Do business cycle peaks predict election calls? 1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Do business cycle peaks predict election calls? 1"

Transcription

1 Do business cycle peaks predict election calls? 1 by Marcel-Cristian Voia and J. Stephen Ferris Third Draft May 7, 2012 Department of Economics Carleton University Ottawa, Ontario, K1S 5B6 Abstract This paper examines the empirical regularity that business cycle peaks and federal elections tend to arise together in Westminster parliamentary democracies, particularly as it applies to Canadian data over the post Confederation time period (1870 onwards). We argue that the appearance of timing simultaneity and the proper identification of causality is possible only if the selection issue associated with observed events is addressed carefully. Our results suggest that it is business cycle peaks that lead federal elections rather than the other way around. While such a finding reinforces the hypothesis of strategic election timing, the result is also insightful because it helps to explain why the predicted presence of a political business cycle is harder to find in parliamentary governments where the date of the next election is under the control of the governing political party than in democratic systems where governing durations and election dates are fixed. Key Words: election timing, political business cycles, selection models, election hazard JEL categories: D72, D78, C41. 1 We would like to thank Hashmat Khan, Niklas Potrafke, Marcos Menchaca, Stan Winer and a referee from this journal for comments on earlier drafts of this paper. Earlier versions of this paper were given at the Public Choice Society Meetings in San Antonio, March 2011 and the Canadian Economic Association Meetings in Ottawa, June 2011.

2 1. Introduction The motivation for this paper is provided in Figure 1 below. There a diagram placing the dates of Canadian federal elections against the dates on which the Canadian business cycle peaked suggests a remarkable coincidence in timing. Between the introduction of parliamentary democracy in Canada (Confederation in 1867) and the present there have been ten occasions when the year of a federal election and the year of a business cycle peak have coincided; in another thirteen cases, they arose within one year of each other. On the other hand, the diagram also shows some obvious exceptions: the 1931 election that arose in the heart of the Great Depression and the relatively long duration of current (post 1980) business cycles in comparison with more frequently arising federal elections. The latter highlights an asymmetry that arises between elections and business cycle peaks--there have been 40 general elections since Confederation as compared to 32 business cycles. 2 All in all, however, the appearance of synchronization seems close enough to pose the question of whether or not there is a meaningful empirical relationship arising between the two. Our purpose in this paper is then to inquire into the relationship between business cycle peaks and elections in Canada and, to the extent a significant statistical relationship can be found, to ask whether one occurrence is the cause of the other. Of particular interest is whether business cycle peaks lead elections and thus whether the data is consistent with the hypothesis of strategic election timing versus the alternatives that the two events arise from common causes or because the election stimulates the economy thus contributing to the business cycle peaking. To investigate this problem we organize the paper as follows: Section 2 describes the methodology followed, Section 3 presents the results of the independent probit models, and Section 4 presents the results of the bivariate probit models. Section 5 discusses causal identification and robustness tests while Section 6 presents the policy implications of the analysis. Section 7 concludes. 2 Canada is a parliamentary democracy where the governing political party is determined by the majority political party elected in a general, first-past-the-post constituency election. Over our time period, , there was set constitutionally a five year maximum term within which the governing party typically could chose the date of the next federal election. The constitutional limit may have restricted artificially the duration of governments relative to business cycle, a feature that will influence the choice of our estimation procedure below. 1

3 -- insert Figure 1 about here Methodology To identify the relationship between business cycle peaks and federal elections in Canada we use a methodology that builds through a sequence of steps. In the first step we model the probability that the two events arise separately by identifying the factors that are exogenous to each event. After doing so we test for whether there exists a correlation between these two events without making any special correction for simultaneity. If no correlation can be identified, we then ask whether simultaneity could be present and first assume that that simultaneity is due to common unobservables missing from the two equations. To do this we estimate a bivariate model that assumes correlated unobservables. When we find that the apparent correlation is not due to unobservables, we next ask whether there is a selection issue that needs to be addressed. To test this we estimate a bivariate model with selection that we expect will capture the correlation between the two events. If a correlation can be identified, we then proceed to establish the proper direction of causation by estimating two selection models (one that conditions the election call on peaks, the other that conditions the peaks on the election). Opposite signed significant correlations, we argue, establishes the appropriate direction of causation between the two events. To quantify the effect of this correlation we first generate the risk measure associated with the event that drives the correlation. This, we argue, is the hazard of a business cycle peak, the risk that a business cycle peak will arise given that it has not yet occurred. This estimated measure of risk is then re-introduced into the original election probability equation as a generated regressor that corrects for selection effects and is so used in both linear and nonlinear versions of the probability model. Because the generated risk measure is the equivalent of an Inverse Mills ratio, a generated variable that corrects for selection in linear models, we expect a stronger effect on the probability measure that is linear. As an additional test, we consider the effect of this generated risk measure on the log-duration of the event at risk. This last model is equivalent to an accelerated 2

4 failure hazard model in linear form. Such a linear specification of the hazard is helpful because it correctly captures the selection effect and therefore the correlation arising between the two events. Proceeding more formally, our task is to estimate parsimonious models that characterize the probabilities of having a business cycle peak and having an election. To begin, we characterize the observation of an election as a binary variable,, where { (1) The realization of is then used to define a latent utility measure of an election call,. Given the available data, the latent utility of an election call can be modeled as:, (2) where represents a set of political variables, a set of macro variables, a set policy variables that may be relevant for an election call. We assume that the error term,, is normally distributed with mean zero and constant variance,. Under the assumption of normalcy and together with the observed election calls,, as the outcome, the model represented in (2) becomes a probit model. The probability of observing an election can then be estimated using the reduced form model: ( ), (3) where ( ) is the cumulative density function (CDF) associated with the normal distribution. For the second case, we characterize the observation of a peak in the business cycle in year t,, as the binary variable: { (4) 3

5 The realization of the business cycle, is in turn used to define a latent utility measure of the probability of realizing a peak in. Given the available data, we use the following model to estimate that latent utility as (5) where is an international indicator of cyclical activity closely associated with the Canadian business cycle, is a set of relative prices, a set of policy variables thought to be associated with real output growth in Canada, and is a random error. Again we assume that the error term in the latent utility model is normally distributed so that together with the observed cycle peaks as the outcome, the model in (5) becomes a probit model. The probability of observing a peak in the business cycle can then be estimated using the following reduced form: ( ) (6) where ( ) is the CDF of a normal distribution. The latter arises because of the assumption made with respect to, i.e. ( ). Before moving to the stage of joint determination, the models in (3) and (6) are tested for specification error, endogeneity, and fit. To anticipate our findings, the tests suggest that the two chosen models are well specified with the results that present no evidence of endogeneity bias and generate a good fit with the data. Our structuring of the problem has thus far focused on finding models that explain the two events when the two events are treated separately. Here the observed coincidence in timing would arise from the timing of the underlying factors, some of which the two relationships may have in common. After finding models that provide the best possible fit for these two independent events, we turn in the second stage of our analysis to the additional possibility that the two observed events are correlated through unobservables. Hence our focus becomes whether there is independent correlation arising between the two events is actually present and, if present, what generates this correlation. Does the correlation arise because important but unobservable 4

6 variables influence both equations or does the correlation arise because there is an important selection issue that links the two events. Our first test for correlation between the two models considers the possibility that the two models are seemingly unrelated but correlated. To account for this correlation, we consider a bivariate model of the form: { (7) where and are correlated with ( ) and where the two sets of covariates may include some of the same together with additional covariates that are important for one model but not the other. If the error of the bivariate model is normally distributed with correlation, we can estimate (7) using a bivariate probit model with bivariate probability: ( ) ( ( ) ( ) ), (8) where ( ) and ( ). Identification is achieved in part through specification of the function form of our test (nonlinear for both equations and the correlation parameter, ) and because the two models have only a few regressors in common and are treated as seemingly unrelated. There is one important reason why the seemingly unrelated specification above would not measure the true degree of correlation arising between the two errors. This is when the selection of one of the events is due to the realization of the other. Hence to account for this selection possibility, we consider a Heckman-type selection model based on the two separate probit models where the disturbances are correlated in the same spirit as in the seemingly unrelated regression model but where the realization of one is conditional on the realization of the other. Note that in general either of the two events could be the triggering mechanism. In our case a business cycle peak could precipitate an election call or an election could trigger a peak in the business cycle. This means that the two forms of the specification test can be used as a single test for which event leads the other. In particular, if a business cycle peak leads an election call, then the unexpected arrival of a business 5

7 cycle peak should increase unexpectedly the probability of an election. The two equation residuals should be positively correlated. At the same time, however, if a business cycle peak truly led an election call then an unexpected election call should not increase the likelihood of a business cycle peak. Rather the business cycle peak should now be less likely. This implies that the residuals of the Heckman specification test should be negatively correlated when the election call is used to condition a business cycle peak. It follows that the two Heckman selection possibilities can be used to test for the ordering of the relationship between elections calls and business cycle peaks. If event A conditions the occurrence of event B, then the correlation among the residuals of the Heckman specification test should be positive when conditioned by A and negative when conditioned by B. To capture selection bias by conditioning on business cycle peaks, the following model is constructed: ( ), together with where and are correlated with ( ). If have a bivariate normal distribution with mean zero and correlation, the model can be written as a bivariate censored probit and specified as { ( ) (9) The new model assumes that the probability of an election call is tied to the business cycle peaking such that its realization,, adds information relevant to the observation of an election. Equation (9) is then estimated as a bivariate probit censored model of the Heckman type. To capture the alternative form of selection bias we condition on elections. Here the same procedure is followed with conditioning in the second probit equation. Maddala (1983) argues that in absence of exclusion restrictions on the exogenous variables, the same regressors cannot be used in the two equations. However, Wilde (2000) showed that identification can be achieved when each equation contains independently varying exogenous regressors. Hence under the method 6

8 we adopt, identification can arise under two conditions. First as long as the joint normality of the error terms is satisfied, identification is achieved. On the other hand, if normalcy is not satisfied, identification will be weak and an exclusion restriction in the separation equation will be needed. It follows that when the necessary parameterization is in question, the use of instruments will be particularly helpful. Consequently we use additional regressors in both parts of our model, regressors that are important for an election call but not for economic growth and vice versa. 3 These additional regressors define the exclusion restrictions used for identification in the bivariate probit model. The significance of these additional variables (shown in the empirical section below) implies that our exclusion restrictions have worked. Our data has the additional complication of having the potential triggering event arise infrequently relative to the other event. This unbalancing arises because the time between elections in Canada is limited constitutionally while business cycles have no similar truncation. It follows that the number of conditioning events is relatively small and that elections and business cycle peaks cannot be matched symmetrically. In partial response and as a robustness test of our initial findings, we redo the timing convention for the dating of our events. Whereas our original test would count an October election as arising in the following year, our redating procedure gives a weight of 1/4 to the current year and 3/4 to the following year. A similar adjustment is made for the dating of the business cycle peak. Doing so both increases the number of years in which elections and business cycle peaks arise and makes their appearance in time more symmetric. The results of these specifications (and an alternative linearized version of the model) identify a positive correlation between the two models when conditioned on business cycle peaks, reinforced by a negative correlation when the models are conditioned on an election call. Hence our tests encourage us to believe that causation runs from business cycle peaks to elections rather than the other way round. To further assess 3 These include the fraction of seats won by the winning political party (Seats) and whether or not the winning political party had a minority government or not (Minority) as regressors for the probability of an election call but not a business cycle peak. The dating of US business cycle peaks (BCP_US) and detrended farm (Farm_deviation) and export prices (exp_deviation) are variables determining the likelihood of a business cycle peak but not an election call. These variables form our exclusion restrictions. 7

9 causality and reinterpret the negative findings for interconnection at the start of the paper, we develop a single equation alternative to the Heckman selection model that conditions the probability of an election arising by an equivalent of the Inverse Mills Ratio (which in our case is the hazard of having a business cycle peak arise). A significant coefficient on that hazard confirms the presence of selection in an election call based on business cycle peaks and thus the hypothesis that the expectation of a cycle peaking has an important causal role to play in explaining the likelihood of a federal election. In addition, the marginal effect associated with its inclusion allows us to quantify the impact of the risk of a cycle peak on an election call. Finally, we consider the effect of this generated measure of risk on the hazard of an election. As both the Cox model and semi-parametric versions of the accelerated failure hazard model (AFT) model are models that leave the baseline hazard (or, equivalently, the baseline survival distribution) unspecified, we rely on the similarities of the two models to do our test on the hazard of an election. An extension of the AFT model to incorporate correlated survival data can be done by including random effects in the regression expression as in a classical linear mixed model. The proposed test uses the later specification of the AFT model. This version of the AFT model takes a linear specification of the form: log(t) = -x + log(u), where t is the length of a governing duration and u is the error term. This last model illustrates dramatically that the risk of a business cycle peaking (given that it has not yet peaked) decreases the length of the election cycle. This linear specification of the hazard is helpful in capturing the selection effect correctly and therefore the appropriate degree of correlation between the two events. In an appendix we show that the choice used for our estimated risk measure does indeed provide the best fit for our true risk measure. 4 4 The appropriate corrections of the standard errors are made when the generated regressor is used in all the specifications above. We also emphasize that the generated regressor of the risk measure should be a consistent estimate 8

10 3. Results: The Independent Probit Models We begin with the probit equation explaining election calls. To derive this relationship we follow our earlier papers, Ferris and Voia (2010, 2011), where the time duration of a federal government is modelled as the outcome of an optimal stopping rule. 5 There the governing political party is assumed to choose the date of the next election to maximize the likelihood of re-election and the predictions of that model are tested against Canadian data. Our starting point here is the set of variables found predictive in that analysis. A complete description of the data used in our tests is provided in the Data appendix together with a Table describing their statistical properties. The data run from 1870 to 2008 and cover 38 federal elections. A key feature of that table is that all variables are I(0) or stationary. In column (1) of Table 1 we present the result of using these variables in a probit model. The results imply that a Canadian federal election in year t (Elyear) was more likely the smaller was the size of the electoral victory by the winning political party (Seats, interpreted as the competitiveness of the political process) and even more likely if the governing party did not have a parliamentary majority (Minority). The optimal stopping rule characteristic itself predicts that an election will be more likely the higher is the current rate of growth of real per capita income (Growth). However, the minimum growth rate needed to trigger an election will fall as the governing party s time in office approaches its constitutional limit (Exp_weighted _growth). Finally, the probability of an election call could depend on the macroeconomic policies adopted by the government at that time. For example, opportunistic theories of the political business cycle imply that the likelihood of an election call is larger the larger is the increase in government of the true risk measure. In an appendix we provide a test that shows that our choice for the estimated risk measure is the best fit of the true risk measure. 5 There is a large literature in political science that models governing durations as optimal stopping rules. Recent examples include: Kayser (2005), Berlinski, Dewan and Dowding (2007), and Huber and Martinez-Gallardo (2008). 9

11 spending (Dlngsize), the decrease in taxes (Dlntaxsize), and the increase in monetary growth (Growthmb). 6 Our results suggest that none of these policy variables has played that role. While the coefficients on these policy variables all have the sign expected for opportunism, none are significantly different from zero. 7 The sub-tables attached to Table 1 provide a test of the appropriateness of this specification and a measure of fit. In the first table, fit is measured by comparing the mean and standard deviation of actual election calls over our time period against the corresponding moments implied by the estimated model. The results indicate a close match between these two distributions. The two means differ by only two percent (.281 versus.275). The table that follows provides a test of misspecification error for our model. This test regresses the link function of the outcome variable (in this particular case, the probability function) on the predicted probability and predicted probability squared. The intuition behind the test is that the predicted probability function should be statistically significant unless the model is misspecified. Proper specification of the model also implies that the square predicted probability should not have predictive power. If the square predicted probability is significant it means either that we have omitted an important variable from the model or that our link function is not correctly specified. The link test finds that the linear prediction is significant and the squared prediction is not, thus providing no evidence of misspecification insert Table 1 about here ---- In columns (2) and (3) we present the result of testing for evidence of a connection between an election call and a peaking of the business cycle by first adding the actual occurrence of a Canadian business cycle peak, Canpeaks, and then adding the probability of a business cycle peak arising, Prob(Canpeaks), as a determinant of the likelihood of an election. 8 Inspection of the results at the bottom of columns (2) and (3) indicates that neither coefficient estimate is significantly different from zero. Neither does their inclusion 6 There is also no evidence of a (Liberal) partisan effect on election calls or Canadian business cycle peaks. 7 This remains true in all versions of our tests. 8 The derivation of Prob(Canpeaks) is described in the following paragraph. 10

12 improve the overall equation fit with the data. It follows that adding the actual occurrence of a business cycle or the probit estimate of that likelihood as a determinant of Canadian elections does not capture the apparent interconnection suggested by Figure 1. The hypothesis that the occurrence of a business cycle peak triggers a federal election call is supported by neither of these single equation estimates. When we turn to establish a probit equation for the likelihood of realizing a Canadian business cycle peak, we find much less help in the economic literature. For Canada, however, there has been considerable work done comparing the characteristics of Canadian and U. S. business cycles (Hay 1966, Cross 1996, and Gregory et al. 1997). The overwhelming conclusion of that literature is that there is a strong interconnection between the two business cycles. Since the direction of causality is unlikely to go from Canada to the US, we use the peak in the US business cycle (BCP_US, as provided by the NBER) as an indicator of the set of unobserved common factors determining a peak in the Canadian business cycle. 9 We supplement that with the hypothesis that as a small open economy, the Canadian economy will experience periods of more rapid growth, and thus be more likely to experience a business cycle peak when export prices generally and commodity prices in particular are relatively high. For Canada, forestry, oil and mineral prices would be the most appropriate commodity prices, but as a class we can find only export and farm product prices to span our entire time period. Over time, relative export prices and relative farm prices have both been trend stationary (downward) so that their deviations from their time trend were used as regressors in our empirical work (exp_deviation and farm_deviation). Because of a more general concern with the intersection of business cycles and economic policy, we include as a final set of considerations federal government economic policies. Hence we include as potential determinates the same set of policy variables used to estimate the likelihood of an election call (Dlngsize, Dlntaxsize and Growthmb). 9 The United States is by far Canada s largest trading partner. For example, in 2006 the United States took roughly eighty percent of Canada s exports versus its next most important trading partner, the United Kingdom, at 2.5 percent. 11

13 The results reported in column (1) of Table 2 suggest that the peaking of the U.S. business cycle (BCP_US) is the key determinant of observing a Canadian business cycle peak. Export prices become significant only if we extend the confidence interval to 10 percent and fiscal expenditures appear counter to expectations. However, this initial impression is misleading. When only BCP_US is included in the probit, the equation as a whole does not fit the data well, generating a distribution mean of.530 as compared to the actual value of.230. When the two commodity price ratios are included along with the policy variables, the overall equation does perform well. First the fit with the data becomes much better, resulting in a mean likelihood of an cycle peak of.274 as compared to the actual likelihood of.230. In addition the link test finds that the linear prediction is highly significant while the squared prediction and constant are not, thus giving no evidence of specification error. The model suggests that increases in relative export prices are somewhat successful as an indicator of a business cycle peak and it is non-farm prices, rather than farm prices, that are more likely to have had a positive effect on business cycle peaks. Finally note that the coefficient signs on the policy variables directly contradict the hypothesis that economic policy is a potential cause of the business cycle peak. Rather the set of coefficient signs and the significance of government spending are consistent with the hypothesis that economic policy is counter-cyclical, a finding complementary to recent findings on the relationship of policy to the Canadian business cycle (Winer and Ferris, 2008) insert Table 2 about here ---- In columns (2) and (3) of Table 2 we present the results of adding first the realization of an election, Elyear, and then the estimated probit value of an election arising, Prob(Elyear), as explanatory variables for the likely emergence of a business cycle peak. Here the public choice hypotheses would be that either the election itself or its expectation may stimulate the economy (Frey and Schneider, 1978) so increasing the likelihood of a business cycle peak. As was the earlier case for the likelihood of an election call, however, neither variable has had a significant effect on the likelihood of a business cycle peak. Neither does their 12

14 inclusion improve the overall model fit. It follows that in neither of our single equation election or business cycle cases does the addition of the actual or expected value of the other give any ground for believing that a relationship arises between these two events. 4. The Results: Bivariate Probit Models While the individual probit models explaining federal election calls and business cycle peaks appear to work well enough individually, the equation standard error estimates will be misspecified if the error terms in the two equations are correlated and the bias cannot be identified. As importantly, system estimation that allows for an interrelationship between the two events may better reveal what we suspect to be important regressors (such as the relative prices). To allow for the possibility of correlated unobservables, we re-estimate the two probit equations as a seemingly unrelated system. The results are shown in Table 3. In that table it can be seen that simultaneous estimation improves somewhat the significance of export and farm prices but is unsuccessful in identifying any significant correlation among the equation residuals. That is, while the seemingly unrelated results suggest the possibility of a positive correlation between the two distributions ( ), the results are not strong enough to identify such a correlation at standard levels of significance. There is only a twenty percent chance that. Accounting for unobservables also improves somewhat the significance of the government policy variables in the business cycle peak probit. However, the significant coefficient signs on both fiscal expenditures and monetary policy are inconsistent with the original hypothesis that policy helps to produce the emergence of a business cycle peak (but are supportive of counter-cyclical government policy government spending and monetary growth falling in the most expansionary stage of the business cycle). Combining these observations, the sign of improvement in coefficient estimates when estimated simultaneously, together with the inability of the seemingly unrelated method to account for the apparent correlation arising between our two events, suggests the possibility that a simultaneous model that allows for selection bias may be more appropriate. 13

15 ---- insert Table 3 about here ---- As discussed earlier, a selection model can be conditioned either on the realization of an election call or on the emergence of a business cycle peak and the ability to do both allows us to better identify the appropriate conditioning event. That is, if one event truly triggers the other, the matched residuals should not be symmetric. Rather conditioning on the event that is triggering should result in correlations among residuals that are positive, while conditioning on the following event should produce residuals that are negative. The unbalanced nature of the two events means that it may be more meaningful to begin the search for the triggering event by conditioning selection on business cycle peaks, since each peak allows for the possibility of a corresponding election call (whereas the reverse does not). In addition, we note that the observation that Canpeaks = 0 is difficult to interpret in terms of its economic effect. That is, while the nonobservance of a business cycle peak is easy enough to understand, the non-emergence of a peak could be associated either with a period of ongoing real growth or with a period of contraction, each having a quite different effect on the likelihood of an election call. Hence restricting our attention to the sample of periods when the business cycle has peaked means that we do not have to deal with the interpretation of exactly what Canpeaks = 0 will imply. In column (1) of Table 4a we present the results of a test of the selection hypothesis that the emergence of an election depends upon the realization of a business cycle peak. In moving to this alternative, the log likelihood function rises in value from to As importantly, by conditioning on the periods when a business cycle peak has arisen, the Heckman-type selection model does uncover strong evidence of a correlation arising among the model residuals. The selection model implies that unexpected shocks arising to Canada s business cycles are virtually perfectly correlated with unexpected election calls. The probability that the two equations are independent, that the correlation among the model residuals is zero, has fallen below 2 percent. 14

16 ---insert Table 4 about here --- It should be noticed that accounting for the interconnection between the two events in terms of a selection criteria does diminish somewhat the significance of the factors found previously to have influenced the likelihood of an election call. While the likelihood of an election call is still inversely related to the size of the winning party s majority, the effect of minority governments is now found to be insignificant. It is perhaps not surprising that conditioning on the emergence of a business cycle peak would reduce the separate importance of the growth rate as a determinant of an election call; however as before, the data remains consistent with the hypothesis that the growth rate falls in importance as the political party s term in office approaches its constitutional limit. Finally, as was the case before, the policy variables remain insignificant in their effect on the likelihood of an election call. On the other hand, conditioning on the emergence of a business cycle peak does increase generally the significance of those factors influencing the likelihood of a business cycle peak. While the occasion of a US business cycle peak significantly raises the likelihood of the Canadian equivalent, the selection method appears to better isolate the estimated effect of relative prices and policy variables. For elections to follow a business cycle peak the second part of our test requires the residuals of the two equations to be correlated negatively when the initial Heckman test is reversed and the probability of a business cycle peak is made conditional on the occurrence of an election. The results of this test are shown in column (1) of Table 4b. There the estimated rho is found to be significantly negative (-.806). The same pattern of coefficient findings is found for the other variables with again the finding that while the policy variables have their expected effect on elections (but are statistically insignificant) the signs of their effect on business cycle peaks are more consistent with the adoption of counter-cyclical policy. Overall the Heckman selection model with system estimation conditional on the realization of a business cycle peak does provides formal support for the observations that began this paper. The empirical relation 15

17 found in the data is consistent with the hypothesis that Canadian business cycle peaks precipitate federal elections. In the next section we examine the robustness of this finding and examine what more can be said about the direction of causality running between these two events. 5. Causal Identification and Robustness Tests In the models estimated thus far we have assumed that the error terms were normally distributed in order to use probit and bivariate probit system estimation. In addition we have argued that while the distribution of our error terms is unknown, our exclusion restrictions will allow identification even if the equation errors are not normally distributed. In this section we first report the results of re-estimating the system of equations reported above using the linear probability model. By imposing linearity in the probability, the test relaxes somewhat the restriction on the form of the distribution of error terms but at the cost of misspecifying the support of the probability measure. A linear probability measure will also help identify causality if the equivalent of an Inverse Mills Ratio is used for identification. For this reason we subsequently test for causality by using an appropriate generated regressor that replaces the Inverse Mills Ratio under a linear specification and also test whether the same regressor can capture causality in a nonlinear probability model (probit in our case). As our first robustness test, then, we re-estimated the entire set of probit equations reported above in the form of a linear probability model. Without including all of these results we can report that the results were broadly similar in almost all instances, indicating the same pattern of associations and correlations across equation residuals reported above. Because of their importance for our argument, we report, as column (2) in Tables 4a and 4b, the results of redoing the Heckman specifications reported in column (1). By inspection it can be seen that while the linear form of the test results in a decrease in the significance of some of the individual variables, the positive correlation found among the equation residuals in Table 4a remains very strong and significantly different from zero. In the opposite conditioning of the Heckman test, the expected negative 16

18 relationship is not found, the rho estimated there found to be insignificantly different from zero. In at least one version of the specification test, the linear probability model confirms our previous finding that business cycle peaks lead election calls. A second empirical issue arises because, in order to maximize the number of elections calls and business cycle peaks, a long time series is required and data limitations over a long time horizon restrict the data frequency to annual versus quarterly or monthly data. This implies that when elections and business cycle peaks arise at different points during the year, they are assigned more or less arbitrarily to one year or another. Hence as a second robustness test, we re-estimate the system using a weighted dating system where the yearly weights were the fraction of each year in which the election or business cycle peak took place. In the case of elections, if the election arose in July, then the election weight applied to the current year would be 5/12 while the remaining weight of 7/12 would be applied to the year that followed. For the business cycle peak we used as a weight the fraction of the year leading into the peak. Re-estimation on this basis is presented as column (3) in Tables 4a and 4b. Here the results are exactly opposite to the linear probability case reported in column (2). The positive correlation expected among the residuals of the two equations in Table 4a was found to be insignificantly different from zero, but the expected negative correlation in Table 4b was found and found to be significantly different from zero. While the individual predictions fit the data less well with this dating of events, in both of these cases the general pattern of correlations among the models residuals is consistent with the hypothesis that business cycle peaks trigger elections. We turn next to the question of causality in terms of the single probit equations that began our empirical analysis. Capturing this successfully would allow us an estimate of the importance of the triggering event. From Tables 1 and 2 where we have already shown that when each probit equation is estimated separately, neither the addition of the realized outcome nor the addition of the estimated probit of the other event has a significant effect on the likelihood function. Hence neither appears to have any significant effect on 17

19 the likelihood of realizing the other. On the other hand, our analysis of the system of probit equations has revealed that selection is an important issue and, when selection is an issue, the use of an unconditional probability both to estimate the causal effect and to correct for selectivity bias is not appropriate. With selection, the hazard of a business cycle peak or the hazard of an election can be shown to be an equivalent measure of the Inverse Mills Ratio that can control for the selection effect and identify causality properly. That is, when looking for the event that triggers selection, we are interested in what is happening in the very near future following that selection event. Because the hazard is a probability conditional in time that addresses specifically what happens in the very next period, the hazard better answers this question. The probit probability, on the other hand, is constructed independent of time and thus is less informative with respect to causality. Thus to the extent that an event triggering causality is indicated, we are more likely to find evidence of its effect through the use of the appropriate hazard specification. In our case this can be shown to be the Cox hazard (see Appendix B). In Table 5 we report the results of adding the two Cox hazards to the single equation models of Tables 1 and The upper half of Table 5 reports the model of business cycle peaks estimated first as a probit model and then as a linear probability model; the lower half of the table reports election model also estimated first as a probit model, then as a linear probability model. What is quite striking is that unlike the case when using the unconditional probit, the Cox hazard of a business cycle peak works well as an explanatory variable in both the election probit and the linear election probability model. The likelihood that the business cycle will peak this period given that it has not yet peaked is marginally significant in its effect on the likelihood of an election in the probit model (at 90 percent), but is highly significant in the alternative linear probability model (at 99 percent). While testing for causality with an equivalent Inverse Mills Ratio is more appropriate for linear models, our results suggest that using the same measure in a nonlinear (probit) model can capture the selection effect. 10 The Cox election hazard is constructed in Ferris and Voia (2010) and used in a test of the political business cycle in Canada in Ferris and Voia (2011). Our construction of the hazard of a business cycle peak is the subject of the separate note included as Appendix B below. 18

20 The electoral importance of the risk of a business cycle peak in generating an election call can be found from its marginal effect on the probit and the linear probability models. In both cases the estimated marginal effects are quite similar, for its marginal effect on the probit and for its marginal effect on the linear probability. The marginal effects can be interpreted as implying that a 1 percent increase in the hazard of a business cycle peak will increase the probability of an election by almost 6 percent. As argued earlier, reversing the conditioning should show evidence of a negative relationship between the likelihood of a business cycle peak conditional on the hazard risk that an election will arise this year given that an election has not yet arisen. Because a high value of the election hazard most often indicates a time period towards the end of a governing mandate when an election has not yet been called, the likelihood that a business cycle peak will be experienced in the immediate future is now less rather than more likely. The negative coefficient in the probit equation for business cycle peak hazard then provides additional support for the hypothesis that business cycle peaks drive elections rather than the other way around and reinforces our earlier findings. The effect and significance of the arrival of a business cycle peak on the likelihood of an election call can be seen most clearly diagrammatically. In Figure 2 the Cox election hazard is plotted for the two cases when a business cycle peak has arisen and when it has not. What stands out in that diagram is that the likelihood of having an election call given that one has not yet been made jumps dramatically when a business cycle peak arises in the middle years of a party s governing tenure. If the business cycle peak arises either very early or very late in a governing term, the arrival of a business cycle peak has no significant effect on the timing of an election call. However, if the business cycle peak arises before the necessity of calling another election, the arrival of a business cycle peak does influence strongly and positively the likelihood of an election call. ---insert Figure 2 about here--- As a final robustness test of our findings we estimate a log-linear accelerated failure hazard model. The results are reported in Appendix C and repeat the same general pattern as that found in the probit equations. In 19

21 particular, business cycle peaks can be seen to have no effect on the duration of an election cycle unless we correct for selection by using the risk of hazard in a business cycle peak. In the final table of the appendix it is shown that the Cox hazard of a business cycle peak accelerates dramatically the ending of a governing duration and the quantitative impact on the log duration implies a 5.6 percent marginal effect. A one percent increase in the hazard of a business cycle peak leads to a reduction in the duration of the governing cycle of about 6 percent. 6. Implications for Policy In the Public Choice literature it is sometimes argued that elections, particularly electoral surprises, have a positive effect on economic growth and so generate a political business/policy cycle (Nordhaus, 1975; and Frey and Schneider, 1978). Others within the same literature have argued that the desire to remain in office means that economic policy can and will be used to signal competence and so influence the probability of re-election (Rogoff and Sibert, 1988; Shi and Svensson, 2006). Still others argue that even without deliberate manipulation, the governing political party in a parliamentary democracy has an incentive to monitor economic performance and so optimally time its election call (Balke, 1990; Kayser, 2005; Berlinski, Dewan and Dowding, 2007; and Ferris and Voia, 2010). The significance of this paper is that for Canada over our time period evidence is found for only one of these hypotheses, namely the hypothesis of election timing. While the results are not inconsistent with some effect of elections on the business cycle and perhaps even with a role for monetary policy in relation to the business cycle, the data is most consistent with the hypothesis that a business cycle peak is a stronger determinant of an election call than vice versa. While the data is supportive of the hypothesis that business cycle peaks drive election calls, the establishment of a selection linkage between these events may also help to explain why public choice economists have had difficulty finding evidence of opportunism and/or a political business cycle (Drazen 2000; Persson and Tabellini, 2003). To see this note that in Canada since Confederation, fiscal policy been 20

22 always been countercyclical and increasingly so since Keynes (Winer and Ferris, 2008). This is consistent with our findings that business cycle peaks are consistently associated with lower levels of government spending and money growth and higher levels of taxation. Hence to the extent that political parties engage in opportunism and elections are timed to take advantage of the peaking of a business cycle, evidence of opportunistic spending may become lost in the aggregate through the countercyclical spending and tax changes that are changing in the opposite direction. The coincidence of elections and cycle peaks means that clear evidence of opportunism in parliamentary countries where elections times are not predetermined will be much harder to come by. In our case this may explain why the signs of the policy coefficient estimates are consistent with opportunism in the election equations but are not found to be significantly different from zero. 7. Conclusion In this paper we have argued that what appears to be a coincidence in the timing of business cycle peaks and election calls in Canada arises neither because the two events are generated by a similar set of causes nor because the two events are correlated because of common but unobserved covariates. Rather the two events appear together in time because the outcomes are sequenced in a specific way. To test whether it is business cycle peaks that lead election calls or elections that precipitate cycles peaking we use Heckman specification tests. The results suggest that it is the expectation of a business cycle peaking (given that the cycle has not yet peaked) that triggers an election call by the governing political party. Moreover the effect of a cycle peak is quantitatively significant, with a 1 percent increase in the hazard of a cycle peaking leading to a more than five times greater increase in the probability of an election arising. This effect is in addition to the way that higher growth rates have usually been thought to (positively) influence election calls. While the results are not inconsistent with elections having some influence on policy choices and hence on economic outcomes, the results are also insightful in explaining why evidence of a political budget cycle is 21

23 often hard to come by in countries with parliamentary governments. Because in such jurisdictions elections can be timed to take advantage of such advantageous circumstances as the arrival of a business cycle peak, evidence of opportunism in the spending, taxation or monetary expansion in government policy will tend to be lost as such policies encounter directly the normal constraint imposed by countercyclical policy arising at the top of the business cycle. 22

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV John E. Floyd University of Toronto May 10, 2013 Our major task here is to look at the evidence regarding the effects of unanticipated money shocks on real

More information

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? AEA Papers and Proceedings 2018, 108: 401 406 https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181116 In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? By Barbara A. Butrica and Nadia S. Karamcheva*

More information

THE BEHAVIOUR OF GOVERNMENT OF CANADA REAL RETURN BOND RETURNS: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY

THE BEHAVIOUR OF GOVERNMENT OF CANADA REAL RETURN BOND RETURNS: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY ASAC 2005 Toronto, Ontario David W. Peters Faculty of Social Sciences University of Western Ontario THE BEHAVIOUR OF GOVERNMENT OF CANADA REAL RETURN BOND RETURNS: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY The Government of

More information

BANK OF CANADA RENEWAL OF BACKGROUND INFORMATION THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET. May 2001

BANK OF CANADA RENEWAL OF BACKGROUND INFORMATION THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET. May 2001 BANK OF CANADA May RENEWAL OF THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET BACKGROUND INFORMATION Bank of Canada Wellington Street Ottawa, Ontario KA G9 78 ISBN: --89- Printed in Canada on recycled paper B A N K O F C

More information

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy.

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy. This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/9880/ Monograph: Gascoigne, J. and Turner, P.

More information

PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3

PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3 PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3 Stress testing operational risk for capital planning and capital adequacy PART 2: Monday, March 18th, 2013, New York Presenter: Alexander Cavallo, NORTHERN TRUST 1 Disclaimer

More information

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve Capacity Utilization As a Real-Time Predictor of Manufacturing Output Evan F. Koenig Research Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve indices

More information

Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that

Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that the strong positive correlation between income and democracy

More information

An Estimate of the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Growth* First draft May 1; revised June 6, 2000

An Estimate of the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Growth* First draft May 1; revised June 6, 2000 An Estimate of the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Growth* First draft May 1; revised June 6, 2000 Jeffrey A. Frankel Kennedy School of Government Harvard University, 79 JFK Street Cambridge MA

More information

Characteristics of Prolonged Users

Characteristics of Prolonged Users 48 PART I, CHAPTER IV CHAPTER IV Characteristics of Prolonged Users 1. This chapter describes some of the main characteristics of the prolonged users in terms of performance and key economic indicators

More information

Is there a significant connection between commodity prices and exchange rates?

Is there a significant connection between commodity prices and exchange rates? Is there a significant connection between commodity prices and exchange rates? Preliminary Thesis Report Study programme: MSc in Business w/ Major in Finance Supervisor: Håkon Tretvoll Table of content

More information

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data Nicolas Parent, Financial Markets Department It is now widely recognized that greater transparency facilitates the

More information

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade The Time Cost of Documents to Trade Mohammad Amin* May, 2011 The paper shows that the number of documents required to export and import tend to increase the time cost of shipments. However, this relationship

More information

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for? Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for? Syed M. Hussain Lin Liu August 5, 26 Abstract In this paper, we estimate the

More information

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment International Journal of Business and Economics, 2002, Vol. 1, No. 1, 59-67 Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment Rosemary Rossiter * Department of Economics, Ohio University,

More information

Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz

Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz Abstract: This paper is an analysis of the mortality rates of beneficiaries of charitable gift annuities. Observed

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

4 managerial workers) face a risk well below the average. About half of all those below the minimum wage are either commerce insurance and finance wor

4 managerial workers) face a risk well below the average. About half of all those below the minimum wage are either commerce insurance and finance wor 4 managerial workers) face a risk well below the average. About half of all those below the minimum wage are either commerce insurance and finance workers, or service workers two categories holding less

More information

9. Logit and Probit Models For Dichotomous Data

9. Logit and Probit Models For Dichotomous Data Sociology 740 John Fox Lecture Notes 9. Logit and Probit Models For Dichotomous Data Copyright 2014 by John Fox Logit and Probit Models for Dichotomous Responses 1 1. Goals: I To show how models similar

More information

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow, Co-movements of Shanghai and New York stock prices by time-varying regressions Gregory C Chow a, Changjiang Liu b, Linlin Niu b,c a Department of Economics, Fisher Hall Princeton University, Princeton,

More information

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage Jin-Chuan Duan * and Yun Li (First draft: April 12, 2006) (This version: May 16, 2006) Abstract This paper identifies a key cause for the documented diversification

More information

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales VV Chari, LJ Christiano and P Kehoe January 2, 27 In this note, we examine the findings of Gertler and Gilchrist, ( Monetary Policy, Business

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data by Peter A Groothuis Professor Appalachian State University Boone, NC and James Richard Hill Professor Central Michigan University

More information

Cross- Country Effects of Inflation on National Savings

Cross- Country Effects of Inflation on National Savings Cross- Country Effects of Inflation on National Savings Qun Cheng Xiaoyang Li Instructor: Professor Shatakshee Dhongde December 5, 2014 Abstract Inflation is considered to be one of the most crucial factors

More information

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan The US recession that began in late 2007 had significant spillover effects to the rest

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Questions of this SAMPLE exam were randomly chosen and may NOT be representative of the difficulty or focus of the actual examination. The professor did NOT review these questions. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose

More information

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS BASEMENT HD28.M414 no. Ibll- Dewey ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Corporate Investments In Common Stock by Wayne H. Mikkelson University of Oregon Richard S. Ruback Massachusetts

More information

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University Volume 30, Issue Random risk aversion and the cost of eliminating the foreign exchange risk of the Euro Samih A Azar Haigazian University Abstract This paper answers the following questions. If the Euro

More information

Macroeconomic Policy: Evidence from Growth Laffer Curve for Sri Lanka. Sujith P. Jayasooriya, Ch.E. (USA) Innovation4Development Consultants

Macroeconomic Policy: Evidence from Growth Laffer Curve for Sri Lanka. Sujith P. Jayasooriya, Ch.E. (USA) Innovation4Development Consultants Macroeconomic Policy: Evidence from Growth Laffer Curve for Sri Lanka Sujith P. Jayasooriya, Ch.E. (USA) Innovation4Development Consultants INTRODUCTION The concept of optimal taxation policies has recently

More information

Fiscal Divergence and Business Cycle Synchronization: Irresponsibility is Idiosyncratic. Zsolt Darvas, Andrew K. Rose and György Szapáry

Fiscal Divergence and Business Cycle Synchronization: Irresponsibility is Idiosyncratic. Zsolt Darvas, Andrew K. Rose and György Szapáry Fiscal Divergence and Business Cycle Synchronization: Irresponsibility is Idiosyncratic Zsolt Darvas, Andrew K. Rose and György Szapáry 1 I. Motivation Business cycle synchronization (BCS) the critical

More information

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael Discussion Benoît Carmichael The two studies presented in the first session of the conference take quite different approaches to the question of price indexes. On the one hand, Coulombe s study develops

More information

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation" Valerie A. Ramey University of California, San Diego and NBER June 30, 2011 Abstract This brief note challenges

More information

The Simple Regression Model

The Simple Regression Model Chapter 2 Wooldridge: Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, 5e Definition of the simple linear regression model Explains variable in terms of variable Intercept Slope parameter Dependent variable,

More information

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender * COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY Adi Brender * 1 Key analytical issues for policy choice and design A basic question facing policy makers at the outset of a crisis

More information

Analysis of Microdata

Analysis of Microdata Rainer Winkelmann Stefan Boes Analysis of Microdata Second Edition 4u Springer 1 Introduction 1 1.1 What Are Microdata? 1 1.2 Types of Microdata 4 1.2.1 Qualitative Data 4 1.2.2 Quantitative Data 6 1.3

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Prediction Market Prices as Martingales: Theory and Analysis. David Klein Statistics 157

Prediction Market Prices as Martingales: Theory and Analysis. David Klein Statistics 157 Prediction Market Prices as Martingales: Theory and Analysis David Klein Statistics 157 Introduction With prediction markets growing in number and in prominence in various domains, the construction of

More information

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr.

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr. The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving James P. Dow, Jr. Department of Finance, Real Estate and Insurance California State University, Northridge

More information

**BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** A random sample of five observations from a population is:

**BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** A random sample of five observations from a population is: **BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** 1. You are given: (i) A random sample of five observations from a population is: 0.2 0.7 0.9 1.1 1.3 (ii) You use the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test for testing the null hypothesis,

More information

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh * Journal of Monetary Economics Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for monetary policy in Japan Carl E. Walsh * Department of Economics, University of California,

More information

Web Appendix for Testing Pendleton s Premise: Do Political Appointees Make Worse Bureaucrats? David E. Lewis

Web Appendix for Testing Pendleton s Premise: Do Political Appointees Make Worse Bureaucrats? David E. Lewis Web Appendix for Testing Pendleton s Premise: Do Political Appointees Make Worse Bureaucrats? David E. Lewis This appendix includes the auxiliary models mentioned in the text (Tables 1-5). It also includes

More information

Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application

Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application Vivek H. Dehejia Carleton University and CESifo Email: vdehejia@ccs.carleton.ca January 14, 2008 JEL classification code:

More information

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy International Review of Business Research Papers Vol. 9. No.1. January 2013 Issue. Pp. 105 115 A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy Kavous Ardalan 1 Two major open-economy

More information

Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem

Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem Owen Zidar Blanchard and Summers NBER Macro Annual 1986 Macro Lunch January 30, 2013 Owen Zidar (Macro Lunch) Hysteresis January 30, 2013 1 / 47 Questions

More information

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Putnam Institute JUne 2011 Optimal Asset Allocation in : A Downside Perspective W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Once an individual has retired, asset allocation becomes a critical

More information

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY Alan J. Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko University of California, Berkeley January 2013 In this paper, we estimate the cross-country spillover effects of government

More information

Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI

Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI Fifth joint EU/OECD workshop on business and consumer surveys Brussels, 17 18 November 2011 Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI Olivier BIAU

More information

Econometrics and Economic Data

Econometrics and Economic Data Econometrics and Economic Data Chapter 1 What is a regression? By using the regression model, we can evaluate the magnitude of change in one variable due to a certain change in another variable. For example,

More information

Summary of: Trade Liberalization, Profitability, and Financial Leverage

Summary of: Trade Liberalization, Profitability, and Financial Leverage Catalogue no. 11F0019MIE No. 257 ISSN: 1205-9153 ISBN: 0-662-40836-5 Research Paper Research Paper Analytical Studies Branch Research Paper Series Summary of: Trade Liberalization, Profitability, and Financial

More information

IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA?

IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA? IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA? C. Barry Pfitzner, Department of Economics/Business, Randolph-Macon College, Ashland, VA, bpfitzne@rmc.edu ABSTRACT This paper investigates the

More information

Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation. Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR

Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation. Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR Fiscal consolidation involves a retrenchment of government expenditures and/or the

More information

The impact of changing diversification on stability and growth in a regional economy

The impact of changing diversification on stability and growth in a regional economy ABSTRACT The impact of changing diversification on stability and growth in a regional economy Carl C. Brown Florida Southern College Economic diversification has long been considered a potential determinant

More information

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality DORON NISSIM* Corporate disclosures are an important source of information for investors. Many studies have documented strong price

More information

Government Size, Government Debt and Economic Performance with particular application to New Zealand 1. J. Stephen Ferris

Government Size, Government Debt and Economic Performance with particular application to New Zealand 1. J. Stephen Ferris Government Size, Government Debt and Economic Performance with particular application to New Zealand 1 J. Stephen Ferris stephen_ferris@carleton.ca Draft November 4 2013 Abstract Many countries have been

More information

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS CEP 14-08 Entry, Exit, and Economic Growth: U.S. Regional Evidence Miguel Casares Universidad Pública de Navarra Hashmat U. Khan Carleton University July 2014 CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS Department of Economics

More information

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Jordi Galí, Mark Gertler and J. David López-Salido Preliminary draft, June 2001 Abstract Galí and Gertler (1999) developed a hybrid

More information

The Simple Regression Model

The Simple Regression Model Chapter 2 Wooldridge: Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, 5e Definition of the simple linear regression model "Explains variable in terms of variable " Intercept Slope parameter Dependent var,

More information

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan; University of New Orleans ScholarWorks@UNO Department of Economics and Finance Working Papers, 1991-2006 Department of Economics and Finance 1-1-2006 Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using

More information

Lecture 1: The Econometrics of Financial Returns

Lecture 1: The Econometrics of Financial Returns Lecture 1: The Econometrics of Financial Returns Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Winter/Spring 2016 Overview General goals of the course and definition of risk(s) Predicting asset returns:

More information

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India Michael Hutchison and Rajeswari Sengupta and Nirvikar Singh University of California Santa Cruz 3. March 2010 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/21106/

More information

Solutions to PSet 5. October 6, More on the AS/AD Model

Solutions to PSet 5. October 6, More on the AS/AD Model Solutions to PSet 5 October 6, 207 More on the AS/AD Model. If there is a zero interest rate lower bound, is fiscal policy more or less effective than otherwise? Explain using the AS/AD model. Is the United

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Europe and the Euro Volume Author/Editor: Alberto Alesina and Francesco Giavazzi, editors Volume

More information

Personal income, stock market, and investor psychology

Personal income, stock market, and investor psychology ABSTRACT Personal income, stock market, and investor psychology Chung Baek Troy University Minjung Song Thomas University This paper examines how disposable personal income is related to investor psychology

More information

The following materials are designed to accompany our article Looking for Audience

The following materials are designed to accompany our article Looking for Audience Online Appendix The following materials are designed to accompany our article Looking for Audience Costs in all the Wrong Places: Electoral Institutions, Media Access and Democratic Constraint. Robustness

More information

Time Invariant and Time Varying Inefficiency: Airlines Panel Data

Time Invariant and Time Varying Inefficiency: Airlines Panel Data Time Invariant and Time Varying Inefficiency: Airlines Panel Data These data are from the pre-deregulation days of the U.S. domestic airline industry. The data are an extension of Caves, Christensen, and

More information

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region Available online at http://sijournals.com/ijae/ Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region Mohsen Mehrara Faculty of Economics, University of Tehran, Tehran, Iran Email: mmehrara@ut.ac.ir

More information

Nonlinearities and Robustness in Growth Regressions Jenny Minier

Nonlinearities and Robustness in Growth Regressions Jenny Minier Nonlinearities and Robustness in Growth Regressions Jenny Minier Much economic growth research has been devoted to determining the explanatory variables that explain cross-country variation in growth rates.

More information

Crowdfunding, Cascades and Informed Investors

Crowdfunding, Cascades and Informed Investors DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7994 Crowdfunding, Cascades and Informed Investors Simon C. Parker February 2014 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Crowdfunding,

More information

the display, exploration and transformation of the data are demonstrated and biases typically encountered are highlighted.

the display, exploration and transformation of the data are demonstrated and biases typically encountered are highlighted. 1 Insurance data Generalized linear modeling is a methodology for modeling relationships between variables. It generalizes the classical normal linear model, by relaxing some of its restrictive assumptions,

More information

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016)

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) 68-131 An Investigation of the Structural Characteristics of the Indian IT Sector and the Capital Goods Sector An Application of the

More information

VERSION 7.2 Mplus LANGUAGE ADDENDUM

VERSION 7.2 Mplus LANGUAGE ADDENDUM VERSION 7.2 Mplus LANGUAGE ADDENDUM This addendum describes changes introduced in Version 7.2. They include corrections to minor problems that have been found since the release of Version 7.11 in June

More information

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS CEP 12-03 An Oil-Driven Endogenous Growth Model Hossein Kavand University of Tehran J. Stephen Ferris Carleton University April 2, 2012 CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS Department of Economics 1125 Colonel By

More information

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning Doug Hostland Department of Finance Working Paper * 2001-20 * The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not reflect those of the Department of Finance. A previous version of this

More information

Fixed Effects Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a Flexibly Parametric Proportional Hazard Model with an Application to Job Exits

Fixed Effects Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a Flexibly Parametric Proportional Hazard Model with an Application to Job Exits Fixed Effects Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a Flexibly Parametric Proportional Hazard Model with an Application to Job Exits Published in Economic Letters 2012 Audrey Light* Department of Economics

More information

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation? 2011 年 2 月第十四卷一期 Vol. 14, No. 1, February 2011 Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation? Tao Chen http://cmr.ba.ouhk.edu.hk Web Journal of Chinese Management Review Vol. 14 No 1 1 Does Commodity

More information

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation Evidence from Randomly Assigned Judges Omar Bamieh University of Vienna November 13th 2018 1 / 27 Why should we care about firing costs? Firing costs make it

More information

Foreign exchange rate and the Hong Kong economic growth

Foreign exchange rate and the Hong Kong economic growth From the SelectedWorks of John Woods Winter October 3, 2017 Foreign exchange rate and the Hong Kong economic growth John Woods Brian Hausler Kevin Carter Available at: https://works.bepress.com/john-woods/1/

More information

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market? International Review of Finance, 2017 Can Hedge Funds Time the Market? MICHAEL W. BRANDT,FEDERICO NUCERA AND GIORGIO VALENTE Duke University, The Fuqua School of Business, Durham, NC LUISS Guido Carli

More information

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region*

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region* Posted SSRN 08/31/01 Last Revised 10/15/01 Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region* Bruce I. Jacobs and Kenneth N. Levy * Previously entitled Leverage Aversion and Portfolio Optimality:

More information

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman Journal of Health Economics 20 (2001) 283 288 Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman Åke Blomqvist Department of Economics, University of

More information

Econ 223 Lecture notes 2: Determination of output and income Classical closed economy equilibrium

Econ 223 Lecture notes 2: Determination of output and income Classical closed economy equilibrium Econ 223 Lecture notes 2: Determination of output and income Classical closed economy equilibrium Kevin Clinton Winter 2005 The classical model assumes that prices and wages etc. are fully flexible. Output

More information

INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA

INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA CAN MONETARY POLICY IN INDIA FOLLOW INFLATION TARGETING AND ARE THE MONETARY POLICY REACTION FUNCTIONS ASYMMETRIC? Abstract Vineeth Mohandas Department of Economics, Pondicherry

More information

Using Fractals to Improve Currency Risk Management Strategies

Using Fractals to Improve Currency Risk Management Strategies Using Fractals to Improve Currency Risk Management Strategies Michael K. Lauren Operational Analysis Section Defence Technology Agency New Zealand m.lauren@dta.mil.nz Dr_Michael_Lauren@hotmail.com Abstract

More information

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley.

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley. Appendix: Statistics in Action Part I Financial Time Series 1. These data show the effects of stock splits. If you investigate further, you ll find that most of these splits (such as in May 1970) are 3-for-1

More information

Business Cycles II: Theories

Business Cycles II: Theories Macroeconomic Policy Class Notes Business Cycles II: Theories Revised: December 5, 2011 Latest version available at www.fperri.net/teaching/macropolicy.f11htm In class we have explored at length the main

More information

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1 Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Philippe Bacchetta Eric van Wincoop January 10, 007 1 Prepared for the May 007 issue of the American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings.

More information

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence Loyola University Chicago Loyola ecommons Topics in Middle Eastern and orth African Economies Quinlan School of Business 1999 Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MEA Countries: Theory

More information

Conditional Convergence: Evidence from the Solow Growth Model

Conditional Convergence: Evidence from the Solow Growth Model Conditional Convergence: Evidence from the Solow Growth Model Reginald Wilson The University of Southern Mississippi The Solow growth model indicates that more than half of the variation in gross domestic

More information

Random Variables and Applications OPRE 6301

Random Variables and Applications OPRE 6301 Random Variables and Applications OPRE 6301 Random Variables... As noted earlier, variability is omnipresent in the business world. To model variability probabilistically, we need the concept of a random

More information

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application Russell Cooper, John Haltiwanger and Jonathan Willis January 2005 Abstract This paper studies capital adjustment costs. Our goal here

More information

Measuring and managing market risk June 2003

Measuring and managing market risk June 2003 Page 1 of 8 Measuring and managing market risk June 2003 Investment management is largely concerned with risk management. In the management of the Petroleum Fund, considerable emphasis is therefore placed

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Exchange Rate Exposure and Firm-Specific Factors: Evidence from Turkey

Exchange Rate Exposure and Firm-Specific Factors: Evidence from Turkey Journal of Economic and Social Research 7(2), 35-46 Exchange Rate Exposure and Firm-Specific Factors: Evidence from Turkey Mehmet Nihat Solakoglu * Abstract: This study examines the relationship between

More information

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? October 19, 2009 Ulrike Malmendier, UC Berkeley (joint work with Stefan Nagel, Stanford) 1 The Tale of Depression Babies I don t know

More information

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM RAY C. FAIR This paper uses a structural multi-country macroeconometric model to estimate the size of the decrease in transfer payments (or tax

More information

The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy

The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy Alexander Kurov and Raluca Stan * Abstract This paper investigates the impact of US unconventional monetary policy on asset prices at the

More information

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright Faculty and Institute of Actuaries Claims Reserving Manual v.2 (09/1997) Section D7 [D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright 1. Introduction

More information