average opportunity profits per second from one minute before till one minute after a simultaneous trade occurs across all simultaneous trades within the day. For each stock i and each day d I get 121 observations n with 60 <= n <= 60 denoted profit i,d (n), where the first (last) observation is the average opportunity profit one minute before (after) a simultaneous trade occurs. I then run regressions as depicted in Eq. 3 for each stock-day to explain the time variation of opportunity 16

19 profits around simultaneous trades. 7 profit i,d (n) = α i,d +β 1,i,d Before n +β 2,i,d T ime n +β 3,i,d T ime n Before n +ɛ i,d,n (3) where, α i,d is the intercept, Before n is a dummy variable which is set to 1 before the event, T ime n is a linear time trend, and T ime n Before n is a time trend before the event. Table 2 reports the results from stock-day regressions as in Eq. 3. In the first two columns the dependent variable is profit i,d (n) (Profit opportunity (%)). In the next and last two columns the dependent variable is constructed as before, but instead of averaging opportunity profits, I average proportional quoted spread of the ADR (ADR PQSPR (%)) and home-market ordinary stock (ORD PQSPR (%)), respectively. The proportional quoted spread is defined as the difference between the ask and the bid quote, divided by the mid quote. For each of the three different dependent variables I report two different regressions. In column 1, 3, and 5 (In) the event is a simultaneous trade with positive opportunity profits (i.e. profit i,d (0) > 0). While column 2, 4, and 6 (Out) report results using simultaneous trades with zero opportunity profits as the event (i.e. profit i,d (0) = 0). For each independent variable I report the pooled average estimated slope coefficient. Estimated coefficients for both time trends are scaled by 60, and hence 7 On days with more than one simultaneous trade, regressions are estimated using Weighted- Least-Square, with weights equal to one over the standard deviation of the average opportunity profit in second n. Using OLS only marginally changes the results, indicating that the standard deviation of the average opportunity profit at second n only marginally varies across the 2-minute interval. Further, to address concerns of overlapping events, which can cause autocorrelations, and to adjust for heteroskedasticity I report Newey-West t-statistics. 17

20 measure the change per minute. I further report the pooled average Newey-West t-stat (t-stat avg) (which are capped at -100, and +100), the percentage of coefficients that are positive (% positive), the percentage of coefficients that are positive and significant at the 5% level (% + significant), and the percentage of coefficients that are negative and significant at the 5% level (% - significant). Further for each regression I report the average R 2 and the number of regressions over which the averages are taken (# regressions). The number of regressions indicates that for around 130K (100K) stock-days a simultaneous trade occurs inside (outside) positive opportunity profits. This is a big fraction of the total number of stock-days of around 166K in the whole sample, but still significantly less than the number of stock-days with positive opportunity profits (98%, as shown later in Table 3). First, the average R 2 slightly varies across different regressions, but is always above 51% and in the majority around 60%. This indicates that the proposed functional form captures most of the 2-minutes time variation in opportunity profits, and liquidity around simultaneous trades. Second, the average opportunity profit around simultaneous trades inside positive opportunity profits are much higher than outside, it is around 35BP and 5BP, respectively. 8 This provides evidence that both trades indeed occur within very different situations and are likely driven by very different motivations. More importantly the opportunity profit is higher before a simultaneous trade occurs within positive opportunity profits (measured by Before), and in this case is also strictly increasing (decreasing) before (after) the event (measured by Time and Time*Before, respectively). The opportunity profit 8 A large difference is also visible between the average traded profit (from Eq. 2) during and outside positive opportunity profits, which is 54BP and 24BP, respectively. 18

21 at the time the trade occurs is on average 43BP ( ( )), which is around 21% higher than the average opportunity profit (the estimated intercept of 35BP). The results further indicate that while liquidity slightly decreases from 60 seconds before to 60 seconds after the trade, the magnitude is similar across both kinds of trades, but with very different dynamics. For simultaneous trades outside positive opportunity profits liquidity is pretty much constant before the trade and then worsens with the trade and slowly recovers. On the other hand, in the case of simultaneous trade which occur inside positive opportunity profits liquidity improves before the trade, indicated by the negative and statistical significant coefficient for Time*Before (explaining the increase in opportunity profits) and then reverts back indicated by the positive coefficient for Time and the fact that the absolute magnitude for Time is less than for Time*Before. In fact the quoted spread for the home market stock (ADR) before the event is 3 BP (5 BP) lower than the overall average. In total for both the ADR and the home-market stock the quoted spread is on average around 8 BP lower, which is roughly the same magnitude as the increase in opportunity profits. In unreported tests I consider the 97K stock-days in which both simultaneous trades occur within and outside positive opportunity profits. I run regressions as before, but as dependent variables I consider the difference in opportunity profits (quoted spread) between simultaneous trades within and outside positive opportunity profits. In all cases the absolute average t-statistic is above 2, indicating that the dynamics around simultaneous trades within and outside positive opportunity profits are significantly different from each other. Because opportunity profits rise (fall) before (after) simultaneous trades dur- 19

22 ing positive opportunity profits, I interpret these trades as driven by arbitrage. Of course taking the average across all simultaneous trades with positive opportunity profits will wrongly classify many trades as arbitrage trades and potentially miss out several arbitrage trades. However, the finding of a statistically and economically significant increase (decrease) in opportunity profits from one minute before (after) the actual trade justifies the interpretation that these trades are at least partly driven by arbitrage motivations. And indicates that simultaneous trades at times during positive opportunity profits behave like arbitrage trades, in the sense that an increase in opportunity profits predicts arbitrage trades and that on the other hand arbitrage trades predict a decrease in opportunity profits. One concern might be that I use all simultaneous trades, and not only signed simultaneous trades, i.e. simultaneous trades for which the trade for one market is buyer and the other market is seller initiated. However, this would not allow arbitrageurs to use limit orders, a potentially unrealistic restriction. Chaboud, Chiquoine, Hjalmarsson, and Vega (2013) find that improvement in the informational efficiency of prices... seems to come predominantly from an increase in the trading activity of algorithmic traders when they are.. posting quotes which are hit. Using a datset provided by Nasdaq in which trades are identified as coming from high-frequency traders (HFT), and if the HFT is on the passive (limit order) or active (market-order) side, Brogaard, Hendershott, and Riordan (2013) find that HFT are passive on around half of their trades. Further, Menkveld (2013) finds that for one particular high-frequency trader that employs a cross-market strategy... four out of five of its trades are passive. This indicates that at least high-frequency and algorithmic traders (and potentially arbitrageurs) significantly rely on limit-orders. The build-up of opportunity profits and that arbitrage op- 20

23 portunities last in average for several minutes (Table 1), indicates that profits an arbitrageur could make are more important than speed. For example, under position limits the arbitrageur solves an optimal stopping problem and will not enter the arbitrage immediately (Brennan and Schwartz, 1990). Therefore it stands to reason that arbitrageurs could also make use of limit orders, to increase potential profits beyond what is available by trading immediately using market-orders. Of course, the arbitrageur would only use a limit-order for one asset, and use a market-order for the other asset as soon as the limit-order was hit. 9 So far I have provided empirically evidence that most arbitrage opportunity arise because of demand shocks (Table 1). While this indicates that arbitrageurs likely act as cross-sectional market makers (Holden, 1995) by trading against net market demand, and hence provide liquidity, most of the time, the overall effect of arbitrageurs on liquidity is not clear yet. Many arbitrage opportunities arise because of information differences (Table 1 indicates around 30%) and hence the overall effect of arbitrageurs on liquidity might still be negative. To study the overall effect I now turn to proxy arbitrage activity, and investigate the joint dynamics between arbitrage activity and market liquidity in the following sections. 9 In unreported robustness tests I use signed trades, and find that the main results are unchanged. However, signed trades occur less frequent, but still in total more than 5 million times, and the average difference between trade prices is only around half the size using signed trades instead of all simultaneous trades during positive opportunity profits. A similar argumentation does not apply for measuring opportunity profits. When constructing opportunity profits I ignore the use of limit orders, to ensure that the estimated profits are actively tradable using market orders. 21

24 3. Daily measures of arbitrage activity, liquidity, and order imbalance 3.1. Daily measures of arbitrage activity A potential channel of how arbitrageurs might impact liquidity is through order imbalance. If arbitrage opportunities mainly arise because of demand shocks (as indicated by Table 1), arbitrageurs will trade against, and not cause, a high absolute market order imbalance (OIB). Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam (2002) provide evidence that high OIB reduces liquidity, contemporaneously, and both O Hara and Oldfield (1986) and Comerton-Forde, Hendershott, Jones, Moulton, and Seasholes (2010) provide theoretical and empirical evidence that overnight OIB affect future liquidity. Hence, a lack of arbitrage activity might increase OIB, which affects current and future liquidity. Following Roll, Schwartz, and Subrahmanyam (2007) I focus on daily data. Using daily data ensures that the time is short enough (compared to lets say weekly data) for example to measure the effect of OIB (as empirically found by Comerton-Forde, Hendershott, Jones, Moulton, and Seasholes (2010) using daily data), but on the same time long enough (compared to intraday data) to capture more persistent effects. 10 Unfortunately, a direct measure of arbitrage activity is not available, but a possible indirect (inverse) measure is absolute price difference. Arbitrageurs function in the financial market is to trade on arbitrage opportunities and thereby to enforce the law of one price. Hence, if arbitrageurs are very active, absolute price differences should be low. On the other hand, failing to align prices indicates that 10 However, estimating impulse response functions per stock-day based on 4-minute intervals, leaves the main results qualitatively unchanged. 22

25 arbitrageurs are not active enough. In a similar way, previous literature measured arbitrage activity by the outcome of arbitrage activity, such as the absolute price difference (Roll, Schwartz, and Subrahmanyam, 2007) 11, and return correlations (Lou and Polk, 2013). 12 Motivated by these observations I construct two daily measures of arbitrage activity based on intraday absolute price differences. First, the stock-day maximum observable opportunity profit within the day (from Eq. 1). And second, the stock-day average trade profit across all arbitrage trades (defined as simultaneous trades that occur during positive opportunity profits, from Eq. 2). The motivation for using the daily maximum opportunity profit is the following. In general opportunity profits are lower than or equal to what arbitrageurs see as a suitable compensation (i.e. risk-, and transaction-cost adjusted profits) for pursuing the trade. Opportunity profits cannot be much higher than the compensation 11 I note that Roll, Schwartz, and Subrahmanyam (2007) interpret end-of-day absolute price differences (the basis) as a direct measure of arbitrage activity, so that if the basis widens on a particular day, arbitrage forces on subsequent days... increase. In contrast, I interpret absolute price differences derived from intraday data as an inverse measure of arbitrage activity. The different interpretations are due to differences in the measure as well as differences in the underlying market. First Roll, Schwartz, and Subrahmanyam (2007) use end-of-day price deviations, whereas I use intraday prices. Second, I also look at price deviations across simultaneous trades. And third, in the ADR market arbitrage opportunities are short lived (Table 1 indicates that in average they vanish after several minutes). 12 Alternatively, previous literature used the excess amount of short-selling to measure arbitrage activity (Choi, Getmansky, and Tookes, 2009; Hanson and Sunderam, 2011), but this measure is not feasible for arbitrage positions that are open for less than three business days (as is the case in the market I look at). Equity transaction (in the US) settle T+3, i.e. traders are required to settle the transaction within three business days, if the short-position is open less than three business days it will likely not show up in any statistic. Another potential measure of arbitrage activity in the ADR market is changes in shares outstanding. If for example the home-market stock is converted into the ADR as part of closing down the arbitrage position this will affect the number of shares outstanding. However, as confirmed by BNY Mellon, a lot of arbitrage positions are not actually closed by converting the shares, but rather by trading in the opposite directions, which yields more profits because the asset that is overvalued often becomes the asset that is undervalued, even within the same trading day. 23

26 required by arbitrageurs, because before profits would have reached this level an arbitrageur would step in and drive prices back to fundamentals. The daily maximum opportunity profit within a day should hence be around the compensation required by arbitrageurs. Following this interpretation one would expect that the average of traded profit within the day is of a similar magnitude as the maximum opportunity profit (which is what I find in Table 3). One concern with these measures might be that arbitrage activity might vary purely because of variations in the costs associated with arbitrage. While the opportunity profit is adjusted for varying transaction costs (i.e. the bid-ask spreads), it is not adjusted for fixed costs, such as transaction fees, or the cost of maintaining the required infrastructure, which also vary over time but at a much slower pace. Another concern might be that both measures of arbitrage activity do not take into account the time it takes for an arbitrageur to become active. Despite a large opportunity profit, if an arbitrageur quickly trades on it, arbitrage activity is still relatively high. To address concerns that arbitrage activity is purely driven by time variation in these costs (that go beyond what is captured in detrending the series as in Eq. 4), and to address the notion of time it takes an arbitrageur to trade I construct another (inverse) measure of arbitrage activity based on Table 2. The sum of both time-trends reported from stock-day regressions in Table 2 measures the velocity at which opportunity profits increase before an arbitrage trade occurs, and hence measure how fast an arbitrageur steps in. For example, Table 2 shows that the average velocity at which opportunity profits increase before an arbitrage trade is on average 5BP per minute (more than 13% of the average 24

27 estimated intercept). If the slope is small this indicates that either a small gradual rise or a sudden bigger jump in opportunity profit is enough for an arbitrageur to step in and trade. On the other hand if the slope is large, it indicates that arbitrageurs wait for an extended time for the opportunity profit to increase before they trade. The latter case indicates that arbitrageurs are less active than in the former. And hence the slope can be interpreted as an inverse measure of arbitrage active. Table 3 presents daily summary statistics for all three measures of arbitrage activity by exchange (Panel A) as well as by time (Panel B). The first three rows in Panel A report cross-sectional summary statistics (the mean, minimum, maximum, and the 25%, 50% (median), and 75% percentile) of the time-series averages of the daily maximum opportunity profit, the average traded profit, and the velocity at which opportunity profit increase before an arbitrage trade across all the 69 stock pairs in the sample. The rest of Panel A reports these cross-sectional summary statistics across all stock pairs from a given exchange. Panel B of Table 3 shows cross-sectional statistics across all stock pairs during two different time periods, namely 1996 to 2000 and 2001 to In all cases the first column (#Stocks) indicates the number of stocks over which the cross-sectional summary statistics are computed, and the second column (%Days+) indicates the percentage of stock-days with a positive opportunity profit, traded profit or velocity. For the majority of all stock-days both traded profits (83%) and opportunity profits (98%) are nonzero, with the exception of the early years (1996 to 2000) in which the trade profit cannot be computed for every two out of five stockdays, because of missing arbitrage trades. While both opportunity profits and 25

The impact of arbitrage on market liquidity

The impact of arbitrage on market liquidity January 24, 2018 The impact of arbitrage on market liquidity Dominik Rösch State University of New York, Buffalo I thank Lamont Black, Ekkehart Boehmer, Dion Bongaerts, Howard Chan, Tarun Chordia, Ruben

More information

The Dynamics of Market Efficiency

The Dynamics of Market Efficiency June 21, 2016 The Dynamics of Market Efficiency Dominik M. Rösch, Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, and Mathijs A. van Dijk Rösch is at the State University of New York, Buffalo; Subrahmanyam is at the UCLA Anderson

More information

Kiril Alampieski and Andrew Lepone 1

Kiril Alampieski and Andrew Lepone 1 High Frequency Trading firms, order book participation and liquidity supply during periods of heightened adverse selection risk: Evidence from LSE, BATS and Chi-X Kiril Alampieski and Andrew Lepone 1 Finance

More information

CFR Working Paper NO Call of Duty: Designated Market Maker Participation in Call Auctions

CFR Working Paper NO Call of Duty: Designated Market Maker Participation in Call Auctions CFR Working Paper NO. 16-05 Call of Duty: Designated Market Maker Participation in Call Auctions E. Theissen C. Westheide Call of Duty: Designated Market Maker Participation in Call Auctions Erik Theissen

More information

PRE-CLOSE TRANSPARENCY AND PRICE EFFICIENCY AT MARKET CLOSING: EVIDENCE FROM THE TAIWAN STOCK EXCHANGE Cheng-Yi Chien, Feng Chia University

PRE-CLOSE TRANSPARENCY AND PRICE EFFICIENCY AT MARKET CLOSING: EVIDENCE FROM THE TAIWAN STOCK EXCHANGE Cheng-Yi Chien, Feng Chia University The International Journal of Business and Finance Research VOLUME 7 NUMBER 2 2013 PRE-CLOSE TRANSPARENCY AND PRICE EFFICIENCY AT MARKET CLOSING: EVIDENCE FROM THE TAIWAN STOCK EXCHANGE Cheng-Yi Chien,

More information

Liquidity as risk factor

Liquidity as risk factor Liquidity as risk factor A research at the influence of liquidity on stock returns Bachelor Thesis Finance R.H.T. Verschuren 134477 Supervisor: M. Nie Liquidity as risk factor A research at the influence

More information

LIQUIDITY EXTERNALITIES OF CONVERTIBLE BOND ISSUANCE IN CANADA

LIQUIDITY EXTERNALITIES OF CONVERTIBLE BOND ISSUANCE IN CANADA LIQUIDITY EXTERNALITIES OF CONVERTIBLE BOND ISSUANCE IN CANADA by Brandon Lam BBA, Simon Fraser University, 2009 and Ming Xin Li BA, University of Prince Edward Island, 2008 THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL

More information

INVENTORY MODELS AND INVENTORY EFFECTS *

INVENTORY MODELS AND INVENTORY EFFECTS * Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance forthcoming INVENTORY MODELS AND INVENTORY EFFECTS * Pamela C. Moulton Fordham Graduate School of Business October 31, 2008 * Forthcoming 2009 in Encyclopedia of Quantitative

More information

High Frequency Trading Literature Review November Author(s) / Title Dataset Findings

High Frequency Trading Literature Review November Author(s) / Title Dataset Findings High Frequency Trading Literature Review November 2012 This brief literature review presents a summary of recent empirical studies related to automated or high frequency trading (HFT) and its impact on

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

Internet Appendix: High Frequency Trading and Extreme Price Movements

Internet Appendix: High Frequency Trading and Extreme Price Movements Internet Appendix: High Frequency Trading and Extreme Price Movements This appendix includes two parts. First, it reports the results from the sample of EPMs defined as the 99.9 th percentile of raw returns.

More information

10th Symposium on Finance, Banking, and Insurance Universität Karlsruhe (TH), December 14 16, 2005

10th Symposium on Finance, Banking, and Insurance Universität Karlsruhe (TH), December 14 16, 2005 10th Symposium on Finance, Banking, and Insurance Universität Karlsruhe (TH), December 14 16, 2005 Opening Lecture Prof. Richard Roll University of California Recent Research about Liquidity Universität

More information

Asymmetric Effects of the Limit Order Book on Price Dynamics

Asymmetric Effects of the Limit Order Book on Price Dynamics Asymmetric Effects of the Limit Order Book on Price Dynamics Tolga Cenesizoglu Georges Dionne Xiaozhou Zhou December 5, 2016 Abstract We analyze whether the information in different parts of the limit

More information

Intraday Return Predictability, Informed Limit Orders, and. Algorithmic Trading

Intraday Return Predictability, Informed Limit Orders, and. Algorithmic Trading Intraday Return Predictability, Informed Limit Orders, and Algorithmic Trading Darya Yuferova October 2017 Abstract I study the strategic choice of informed traders for market vs. limit orders by analyzing

More information

Scarcity effects of QE: A transaction-level analysis in the Bund market

Scarcity effects of QE: A transaction-level analysis in the Bund market Scarcity effects of QE: A transaction-level analysis in the Bund market Kathi Schlepper Heiko Hofer Ryan Riordan Andreas Schrimpf Deutsche Bundesbank Deutsche Bundesbank Queen s University Bank for International

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

Tick Size Constraints, High Frequency Trading and Liquidity

Tick Size Constraints, High Frequency Trading and Liquidity Tick Size Constraints, High Frequency Trading and Liquidity Chen Yao University of Warwick Mao Ye University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign December 8, 2014 What Are Tick Size Constraints Standard Walrasian

More information

CHAPTER 6 DETERMINANTS OF LIQUIDITY COMMONALITY ON NATIONAL STOCK EXCHANGE OF INDIA

CHAPTER 6 DETERMINANTS OF LIQUIDITY COMMONALITY ON NATIONAL STOCK EXCHANGE OF INDIA CHAPTER 6 DETERMINANTS OF LIQUIDITY COMMONALITY ON NATIONAL STOCK EXCHANGE OF INDIA 6.1 Introduction In the previous chapter, we established that liquidity commonality exists in the context of an order-driven

More information

HIGH FREQUENCY TRADING AND ITS IMPACT ON MARKET QUALITY

HIGH FREQUENCY TRADING AND ITS IMPACT ON MARKET QUALITY HIGH FREQUENCY TRADING AND ITS IMPACT ON MARKET QUALITY Jonathan A. Brogaard Northwestern University Kellogg School of Management Northwestern University School of Law JD-PhD Candidate j-brogaard@kellogg.northwestern.edu

More information

A Blessing or a Curse? The Impact of High Frequency Trading on Institutional Investors

A Blessing or a Curse? The Impact of High Frequency Trading on Institutional Investors Second Annual Conference on Financial Market Regulation, May 1, 2015 A Blessing or a Curse? The Impact of High Frequency Trading on Institutional Investors Lin Tong Fordham University Characteristics and

More information

Liquidity Supply across Multiple Trading Venues

Liquidity Supply across Multiple Trading Venues Liquidity Supply across Multiple Trading Venues Laurence Lescourret (ESSEC and CREST) Sophie Moinas (University of Toulouse 1, TSE) Market microstructure: confronting many viewpoints, December, 2014 Motivation

More information

Multimarket Trading, Volume Dynamics, and Market Integration

Multimarket Trading, Volume Dynamics, and Market Integration Multimarket Trading, Volume Dynamics, and Market Integration Michael Halling Pamela C. Moulton Marios Panayides * August 7, 2008 Keywords: multimarket trading, cross-listing, market integration, trading

More information

Introduction Theory Equilibrium Data and Methodology Results conclusion. Toxic Arbitrage. Wing Wah Tham. Erasmus University Rotterdam

Introduction Theory Equilibrium Data and Methodology Results conclusion. Toxic Arbitrage. Wing Wah Tham. Erasmus University Rotterdam Toxic Arbitrage Thierry Foucault Roman Kozhan HEC University of Warwick Wing Wah Tham Erasmus University Rotterdam National Bank of Belgium May 27-28, 2015 Arbitrage ˆ Arbitrage is a cornerstone of finance...

More information

Intraday return patterns and the extension of trading hours

Intraday return patterns and the extension of trading hours Intraday return patterns and the extension of trading hours KOTARO MIWA # Tokio Marine Asset Management Co., Ltd KAZUHIRO UEDA The University of Tokyo Abstract Although studies argue that periodic market

More information

Cross-sectional identification of informed trading

Cross-sectional identification of informed trading November 30, 2014 Cross-sectional identification of informed trading Dion Bongaerts, Dominik Rösch, and Mathijs van Dijk Abstract We propose a new approach to measuring informed trading in individual securities

More information

Internet Appendix to. Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity

Internet Appendix to. Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity Internet Appendix to Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity Joel PERESS & Daniel SCHMIDT 6 October 2018 1 Table of Contents Internet Appendix A: The Implications of Distraction

More information

Market Integration and High Frequency Intermediation*

Market Integration and High Frequency Intermediation* Market Integration and High Frequency Intermediation* Jonathan Brogaard Terrence Hendershott Ryan Riordan First Draft: November 2014 Current Draft: November 2014 Abstract: To date, high frequency trading

More information

ETF Short Interest and Failures-to-Deliver: Naked Short-selling or Operational Shorting?

ETF Short Interest and Failures-to-Deliver: Naked Short-selling or Operational Shorting? ETF Short Interest and Failures-to-Deliver: Naked Short-selling or Operational Shorting? PRESENTER Richard Evans Darden School of Business, University of Virginia CO-AUTHORS Rabih Moussawi, Michael Pagano,

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance.

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. RESEARCH STATEMENT Heather Tookes, May 2013 OVERVIEW My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. Much of my work focuses on understanding the ways in which capital market

More information

The Propagation of Shocks Across International Equity Markets: A Microstructure Perspective

The Propagation of Shocks Across International Equity Markets: A Microstructure Perspective DIVISION OF THE HUMANITIES AND SOCIAL SCIENCES CALIFORNIA INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY PASADENA, CALIFORNIA 91125 The Propagation of Shocks Across International Equity Markets: A Microstructure Perspective

More information

Liquidity Variation and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns *

Liquidity Variation and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns * Liquidity Variation and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns * Fangjian Fu Singapore Management University Wenjin Kang National University of Singapore Yuping Shao National University of Singapore Abstract

More information

Order flow and prices

Order flow and prices Order flow and prices Ekkehart Boehmer and Julie Wu Mays Business School Texas A&M University 1 eboehmer@mays.tamu.edu October 1, 2007 To download the paper: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=891745

More information

Multimarket Trading, Volume Dynamics, and Market Integration

Multimarket Trading, Volume Dynamics, and Market Integration Multimarket Trading, Volume Dynamics, and Market Integration Michael Halling Pamela C. Moulton Marios Panayides * April 1 st, 2009 Keywords: multimarket trading, cross-listing, market integration, trading

More information

U.S. Quantitative Easing Policy Effect on TAIEX Futures Market Efficiency

U.S. Quantitative Easing Policy Effect on TAIEX Futures Market Efficiency Applied Economics and Finance Vol. 4, No. 4; July 2017 ISSN 2332-7294 E-ISSN 2332-7308 Published by Redfame Publishing URL: http://aef.redfame.com U.S. Quantitative Easing Policy Effect on TAIEX Futures

More information

FINRA/CFP Conference on Market Fragmentation, Fragility and Fees September 17, 2014

FINRA/CFP Conference on Market Fragmentation, Fragility and Fees September 17, 2014 s in s in Department of Economics Rutgers University FINRA/CFP Conference on Fragmentation, Fragility and Fees September 17, 2014 1 / 31 s in Questions How frequently do breakdowns in market quality occur?

More information

Making Derivative Warrants Market in Hong Kong

Making Derivative Warrants Market in Hong Kong Making Derivative Warrants Market in Hong Kong Chow, Y.F. 1, J.W. Li 1 and M. Liu 1 1 Department of Finance, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong Email: yfchow@baf.msmail.cuhk.edu.hk Keywords:

More information

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2015 Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis Seth E. Williams Utah State University

More information

THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS

THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS PART I THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS Introduction and Overview We begin by considering the direct effects of trading costs on the values of financial assets. Investors

More information

Illiquidity and Stock Returns:

Illiquidity and Stock Returns: Illiquidity and Stock Returns: Empirical Evidence from the Stockholm Stock Exchange Jakob Grunditz and Malin Härdig Master Thesis in Accounting & Financial Management Stockholm School of Economics Abstract:

More information

Equilibrium Fast Trading

Equilibrium Fast Trading Equilibrium Fast Trading Bruno Biais 1 Thierry Foucault 2 and Sophie Moinas 1 1 Toulouse School of Economics 2 HEC Paris September, 2014 Financial Innovations Financial Innovations : New ways to share

More information

Adjusting for earnings volatility in earnings forecast models

Adjusting for earnings volatility in earnings forecast models Uppsala University Department of Business Studies Spring 14 Bachelor thesis Supervisor: Joachim Landström Authors: Sandy Samour & Fabian Söderdahl Adjusting for earnings volatility in earnings forecast

More information

Market Microstructure Invariants

Market Microstructure Invariants Market Microstructure Invariants Albert S. Kyle and Anna A. Obizhaeva University of Maryland TI-SoFiE Conference 212 Amsterdam, Netherlands March 27, 212 Kyle and Obizhaeva Market Microstructure Invariants

More information

Short Sales and Put Options: Where is the Bad News First Traded?

Short Sales and Put Options: Where is the Bad News First Traded? Short Sales and Put Options: Where is the Bad News First Traded? Xiaoting Hao *, Natalia Piqueira ABSTRACT Although the literature provides strong evidence supporting the presence of informed trading in

More information

The Reporting of Island Trades on the Cincinnati Stock Exchange

The Reporting of Island Trades on the Cincinnati Stock Exchange The Reporting of Island Trades on the Cincinnati Stock Exchange Van T. Nguyen, Bonnie F. Van Ness, and Robert A. Van Ness Island is the largest electronic communications network in the US. On March 18

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Multimarket High-Frequency Trading and. Commonality in Liquidity

Multimarket High-Frequency Trading and. Commonality in Liquidity Multimarket High-Frequency Trading and Commonality in Liquidity Olga Klein and Shiyun Song January 22, 2018 Abstract This paper examines the effects of multimarket high-frequency trading (HFT) activity

More information

High-Frequency Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market: New Evil or Technological Progress? Ryan Perrin

High-Frequency Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market: New Evil or Technological Progress? Ryan Perrin High-Frequency Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market: New Evil or Technological Progress? Ryan Perrin 301310315 Introduction: High-frequency trading (HFT) was introduced into the foreign exchange market

More information

Order flow and prices

Order flow and prices Order flow and prices Ekkehart Boehmer and Julie Wu * Mays Business School Texas A&M University College Station, TX 77845-4218 March 14, 2006 Abstract We provide new evidence on a central prediction of

More information

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n.

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. 5/2014 April 2014 ISSN: 2239-2734 This Working Paper is published under

More information

BIS working paper No. 271 February 2009 joint with M. Loretan, J. Gyntelberg and E. Chan of the BIS

BIS working paper No. 271 February 2009 joint with M. Loretan, J. Gyntelberg and E. Chan of the BIS 2 Private information, stock markets, and exchange rates BIS working paper No. 271 February 2009 joint with M. Loretan, J. Gyntelberg and E. Chan of the BIS Tientip Subhanij 24 April 2009 Bank of Thailand

More information

The Impact of Cross-listing on High-Frequency Trading

The Impact of Cross-listing on High-Frequency Trading The Impact of Cross-listing on High-Frequency Trading Olga Dodd a, Bart Frijns a, Ivan Indriawan a, Roberto Pascual b a Auckland University of Technology, Auckland, New Zealand b University of the Balearic

More information

Are Retail Orders Different? Charles M. Jones Graduate School of Business Columbia University. and

Are Retail Orders Different? Charles M. Jones Graduate School of Business Columbia University. and Are Retail Orders Different? Charles M. Jones Graduate School of Business Columbia University and Marc L. Lipson Department of Banking and Finance Terry College of Business University of Georgia First

More information

Discussion of "The Value of Trading Relationships in Turbulent Times"

Discussion of The Value of Trading Relationships in Turbulent Times Discussion of "The Value of Trading Relationships in Turbulent Times" by Di Maggio, Kermani & Song Bank of England LSE, Third Economic Networks and Finance Conference 11 December 2015 Mandatory disclosure

More information

Caught on Tape: Institutional Trading, Stock Returns, and Earnings Announcements

Caught on Tape: Institutional Trading, Stock Returns, and Earnings Announcements Caught on Tape: Institutional Trading, Stock Returns, and Earnings Announcements The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters.

More information

Intraday Return Predictability, Informed Limit Orders, and Algorithmic Trading

Intraday Return Predictability, Informed Limit Orders, and Algorithmic Trading Intraday Return Predictability, Informed Limit Orders, and Algorithmic Trading DARYA YUFEROVA May 10, 2018 Preliminary and incomplete ABSTRACT We study the effect of algorithmic trading on strategic choice

More information

High-Frequency Trading and Market Stability

High-Frequency Trading and Market Stability Conference on High-Frequency Trading (Paris, April 18-19, 2013) High-Frequency Trading and Market Stability Dion Bongaerts and Mark Van Achter (RSM, Erasmus University) 2 HFT & MARKET STABILITY - MOTIVATION

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

Predicting RMB exchange rate out-ofsample: Can offshore markets beat random walk?

Predicting RMB exchange rate out-ofsample: Can offshore markets beat random walk? Predicting RMB exchange rate out-ofsample: Can offshore markets beat random walk? By Chen Sichong School of Finance, Zhongnan University of Economics and Law Dec 14, 2015 at RIETI, Tokyo, Japan Motivation

More information

Measuring and explaining liquidity on an electronic limit order book: evidence from Reuters D

Measuring and explaining liquidity on an electronic limit order book: evidence from Reuters D Measuring and explaining liquidity on an electronic limit order book: evidence from Reuters D2000-2 1 Jón Daníelsson and Richard Payne, London School of Economics Abstract The conference presentation focused

More information

An Investigation of Spot and Futures Market Spread in Indian Stock Market

An Investigation of Spot and Futures Market Spread in Indian Stock Market An Investigation of and Futures Market Spread in Indian Stock Market ISBN: 978-81-924713-8-9 Harish S N T. Mallikarjunappa Mangalore University (snharishuma@gmail.com) (tmmallik@yahoo.com) Executive Summary

More information

Participation Strategy of the NYSE Specialists to the Trades

Participation Strategy of the NYSE Specialists to the Trades MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Participation Strategy of the NYSE Specialists to the Trades Köksal Bülent Fatih University - Department of Economics 2008 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/30512/

More information

THE TERM STRUCTURE OF BOND MARKET LIQUIDITY

THE TERM STRUCTURE OF BOND MARKET LIQUIDITY THE TERM STRUCTURE OF BOND MARKET LIQUIDITY Ruslan Goyenko, University Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, Andrey Ukhov, ON-the-Run vs OFF-the-Run Treasury market illiquidity literature focus: on-the-run ( Fleming

More information

Foreign Fund Flows and Asset Prices: Evidence from the Indian Stock Market

Foreign Fund Flows and Asset Prices: Evidence from the Indian Stock Market Foreign Fund Flows and Asset Prices: Evidence from the Indian Stock Market ONLINE APPENDIX Viral V. Acharya ** New York University Stern School of Business, CEPR and NBER V. Ravi Anshuman *** Indian Institute

More information

Potential Pilot Problems. Charles M. Jones Columbia Business School December 2014

Potential Pilot Problems. Charles M. Jones Columbia Business School December 2014 Potential Pilot Problems Charles M. Jones Columbia Business School December 2014 1 The popular view about equity markets 2 Trading certainly looks different today 20 th century 21 st century Automation

More information

Price Pressure in Commodity Futures or Informed Trading in Commodity Futures Options. Abstract

Price Pressure in Commodity Futures or Informed Trading in Commodity Futures Options. Abstract Price Pressure in Commodity Futures or Informed Trading in Commodity Futures Options Alexander Kurov, Bingxin Li and Raluca Stan Abstract This paper studies the informational content of the implied volatility

More information

The True Cross-Correlation and Lead-Lag Relationship between Index Futures and Spot with Missing Observations

The True Cross-Correlation and Lead-Lag Relationship between Index Futures and Spot with Missing Observations The True Cross-Correlation and Lead-Lag Relationship between Index Futures and Spot with Missing Observations Shih-Ju Chan, Lecturer of Kao-Yuan University, Taiwan Ching-Chung Lin, Associate professor

More information

The information value of block trades in a limit order book market. C. D Hondt 1 & G. Baker

The information value of block trades in a limit order book market. C. D Hondt 1 & G. Baker The information value of block trades in a limit order book market C. D Hondt 1 & G. Baker 2 June 2005 Introduction Some US traders have commented on the how the rise of algorithmic execution has reduced

More information

NYSE Closure and Global Liquidity: The Case of Cross-listed Stocks

NYSE Closure and Global Liquidity: The Case of Cross-listed Stocks NYSE Closure and Global Liquidity: The Case of Cross-listed Stocks OLGA DODD a,* and BART FRIJNS a a Department of Finance, Auckland University of Technology, Auckland, New Zealand This version: December

More information

Slow-Moving Capital and Execution Costs: Evidence from a Major Trading Glitch

Slow-Moving Capital and Execution Costs: Evidence from a Major Trading Glitch Slow-Moving Capital and Execution Costs: Evidence from a Major Trading Glitch Vincent Bogousslavsky Swiss Finance Institute EPFL vincent.bogousslavsky@epfl.ch Mehmet Sağlam Lindner College of Business

More information

High-Frequency Quoting: Measurement, Detection and Interpretation. Joel Hasbrouck

High-Frequency Quoting: Measurement, Detection and Interpretation. Joel Hasbrouck High-Frequency Quoting: Measurement, Detection and Interpretation Joel Hasbrouck 1 Outline Background Look at a data fragment Economic significance Statistical modeling Application to larger sample Open

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Centralized Trading, Transparency and Interest Rate Swap Market Market Liquidity: Evidence from the Implementation of the Dodd-Frank Act

Centralized Trading, Transparency and Interest Rate Swap Market Market Liquidity: Evidence from the Implementation of the Dodd-Frank Act Centralized Trading, Transparency and Interest Rate Swap Market Market Liquidity: Evidence from the Implementation of the Dodd-Frank Act Evangelos Benos Bank of England Michalis Vasios Bank of England

More information

Cycles of Declines and Reversals. following Overnight Market Declines

Cycles of Declines and Reversals. following Overnight Market Declines Cycles of Declines and Reversals * following Overnight Market Declines Farshid Abdi Job Market Paper This version: October 2018 Latest version available at farshidabdi.net/jmp ABSTRACT This paper uncovers

More information

Shades of Darkness: A Pecking Order of Trading Venues

Shades of Darkness: A Pecking Order of Trading Venues Shades of Darkness: A Pecking Order of Trading Venues Albert J. Menkveld (VU University Amsterdam) Bart Zhou Yueshen (INSEAD) Haoxiang Zhu (MIT Sloan) May 2015 Second SEC Annual Conference on the Regulation

More information

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg OTTO-VON-GUERICKE-UNIVERSITY MAGDEBURG FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT Comparison of the Stock Price Clustering of stocks which are traded in the US and Germany Is XETRA more efficient than the NYSE?

More information

Which is Limit Order Traders More Fearful Of: Non-Execution Risk or Adverse Selection Risk?

Which is Limit Order Traders More Fearful Of: Non-Execution Risk or Adverse Selection Risk? Which is Limit Order Traders More Fearful Of: Non-Execution Risk or Adverse Selection Risk? Wee Yong, Yeo* Department of Finance and Accounting National University of Singapore September 14, 2007 Abstract

More information

Benefits of International Cross-Listing and Effectiveness of Bonding

Benefits of International Cross-Listing and Effectiveness of Bonding Benefits of International Cross-Listing and Effectiveness of Bonding The paper examines the long term impact of the first significant deregulation of U.S. disclosure requirements since 1934 on cross-listed

More information

Style Timing with Insiders

Style Timing with Insiders Volume 66 Number 4 2010 CFA Institute Style Timing with Insiders Heather S. Knewtson, Richard W. Sias, and David A. Whidbee Aggregate demand by insiders predicts time-series variation in the value premium.

More information

Why Do Traders Choose Dark Markets? Ryan Garvey, Tao Huang, Fei Wu *

Why Do Traders Choose Dark Markets? Ryan Garvey, Tao Huang, Fei Wu * Why Do Traders Choose Dark Markets? Ryan Garvey, Tao Huang, Fei Wu * Abstract We examine factors that influence U.S. equity trader choice between dark and lit markets. Marketable orders executed in the

More information

Algorithmic Trading in Volatile Markets

Algorithmic Trading in Volatile Markets Algorithmic Trading in Volatile Markets First draft: 19 August 2013 Current draft: 15 January 2014 ABSTRACT Algorithmic trading (AT) is widely adopted by equity investors. In the current paper we investigate

More information

Daniel Lange TAXES, LIQUIDITY RISK, AND CREDIT SPREADS: EVIDENCE FROM THE GERMAN BOND MARKET

Daniel Lange TAXES, LIQUIDITY RISK, AND CREDIT SPREADS: EVIDENCE FROM THE GERMAN BOND MARKET Daniel Lange TAXES, LIQUIDITY RISK, AND CREDIT SPREADS: EVIDENCE FROM THE GERMAN BOND MARKET DANIEL LANGE Introduction Over the past decade, the European bond market has been on a path of dynamic growth.

More information

Price Effects of Addition or Deletion from the Standard & Poor s 500 Index

Price Effects of Addition or Deletion from the Standard & Poor s 500 Index Price Effects of Addition or Deletion from the Standard & Poor s 5 Index Evidence of Increasing Market Efficiency The Leonard N. Stern School of Business Glucksman Institute for Research in Securities

More information

Option listing, trading activity and the informational efficiency of the underlying stocks

Option listing, trading activity and the informational efficiency of the underlying stocks Option listing, trading activity and the informational efficiency of the underlying stocks Khelifa Mazouz, Shuxing Yin and Sam Agyei-Amponah Abstract This paper examines the impact of option listing on

More information

The Liquidity of Dual-Listed Corporate Bonds: Empirical Evidence from Italian Markets

The Liquidity of Dual-Listed Corporate Bonds: Empirical Evidence from Italian Markets The Liquidity of Dual-Listed Corporate Bonds: Empirical Evidence from Italian Markets N. Linciano, F. Fancello, M. Gentile, and M. Modena CONSOB BOCCONI Conference Milan, February 27, 215 The views and

More information

Dual-Listed Shares and Trading

Dual-Listed Shares and Trading Dual-Listed Shares and Trading This Version: 15-Dec-2011 Abstract We study companies with dual-listed shares in China (mainland) and Hong Kong. When China has a short-sale ban, Chinese stock prices are

More information

Changes in REIT Liquidity : Evidence from Daily Data

Changes in REIT Liquidity : Evidence from Daily Data J Real Estate Finan Econ (2011) 43:258 280 DOI 10.1007/s11146-010-9270-3 Changes in REIT Liquidity 1988 2007: Evidence from Daily Data Susanne E. Cannon & Rebel A. Cole Published online: 9 September 2010

More information

Analysis Determinants of Order Flow Toxicity, HFTs Order Flow Toxicity and HFTs Impact on Stock Price Variance

Analysis Determinants of Order Flow Toxicity, HFTs Order Flow Toxicity and HFTs Impact on Stock Price Variance Analysis Determinants of Order Flow Toxicity, HFTs Order Flow Toxicity and HFTs Impact on Stock Price Variance Serhat Yildiz University of Mississippi syildiz@bus.olemiss.edu Bonnie F. Van Ness University

More information

Inverse ETFs and Market Quality

Inverse ETFs and Market Quality Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-215 Inverse ETFs and Market Quality Darren J. Woodward Utah State University Follow this and additional

More information

CFR Working Paper NO Resiliency: A Dynamic View of Liquidity. A. Kempf D. Mayston M. Gehde-Trapp P. K. Yadav

CFR Working Paper NO Resiliency: A Dynamic View of Liquidity. A. Kempf D. Mayston M. Gehde-Trapp P. K. Yadav CFR Working Paper NO. 15-04 Resiliency: A Dynamic View of Liquidity A. Kempf D. Mayston M. Gehde-Trapp P. K. Yadav Resiliency: A Dynamic View of Liquidity by Alexander Kempf Daniel Mayston Monika Gehde

More information

Portfolio performance and environmental risk

Portfolio performance and environmental risk Portfolio performance and environmental risk Rickard Olsson 1 Umeå School of Business Umeå University SE-90187, Sweden Email: rickard.olsson@usbe.umu.se Sustainable Investment Research Platform Working

More information

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Badrinath Kottimukkalur * January 2018 Abstract This paper provides an arbitrage based explanation for the puzzling negative

More information

Economic Consequences of International Cross-listing and Multimarket Trading. Olga Dodd

Economic Consequences of International Cross-listing and Multimarket Trading. Olga Dodd Economic Consequences of International Cross-listing and Multimarket Trading Olga Dodd Abstract This study examines the impact of cross-listing and multimarket trading on the stock s information environment.

More information

TraderEx Self-Paced Tutorial and Case

TraderEx Self-Paced Tutorial and Case Background to: TraderEx Self-Paced Tutorial and Case Securities Trading TraderEx LLC, July 2011 Trading in financial markets involves the conversion of an investment decision into a desired portfolio position.

More information

Upstairs Market for Principal and Agency Trades: Analysis of Adverse Information and Price Effects

Upstairs Market for Principal and Agency Trades: Analysis of Adverse Information and Price Effects THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LVI, NO. 5 OCT. 2001 Upstairs Market for Principal and Agency Trades: Analysis of Adverse Information and Price Effects BRIAN F. SMITH, D. ALASDAIR S. TURNBULL, and ROBERT W.

More information

Rating Efficiency in the Indian Commercial Paper Market. Anand Srinivasan 1

Rating Efficiency in the Indian Commercial Paper Market. Anand Srinivasan 1 Rating Efficiency in the Indian Commercial Paper Market Anand Srinivasan 1 Abstract: This memo examines the efficiency of the rating system for commercial paper (CP) issues in India, for issues rated A1+

More information

Appendix. A. Firm-Specific DeterminantsofPIN, PIN_G, and PIN_B

Appendix. A. Firm-Specific DeterminantsofPIN, PIN_G, and PIN_B Appendix A. Firm-Specific DeterminantsofPIN, PIN_G, and PIN_B We consider how PIN and its good and bad information components depend on the following firm-specific characteristics, several of which have

More information

Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility. David A. Hsieh. Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC (919)

Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility. David A. Hsieh. Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC (919) Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility by David A. Hsieh Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC 27706 (919)-660-7779 October 1993 Prepared for the Conference on Financial Innovations: 20 Years

More information

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH ORDER IMBALANCE AND THE PRICING OF INDEX FUTURES Joseph K.W. Fung HKIMR Working Paper No.13/2006 October 2006 Working Paper No.1/ 2000 (a company incorporated

More information