The nation's social welfare policy reflects an ongoing effort to balance sometimes

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The nation's social welfare policy reflects an ongoing effort to balance sometimes"

Transcription

1 Journal of Economic Perspectives Volume 4, Number 1 Winter 1990 Pages Work and Welfare: Lessons on Employment Programs Judith M. Gueron The nation's social welfare policy reflects an ongoing effort to balance sometimes competing objectives alleviating poverty and promoting self-sufficiency in a manner consistent with underlying public values about the primacy of the family and the importance of work. Concern has been growing that the welfare system has not been doing this very well, and welfare reform once again moved towards the top of the policy agenda, resulting in passage of the Family Support Act of 1988 (FSA). That the bill was passed is evidence of broad agreement about elements of the problem and its solution. That it was passed amidst acrimony and with relatively modest provisions reflects continuing disagreement about the fundamental objectives of reform. This paper discusses what economists know about the potential of one central component of the new legislation: the effort to transform welfare from a means-tested entitlement into a reciprocal obligation, in which getting a welfare check would carry with it a requirement to look for and accept a job, or to participate in activities that prepare people for work. It sets the context for this discussion by briefly outlining why this approach to reform gained support and by summarizing major policy and program alternatives. Why Welfare Reform? The extent of poverty in the United States and the choices facing poor people are affected by a broad range of policies that influence the distribution of income and the Judith M. Gueron is President of Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation, New York, New York.

2 80 Journal of Economic Perspectives rewards of work. Public assistance (welfare) programs the most visible of which is Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) are means-tested: that is, eligibility and benefits depend on income and assets. Other policy tools include social insurance programs (such as Social Security or unemployment insurance), which are available to everyone and are based on age, disability, or employment, and a range of "nonwelfare" programs including child support enforcement and tax and education policies. Welfare has few supporters and many critics, yet it has resisted repeated efforts at major reform. The fundamental dilemma is the impossibility of simultaneously maximizing the two primary policy objectives: reducing poverty and encouraging self-support. Simple logic dictates a trade-off, at least in the short run and probably in the long run. Because welfare programs are means-tested, they discourage work, since the more you work, the less assistance you receive. Moreover, any effort to increase benefits to combat poverty more effectively will only further decrease the incentives for recipients to take low-paying jobs and work. The concern that generous public assistance would undermine self-reliance has a long history. It was central to the debates about the seventeenth-century English poor laws, which established the principle that the state is responsible for aiding the poor, and it has been voiced repeatedly in this country by public figures ranging from Benjamin Franklin to Franklin D. Roosevelt, Lyndon Johnson, and Ronald Reagan. The dilemma could be resolved if the poor could be divided into two groups those who are able and expected to work and those who are not and assistance limited to the second group. While the vocabulary has changed with the century, the attempt to categorize the poor has been fundamental to the rhetoric and design of assistance programs. The Social Security Act of 1935 (SSA), which provided the first federal support for welfare programs, adopted this approach and limited assistance to the aged, the blind, and dependent children in single-parent households. (SSA created the Aid to Dependent Children ADC program, which was later retitled AFDC when benefits were expanded to cover mothers as well as children.) This categorization has worked smoothly for the aged and severely disabled, who have been provided with increasingly generous assistance with relatively little concern about its impact on work incentives. The continued controversy has centered on single mothers, the primary adult beneficiaries of AFDC. Expectations for single mothers have undergone major shifts in the past century. The pre-twentieth-century view that such women should work was slowly changed in the early 1900s. This was embodied in the Social Security Act, which represented a "national commitment to the idea that a mother's place is in the home" (Steiner, 1971, p. 54). 1 Designers of the AFDC program hoped that it would provide (what was then thought to be) a relatively small group of poor widows with 1 See Garfinkel and McLanahan (1986) and Katz (1986) for recent discussions of the evolution of policy on the employability of women.

3 Judith M. Gueron 81 sufficient income to stay home and care for their children in accordance with prevailing middle-class norms. Concern about work incentives was muted. Developments over the past 30 years, however, have undermined support for the 1935 vision of the AFDC program. First, employment rates for all women, including single parents and women with very young children, have increased dramatically. Thus, 65 percent of all women with children and 57 percent of married women with children under the age of 6 participated in the labor force in 1987 compared to 30 percent and 19 percent, respectively, in 1960 (Reischauer, 1989). With the majority of mothers working at least part time and often from economic necessity, it became difficult to defend the equity of excusing single mothers who were rearing children from the obligation to work. The argument suffered too from the absence of clear research evidence of a link between a mother's employment and the well-being of her children. (See, for example, Garfinkel and McLanahan, 1986.) Second, in contrast to original expectations, AFDC caseloads and costs grew rapidly in the 1960s and early 1970s. Although caseloads later stabilized, and current costs account for less than one percent of the federal budget, the perception of high cost remains widespread. In fact, the more recent increases in costs have been for in-kind programs, particularly food stamps and Medicaid. 2 The nature of the caseload also changed: currently, more than 90 percent of all women heading AFDC cases have never been married or are divorced or separated rather than widowed. Historically, the welfare system had discriminated among technically eligible groups in its behavioral requirements and administrative practices, and this shift in caseload subtly and not so subtly affected public support. Third, in what Senator Daniel P. Moynihan refers to as "the earthquake that shuddered through the American family," there has been a dramatic increase in the number of female-headed families, the major demographic group most at risk of poverty. For example, in 1987, 21 percent of all children lived with single mothers compared to 7 percent in Even more dramatically, more than half the children born today will spend some time in a mother-only family and half of all such families are likely to be poor (Garfinkel and McLanahan, 1986, p. 1). Concern about the resulting high rate of child poverty has focused attention on the minimal support by absent fathers, the limited capacity of women on welfare to work their way out of poverty, and the very design of the AFDC program, which in half the states has been available only to single-parent households. In response, Congress has strengthened child support enforcement and (since 1988) required states to extend benefits to two-parent families in which the principal earner is unemployed. While creation of this relatively small AFDC-UP (AFDC-Unemployed Parent) program increased incentives for families to stay together, it raised anew the question of work behavior, since it extended benefits to a clearly employable group. Fourth, although recent research confirms that most people use welfare for short-term support only, it also points to a substantial minority who remain poor and dependent for long periods: Approximately one-quarter of those who ever use AFDC 2 See the accompanying paper by Gary Burtless.

4 82 Journal of Economic Perspectives stay on welfare for ten or more years. They account for 60 percent of those on the rolls at any one time and at least 60 percent of the cost of AFDC (Ellwood, 1986, p. xii). Such findings have intensified concern about the high cost of supporting these families and the possible negative effects of welfare on both the mothers and their children. While it is not clear to what extent the design of the AFDC program has contributed to these developments, they have focused attention on whether welfare programs appropriately address the fundamental tension between the competing values of self-reliance and compassion. The four changes described above undermined the idea that welfare should provide an alternative to work and spawned resistance to using AFDC benefit increases to combat poverty. (AFDC benefits were allowed to decline by about 25 percent in constant dollars between 1975 and 1985.) Instead, policy has increasingly emphasized the responsibility of parents, mothers as well as fathers, to support their children. But questions are also being raised about the structure of AFDC, and the strong work disincentives created by its high implicit tax rates and the linkage between AFDC benefits and the entitlement to Medicaid health insurance. The challenge is how to reshape social policy to emphasize parental responsibility without increasing the risk that children of parents who fail to fulfill their responsibilities will suffer. 3 Reform Options Over the years, debate has focused on two broad approaches, currently referred to as "welfare" and "nonwelfare" reform, which place different emphases on the goals of reducing poverty and dependence. "Welfare" reformers have focused on changing the AFDC program either to create more effective incentives to reduce dependence, or to devise requirements and provide services that directly encourage employment. Advocates of the second, "nonwelfare" approach stress that reforms within the welfare system are likely to be inadequate. In general, they endorse more far-reaching, and often substantially more expensive, reforms designed to assure that the kinds of jobs realistically open to welfare recipients will provide income that is above the poverty level, for example, through raising the minimum wage and the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC). 4 Welfare Reform The welfare reform strategy seeks to encourage self-support by changing the expectations and incentives within the AFDC program. This strategy took many forms 3 Garfinkel and McLanahan (1986) call the "new American dilemma" the government's choice between reducing poverty among women and children by offering more generous benefits or reducing the prevalence and dependency of such families by cutting benefits. 4 The Earned Income Tax Credit is a tax supplement to earnings for taxpayers who maintain a household for one or more children. If a worker's family income falls below a certain level, the federal government funnels money to him or her by cutting his or her taxes. The credit is also "refundable": If a family pays no federal taxes, it stills gets the benefit in the form of a check from the government.

5 Work and Welfare: Lessons on Employment Programs 83 in the 1960s. Some approaches emphasized rehabilitation through social services. Others favored modest financial incentives (by changing the rules for determining welfare benefits) in the hope that recipients would voluntarily choose to work, even if that reduced their welfare benefits. Neither social services nor the increase in financial incentives seemed to have much impact on caseloads or on the share of recipients who worked. Moreover, research pointed to the high cost of the incentive approach: Cutting welfare tax rates could actually expand the size of the welfare population and even lead to an aggregate decline in work effort. While these findings contributed to a return to higher AFDC tax rates in 1981, restiveness with the resulting obviously high work disincentives, especially when combined with income-conditioned health insurance and child care costs, have led to some restoration of AFDC work incentives and a movement to provide at least transitional in-kind benefits to people who work their way off welfare. 5 Given the disillusionment with incentives and social services, attention shifted starting with legislation in 1971 towards requirements and the provision of employment-related services. While the role of carrots and sticks varied, the basic thrust was to move AFDC from an income-conditioned entitlement towards a "reciprocal obligation" or "new social contract." Under this approach, the welfare recipient is required to look for and accept a job or to participate in work experience, education, or training to prepare for work, or risk losing some welfare benefits. The government is responsible for providing, in addition to the basic grant, the services and supports that will help the recipient obtain and retain employment. In this paper, the phrase "welfare employment programs" refers to programs that attempt to implement this concept. (While some have argued that these requirements will transform AFDC into a transitional or short-term program, actual legislated changes have been less stringent: People satisfying the program's participation requirements continue to receive full grants of indefinite duration; those not satisfying program requirements usually continue to receive partial grants.) This approach, initially advocated by conservatives, now receives broader support, as seen in proposals by the nation's governors that preceded the passage of the Family Support Act (National Governors' Association, 1987) and in the legislation itself, as discussed below. However, the rhetoric of support should not mask the extent to which persistent differences in objectives or values and in views of social justice or the causes of poverty and unemployment translate this broad agreement into highly diverse specific programs. To simplify a complex debate, in which there is more of a continuum than a dichotomy of views, liberals and conservatives stress different designs and outcomes. Liberals generally accept the premise that work is better than welfare but continue to emphasize reducing poverty over reducing dependence. They argue that welfare recipients want to work but lack the education and skills to get jobs that assure 5 The accompanying paper by Gary Burtless summarizes the numerous changes in AFDC work incentives enacted over the past 20 years, the way in which benefit-reduction rates combine across transfer programs to limit the income gained from work, and the results of the earlier Negative Income Tax experiments.

6 84 Journal of Economic Perspectives self-sufficiency and a decent standard of living, and that many of them would not be able to find adequate care for their children if they did find jobs. Thus, liberals prefer programs that serve volunteers first, offer choices, provide intensive education and training services, do not require people to take low-wage jobs or indeed any job, and assure adequate child care and health insurance to those who leave welfare to work. Liberals focus on insufficient human capital as the critical reason for continued dependence, and they believe that countering this will have high returns. Conservatives, on the other hand, usually emphasize reducing dependence over reducing poverty. They argue that jobs are available and believe that welfare recipients are unwilling to work, are too discouraged to try, or have unrealistic expectations about their job prospects. Thus, conservatives favor programs that set clear expectations for recipients, require participation in program activities or regular employment, provide low-cost job placement assistance rather than expensive training, and mandate "workfare" for those who remain on the rolls. 6 They tend to doubt that providing recipients with more human capital will enable them to get jobs that meet their unrealistically high expectations, or that such efforts can be cost-effective. In sum, liberals look to increases in earnings and reductions in poverty, while conservatives stress welfare savings and the intrinsic value of program participation and work performed while on welfare. The Family Support Act of 1988 (FSA), especially its centerpiece, the Job Opportunities and Basic Skills Training (JOBS) Program, redefines federal policy on welfare employment programs and represents a compromise among these conflicting visions of welfare reform. The key elements of FSA are that parents, both fathers and mothers, should be the primary supporters of their children and that government should provide incentives and assistance to welfare recipients to find employment. For absent fathers, this translates into greater enforcement of child support collections and new obligations on welfare mothers to cooperate with such efforts. For welfare recipients, JOBS contains features of both the conservative and liberal views: an expansion of the program participation mandate to women with younger children (as young as age 3, or age 1 at state option), a complex balance of mandatory and voluntary elements (including an emphasis on serving volunteers first and on determining services through case management and client choice), child care guarantees, and investments designed to improve the capacity of AFDC mothers to obtain jobs and, hopefully, self-sufficiency. While JOBS gives states substantial flexibility in designing welfare employment programs, it includes incentives to move the system in new directions. In contrast to state programs of the 1980s, which typically provided job search activities followed by unpaid work experience, JOBS places much greater emphasis on education. It requires that (to the extent resources are available) education be offered to any adult on AFDC who lacks a high school diploma or does not demonstrate basic literacy. 6 Throughout this paper, "workfare" refers to a mandatory work-for-benefits program using either the Community Work Experience Program or WIN (Work Incentive) work experience approaches and not the evolving broader definition that encompasses any work-related activity.

7 Judith M. Gueron 85 States must also provide job skills training, job placement services, and two of the following: group or individual assistance in locating a job (job search), on-the-job training, or community work experience (workfare). JOBS also introduces a new vision for teenage custodial parents by requiring that they participate in an educational activity (the "learnfare" provision) and adds a stronger work mandate for AFDC-UP adults. Other provisions of FSA authorize funding for in-program child care for JOBS participants, require states to provide benefits to unemployed parents, and provide for a year of transitional child care and Medicaid for individuals leaving welfare for employment. Nonwelfare Reform Proponents of nonwelfare reform argue that poor women are unlikely to move from welfare to above-poverty-level incomes, at least in the short run and even after participating in an employment or education program, that reducing poverty should be the fundamental goal of reform, and that policies should equitably treat the working and the dependent poor. Maintaining that AFDC and other income-conditioned programs are inherently flawed because they cannot "reflect and reinforce our basic values" and are also stigmatizing and degrading (Ellwood, 1988, p. 237), this group seeks to institute policies outside the means-tested welfare system that increase the returns from part- or full-time work and provide alternative sources of income. Examples include strengthening the child support system (or even guaranteeing a child support payment), "making work pay" by either increasing the minimum wage and the Earned Income Tax Credit or requiring employers to provide health insurance, improving the education and training systems, and providing jobs directly if there is an insufficient demand for labor. Advocates of nonwelfare reform stress parental responsibility but seek specific measures to assure that work will result in adequate income and security. This greater generosity towards the working poor is often combined with restrictions on the ability of those not working to get long-term welfare, or replacing AFDC with a transitional program focused on employment and jobs. This reorientation would make work more rewarding, but would offer no increase and possibly even a reduction in support for those who do not work. 7 In theory, welfare and nonwelfare reform are complements, since work mandates should be more effective in an environment in which work pays. In practice, budget constraints may make them alternatives. With the passage of FSA, which contained elements of both approaches (in the JOBS title and in strengthened child support enforcement), Congressional action in 1989 shifted towards reforms that would assist the non-dependent poor. The remainder of this paper summarizes what is known about the effectiveness of welfare employment programs. At the end, it returns to a discussion of the tradeoffs between welfare and nonwelfare reform. 7 Ellwood (1988), Garfinkel and McLanahan (1986), and the Ford Foundation (1989) outline specific nonwelfare reform policies. Reischauer (1989) discusses the constraints on efforts to reform welfare.

8 86 Journal of Economic Perspectives Reforming Welfare with Work The current push for work requirements should be viewed as only the latest version of an ancient alternative with a very checkered history. 8 What is new, however, is that the current discussion draws less on assertions of competing values and more on information about what can realistically be accomplished, based on studies of state experiences during the early and mid-1980s. State welfare programs for able-bodied men have often included work requirements. Congress first expressed a preference for "reciprocal obligations" in the AFDC program in 1971, when it required all adult recipients with school-age children to register and participate in a welfare employment program the recently enacted Work Incentive (WIN) program and take jobs, or risk grant reductions. Because of meager appropriations, however, participation was often limited to registration, and the program lost credibility as it failed both to meet its operational objectives and to generate reliable information on caseload changes and cost-effectiveness. Several state-run demonstrations in the 1970s also generated more questions than answers as attempts at welfare reform foundered against bureaucratic resistance, legal challenges, and implementation problems. 9 While the large-scale feasibility and cost-effectiveness of mandatory work programs remained uncertain, some careful social experiments pointed to the realistic potential of smaller-scale voluntary employment strategies. The National Supported Work Demonstration (implemented in 15 sites between 1975 and 1980) showed that structured, transitional, paid work experience could have positive long-term effects for very disadvantaged welfare recipients and could also be cost-effective for taxpayers, despite high initial costs. For example, by months 19 through 27 after enrollment, a period during which most people had been out of the program for close to a year, the supported work group had average monthly earnings that were $77 (more than 45 percent) higher than those of women in the experiment's control group, and average monthly AFDC payments that were $52 (23 percent) less than those of controls (Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation, 1980, p. 153). Evaluations of programs that assisted women in searching for jobs indicated that this low-cost approach could also provide lasting benefits to a wide range of recipients (Wolfhagen with Goldman, 1983). Both programs showed clear impacts, although not large ones, and indicated greater effects for the more disadvantaged. While encouraging, these studies did not address the question of whether largescale mandatory programs could have similar effects. In the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1981, Congress gave states an option to convert WIN into a block grant administered by welfare agencies and to use workfare for the first time as a component of state programs. This action gave states the flexibility to put their own 8 Katz (1986) provides a useful summary of the continuity between the current debate and earlier controversies, including the debate about the relative merits of "outdoor" relief (cash assistance) and "indoor" relief (in a poorhouse that required one to work). 9 See Mead (1986) and Rein (1982) for different views of the WIN program, and see Gueron and Nathan (1985) for a summary of pre-1980 state demonstrations.

9 Work and Welfare: Lessons on Employment Programs 87 stamp on what had been seen as a federally mandated and bureaucratic program, but less money to do it with. WIN, the major federal funding source for these programs, had become a target for annual budget cuts, with funding falling 70 percent between 1981 and 1987 in nominal dollars. The combination of increased flexibility and reduced resources led to a mixed response. Overall, the scale of work programs declined, with fewer people and areas of the country covered. But what remained, even if usually modest in design, seemed reenergized, as states reorganized staff and shaped work initiatives to reflect prevailing values and experience. Studies by the U.S. General Accounting Office (1987) and the Urban Institute (Nightingale and Burbridge, 1987) show that in 1986, 37 states were operating some form of job search assistance or workfare, the most common activities; however, these were implemented in areas covering only about 40 and 30 percent, respectively, of the national AFDC caseload. But because of the absence of reliable and consistent state data, these reports offer no firm estimates of the percentage of the caseload participating in these programs, nor of more complex outcomes such as the programs' cost-effectiveness or impact on employment or welfare dependence. Much of what is known about these questions comes from the smaller number of states with welfare employment programs that were carefully evaluated using largescale controlled social experiments involving almost 40,000 people. Recent work confirms the importance of this approach in determining the effectiveness of social programs. 10 Extensive research has shown that, contrary to popular belief, many recipients move off the welfare rolls fairly rapidly. To find out if an employment program changes earnings or welfare dependence, it is important to be able to distinguish between program-induced changes and the normal dynamics of welfare turnover. While many approaches have tried to obtain such estimates, including those using time series studies and comparison groups, the most accurate employ the techniques of social experimentation, in which welfare applicants or recipients are randomly assigned either to the mandatory work program or to a control group excused from program requirements. The behavior of these two groups can then be tracked over time, with differences between them providing estimates of program impacts. The seven social experiments summarized here are of programs generally representative of mandatory state welfare employment initiatives during the early and mid-1980s, and include projects in Baltimore, Cook County (including Chicago), and San Diego (two different approaches), as well as multi-county efforts in Arkansas, Virginia, and West Virginia. These studies answer several questions important to the debate on welfare employment strategies. Further detail on these programs is available in Gueron (1987) and reports by the Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation (MDRC). 10 See Burtless and Orr (1986), Ashenfelter (1987), and Lalonde and Maynard (1987) for discussions of the relative merits of experimental and nonexperimental studies.

10 88 Journal of Economic Perspectives Program Design and Participation The participation requirements that these state initiatives imposed varied along a number of dimensions: the duration of the obligation, the activities provided, who was required to participate, and the extent to which the requirement was enforced. Table 1 summarizes the seven programs along these dimensions. Duration of Obligation. While all seven programs were mandatory that is, people could lose some benefits if they refused to meet program requirements five imposed obligations that usually lasted no more than four months. Only two, West Virginia and the San Diego Saturation program, mandated participation as long as Table 1 Dimensions of welfare employment programs in seven areas

11 Judith M. Gueron 89 someone remained on welfare. In fact, the San Diego Saturation program was a federally funded demonstration designed to test the feasibility and impact of imposing an open-ended participation requirement. Activities Required. In general, the states offered limited services at relatively low cost, ranging from under $200 per eligible person in Cook County and Arkansas to around $1,000 in Baltimore. Except for West Virginia, which required recipients to work in exchange for their benefits, the states chose to implement a participation rather than a strict work requirement. Typically, welfare applicants or recipients were required to look for a job with program assistance for two to four weeks. In a two-week version, the first week might consist of three-hour-per-day group sessions designed to build self-confidence and job-seeking skills; the second week might consist of two to three hours per day of supervised telephone contact with prospective employers. If not successful, program registrants might be required to work for up to three months doing unpaid work (workfare). Usually, these were entry-level jobs in public or nonprofit agencies involving maintenance, clerical, park upkeep, or human services functions. Monthly work hours equaled the welfare grant divided by the minimum wage. After this, if they were still not employed, the obligation would end or some minimal job search would periodically be imposed. This was the pattern in Arkansas, Cook County, and Virginia, and in San Diego's first project, although the programs differed substantially in the extent to which they provided assistance in job search and actually enforced participation in workfare. San Diego's Saturation program mandated education or training for those who completed the sequence without finding a job and were still on welfare. In contrast, the Baltimore program did not impose a fixed sequence of activities but tried to offer a choice of job search, unpaid work experience, or a range of short- or longer-term educational and training activities. Mandatory Participants. Severe budget constraints combined with concern about requiring women with young children to work led all of the states to limit the share of the caseload subject to the mandate. Except for Arkansas, which included women with children age 3 or over, the states imposed an obligation on only the one-third of the AFDC caseload with school-age children, the group that during this period was subject to the WIN mandate. (As noted earlier, FSA extends this to women with younger children.) Some states required all adults in this group to participate (spending very little per person), but others focused the program on certain areas of the state or certain subgroups. 11 Extent of Enforcement. Someone unfamiliar with welfare employment programs or with the daily situations facing many women on public assistance might expect participation in well-administered programs to be close to 100 percent. However, given substantial welfare turnover, temporary deferrals (because of part-time employment, illness, child care, or other reasons acceptable to the program), and normal administrative delays, this is clearly not reasonable. In fact, administrators during this 11 As indicated in Table 1, some states also required participation of parents in AFDC-UP cases. The discussion in this paper focuses on the results for single-parent AFDC cases.

12 90 Journal of Economic Perspectives period faced substantial uncertainty about the feasibility of requiring participation or the level of activity that would reflect the successful implementation of a participation mandate. In the seven programs, participation rates, however defined, were less than universal. In the five areas with short-term requirements, a useful way to measure participation was to track newly enrolled AFDC applicants or recipients and ask what fraction were ever active in the program or otherwise satisfied its requirements. Using this undemanding measure, typically about half the women had taken part in some activity within nine months of registration, and between 75 and 90 percent (depending on the location) had in some sense satisfied the program mandate (if not through participation, then by getting a job, leaving the rolls, or having their welfare grant reduced). (The rate of sanctions or temporary grant reductions varied from between 2 and 12 percent across the seven programs.) In areas with ongoing requirements, a more appropriate indicator is the share of the eligible caseload participating each month in the program or an alternative activity (such as employment or education) that satisfies the program mandate. The best data on this come from the San Diego Saturation program, which implemented a sequence of job search assistance, workfare, and referrals to community education and training programs. During a typical month, 52 percent of the WIN-mandatory caseload subject to the requirement participated in some relevant activity. Importantly, the monthly rate was very sensitive to the types of activities counted: if only the three sequenced activities were included, 33 percent of the caseload participated; if the 19 percent of those registered for the program who were employed in any month were counted, the rate rose to 52 percent. While these monthly rates may appear low, a number of factors suggest that 50 to 60 percent participation, broadly defined, probably represented the upper bound of administrative feasibility. Ninety percent of the registrants in the San Diego Saturation program who were eligible were either active in program services or inactive but had complied with program requirements during the month, even if they did not participate. Many of those inactive were assigned to components scheduled to begin during the next month; some were temporarily excused from participation owing to illness or other situational factors (Hamilton, 1988). Participation rates are also affected by the program model and local conditions. San Diego's relatively healthy economy during the period the Saturation program operated, its extensive network of education and training facilities, and California's high AFDC grant levels (which enabled more people to combine unsubsidized employment with the receipt of welfare than would be the case in other areas) suggest that other communities would have substantial difficulty replicating these rates. While the seven initiatives differed in terms of the liberal and conservative preferences for the design of welfare employment programs discussed earlier, in general they came out somewhere between the two. Primarily as a result of funding constraints, services were usually low-cost, offered little choice, and emphasized job placement rather than skills development. However, obligations were generally brief, sanctions were infrequent, and workfare did not emerge as the predominant activity.

13 Work and Welfare: Lessons on Employment Programs 91 Overall, the initiatives were incremental, not radical. As a result, questions remain about the feasibility and effectiveness of more intensive services or tougher work requirements, such as mandating more hours per week or more months of participation, stressing workfare rather than alternatives, or achieving higher participation rates among those eligible for the programs. Program Impacts and Cost-Effectiveness The results from the seven studies, summarized in Table 2, show that in most cases programs led to consistent and measurable increases in employment and earnings. 12 These positive impacts appeared to continue for at least three years in the states where data were available, with earnings gains of approximately 10 to 30 percent per eligible person in the caseload in the final year of the study. In Arkansas, for example, members of the experimental group were more likely to be employed, with increases of 4 to 6 percentage points in each of the three years of follow-up. By the third year, this translated into earnings gains of $337, or 31 percent, when experimentals as a group (including those who did not work as well as those who did) averaged $1,422 in earnings compared to $1,085 for controls. In Baltimore, increases in employment rates were smaller, but third-year earnings gains were larger, $511. Both the San Diego programs, serving two different groups of the WIN-mandatory population, also had notable impacts. 13 In general, these programs also led to welfare savings, although these were usually smaller and less consistent than the earnings gains. In Arkansas and the San Diego Saturation program, for example, welfare recipiency was reduced significantly (by 7 percentage points by the end of the last year of follow-up), with annual savings of $168 per person in Arkansas and $553 in San Diego (including those on the rolls as well as those off welfare) in the final year. In other states, there were smaller or no reductions in the rolls and variations in the effect on average welfare payments. However, the findings from two states provide important exceptions. First, the workfare program in West Virginia did not lead to increased employment and earnings. As program planners foresaw, this was probably because West Virginia is a rural state with exceptionally high unemployment. As a result, while the program could reinforce community preferences for work, keep job skills from deteriorating, and provide useful public services, it could not translate these into gains in unsubsidized employment. Second, the program in Cook County (which has since been ended) resulted in no statistically significant increases in employment and earnings, although there were small welfare savings. Here, the key explanation may lie in the program design. The Cook County program was the least expensive of those studied; mainly, it monitored people and sanctioned those who did not participate, providing little direct assistance 12 Throughout this paper, increases and decreases are noted only for changes that are statistically significant in Table 2 or in more detailed quarterly results. 13 These employment and earnings impacts and the benefit-cost findings discussed below assume that the increased employment of welfare recipients did not come at the expense of nonrecipients. The extent of any such displacement is unknown and very difficult to measure.

14 92 Journal of Economic Perspectives Table 2 Summary of the impacts on AFDC eligibles of welfare employment programs in seven areas

15 Table 2 (Continued) Judith M. Gueron 93

16 94 Journal of Economic Perspectives even in its job search component. These exceptions provide useful reminders of the importance of labor market conditions and possibly of the need to provide at least minimal assistance to get employment results (if not welfare savings). An analysis of five of the programs (Friedlander, 1988) showed, moreover, that gains were not distributed uniformly across the eligible caseload. The most employable people for example, women who were first-time welfare applicants and had recent work experience usually did not gain from program participation. While this group showed high program outcomes (as measured, for example, by employment rates), similarly high rates were found for comparable people in the control group. That is, even without special assistance, many of these women stayed on welfare only for relatively brief periods. In contrast, women with little or no recent work history benefited more consistently from these programs, even though the programs offered only limited assistance and almost no intensive training. While more of these women remained on welfare after participating in a work program, their performance relative to similar people in the control group was more impressive. However, Friedlander (1988) also identified a third, more disadvantaged group long-term welfare recipients with no recent employment who did not show consistent earnings impacts, despite some welfare savings. The JOBS legislation's focus on serving long-term recipients suggests the importance of determining whether more intensive services (including education and training) will be more successful in increasing this group's earnings and self-sufficiency. A detailed benefit-cost study examined the effects of these programs from several perspectives: the government budget, the welfare population, and society as a whole. In general, the results showed that the budgetary cost was more than offset by projected savings within two to five years of program enrollment and that, for the women on welfare, projected earnings gains usually exceeded estimated reductions in welfare benefits and other transfer payments (such as Medicaid and food stamps). The programs also scored positively from society's perspective, leading to gains in total social resources. Overall, these studies answer some key questions about the "welfare reform" option. First, with resources and time, such programs can be successfully implemented and can impose obligations on some share of the caseload. Second, even the relatively modest initiatives implemented in the early to mid-1980s led to a notable substitution of earnings for welfare and proved cost-effective, suggesting that the success can be repeated on a larger scale. The earnings gains are particularly important because they are averages that include all persons on welfare eligible for the program, not just the approximately 50 percent who actually participated or the people who found jobs. 14 Of course, average increases of about $300 to $650 a year conceal wide variations. For the people who benefit, through new jobs or higher earnings, the gains are much larger. 14 Both the impact and benefit-cost results were estimated for all persons eligible for the program, not just the 50 percent who participated. This is appropriate because mandatory programs spend resources processing nonparticipants and can have impacts on them if people change their behavior to avoid program participation or if welfare grants are reduced as a result of sanctions.

17 Work and Welfare: Lessons on Employment Programs 95 But the results also suggest caution in what can be expected from this type of reform: Alone, these programs do not offer an immediate cure for poverty or dependence. Their impacts are modest; many people remain dependent; and those who move off welfare often remain poor. Where Do We Go from Here? This paper has outlined two current approaches to restructuring social welfare policy: an expansion of welfare employment programs ("welfare reform") or the use of other tools to attack poverty ("nonwelfare reform"). The studies of the past seven years provide substantial information on the potential of the first approach, but the limited nature of the state initiatives described above suggests that two key questions remain unanswered. First, would either tougher work requirements (as advocated by conservatives) or more expensive education and training services (as advocated by liberals) make these programs more effective in reducing poverty or dependence? Different judgments on the answer to this question underlie the dispute that almost torpedoed the Family Support Act. Substituting reliable findings for rhetoric is particularly important because the new resources provided by the act's JOBS title will not be sufficient for states to offer comprehensive and intensive employment services to the full AFDC caseload. Instead, states will have to make choices. The JOBS legislation assures continued state flexibility, since it does not establish a uniform program but, rather, uses the carrot of higher federal matching rates as an incentive for states to satisfy certain design features: importantly, meeting targets for participation rates and for service to potentially long-term welfare recipients. 15 States moving to implement the JOBS legislation before the October 1990 deadline will be starting from very different positions and are likely to face widely divergent budget constraints, since overall JOBS resources will depend on the extent to which state legislatures put up money to draw down matching federal funds. As a result of the different pressures in JOBS, states will be called on to balance coverage and intensity, that is, using new resources either to extend lower-cost services to more people (for example, to meet participation targets) or to provide more enriched services to fewer people, or some combination of the two. The research to date does not provide clear guidance on whether greater investments in education and training will result in sufficiently greater returns to justify the additional outlays. While some studies of small-scale, voluntary programs suggest that more expensive services have higher returns, there is no evidence that 15 Thus, in order to avoid a reduction in federal matching rates, states must have at least 20 percent of the newly expanded mandatory caseload participating in program activities (not counting employment) in each month by 1995 (with higher rates for adults in AFDC-UP cases) and spend at least 55 percent of JOBS funds on families in which the custodial parent is under age 24 and has no high school diploma (or equivalency) or has had little or no work in the last year; the youngest child is within two years of ineligibility for AFDC; or the family received AFDC in 36 of the previous 60 months.

18 96 Journal of Economic Perspectives these can be replicated for a larger and more diverse population. (The San Diego Saturation program provides the first indication that this may be the case.) A second unanswered question is whether the results summarized in this paper can be replicated or improved upon if programs are expanded to serve a larger share of the caseload, particularly women with younger children. The new legislation places a priority on serving young mothers, based on extensive evidence of the high personal and social costs of their likely long-term dependence (Bane and Ellwood, 1983; Burt, 1986). Unfortunately, while there is a widespread consensus on the urgency of addressing the problems caused by teenage pregnancy, there is much less information on successful ways to assist young mothers and their children. Relatively little is known about what services or requirements will prove effective for this population, or about the adequacy or cost of providing needed child care. In particular, it is not clear whether low-cost mandates will be effective or feasible for this group, or whether very intensive services will be required to encourage and enable these young women to choose employment over long-term dependence. Current and planned state initiatives address both questions. For example, California's Greater Avenues for Independence (GAIN) and New Jersey's Realizing Economic Achievement (REACH) programs two of the more complex state JOBSfunded programs are designed to provide a much more extensive range of services and, in GAIN, to require education for everyone determined in need. GAIN also requires continuous and active participation in the program for as long as someone remains on welfare. Other states are beginning to implement the JOBS "learnfare" provisions, requiring teenage AFDC parents to enroll in school or have their grants reduced. To the extent that these and other state JOBS initiatives are carefully assessed, the promised expansion of employment programs should provide important new information. 16 Uncertainties about how states will use the JOBS resources, about the actual scale of future programs, and about the relative effectiveness of different approaches suggest caution in predicting the results of the new legislation. The lessons from the early to mid-1980s suggest that these programs can improve the tradeoff within the welfare system between the two goals of reducing poverty and promoting self-sufficiency. As a result of these programs, more people are working and a greater share of their income comes from their own earnings, rather than transfers. However, while this did not come at the price of increasing poverty, it was not accompanied by any notable reduction in it, either. While more intensive or targeted services may increase average impacts and overall income, other research suggests that employment programs alone are unlikely 16 Several multi-site social experiments are under way that should provide reliable information on alternative programs for young mothers: a project testing mandatory employment-related activities and case management in two locations (the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services' Teenage Parent Demonstration); a demonstration of a comprehensive voluntary program providing employment, education, health, and child care services in a multi-generational model (MDRC's New Chance Demonstration); and an evaluation of Ohio's statewide learnfare initiative, Project Learn. The U.S. Department of Health and Human Services has also funded a 10-site social experiment to test the impact of different JOBS approaches.

The JOBS Evaluation: Monthly Participation Rates in Three Sites and Factors Affecting Participation Levels in Welfare-to-Work Programs

The JOBS Evaluation: Monthly Participation Rates in Three Sites and Factors Affecting Participation Levels in Welfare-to-Work Programs The JOBS Evaluation: Monthly Participation Rates in Three Sites and Factors Affecting Participation Levels in Welfare-to-Work Programs July 1995 Gayle Hamilton In 1988, the Family Support Act (FSA) sought

More information

POVERTY AND WELFARE: THE GAO REPORT

POVERTY AND WELFARE: THE GAO REPORT POVERTY AND WELFARE: THE GAO REPORT From time to time we have reported on the state of the social science research on poverty, race, and welfare. The Government Accounting Office recently issued a report

More information

The Family Transition Program Implementation and Three-Year Impacts of Florida's Initial Time-Limited Welfare Program

The Family Transition Program Implementation and Three-Year Impacts of Florida's Initial Time-Limited Welfare Program The Family Transition Program Implementation and Three-Year Impacts of Florida's Initial Time-Limited Welfare Program Dan Bloom, Mary Farrell, James J. Kemple, Nandita Verma Preface This is the fourth

More information

POLICY BRIEF. Making Work Pay for Public Housing Residents Learning from the Jobs-Plus Demonstration

POLICY BRIEF. Making Work Pay for Public Housing Residents Learning from the Jobs-Plus Demonstration Making Work Pay for Public Housing Residents Learning from the Jobs-Plus Demonstration James A. Riccio and Steven Bliss POLICY BRIEF APRIL 2002 JOBSPLUS RESIDENTS of the nation s public housing developments

More information

Results from the South Carolina ERA Site

Results from the South Carolina ERA Site November 2005 The Employment Retention and Advancement Project Results from the South Carolina ERA Site Susan Scrivener, Gilda Azurdia, Jocelyn Page This report presents evidence on the implementation

More information

BEYOND WELFARE: NEW OPPORTUNITIES TO USE TANF TO HELP LOW-INCOME WORKING FAMILIES OVERVIEW

BEYOND WELFARE: NEW OPPORTUNITIES TO USE TANF TO HELP LOW-INCOME WORKING FAMILIES OVERVIEW BEYOND WELFARE: NEW OPPORTUNITIES TO USE TANF TO HELP LOW-INCOME WORKING FAMILIES By MARK H. GREENBERG CENTER FOR LAW AND SOCIAL POLICY JULY 1999 OVERVIEW In recent months, three stories have emerged about

More information

Chapter 19 Social Welfare

Chapter 19 Social Welfare Chapter 19 Social Welfare Social Welfare: Framing the Issue Who should benefit? Who should pay? How important is social justice? As society and the economy changes, the answers to these questions change.

More information

Wisconsin officials raise questions about federal barriers that now stand in the way of a new state program to help poor families.

Wisconsin officials raise questions about federal barriers that now stand in the way of a new state program to help poor families. Perspective BadgerCare: A Case Study Of The Elusive New Federalism Wisconsin officials raise questions about federal barriers that now stand in the way of a new state program to help poor families. by

More information

FINANCE COMMITTEE MAKES FLAWED EMPLOYER REQUIREMENT IN HEALTH REFORM BILL STILL MORE PROBLEMATIC

FINANCE COMMITTEE MAKES FLAWED EMPLOYER REQUIREMENT IN HEALTH REFORM BILL STILL MORE PROBLEMATIC 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org Revised October 21, 2009 FINANCE COMMITTEE MAKES FLAWED EMPLOYER REQUIREMENT IN HEALTH

More information

The Minimum Wage Ain t What It Used to Be

The Minimum Wage Ain t What It Used to Be http://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/12/09/the-minimum-wage-aint-what-it-used-to-be DECEMBER 9, 2013, 11:00 AM The Minimum Wage Ain t What It Used to Be By DAVID NEUMARK David Neumarkis professor of

More information

The GAIN Evaluation. Working Paper 96.1 FIVE-YEAR IMPACTS ON EMPLOYMENT, EARNINGS, AND AFDC RECEIPT

The GAIN Evaluation. Working Paper 96.1 FIVE-YEAR IMPACTS ON EMPLOYMENT, EARNINGS, AND AFDC RECEIPT The GAIN Evaluation Working Paper 96.1 FIVE-YEAR IMPACTS ON EMPLOYMENT, EARNINGS, AND AFDC RECEIPT Stephen Freedman, Daniel Friedlander, Winston Lin, and Amanda Schweder Manpower Demonstration Research

More information

Welfare and Poverty: The Elements of Reform

Welfare and Poverty: The Elements of Reform Yale Law & Policy Review Volume 11 Issue 1 Yale Law & Policy Review Article 5 1993 Welfare and Poverty: The Elements of Reform Judith M. Gueron Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/ylpr

More information

The Cross-State Study of Time-Limited Welfare Welfare Time Limits: An Interim Report Card. Dan Bloom

The Cross-State Study of Time-Limited Welfare Welfare Time Limits: An Interim Report Card. Dan Bloom The Cross-State Study of Time-Limited Welfare Welfare Time Limits: An Interim Report Card Dan Bloom April 1999 Of all the fundamental changes that have swept through the nation s welfare system over the

More information

Public-Private Partnerships in Medicaid Long-Term Care

Public-Private Partnerships in Medicaid Long-Term Care Public-Private Partnerships in Medicaid Long-Term Care by Chuck Milligan, J.D. and M.P.H., Executive Director and Ann Volpel, M.P.A., Senior Research Analyst Center for Health Program Development and Management

More information

by sheldon danziger and rucker c. johnson

by sheldon danziger and rucker c. johnson trends by sheldon danziger and rucker c. johnson The Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 1996, a k a welfare reform, has been widely praised for ending welfare as we knew

More information

Medicare Beneficiaries and Their Assets: Implications for Low-Income Programs

Medicare Beneficiaries and Their Assets: Implications for Low-Income Programs The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation Medicare Beneficiaries and Their Assets: Implications for Low-Income Programs by Marilyn Moon The Urban Institute Robert Friedland and Lee Shirey Center on an Aging

More information

Poverty in Our Time. The Challenges and Opportunities of Fighting Poverty in Virginia. Executive Summary. By Michael Cassidy and Sara Okos

Poverty in Our Time. The Challenges and Opportunities of Fighting Poverty in Virginia. Executive Summary. By Michael Cassidy and Sara Okos May 2009 Poverty in Our Time The Challenges and Opportunities of Fighting Poverty in Virginia By Michael Cassidy and Sara Okos Executive Summary Even in times of economic expansion, the number of Virginians

More information

The Progressive Policy Institute

The Progressive Policy Institute To: The Next President From: Katie Campbell, The Progressive Policy Institute Re: A Work Bonus for Men One of the most serious social problems our nation faces is the persistence of poverty and joblessness

More information

WikiLeaks Document Release

WikiLeaks Document Release WikiLeaks Document Release February 2, 2009 Congressional Research Service Report RL32598 TANF Cash Benefits as of January 1, 2004 Meridith Walters, Gene Balk, and Vee Burke, Domestic Social Policy Division

More information

Unemployment and its natural rate. Chapter 27

Unemployment and its natural rate. Chapter 27 1 Unemployment and its natural rate Chapter 27 What we learn in this chapter? This is the last chapter of Part IX: the real economy in the long run In Chapter 24 we established the link between production,

More information

Federal Minimum Wage, Tax-Transfer Earnings Supplements, and Poverty

Federal Minimum Wage, Tax-Transfer Earnings Supplements, and Poverty Federal Minimum Wage, Tax-Transfer Earnings Supplements, and Poverty -name redacted- Specialist in Social Policy -name redacted- Specialist in Social Policy -name redacted- Specialist in Labor Economics

More information

Analysis of Food Stamp and Medical Assistance Caseload Reductions in Milwaukee County:

Analysis of Food Stamp and Medical Assistance Caseload Reductions in Milwaukee County: University of Wisconsin Milwaukee UWM Digital Commons ETI Publications Employment Training Institute 2000 Analysis of Food Stamp and Medical Assistance Caseload Reductions in Milwaukee County: 1995-1999

More information

The TANF Reconciliation Bill Provisions

The TANF Reconciliation Bill Provisions The TANF Reconciliation Bill Provisions Presentation for Coalition on Human Needs, Welfare Advocates Meeting, January 12, 2006 Mark Greenberg Director of Policy Center for Law and Social Policy 1015 15

More information

Why TANF Is Not a Model for Other Safety Net Programs

Why TANF Is Not a Model for Other Safety Net Programs 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org June 6, 2016 Why TANF Is Not a Model for Other Safety Net Programs By Liz Schott House

More information

Chart Book: TANF at 20

Chart Book: TANF at 20 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org Updated August 5, 2016 Chart Book: TANF at 20 The Temporary Assistance for Needy Families

More information

Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF): Welfare-to-Work Revisited

Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF): Welfare-to-Work Revisited Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF): Welfare-to-Work Revisited Gene Falk Specialist in Social Policy October 2, 2012 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Congressional

More information

The Fiscal Environment

The Fiscal Environment Section 7: Fiscal Responsibilities Chapter 29 The Fiscal Environment Understanding the fiscal role and responsibilities of the governing board means understanding the fiscal environment in which the community

More information

The Ins and Outs of Delinking: Promoting Medicaid Enrollment of Children Who are Moving In and Out of the TANF System. March 1999.

The Ins and Outs of Delinking: Promoting Medicaid Enrollment of Children Who are Moving In and Out of the TANF System. March 1999. The Ins and Outs of Delinking: Promoting Medicaid Enrollment of Children Who are Moving In and Out of the TANF System March 1999 A National Health Access Initiative for Low-Income Uninsured Children Prepared

More information

Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends

Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Federal Publications Key Workplace Documents 9-15-2008 Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends Patrick Purcell Congressional Research Service; Domestic

More information

Balancing Activation and Protection Learning from Active Social Policies in the European Union and the United States

Balancing Activation and Protection Learning from Active Social Policies in the European Union and the United States uman evelopment conomics, urope and Central Asia Region Balancing Activation and Protection Learning from Active Social Policies in the uropean Union and the United States Arup Banerji Sofia, Bulgaria

More information

A $7.25 MINIMUM WAGE WOULD BE A USEFUL STEP IN HELPING WORKING FAMILIES ESCAPE POVERTY by Jason Furman and Sharon Parrott

A $7.25 MINIMUM WAGE WOULD BE A USEFUL STEP IN HELPING WORKING FAMILIES ESCAPE POVERTY by Jason Furman and Sharon Parrott 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org January 5, 2007 A $7.25 MINIMUM WAGE WOULD BE A USEFUL STEP IN HELPING WORKING FAMILIES

More information

Key State TANF Policies Affecting Microenterprise. California

Key State TANF Policies Affecting Microenterprise. California Key State TANF Policies Affecting Microenterprise California The Charles Stewart Mott microenterprise grantees in California are West Company in Mendocino County and Women s Initiative for Self-Employment

More information

SOCIAL SECURITY OFFSETS. Improvements to Program Design Could Better Assist Older Student Loan Borrowers with Obtaining Permitted Relief

SOCIAL SECURITY OFFSETS. Improvements to Program Design Could Better Assist Older Student Loan Borrowers with Obtaining Permitted Relief United States Government Accountability Office Report to Congressional Requesters December 2016 SOCIAL SECURITY OFFSETS Improvements to Program Design Could Better Assist Older Student Loan Borrowers with

More information

THE FOOD STAMP PROGRAM Working Smarter for Working Families by Dorothy Rosenbaum and David Super

THE FOOD STAMP PROGRAM Working Smarter for Working Families by Dorothy Rosenbaum and David Super 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org Revised June 29, 2005 THE FOOD STAMP PROGRAM Working Smarter for Working Families by

More information

Factors Affecting Individual Premium Rates in 2014 for California

Factors Affecting Individual Premium Rates in 2014 for California Factors Affecting Individual Premium Rates in 2014 for California Prepared for: Covered California Prepared by: Robert Cosway, FSA, MAAA Principal and Consulting Actuary 858-587-5302 bob.cosway@milliman.com

More information

The Temporary Assistance for Needy Families Program. Robert A. Moffitt Johns Hopkins University and National Bureau of Economic Research

The Temporary Assistance for Needy Families Program. Robert A. Moffitt Johns Hopkins University and National Bureau of Economic Research The Temporary Assistance for Needy Families Program Robert A. Moffitt Johns Hopkins University and National Bureau of Economic Research May, 2000 Revised, December 2001 Revised, August, 2002 Forthcoming

More information

WELFARE TIME LIMITS IN

WELFARE TIME LIMITS IN WELFARE TIME LIMITS IN THE UNITED STATES CHARLES MICHALOPOULOS* Introduction In 1996, the US Congress passed and President Clinton signed welfare legislation that made dramatic changes to the benefits

More information

THE GROWTH RATE OF GNP AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MONETARY POLICY. Remarks by. Emmett J. Rice. Member. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

THE GROWTH RATE OF GNP AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MONETARY POLICY. Remarks by. Emmett J. Rice. Member. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System THE GROWTH RATE OF GNP AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MONETARY POLICY Remarks by Emmett J. Rice Member Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System before The Financial Executive Institute Chicago, Illinois

More information

Medicaid Benefits for Children and Adults: Issues Raised by the National Governors Association s Preliminary Recommendations

Medicaid Benefits for Children and Adults: Issues Raised by the National Governors Association s Preliminary Recommendations Medicaid Benefits for Children and Adults: Issues Raised by the National Governors Association s Preliminary Recommendations July 12, 2005 Cindy Mann Overview The Medicaid benefit package determines which

More information

Demographic and Economic Characteristics of Children in Families Receiving Social Security

Demographic and Economic Characteristics of Children in Families Receiving Social Security Each month, over 3 million children receive benefits from Social Security, accounting for one of every seven Social Security beneficiaries. This article examines the demographic characteristics and economic

More information

INTRODUCTION NEW YORK STATE SURPLUS SPENDING. Continued on page 4. New York State Programmed TANF Surplus (Dollars in millions)

INTRODUCTION NEW YORK STATE SURPLUS SPENDING. Continued on page 4. New York State Programmed TANF Surplus (Dollars in millions) IBO New York City Independent Budget Office Fiscal Brief August 2001 New York s Increasing Dependence on the Welfare Surplus SUMMARY This month marks the fifth anniversary of the 1996 federal welfare reform

More information

17- May 1, Robyn Frost, Executive Director Massachusetts Coalition for the Homeless 15 Bubier Street Lynn, MA Dear M.

17- May 1, Robyn Frost, Executive Director Massachusetts Coalition for the Homeless 15 Bubier Street Lynn, MA Dear M. Common wealth of Massachusetts Executive Office of Health and Human Services Departm ent of Transitional Assistance 600 Washington Street Boston MA 02111 DEVAL L. PATRICK Governor TIMOTHY P. MURRAY Lieutenant

More information

Summary Most Americans with private group health insurance are covered through an employer, coverage that is generally provided to active employees an

Summary Most Americans with private group health insurance are covered through an employer, coverage that is generally provided to active employees an Health Insurance Continuation Coverage Under COBRA Janet Kinzer Information Research Specialist Meredith Peterson Information Research Specialist December 18, 2009 Congressional Research Service CRS Report

More information

Frozen at $16.5 billion through FY pregnancy reduction and twoparent. need to be targeted to lowincome

Frozen at $16.5 billion through FY pregnancy reduction and twoparent. need to be targeted to lowincome Updated: August 9, 2002 Summary Comparison of TANF Reauthorization Provisions: Bills Passed by Senate Finance Committee and the House of Representatives, and Related Proposals by Shawn Fremstad, Zoë Neuberger,

More information

Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends

Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Federal Publications Key Workplace Documents September 2005 Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends Patrick Purcell Congressional Research Service

More information

TRENDS IN FSP PARTICIPATION RATES: FOCUS ON SEPTEMBER 1997

TRENDS IN FSP PARTICIPATION RATES: FOCUS ON SEPTEMBER 1997 Contract No.: 53-3198-6-017 MPR Reference No.: 8370-058 TRENDS IN FSP PARTICIPATION RATES: FOCUS ON SEPTEMBER 1997 November 1999 Laura Castner Scott Cody Submitted to: Submitted by: U.S. Department of

More information

)*+,($&''( -#./))0 1!!7#8".1.8.!"3

)*+,($&''( -#./))0 1!!7#8.1.8.!3 !"#"#$%&''( )*+,($&''( " -#./))0 1#.2!3 45#6 &'4/,.!!7!!8.9 31#. :#819#;###;# #65"#"##..8;91,$&/))03718.8 19

More information

Federal Employees Retirement System: Budget and Trust Fund Issues

Federal Employees Retirement System: Budget and Trust Fund Issues Federal Employees Retirement System: Budget and Trust Fund Issues Katelin P. Isaacs Analyst in Income Security September 27, 2012 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress

More information

CalWORKs. Program and Budget History

CalWORKs. Program and Budget History CalWORKs Program and Budget History State budgets in recent years reflect vast and deep changes in the CalWORKs Program, at the same time that an increased caseload of parents and children have relied

More information

Prospects for the Social Safety Net for Future Low Income Seniors

Prospects for the Social Safety Net for Future Low Income Seniors Prospects for the Social Safety Net for Future Low Income Seniors Marilyn Moon American Institutes for Research Presented at Forgotten Americans: The Future of Support for Older Low-Income Adults National

More information

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code RL33387 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Topics in Aging: Income of Americans Age 65 and Older, 1969 to 2004 April 21, 2006 Patrick Purcell Specialist in Social Legislation

More information

Changes in TANF Work Requirements Could Make Them More Effective in Promoting Employment

Changes in TANF Work Requirements Could Make Them More Effective in Promoting Employment 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org February 26, 2013 Changes in TANF Work Requirements Could Make Them More Effective in

More information

Chairman Herger, and Members of the Subcommittee on Human Resources:

Chairman Herger, and Members of the Subcommittee on Human Resources: TESTIMONY OF DOUGLAS J. BESHAROV Resident Scholar, American Enterprise Institute Professor, University of Maryland School of Public Affairs before the Subcommittee on Human Resources of the Committee on

More information

(Outlays, by fiscal year, in millions of dollars) 5-Year Estimate Date Total

(Outlays, by fiscal year, in millions of dollars) 5-Year Estimate Date Total CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE U.S. CONGRESS WASHINGTON, DC 20515 March 31, 1988 MEMORANDUM TO: FROM: Rikki Baum Jan Peskin, Richard Curley, Julie Isaacs and Alan Fairbank SUBJECT: Factors Underlying the

More information

OPPAGA provides objective, independent, professional analyses of state policies and services to assist the Florida Legislature in decision making, to

OPPAGA provides objective, independent, professional analyses of state policies and services to assist the Florida Legislature in decision making, to Justification Review Child Support Enforcement Program Florida Department of Revenue Report No. 00-24 December 2000 Office of Program Policy Analysis and Government Accountability an office of the Florida

More information

HOW FAR SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT GO IN PROVIDING A MINIMUM LEVEL OF NUTRITION?

HOW FAR SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT GO IN PROVIDING A MINIMUM LEVEL OF NUTRITION? HOW FAR SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT GO IN PROVIDING A MINIMUM LEVEL OF NUTRITION? G. William Hoagland Administrator Food and Nutrition Service U.S. Department of Agriculture "I hope we shall prove how much happier

More information

State Tax Relief for the Poor

State Tax Relief for the Poor State Tax Relief for the Poor David S. Liebschutz and Steven D. Gold T his paper summarizes highlights of the book State Tax Relief for the Poor by David S. Liebschutz, associate director of the Center

More information

Submission to House of Commons Standing Committee on Finance Pre-Budget Consultation Giving Priority to Low-Income, Unattached, Women Seniors

Submission to House of Commons Standing Committee on Finance Pre-Budget Consultation Giving Priority to Low-Income, Unattached, Women Seniors 383 Parkdale Avenue Suite 402 Ottawa ( Ontario) K1Y 4R4 Tel. : (613) 729-6668 Fax. : (613) 729-9608 E-mail : casw@casw-acts.ca Submission to House of Commons Standing Committee on Finance Pre-Budget Consultation

More information

Welfare Reform in the USA. Frank Fuentes Deputy Director, ACYF Administration for Children and Families

Welfare Reform in the USA. Frank Fuentes Deputy Director, ACYF Administration for Children and Families Welfare Reform in the USA Frank Fuentes Deputy Director, ACYF Administration for Children and Families Historical Context Elizabethan Poor Laws family, local, State responsibility 1935 Social Security

More information

By eliminating jobs and/or reducing employment growth,

By eliminating jobs and/or reducing employment growth, Issue Brief M M A N H A T T A N I N S T I T U T E F O R P O L I C Y R E S E A R C H I No. 36 July 2015 Published by the Manhattan Institute and American Action Forum COUNTERPRODUCTIVE The Employment and

More information

Chapter 15 Government and Society. AP Government

Chapter 15 Government and Society. AP Government Chapter 15 Government and Society AP Government Aims of Social Policies Part of the aim of government is to devise and implement policies that improve society. Social policies aim: to protect people against

More information

EBRI. The Erosion of Health Insurance Coverage Among the Nonelderly Population: Public Policy Issues and Options. Statement

EBRI. The Erosion of Health Insurance Coverage Among the Nonelderly Population: Public Policy Issues and Options. Statement EBRI T-56 (revised) The Erosion of Health Insurance Coverage Among the Nonelderly Population: Public Policy Issues and Options Statement of Deborah J. Chollet, Ph.D. _ Hearing before the United States

More information

WELFARE REFORM IN UNITED STATES of AMERICA

WELFARE REFORM IN UNITED STATES of AMERICA WELFARE REFORM IN UNITED STATES of AMERICA We Are Different 1, The argument regarded in welfare system is Equity vs. Efficiency. 2, Market failure argument exists before and after government intervention.

More information

Does It Pay to Move from Welfare to Work? A Comment on Danziger, Heflin, Corcoran, Oltmans, and Wang. Robert Moffitt Katie Winder

Does It Pay to Move from Welfare to Work? A Comment on Danziger, Heflin, Corcoran, Oltmans, and Wang. Robert Moffitt Katie Winder Does It Pay to Move from Welfare to Work? A Comment on Danziger, Heflin, Corcoran, Oltmans, and Wang Robert Moffitt Katie Winder Johns Hopkins University April, 2004 Revised, August 2004 The authors would

More information

Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017

Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017 Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017 1. Governments should act to further the public interest. This statement would probably receive general agreement, but it is not always

More information

Will Carter's Welfare Reform Plan Reform Welfare?: Evidence from Empirical Research

Will Carter's Welfare Reform Plan Reform Welfare?: Evidence from Empirical Research The Journal of Sociology & Social Welfare Volume 7 Issue 1 January Article 3 January 1980 Will Carter's Welfare Reform Plan Reform Welfare?: Evidence from Empirical Research Mary Bryna Sanger New School

More information

About two-thirds of americans who become uninsured do so when

About two-thirds of americans who become uninsured do so when Health Insurance For Workers Who Lose Jobs: Implications For Various Subsidy Schemes Subsidies for continuation coverage would benefit few of the uninsured; subsidies to all low-income people who leave

More information

Unemployment Insurance As a Potential Safety Net for TANF Leavers: Evidence from Five States

Unemployment Insurance As a Potential Safety Net for TANF Leavers: Evidence from Five States Contract No.: 1-98-9 MPR Reference No.: 855-144 Unemployment Insurance As a Potential Safety Net for TANF Leavers: Evidence from Five States Final Report September 24 Anu Rangarajan Carol Razafindrakoto

More information

The State of the Safety Net in the Post- Welfare Reform Era

The State of the Safety Net in the Post- Welfare Reform Era The State of the Safety Net in the Post- Welfare Reform Era Marianne Bitler (UC Irvine) Hilary W. Hoynes (UC Davis) Paper prepared for Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Sept 21 Motivation and Overview

More information

Room Attendant Training Program

Room Attendant Training Program SOCIAL RETURN ON INVESTMENT Room Attendant Training Program August 2014 Kenzie Gentry and Anthony Harrison 2011 Annual Report TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction.... 3 Summary of Results... 4 Methodology...

More information

Living Arrangements, Doubling Up, and the Great Recession: Was This Time Different?

Living Arrangements, Doubling Up, and the Great Recession: Was This Time Different? Living Arrangements, Doubling Up, and the Great Recession: Was This Time Different? Marianne Bitler (UC Irvine) Hilary Hoynes (UC Berkeley) AEA session on How Did the Safety Net Perform During the Great

More information

At the end of Class 20, you will be able to answer the following:

At the end of Class 20, you will be able to answer the following: 1 Objectives for Class 20: The Tax System At the end of Class 20, you will be able to answer the following: 1. What are the main taxes collected at each level of government? 2. How do American taxes as

More information

WORKFARE.. BREAKING THE POVERTY CYCLE

WORKFARE.. BREAKING THE POVERTY CYCLE 195 July 9, 1982 WORKFARE.. BREAKING THE POVERTY CYCLE INTRODUCTION Expenditures on welfare programs have been rising at an alarming rate over the last two decades. A principal cause of this enormous expansion

More information

Key Policy Issues for the. Next Phase of Welfare Reform

Key Policy Issues for the. Next Phase of Welfare Reform New York Public Welfare Association Key Policy Issues for the Next Phase of Welfare Reform Sheila Harrigan, Executive Director August 22, 2006 Featuring: Spotlight on Key Policy Issues Welfare Reform Law

More information

Social Security and Medicare Lifetime Benefits and Taxes

Social Security and Medicare Lifetime Benefits and Taxes E X E C U T I V E O F F I C E R E S E A R C H Social Security and Lifetime Benefits and Taxes 2018 Update C. Eugene Steuerle and Caleb Quakenbush October 2018 Since 2003, we and our colleagues have released

More information

DIVERSION AS A WORK-ORIENTED WELFARE REFORM STRATEGY AND ITS EFFECT ON ACCESS TO MEDICAID: AN EXAMINATION OF THE EXPERIENCES OF FIVE LOCAL COMMUNITIES

DIVERSION AS A WORK-ORIENTED WELFARE REFORM STRATEGY AND ITS EFFECT ON ACCESS TO MEDICAID: AN EXAMINATION OF THE EXPERIENCES OF FIVE LOCAL COMMUNITIES DIVERSION AS A WORK-ORIENTED WELFARE REFORM STRATEGY AND ITS EFFECT ON ACCESS TO MEDICAID: AN EXAMINATION OF THE EXPERIENCES OF FIVE LOCAL COMMUNITIES A Report of the Findings of the Second Phase of the

More information

The Earned Income Tax Credit, Welfare Reform, and the Employment of Low Skill Single Mothers

The Earned Income Tax Credit, Welfare Reform, and the Employment of Low Skill Single Mothers The Earned Income Tax Credit, Welfare Reform, and the Employment of Low Skill Single Mothers Strategies for Improving Economic Mobility Of Workers November 15-16, 2007 Hilary W. Hoynes Professor, University

More information

American Labor and the Great Depression

American Labor and the Great Depression American Labor and the Great Depression (Genre: Online Article) 1 Welcome to the next section of our online series on the history of workers rights in the United States. Here, we take a look at a defining

More information

A DECADE OF WELFARE REFORM: FACTS AND FIGURES

A DECADE OF WELFARE REFORM: FACTS AND FIGURES THE URBAN INSTITUTE Fact Sheet Office of Public Affairs, 2100 M STREET NW, WASHINGTON, D.C. 20037 (202) 261-5709; paffairs@ui.urban.org A DECADE OF WELFARE REFORM: FACTS AND FIGURES Assessing the New Federalism

More information

ISSUE. Evaluate several options for expanding eligibility for North Carolina s Earned Income

ISSUE. Evaluate several options for expanding eligibility for North Carolina s Earned Income To: Professor Gene Nichol From: Jared Elosta Re: Options for Expanding EITC Eligibility in North Carolina Date: June 11, 2010 ISSUE Evaluate several options for expanding eligibility for North Carolina

More information

Opportunities under the Recovery Act for Income Support for Low Income Families

Opportunities under the Recovery Act for Income Support for Low Income Families Opportunities under the Recovery Act for Income Support for Low Income Families Elizabeth Lower Basch CLASP April 22, 2009 2009 Illinois Family Impact Seminar Unemployment Insurance 38 percent of unemployed

More information

The Fiscal Condition of Albany County for the Year Presented May 12, 2014 by Michael F. Conners, II

The Fiscal Condition of Albany County for the Year Presented May 12, 2014 by Michael F. Conners, II The Fiscal Condition of Albany County for the Year 2013 Presented May 12, 2014 by Michael F. Conners, II Overall comparison 2012 2013 Increase/ Decrease Excess of revenue, appropriation of prior year

More information

From the War on Poverty to a war on welfare a brief history of U.S. Work and Welfare support Programs. U.S. Poverty Policy ECRG 3240 Spring 2013

From the War on Poverty to a war on welfare a brief history of U.S. Work and Welfare support Programs. U.S. Poverty Policy ECRG 3240 Spring 2013 From the War on Poverty to a war on welfare a brief history of U.S. Work and Welfare support Programs U.S. Poverty Policy ECRG 3240 Spring 2013 Early in 1964 President Johnson s Council of Economic Advisors

More information

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 13 Basic things you need to know about SS. SS is essentially a public annuity, it gives insurance against low

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 13 Basic things you need to know about SS. SS is essentially a public annuity, it gives insurance against low Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 13 Basic things you need to know about SS. SS is essentially a public annuity, it gives insurance against low income in old age. Because there is forced participation

More information

Data and Methods in FMLA Research Evidence

Data and Methods in FMLA Research Evidence Data and Methods in FMLA Research Evidence The Family and Medical Leave Act (FMLA) was passed in 1993 to provide job-protected unpaid leave to eligible workers who needed time off from work to care for

More information

REPORT ON LEGISLATION BY THE SOCIAL WELFARE COMMITTEE. S.4830 Sen. Savino

REPORT ON LEGISLATION BY THE SOCIAL WELFARE COMMITTEE. S.4830 Sen. Savino Contact: Maria Cilenti - Director of Legislative Affairs - mcilenti@nycbar.org - (212) 382-6655 REPORT ON LEGISLATION BY THE SOCIAL WELFARE COMMITTEE A.2669-B M. of A. Wright S.4830 Sen. Savino AN ACT

More information

The misplaced debate about job loss and a $15 minimum wage

The misplaced debate about job loss and a $15 minimum wage Washington Center for Equitable Growth The misplaced debate about job loss and a $15 minimum wage By David R. Howell July 2016 Overview The leading criticism of the Fight for $15 campaign to raise the

More information

California has one of the largest economies in the world and is home to incredible prosperity,

California has one of the largest economies in the world and is home to incredible prosperity, Issue Brief JUNE 201 BY ALISSA ANDERSON Five Facts Everyone Should Know About Deep Poverty California has one of the largest economies in the world and is home to incredible prosperity, but that prosperity

More information

2000 HOUSING AND POPULATION CENSUS

2000 HOUSING AND POPULATION CENSUS Ministry of Finance and Economic Development CENTRAL STATISTICS OFFICE 2000 HOUSING AND POPULATION CENSUS REPUBLIC OF MAURITIUS ANALYSIS REPORT VOLUME VIII - ECONOMIC ACTIVITY CHARACTERISTICS June 2005

More information

Results from the Post-Assistance Self-Sufficiency (PASS) Program in Riverside, California

Results from the Post-Assistance Self-Sufficiency (PASS) Program in Riverside, California The Employment Retention and Advancement Project Results from the Post-Assistance Self-Sufficiency (PASS) Program in Riverside, California David Navarro, Mark van Dok, and Richard Hendra May 2007 This

More information

Risky Business: Capitated Financing in the Dual Eligible Demonstration Projects

Risky Business: Capitated Financing in the Dual Eligible Demonstration Projects Risky Business: Capitated Financing in the Dual Eligible Demonstration Projects Ellen Breslin Davidson and Tony Dreyfus BD Group Community Catalyst, Inc. 30 Winter St. 10 th Floor Boston, MA 02108 617.338.6035

More information

WORKING P A P E R. The Returns to Work for Children Leaving the SSI- Disabled Children Program RICHARD V. BURKHAUSER AND MARY C.

WORKING P A P E R. The Returns to Work for Children Leaving the SSI- Disabled Children Program RICHARD V. BURKHAUSER AND MARY C. WORKING P A P E R The Returns to Work for Children Leaving the SSI- Disabled Children Program RICHARD V. BURKHAUSER AND MARY C. DALY WR-802-SSA October 2010 Prepared for the Social Security Administration

More information

TANF FUNDS MAY BE USED TO CREATE OR EXPAND REFUNDABLE STATE CHILD CARE TAX CREDITS

TANF FUNDS MAY BE USED TO CREATE OR EXPAND REFUNDABLE STATE CHILD CARE TAX CREDITS 820 First Street, NE, Suite 510, Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org http://www.cbpp.org October 11, 2000 TANF FUNDS MAY BE USED TO CREATE OR EXPAND REFUNDABLE STATE

More information

Response to the Manitoba Government Employment and Income Assistance Rate Review 2013

Response to the Manitoba Government Employment and Income Assistance Rate Review 2013 Response to the Manitoba Government Employment and Income Assistance Rate Review 2013 Social Planning Council of Winnipeg In partnership with the EIA Advocates Network February 2014 The Manitoba Ombudsman's

More information

Integrating TANF and WIA Into a Single Workforce System: An Analysis of Legal Issues

Integrating TANF and WIA Into a Single Workforce System: An Analysis of Legal Issues Integrating and Into a Single Workforce System: An Analysis of Legal Issues Executive Summary February 2004 Mark H. Greenberg Emil Parker Abbey Frank www.clasp.org (202) 906-8000 1015 15 th Street, NW,

More information

Oren M. Levin-Waldman and George W. McCarthy

Oren M. Levin-Waldman and George W. McCarthy Policy Note 1998/3 Small Business and the Minimum Wage Oren M. Levin-Waldman and George W. McCarthy Do small businesses change their hiring and employment practices in response to an increase in the minimum

More information

IBO. Despite Recession,Welfare Reform and Labor Market Changes Limit Public Assistance Growth. An Analysis of the Hudson Yards Financing Plan

IBO. Despite Recession,Welfare Reform and Labor Market Changes Limit Public Assistance Growth. An Analysis of the Hudson Yards Financing Plan IBO Also Available... An Analysis of the Hudson Yards Financing Plan...at www.ibo.nyc.ny.us New York City Independent Budget Office Fiscal Brief August 2004 Despite Recession,Welfare Reform and Labor Market

More information

Child Health Advocates Guide to Essential Health Benefits

Child Health Advocates Guide to Essential Health Benefits Child Health Advocates Guide to Essential Health Benefits One of the Affordable Care Act s important features for health insurance consumers is the establishment of a package of essential health benefits

More information

Labor Markets, Poverty, and Income Distribution. Chapter 12. McGraw-Hill/Irwin. Copyright 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Labor Markets, Poverty, and Income Distribution. Chapter 12. McGraw-Hill/Irwin. Copyright 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Labor Markets, Poverty, and Income Distribution Chapter 12 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Learning Objectives 1. Understand the relationship between

More information

Labor Markets, Poverty, and Income Distribution. Chapter 12. Learning Objectives

Labor Markets, Poverty, and Income Distribution. Chapter 12. Learning Objectives Labor Markets, Poverty, and Income Distribution Chapter 12 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Learning Objectives 1. Understand the relationship between

More information