Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM"

Transcription

1 Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara 2 This version: February Hanken School of Economics. paulofmaio@gmail.com. 2 Nova School of Business and Economics, NBER, and CEPR. psc@novasbe.pt. 3 We thank an anonymous referee, António Antunes, Matti Keloharju, Timo Korkeamaki, Anders Löflund, Peter Nyberg, Bill Schwert (the editor), and seminar participants at the Helsinki Finance Seminar and the Bank of Portugal for helpful comments. We are grateful to Kenneth French, Amit Goyal, Luboš Pástor, and Robert Shiller for making data available on their webpages. A previous version of this paper was entitled The time-series and cross-sectional consistency of the ICAPM. Maio acknowledges financial support from the Hanken Foundation. Santa-Clara is supported by a grant from the Fundação para a Ciência e Tecnologia (PTDC/EGE-GES/101414/2008). All errors are ours.

2 Abstract Can any multifactor model be interpreted as a variant of the ICAPM? The ICAPM places restrictions on time series and cross-sectional behavior of state variables and factors. If a state variable forecasts positive (negative) changes in investment opportunities in time-series regressions, its innovation should earn a positive (negative) risk price in the cross-sectional test of the respective multifactor model. Second, the market (covariance) price of risk estimated from the cross-sectional tests must be economically plausible as an estimate of the coefficient of relative risk aversion (RRA). We apply our ICAPM criteria to eight popular multifactor models tested over 25 portfolios sorted on size and book-to-market (SBM25), and 25 portfolios sorted on size and momentum (SM25). Our results show that most factor models do not satisfy the ICAPM restrictions. Specifically, the hedging risk prices have the wrong sign and the estimates of RRA are not economically plausible. Overall, the Fama and French (1993), and Carhart (1997) models perform the best in consistently meeting the ICAPM restrictions. The remaining models, which represent some of the most relevant examples presented in the empirical asset pricing literature, can still empirically explain the size, value, and momentum anomalies, but they are generally inconsistent with the ICAPM. Keywords: Asset pricing models; Intertemporal CAPM; Predictability of returns; Linear multifactor models; Cross-section of stock returns; Size and value anomalies; Momentum; Timevarying investment opportunities; Fama-French factors JEL classification: G12; G14.

3 1 Introduction Explaining the dispersion in average excess returns in the cross-section of stocks has been one of the most important topics in the asset pricing literature. The inability of the Sharpe (1964) Lintner (1965) CAPM to price portfolios sorted on size, book-to-market, momentum, and other stock characteristics has led to so-called size, value, and momentum anomalies [Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1996), among others]. In response, several multifactor models seeking to explain these various anomalies have emerged in the literature. Typically, these models include factors in addition to the market return whose betas help match the dispersion in excess portfolio returns observed in the cross-section. Many of these multifactor models have been justified as empirical applications of the Intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM, Merton, 1973), leading Fama (1991) to interpret the ICAPM as a fishing license to the extent that authors claim it provides a theoretical background for relatively ad hoc risk factors in their models. However, Cochrane (2005, Chapter 9) notes that although the ICAPM does not directly identify the state variables underlying the risk factors, there are some restrictions that these state variables must satisfy. According to Merton, the state variables relate to changes in the investment opportunity set, which implies that they should forecast the distribution of future aggregate stock returns. Moreover, the innovations in these state variables should be priced factors in the cross-section. We examine the restrictions associated with the ICAPM that prevent it from being a fishing license for any multifactor model that seeks to explain the cross-section of stock returns. We identify three main conditions that a multifactor model must meet to be justifiable by the ICAPM and find that most multifactor models in the literature do not satisfy these restrictions. First, the candidates for ICAPM state variables must forecast the first or second moments of aggregate stock returns. We assess the forecasting power of each variable by conducting time-series long-horizon regressions. Second, if a given state variable forecasts positive expected aggregate returns, its innovation (the risk factor) should earn a positive risk price in cross-sectional tests, while state variables that forecast negatively expected aggregate returns should earn a negative risk price. Risk premiums with opposite signs should accrue to innovations to state variables that forecast market volatility. Thus, it is not enough that the candidate state variables forecast future aggregate expected returns or the volatility of returns, the corresponding factors should also be priced in the cross-section. The intuition for this result is simple. An asset that covaries 1

4 positively with innovations to the state variable also covaries positively with future expected returns. It does not provide a hedge for reinvestment risk because it offers lower returns when aggregate returns are expected to be lower. Hence, a risk-averse rational investor will require a positive risk premium to invest in such an asset, implying a positive price of risk for the factor. A similar argument applies to assets that covary with innovations to market volatility. The third restriction associated with the ICAPM is that the market (covariance) price of risk estimated from the cross-sectional tests must be economically plausible as an estimate of the coefficient of relative risk aversion (RRA) of the representative investor. Most of the empirical literature on the ICAPM uses state variables from the predictability literature (short-term interest rates, bond yields, and aggregate financial ratios) in order to meet the first ICAPM restriction that the state variables should forecast expected market returns. Yet authors largely neglect the other constraints of the ICAPM: that the market price of risk corresponds to the risk aversion of the representative investor and especially that there must be consistency between the hedging factor risk prices and the corresponding slopes from the predictive regressions. In Campbell (1996), the risk prices associated with the VAR state variables that forecast market returns are constrained in the sense that they are linked with the estimated slopes from the VAR. However, Campbell only tests a specific parametrization with Epstein-Zin preferences and a VAR to estimate market discount rate news. This paper extends this work, focusing on whether commonly used empirical factor models satisfy the consistency between time series slopes and cross-sectional risk prices to be justifiable as ICAPM applications. Our work is also related to Lewellen, Nagel, and Shanken (2010), and Lewellen and Nagel (2006), who advocate that cross-sectional tests of asset pricing models in general, and the conditional CAPM in particular, should impose the models theoretical restrictions on the factor risk prices. We apply our ICAPM criteria to eight multifactor models, tested over 25 portfolios sorted on size and book-to-market (SBM25) and 25 portfolios sorted on size and momentum (SM25). We include the market return in the set of testing assets, which enables us to merge the crosssectional literature on the ICAPM with the literature on the time-series aggregate risk-return trade-off. Hence, we have a total of 16 empirical tests in the cross-section: eight models and two sets of portfolios. Table 1 summarizes the main results regarding the multifactor models satisfying the ICAPM criteria. When investment opportunities are driven by changing expected market returns, our 2

5 results show that only two models the Fama and French (1993) three-factor model tested over SBM25, and the Carhart (1997) model tested over SBM25 and SM25 meet the ICAPM consistency criteria. When we consider changes in the investment opportunity set driven by the second moment of aggregate returns, only the Fama and French (1993) model satisfies the ICAPM criteria when tested with the SBM25 portfolios. In most other models the hedging risk prices have the wrong sign and the estimates of RRA are not economically plausible. The Koijen, Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2010) and Pástor and Stambaugh (2003) models in tests with SBM25 meet the sign restriction on the hedging risk prices but do not produce a reasonable estimate for the risk aversion coefficient. The Hahn and Lee (2006) model in the test with SM25 produces a plausible estimate for RRA, but fails the sign restriction on the risk prices for the state variable factors. These rejections show that the ICAPM is not really a fishing license after all. Our findings are robust to estimating the multifactor models with an intercept, estimating each model by second-stage GMM, using alternative measures of the innovations in the state variables, using alternative test equity portfolios, adding bond risk premia to the menu of test assets, estimating the models in expected return-beta form, conducting a bootstrap simulation for the slopes in the predictive regressions, and using alternative proxies for the expected market return. Our paper is related to the growing empirical literature on the ICAPM. An incomplete list of empirical tests of the ICAPM over the cross-section of stock returns includes Shanken (1990), Brennan, Wang, and Xia (2004), Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006), Gerard and Wu (2006), Hahn and Lee (2006), Lo and Wang (2006), Petkova (2006), Bali (2008), Guo and Savickas (2008), Ozoguz (2009), and Bali and Engle (2010). In related work, Campbell (1993) develops a theoretical model based on a representative agent with Epstein and Zin (1991) preferences that leads to two risk factors the excess market return (as in the standard CAPM) and expectations about future market returns (discount rate news). Campbell (1996), Chen (2003), Guo (2006a), Campbell and Vuolteenaho (2004), Chen and Zhao (2009), and Maio (2012b) represent variants or extensions of the two-factor model developed in Campbell (1993). A related literature focuses on the time-series aggregate risk-return trade-off. An incomplete list of recent papers includes Scruggs (1998), Whitelaw (2000), Brandt and Kang (2004), Ghysels, Santa-Clara, and Valkanov (2005), Guo and Whitelaw (2006), Lundblad (2007), Pástor, Sinha, and Swaminathan (2008), 3

6 Bali, Demirtas, and Levy (2009), and Guo, Savickas, Wang, and Yang (2009). This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we discuss the theoretical restrictions associated with the ICAPM. In Section 3 we analyze the forecasting power of ICAPM state variable candidates with regards to the expected market return. In Section 4 we analyze whether the factor risk prices from cross-sectional asset pricing tests are consistent with the time-series predictability of market returns. In Section 5 we conduct a sensitivity analysis. In Section 6 we evaluate the predictive ability of the ICAPM state variables with regards to the volatility of market return. In Section 7, we conduct a Monte Carlo simulation experiment to assess the plausibility of our results. [Table 1 about here.] 2 Time-series and cross-sectional implications of the ICAPM A simplified version of the Merton (1973) Intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM) is based on the consumption/portfolio choice of a representative investor in continuous time. 1 We discuss the restrictions this model imposes on multifactor asset pricing models. There are N risky assets, and asset i has an instantaneous rate of return given by ds i S i = µ i (z, t)dt + σ i (z, t)dξ i, i = 1,..., N, (1) where S i denotes the price of asset i; dξ i is a Wiener process; and the covariance between two arbitrary risky assets is equal to σ ij dt. In this model, investment opportunities are time-varying since both the mean (µ i ) and volatility (σ i ) of asset returns are functions of a single state variable, z, which also evolves as a diffusion process: dz = a(z, t)dt + b(z, t)dζ, (2) where dζ denotes another Wiener process, and the covariance with the return on risky asset i is equal to σ iz dt. 2 The N + 1th asset is a risk-free asset with instantaneous rate of return equal to r: db B = rdt. (3) 1 For a textbook treatment see Pennacchi (2008), Chapter The Merton (1973) ICAPM does not directly identify the state variables. The main restriction in this simple model is that the state variables forecast the first two moments of stock returns. 4

7 To simplify the exposition, we assume that the risk-free rate is constant. The dynamics of wealth (W ) are given by dw = N N ω i (µ i r)w dt + (rw C)dt + ω i W σ i dξ i, (4) i=1 i=1 where ω i denotes the portfolio weight for asset i, and C stands for consumption. The investor maximizes lifetime utility: [ ] J(W, z, t) = max E t U(C, s)ds, (5) C,ω i s=t subject to the intertemporal budget constraint (4), where J(W, z, t) denotes the value function. It can be shown that the ICAPM equilibrium relation between expected return and risk is given by µ i r = γσ im + γ z σ iz, (6) where γ W J W W (W,z,t) J W (W,z,t) denotes the parameter of relative risk aversion; σ im and σ iz denote the covariances between the return on asset i and the market return and state variable, respectively; and γ z denotes the (covariance) risk price associated with the state variable, which is given by γ z J W z(w, z, t) J W (W, z, t), (7) where J W ( ) denotes the marginal value of wealth; J W W ( ) is the growth in the marginal value of wealth; and J W z ( ) represents a second-order cross-derivative relative to wealth and the state variable. As in Cochrane (2005), Chapter 9, we can approximate Eq. (6) in discrete time, leading to the pricing equation: E t (R i,t+1 ) R f,t+1 = γ Cov t (R i,t+1, R m,t+1 ) + γ z Cov t (R i,t+1, z t+1 ), (8) where R i,t+1 is the return on asset i between t and t + 1; R f,t+1 denotes the risk-free rate, which is known at t; R m,t+1 is the market return; and z t+1 denotes the innovation or change in the state variable. In Eq. (8), the novelty relative to the standard CAPM (Sharpe, 1964; and Lintner, 1965) is the second term on the right-hand side, γ z Cov t (R i,t+1, z t+1 ). This means that if the risk price associated with the state variable is zero, γ z = J W z ( ) = 0, we 5

8 are back to the standard static CAPM. This pricing equation represents the theory behind many multifactor models in the empirical asset pricing literature, leading Fama (1991) to call the ICAPM a fishing license. Yet, as should be clear from the derivation of (8), the non-market factors in such models should proxy for the innovation in some state variable, z t+1, so they cannot be just anything. By using the law of iterated expectations, we can obtain the ICAPM in unconditional form: E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1, R m,t+1 ) + γ z Cov(R i,t+1, z t+1 ). (9) In Eq. (9) there are two sources of risk that explain average risk premiums. 3 The first is captured by the static market risk premium associated with the CAPM, γ Cov(R i,t+1, R m,t+1 ), which postulates that an asset that covaries positively with the market return earns a positive risk premium over the risk-free rate. The intuition is that such an asset does not provide a hedge against changes in current aggregate wealth, as it pays in good times (periods with high returns on wealth), so a risk averse investor is willing to hold such an asset only if it offers a premium over the risk-free rate. The estimate for the relative risk aversion (RRA) coefficient should be between one and ten (see Mehra and Prescott, 1985, for example). To understand that the second source of risk in Eq. (9) is captured by the term, γ z Cov(R i,t+1, z t+1 ), consider a state variable that predicts future market returns. If the risk price for intertemporal risk (γ z ) is positive, an asset that covaries positively with changes in the state variable (and is thus positively correlated with future market expected return) earns a risk premium. The intuition is that the asset does not provide a hedge against future negative shocks in the returns of aggregate wealth (reinvestment risk), as it offers low returns when future aggregate returns are also expected to be low. Therefore, a rational investor is willing to hold such asset only if it offers an expected return in excess of the risk-free rate. This central economic intuition of the ICAPM puts a constraint on the sign of γ z, when the model is forced to price a set of assets in the cross-section. Specifically, if the state variable is 3 If the factor risk prices were time-varying (as a function of state variables), there would be additional (scaled) risk factors in the pricing equation from the interaction between the original factor and the state variables (see Jagannathan and Wang, 1996; Lettau and Ludvigson, 2001; and Cochrane, 2005, Chapter 8, among others). In our case, and following most of the empirical literature on the ICAPM, we assume that the risk prices are constant through time. In the next sections, we test only the unconditional versions of the empirical multifactor models that are candidates to ICAPM applications. 6

9 positively correlated with future aggregate returns, Cov t (R m,t+2, z t+1 ) = Cov t [E t+1 (R m,t+2 ), z t+1 ] = Cov t [E t+1 (R m,t+2 ), z t+1 ] > 0, (10) then the intertemporal risk price must be positive. To see this point, assume without loss of generality that the return on asset i is positively correlated with the (innovation in the) state variable: Cov t (R i,t+1, z t+1 ) = Cov t (R i,t+1, z t+1 ) > 0. (11) These two conditions imply that the return on asset i is also positively correlated with the future expected market return: Cov t (R i,t+1, R m,t+2 ) = Cov t [R i,t+1, E t+1 (R m,t+2 )] > 0. (12) This last condition has an important economic content: This asset does not provide a hedge for reinvestment risk, and should earn a higher risk premium than an asset with Cov(R i,t+1, R m,t+2 ) = 0, that is, γ z Cov t (R i,t+1, z t+1 ) > 0. This in turn implies that γ z > 0, given the assumption that Cov t (R i,t+1, z t+1 ) > 0. If we assume instead that the state variable forecasts negative expected market returns, then the intertemporal risk price must be negative, and the argument is just symmetric. 4 The main practical implication of this result is that if a state variable positively forecasts expected returns, the asset s covariance with its innovation should earn a risk premium in the cross-section. Thus, it is not enough that the candidate state variables forecast future aggregate returns. It must be the case that the (covariance) risk prices with (the innovations in) those state variables have the correct sign. Otherwise, the risk based explanation associated with those factors is inconsistent with the rational explanation underlying the ICAPM. 4 This positive correlation between the factor risk price and the forecasting slope is also valid under the (more restrictive) Campbell (1993) version of the ICAPM, as long as the coefficient of relative risk aversion is greater than one, γ > 1. In the (implausible) case of an investor less risk averse than the log investor the risk price of discount rate news would be negative, that is, an asset that is positively correlated with good news about future market returns (or alternatively, an asset that is positively correlated with a state variable that forecasts positive market returns) would earn a lower risk premium than an asset that is uncorrelated with future market discount rates. The intuition is that for an investor with very low risk aversion, the upside effect of a positive correlation between a given asset and future market returns (in the sense that it allows the investor to profit from the improvement in future investment opportunities) outweighs the downside effect (a reduced ability to hedge changes in future investment opportunities). However, we follow the extant literature and assume that the representative investor is more risk averse than the log investor, thus ruling out this perverse effect. 7

10 In the predictability literature, most predictive variables forecast positive expected equity market returns. This is the case for aggregate financial ratios (dividend-to-price ratio; earningsto-price ratio; book-to-market ratio), or bond yield spreads like the slope of the yield curve or the default spread. Next, we consider a state variable that forecasts the future variance of market return, and reexamine the corresponding implications for the sign of γ z in the cross-sectional asset pricing tests. The main result in this case is the following: If the state variable is positively correlated with the future volatility of aggregate returns, Cov t (R 2 m,t+2, z t+1 ) = Cov t [E t+1 (R 2 m,t+2), z t+1 ] = Cov t [E t+1 (R 2 m,t+2), z t+1 ] > 0, (13) then the risk price of intertemporal risk must be negative. 5 To see this point, assume again without loss of generality that the return on asset i is positively correlated with the (innovation in the) state variable, which implies that the return on asset i is also positively correlated with the future volatility of market return: Cov t (R i,t+1, R 2 m,t+2) = Cov t [R i,t+1, E t+1 (R 2 m,t+2)] > 0. (14) The economic implication of this last condition is that such an asset provides a hedge for reinvestment risk, as it pays high returns when future aggregate volatility is also high. Thus, such an asset should earn a lower risk premium than an asset with Cov t (R i,t+1, R 2 m,t+2 ) = 0, that is, γ z Cov t (R i,t+1, z t+1 ) < 0, which implies that γ z < 0, given the assumption that Cov t (R i,t+1, z t+1 ) > 0. If we assume instead that the state variable forecasts negative market volatility, then the intertemporal risk price must be positive, and the argument is just symmetric. Thus we have an opposite result relative to the case of expected returns: If a state variable negatively forecasts the volatility of returns, the asset s covariance with its innovation should earn a risk premium in the cross-section. The intuition is that an asset that covaries negatively with future aggregate volatility does not provide an hedge for risk averse investors (who dislike increased uncertainty in their future wealth), who in turn are willing to invest in such an asset if it offers a premium. Because R f,t+1 is known at the beginning of the period, we have Cov t (R f,t+1, R m,t+1 ) = 5 This proposition is consistent with the model developed by Chen (2003). 8

11 Cov t (R f,t+1, z t+1 ) = 0, leading to the pricing equation that we test on our data: E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, R m,t+1 ) + γ z Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 ). (15) 3 Do state variables forecast future investment opportunities? In this section, we test the first restriction associated with the Intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM), that is, do the candidates for state variables forecast future investment opportunities? Second, and most important, we want to assess the sign of the correlation between the state variables and future aggregate returns, for comparison with the factor risk prices we estimate, which represent our main criteria to evaluate the ICAPM. Our proxy for the investment opportunity set is the aggregate equity market, which is captured by the monthly return on the value-weighted stock market index available from the Chicago Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP). We conduct long-horizon predictive regressions, which are commonly used in the predictability literature to assess the forecasting power of the state variables over future expected market returns [Keim and Stambaugh, 1986; Campbell, 1987; Fama and French (1988, 1989), among others]: r t,t+q = a q + b q z t + u t,t+q, (16) where r t,t+q r t r t+q is the continuously compounded return over q periods (from t + 1 to t + q), and u t,t+q denotes a forecasting error with zero conditional mean, E t (u t,t+q ) = 0. It follows that the conditional expected return at time t is given by E t (r t,t+q ) = a q + b q z t. The sign of the slope coefficient, b q, indicates whether a given state variable forecasts positive or negative changes in future expected aggregate stock returns, and the associated t-statistic indicates whether this effect is statistically significant. We use forecasting horizons of 1, 3, 12, 24, 36, 48, and 60 months ahead. 6 The original sample is 1963: :12, which corresponds to the time span used in most empirical asset pricing studies of the cross-section. We evaluate the statistical significance of the regression coefficients by using both Newey and West (1987), and Hansen and Hodrick (1980) asymptotic standard errors with q lags. 7 The first set of state variables we use in our empirical test are variables from the predictability 6 There is a recent debate between in-sample versus out-of-sample predictability of stock market returns (see Campbell and Thompson, 2008; Cochrane, 2008; and Goyal and Welch, 2008, among others). In our case, it makes sense to use in-sample regressions since we are interested in the long run predictive power of the state variables, and also to use the same time series that is used in the estimation of the factor covariances (betas) and average excess returns, which are employed in the cross-sectional tests. 7 We use q lags to correct for the serial correlation in the residuals caused by the overlapping returns. 9

12 literature. The first two variables are bond yield spreads: The slope of the Treasury yield curve (T ERM, Campbell, 1987; Fama and French, 1989) and the corporate bond default spread (DEF, Keim and Stambaugh, 1986; Fama and French, 1989). We measure T ERM as the yield spread between the ten-year and the one-year Treasury bond, while DEF represents the yield spread between BAA and AAA corporate bonds from Moody s. The yield data are available from the FRED (St. Louis Fed) database. We also use the market dividend-to-price ratio [DY, Fama and French (1988, 1989); Campbell and Shiller (1988a)], and the aggregate price-earnings ratio [P E, Campbell and Shiller (1988b); Campbell and Vuolteenaho, 2004], both for the S&P 500 index. DY is computed as the log ratio of the sum of annual dividends to the level of the S&P 500 index, and P E corresponds to the log ratio of the price of the S&P 500 index to a ten-year moving average of earnings. The price, dividend, and earnings data for the S&P 500 index are available from Robert Shiller s website. The next two state variables are the one-month Treasury bill rate (RF, Fama and Schwert, 1977; Campbell, 1991; Hodrick, 1992), which is available from Kenneth French s website, and the value spread (V S, Campbell and Vuolteenaho, 2004). The value spread is computed as the difference between the monthly log book-to-market ratios of small-value and small-growth stocks. 8 The last state variable is the Cochrane and Piazzesi (2005) factor (CP ), which is related to bond risk premia. 9 Hahn and Lee (2006) use T ERM and DEF in their ICAPM application. Petkova (2006) uses DY and RF, in addition to T ERM and DEF, to proxy for changes in future investment opportunities. Campbell and Vuolteenaho (2004) use P E rather than DY and the value spread in addition to T ERM to forecast aggregate returns in their ICAPM application. In Koijen, Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2010), the two state variables are T ERM and CP. 10 Therefore, in addition to single-variable forecasting regressions, we conduct multiple-variable regressions 8 The value spread is calculated from six portfolios sorted on both size and book-to-market, available from Kenneth French s website. For details on the construction of V S, see the appendix in Campbell and Vuolteenaho (2004). 9 CP is the fitted value from a regression of an average of excess bond returns on forward rates. For details on the construction of CP, see Cochrane and Piazzesi (2005). We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting the inclusion of CP in the empirical analysis conducted in the paper. 10 The proxy for the level of the yield curve in Koijen, Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2010) is constructed differently than T ERM, however, both proxies are highly correlated. 10

13 to assess the joint forecasting power of the state variables in four ICAPM applications: 11 r t,t+q = a q + b q T ERM t + c q DEF t + u t,t+q, (17) r t,t+q = a q + b q T ERM t + c q DEF t + d q DY t + e q RF t + u t,t+q, (18) r t,t+q = a q + b q T ERM t + c q P E t + d q V S t + u t,t+q, (19) r t,t+q = a q + b q T ERM t + c q CP t + u t,t+q. (20) The second set of state variables is based on risk factors widely used in the empirical asset pricing literature. Although several of these multifactor models are justified as applications of the ICAPM, it is not clear whether the associated state variables do actually forecast future stock returns. The first two variables are the size (SMB) and value (HML) factors used by Fama and French (1993, 1996). 12 We also use the momentum factor (UMD) from Carhart (1997). These three factors are obtained from Kenneth French s website. The fourth empirical factor we use is the liquidity factor from Pástor and Stambaugh (2003) (L), which is obtained from Luboš Pástor s website. 13 To obtain the associated state variables we use the cumulative sums on the factors for UMD and L. For example, in the case of L, the cumulative sum is obtained as: t CL t = L s. (21) s=t 59 We use the cumulative sum over the last 60 months since the total cumulative sum is close to being non-stationary (auto-regressive coefficients around one). In the case of SMB, the corresponding state variable, SMB, is constructed as the difference between the monthly market-to-book ratios of small and big stocks, using the six portfolios sorted on both size and book-to-market, available from Kenneth French s website: SMB = MB SL + MB SM + MB SH 3 MB BL + MB BM + MB BH, (22) 3 where MB SL, MB SM, MB SH, MB BL, MB BM, and MB BH denote the monthly market-to- 11 When there are multiple state variables, we should focus on the marginal predictive role of each variable for changes in future investment opportunities, conditional on all other variables. This is why we use multivariate forecasting regression, instead of univariate regressions for each variable separately. 12 Vassalou (2003) provides evidence that both SMB and HML convey information about future GDP growth while Da and Schaumburg (2011) find that these factors are related to market volatility. 13 We use the non-traded liquidity factor (Eq. (8) in Pástor and Stambaugh, 2003). 11

14 book ratios of small-growth, small-middle BM, small-value, big-growth, big-middle BM, and big-value portfolios, respectively. Similarly, HML corresponds to the difference between the monthly market-to-book ratios of value and growth stocks: HML = MB SH + MB BH 2 MB SL + MB BL. (23) 2 Since SMB SMB and HML HML, this procedure enables us to interpret the original factors as innovations in the state variables, which we use in the cross-sectional regressions conducted later. 14 Thus, we conduct multiple regressions corresponding to three different multifactor models: r t,t+q = a q + b q SMB t + c q HML t + u t,t+q, (24) r t,t+q = a q + b q SMB t + c q HML t + d q CUMD t + u t,t+q, (25) r t,t+q = a q + b q SMB t + c q HML t + d q CL t + u t,t+q. (26) Also we estimate a predictive regression associated with the augmented model estimated in Fama and French (1993): r t,t+q = a q + b q SMB t + c q HML t + d q T ERM t + e q DEF t + u t,t+q. (27) Table 2 presents summary statistics for the state variables described above. Most state variables are highly persistent, with autoregressive coefficients above The least persistent variable is CP with an autoregressive coefficient of [Table 2 about here.] Table 3 presents the results for the single long-horizon regressions associated with T ERM, DEF, DY, RF, P E, V S, and CP. We can see that T ERM, DEF, DY, RF, and CP forecast positive market returns, although only in the cases of DY, DEF, RF, and CP do the asymptotic t-stats indicate statistical significance (and for DEF and RF only at longer horizons). On the other hand, P E consistently forecasts negative market returns at all horizons, and this effect is statistically significant at horizons of and beyond three months. The value spread also forecasts 14 The relation is only approximate, since we are ignoring the dividend component of returns. The construction of SMB and HML is similar in spirit to the value spread computed by Campbell and Vuolteenaho (2004). 12

15 negative market returns at all horizons, and the slopes are significant at the 5% level for horizons between three and 48 months. 15 Basically, all the variables forecast positive market returns with the exception of P E and V S and the forecasting power of most variables increases with the horizon as indicated by the approximately monotonic pattern in the R 2 estimates. [Table 3 about here.] The results for the multiple long-horizon regressions (17)-(20) are displayed in Table 4. To save space, we report results only for horizons of 1, 12, and 60 months. The slope estimates indicate that both T ERM and DEF forecast positive market returns, but only the slope associated with DEF is statistically significant at horizons of 12 and 60 months. In the case of regression (18), at q = 60, for which there is greater evidence of predictability as indicated by the adjusted R 2 estimates, T ERM, DY, and RF are statistically significant and forecast positive market returns but the slope associated with DEF is negatively estimated, although not significant. In the case of regression (19), T ERM forecasts positive market returns, while P E is negatively correlated with future expected returns at all three horizons. V S forecasts negative market returns at q = 1, 12, but the predictive slope is positive at the 60-month horizon. The three forecasting coefficients are statistically significant at q = 60. Regarding the state variables in regression (20), CP forecasts positive market returns, conditional on T ERM, and the slopes are significant at the 5% or 1% levels for q = 1 and q = 60. T ERM forecasts negative market returns for q = 1 and positive returns thereafter, but none of the slopes is significant at the 10% level. [Table 4 about here.] The results for the multiple long-horizon regressions (24)-(27) are displayed in Table 5. Both SMB and HML forecast positive market returns at all horizons; the slope associated with HML is statistically significant at all horizons, while SMB is only marginally significant at q = 60. CUMD forecasts positive market returns at horizons of 12 and 60 months, conditional on both SMB and HML, but the slopes are statistically significant only at very long horizons (q = 60). The liquidity factor is positively correlated with future expected returns at all horizons, but the coefficients are statistically significant only at q = 12. In the fourth multiple regression 15 The negative slopes associated with V S are in line with the results obtained in Campbell and Vuolteenaho (2004). 13

16 (27), we can see that the slopes associated with T ERM and DEF, conditional on SMB and HML, are positive, although only T ERM is marginally significant in predicting the market return for q = 60 (based on the Newey-West standard errors). 16 Overall, these results show that most candidates for ICAPM state variables can forecast market returns, although the evidence of predictability is much stronger at longer horizons. [Table 5 about here.] 4 Are factor risk prices consistent with the ICAPM? To assess the ICAPM restrictions regarding factor risk prices, we test different multifactor models in the cross-section of stock returns. In each model, the first factor is the market equity premium, RM, computed as the monthly return of the value-weighted index in excess of the one-month Treasury bill rate, available from Kenneth French s website. The first group of multifactor models corresponds to models explicitly justified as ICAPM applications in which the risk factors represent innovations to state variables used in the predictability of returns literature to forecast aggregate equity returns. The first model we estimate is the ICAPM version of Hahn and Lee (2006), in which the additional risk factors relative to the market factor are the innovations in T ERM and DEF : E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) +γ T ERM Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, T ERM t+1 ) + γ DEF Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, DEF t+1 ). (28) The second model is the ICAPM of Petkova (2006) that consists of the innovations to RF and DY, in addition to T ERM and DEF : E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) + γ T ERM Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, T ERM t+1 ) +γ DEF Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, DEF t+1 ) + γ DY Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, DY t+1 ) +γ RF Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RF t+1 ). (29) The third model is an unrestricted version of the Campbell and Vuolteenaho (2004) ICAPM, 16 We also conduct multiple predictive regressions for the equity premium. In most cases, the signs of the slopes are the same as in the regressions for the market return. In the few cases in which the sign flips the point estimates of the slopes are not statistically significant. 14

17 in which investment opportunities are described by P E, T ERM, and V S: 17 E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) + γ T ERM Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, T ERM t+1 ) +γ P E Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, P E t+1 ) + γ V S Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, V S t+1 ). (30) The fourth model is the three-factor model from Koijen, Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2010), in which the state variables are T ERM and CP : 18 E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) +γ T ERM Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, T ERM t+1 ) + γ CP Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, CP t+1 ). (31) Next, we use multifactor models with less theoretical justification, but that some authors consider as possible applications of the ICAPM. The fifth model is the Fama and French (1993, 1996) three-factor model (FF3), in which the factors are SMB and HML in addition to the market risk premium: E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) + γ SMB Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, SMB t+1 ) +γ HML Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, HML t+1 ). (32) SM B is used to explain the size premium, the positive spread in average returns between small and big stocks. HM L seeks to explain the value premium, that value stocks (stocks with high book-to-market) have larger average returns than growth stocks (stocks with low book-to-market). The sixth model is the Fama-French three-factor model augmented by T ERM and DEF 17 Campbell and Vuolteenaho estimate a model with two factors, cash flow news (N CF ) and discount rate news (N DR ). Both N CF and N DR are linear functions of the innovations in the state variables, so that the two specifications are equivalent. For further details see Maio (2012a). 18 The Koijen, Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2010) model is not motivated by the authors as an ICAPM application. However, since the respective factors (other than the market factor) are related to state variables widely used in the predictability literature (T ERM and CP ), it makes sense to test whether this model satisfies the ICAPM restrictions. 15

18 (FF5): E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) + γ SMB Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, SMB t+1 ) +γ HML Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, HML t+1 ) + γ T ERM Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, T ERM t+1 ) +γ DEF Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, DEF t+1 ). (33) Fama and French (1993) use this model to explain both equity and bond risk premiums. The seventh model is Carhart s (1997) four-factor model (C): E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) + γ SMB Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, SMB t+1 ) +γ HML Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, HML t+1 ) + γ UMD Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, UMD t+1 ). (34) Added to the Fama and French (1993) model is the momentum (UMD) factor. The role of UMD is to explain the momentum anomaly; that is, past short-term winners tend to have higher average returns than past losers (Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993). Finally, we use the four-factor model employed by Pástor and Stambaugh (2003), which incorporates a liquidity related risk factor (L): E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) + γ SMB Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, SMB t+1 ) +γ HML Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, HML t+1 ) + γ L Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, L t+1 ), (35) which is denoted as PS. We use two sets of portfolio returns for testing assets. The first group is the 25 portfolios sorted on size and book-to-market (SBM25). The second group is 25 portfolios sorted on size and momentum (SM25). The portfolio return data are obtained from Kenneth French s website. We add the market return to each group of portfolios. Adding the market return enables a more powerful empirical test, and allows us to combine the literature on cross-sectional asset pricing with the literature on the market risk-return trade-off. Thus, the estimates of risk aversion and the intertemporal risk prices incorporate information from both the cross-section of equity premiums and the aggregate equity premium. 19 Moreover, adding factors to the menu 19 Note that it is common practice in the literature on the aggregate risk-return trade-off to estimate only the risk aversion parameter by assuming (in opposition with the underlying theory of the ICAPM) that the risk prices associated with time-varying investment opportunities are negligible, i.e., that hedging motives are marginal. In our case, the hedging factor risk prices are the core of the analysis. 16

19 of testing assets when the factors are returns themselves represents a more appropriate test of asset pricing models, as suggested by Lewellen, Nagel, and Shanken (2010). We estimate each multifactor model in expected return-covariance form by a one-stage generalized method of moments procedure (GMM, Hansen, 1982). This method uses equally weighted moments, which is conceptually equivalent to running an ordinary least squares (OLS) crosssectional regression of average excess returns on factor covariances (right-hand side variables). The advantage of the GMM procedure is that we don t need to have previous estimates of the individual covariances, as these are implied in the GMM moment conditions. This estimation allows us to assess whether each model can explain the returns of a set of economically interesting portfolios (e.g., SBM25). 20 The GMM system includes N + K + 1 moment conditions. The first N sample moments correspond to the pricing errors for each of the N testing returns: g T (b) (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) γ(r i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) (RM t+1 µ m ) 1 T T 1 t=0 γ 1 (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) (f 1,t+1 µ 1 ) γ 2 (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) (f 2,t+1 µ 2 )... γ K (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) (f K,t+1 µ K ) RM t+1 µ m f 1,t+1 µ 1. f K,t+1 µ K = 0, i = 1,..., N. (36) K denotes the number of factors in addition to the market factor (that is, each model has K +1 factors). In this system, the market return (RM t+1 ) is the first factor, with unconditional mean given by µ m. The remaining factors are given by (f 1,t+1,..., f K,t+1 ), and the respective means are denoted by (µ 1,..., µ K ). For example, in the case of the Fama-French model, we have K = 2 with f 1,t+1 SMB t+1, f 2,t+1 HML t+1. (γ 1,..., γ K ) denote the (covariance) risk prices associated with the hedging factors. The last K + 1 moment conditions in system (36) 20 The procedure is also more convenient than the two-pass time-series/cross-sectional regressions approach (Cochrane, 2005; Brennan, Wang, and Xia, 2004), since we want to estimate the model in expected returncovariance form rather than in expected return-beta form to obtain the covariance risk prices for each factor, and specifically the market (covariance) risk price, which represents an estimate of the relative risk aversion. 17

20 enable us to estimate the factor means. Thus, the estimated covariance risk prices from the first N moment conditions do account for the estimation error in the factor means, as in Cochrane (2005) (Chapter 13), and Yogo (2006). In this system, there are N K 1 overidentifying conditions (N + K + 1 moments and 2(K + 1) parameters to estimate). The standard errors for the parameter estimates, and the remaining GMM formulas are presented in Appendix 8. To assess the robustness of the asymptotic standard errors, we conduct a bootstrap simulation to produce empirical p-values for the tests of individual significance of the factor risk prices. The bootstrap simulation consists of 10,000 replications in which the portfolio return data and the factors are simulated independently, that is, the data are simulated under the hypothesis that the model is not true. Full details of this bootstrap simulation are available in Appendix 8. Although our focus is on the analysis of the factor risk prices, for completeness we also present some measures for the overall explanatory power of each model. The idea is to assess whether each model satisfies the economic restrictions associated with the ICAPM, in addition to explaining the dispersion in equity premiums over the cross-section. The first measure is the mean absolute pricing error: MAE = 1 N N α i, (37) i=1 where α i, i = 1,..., N represents the first N moments, i.e., the pricing errors associated with the N testing assets. The second goodness-of-fit measure is the cross-sectional OLS coefficient of determination: where R i = 1 T R 2 OLS = 1 Var N(ˆα i ) Var N (R i ), (38) T 1 t=0 (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) denotes the average excess return for asset i, and Var N ( ) stands for the cross-sectional variance. R 2 OLS measures the fraction of the cross-sectional variance in average excess returns explained by the model. 21 [Table 6 about here.] We start the empirical analysis by estimating two-factor models that include a hedging 21 We do not present the values for the asymptotic χ 2 test of overidentifying restrictions, since both the mean absolute error (MAE) and R 2 OLS represent more robust measures of the models global fit. 18

21 risk factor in addition to the market return: E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) + γ z Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 ), (39) where z = T ERM, DEF, DY, RF, P E, V S, and CP. The objective is to analyze whether some of the most relevant predictors of market returns proposed in the predictability literature can be justified in two-factor ICAPM specifications. The factor risk price estimates are displayed in Table 6. In the tests with SBM25 (Panel A), the point estimates for the relative risk aversion (RRA) parameter are negative in most specifications; the exceptions are the models with DEF, V S, and CP. Moreover, the risk price estimates associated with the intertemporal factor are negative in the specifications with DEF, DY, and RF, which are inconsistent with the positive forecasting slopes over the market return associated with the level of these variables, as shown in the last section. In the model with P E, the positive risk price estimate is also inconsistent with the corresponding negative slope estimated in the single predictive regression (16). Only in the specifications with T ERM, V S, and CP is there consistency in sign between the factor risk price estimates from the cross-sectional regressions and the slopes from the forecasting regressions over the market return. Overall, only two two-factor models (including V S or CP ) satisfy the restrictions on the market (covariance) risk price (RRA parameter) and on the hedging factor risk price. In the tests with SM25 (Panel B), only in the specifications with RF and V S is there an implausible negative estimate for γ. The factor risk prices associated with T ERM, DEF, RF, and CP are negative in all cases, which is inconsistent with the corresponding positive slopes estimated in the single predictive regressions. Moreover, the risk price estimate for V S is estimated positively, which is inconsistent with the negative slopes from the single forecasting regressions. On the other hand, the signs of the risk price estimates associated with DY and P E are consistent with the forecasting ability of these variables over market returns, although in both cases the risk price estimates are largely insignificant. Furthermore, in both cases there is no explanatory power over the cross-section of returns, as illustrated by the negative estimates for the cross-sectional R 2, indicating that these two models perform more poorly than a model that predicts constant expected risk premiums in the cross-section of equities. 19

22 The results in Table 6 show overall that most of the state variables in the literature are not valid risk factors under the ICAPM. Specifically, only two two-factor models satisfy the economic restrictions underlying the ICAPM, jointly with a reasonable explanatory power over the crosssection of excess stock returns ( V S and CP in the test with SBM25, with R 2 = 38% and 42%, respectively). We next estimate factor models presented in the literature as empirical applications of the ICAPM, which include combinations of the state variables analyzed above, specifically the threefactor Hahn and Lee (2006) model (henceforth, HL); the five-factor Petkova (2006) model (P); a four-factor model that corresponds to an unrestricted version of Campbell and Vuolteenaho (2004) (CV); and the three-factor model from Koijen, Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2010) (KLVN). The results are displayed in Table 7. In the tests with SBM25 (Panel A), we have the usual result that the CAPM cannot price the SBM25 portfolios, as shown by the negative cross-sectional R 2 of -42%, while the four multifactor models show a considerable explanatory power over the dispersion in risk premiums within these portfolios, with R 2 estimates above 70%. The point estimates for the RRA parameter, however, are negative and statistically insignificant in all four factor models, compared to a positive estimate of 2.79 in the CAPM, which is statistically significant. In the case of HL, the estimates for γ T ERM and γ DEF are positive and negative, respectively, although only the risk price associated with T ERM is statistically significant. Thus, the sign of γ DEF is inconsistent with evidence above that DEF (conditional on T ERM) forecasts positive market returns. In the case of P, both γ DY and γ RF are negative, while both γ T ERM and γ DEF are positive. All four risk price estimates are not statistically significant, however, which indicates evidence of multicollinearity. Thus, the signs of γ DEF, γ DY, and γ RF are inconsistent with the evidence from the multiple regressions (18) at a horizon of 60 months (for which there is stronger evidence of predictability) that both DY and RF (conditional on the other variables) forecast positive market returns, while DEF forecasts negative market returns (although with no significance). In the case of CV, the estimate for γ P E is positive, and thus inconsistent with the corresponding negative slopes found in the predictive regressions (19), while γ V S is estimated negatively, which also goes against the sign of the predictive slope at q = 60. Both γ P E and γ V S are not statistically significant at the 10% level, suggesting the presence of multicollinearity. Regarding the KLVN model, the point estimates for γ T ERM and γ CP are both positive, 20

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Addendum Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara This version: February 01 1 Hanken School of Economics. E-mail: paulofmaio@gmail.com. Nova School of Business

More information

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and education use, including for instruction at the authors institution

More information

Equity risk factors and the Intertemporal CAPM

Equity risk factors and the Intertemporal CAPM Equity risk factors and the Intertemporal CAPM Ilan Cooper 1 Paulo Maio 2 This version: February 2015 3 1 Norwegian Business School (BI), Department of Financial Economics. E-mail: ilan.cooper@bi.no Hanken

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Understanding Stock Return Predictability Hui Guo and Robert Savickas Working Paper 2006-019B http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2006/2006-019.pdf

More information

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 2/28/2012 Abstract We

More information

Estimation and Test of a Simple Consumption-Based Asset Pricing Model

Estimation and Test of a Simple Consumption-Based Asset Pricing Model Estimation and Test of a Simple Consumption-Based Asset Pricing Model Byoung-Kyu Min This version: January 2013 Abstract We derive and test a consumption-based intertemporal asset pricing model in which

More information

Paulo Maio 1. First draft: October This version: January

Paulo Maio 1. First draft: October This version: January Do stock return factors outperform other risk factors? Evidence from a large cross-section of anomalies Paulo Maio 1 First draft: October 2014 This version: January 2015 2 1 Hanken School of Economics,

More information

Internet Appendix to Interest rate risk and the cross section. of stock returns

Internet Appendix to Interest rate risk and the cross section. of stock returns Internet Appendix to Interest rate risk and the cross section of stock returns Abraham Lioui 1 Paulo Maio 2 This version: April 2014 1 EDHEC Business School. E-mail: abraham.lioui@edhec.edu. 2 Hanken School

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

Bad, Good and Excellent: An ICAPM with bond risk premia JOB MARKET PAPER

Bad, Good and Excellent: An ICAPM with bond risk premia JOB MARKET PAPER Bad, Good and Excellent: An ICAPM with bond risk premia JOB MARKET PAPER Paulo Maio* Abstract In this paper I derive an ICAPM model based on an augmented definition of market wealth by incorporating bonds,

More information

Accruals and Conditional Equity Premium 1

Accruals and Conditional Equity Premium 1 Accruals and Conditional Equity Premium 1 Hui Guo and Xiaowen Jiang 2 January 8, 2010 Abstract Accruals correlate closely with the determinants of conditional equity premium at both the firm and the aggregate

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Does Idiosyncratic Volatility Proxy for Risk Exposure?

Does Idiosyncratic Volatility Proxy for Risk Exposure? Does Idiosyncratic Volatility Proxy for Risk Exposure? Zhanhui Chen Nanyang Technological University Ralitsa Petkova Purdue University We decompose aggregate market variance into an average correlation

More information

Understanding Stock Return Predictability

Understanding Stock Return Predictability Understanding Stock Return Predictability Hui Guo * Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Robert Savickas George Washington University This Version: January 2008 * Mailing Addresses: Department of Finance,

More information

On the Cross-Section of Conditionally Expected Stock Returns *

On the Cross-Section of Conditionally Expected Stock Returns * On the Cross-Section of Conditionally Expected Stock Returns * Hui Guo Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Robert Savickas George Washington University October 28, 2005 * We thank seminar participants at

More information

Understanding Volatility Risk

Understanding Volatility Risk Understanding Volatility Risk John Y. Campbell Harvard University ICPM-CRR Discussion Forum June 7, 2016 John Y. Campbell (Harvard University) Understanding Volatility Risk ICPM-CRR 2016 1 / 24 Motivation

More information

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor In this online appendix, we provide a comparative static analysis of the theoretical model as well as further robustness checks on the trend factor.

More information

The Conditional CAPM Does Not Explain Asset- Pricing Anomalies. Jonathan Lewellen * Dartmouth College and NBER

The Conditional CAPM Does Not Explain Asset- Pricing Anomalies. Jonathan Lewellen * Dartmouth College and NBER The Conditional CAPM Does Not Explain Asset- Pricing Anomalies Jonathan Lewellen * Dartmouth College and NBER jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu Stefan Nagel + Stanford University and NBER Nagel_Stefan@gsb.stanford.edu

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( ) Lecture 5 Predictability Traditional Views of Market Efficiency (1960-1970) CAPM is a good measure of risk Returns are close to unpredictable (a) Stock, bond and foreign exchange changes are not predictable

More information

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs John L. Glascock 1 University of Connecticut Ran Lu-Andrews 2 California Lutheran University (This version: August 2016) Abstract The traditional

More information

One-Factor Asset Pricing

One-Factor Asset Pricing One-Factor Asset Pricing with Stefanos Delikouras (University of Miami) Alex Kostakis MBS 12 January 217, WBS Alex Kostakis (MBS) One-Factor Asset Pricing 12 January 217, WBS 1 / 32 Presentation Outline

More information

Measuring the Time-Varying Risk-Return Relation from the Cross-Section of Equity Returns

Measuring the Time-Varying Risk-Return Relation from the Cross-Section of Equity Returns Measuring the Time-Varying Risk-Return Relation from the Cross-Section of Equity Returns Michael W. Brandt Duke University and NBER y Leping Wang Silver Spring Capital Management Limited z June 2010 Abstract

More information

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence Journal of Money, Investment and Banking ISSN 1450-288X Issue 5 (2008) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2008 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New

More information

The pricing of volatility risk across asset classes. and the Fama-French factors

The pricing of volatility risk across asset classes. and the Fama-French factors The pricing of volatility risk across asset classes and the Fama-French factors Zhi Da and Ernst Schaumburg, Version: May 6, 29 Abstract In the Merton (1973) ICAPM, state variables that capture the evolution

More information

Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns

Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns Carlo Favero July 2012 Favero, Xiamen University () Demographics & Stock Market July 2012 1 / 37 Outline Return Predictability and the dynamic dividend growth

More information

Does Idiosyncratic Volatility Proxy for Risk Exposure?

Does Idiosyncratic Volatility Proxy for Risk Exposure? Does Idiosyncratic Volatility Proxy for Risk Exposure? Zhanhui Chen Nanyang Technological University Ralitsa Petkova Purdue University We thank Geert Bekaert (editor), two anonymous referees, and seminar

More information

where T = number of time series observations on returns; 4; (2,,~?~.

where T = number of time series observations on returns; 4; (2,,~?~. Given the normality assumption, the null hypothesis in (3) can be tested using "Hotelling's T2 test," a multivariate generalization of the univariate t-test (e.g., see alinvaud (1980, page 230)). A brief

More information

Improving the asset pricing ability of the Consumption-Capital Asset Pricing Model?

Improving the asset pricing ability of the Consumption-Capital Asset Pricing Model? Improving the asset pricing ability of the Consumption-Capital Asset Pricing Model? Anne-Sofie Reng Rasmussen Keywords: C-CAPM, intertemporal asset pricing, conditional asset pricing, pricing errors. Preliminary.

More information

One-Factor Asset Pricing

One-Factor Asset Pricing One-Factor Asset Pricing with Stefanos Delikouras (University of Miami) Alex Kostakis Manchester June 2017, WFA (Whistler) Alex Kostakis (Manchester) One-Factor Asset Pricing June 2017, WFA (Whistler)

More information

Does inflation explain equity risk premia?

Does inflation explain equity risk premia? Does inflation explain equity risk premia? Paulo Maio November 2017 Abstract I derive a simple linear macro asset pricing model that contains inflation as a risk factor in addition to the standard consumption

More information

Macroeconomic Risks and the Fama and French/Carhart Model

Macroeconomic Risks and the Fama and French/Carhart Model Macroeconomic Risks and the Fama and French/Carhart Model Kevin Aretz Söhnke M. Bartram Peter F. Pope Abstract We examine the multivariate relationships between a set of theoretically motivated macroeconomic

More information

Common Risk Factors in the Cross-Section of Corporate Bond Returns

Common Risk Factors in the Cross-Section of Corporate Bond Returns Common Risk Factors in the Cross-Section of Corporate Bond Returns Online Appendix Section A.1 discusses the results from orthogonalized risk characteristics. Section A.2 reports the results for the downside

More information

A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective

A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective Ravi Bansal Dana Kiku Amir Yaron November 14, 2007 Abstract Asset return and cash flow predictability is of considerable

More information

Department of Finance Working Paper Series

Department of Finance Working Paper Series NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LEONARD N. STERN SCHOOL OF BUSINESS Department of Finance Working Paper Series FIN-03-005 Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch, Jessica Wachter

More information

Appendix to Dividend yields, dividend growth, and return predictability in the cross-section of. stocks

Appendix to Dividend yields, dividend growth, and return predictability in the cross-section of. stocks Appendix to Dividend yields, dividend growth, and return predictability in the cross-section of stocks Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara 2 This version: February 2015 1 Hanken School of Economics. E-mail:

More information

ICAPM with time-varying risk aversion

ICAPM with time-varying risk aversion ICAPM with time-varying risk aversion Paulo Maio* Abstract A derivation of the ICAPM in a very general framework and previous theoretical work, argue for the relative risk aversion (RRA) coefficient to

More information

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Ravi Bansal Fuqua School of Business, Duke University Robert F. Dittmar Kelley School of Business, Indiana University Christian T. Lundblad

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 2: Factor models and the cross-section of stock returns Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Next week (30

More information

Modelling Stock Returns in India: Fama and French Revisited

Modelling Stock Returns in India: Fama and French Revisited Volume 9 Issue 7, Jan. 2017 Modelling Stock Returns in India: Fama and French Revisited Rajeev Kumar Upadhyay Assistant Professor Department of Commerce Sri Aurobindo College (Evening) Delhi University

More information

Are the Fama-French Factors Proxying News Related to GDP Growth? The Australian Evidence

Are the Fama-French Factors Proxying News Related to GDP Growth? The Australian Evidence Are the Fama-French Factors Proxying News Related to GDP Growth? The Australian Evidence Annette Nguyen, Robert Faff and Philip Gharghori Department of Accounting and Finance, Monash University, VIC 3800,

More information

The Market Price of Risk of the Volatility Term Structure

The Market Price of Risk of the Volatility Term Structure The Market Price of Risk of the Volatility Term Structure George Dotsis Preliminary and Incomplete This Draft: 07/09/09 Abstract In this paper I examine the market price of risk of the volatility term

More information

Estimating time-varying risk prices with a multivariate GARCH model

Estimating time-varying risk prices with a multivariate GARCH model Estimating time-varying risk prices with a multivariate GARCH model Chikashi TSUJI December 30, 2007 Abstract This paper examines the pricing of month-by-month time-varying risks on the Japanese stock

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns

Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns Thanos Verousis a and Nikolaos Voukelatos b a Newcastle University Business School, Newcastle University b Kent Business School, University of Kent Abstract

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model Hui Guo and Christopher

More information

Relation between Time-Series and Cross-Sectional Effects of. Idiosyncratic Variance on Stock Returns

Relation between Time-Series and Cross-Sectional Effects of. Idiosyncratic Variance on Stock Returns Relation between Time-Series and Cross-Sectional Effects of Idiosyncratic Variance on Stock Returns Hui Guo a and Robert Savickas b* First Version: May 2006 This Version: February 2010 *a Corresponding

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURING THE RISK-RETURN TRADEOFF WITH TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL COVARIANCES. Esben Hedegaard Robert J.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURING THE RISK-RETURN TRADEOFF WITH TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL COVARIANCES. Esben Hedegaard Robert J. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURING THE RISK-RETURN TRADEOFF WITH TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL COVARIANCES Esben Hedegaard Robert J. Hodrick Working Paper 20245 http://www.nber.org/papers/w20245 NATIONAL BUREAU

More information

Using Pitman Closeness to Compare Stock Return Models

Using Pitman Closeness to Compare Stock Return Models International Journal of Business and Social Science Vol. 5, No. 9(1); August 2014 Using Pitman Closeness to Compare Stock Return s Victoria Javine Department of Economics, Finance, & Legal Studies University

More information

Predicting Dividends in Log-Linear Present Value Models

Predicting Dividends in Log-Linear Present Value Models Predicting Dividends in Log-Linear Present Value Models Andrew Ang Columbia University and NBER This Version: 8 August, 2011 JEL Classification: C12, C15, C32, G12 Keywords: predictability, dividend yield,

More information

Risk-managed 52-week high industry momentum, momentum crashes, and hedging macroeconomic risk

Risk-managed 52-week high industry momentum, momentum crashes, and hedging macroeconomic risk Risk-managed 52-week high industry momentum, momentum crashes, and hedging macroeconomic risk Klaus Grobys¹ This draft: January 23, 2017 Abstract This is the first study that investigates the profitability

More information

Time-variation of CAPM betas across market volatility regimes for Book-to-market and Momentum portfolios

Time-variation of CAPM betas across market volatility regimes for Book-to-market and Momentum portfolios Time-variation of CAPM betas across market volatility regimes for Book-to-market and Momentum portfolios Azamat Abdymomunov James Morley Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis October

More information

Predictability of Stock Returns

Predictability of Stock Returns Predictability of Stock Returns Ahmet Sekreter 1 1 Faculty of Administrative Sciences and Economics, Ishik University, Iraq Correspondence: Ahmet Sekreter, Ishik University, Iraq. Email: ahmet.sekreter@ishik.edu.iq

More information

Interest rate risk and the cross-section of stock returns

Interest rate risk and the cross-section of stock returns Interest rate risk and the cross-section of stock returns Paulo Maio 1 First draft: November 2009 This draft: December 2010 1 Durham Business School. Corresponding address: Durham Business School, Durham

More information

Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns

Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns Wei Huang, Qianqiu Liu, S.Ghon Rhee and Liang Zhang Shidler College of Business University of Hawaii at Manoa 2404 Maile Way Honolulu, Hawaii,

More information

Common Factors in Return Seasonalities

Common Factors in Return Seasonalities Common Factors in Return Seasonalities Matti Keloharju, Aalto University Juhani Linnainmaa, University of Chicago and NBER Peter Nyberg, Aalto University AQR Insight Award Presentation 1 / 36 Common factors

More information

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach Hossein Asgharian and Björn Hansson Department of Economics, Lund University Box 7082 S-22007 Lund, Sweden

More information

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Ralph S.J. Koijen, Hanno Lustig, and Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh University of Chicago, UCLA & NBER, and NYU, NBER & CEPR UC Berkeley, September 10, 2009 Unified Stochastic

More information

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy This online appendix is divided into four sections. In section A we perform pairwise tests aiming at disentangling

More information

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Yuhang Xing Rice University This version: July 25, 2006 1 I thank Andrew Ang, Geert Bekaert, John Donaldson, and Maria Vassalou

More information

Global Currency Hedging

Global Currency Hedging Global Currency Hedging JOHN Y. CAMPBELL, KARINE SERFATY-DE MEDEIROS, and LUIS M. VICEIRA ABSTRACT Over the period 1975 to 2005, the U.S. dollar (particularly in relation to the Canadian dollar), the euro,

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM

MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM Samit Majumdar Virginia Commonwealth University majumdars@vcu.edu Frank W. Bacon Longwood University baconfw@longwood.edu ABSTRACT: This study

More information

HIGHER ORDER SYSTEMATIC CO-MOMENTS AND ASSET-PRICING: NEW EVIDENCE. Duong Nguyen* Tribhuvan N. Puri*

HIGHER ORDER SYSTEMATIC CO-MOMENTS AND ASSET-PRICING: NEW EVIDENCE. Duong Nguyen* Tribhuvan N. Puri* HIGHER ORDER SYSTEMATIC CO-MOMENTS AND ASSET-PRICING: NEW EVIDENCE Duong Nguyen* Tribhuvan N. Puri* Address for correspondence: Tribhuvan N. Puri, Professor of Finance Chair, Department of Accounting and

More information

A New Approach to Asset Integration: Methodology and Mystery. Robert P. Flood and Andrew K. Rose

A New Approach to Asset Integration: Methodology and Mystery. Robert P. Flood and Andrew K. Rose A New Approach to Asset Integration: Methodology and Mystery Robert P. Flood and Andrew K. Rose Two Obectives: 1. Derive new methodology to assess integration of assets across instruments/borders/markets,

More information

Gold Betas. Vijay Gondhalekar * and Lawrence Blose. Seidman College of Business, Grand Valley State University

Gold Betas. Vijay Gondhalekar * and Lawrence Blose. Seidman College of Business, Grand Valley State University Gold Betas Vijay Gondhalekar * and Lawrence Blose Seidman College of Business, Grand Valley State University Abstract On the basis of daily returns, gold exhibits no sensitivity to the market factor, SMB,

More information

University of California Berkeley

University of California Berkeley University of California Berkeley A Comment on The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns : The Statistical Significance of FVIX is Driven by a Single Outlier Robert M. Anderson Stephen W. Bianchi

More information

A Skeptical Appraisal of Asset-Pricing Tests

A Skeptical Appraisal of Asset-Pricing Tests A Skeptical Appraisal of Asset-Pricing Tests Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth and NBER jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu Stefan Nagel Stanford and NBER nagel_stefan@gsb.stanford.edu Jay Shanken Emory and NBER jay_shanken@bus.emory.edu

More information

Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle

Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle Robert F. Stambaugh, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania and NBER Jianfeng Yu, Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota

More information

TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM

TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM Campbell R. Harvey and Akhtar Siddique ABSTRACT Single factor asset pricing models face two major hurdles: the problematic time-series properties

More information

Do stock fundamentals explain idiosyncratic volatility? Evidence for Australian stock market

Do stock fundamentals explain idiosyncratic volatility? Evidence for Australian stock market Do stock fundamentals explain idiosyncratic volatility? Evidence for Australian stock market Bin Liu School of Economics, Finance and Marketing, RMIT University, Australia Amalia Di Iorio Faculty of Business,

More information

Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques

Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques Day 1: Equilibrium Models and the Dynamics of Bond Returns Pietro Veronesi Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago CEPR, NBER Bank

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle?

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch New York University and NBER Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania and NBER First Version: 15 November 2002 Current Version:

More information

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Leonid Kogan 1 Dimitris Papanikolaou 2 1 MIT and NBER 2 Northwestern University Boston, June 5, 2009 Kogan,

More information

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly Online Appendix Section I provides details of the calculation of the variables used in the paper. Section II examines the robustness of the beta anomaly.

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT. Long Chen Lu Zhang. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT. Long Chen Lu Zhang. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT Long Chen Lu Zhang Working Paper 15219 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15219 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue

More information

Journal of Banking & Finance

Journal of Banking & Finance Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 67 81 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Banking & Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf Future labor income growth and the cross-section

More information

CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM?

CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? WORKING PAPERS SERIES WP05-04 CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? Devraj Basu and Alexander Stremme CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? 1 Devraj Basu Alexander

More information

September 12, 2006, version 1. 1 Data

September 12, 2006, version 1. 1 Data September 12, 2006, version 1 1 Data The dependent variable is always the equity premium, i.e., the total rate of return on the stock market minus the prevailing short-term interest rate. Stock Prices:

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNCOVERING THE RISK-RETURN RELATION IN THE STOCK MARKET. Hui Guo Robert F. Whitelaw

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNCOVERING THE RISK-RETURN RELATION IN THE STOCK MARKET. Hui Guo Robert F. Whitelaw NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNCOVERING THE RISK-RETURN RELATION IN THE STOCK MARKET Hui Guo Robert F. Whitelaw Working Paper 9927 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9927 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050

More information

Paper topic suggestions for PhD Students

Paper topic suggestions for PhD Students Paper topic suggestions for PhD Students These are suggestions for class papers or second year papers. I have not researched their novelty to make sure nobody has done them before (and I welcome pointers

More information

Consumption, Dividends, and the Cross-Section of Equity Returns

Consumption, Dividends, and the Cross-Section of Equity Returns Consumption, Dividends, and the Cross-Section of Equity Returns Ravi Bansal, Robert F. Dittmar, and Christian T. Lundblad First Draft: July 2001 This Draft: June 2002 Bansal (email: ravi.bansal@duke.edu)

More information

Investigating ICAPM with Dynamic Conditional Correlations *

Investigating ICAPM with Dynamic Conditional Correlations * Investigating ICAPM with Dynamic Conditional Correlations * Turan G. Bali a and Robert F. Engle b ABSTRACT This paper examines the intertemporal relation between expected return and risk for 30 stocks

More information

The Common Factor in Idiosyncratic Volatility:

The Common Factor in Idiosyncratic Volatility: The Common Factor in Idiosyncratic Volatility: Quantitative Asset Pricing Implications Bryan Kelly University of Chicago Booth School of Business (with Bernard Herskovic, Hanno Lustig, and Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh)

More information

The FED model and expected asset returns

The FED model and expected asset returns The FED model and expected asset returns Paulo Maio 1 First draft: March 2005 This version: November 2008 1 Bilkent University. Corresponding address: Faculty of Business Administration, Bilkent University,

More information

Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners

Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners A Model: Who Gains and Who Loses When Divergence-of-Opinion is Resolved? In the baseline model, the pessimist s gain or loss is equal to her shorting demand times

More information

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru i Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2012 ii Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru (B.Sc National University

More information

Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1

Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick January 2006 address

More information

Interpreting factor models

Interpreting factor models Discussion of: Interpreting factor models by: Serhiy Kozak, Stefan Nagel and Shrihari Santosh Kent Daniel Columbia University, Graduate School of Business 2015 AFA Meetings 4 January, 2015 Paper Outline

More information

Some Features of the Three- and Four- -factor Models for the Selected Portfolios of the Stocks Listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange,

Some Features of the Three- and Four- -factor Models for the Selected Portfolios of the Stocks Listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange, Some Features of the Three- and Four- -factor Models for the Selected Portfolios of the Stocks Listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange, 2003 2007 Wojciech Grabowski, Konrad Rotuski, Department of Banking and

More information

Momentum and Downside Risk

Momentum and Downside Risk Momentum and Downside Risk Abstract We examine whether time-variation in the profitability of momentum strategies is related to variation in macroeconomic conditions. We find reliable evidence that the

More information

The Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets

The Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets The Financial Review 41 (2006) 565--587 The Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets Hui Guo Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Abstract We investigate the risk-return relation in international

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle Tolga Cenesizoglu March 1, 2016 Cenesizoglu Return Decomposition & the Business Cycle March 1, 2016 1 / 54 Introduction Stock prices depend on investors expectations

More information

Why Is Long-Horizon Equity Less Risky? A Duration-Based Explanation of the Value Premium

Why Is Long-Horizon Equity Less Risky? A Duration-Based Explanation of the Value Premium THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXII, NO. 1 FEBRUARY 2007 Why Is Long-Horizon Equity Less Risky? A Duration-Based Explanation of the Value Premium MARTIN LETTAU and JESSICA A. WACHTER ABSTRACT We propose a

More information

The Implied Equity Duration - Empirical Evidence for Explaining the Value Premium

The Implied Equity Duration - Empirical Evidence for Explaining the Value Premium The Implied Equity Duration - Empirical Evidence for Explaining the Value Premium This version: April 16, 2010 (preliminary) Abstract In this empirical paper, we demonstrate that the observed value premium

More information

Note on The Cross-Section of Foreign Currency Risk Premia and Consumption Growth Risk

Note on The Cross-Section of Foreign Currency Risk Premia and Consumption Growth Risk Note on The Cross-Section of Foreign Currency Risk Premia and Consumption Growth Risk Hanno Lustig and Adrien Verdelhan UCLA and Boston University June 2007 1 Introduction In our paper on The Cross-Section

More information