Nora Lustig a, * Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries: Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru and South Africa

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Nora Lustig a, * Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries: Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru and South Africa"

Transcription

1 JGD 2016; 7(1): Open Access Nora Lustig a, * Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries: Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru and South Africa DOI /jgd Abstract: This paper examines the redistributive impact of fiscal policy for Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru and South Africa using comparable fiscal incidence analysis with data from around The largest redistributive effect is in South Africa and the smallest in Indonesia. Success in fiscal redistribution is driven primarily by redistributive effort (share of social spending to GDP in each country) and the extent to which transfers/subsidies are targeted to the poor and direct taxes targeted to the rich. While fiscal policy always reduces inequality, this is not the case with poverty. When pensions are not considered a transfer, fiscal policy increases poverty in Brazil (over and above market income poverty) due to high consumption taxes on basic goods. Total spending on education is pro-poor except for Indonesia, where it is neutral in absolute terms. Health spending is pro-poor in Brazil, Chile and South Africa, roughly neutral in absolute terms in Mexico, and not pro-poor in Indonesia and Peru. Keywords: developing countries; fiscal incidence; inequality; poverty; social spending. JEL Codes: H22; H5; D31; I3. 1 Introduction On average, advanced countries are less unequal than other regions of the world. Around 2010, the average Gini coefficient for advanced economies was roughly a Nora Lustig is Samuel Z. Stone Professor of Latin American Economics and Director of the Commitment to Equity Institute (CEQI), Tulane University and nonresident fellow of the Center for Global Development and the Inter-American Dialogue. *Corresponding author: Nora Lustig, Department of Economics, Tulane University, New Orleans, LA, USA, nlustig@tulane.edu 2016, Nora Lustig, published by De Gruyter. This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 3.0 License.

2 18 Nora Lustig equal to 0.30 while the Gini coefficient for the rest of the world was approximately equal to Advanced countries, however, are not born less unequal. Relatively low inequality is the result of fiscal redistribution on a large scale. In the European Union, for example, the reduction in the Gini coefficient induced by direct taxes and transfers hovers around 21 percentage points if social insurance pensions are considered a transfer and 9 percentage points if pensions are assumed to be deferred income (EUROMOD 2015). 2 Higgins et al. (2015) find that in the United States, the figures are 11 and 7 percentage points, respectively. 3 How much fiscal redistribution takes place in middle-income countries? In this paper, I examine the redistributive impact of fiscal policy in Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru and South Africa, seven middle-income countries that were available in the commitment to equity (CEQ) project. 4 In particular, I address the following questions: What is the impact of fiscal policy on inequality and poverty? What is the contribution of direct taxes and transfers, net indirect taxes and spending on education and health to the overall reduction in inequality? How pro-poor is spending on education and health? To put the fiscal redistribution efforts in context, I start by presenting a brief overview of the evolution of inequality (measured by the Gini coefficient) by region and income per capita categories. The information used here is based on the following fiscal incidence analyses: Brazil (Higgins and Pereira 2014), Chile (Martinez-Aguilar et al. 2016), Colombia (Lustig and Melendez 2015), Indonesia (Afkar et al. 2016), Mexico (Scott 2014), Peru (Jaramillo 2014) and South Africa (Inchauste et al. 2015). Lustig et al. (2014) and Lustig (2015a,b) 5 provide syntheses of the results. These studies use a 1 The Gini coefficients are simple averages calculated with the following data. Advanced countries: OECD Income Distribution Database: Gini, poverty, income, Methods and Concepts. OECD. Accessed December, 22, Developing countries except for Latin America and the Caribbean: PovcalNet: an online poverty analysis tool. The World Bank. Accessed November 05, PovcalNet/index.htm?0,0. Latin America and the Caribbean: Socio-Economic Database for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEDLAS and The World Bank). Accessed July 22, econo.unlp.edu.ar/eng/statistics-detalle.php?ide=35. 2 If pensions are assumed to be deferred income, they are counted as part of market or consumable income of people receiving them. The data are for Data is for Launched in 2008, the CEQ project is an initiative of the Center for Inter-American Policy and Research (CIPR) and the Department of Economics, Tulane University, the Center for Global Development and the Inter-American Dialogue. For more details visit 5 The analysis is based on the country studies that have been undertaken and completed under the CEQ project by January The authors of the country studies are: Brazil (Higgins and Pereira 2014), Chile (Martinez-Aguilar et al. 2016), Colombia (Lustig and Melendez 2015), Indonesia (Afkar et al. 2016), Mexico (Scott 2014), Peru (Jaramillo 2014) and South Africa (Inchauste et al. 2015).

3 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 19 common fiscal incidence method described in detail in Lustig and Higgins (2013) and of which a brief summary is included below. Known in the literature as the accounting approach because it ignores behavioral responses and general equilibrium effects, incidence analysis of public spending and taxation is designed to respond to the question of who benefits from government transfers and who ultimately bears the burden of taxes in the economy. With a long tradition in applied public finance, tax and benefit incidence analysis is an efficient instrument to evaluate whether fiscal policy has the desired effect on poverty and inequality (Musgrave 1959; Pechman 1985; Martínez-Vazquez 2008). The increasing availability of household surveys containing sufficient information to assess the effects of fiscal policy on incomes and their distribution, has increased considerably the number of empirical studies in this area. The contribution of specific fiscal interventions is calculated using the marginal contribution method. This method is equivalent to asking the question: how much would have inequality changed if the fiscal intervention of interest had not been there (keeping the rest of the fiscal system in place)? 6 The progressivity and pro-poorness of education and health spending are determined based on the size and sign of the relevant concentration coefficient. In keeping with generally accepted convention, spending is regressive when the concentration coefficient is higher than the market-income Gini. Spending is progressive, when the concentration coefficient is lower than the market-income Gini. Spending is pro-poor when the concentration coefficient is not only lower than the marketincome Gini, but also has a negative value. 7 A negative concentration coefficient implies that per capita spending tends to be higher the poorer the individual. 8 When the concentration coefficient equals zero, per capita spending is the same across the distribution: spending is neutral in absolute terms. By definition, government spending that is pro-poor (or neutral in absolute terms) is also progressive. However, not all government spending that is progressive is pro-poor. This article makes three important contributions. First, because the fiscal incidence analysis is comprehensive, one can estimate both the overall impact of the fiscal system as well as the marginal contribution of the main fiscal interventions to the overall reduction in inequality. The main fiscal interventions included here are: direct taxes, direct transfers, net indirect taxes and transfers in-kind (in the form of education and healthcare services). Second, the analysis 6 This method is described and used in OECD (2011). The analytical merits of this method compared to the sequential method are discussed in Lustig et al. (forthcoming). 7 Implicit in the rankings is the assumption that concentration curves do not cross. 8 This does not need to happen at every income level. A concentration coefficient will be negative as long as the concentration curve lies above the diagonal.

4 20 Nora Lustig includes the effects of fiscal policy not only on inequality but also on poverty. Third, because the seven studies apply a common methodology, results are comparable across countries. The findings can be summarized as follows. Overall, there is evidence that in the 2000s the average inequality for the world (measured by the average of the unweighted Gini coefficients) declined very slightly. There also appears evidence of convergence: countries with initially higher (lower) levels of inequality more frequently experienced a decline (increase). There are two regions which show noticeable declines in average inequality: Latin America and the Caribbean and South Asia. The impact of fiscal policy on income redistribution results in various degrees of equalization with the largest redistributive effect in South Africa and the smallest one in Indonesia. South Africa s result can be attributed to the combination of a large redistributive effort with transfers targeted to the poor and direct taxes targeted to the rich. In spite of this, South Africa remains the most unequal of the seven countries. Income redistribution tends to be higher in more unequal countries to start with: redistribution is considerable higher in countries with higher market income inequality such as South Africa and Brazil than in countries with relatively lower inequality such as Indonesia and Peru. As expected, the level of income redistribution and the size of the budget allocated to social spending (as a share of GDP) are associated. However, differences across countries suggest that institutional, political and demographic factors also affect the level of redistribution. Redistribution is considerably larger in countries with high social spending, such as Brazil and South Africa, than in Indonesia and Peru, where social spending is more limited. Direct taxes and direct transfers generally exercise an equalizing force. Indirect taxes are unequalizing in Colombia and Indonesia, but equalizing in Chile and neutral in South Africa. Contributory pensions are equalizing in Brazil, Chile and Indonesia, and slightly unequalizing in Colombia, Mexico and Peru. Per capita total spending on public education tends to be higher for poorer households (i.e. pro-poor) in all countries except for Indonesia, where the per capita benefit is roughly the same for all households. Government spending on tertiary education increases with income in all countries, but only in Indonesia it increases inequality. Health spending is pro-poor (that is, per capita spending declines with income) in Brazil, Chile, and South Africa. In Mexico, the per capita benefit is roughly the same across the income scale. In Indonesia and Peru, health spending per person tends to increase with income but still reduces inequality. Although education and health spending have the highest redistributive effect of the different components of fiscal policy, the existing information cannot disentangle to what extent the progressivity or pro-poorness of education and health spending is a result of differences in household or personal characteristics

5 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 21 that could explain a more intense use by poorer households (e.g. having more children and worse health) or the opting-out of those better-off. While fiscal policies overall unambiguously reduce income inequality, in terms of poverty reduction, the outcome is less auspicious. In Chile, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru, Colombia and South Africa poverty after cash transfers, net direct taxes and net indirect taxes is lower than market income poverty. In Brazil, however, income poverty would be higher if public pensions are considered as deferred income rather than a direct transfer, which means that a portion of the poor who are not pensioners are net payers into the fiscal system and are, thus, impoverished by the fiscal system (Higgins and Lustig 2016). The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a brief overview of levels and trends in inequality for the world, by region and income level, and by country. Section 3 presents spending allocation and revenue raising patterns for the seven countries. Section 4 includes a brief description of the fiscal incidence methodology. Sections 5 and 6 discuss the impact of fiscal policy on inequality and poverty, respectively. Section 7 examines the pro-poorness of government spending on education and health. Section 8 concludes. 2 The Evolution of Inequality in the Developing World Table 1 presents the (unweighted) average Gini coefficient by region and income category for the period There are several observations to be made. In 2010, world inequality can be classified as moderate: the average Gini is just below 0.4, the median of the difference between the region with the lowest and the highest Gini coefficient. The level of inequality in Advanced Economies, Eastern Europe and Central Asia and South Asia is below the world average; it is above the world average in Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America and the Caribbean. East Asia s inequality is roughly the same as the world s average. Latin America and the Caribbean is the region with the highest extent of inequality by far: its average Gini is 12 points above the world s average. Using the World Bank s clas- 9 The welfare measure utilized here is per capita disposable income (i.e., income after direct taxes and transfers) for Latin America and the Caribbean (SEDLAC), equivalized disposable income for OECD non-lac countries (IDD), and per capita consumption for the rest (World Bank s POVCAL). A caveat is in order. The microdata for advanced countries distinguishes between income before and income after taxes and transfers in a clear way, this is not the case, however, for the income-based surveys in Latin America.

6 22 Nora Lustig Table 1: Average inequality by region and income level (5 year averages) Region b Gini coefficient a World Advanced economies East Asia and the Pacific Eastern Europe and Central Asia Latin America and the Caribbean Middle East and North Africa Not enough data South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa Income Category c Low income countries Lower middle income countries Upper middle income countries Total middle income countries High income countries Source: Author s calculations based on: OECD Income Distribution Database: Gini, poverty, income, Methods and Concepts. OECD. Accessed December, 22, PovcalNet: an online poverty analysis tool. The World Bank. Accessed November 05, Socio-Economic Database for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEDLAS and The World Bank). Accessed July 22, a Data for Latin America comes from SEDLAC (household per capita income Gini series). Gini Estimates for OECD countries outside of Latin America are based on OECD IDD (Gini at disposable income, post taxes and transfers, using square root of family size equivalence scales). All other Gini estimates are based on POVCAL (household per capita consumption Gini). Regional Gini Coefficients are calculated in two steps. First, for each country we take the average estimated Gini Coefficient for the 5-year period surrounding the displayed year. For example, we use 1998, 1999, 2000, 2001, and 2002 for Second, for all countries for whom we have estimates in each of the 3 years above, we take a simple, unweighted average across the region. Where there were fewer than three countries that we could track across all three periods, we do not report the regional average. b Regional Averages were based on the following countries with the welfare measure (with I denoting income or C denoting consumption) in parentheses: Advanced Economies: Australia (I), Canada (I), Czech Republic (I), Denmark (I), Finland (I), France (I), Germany (I), Greece (I), Israel (I), Italy (I), Japan (I), Luxembourg (I), Netherlands (I), New Zealand (I), Norway (I), Sweden (I), United Kingdom (I), and United States (I) East Asia and the Pacific: China (C), Indonesia (C), Laos (C), Philippines (C), Thailand (C), and Vietnam (C). Eastern Europe and Central Asia: Albania (C), Armenia (C), Azerbaijan (C), Belarus (C), Croatia (C), Georgia (C), Kazakhstan (C), Kyrgyz Republic (C), Latvia (C), Lithuania (C), Macedonia (C), Moldova (C), Romania (C), Russian Federation (C), Serbia (C), Tajikistan (C), Turkey (C), and Ukraine (C).

7 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 23 Table 1 (continued) Latin America and the Caribbean: Bolivia (I), Brazil (I), Chile (I), Colombia (I), Costa Rica (I), Dominican Republic (I), Ecuador (I), Guatemala (I), Honduras (I), Mexico (I), Nicaragua (I), Panama (I), Paraguay (I), and Peru (I). South Asia: Bangladesh (C), Pakistan (C), and Sri Lanka (C). Sub-Saharan Africa: Burkina Faso (C), Ethiopia (C), Madagascar (C), Malawi (C), Mali (C), Mauritania (C), Rwanda (C), Senegal (C), South Africa (C), Tanzania (C), Uganda (C), and Zambia (C). c The classification by income category follows the World Bank (February 2015): sification of countries by income level, low income countries inequality is well below the world s average. The most unequal group is comprised of upper middle income countries, a reflection of the influence of unequal Latin America since a significant number of middle income countries are from that region. Inequality trends feature what has already been documented: there is evidence in support of a slight decline in world inequality 10 and inequality convergence. 11 In particular, Latin America and the Caribbean which was and still is the most unequal region has experienced a significant decline. 12 Inequality in lowincome countries has experienced a slight increase, while inequality in middle and high income countries has fallen a bit. Convergence is graphically apparent on Figure 1 below. This figure also shows that declining inequality has been more frequent in the 2000s. Of the 78 countries included in the graph, 45 experienced a decline, 30 experienced an increase, and three experienced no change. In Figure 2, one can observe the level and evolution of the Gini coefficient for the seven countries analysed here. South Africa features the highest levels of inequality, followed by Brazil and Chile.Indonesia has the lowest level of inequality in this group, and Mexico and Peru are closer to the most unequal. One important aspect to bear in mind, however, is that the data for Indonesia and South Africa is consumption-based while it is income-based for the rest. A well-known fact is that consumption-based inequality data tends to be lower than income-based one. Hence, Indonesia and South Africa are likely to be more unequal in the income per capita space than shown below. 13 Regarding trends, 10 World inequality here means the average of unweighted Ginis. Note that it is different from the concept of global inequality which integrates all the individuals in the world (from all the available household surveys) under a single ranking. 11 See, for example, Bourguignon (2015) and Ravallion (2003). 12 The decline in inequality in Latin America has been analyzed by López-Calva and Lustig (2010) and Cornia (2014), among others. 13 For South Africa this is evident when one looks at the income-based measures in Inchauste et al. (2015).

8 24 Nora Lustig Figure 1: Gini coefficient: level and change by country: Source: Author s calculations based on: OECD Income Distribution Database: Gini, poverty, income, Methods and Concepts. OECD. Accessed December, 22, PovcalNet: an online poverty analysis tool. The World Bank. Accessed November 05, Socio-Economic Database for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEDLAS and The World Bank). Accessed July 22, Notes: All Gini estimates from Latin America use SEDLAC as their source. Gini Estimates for OECD countries outside of Latin America are based on OECD IDD. All other Gini estimates are based on POVCAL. Change in Gini is calculated as the average Gini coefficient between 2008 and 2012 minus the average Gini coefficient between 1998 and (I) denotes Gini based on per capita income and (C) denotes Gini based on per capita consumption. Figure 2: The evolution of inequality in Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru and South Africa. Source: Author s calculations based on: PovcalNet:an online poverty analysis tool. The World Bank. Accessed November 05, Socio-Economic Database for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEDLAS and The World Bank). Accessed July 22, Notes:All Gini estimates from Latin America use SEDLAC as their source and Indonesia and South Africa are based on POVCAL Gini Coefficients.

9 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 25 Income inequality in Brazil: Income inequality in Chile: Gini coefficient Gini coefficient Year Income inequality in Colombia: Year Income inequality in Indonesia: Gini coefficient Gini coefficient Year Year Income inequality in Mexico: Income inequality in Peru: Gini coefficient Gini coefficient Year Income inequality in South Africa: Year Gini coefficient Year

10 26 Nora Lustig the four countries from Latin America show a decline while Indonesia and South Africa experienced an increase. 14 The data for Colombia, however, has to be taken with caution because of changes in the household surveys used as source for these trends. 3 Budget Size, Social Spending and Taxation The redistributive potential of a country is determined first and foremost by the size and composition of its budget and how government spending is financed. Figure 3 shows social spending as a share of GDP for around Social spending includes direct transfers, contributory and noncontributory pensions, and public spending on education and health. 15 It does not include housing subsidies or other forms of social spending. As one can observe, the seven countries are quite heterogeneous in terms of government size and resources committed to social spending. Brazil and South Africa stand out as countries with a relatively large government and more fiscal resources devoted to social spending. Brazil, for instance, allocates 23.7 percent of its GDP to direct transfers, pensions, education and health. On the other extreme is Indonesia, where the share is 5.4 percent. Panel A in Figure 3 shows the composition of social spending for the following categories: direct transfers, pensions, education and health around Direct transfers include noncontributory (social) pensions. Brazil and South Africa devote a sizeable share to direct transfers: 4.2 percent and 3.8 percent, respectively. In addition to Bolsa Familia and the basic noncontributory 14 For an analysis of the factors behind the increase in inequality in post-apartheid South Africa, see Leibbrandt et al. (2010). 15 Note that the numbers included in this section are those provided by the authors of the individual studies based on government statistics. The numbers do not necessarily match those found in bulk databases such as the World Bank s World Development Indicators, OECD SOCX or other institutions that form part of the United Nations system broadly defined. Definitions of categories may vary too. The definition of social spending here is different from, for example, OECD s. The OECD SOCX definition for public social expenditure is as follows: social spending with financial flows controlled by General Government (different levels of government and social security funds), as social insurance and social assistance payments. Social benefits include cash benefits (e.g. pensions, income support during maternity leave and social assistance payments) and social services (e.g. childcare, care for the elderly and disabled). It therefore excludes education spending.

11 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 27 A 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% Indonesia** (2012) Peru (2009) (Ranked by social spending/gdp; GNI right hand scale) Mexico (2010) Colombia (2010) Chile* (2013) South Africa*** (2010) Brazil (2009) Seven countries Direct transfers Education Health Contributory pensions OECD (2011) 25,000 20,000 15,000 10, Other social spending GNI per capita (2011 PPP) B 50% 45% (Ranked by total government revenue/gdp; GNI right hand scale) 25,000 40% 35% 20,000 30% 25% 15,000 20% 15% 10,000 10% 5% % Colombia (2010) Indonesia** (2012) Chile* (2013) Mexico (2010) Peru (2009) South Africa*** (2010) Brazil (2009) Seven countries 0 Direct taxes Indirect and other taxes Social security contributions Other revenues GNI per capita (2011 PPP) Figure 3: Size and composition of Government budgets (Circa 2010). Panel A: Composition of social spending as a share of GDP; Panel B: Composition of total government revenues as a share of GDP. Source: Author s calculations based on Brazil: Higgins and Pereira (2014); Chile: Martinez- Aguilar et al. (2016); Colombia: Lustig and Melendez (2015); Indonesia: Afkar et al. (2016); Mexico: Scott (2014); OECD: averages were provided by the organization itself and are for 2011; Peru: Jaramillo (2014); South Africa: Inchauste et al. (2015). Note: Year of household survey in parenthesis. Data shown here is administrative data as reported by the studies cited above and the numbers do not necessarily coincide with those of the OECD databases (or other multilateral organizations). Gross National Income per capita on right axis is in 2011 PPP from World Development Indicators, July 10th, 2015: worldbank.org/indicator/ny.gnp.pcap.pp.cd *Chile only has a pay-as-you-go system for older workers and a fully funded system running since 1980 based on individual accounts. **For Indonesia, the fiscal incidence analysis was carried out adjusting for spatial price differences. This adjustment, however, does not affect figures on this figure. ***The only contributory pensions in South Africa are for public servants who must belong to the Government Employees Pension Fund; they were not included in the analysis for South Africa and are not shown here.

12 28 Nora Lustig pensions (which together comprise close to 1 percent of GDP), Brazil has another noncontributory program called Special Circumstances Pensions (that covers idiosyncratic shocks such as accident at work, sickness and other related shocks) to which it devotes 2.3 percent of GDP. In South Africa, the largest program is the noncontributory old-age pension (1.3 percent of GDP) followed by the child grant program (1.1 percent of GDP). On the other end of the spectrum are Indonesia and Peru, where direct transfers represent only 0.4 percent of GDP (in both cases). Peru allocates relatively little to income redistribution through its signature cash transfer Juntos. In the case of Indonesia, at the time of the survey (2012), the government allocated much more of its resources to energy subsidies (3.7 percent of GDP) than cash transfers (0.4 percent of GDP). On average, these seven countries spend 1.7 percent of GDP on direct transfers, 2.9 percent on pensions (includes contributory pensions only and not social pensions, which are part of direct transfers), 4.3 percent on education and 3.6 percent on health. Total social spending equals 13.9 percent of GDP. In comparison, the OECD countries (of which Chile and Mexico are members) on average spend 4.4 percent of GDP on direct transfers, 7.9 percent on pensions (includes contributory and social pensions), 5.3 percent on education and 6.2 percent on health. The average of total social spending is 26.7 percent of GDP, almost twice the average for the seven middle income countries. The largest difference occurs in direct transfers and contributory pensions. Direct transfers are almost three times as large, on average, in the OECD countries (even though the category does not include noncontributory pensions). 16 The revenue collection patterns, as shown in Panel B, are heterogeneous as well. Mexico relies heavily on nontax revenues (from the state-owned oil company), followed by Brazil and Peru. In general, indirect taxes are a larger share of GDP, except for South Africa. Given their size and structure of spending, Brazil and South Africa have the largest amount of resources at their disposal to engage in fiscal redistribution. At the other end of the spectrum are Colombia and Indonesia. Whether Brazil and South Africa achieve their higher redistributive potential, however, depends on how the burden of taxation and the benefits of social spending is distributed. This shall be discussed below. First, however, the next section presents a brief description of the fiscal incidence methodology utilized in the seven studies. 16 Figures for the seven countries are: Brazil (2009), Chile (2013), Colombia (2010), Indonesia (2012), Mexico (2010), Peru (2009) and South Africa (2010). OECD averages were provided by the organization itself and are for 2011.

13 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 29 4 Fiscal Incidence Analysis: Methodological Highlights 17 Fiscal incidence analysis is used to assess the distributional impacts of a country s taxes and transfers. Essentially, fiscal incidence analysis consists of allocating taxes (personal income tax and consumption taxes, in particular) and public spending (social spending in particular) to households or individuals so that one can compare incomes before taxes and transfers with incomes after taxes and transfers. 18 Transfers include both cash transfers and benefits in kind such as free government services in education and healthcare. Transfers also include consumption subsidies such as food, electricity and fuel subsidies. As with any fiscal incidence study, let s start by defining the basic income concepts. Here there are four: market, disposable, consumable and final income. 19 These income concepts are described below and summarized in Figure 4. Market income 20 is total current income before direct taxes, equal to the sum of gross (pre-tax) wages and salaries in the formal and informal sectors (also known as earned income), income from capital (dividends, interest, profits, rents, etc.) in the formal and informal sectors (excludes capital gains and gifts), consumption of own production, 21 imputed rent for owner occupied housing, and private transfers (remittances, pensions from private schemes and other private transfers such as alimony). Disposable income is defined as market income minus direct personal income taxes on all income sources (included in market income) that are subject to taxation plus direct government transfers (mainly cash transfers but can include near cash transfers such as food transfers, free textbooks and school uniforms). Consumable income is defined as disposable income plus indirect subsidies (e.g. food and energy price subsidies) minus indirect taxes (e.g. value added taxes, excise taxes, sales taxes, etc.). Final income is defined as consumable income plus government transfers in the form of free or subsidized services in education and health valued at average cost of provision 22 (minus co-payments or user fees, when they exist). 17 This section is based on Lustig and Higgins (2013). 18 In addition to the studies cited here and other studies in see, for example, Förster and Whiteford (2009), Immervoll and Richardson (2011) and OECD (2011). 19 In the case of Indonesia, the surveys do not have income data so the incidence analysis is based on assuming consumption equals disposable income. 20 Market income is sometimes called primary or original income. 21 Except in the case of South Africa, whose data on auto-consumption (also called own-production or self-consumption) was not considered reliable. 22 See, for example, Sahn and Younger (2000).

14 30 Nora Lustig Transfers Market income Wages and salaries, income from capital, private transfers (remittances, private pensions, etc.) before taxes, social security contributions and government transfers AND contributory social insurance old-age pensions ONLY in the case in which pensions are treated as deferred income Taxes Direct cash and near cash transfers: conditional and unconditional cash transfers, school feeding programs, free food transfers, etc. + Personal income taxes AND employee contributions to social security ONLY in the case that contributory pensions are treated as transfers Disposable income Indirect subsidies: energy, food and other general or targeted price subsidies + Indirect taxes: VAT, excise taxes and other indirect taxes Post-fiscal (or Consumable) In-kind transfers: free or subsidized government services in education and health + Final income Co-payments, user fees Figure 4: Basic income concepts. One area in which there is no clear consensus is how pensions from a pay-as-yougo contributory system should be treated. Arguments exist in favor of both treating contributory pensions as deferred income 23 or as a government transfer, especially in systems with a large subsidized component. 24 Since this is an unresolved issue, the studies analyzed here present results for both methods. One scenario treats 23 Breceda et al. (2008); Immervoll et al. (2009). 24 Goñi et al. (2011); Immervoll et al. (2009); Lindert et al. (2006).

15 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 31 social insurance contributory pensions (herewith called contributory pensions) as deferred income (which in practice means that they are added to market income to generate the original or pre-fisc income). The other scenario treats these pensions as any other cash transfer from the government. 25 For consistency, when pensions are treated as deferred income, the contributions by individuals are included under savings (they are mandatory savings) while when they are treated as government transfers, the contributions are considered a direct tax. It is important to note that the treatment of contributory pensions not only affects the amount of redistributive spending and how it gets redistributed, but also the ranking of households by original income or pre-fiscal income. For example, in the scenario in which contributory pensions are considered a government transfer, households whose main (or sole) source of income is pensions will have close to (or just) zero income before taxes and transfers and hence will be ranked at the bottom of the income scale. When contributory pensions are treated as deferred income, in contrast, households who receive contributory pensions will be placed at a (sometimes considerably) higher position in the income scale. Thus, the treatment of contributory pensions in the incidence exercise could have significant implications for the order of magnitude of the pre-fisc and postfisc inequality and poverty indicators. In the construction of final income, the method for education spending consists of imputing a value to the benefit accrued to an individual of going to public school which is equal to the per beneficiary input costs obtained from administrative data: for example, the average government expenditure per primary school student obtained from administrative data is allocated to the households based on how many children are reported attending public school at the primary level. In the case of health, the approach was analogous: the benefit of receiving healthcare in a public facility is equal to the average cost to the government of delivering healthcare services to the beneficiaries. In the case of Colombia, however, the method used was to impute the insurance value to beneficiary households rather than base the valuation on utilization of healthcare services. This approach to valuing education and healthcare services amounts to asking the following question: how much would the income of a household have to be increased if it had to pay for the free or subsidized public service (or the insurance value in the cases in which this applies to healthcare benefits) at the full cost to the government? Such an approach ignores the fact that consumers may value services quite differently from what they cost. Given the limitations of available data, however, the cost of provision method is the best one can do for 25 Immervoll et al. (2009) do the analysis under these two scenarios as well.

16 32 Nora Lustig now. 26 For the readers who think that attaching a value to education and health services based on government costs is not accurate, the method applied here is equivalent to using a simple binary indicator of whether or not the individual uses the government service. 27,28 The welfare indicator used in the fiscal incidence analysis is income per capita, 29 except for the case of Indonesia in which the welfare indicator was consumption-based (also in per capita) 30 In Indonesia, the method was to assume that disposable income equals consumption and market income was generated backwards applying a net to gross conversion. 31 Furthermore, the Indonesian survey does not include individuals with income levels beyond the threshold at which direct taxes begin to apply (see Afkar et al. 2016). In the data for South Africa, Free Basic Services are considered as direct transfers. 32 The only contributory pensions in South Africa are for public servants who must belong to the Government Employees Pension Fund (GEPF). Since the government made no transfers to the GEPF in 2010/2011, there is no scenario in which contributory pensions are treated as a transfer. Also, survey data on own-consumption (which is part of market income) were not considered reliable in the case of South Africa (see Inchauste et al. 2015). In Chile, only has a pay-as-you-go system for older workers and a fully funded system running since 1980 based on individual accounts (Martinez-Aguilar et al. 2016) By using averages, it also ignores differences across income groups and regions: e.g. governments may spend less (or more) per pupil or patient in poorer areas of a country. Some studies in the CEQ project adjusted for regional differences. For example, Brazil s health spending was based on regional specific averages. 27 This is of course only true within a level of education. A concentration coefficient for total non-tertiary education, for example, where the latter is calculated as the sum of the different spending amounts by level, is not equivalent to the binary indicator method. 28 In order to avoid exaggerating the effect of government services on inequality, the totals for education and health spending in the studies reported here were scaled-down so that their proportion to disposable income in the national accounts are the same as those observed using data from the household surveys. 29 No adjustments were made for household composition or economies of scale. For Brazil, Higgins and Lustig (2016) analyze the impact of taxes and transfers using equivalized income. 30 In Indonesia, the fiscal incidence analysis was carried out adjusting for spatial price differences because they are considered to be very large. 31 See, for example, Immervoll and O Donoghue (2001). 32 These Free Basic Services are delivered by municipal governments sometimes at zero cost and sometimes at a subsidized price. Given the difficulty in determining which case applies for households included in the survey, the analysis was carried out in both ways. Results in which the Free Basic Services are considered a subsidy are available upon request. 33 For details, see Lustig and Higgins (2013).

17 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 33 The fiscal incidence analysis used here is point-in-time and does not incorporate behavioral or general equilibrium effects. That is, no claim is made that the original or market income equals the true counter-factual income in the absence of taxes and transfers. It is a first-order approximation that measures the average incidence of fiscal interventions. However, the analysis is not a mechanically applied accounting exercise. The incidence of taxes is the economic rather than statutory incidence. It is assumed that individual income taxes and contributions both by employees and employers, for instance, are borne by labor in the formal sector. Individuals who are not contributing to social security are assumed to pay neither direct taxes nor contributions. Consumption taxes are fully shifted forward to consumers. In the case of consumption taxes, the analyses take into account the lower incidence associated with own-consumption, rural markets and informality. In general, fiscal incidence exercises are carried out using household surveys and this is what was done here. The surveys used in the country studies are the following: Brazil: Pesquisa de Orçamentos Familiares, 2009 (I); Chile: Encuesta de Caracterización Social (CASEN), 2013 (I); Colombia: Encuesta de Calidad de Vida, 2010 (I); Indonesia: Survei Sosial-Ekonomi Nasional, 2012 (C); Mexico: Encuesta Nacional de Ingreso y Gasto de los Hogares, 2010 (I); Peru: Encuesta Nacional de Hogares, 2009 (I); South Africa: Income and Expenditure Survey and National Income Dynamics Study, (I). The description of how each income concept was constructed and which assumptions were made in each country can be found in the following references: Brazil (Higgins and Pereira 2014), Chile (Martinez-Aguilar et al. 2016), Colombia (Lustig and Melendez 2015), Indonesia (Afkar et al. 2016), Mexico (Scott 2014), Peru (Jaramillo 2014) and South Africa (Inchauste et al. 2015) The Redistributive Effect of Fiscal Policy A typical indicator of the redistributive effect of fiscal policy is the difference between the market income Gini and the Gini for income after taxes and transfers. 35 If the redistributive effect is positive (negative), fiscal policy is equalizing (unequalizing). 34 Note that empirically one often starts from a concept different from market income. In many income-based surveys, reported income corresponds (or is assumed to be) market income net of direct taxes. In consumption-based surveys, there is often no reported income at all. In those cases, the incidence analysis assumed that consumption is equivalent to disposable income. 35 All the theoretical derivations that link changes in inequality to the progressivity of fiscal interventions have been derived based on the so-called family of S-Gini indicators, of which the Gini coefficient is one case. See for example, Duclos and Araar (2006). While one can calculate the impact of fiscal policy on inequality using other indicators (and one should), it will not be possible to link them to the progressivity of the interventions.

18 34 Nora Lustig Figure 5 presents the Gini coefficient for market income and the other three income concepts shown in Figure 4: disposable, consumable and final income. 36 In broad terms, disposable income measures how much income individuals may spend on goods and services (and save, including mandatory savings such as contributions to a public pensions system that is actuarially fair). Consumable income measures how much individuals are able to actually consume. For example, a given level of disposable income even if consumed in full could mean different levels of actual consumption depending on the size of indirect taxes and subsidies. Final income includes the value of public services in education and health if individuals would have had to pay for those services at the average cost to the government. Based on the fact that contributory pensions can be treated as deferred income or as a direct transfer, here all the calculations are presented for two scenarios: one with contributory pensions included in market income and another with them as government transfers. For consistency, remember that in the first scenario contributions to the system are treated as mandatory savings and in the second as a tax. As can be observed, in Colombia, Indonesia and Peru, fiscal income redistribution is quite limited while in South Africa and Brazil, it is of a relevant magnitude. Mexico is in the middle of these two groups. One can observe that South Africa is the country that redistributes the most but it still remains the most unequal of all seven. It is interesting to note that although Brazil and Colombia start out with similar market income inequality, Brazil reduces inequality considerably while Colombia does not. Similarly, Mexico, Chile and Peru start out with similar levels of market income inequality but Mexico and Chile reduce inequality by more. Indonesia is the less unequal of all seven and fiscal redistribution is also the smallest in order of magnitude. The largest change in inequality occurs between consumable and final income. This is not surprising given the fact that governments spend more on education and health than on direct transfers and pensions. However, one should not make sweeping conclusions from this result because as discussed above in-kind transfers are valued at average government cost which is not really a measure of the true value of these services to the individuals who use them. Panels A and B in Figure 5 show that the patterns of inequality decline are similar whether one looks at the scenario in which contributory pensions are considered deferred income (and, thus, part of market income) or with pensions as transfers. In Brazil and Colombia, and to a lesser extent in Indonesia, the redistributive effect is larger when pensions are treated as a transfer, while in Mexico and Peru it is somewhat lower. 36 Other measures of inequality such as the Theil index or the 90/10 ratio are available in the individual studies. Requests should be addressed directly to the authors.

19 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 35 A Market income Disposable income Consumable income Final income Brazil (2009) Chile* (2013) Colombia (2010) Indonesia** (2012) Mexico (2010) Peru (2009) South Africa*** (2010) B Market income Disposable income Consumable income Final income Brazil (2009) Chile* (2013) Colombia (2010) Indonesia** (2012) Mexico (2010) Peru (2009) Figure 5: Fiscal policy and inequality (Circa 2010): Gini coefficient for market, disposable, consumable and final income. Panel A: Contributory pensions as deferred income; Panel B: Contributory pensions as transfers. Source: Author s calculations based on Brazil: Higgins and Pereira (2014); Chile: Martinez- Aguilar et al. (2016); Colombia: Lustig and Melendez (2015); Indonesia: Afkar et al. (2016); Mexico: Scott (2014); Peru: Jaramillo (2014); South Africa: Inchauste et al. (2015). *Chile only has a pay-as-you-go system for older workers and a fully funded system running since 1980 based on individual accounts. Ginis for Chile are estimated using Total Income. Official figures of inequality are estimated using Monetary Income. **For Indonesia, the fiscal incidence analysis was carried out adjusting for spatial price differences. This adjustment, however, does not affect figures on this figure. ***The only contributory pensions in South Africa are for public servants who must belong to the Government Employees Pension Fund; they were not included in the analysis for South Africa and are not shown here. The scenario for South Africa assumed free basic services are direct transfers.

20 36 Nora Lustig Table 2: Gini coefficient for pre-pension and post-pension market income (Circa 2010). Brazil (2009) Chile* (2013) Colombia (2010) Indonesia** (2012) Mexico (2008) Peru (2009) South Africa*** (2010) Pension as % 9.06% 2.93% 3.14% 0.76% 2.58% 0.90% 0.97% GDP Gini market income w/o pensions Gini market income w/ pensions Change in % 3.6% 1.9% 0.8% 0.1% 0.4% 0.3% Change in ppts Source: Author s calculations based on Brazil: Higgins and Pereira (2014); Chile: Martinez- Aguilar et al. (2016); Colombia: Lustig and Melendez (2015); Indonesia: Afkar et al. (2016); Mexico: Scott (2014); Peru: Jaramillo (2014); South Africa: Inchauste et al. (2015). Year of household survey in parenthesis. *Chile only has a pay-as-you-go system for older workers and a fully funded system running since 1980 based on individual accounts. Ginis for Chile are estimated using Total Income. Official figures of inequality are estimated using Monetary Income. **For Indonesia, the fiscal incidence analysis was carried out adjusting for spatial price differences. ***The only contributory pensions in South Africa are for public servants who must belong to the Government Employees Pension Fund. Since the government made no transfers to the GEPF in 2010/2011, there is no scenario in which contributory pensions are treated as a transfer. The scenario for South Africa assumed free basic services are direct transfers. i. Are Contributory Pensions Equalizing or Unequalizing? One common question is whether contributory pensions are equalizing or unequalizing. Table 2 shows the Gini coefficients with market income with and without contributory pensions. As one can observe, contributory pensions are equalizing in Brazil, Chile and Indonesia and slightly unequalizing in Mexico, Peru and Colombia. 37 The fact that the pattern depends on the country is interesting. Statements such as pensions are regressive (by that meaning that they are unequalizing) are not universally true. ii. The redistributive effect of fiscal policy: do more unequal countries redistribute more? Income redistribution tends to be higher in more unequal countries to start with: redistribution is considerable higher in countries with higher market 37 Note that this is not equivalent to estimating the marginal contribution of pensions assuming all the other fiscal interventions are in place.

21 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries A 0.18 ZAF B 0.60 ZAF Redistributive effect 0.14 BRA COL PER 0.08 MEX 0.45 CHL 0.06 COL MEX BRA CHL 0.04 PER IDN IDN Gini market income Gini market income Gini final income Figure 6: Inequality and redistribution, Panel A: Redistribution and market income inequality; Panel B: Final income inequality and market income inequality. Source: Lustig (2015a). Note: Red line is the trends. Redistribution measures the difference between Gini of market and final incomes. *Chile only has a pay-as-you-go system for older workers and a fully funded system running since 1980 based on individual accounts. Ginis for Chile are estimated using Total Income. Official figures of inequality are estimated using Monetary Income. **For Indonesia, the fiscal incidence analysis was carried out adjusting for spatial price differences. ***The only contributory pensions in South Africa are for public servants who must belong to the Government Employees Pension Fund. Since the government made no transfers to the GEPF in 2010/2011, there is no scenario in which contributory pensions are treated as a transfer. The scenario for South Africa assumed free basic services are direct transfers. income inequality such as South Africa, Brazil, Mexico and Chile than in countries with relatively lower inequality, such as Indonesia and Peru (see Figure 6, Panel A). Among these countries, Colombia stands as an outlier with a rather low degree of redistribution given its high level of market income inequality. Previous studies also generally suggest a positive correlation between market income inequality and measures of redistribution. Lustig (2015b) finds this in an analysis for 13 developing countries. An OECD study (2011, Chapter 7) illustrates that more market income inequality tends to be associated with higher redistribution, for a sub-set of OECD countries, both within countries (over time) and across countries. Differences in redistribution change the relative ranking of countries by in equality level. Figure 6, Panel B displays the levels of income inequality before (horizontal axis) and after (vertical axis) accounting for fiscal policies. Fiscal policies reduce inequality in all countries and South Africa continues to be the most unequal country and Indonesia the least unequal country based on income

22 38 Nora Lustig Redistributive effect IDN PER MEX COL % 5% 10% 15% 20% 25% 30% CHL Social spending Figure 7: Redistribution and social spending, Source: Lustig (2015a). Note: Trend line in red. Social Spending includes all direct transfers, all pensions and spending on education and health. Data shown here is administrative data as reported by the studies of each country and the numbers do not necessarily coincide with those of the OECD databases (or other multilateral organizations). *Chile only has a pay-as-you-go system for older workers and a fully funded system running since 1980 based on individual accounts. Ginis for Chile are estimated using Total Income. Official figures of inequality are estimated using Monetary Income. **For Indonesia, the fiscal incidence analysis was carried out adjusting for spatial price differences. ***The only contributory pensions in South Africa are for public servants who must belong to the Government Employees Pension Fund. Since the government made no transfers to the GEPF in 2010/11, there is no scenario in which contributory pensions are treated as a transfer. The scenario for South Africa assumed free basic services are direct transfers. ZAF BRA before or after fiscal policy. However, due to lower redistribution, Colombia and Peru end up being more unequal than Brazil, Chile and Mexico, once fiscal policies are considered. As expected, the level of income redistribution and the size of the budget allocated to social spending (as a share of GDP) are associated. However, differences across countries suggest that institutional factors such as the composition and design of such policies and their interaction with socio-economic circumstances also affect the level of redistribution. Figure 7 presents the level of redistribution and social spending measured in the CEQ database. Redistribution is considerably larger in countries with high social spending, such as Brazil and South Africa, than in Colombia, Indonesia and Peru, where social spending is more limited. Given the level of social spending, income redistribution is particularly high in South Africa. iii. Redistributive Effect: A Comparison with Advanced Countries How do these seven middle income countries compare with the fiscal redistribution that occurs in advanced countries? Although the methodology is somewhat

23 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 39 different, one obvious comparator is the analysis produced by EUROMOD for the 27 countries in the European Union. 38 Given that EUROMOD covers only direct taxes, contributions to social security and direct transfers, the comparison can be done for the redistributive effect from market to disposable income. A comparison is also made with the United States. 39 There are three important differences between the advanced countries and the seven middle income ones analyzed here. First, market income inequality tends to be somewhat higher for the middle income countries. 40 However, the difference is most striking when pensions are treated as transfers. The average Gini coefficient for the seven middle income countries for the scenario in which pensions are treated as deferred income and the scenario in which they are considered transfers is 54.7 and 51.3 percent, respectively. In contrast, in the EU, the corresponding figures are 38.2 and 49.9 percent, respectively; and in the US, they are, 44.6 and 48.1, respectively. One important aspect to note, however, is that in the EU, pensions include both contributory and noncontributory social pensions while in the middle income countries and the US, the category of pensions includes only contributory pensions. If the latter would include noncontributory pensions as part of market income, the Gini would be lower. Second, as expected and shown in Figure 8, the redistributive effect is larger in the EU countries and, to a lesser extent, in the United States (except for South Africa, whose redistributive effect is larger than in the US when pensions are part of market income). In the seven middle income countries, whether pensions are treated as deferred income or a transfer makes a relatively small difference. This is not the case in the EU countries where the difference is huge. In the EU, the redistributive effect with contributory pensions as deferred income and contributory pensions as a transfer is 9.2 and 20.8 Gini points, respectively. In the United States, the numbers are less dramatically different: 7 and 10.9, respectively. In the seven middle income countries, the numbers are 2.6 and 2.3 Gini points, respectively. Clearly, the assumption made about how to treat incomes from pensions, again, makes a big difference. Third, in no European country nor in the United States, contributory pensions are unequalizing. On the contrary, vis-à-vis market income without pensions, they exert a large equalizing force in the EU and less so in the US. Using data for 2010, for example, the difference between the market income Gini and 38 The data for EU 27 is from EUROMOD statistics on Distribution and Decomposition of Disposable Income, accessed at using EUROMOD version no. G2.0. The year 2010 was used. 39 Higgins and Lustig (2016). 40 South Africa pulls the average up but Indonesia pulls it down.

24 40 Nora Lustig Redistributive effect: market to disposable Indonesia** (2012) Colombia (2010) Peru (2009) (Ranked by redistributive effect; Gini right hand scale) South Mexico Africa*** (2010) Brazil (2009) Chile* (2013) (2010) Seven countries USA**** (2011) EU (2010) Market income Gini Contributory pension as deferred income Market income Gini (contributory pensions as deferred income) Contributory pension as transfer 0.00 Market income Gini (contributory pensions as transfers) Figure 8: Redistributive effect: Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru, South Africa, Eu and The United States: Change in Gini points: market to disposable income; Circa (2010). Source: Author s calculations based on Brazil: Higgins and Pereira (2014); Chile: Martinez- Aguilar et al. (2016); Colombia: Lustig and Melendez (2015); European Union: EUROMOD statistics on Distribution and Decomposition of Disposable Income, accessed at ac.uk/euromod/statistics/ using EUROMOD version no. G2.0. Indonesia: Afkar et al. (2016); Mexico: Scott (2014); Peru: Jaramillo (2014); South Africa: Inchauste et al. (2015). United States: Higgins et al. (2015). Note: Year of household survey in parenthesis. For definition of income concepts see the Section on methodological highlights in text. *Ginis for Chile are estimated using Total Income. Official figures of inequality are estimated using Monetary Income. **For Indonesia, the fiscal incidence analysis was carried out adjusting for spatial price differences. ***The only contributory pensions in South Africa are for public servants who must belong to the Government Employees Pension Fund. Since the government made no transfers to the GEPF in 2010/2011, there is no scenario in which contributory pensions are treated as a transfer. The scenario for South Africa assumed free basic services are direct transfers. ****The Gini coefficients for the United States are for equivalized income. the market income Gini plus pensions is 11.6 percentage points in the EU and 3.5 in the United States. As we saw above, in the seven middle income countries pensions are not always equalizing. iv. Measuring the Contribution of Taxes and Transfers 41 Suppose one observes that fiscal policy has an equalizing effect. Can one measure the influence of specific taxes (direct vs. indirect, for example) or transfers (direct transfers vs. indirect subsidies or in-kind transfers, for example) on the 41 This section is based on Lustig et al. (forthcoming).

25 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 41 Table 3: Lambert s conundrum Total Original income x Tax liability t(x) Benefit level b(x) Post-benefit income Final income Source: Lambert (2001), Table 11.1: p observed result? 42 A fundamental question in the policy discussion is whether a particular fiscal intervention (or a particular combination of them) is equalizing or unequalizing. In a world with a single fiscal intervention (and no reranking), it is sufficient to know whether a particular intervention is progressive or regressive to give an unambiguous response using the typical indicators of progressivity such as the Kakwani index. 43 In a world with more than one fiscal intervention (even in the absence of reranking), this one-to-one relationship between the progressivity of a particular intervention and its effect on inequality breaks down. As Lambert (2001) so eloquently demonstrates it, depending on certain characteristics of the fiscal system, a regressive tax can exert an equalizing force over and above that which would prevail in the absence of that regressive tax. 44 An example borrowed from Lambert (2001, Table 11.1: p. 278) helps illustrate this point in the case of a regressive tax (Table 3). 45 The table below shows that taxes may be regressive in their original income and yet the net system may exhibit more progressivity than the progressive benefits alone. The redistributive effect for taxes only in this example is equal to , highlighting their regressivity. 46 Yet, the redistributive effect for the net fiscal system is 0.25, higher than the redis- 42 Note that the influence of specific interventions may not be equalizing, even if the overall effect of the net fiscal system is. 43 The Kakwani index for taxes is defined as the difference between the concentration coefficient of the tax and the Gini for market income. For transfers, it is defined as the difference between the Gini for market income and the concentration coefficient of the transfer. See, for example, Kakwani (1977). 44 See Lambert (2001), pp. 277 and 278. Also, for a derivation of all the mathematical conditions that can be used to determine when adding a regressive tax is equalizing or when adding a progressive transfer is unequalizing, see Lustig et al. (forthcoming). 45 Lambert (2001) The Distribution and Redistribution of Income. Third Edition. Manchester University Press. 46 Since there is no reranking, the R-S equals the difference between the Ginis before and after the fiscal intervention.

26 42 Nora Lustig tributive effect for benefits only equal to If taxes are regressive vis-à-vis the original income but progressive with respect to the less unequally distributed post-transfers income, regressive taxes exert an equalizing effect over and above the effect of progressive transfers. 47 Note that Lambert s conundrum is not equivalent to the well-known (and frequently repeated) result that efficient regressive taxes can be fine as long as, when combined with transfers, the net fiscal system is equalizing. 48 The surprising aspect of Lambert s conundrum is that a net fiscal system with a regressive tax (vis-à-vis market) is more equalizing than without it. 49 The implications of Lambert s conundrum 50 in real fiscal systems are quite profound. It means that in order to determine whether a particular intervention (or, a particular policy change) is inequality increasing or inequality reducing and by how much one must resort to numerical calculations that include the whole system. As Lambert mentions, his example is not altogether farfetched: 51 Two renowned studies in the 1980s found this type of result for the US and the UK. 52 It also made its appearance in a 1990s study for Chile. 53 In the present analysis, as shall be seen below, Lambert s conundrum is found for indirect taxes in the cases of Chile and to a smaller extent in South Africa. This counter-intuitive result is the consequence of path dependency: a particular tax can be regressive 47 Note that Lambert uses the term progressive and regressive differently than other authors in the theoretical and empirical incidence analysis literature. Thus, he calls regressive transfers that are equalizing. See definitions in earlier chapters of his book. 48 As Higgins and Lustig (2016) mention, efficient taxes that fall disproportionately on the poor, such as a noexemption value added tax, are often justified with the argument that spending instruments are available that are better targeted to the pursuit of equity concerns (Keen and Lockwood, 2010: p Similarly, Engel et al. (1999: p. 186) assert that it is quite obvious that the disadvantages of a proportional tax are moderated by adequate targeting of transfers, since what the poor individual pays in taxes is returned to her. Ebrill et al. (2001: p. 105) argue that a regressive tax might conceivably be the best way to finance pro-poor expenditures, with the net effect being to relieve poverty. 49 It can also be shown that if there is reranking, a pervasive feature of net tax systems in the real world, making a tax (or a transfer) more progressive can increase post-tax and transfers inequality. In Lambert s example, regressive taxes not only enhance the equalizing effect of transfers, but making taxes more progressive (i.e. more disproportional in the Kakwani sense) would result in higher(!) inequality; any additional change (towards more progressivity) in taxes or transfers would just cause reranking and an increase in inequality. 50 This is Lambert s choice of words (p. 278). 51 Quotes are from Lambert, op. cit., p O Higgins and Ruggles (1981) for the UK and Ruggles and O Higgins (1981) for the US. 53 Engel et al. (1999). Although the authors did not acknowledge this characteristic of the Chilean system in their article, in a recent interaction with the lead author, it was concluded that the Chilean system featured regressive albeit equalizing indirect taxes.

27 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 43 vis-à-vis market income but progressive vis-à-vis the income that would prevail if all the other fiscal interventions were already in place. There are several ways of calculating the contribution of a particular fiscal intervention to the change in inequality (or poverty) taking account of path dependency. The most commonly used in the literature are the marginal contribution and the sequential contribution. A less commonly used measure is the total average contribution. The total average contribution is calculated by considering all the possible paths and taking, for example, the so-called Shapley value. 54 The sequential contribution is calculated as the difference between inequality indicators with fiscal interventions ordered in a path according to their institutional design. 55 For example, if direct transfers are subject to taxation, the sequential contribution of personal income taxes is the difference between market income plus transfers and market income plus transfers and minus personal income taxes. The marginal contribution of a tax (or transfer) is calculated by taking the difference between the inequality indicator without the tax (or transfer) and with it. 56 For example, the marginal contribution of indirect taxes is the difference between the Gini for consumable income plus indirect taxes (i.e. consumable income without the indirect taxes) and consumable income. Given the uncertainties that surround choosing the correct institutional path, this paper uses the marginal contribution method. In addition, the marginal contribution has a straightforward policy interpretation because it is equivalent to asking the question: what would inequality be if the system did not have a particular tax (or transfer) or if a tax (or transfer) was modified? Would inequality be higher, the same or lower with the tax (or transfer) than without it? 57 Figure 9 shows the marginal contribution for four of the countries and for two net fiscal systems: from market to disposable income and from market to 54 For an analysis of the Shapley value and its properties see, for example, Shorrocks (2013). 55 OECD (2011) used this method, for example. 56 The marginal contribution should not be confused with the marginal incidence, the latter being the incidence of a small change in spending. The marginal contribution is not a derivative. Note that, because of path dependency, adding up the marginal contributions of each intervention will not be equal to the total change in inequality. Clearly, adding up the sequential contributions will not equal the total change in inequality either. An approach that has been suggested to calculate the contribution of each intervention in a way that they add up to the total change in inequality, is to use the Shapley value. The studies analyzed here do not have estimates for the latter. 57 Note that if certain fiscal interventions come in bundles (e.g. a tax that only kicks in if a certain transfer is in place), the marginal contribution can be calculated for the net tax (or the net benefit) in question.

28 44 Nora Lustig A 0.09 (Ranked by marginal contribution of direct transfers) Indonesia** (2012) Colombia (2010) Chile* (2013) South Africa*** (2010) 0.01 B Direct taxes Direct transfers Redistributive effect (Ranked by marginal contribution of direct transfers) Indonesia** (2012) Colombia (2010) Chile* (2013) South Africa*** (2010) Direct taxes Direct transfers Indirect taxes Indirect subsidies Redistributive effect

29 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 45 Figure 9: Marginal contribution of taxes and transfers (Circa 2010): pensions and market income. Panel A: Redistributive effect from market to disposable income; Panel B: Redistributive effect from market to consumable income. Source: Author s calculations based on Chile: Martinez-Aguilar et al. (2016); Colombia: Lustig and Melendez (2015); Indonesia: Afkar et al. (2016); South Africa: Inchauste et al. (2015). Note: The Redistributive Effect (Black dot) is measured in Gini points and equals the difference between market income Gini and disposable income Gini (panel A) and between market income Gini and consumable income Gini (panel B). The Marginal Contribution (bars) is measured in Gini points and equals the difference between the Gini coefficient with the intervention of interest (with all the others in place) and the Gini coefficient without it (with all the others in place). Fiscal interventions that do not apply to a certain country are left blank. *Chile only has a pay-as-you-go system for older workers and a fully funded system running since 1980 based on individual accounts. **The Indonesian survey does not include individuals beyond the income at which direct taxes begin to apply, this scenario uses a consumption based survey. ***The South Africa scenario assumes Free Basic Services as direct transfers. The fiscal incidence analysis for South Africa does not include a scenario with contributory pensions as transfers. consumable income. Both are presented because the existing fiscal redistribution studies frequently stop at direct taxes and direct transfers. 58 The numbers in this figure were calculated subtracting the Gini of disposable (consumable) income to the Gini of disposable (consumable) income without the particular fiscal intervention. Note that an equalizing (unequalizing) effect is presented with a positive (negative) sign. 59 The first result to note is that direct taxes and direct transfers are, as expected, always equalizing whether one calculates their marginal contribution with respect to disposable income or consumable income. 60 Direct transfers exert a particularly high equalizing force in South Africa. 61 The second result to note is that the marginal contribution of direct transfers is always higher than the marginal contribution of direct taxes. The third result 58 For example, the data published by EUROMOD, op cit. 59 Note that for the reasons mentioned in the paragraph immediately above, one cannot compare the orders of magnitude between categories of income. 60 Although not shown here, the same is true for in-kind transfers. These are not shown because the marginal contribution is identical to the sequential contribution presented in Figure 4.1 given that in-kind transfers are added at the end. 61 Note that one cannot compare orders of magnitude between interventions in an exact way because one drawback of the marginal contribution method is that the sum of all the marginal contributions is not equal to the total redistributive effect.

30 46 Nora Lustig to note is that the effect of indirect taxes is not always unequalizing. The marginal contribution is equalizing in the case of Chile and neutral in the case of South Africa. More interesting still is the fact that indirect taxes in Chile are regressive the Kakwani coefficients for indirect taxes is 0.03 and yet equalizing. That is, in this country one finds the counter-intuitive effect known as Lambert s conundrum: a regressive tax can be equalizing (or neutral). Finally, the fourth result to note is that indirect subsidies are equalizing or neutral. 6 Fiscal Policy and the Poor The above discussion has concentrated on the impact of fiscal policy on inequality. As important is the impact of fiscal policy on poverty. In particular, because the results not necessarily go in the same direction: i.e. an inequality reducing fiscal system could be poverty increasing. The effect of fiscal policy on poverty can be measured using the typical indicators such as the headcount ratio for market income and income after taxes and transfers. Another measure that one can use to assess the impact of fiscal policy on the poor is the extent to which market income poor end up being net payers to the fiscal system in cash terms (leaving out in-kind services). When both direct and indirect taxes are included and using the $2.50 ppp a day poverty line, 62 fiscal policy reduces the headcount ratio in Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru and South Africa (Figure 10). 63 However, there is a startling result. In the scenario in which pensions are considered deferred income, while Brazil s poverty rates declines as a result of direct transfers (not shown in the figure), the effect of consumption taxes is such that consumable income poverty is higher than market income poverty. This is clearly the consequence of its tax system in which basic foodstuff such as rice and beans end up being heavily taxed. 64 This is a worrisome result. Poverty should not be higher as a result of fiscal policy. Note that Brazil shows this feature despite the fact that the 62 The $2.50 ppp a day poverty line is considered to be a reasonable international extreme poverty line for middle-income countries: for example, in the case of Latin America, this poverty line is close to the average of the local extreme poverty lines. 63 Chile s result is particularly high because market income poverty is lower in Chile than in the other countries. Thus, a similar change in percentage points represents a large change when measured in percentage change as done in Figure 9 above. 64 See Higgins and Pereira (2014).

31 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 47 20% 10% 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% Brazil (2009) 8.1% 19.2% (Ranked by poverty reduction in %; poverty measured with $ PPP/day) Indonesia** South Africa*** (2012) Peru (2009) Colombia (2010) (2010) Mexico (2010) Chile* (2013) Seven countries 2.9% 3.7% 4.4% 6.1% 9.0% 14.6% 10.6% 15.1% 12.2% 20.0% 20.8% 51.8% 60.9% Contributory pensions as deferred income Contributory pensions as transfer Figure 10: Fiscal policy and poverty reduction (Circa 2010): change in headcount ratio from market to consumable income for contributory pensions as deferred income and as transfers; in %. Source: Author s calculations based on Brazil: Higgins and Pereira (2014); Chile: Martinez- Aguilar et al. (2016); Colombia: Lustig and Melendez (2015); Indonesia: Afkar et al. (2016); Mexico: Scott (2014); Peru: Jaramillo (2014); South Africa: Inchauste et al. (2015). Notes: Poverty is measured with the international poverty line of US$2.50 ppp/day (with the 2005 ppp). Countries are ranked by the change in poverty for the scenario where contributory pensions are treated as deferred income. *Chile only has a pay-as-you-go system for older workers and a fully funded system running since 1980 based on individual accounts. **Data for Indonesia is consumption-based and income-based for the rest. ***The South Africa scenario assumes Free Basic Services as direct transfers. The fiscal incidence analysis for South Africa does not include a scenario with contributory pensions as transfers, hence it is not shown above. net fiscal system (even without including in-kind transfers) reduces inequality. This emphasizes the fact that the impact of fiscal interventions on inequality and poverty should be studied separately. When analyzing the impact of fiscal interventions on living standards, it is useful to distinguish between the net benefits in cash from the benefits received in the form of free government services in education and health. The cash component is measured by consumable income. The level of consumable income will tell whether the government has enabled an individual to be able to purchase private goods and services above his or her original market income. In principle, it would be desirable for the poor especially the extreme poor to be net receivers of fiscal resources in cash so that poor individuals can buy/consume the minimum amounts of food and other essential goods imbedded in the selected poverty line. Figure 11 shows at which market income category, individuals on average become net payers to the fiscal system (again, this calculation only takes into account direct transfers in cash or near cash such as

32 48 Nora Lustig A Indonesia** (2012) Net receivers Net payers South Africa*** (2010) Chile* (2013) Mexico (2010) Brazil (2009) Peru (2009) y< y< y<4 4 y<10 10 y<50 y 50 B Net receivers Net payers Brazil (2009) Mexico (2010) Chile* (2013) Peru (2009) y< y< y<4 4 y<10 10 y<50 y 50 food). 65 In Brazil and Peru net payers to the fiscal system begin in the income category $US2.50 $US4/day in purchasing power parity. That is, in the group classified as moderately poor. In the case of South Africa, Chile and Mexico, the net 65 Note that this graph presents a nonanonymous result: it looks at the extent to which the market income poor become net payers to the fiscal system on average. This information cannot be extrapolated from the typical poverty measures where winners and losers are not tracked.

33 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 49 Figure 11: Net payers to the fiscal system (Circa 2010). Panel A: Contributory pensions as deferred income; Panel B: Contributory pensions as transfers. Source: Author s calculations based on Brazil: Higgins and Pereira (2014); Chile: Martinez- Aguilar et al. (2016); Colombia: Lustig and Melendez (2015); Indonesia: Afkar et al. (2016); Mexico: Scott (2014); Peru: Jaramillo (2014); South Africa: Inchauste et al. (2015). Note: Year of household survey in parenthesis. The income categories are based on López-Calva and Ortiz-Juárez (2014) and Ferreira et al. (2012). *Chile only has a pay-as-you-go system for older workers and a fully funded system running since 1980 based on individual accounts. **For Indonesia, the fiscal incidence analysis was carried out adjusting for spatial price differences. ***The results for South Africa are for the scenario in which Free Basic Services are considered a direct transfer. payers start in the group known as vulnerable. In Indonesia, only the rich are net payers to the fiscal system (on average). 66 If contributory pensions are considered a government transfer (not shown), net payers to fiscal system start in the middle class in Brazil, Chile and Mexico and in Peru, they start in the group named as moderately poor. 67 These results are the consequence of a variety of factors. In the case of Brazil, it is the consequence of consumption taxes on basic foodstuffs that wipe out the benefits from direct transfers such as Bolsa Familia for a considerable number of the market income poor. In the case of Indonesia, direct taxes start at income levels that are higher than the highest income in the survey and the indirect taxes are not high; in addition, the energy subsidies in Indonesia, although not targeted to the poor in particular, do help the poor as well as the vulnerable and middle-class groups. 7 Education and Health Spending 68 To what extent are the poor benefitting from government spending on education and health? The pro-poorness of public spending on education and health here is 66 These income categories are based on López-Calva and Ortiz-Juárez (2014) and Ferreira et al. (2012). 67 For Colombia and Peru, information for the case with pensions as government transfers is not available. The only contributory pensions in South Africa are for public servants who must belong to the Government Employees Pension Fund. Since the government made no transfers to the GEPF in 2010/2011, there is no scenario in which contributory pensions are treated as a transfer. 68 Section based on Lustig (2015b).

34 50 Nora Lustig measured using concentration coefficients (also called quasi-ginis). 69 In keeping with conventions, spending is defined as regressive whenever the concentration coefficient is higher than the Gini for market income. When this occurs, it means that the benefits from that spending as a share of market income tend to rise with market income. 70 Spending is progressive whenever the concentration coefficient is lower than the Gini for market income. This means that the benefits from that spending as a share of market income tend to fall with market income. Within progressive spending, spending is neutral in absolute terms spending per capita is the same across the income distribution whenever the concentration coefficient is equal to zero. Spending is defined as pro-poor whenever the concentration coefficient is not only lower than the Gini but also its value is negative. Pro-poor spending implies that the per capita government spending on the transfer tends to fall with market income. 71 Any time spending is pro-poor or neutral in absolute terms, by definition it is progressive. The converse, of course, is not true. 72 The taxonomy of transfers is synthesized in Figure 12. A clarification is in order. In the analysis presented here, households are ranked by per capita market income, and no adjustments are made to their size because of differences in the composition by age and gender. In some analyses, the pro-poorness of education spending, for example, is determined using children not all members of the household as the unit of analysis. Because poorer families have, on average, a larger number of children, the observation that concentration curves are pro-poor is a reflection of this fact. It does not mean that poorer families receive more resources per child. Figure 13 shows the market and final income Lorenz curves and the concentration curves for education and health spending for each country. Brazil and South Africa push the market income Lorenz curve outward (towards the diagonal) the 69 A concentration coefficient is calculated in a way analogous to the Gini coefficient. Let p be the cumulative proportion of the total population when individuals are ordered in increasing income values using market income, and let C(p) be the concentration curve, i.e. the cumulative proportion of total program benefits (of a particular program or aggregate category) received by the poorest p percent of the population. Then, the concentration coefficient of that program or category is defined as 2 1 ( p C( p)) dp I say tend because for global regressivity/progressivity to occur it is not a necessary condition for the share of the benefit to rise/fall at each and every income level. When the latter occurs, the benefit is regressive/progressive everywhere. Whenever a benefit is everywhere regressive/ progressive, it will be globally regressive/progressive, but the converse is not true. 71 This case is also sometimes called progressive in absolute terms. 72 As mentioned above, care must be taken not to infer that any spending that is progressive (regressive) will automatically be equalizing (unequalizing).

35 Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries 51 Progressivity of transfers: a diagrammatic representation 0 Cumulative share of income and transfers 1 Globally progressive transfer in absolute terms (pro-poor): per capita benefit declines with pretransfer income (not necessarily everywhere) Concentration curve lies above the diagonal Concentration coefficient < 0 Kakwani index > 0 Globally progressive transfer: benefit as a share of pre-transfer income declines with income (not necessarily everywhere) Concentration curve lies above pre-transfers Lorenz curve Concentration coefficient < Gini for pre-transfer income Kakwani Index > 0 Proportional transfer: benefit as a share of pre-transfer income is the same for everyone Concentration curve coincides with the pre-transfer Lorenz curve Concentration coefficient = Gini for pre-transfer income Kakwani index = 0 Transfer neutral in absolute terms: per capita benefit is equal for everyone. Concentration curve coincides with the diagonal Concentration coefficient = 0 Kakwani index > 0 Pre-transfer Lorenz curve Globally regressive transfer: benefit as a share of pre-transfer income increases with income (not necessarily everywhere) Concentration curve lies below market income Lorenz curve Concentration coefficient > Gini for pretransfer income Kakwani index < 0 0 Cumulative share of population (ordered by market income) 1 Figure 12: Progressivity of transfers. Source: Lustig et al. (forthcoming). most while Indonesia the least. 73 This result is driven primarily by the level of spending on education and health and its progressivity, as can be observed in Figure 14. Table 4 summarizes the results regarding the pro-poorness of government spending on education (total and by level) and health. Total spending on education is pro-poor in all countries for which there is data except for Indonesia, where it is (approximately) neutral in absolute terms. Pre-school tends to be pro-poor in all countries for which there is data, particularly so in South Africa. Primary school is pro-poor in all countries. For secondary school, is pro-poor in all countries for which there is data except for Indonesia, where it is (approximately) neutral in absolute terms. Government spending on tertiary education is regressive in Indonesia and progressive only in relative terms in various degrees in the rest. Compared with their respective levels of market income inequality, spending on tertiary education is most progressive in South Africa followed by Colombia and Chile. Health spending is progressive in only relative terms in Indonesia and Peru; roughly neutral in absolute terms in Mexico; and, pro-poor in Brazil, Chile and 73 The fact that South Africa stands out as the most redistributive is also a consequence of it being the country with the highest market income inequality. See, for example, Figure 7.2 in OECD (2011).

36 52 Nora Lustig Cumulative proportion of benefit Brazil (2009) 45 Degree line Market income Health Education Cumulative proportion of population Cumulative proportion of benefit Chile* (2013) 45 Degree line Market income Health Education Cumulative proportion of population Colombia (2010) Indonesia** (2012) Cumulative proportion of benefit Degree line Market income Health Education Cumulative proportion of population Cumulative proportion of benefit Degree line Market income Health Education Cumulative proportion of population Mexico (2010) Peru (2009) Cumulative proportion of benefit Degree line Market income Health Education Cumulative proportion of population Cumulative proportion of benefit Degree line Market income Health Education Cumulative proportion of population South Africa*** (2010) Cumulative proportion of benefit Degree line Market income Health Education Cumulative proportion of population Figure 13: Lorenz curves for market and final income and concentration curves for education and health (Circa 2010). Source: Author s calculations based on Brazil: Higgins and Pereira (2014); Chile: Martinez- Aguilar et al. (2016); Colombia: Lustig and Melendez (2015); Indonesia: Afkar et al. (2016); Mexico: Scott (2014); Peru: Jaramillo (2014); South Africa: Inchauste et al. (2015). Note: Year of household survey next to name. *Chile only has a pay-as-you-go system for older workers and a fully funded system running since 1980 based on individual accounts. **The Indonesian survey does not include individuals beyond the income at which direct taxes begin to apply; this scenario uses a consumption-based survey. ***The scenario for South Africa assumed free basic services are direct transfers.

Abstract. Keywords: fiscal incidence, social spending, inequality, developing countries

Abstract. Keywords: fiscal incidence, social spending, inequality, developing countries INEQUALITY AND FISCAL REDISTRIBUTION IN MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES BRAZIL, CHILE, COLOMBIA, INDONESIA, MEXICO, PERU AND SOUTH AFRICA * Nora Lustig (nlustig@tulane.edu) ** CEQ Working Paper No. 31 July 1,

More information

Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries: Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru and South Africa

Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries: Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru and South Africa Tulane Economics Working Paper Series Inequality and Fiscal Redistribution in Middle Income Countries: Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru and South Africa Nora Lustig Department of Economics

More information

INEQUALITY AND FISCAL REDISTRIBUTION IN MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES: BRAZIL, CHILE, COLOMBIA, INDONESIA, MEXICO, PERU AND SOUTH AFRICA

INEQUALITY AND FISCAL REDISTRIBUTION IN MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES: BRAZIL, CHILE, COLOMBIA, INDONESIA, MEXICO, PERU AND SOUTH AFRICA INEQUALITY AND FISCAL REDISTRIBUTION IN MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES: BRAZIL, CHILE, COLOMBIA, INDONESIA, MEXICO, PERU AND SOUTH AFRICA Nora Lustig Working Paper 31 October 2015 1 The CEQ Working Paper Series

More information

WIDER Working Paper 2016/164. Fiscal policy, inequality, and the poor in the developing world. Nora Lustig*

WIDER Working Paper 2016/164. Fiscal policy, inequality, and the poor in the developing world. Nora Lustig* WIDER Working Paper 2016/164 Fiscal policy, inequality, and the poor in the developing world Nora Lustig* December 2016 Abstract: Using comparable fiscal incidence analysis, this paper examines the impact

More information

Fiscal Policy, Inequality and the Poor in the Developing World

Fiscal Policy, Inequality and the Poor in the Developing World Fiscal Policy, Inequality and the Poor in the Developing World Nora Lustig Abstract Using comparable fiscal incidence analysis, this paper examines the impact of fiscal policy on inequality and poverty

More information

FISCAL POLICY, INEQUALITY AND THE POOR IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD

FISCAL POLICY, INEQUALITY AND THE POOR IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD FISCAL POLICY, INEQUALITY AND THE POOR IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD Nora Lustig Working Paper 23 October 2016 (Revised July 2017) 1 The CEQ Working Paper Series The CEQ Institute at Tulane University works

More information

Fiscal Policy, Inequality and the Poor in the Developing World

Fiscal Policy, Inequality and the Poor in the Developing World Tulane Economics Working Paper Series Fiscal Policy, Inequality and the Poor in the Developing World Nora Lustig Department of Economics Tulane University nlustig@tulane.edu Working Paper 1612 Original

More information

WIDER Working Paper 2016/164, revised version May Fiscal policy, inequality, and the poor in the developing world.

WIDER Working Paper 2016/164, revised version May Fiscal policy, inequality, and the poor in the developing world. WIDER Working Paper 2016/164, revised version May 2017 Fiscal policy, inequality, and the poor in the developing world Nora Lustig * May 2017 Abstract: Using comparable fiscal incidence analysis, this

More information

FISCAL POLICY, INCOME REDISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY REDUCTION IN LOW AND MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES

FISCAL POLICY, INCOME REDISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY REDUCTION IN LOW AND MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES FISCAL POLICY, INCOME REDISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY REDUCTION IN LOW AND MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES Nora Lustig Working Paper 54 January 2017 (Revised June 2017) 1 The CEQ Working Paper Series The CEQ Institute

More information

econstor Make Your Publications Visible.

econstor Make Your Publications Visible. econstor Make Your Publications Visible. A Service of Wirtschaft Centre zbwleibniz-informationszentrum Economics Lustig, Nora Working Paper Fiscal policy, inequality, and the poor in the developing world

More information

Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution and Poverty Reduction in Low and Middle Income Countries. 1. Nora Lustig 2. Version: October 31, 2016

Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution and Poverty Reduction in Low and Middle Income Countries. 1. Nora Lustig 2. Version: October 31, 2016 1 Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution and Poverty Reduction in Low and Middle Income Countries. 1 Introduction Nora Lustig 2 Version: October 31, 2016 Chapter 9 Lustig, Nora, editor Commitment to Equity

More information

Declining Inequality in Latin America: Labor Markets & Redistributive Policies

Declining Inequality in Latin America: Labor Markets & Redistributive Policies Declining Inequality in Latin America: Labor Markets & Redistributive Policies Nora Lustig Tulane University New Challenges for Growth and Productivity The Growth Dialogue G24 Washington, DC -- September

More information

Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution and Poverty Reduction in Low and Middle Income Countries

Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution and Poverty Reduction in Low and Middle Income Countries Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution and Poverty Reduction in Low and Middle Income Countries Nora Lustig Abstract Current policy discussion focuses primarily on the power of fiscal policy to reduce inequality.

More information

Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality

Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality Francesca Bastagli Overseas Development Institute Taxation & Developing Countries (a PEAKS training course) 16 September 2013 Overview Trends in income inequality The

More information

Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution and Poverty Reduction in Low and Middle Income Countries. 1. Nora Lustig 2. June 5, 2017

Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution and Poverty Reduction in Low and Middle Income Countries. 1. Nora Lustig 2. June 5, 2017 Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution and Poverty Reduction in Low and Middle Income Countries. 1 Introduction Nora Lustig 2 June 5, 2017 Chapter 9 Lustig, Nora, editor Commitment to Equity Handbook A Guide

More information

Argentina Bahamas Barbados Bermuda Bolivia Brazil British Virgin Islands Canada Cayman Islands Chile

Argentina Bahamas Barbados Bermuda Bolivia Brazil British Virgin Islands Canada Cayman Islands Chile Americas Argentina (Banking and finance; Capital markets: Debt; Capital markets: Equity; M&A; Project Bahamas (Financial and corporate) Barbados (Financial and corporate) Bermuda (Financial and corporate)

More information

Comparing Taxation, Transfers, and Redistribution in Brazil and the United States

Comparing Taxation, Transfers, and Redistribution in Brazil and the United States Comparing Taxation, Transfers, and Redistribution in Brazil and the United States Sean Higgins Nora Lustig Whitney Ruble Tulane University Timothy Smeeding University of Wisconsin at Madison Commitment

More information

SESSION 8 Fiscal Incidence in South Africa

SESSION 8 Fiscal Incidence in South Africa DG DEVCO Staff Seminar on Social Protection - from strategies to concrete approaches - 26-30 September 2016, Brussels SESSION 8 Fiscal Incidence in South Africa Jon JELLEMA Associate Director for Africa,

More information

Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution, and Poverty Reduction in Low- and Middle-Income Countries 1

Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution, and Poverty Reduction in Low- and Middle-Income Countries 1 Fiscal Policy, Income Redistribution, and Poverty Reduction in Low- and Middle-Income Countries 1 Nora Lustig 2 May 2018 Abstract Using comparative fiscal incidence analysis, this paper examines the impact

More information

ANNEX 2: Methodology and data of the Starting a Foreign Investment indicators

ANNEX 2: Methodology and data of the Starting a Foreign Investment indicators ANNEX 2: Methodology and data of the Starting a Foreign Investment indicators Methodology The Starting a Foreign Investment indicators quantify several aspects of business establishment regimes important

More information

Scale of Assessment of Members' Contributions for 2008

Scale of Assessment of Members' Contributions for 2008 General Conference GC(51)/21 Date: 28 August 2007 General Distribution Original: English Fifty-first regular session Item 13 of the provisional agenda (GC(51)/1) Scale of Assessment of s' Contributions

More information

Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law

Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law Laurence Ball Johns Hopkins University Global Labor Markets Workshop Paris, September 1-2, 2016 1 What the paper does and why Provides estimates

More information

TRENDS AND MARKERS Signatories to the United Nations Convention against Transnational Organised Crime

TRENDS AND MARKERS Signatories to the United Nations Convention against Transnational Organised Crime A F R I C A WA T C H TRENDS AND MARKERS Signatories to the United Nations Convention against Transnational Organised Crime Afghanistan Albania Algeria Andorra Angola Antigua and Barbuda Argentina Armenia

More information

Dutch tax treaty overview Q3, 2012

Dutch tax treaty overview Q3, 2012 Dutch tax treaty overview Q3, 2012 Hendrik van Duijn DTS Duijn's Tax Solutions Zuidplein 36 (WTC Tower H) 1077 XV Amsterdam The Netherlands T +31 888 387 669 T +31 888 DTS NOW F +31 88 8 387 601 duijn@duijntax.com

More information

Fiscal Policy Incidence on Inequality and Poverty in Low- and Middle-Income Countries 1

Fiscal Policy Incidence on Inequality and Poverty in Low- and Middle-Income Countries 1 Fiscal Policy Incidence on Inequality and Poverty in Low- and Middle-Income Countries 1 Working Paper commissioned by the Group of 24 and Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung New York January 2019 Nora Lustig and

More information

Domestic Resource Mobilization and the Poor

Domestic Resource Mobilization and the Poor BACKGROUND PAPER GOVERNANCE and THE LAW Domestic Resource Mobilization and the Poor Nora Lustig Tulane University Disclaimer This background paper was prepared for the World Development Report 2017 Governance

More information

Linking Education for Eurostat- OECD Countries to Other ICP Regions

Linking Education for Eurostat- OECD Countries to Other ICP Regions International Comparison Program [05.01] Linking Education for Eurostat- OECD Countries to Other ICP Regions Francette Koechlin and Paulus Konijn 8 th Technical Advisory Group Meeting May 20-21, 2013 Washington

More information

Clinical Trials Insurance

Clinical Trials Insurance Allianz Global Corporate & Specialty Clinical Trials Insurance Global solutions for clinical trials liability Specialist cover for clinical research The challenges of international clinical research are

More information

Dutch tax treaty overview Q4, 2013

Dutch tax treaty overview Q4, 2013 Dutch tax treaty overview Q4, 2013 Hendrik van Duijn DTS Duijn's Tax Solutions Zuidplein 36 (WTC Tower H) 1077 XV Amsterdam The Netherlands T +31 888 387 669 T +31 888 DTS NOW F +31 88 8 387 601 duijn@duijntax.com

More information

Index. tax evasion ethics in tax system change in Bureaucracy 3-11 Canada

Index. tax evasion ethics in tax system change in Bureaucracy 3-11 Canada Ability to pay principle 58 Administrative burden 51-79, 73-90, 430 Albania 112 Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT) 75 Anti-capitalistic mentality 318 Appeals in Armenia 317 Argentina 281-308 Armenia 113, 309-358

More information

Index of Financial Inclusion. (A concept note)

Index of Financial Inclusion. (A concept note) Index of Financial Inclusion (A concept note) Mandira Sarma Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations Core 6A, 4th Floor, India Habitat Centre, Delhi 100003 Email: mandira@icrier.res.in

More information

Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide Out-of-sample results based on IMF s new Global Debt Database

Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide Out-of-sample results based on IMF s new Global Debt Database Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide Out-of-sample results based on IMF s new Global Debt Database Atif Mian Princeton University and NBER Amir Sufi University of Chicago Booth School of Business

More information

Fiscal Incidence Analysis in Theory and Practice Nora Lustig Tulane University Nonresident Fellow CGD and IAD

Fiscal Incidence Analysis in Theory and Practice Nora Lustig Tulane University Nonresident Fellow CGD and IAD Fiscal Incidence Analysis in Theory and Practice Nora Lustig Tulane University Nonresident Fellow CGD and IAD Workshop The Distributional Impact of Fiscal Policy The World Bank and Tulane University Washington,

More information

SHARE IN OUR FUTURE AN ADVENTURE IN EMPLOYEE STOCK OWNERSHIP DEBBI MARCUS, UNILEVER

SHARE IN OUR FUTURE AN ADVENTURE IN EMPLOYEE STOCK OWNERSHIP DEBBI MARCUS, UNILEVER SHARE IN OUR FUTURE AN ADVENTURE IN EMPLOYEE STOCK OWNERSHIP DEBBI MARCUS, UNILEVER DEBBI.MARCUS@UNILEVER.COM RUTGERS SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT AND LABOR RELATIONS NJ/NY CENTER FOR EMPLOYEE OWNERSHIP AGENDA

More information

SURVEY TO DETERMINE THE PERCENTAGE OF NATIONAL REVENUE REPRESENTED BY CUSTOMS DUTIES INTRODUCTION

SURVEY TO DETERMINE THE PERCENTAGE OF NATIONAL REVENUE REPRESENTED BY CUSTOMS DUTIES INTRODUCTION SURVEY TO DETERMINE THE PERCENTAGE OF NATIONAL REVENUE REPRESENTED BY CUSTOMS DUTIES INTRODUCTION This publication provides information about the share of national revenues represented by Customs duties.

More information

HEALTH WEALTH CAREER 2017 WORLDWIDE BENEFIT & EMPLOYMENT GUIDELINES

HEALTH WEALTH CAREER 2017 WORLDWIDE BENEFIT & EMPLOYMENT GUIDELINES HEALTH WEALTH CAREER 2017 WORLDWIDE BENEFIT & EMPLOYMENT GUIDELINES WORLDWIDE BENEFIT & EMPLOYMENT GUIDELINES AT A GLANCE GEOGRAPHY 77 COUNTRIES COVERED 5 REGIONS Americas Asia Pacific Central & Eastern

More information

WHAT WILL IT TAKE TO ERADICATE EXTREME POVERTY AND PROMOTE SHARED PROSPERITY?

WHAT WILL IT TAKE TO ERADICATE EXTREME POVERTY AND PROMOTE SHARED PROSPERITY? WHAT WILL IT TAKE TO ERADICATE EXTREME POVERTY AND PROMOTE SHARED PROSPERITY? Pathways to poverty reduction and inclusive growth Ana Revenga Senior Director Poverty and Equity Global Practice February

More information

Request to accept inclusive insurance P6L or EASY Pauschal

Request to accept inclusive insurance P6L or EASY Pauschal 5002001020 page 1 of 7 Request to accept inclusive insurance P6L or EASY Pauschal APPLICANT (INSURANCE POLICY HOLDER) Full company name and address WE ARE APPLYING FOR COVER PRIOR TO DELIVERY (PRE-SHIPMENT

More information

Taxation, Transfers, and Redistribution Brazil and the United States

Taxation, Transfers, and Redistribution Brazil and the United States Taxation, Transfers, and Redistribution Brazil and the United States Nora Lus)g Tulane University Nonresident Fellow CGD and IAD Presented at Sustainable Growth in the XXIst Century, Ins)tute for New Economic

More information

International Trade: Mainstream and Heterodox Perspectives

International Trade: Mainstream and Heterodox Perspectives International Trade: Mainstream and Heterodox Perspectives Anwar Shaikh New School for Social Research Department of Economics Homepage: http://homepage.newschool.edu/~ashaikh/ Trade and Gender 1. Standard

More information

Fiscal Policy and the Ethno- Racial Divide: Bolivia, Brazil and Uruguay

Fiscal Policy and the Ethno- Racial Divide: Bolivia, Brazil and Uruguay Fiscal Policy and the Ethno- Racial Divide: Bolivia, Brazil and Uruguay Nora Lustig Tulane University Inter-American Development Bank Washington, DC, November 21, 2013 Commitment to Equity (CEQ) www.commitmentoequity.org

More information

International Economic Outlook

International Economic Outlook International Monetary Fund September 9, 16 International Economic Outlook Alejandro Werner Director Western Hemisphere Department 1 Global and Regional Developments Relevant Issues Global and Regional

More information

AN APPLICATION OF THE CEQ EFFECTIVENESS INDICATORS: THE CASE OF IRAN

AN APPLICATION OF THE CEQ EFFECTIVENESS INDICATORS: THE CASE OF IRAN AN APPLICATION OF THE CEQ EFFECTIVENESS INDICATORS: THE CASE OF IRAN Ali Enami Working Paper 58 November 2016 (Revised July 2017) 1 The CEQ Working Paper Series The CEQ Institute at Tulane University works

More information

Pros and Cons of BITs for Developing Countries

Pros and Cons of BITs for Developing Countries Pros and Cons of BITs for Developing Countries Manuel F Montes Institute of Policy Studies Colombo, 7 November 2016 PROS PROS o Developing countries need for foreign investment o BITs as ONE strategy CONS

More information

JPMorgan Funds statistics report: Emerging Markets Debt Fund

JPMorgan Funds statistics report: Emerging Markets Debt Fund NOT FDIC INSURED NO BANK GUARANTEE MAY LOSE VALUE JPMorgan Funds statistics report: Emerging Markets Debt Fund Data as of November 30, 2016 Must be preceded or accompanied by a prospectus. jpmorganfunds.com

More information

KPMG s Individual Income Tax and Social Security Rate Survey 2009 TAX

KPMG s Individual Income Tax and Social Security Rate Survey 2009 TAX KPMG s Individual Income Tax and Social Security Rate Survey 2009 TAX B KPMG s Individual Income Tax and Social Security Rate Survey 2009 KPMG s Individual Income Tax and Social Security Rate Survey 2009

More information

Current Issues in International Tax Policy

Current Issues in International Tax Policy Current Issues in International Tax Policy Shigeto HIKI Director, International Tax Policy Division, Tax Bureau, Ministry of Finance, Japan The Fourth IMF-Japan High-Level Tax Conference For Asian Countries

More information

Trends, like horses, are easier to ride in the direction they are going

Trends, like horses, are easier to ride in the direction they are going 2050 Hindsight. Trends, like horses, are easier to ride in the direction they are going - John Naisbitt, Megatrends, 1982 CFA Society San Diego Lawrence Speidell Chief Investment Officer, CEO Frontier

More information

GLOBAL INEQUALITY AND AUSTRALIA S ROLE

GLOBAL INEQUALITY AND AUSTRALIA S ROLE GLOBAL INEQUALITY AND AUSTRALIA S ROLE PRESENTATION TO A RECEPTION HOSTED BY OXFAM AUSTRALIA GOVERNMENT HOUSE, HOBART, TASMANIA 29 TH MAY 217 The good news: global poverty has fallen by almost 6% over

More information

Voice and Governance Reform in the BWIs An Update. Amar Bhattacharya G24 Secretariat May 26, 2010

Voice and Governance Reform in the BWIs An Update. Amar Bhattacharya G24 Secretariat May 26, 2010 Voice and Governance Reform in the BWIs An Update Amar Bhattacharya G24 Secretariat May 26, 2010 Total Votes for Developed and Developing Countries in Shares 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 IMF IBRD AsDB IADB Developed

More information

The world of CARE. 2 CARE Facts & Figures

The world of CARE. 2 CARE Facts & Figures CARE Facts & Figures 2004 The world of CARE 2 CARE Facts & Figures 2003 www.care.org 71 Australia 75 France 79 Norway CARE International Member countries: 72 Austria 73 Canada 76 Germany 77 Japan 80 Thailand

More information

Doing Business Smarter Regulations for Small and Medium-sized Enterprises. Augusto Lopez-Claros

Doing Business Smarter Regulations for Small and Medium-sized Enterprises. Augusto Lopez-Claros Doing Business 2013 Smarter Regulations for Small and Medium-sized Enterprises Augusto Lopez-Claros alopezclaros@ifc.org December 2012 1 Pace of reforms remains strong in 2011/12: share of economies with

More information

Note on Revisions. Investing Across Borders 2010 Report

Note on Revisions. Investing Across Borders 2010 Report Note on Revisions Last revision: August 30, 2011 Investing Across Borders 2010 Report This note documents all data and revisions to the Investing Across Borders (IAB) 2010 report since its release on July

More information

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary Social Situation Monitor - Glossary Active labour market policies Measures aimed at improving recipients prospects of finding gainful employment or increasing their earnings capacity or, in the case of

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 3/7/2018 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 01/2017 01/2018 % Change 2017 2018 % Change MEXICO 54,235,419 58,937,856 8.7 % 54,235,419 58,937,856 8.7 % NETHERLANDS 12,265,935 10,356,183

More information

Overview of FSC-certified forests January January Maps of extend of FSC-certified forest globally and country specific

Overview of FSC-certified forests January January Maps of extend of FSC-certified forest globally and country specific Overview of FSCcertified forests January 2009 Maps of extend of FSCcertified forest globally and country specific Global certified forest area: 120.052.350 ha ( = 4,3%) + 11% Hectare FSCcertified forest

More information

Summary 715 SUMMARY. Minimum Legal Fee Schedule. Loser Pays Statute. Prohibition Against Legal Advertising / Soliciting of Pro bono

Summary 715 SUMMARY. Minimum Legal Fee Schedule. Loser Pays Statute. Prohibition Against Legal Advertising / Soliciting of Pro bono Summary Country Fee Aid Angola No No No Argentina No, with No No No Armenia, with No No No No, however the foreign Attorneys need to be registered at the Chamber of Advocates to be able to practice attorney

More information

Appendix. Table S1: Construct Validity Tests for StateHist

Appendix. Table S1: Construct Validity Tests for StateHist Appendix Table S1: Construct Validity Tests for StateHist (5) (6) Roads Water Hospitals Doctors Mort5 LifeExp GDP/cap 60 4.24 6.72** 0.53* 0.67** 24.37** 6.97** (2.73) (1.59) (0.22) (0.09) (4.72) (0.85)

More information

Global Assessment of Environmental-Economic Accounting and Supporting Statistics

Global Assessment of Environmental-Economic Accounting and Supporting Statistics Global Assessment of Environmental-Economic Accounting and Supporting Statistics Additional analysis Version 3.0 THE SOUTH AFRICA I KNOW, THE HOME I UNDERSTAND Contents Abbreviations and acronyms Figures

More information

The Inclusive Development Index 2018 Summary and Data Highlights

The Inclusive Development Index 2018 Summary and Data Highlights The Inclusive Development Index 2018 Summary and Data Highlights Slow progress in living standards and widening inequality have contributed to political polarization and erosion of social cohesion in many

More information

Leaving no one behind measurement issues

Leaving no one behind measurement issues Leaving no one behind measurement issues Patricia Conboy, Head of Global Ageing, Advocacy, Campaigning, HelpAge International Expert Group Meeting, Measuring population ageing: Bridging research and policy

More information

Fiscal Policy and Redistribution in Latin America

Fiscal Policy and Redistribution in Latin America Fiscal Policy and Redistribution in Latin America Nora Lustig Tulane University LACEA-LAMES Colegio de Mexico Mexico City, Oct 31, 2013 1 Commitment to Equity (CEQ), joint project of Tulane University

More information

The ILO Social Security Inquiry SSI

The ILO Social Security Inquiry SSI Steve Brandon The ILO Social Security Inquiry SSI Florence Bonnet Social Security Department International Labour Office (ILO) The Social Security Inquiry Outline Why Main objective and rationale What

More information

THE IMPACT OF REFORMING ENERGY SUBSIDIES, CASH TRANSFERS, AND TAXES ON INEQUALITY AND POVERTY IN GHANA AND TANZANIA

THE IMPACT OF REFORMING ENERGY SUBSIDIES, CASH TRANSFERS, AND TAXES ON INEQUALITY AND POVERTY IN GHANA AND TANZANIA THE IMPACT OF REFORMING ENERGY SUBSIDIES, CASH TRANSFERS, AND TAXES ON INEQUALITY AND POVERTY IN GHANA AND TANZANIA Stephen D. Younger Working Paper 55 November 2016 (Revised June 2017) 1 The CEQ Working

More information

Juan Pablo Jiménez Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean

Juan Pablo Jiménez Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean Juan Pablo Jiménez Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean ITC-Workshop How to Operationalize the International Tax and Development Agenda 12-14 September 2011 Bonn, Germany I. Diagnosis

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 7/6/2018 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 05/2017 05/2018 % Change 2017 2018 % Change MEXICO 71,166,360 74,896,922 5.2 % 302,626,505 328,397,135 8.5 % NETHERLANDS 12,039,171 13,341,929

More information

YUM! Brands, Inc. Historical Financial Summary. Second Quarter, 2017

YUM! Brands, Inc. Historical Financial Summary. Second Quarter, 2017 YUM! Brands, Inc. Historical Financial Summary Second Quarter, 2017 YUM! Brands, Inc. Consolidated Statements of Income (in millions, except per share amounts) 2017 2016 2015 YTD Q3 Q4 FY FY Revenues Company

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 11/2/2018 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 09/2017 09/2018 % Change 2017 2018 % Change MEXICO 49,299,573 57,635,840 16.9 % 552,428,635 601,679,687 8.9 % NETHERLANDS 11,656,759 13,024,144

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 4/5/2018 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 02/2017 02/2018 % Change 2017 2018 % Change MEXICO 53,961,589 55,268,981 2.4 % 108,197,008 114,206,836 5.6 % NETHERLANDS 12,804,152 11,235,029

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 10/5/2018 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 08/2017 08/2018 % Change 2017 2018 % Change MEXICO 67,180,788 71,483,563 6.4 % 503,129,061 544,043,847 8.1 % NETHERLANDS 12,954,789 12,582,508

More information

THE ICSID CASELOAD STATISTICS (ISSUE )

THE ICSID CASELOAD STATISTICS (ISSUE ) THE ICSID CASELOAD STATISTICS (ISSUE 03-) The ICSID Caseload Statistics (Issue 03-) This issue of the ICSID Caseload Statistics updates the profile of the ICSID caseload, historically and for the Centre

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 3/6/2019 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 12/2017 12/2018 % Change 2017 2018 % Change MEXICO 54,169,734 56,505,154 4.3 % 712,020,884 773,421,634 8.6 % NETHERLANDS 11,037,475 8,403,018

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 12/6/2018 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 10/2017 10/2018 % Change 2017 2018 % Change MEXICO 56,462,606 60,951,402 8.0 % 608,891,240 662,631,088 8.8 % NETHERLANDS 11,381,432 10,220,226

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 2/6/2019 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 11/2017 11/2018 % Change 2017 2018 % Change MEXICO 48,959,909 54,285,392 10.9 % 657,851,150 716,916,480 9.0 % NETHERLANDS 11,903,919 10,024,814

More information

ide: FRANCE Appendix A Countries with Double Taxation Agreement with France

ide: FRANCE Appendix A Countries with Double Taxation Agreement with France Fiscal operational guide: FRANCE ide: FRANCE Appendix A Countries with Double Taxation Agreement with France Albania Algeria Argentina Armenia 2006 2006 From 1 March 1981 2002 1 1 1 All persons 1 Legal

More information

Taxes, Transfers, Inequality, and Poverty: Argen9na, Bolivia, Brazil, Mexico, and Peru

Taxes, Transfers, Inequality, and Poverty: Argen9na, Bolivia, Brazil, Mexico, and Peru Taxes, Transfers, Inequality, and Poverty: Argen9na, Bolivia, Brazil, Mexico, and Peru Nora Lus9g Tulane University Nonresident Fellow Center for Global Development and Inter- American Dialogue Inter-

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 10/5/2017 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 08/2016 08/2017 % Change 2016 2017 % Change MEXICO 51,349,849 67,180,788 30.8 % 475,806,632 503,129,061 5.7 % NETHERLANDS 12,756,776 12,954,789

More information

Fiscal Policy and the Ethno- Racial Divide: Bolivia, Brazil and Uruguay

Fiscal Policy and the Ethno- Racial Divide: Bolivia, Brazil and Uruguay Fiscal Policy and the Ethno- Racial Divide: Bolivia, Brazil and Uruguay Nora Lustig Tulane University Inter-American Development Bank Washington, DC, November 21, 2013 Commitment to Equity (CEQ) www.commitmentoequity.org

More information

Poverty, Inequality and the Millennium Development Goals in La:n America. Nora Lus)g Professor, Tulane University Nonresident Fellow, CGD and IAD

Poverty, Inequality and the Millennium Development Goals in La:n America. Nora Lus)g Professor, Tulane University Nonresident Fellow, CGD and IAD Poverty, Inequality and the Millennium Development Goals in La:n America Nora Lus)g Professor, Tulane University Nonresident Fellow, CGD and IAD OECD, Paris, February 27, 2012 1 La:n America and MDGs Significant

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 6/6/2018 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 04/2017 04/2018 % Change 2017 2018 % Change MEXICO 60,968,190 71,994,646 18.1 % 231,460,145 253,500,213 9.5 % NETHERLANDS 13,307,731 10,001,693

More information

INTERNATIONAL BANK FOR RECONSTRUCTION AND DEVELOPMENT BOARD OF GOVERNORS. Resolution No. 612

INTERNATIONAL BANK FOR RECONSTRUCTION AND DEVELOPMENT BOARD OF GOVERNORS. Resolution No. 612 INTERNATIONAL BANK FOR RECONSTRUCTION AND DEVELOPMENT BOARD OF GOVERNORS Resolution No. 612 2010 Selective Increase in Authorized Capital Stock to Enhance Voice and Participation of Developing and Transition

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 1/5/2018 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 11/2016 11/2017 % Change 2016 2017 % Change MEXICO 50,994,409 48,959,909 (4.0)% 631,442,105 657,851,150 4.2 % NETHERLANDS 9,378,351 11,903,919

More information

Fernanda Ruiz Nuñez Senior Economist Infrastructure, PPPs and Guarantees Group The World Bank

Fernanda Ruiz Nuñez Senior Economist Infrastructure, PPPs and Guarantees Group The World Bank Fernanda Ruiz Nuñez Senior Economist Infrastructure, PPPs and Guarantees Group The World Bank Mikel Tejada Consultant. Topic Leader Procuring Infrastructure PPPs The World Bank 2018 ICGFM 32nd Annual International

More information

Social Protection: An Indispensable Tool for a New Social Contract

Social Protection: An Indispensable Tool for a New Social Contract Social Protection: An Indispensable Tool for a New Social Contract Rethinking Social Protection in the Arab Region Amman, 13-15 May 2014 Isabel Ortiz Director Social Protection Department International

More information

Redistribution via VAT and cash transfers: an assessment in four low and middle income countries

Redistribution via VAT and cash transfers: an assessment in four low and middle income countries Redistribution via VAT and cash transfers: an assessment in four low and middle income countries IFS Briefing note BN230 David Phillips Ross Warwick Funded by In partnership with Redistribution via VAT

More information

On Minimum Wage Determination

On Minimum Wage Determination On Minimum Wage Determination Tito Boeri Università Bocconi, LSE and fondazione RODOLFO DEBENEDETTI March 15, 2014 T. Boeri (Università Bocconi) On Minimum Wage Determination March 15, 2014 1 / 1 Motivations

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 2/6/2018 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 12/2016 12/2017 % Change 2016 2017 % Change MEXICO 50,839,282 54,169,734 6.6 % 682,281,387 712,020,884 4.4 % NETHERLANDS 10,630,799 11,037,475

More information

The Microfinance Rating Market Outlook The Rating Fund Market Survey 2005

The Microfinance Rating Market Outlook The Rating Fund Market Survey 2005 The Microfinance Rating Market Outlook The Rating Fund Market Survey 25 Introduction Microfinance rating services are playing a key role in helping MFIs to improve performance and to source commercial

More information

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) 5/4/2016 Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country) YTD YTD Country 03/2015 03/2016 % Change 2015 2016 % Change MEXICO 53,821,885 60,813,992 13.0 % 143,313,133 167,568,280 16.9 % NETHERLANDS 11,031,990 12,362,256

More information

Corporate Presentation

Corporate Presentation Corporate Presentation 2018 Mission Statement Our mission is to provide our clients with security so that they can concentrate on growing their business. We strive to create value and long term mutually

More information

The Commodities Roller Coaster: A Fiscal Framework for Uncertain Times

The Commodities Roller Coaster: A Fiscal Framework for Uncertain Times International Monetary Fund October 215 Fiscal Monitor The Commodities Roller Coaster: A Fiscal Framework for Uncertain Times Tidiane Kinda Fiscal Affairs Department Vienna, November 26, 215 The views

More information

Withholding Tax Rate under DTAA

Withholding Tax Rate under DTAA Withholding Tax Rate under DTAA Country Albania 10% 10% 10% 10% Armenia 10% Australia 15% 15% 10%/15% [Note 2] 10%/15% [Note 2] Austria 10% Bangladesh Belarus a) 10% (if at least 10% of recipient company);

More information

THE IMPACT OF TAXES AND SOCIAL SPENDING ON INEQUALITY AND POVERTY IN ARGENTINA, BOLIVIA, BRAZIL, MEXICO AND PERU: A SYNTHESIS OF RESULTS

THE IMPACT OF TAXES AND SOCIAL SPENDING ON INEQUALITY AND POVERTY IN ARGENTINA, BOLIVIA, BRAZIL, MEXICO AND PERU: A SYNTHESIS OF RESULTS THE IMPACT OF TAXES AND SOCIAL SPENDING ON INEQUALITY AND POVERTY IN ARGENTINA, BOLIVIA, BRAZIL, MEXICO AND PERU: A SYNTHESIS OF RESULTS Nora Lustig, George Gray-Molina, Sean Higgins, Miguel Jaramillo,

More information

Taxes, Social Spending, Inequality and the Middle Class in Latin America

Taxes, Social Spending, Inequality and the Middle Class in Latin America Taxes, Social Spending, Inequality and the Middle Class in Latin America Nora Lustig Tulane University Nonresident Fellow CGD and IAD LASA Washington, DC May 30,2013 www.commitmentoequity.org 2 CEQ Authors

More information

PROGRESSIVITY IN TAX DESIGN. Michael Keen International Monetary Fund

PROGRESSIVITY IN TAX DESIGN. Michael Keen International Monetary Fund PROGRESSIVITY IN TAX DESIGN Michael Keen International Monetary Fund The 5th IMF-Japan High-Level Tax Conference for Asian Countries Tokyo, April 21, 2014 CONTEXT Inequality has been increasing 0.55 0.5

More information

Financial wealth of private households worldwide

Financial wealth of private households worldwide Economic Research Financial wealth of private households worldwide Munich, October 217 Recovery in turbulent times Assets and liabilities of private households worldwide in EUR trillion and annualrate

More information

Fiscal policy for inclusive growth in Asia

Fiscal policy for inclusive growth in Asia Fiscal policy for inclusive growth in Asia Dr. Donghyun Park, Principal Economist Economics and Research Department, Asian Development Bank PRI-IMF-ADBI Tokyo Fiscal Forum on Fiscal Policy toward Long-Term

More information

a closer look GLOBAL TAX WEEKLY ISSUE 249 AUGUST 17, 2017

a closer look GLOBAL TAX WEEKLY ISSUE 249 AUGUST 17, 2017 GLOBAL TAX WEEKLY a closer look ISSUE 249 AUGUST 17, 2017 SUBJECTS TRANSFER PRICING INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY VAT, GST AND SALES TAX CORPORATE TAXATION INDIVIDUAL TAXATION REAL ESTATE AND PROPERTY TAXES INTERNATIONAL

More information

Memoranda of Understanding

Memoranda of Understanding UNEP/CMS/Inf.10.4 Parties to the CONVENTION ON THE CONSERVATION OF MIGRATORY SPECIES OF WILD ANIMALS and its Agreements as at 1 November 2011 Legend CMS Party n = shows the chronological order of the Parties

More information

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - APRIL 2017 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - APRIL 2017 (PRELIMINARY DATA) BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - APRIL 2017 (PRELIMINARY DATA) In the period January - April 2017 Bulgarian exports to the EU increased by 8.6% 2016 and amounted to 10 418.6 Million BGN

More information