The rth moment of a real-valued random variable X with density f(x) is. x r f(x) dx

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The rth moment of a real-valued random variable X with density f(x) is. x r f(x) dx"

Transcription

1 1 Cumulants 11 Definition The rth moment of a real-valued random variable X with density f(x) is µ r = E(X r ) = x r f(x) dx for integer r = 0, 1, The value is assumed to be finite Provided that it has a Taylor expansion about the origin, the moment generating function M(ξ) = E(e ξx ) = E(1 + ξx + + ξ r X r /r! + ) = µ r ξ r /r! r=0 is an easy way to combine all of the moments into a single expression The rth moment is the rth derivative of M at the origin: µ r = M (r) (0) The cumulants κ r are the coefficients in the Taylor expansion of the cumulant generating function about the origin K(ξ) = log M(ξ) = r κ r ξ r /r!, so that κ r = K (r) 0) Evidently µ 0 = 1 implies κ 0 = 0 The relationship between the first few moments and cumulants, obtained by extracting coefficients from the expansion, is as follows κ 1 = µ 1 κ 2 = µ 2 µ 2 1 κ 3 = µ 3 3µ 2 µ 1 + 2µ 3 1 κ 4 = µ 4 4µ 3 µ 1 3µ µ 2 µ 2 1 6µ 4 1 κ 5 = µ 5 5µ 4 µ 1 10µ 3 µ µ 3 µ µ 2 2µ 1 60µ 2 µ µ 5 1 In the reverse direction µ 2 = κ 2 + κ 2 1 µ 3 = κ 3 + 3κ 2 κ 1 + κ 3 1 µ 4 = κ 4 + 4κ 3 κ 1 + 3κ κ 2 κ κ 4 1 µ 5 = κ 5 + 5κ 4 κ κ 3 κ κ 3 κ κ 2 2κ κ 2 κ κ 5 1 1

2 In particular, κ 1 = µ 1 is the mean of X, κ 2 is the variance, and κ 3 = E((X µ 1 ) 3 ) Higher-order cumulants are not the same as moments about the mean This definition of cumulants is nothing more than the formal relation between the coefficients in the Taylor expansion of one function M(ξ) with M(0) = 1, and the coefficients in the Taylor expansion of log M(ξ) For example Student s t distribution on five degrees of freedom has finite moments up to order four, with infinite moments of order five and higher The moment generating function does not exist for real ξ 0, but the characteristic function M(iξ) = e ξ (1 + ξ + ξ 2 /3) is real and finite for all real ξ Both M(iξ) and K(iξ) have Taylor expansions about ξ = 0 up to order four only: M(iξ) = (1 ξ + ξ 2 /2 ξ 3 /3! + ξ 4 /4! + o(ξ 4 )) (1 + ξ + ξ 2 /3) = 1 + ξ 2 ( ) + ξ 3 ( ) + ξ4 ( 1 4! 1 3! ) + o(ξ4 ) = 1 ξ 2 /6 + ξ 4 /4! + o(ξ 4 ); K(iξ) = ξ + log(1 + ξ + ξ 2 /3) = ξ 2 /3 ( ξ + ξ 2 /3) 2 /2 + ( ξ + ξ 2 /3) 3 /3 ( ξ + ξ 2 /3) 4 /4 + = ξ 2 /6 + ξ 4 /36 + o(ξ 4 ), which means µ 2 = κ 2 = 1/3, µ 4 = 1 and κ 4 = 2/3 The normal distribution N(µ, σ 2 ) has cumulant generating function ξµ+ ξ 2 σ 2 /2, a quadratic polynomial implying that all cumulants of order three and higher are zero Marcinkiewicz (1935) showed that the normal distribution is the only distribution whose cumulant generating function is a polynomial, ie, the only distribution having a finite number of non-zero cumulants The Poisson distribution with mean µ has moment generating function exp(µ(e ξ 1)) and cumulant generating function µ(e ξ 1) Consequently all the cumulants are equal to the mean Two distinct distributions may have the same moments, and hence the same cumulants This statement is fairly obvious for distributions whose moments are all infinite, or even for distributions having infinite higherorder moments But it is much less obvious for distributions having finite moments of all orders Heyde (1963) gave one such pair of distributions with densities f 1 (x) = exp( (log x) 2 /2)/(x 2π) f 2 (x) = f 1 (x)[1 + sin(2π log x)/2] 2

3 for x > 0 The first of these is called the log normal distribution To show that these distributions have the same moments it suffices to show that x k f 1 (x) sin(2π log x) dx = 0 0 for integer k 1, which can be shown by making the substitution log x = y + k Cumulants of order r 2 are called semi-invariant on account of their behaviour under affine transformation of variables (Thiele 188?, Dressel 1942) For r 2, the rth cumulant of the affine transformation a + bx is b r κ r, independent of a This behaviour is considerably simpler than that of moments However, moments about the mean are also semi-invariant, so this property alone does not explain why cumulants are so natural for statistical purposes The notion of a cumulant can be traced to the work of Thiele (18??), who called them semi-invariants, but the moderm theory of cumulants and the associated k-statistics begins with the remarkable 1929 paper by Fisher Fisher used the term cumulative moment function for what we now call the cumulant generating function on account of its behaviour under convolution of independent random variables For the coefficients in the expansion, the term cumulant was suggested by Hotelling in a letter to Fisher, who approved of the coinage Let S = X + Y be the sum of two independent random variables The moment generating function of the sum is the product M S (ξ) = E(e ξ(x+y ) ) = E(e ξx e ξy ) = M X (ξ)m Y (ξ), and the cumulant generating function of the sum is the sum of the cumulant generating functions K S (ξ) = K X (ξ) + K Y (ξ) Consequently, the rth cumulant of the sum is the sum of the rth cumulants By extension, if X 1, X n are independent real-valued random variables, the rth cumulant of the sum is the sum of the rth cumulants If they are also identically distributed, the rth cumulant is nκ r, and the rth cumulant of the standardized sum n 1/2 (X 1 + +X n ) is n 1 r/2 κ r Provided that the cumulants are finite, all cumulants of order r 3 of the standardized sum tend to zero, which is a simple demonstration of the central limit theorem Good (195?) obtained an expression for the rth cumulant of X as the rth moment of the discrete Fourier transform of an independent and identically distributed sequence as follows Let X 1, X 2, be independent copies of X 3

4 with rth cumulant κ r, and let ω = e 2πi/n be a primitive nth root of unity The discrete Fourier combination Z = X 1 + ωx ω n 1 X n is a complex-valued random variable whose distribution is invariant under rotation Z ωz through multiples of 2π/n The rth cumulant of the sum is κ r nj=1 ω rj, which is equal to nκ r if r is a multiple of n, and zero otherwise Consequently E(Z r ) = 0 for integer r < n and E(Z n ) = nκ n 12 Multivariate cumulants Somewhat surprisingly, the relation between moments and cumulants is simpler and more transparent in the multivariate case than in the univariate case Let X = (X 1,, X k ) be the components of a random vector in R k In a departure from the univariate notation, we write κ r = E(X r ) for the components of the mean vector, κ rs = E(X r X s ) for the components of the second moment matrix, κ rst = E(X r X s X t ) for the third moments, and so on It is convenient notationally to adopt Einstein s summation convention in which ξ r X r denotes the linear combination ξ 1 X ξ k X k, the square of the linear combination is (ξ r X r ) 2 = ξ r ξ s X r X s a sum of k 2 terms, and so on for higher powers Technically speaking, the components of a vector X in V = R k are denoted by X 1,, X k, which is abbreviated to X r using a dummy superscript ranging over the index set [k] A linear functional ξ: V R is a vector in the dual space V of linear functionals The rth component of ξ is typically denoted by ξ r using subscripts for the coefficients, so that the value of ξ at X is a the real number ξ(x) = ξ 1 X ξ k X k which is abbreviated to ξ r X r In Einstein s notation, each repeated index should occur exactly twice, once as a subscript indexing the linear functional, and once as a superscript indexing the components of a vector in V The tensor product of X with Y is a vector or tensor in V 2 whose (r, s)-component is (X Y ) rs = X r Y s An arbitrary vector A in V 2 is a k k array of components A rs, which can be decomposed as the sum of a symmetric array and a skew-symmetric array A rs = (A rs + A sr )/2 + (A rs A sr )/2 = sym 2 (A) + alt 2 (A) 4

5 In this setting sym 2 and alt 2 are projections V 2 V 2, which are linear and complementary (the image of one is the kernel of the other) The dimensions are k(k + 1)/2 for sym 2 (V) and k(k 1)/2 for alt 2 (V) Note that (X X) rs = (X X) sr implies that the tensor product of a vector X V with itself is symmetric, so X X is a vector in the symmetric tensor product space sym 2 (V) The tensor product map X X X defines a transformation V sym 2 (V) from one vector space into another, and although 0 0, the transformation is not linear: (X + Y ) 2 is not equal to X 2 + Y 2 The image of the tensor product transformation is the set of rank-one [symmetric] tensors or matrices, and the span of these matrices is the whole space sym 2 (V) The moment generating function of [the distribution of] a random variable X taking values in V is a function M(ξ) = E(exp(ξ r X r )) on the dual space of linear functionals Its Taylor expansion is M(ξ) = 1 + ξ r κ r + 1 2! ξ rξ s κ rs + 1 3! ξ rξ s ξ t κ rst +, where each of the joint moments κ r = E(X r ), κ rs = E(X r X s ), κ rst = E(X r X s X t ), is a symmetric tensor in V, V 2, V 3 and so on The cumulants are defined as the coefficients κ r,s, κ r,s,t, in the Taylor expansion log M(ξ) = ξ r κ r + 1 2! ξ rξ s κ r,s + 1 3! ξ rξ s ξ t κ r,s,t + This notation does not distinguish first-order moments from first-order cumulants, but commas separating the superscripts serve to distinguish higherorder cumulants from moments: κ r,s = cum 2 (X r, X s ), κ r,s,t = cum 3 (X r, X s, X t ), Each superscript in this setting denote a vector component r [k], not a power Comparison of coefficients reveals that the each moment κ rs, κ rst, is a sum over partitions of the superscripts, each term in the sum being a product of cumulants: κ rs = κ r,s + κ r κ s κ rst = κ r,s,t + κ r,s κ t + κ r,t κ s + κ s,t κ r + κ r κ s κ t = κ r,s,t + κ r,s κ t [3] + κ r κ s κ t κ rstu = κ r,s,t,u + κ r,s,t κ u [4] + κ r,s κ t,u [3] + κ r,s κ t κ u [6] + κ r κ s κ t κ u 5

6 Each parenthetical number indicates a sum over distinct partitions having the same block sizes The fourth-order moment is a sum of 15 distinct cumulant products of which three are of type 2 2 with two blocks of size two, and six are of type 21 2 with three blocks: rs tu[3] = {rs tu, rt su, ru st} κ r,s κ t,u [3] = κ r,s κ t,u + κ r,t κ s,u + κ r,u κ s,t rs t u[6] = {rs t u, rt s u, ru s t, st r u, su r t, tu r s} κ r,s κ t κ u [6] = κ r,s κ t κ u + + κ t,u κ r κ s The blocks are unlabelled, so tu rs rs tu, and each block is a subset of the four elements or labels rstu, so rs tu = sr tu = rs ut = sr tu In the reverse direction, each cumulant is also a sum over partitions of the indices Each term in the sum is a product of moments, but with coefficient ( 1) ν 1 (ν 1)! where ν is the number of blocks: κ r,s = κ rs κ r κ s κ r,s,t = κ rst κ rs κ t [3] + 2κ r κ s κ t κ r,s,t,u = κ rstu κ rst κ u [4] κ rs κ tu [3] + 2κ rs κ t κ u [6] 6κ r κ s κ t κ u Partition notation serves one additional purpose It establishes moments and cumulants as special cases of generalized cumulants, which includes objects of the type κ r,st = cov(x r, X s X t ), κ rs,tu = cov(x r X s, X t X u ), and κ rs,t,u with incompletely partitioned indices These objects arise very naturally in statistical work involving asymptotic approximation of distributions They are intermediate between moments and cumulants, and have characteristics of both Every generalized cumulant can be expressed as a sum of certain products of ordinary cumulants Some examples are as follows: κ rs,t = κ r,s,t + κ r κ s,t + κ s κ r,t = κ r,s,t + κ r κ s,t [2] κ rs,tu = κ r,s,t,u + κ r,s,t κ u [4] + κ r,t κ s,u [2] + κ r,t κ s κ u [4] κ rs,t,u = κ r,s,t,u + κ r,t,u κ s [2] + κ r,t κ s,u [2] Each generalized cumulant is associated with a partition τ of the given set of indices For example, κ rs,t,u is associated with the partition τ = rs t u of four indices into three blocks Each term on the right is a cumulant product associated with a partition σ of the same indices The coefficient is one if the least upper bound σ τ has a single block, otherwise zero Thus, 6

7 with τ = rs t u, the product κ r,s κ t,u does not appear on the right because σ τ = rs tu has two blocks As an example of the way these formulae may be used, let X be a scalar random variable with cumulants κ 1, κ 2, κ 3, By translating the second formula in the preceding list, we find that the variance of the squared variable is var(x 2 ) = κ 4 + 4κ 3 κ 1 + 2κ κ 2 κ 2 1, reducing to κ 4 + 2κ 2 2 if the mean is zero Exercises Let V = R n, and let A be a tensor in V 2 with components A ij Show that sym 2 (A) ij = (A ij + A ji )/2 alt 2 (A) ij = (A ij A ji )/2 are linear projections V 2 V 2 Show also that the projections are complementary What are the dimensions of the image spaces sym 2 (V) and alt 2 (V)? 122 Let A be a tensor in V 3 with components A ijk Show that sym 3 (A) ijk = (A ijk + A jik + A kji + A ikj + A jki + A kij )/6 alt 3 (A) ijk = (A ijk A jik A kji A ikj + A jki + A kij )/6 res 3 (A) ijk = (2A ijk A jki A kij )/3 are linear projections V 3 V 3, ie, satisfying T (T (A)) = T (A) Show also that the projections are complementary in the sense that the kernel of each one is the direct sum of the images of the other two What are the dimensions of the image spaces sym 3 (V), alt 3 (V) and res 3 (V)? 13 Partition lattice 131 Poset A Boolean function S S {0, 1}, ie, a subset of S 2, is called a partial order if the subset or relationship ( ) is reflexive and transitive Reflexive means a a [is true] for every a S; transitive means that a b and b c implies a c To simplify matters, a third condition is imposed such that a b and b a together imply a = b; otherwise it is necessary to reduce the discussion to equivalence classes 7

8 The real line is a partially ordered set that is also a total order (either a b or b a for every pair) The real plane or complex plane ordered componentwise (a b if a 1 b 1 and a 2 b 2 ) is partially ordered but not completely ordered: there exist pairs for which a b and b a are both false For any set A each S 2 A is a collection of subsets of A, which is partially ordered by subset inclusion The set of subspaces of a vector space V is partially ordered by subspace inclusion The set of factorial models (factorial subspaces) generated by factors A, B, C is also partially ordered by subspace inclusion 132 Set partition Let n 1 be a positive integer, and let [n] = {1,, n} be a finite set A partition of the set [n] is a collection of disjoint non-empty subsets, called blocks, whose union is [n] The partition type is the set of block sizes counted with multiplicity Since the sum of the block sizes is n, the partition type is a partition of the integer n For example {{1, 3}, {2, 5}, {4}} and {{1, 5}, {2, 3}, {4}} are two distinct partitions of [5], usually abbreviated to and Since a partition is a set of subsets, the order of the blocks, and the order within blocks are ignored All told, there are 15 distinct partitions of [5] of the same type or A partition of [n] is also an equivalence relation B: [n] 2 {0, 1} In other words, B [n] 2 is a symmetric Boolean matrix that is also reflexive and transitive The matrix representations of and are = , = Evidently the expressions and determine the same subset B [5] 2, and therefore the same partition Let Pn be the set of partitions of [n] For n 5 the elements of Pn grouped by partition type are P1 : 1 P2 : 12, 1 2 P3 : 123, 12 3, 13 2, 23 1, P4 : 1234, [4], [3], [6],

9 P5 : 12345, [5], [10], [10], [15], [10], Thus, [3] = {12 34, 13 24, 14 23} P4 is the subset consisting of all distinct set partitions of type 2 2, and [15] P5 is the subset of 15 partitions of type 12 2 (five ways to choose the singleton, and three ways to split the remaining four into two pairs) Each subset of a given type is an orbit of the symmetric group [n] [n] acting on partitions Pn in the obvious way by permutation or re-labelling of elements When we say that B = is a partition of [5], we make no distinction between different representations: (i) as a subset B [5] 2 ; (ii) as the symmetric binary matrix displayed above with rows and columns indexed by [n]; (iii) as a Boolean function B: [n] 2 {0, 1}; (iv) as the set of disjoint non-empty subsets B = {{1, 5}, {2, 3}, {4}} The symbol #A applied to a set A means the number of its elements; the same symbol #B applied to a partition B denotes the number of blocks (which is the same as the rank of the matrix of B) 133 Sub-partition Let B, B be two partitions of the same finite set [n] If each block of B is a subset of some block of B we write B B, which is a partial order on Pn As subsets of the square [n] 2, B B if and only if B B The maximal partition is the one-block partition {[n]}, conventionally denoted by 1 or 1 n ; the minimal partition is the n-block partition by singletons, conventionally denoted by 0 or 0 n As subsets of the n-square, 1 n = [n] 2 is the entire square or the n n matrix whose components are all one; 0 n = diag([n] 2 ) is the diagonal subset or the identity matrix I n or the Kronecker function δ(b, B ) For every partition B we have 0 n B 1 n To each pair of partitions B, B Pn there corresponds a least upper bound B B = B B and a greatest lower bound B B = B B The greatest lower bound is the intersection B B of B and B as subsets of [n] 2 ; equivalently, the blocks of B B are the non-empty intersections of the blocks of B with the blocks of B The least upper bound is the intersection of all partitions that contain B B as subsets of [n] 2 For example, the least upper bound of and is The partition lattices P2 P4 are illustrated as graphs in Figure 1, with each partition as a node, and an edge joining two nodes B < B only if 9

10 Figure 1: Hasse diagrams for smaller partition lattices B is a parent of B, ie, there is no intermediate partition B such that B < B < B 134 Zeta and Möbius functions For any partially ordered set S, the partial order is encoded in the zeta function ζ(a, b) = 1 if a b and zero otherwise In particular, this implies ζ(a, a) = 1 for every a S If the elements of S are listed in non-decreasing order, then ζ is ab upper triangular matrix with unit values along the diagonal For example, the zeta function for P3 with elements listed in decreasing number of blocks is S = {1 2 3, 12 3, 13 2, 23 1, 123} ζ = 1 0 1, with all entries below the diagonal equal to zero, and also some of those above the diagonal 10

11 Let S be finite and let f be a real-valued function on S, ie, f R S Then F = ζ f is also a real-valued function, so ζ is a linear function R S R S In fact F (a) = (ζ f)(a) = ζ(b, a)f(b) = f(b) b b a is the cumulative sum of f-values over the subset b a If S is a finite lattice, it has a minimal element 0, and the sum is a sum over the lattice interval [0, a] The inverse function m(a, b) is also upper-triangular, and satisfies m(a, b)ζ(b, c) b S ζ(a, b)m(b, c) = δ(a, c) = b S and the sum may be restricted to the interval [a, c] = {b: a b c} In particular, for a < c, the sum over the interval [a, c] is zero m(b, c) = 0 = m(a, b) a b c a b c More explicitly, back-substitution gives m(a, a) = 1 for every a and m(a, c) = m(b, c) a<b c for a < c The Möbius function depends on the structure of the lattice For the partition lattice Pn, it is sufficient to know that the value relative to the maximal one-block partition is m(σ, 1 n ) = ( 1) #σ 1 (#σ 1)! = ( 1) #σ 1 Γ(#σ), the gamma function with alternating sign, independent of the block sizes More generally, if σ is a partition of [n], the restriction of σ to b [n] is a partition of the subset b denoted by σ[b] For example, the restriction of σ = to b = {2, 3, 4, 5} is σ[b] = consisting of two complete blocks and one partial block of σ In general, the restriction σ[b] is not a subset of the blocks of σ For any interval [σ, τ] with σ τ, each block b τ is the union of certain blocks σ[b] σ, so the restriction σ[b] is a subset consisting of certain blocks of σ (with no partial blocks) The Möbius function is m(σ, τ) = m(σ[b], 1 b ) = ( 1) #σ #τ Γ(#σ[b]) b τ b τ for σ τ, and zero otherwise 11

12 14 Cumulants and generalized cumulants The relationship between moments and cumulants is most conveniently described by summation over the partition lattice Let [n] = {1,, n} be the index set For any subset b [n] let µ b = E( i b Y i ) be the moment and let κ b be the joint cumulant or order #b of the variables Y [b] = {Y i : i b} Then µ [n] = κ [n] = σ Pn b σ κ b σ Pn( 1) #σ 1 (#σ 1)! b σ More generally, for any partition τ Pn, the interval [0, τ] is isomorphic with the Cartesian product b τ [0, b] of smaller lattices Consequently, the moment product F (τ) = b τ µb is expressible as a sum of cumulant products f(σ) = b σ κb over partitions σ in [0, τ] F (τ) = µ b = κ b = f(σ) b τ σ τ b σ σ τ f(τ) = κ b = m(σ, τ) µ b b τ σ τ b σ µ b Now consider a different sort of mixed cumulant of order less than the number of variables A partition τ splits the random variables Y 1,, Y n into disjoint subsets, one subset Y [b] for each block b τ Now consider the joint cumulant κ(τ) of order k = #τ of the variables X 1 = Y i,, X k = Y i i b 1 i b k By definition, κ(τ) = cum k (X 1,, X k ) = ς τ m(ς, 1 n )F (ς) where F (ς) is the moment product over the blocks of ς Now substitute the expression F (ς) = σ ς f(σ) for moment products in terms of cumulant products κ(τ) = m(ς, 1 n ) f(σ) ς τ σ ς = σ Pn f(σ) ς τ ς σ 12 m(ς, 1 n )

13 κ(τ) = = f(σ) σ Pn σ:τ σ=1 n b σ ς τ σ κ b m(ς, 1 n ) This result is fundamental for computing means, variances and higherorder cumulants of quadratic forms and higher-order polynomial functions of random variables To understand how it works, we list, for various small integers n and selected partitions τ Pn, the subset of partitions σ Pn satisfying the connectivity condition σ τ = 1 n A short list of some connected set-partitions τ {σ : σ τ = 1} , 12 3, 13 2, 23 1, , 13 2, , [3], [3], [3] , [4], [2], [4] , [2], [2] excluding partitions having a singleton block , [6], [9], [9], [9], [6] , [12], [6], [4] [8] For a scalar random variable Y having zero mean, it follows from lines 5, 7, 8 of the table that var(y 2 ) = κ 4 + 2κ 2 2 var(y 3 ) = κ κ 4 κ 2 + 9κ κ 3 2 cum 3 (Y 2 ) = κ κ 4 κ κ κ Gaussian moments and the Isserlis-Wick formulae Suppose that the random vector ψ = (ψ 1,, ψ n ) is zero-mean Gaussian in R n with covariance matrix K whose (i, j) component is K i,j We ask for the joint cumulant of order n of the n squared variables κ(τ) = cum n ( ψ 1 2,, ψ n 2 ) 13

14 If the component variables are all equal, ψ 1 = = ψ n, then ψ 2 is distributed as κ 2 χ 2 1 The cumulant generating function is log(1 2κ 2ξ)/2, and the cumulants are cum n ( ψ 2 ) = 2 n 1 (n 1)!κ n 2 The moment generating function is (1 2κ 2 ξ) 1/2, so the moment of order n is proportional to the ascending factorial ( 1/2) n ( 2κ 2 ) n = (1/2) n (2κ 2 ) n = (2n)! κn 2 2 n n! For the more general setting, τ is a partition of the set [2n] of type 2 n τ = 1, 1 2, 2 n, n in which [n] and [n] are duplicate copies of the same index set, and ψ r 2 gives rise to two matching indices r, r, distinguished by primes but numerically equal Since the only non-zero cumulants are of order two, the expression for κ(τ) is a sum over all partitions σ of type 2 n such that σ τ = 1 2n Consider a cyclic permutation π: [n] [n], with the same permutation also acting on the second copy π: [n] [n], ie, 1 π(1) π 2 (1) π n 1 (1) π n (1) = 1 1 π(1 ) π 2 (1 ) π n 1 (1 ) π n (1 ) = 1 We associate with π a partition σ of [2n] as follows σ = 1π(1 ) π(1)π 2 (1 ) π 2 (1)π 3 (1 ) π n 1 (1)1 so that each block contains a pair j, π(j) with j [n] and π(j) [n] Clearly, σ τ = 1 2n, and the contribution of σ to κ(τ) is n K j,π(j) j=1 There are 2 n 1 essentially distinct ways of assigning the primes to one element in each block of τ, so the total contribution to the joint cumulant is κ(τ) = 2 n 1 n K j,π(j) = 2 1 cyp(2k), π:#π=1 j=1 where the sum runs over (n 1)! permutations π: [n] [n] having a single cycle 14

15 The expected value of the n-fold product µ(τ) = E ψ j 2 is the sum over partitions of [n] of cumulant products µ(τ) = κ(τ[b]) σ Pn b σ = 2 #b 1 cyp(k[b]) σ Pn b σ = n 2 n #σ κ j,σ(j) σ Π n j=1 = per 1/2 (2K) = 2 n per 1/2 (K) This derivation implies that per 1/2 (K) 0 for all positive semi-definite symmetric matrices, and a simple extension shows that per α/2 (K) 0 for all positive integers α For any real number α, the α-permanent per α (K) of a square matrix K of order n is the sum over n! permutations per α (K) = cyp(k) = α #σ n K j,σ(j) σ:[n] [n] j=1 n Σ:#σ=1 j=1 K j,σ(j) = lim α 0 α 1 per α (K) Note that per α (K) is a polynomial of degree n in α; it is homogeneous of total degree n in K In addition, per 1 (K) = ( 1) n det(k) In applications to quantum mechanics, ψ arises as a wave function, which is regarded as a zero-mean complex-valued Gaussian process Each component is distributed symmetrically with respect to rotation in the complex plane, and the joint distribution is invariant with respect to scalar multiplication by a unit complex number For this setting, all the algebraic joint moments and cumulants of ψ are zero The only non-zero cumulants are those of the form E(ψ r ψs ) = K rs = K sr, and higher-order products involving an equal number of conjugated and non-conjugated terms The argument given above for Gaussian cumulants applies equally to complex-valued Gaussian process The details are a little simpler in the complex case because the label-assignment factor 2 n 1 does not arise: [n] is the set of indices, [n ] is the conjugated copy, and there are no symmetries from switching elements As a result, κ(τ) = cum n ( ψ 1 2,, ψ n 2 ) = cyp(k) µ(τ) = E( ψ 1 2 ψ n 2 ) = per 1 (K) = per(k) 15

16 This derivation implies that per(k) 0 for all positive semi-definite Hermitian matrices, and a simple extension shows that per α (K) 0 for all positive integers α Exercises Let ψ be a complex-valued zero-mean process on some space with covariance function K(x, x ) = E(ψ(x) ψ(x )) Let x = {x 1,, x n } and x = {x 1,, x n} be two subsets of n points in the domain, possibly but not necessarily equal Use the matching argument given above to compute the joint cumulants cum 2n (ψ(x 1 ),, ψ(x n ), ψ(x 1),, ψ(x n)), cum n (ψ(x 1 ) ψ(x 1),, ψ(x n ) ψ(x n)), and the joint moment ( E ψ(x) ) ψ(x ) x x x x Both of these are complex numbers 152 Explain how the answers to the preceding exercise are modified if ψ is a real-valued Gaussian process 16 Exponential families 2 Generating functions and formal power series 21 The vector spaces Seq and Seq n To any sequence of scalars f = (f 1, f 2, ), in which f n is a scalar, we may associate a formal polynomial in a variable t by f(t) = f 1 t + f 2 t 2 /2! + f 3 t 3 /3! + + f n t n /n! + Thus f(t) is the generating function for the sequence f; we say it is a generating function of exponential type because f n is the coefficient of t n /n! in the polynomial In particular, the constant sequence with f n = 1 corresponds to the function exp(t) 1, while the sequence m n = ( 1) n 1 (n 1)! corresponds to the inverse function m(t) = log(1 + t) Some further examples are 16

17 given below Function Coefficient sequence f n f(t) (f 1, f 2, ) (1 t) 1 1 n! log(1 t) (n 1)! exp(t) 1 1 exp(e t 1) 1 B n (Bell number) log(1 + t) ( 1) n 1 (n 1)! (1 + t) α 1 α n = α(α 1) (α n + 1) Whether f is regarded as a sequence of scalars or as a formal polynomial, the set of such sequences or formal polynomials is denoted by Seq To say that f is a formal polynomial is to imply that certain operations on sequences f, g are carried out as if these were polynomials The simplest such operations are addition and scalar multiplication Thus if α is a scalar, αf is a sequence whose components are (αf 1, αf 2, ), and the associated polynomial is (αf)(t) = αf(t) Likewise, addition operates component-wise, so that f + g = (f 1 + g 1, f 2 + g 2,, f n + g n, ) (f + g)(z) = f(z) + g(z) The set of sequences with these operations of addition and scalar multiplication is a vector space denoted by Seq + The restriction to finite sequences of n components is a vector space of dimension n denoted by Seq + n 22 Composition of series Let g(ξ) be a formal power series of exponential type in the variable ξ g(ξ) = g r ξ r /r! r=1 Evidently each monomial g 2 (ξ), g 3 (ξ), is also a formal power series The coefficient of ξ n /n! in the monomial g 2 is g 2 (ξ)[ξ n /n!] = r+s=n n! r! s! g rg s where the sum runs over ordered pairs (r, s) in the square [n] 2 subject to the restriction that they add to n If n is odd, every pair occurs twice, once as 17

18 (r, s) and once as (s, r); if n is even, every pair occurs twice except for the pair on the diagonal with r = s = n/2 For example, if n = 6, the sum runs over pairs (1, 5), (2, 4), (3, 3), (4, 2), (5, 1) with transpose pairs contributing equally For combinatorial accounting purposes, it is more convenient to combine the symmetric pairs, in effect to ignore the order of the two parts Instead of summing over strictly positive integer vectors adding to n (compositions of n), we combine similar terms and sum over integer partitions having two parts For n = 6, the total contribution of the {1, 5} terms is 2! 6 g 1 g 5, the total contribution of the {2, 4} terms is 2! 15g 2 g 4 and the contribution of the (3, 3) term is 1! 20g3 2 = 2! 10g2 3 The number of partitions of [6] of type is 6, the number of type is 15, and the number of type 3 2 is 10 (not 20) For that reason, is most convenient to write the quadratic monomial as a sum over partitions of the set [n] into two blocks g 2 (ξ)[ξ n /n!] = r+s=n n! r! s! g rg s = 2! σ Pn:#σ=2 b σ g #b, where σ is a partition of [n], #σ is the number of elements (blocks), b σ is a block, and #b is the block size The extension to higher-order monomials follows the same pattern g 3 (ξ)[ξ n /n!] = g k (ξ)[ξ n /n!] = r+s+t=n r 1 + +r k =n n! r! s! t! g rg s g t = 3! σ P (3) n g #b b σ n! r 1! r k! g r 1 g rk = k! σ P (k) n g #b, b σ where P n (k) Pn is the subset of partitions having k blocks The first sum runs over k-part compositions of n, which are strictly positive integer vectors r = (r 1,, r k ) whose components add to n Two compositions consisting of the same components in a different order determine the same integer partition If the components of r are distinct integers, there are k! permutations giving rise to the same product, and n!/(r 1! r k!) is the number of partitions of the set [n] having k blocks of sizes r 1,, r k Otherwise, if some of the components of r are equal, the number of compositions giving rise to a particular product g r1 g rk is reduced by the product of the factorials of the multiplicities For example, if n = 10 and k = 4, the point r = (1, 2, 3, 4) gives rise to the product g 1 g 2 g 3 g 4, and there are k! compositions giving rise to the same product However, if n = 8 and k = 5, the 18

19 composition r = (2, 2, 2, 1, 1) gives rise to g2 3g2 1, but there are only k!/(3!2!) similar compositions giving rise to the same product To each integer partition m = 1 m 1 2 m2 n mn having k = m parts, there correspond k!/(m 1!m 2! ) compositions with parts r 1,, r k in some order In the expansion of g k (ξ), each composition r of n has a combinatorial factor n!/r! This means that the product associated with the integer partition m has a combinatorial factor g m = g m 1 1 gm 2 2 gn mn n! r 1! r k! k! m 1! m n! = n! k! j j!m j m j!, which is k! times the number of set partitions of [n] corresponding to the given integer partition In other words, these awkward combinatorial factors are automatically accommodated by summation over set partitions: g k (ξ) k! = n k ξ n n! σ P (k) n g #b Now let f be another formal power series of exponential type The compositional product fg is a sequence whose polynomial is f(g(ξ)) Note that fg is ordinarily different from gf, so the product operation is not commutative However, it is associative, so fgh is well defined By definition, the series expansion of the composition (f g)(ξ) is a linear combination of the monomials g k (ξ)/k! with coefficients f k, giving (fg)(ξ) = = k=1 n=1 (fg) n = σ Pn f k g k (ξ) k! ξ n n! σ Pn b σ f #σ f #σ g #b With this operation, the space of sequences or formal exponential generating functions is a vector space with a non-commutative compositional product (f, g) fg that is linear in the first argument but not in the second Exercises Use Faà di Bruno s formula to derive the coefficient (fg) n in the Taylor expansion of the composition b σ b σ g #b 19

20 23 Inverse function The unit sequence e = (1, 0, 0, ), ie, e(ξ) = ξ is the compositional identity satisfying eg = ge = g for every g If g is given with g 1 0, the compositional equation fg = e has a left-inverse solution, satisfying f 1 = g1 1, and recursively f n = g n 1 1 k<n for n > 1 This produces f 1 = g 1 1, f 2 g 3 1 = g 2, f 3 g 5 1 = g 1 g 3 + 3g 2 2 f 4 g 7 1 = g 4 g g 1 g 2 g 3 15g 3 2 σ P (k) n f k f 5 g 9 1 = g 5 g g 4 g 2 g g 2 3g g 3 g 2 2g g 4 2 f 6 g 11 1 = g 6 g g 5 g 2 g g 4 g 3 g g 4 g 2 2g g 2 3g 2 g g 3 g 3 2g 1 945g 5 2 Conversely, the equation gf = e has a right-inverse solution satisfying f 1 = g1 1, and subsequently fn = g1 1 g k f #b 1<k n σ P (k) n b σ b σ g #b for n > 1 This sequence produces the same solution, which is k 1 f k g1 k = ( 1) ν g ν ν=1 1 σ P ( ν) b σ k+ν 1 g #b for k > 1, where the sum runs over partitions of [k + ν 1] having ν nonsingleton blocks (Why?) Note that if g k = 1 for every k, then f = (1, 1, 2, 6, 24, 120, ), and the extension to general k 1 is f k = ( 1) k 1 (k 1)!; conversely, if f k = 1 for every k, then g k = ( 1) k 1 (k 1)! For f(ξ) = log(1 + ξ), the coefficients are f n = ( 1) n 1 (n 1)!, in which case log(1 + g(ξ))[ξ n /n!] = σ Pn( 1) n 1 (n 1)! b σ is the expression for the cumulant of order n in terms of moment products of total order n Conversely, for f(ξ) = exp(ξ) 1 with f n = 1, we obtain the expression for the moment of order n in terms of cumulant products of total order n 20 g #b

21 24 The vector spaces Seq and Seq n Consider now a different operation (convolution) on the space of sequences, one that is more readily understood as an operation on polynomials than as an operation on sequences For any scalar α and sequences f, g, define the sequences f g and α g by (f g)(ξ) = f(ξ) + g(ξ) + f(ξ)g(ξ), (α g)(ξ) = (1 + g(ξ)) α 1 Equivalently, 1+(f g)(ξ) = (1+f(ξ))(1+g(ξ)), showing that this operation is commutative: f g = g f In addition 1 f = f and f f = 2 f for every f, the zero vector is the zero sequence, and so on In terms of the augmented sequences with f 0 = g 0 = 1, the components of f g and α g are n ( ) n (f g) n = f j g n j j j=0 (α g) n = σ Pn α #σ b σ where σ Pn is a partition of [n] containing #σ blocks, and for each block b σ, #b is the number of elements The descending factorial product α r = α(α 1) (α r + 1) is the rth Taylor coefficient associated with the function (1 + ξ) α 1 The space of sequences with these operations is a vector space denoted by Seq, the vector-space properties being more obvious from the polynomial representation than the sequence representation The restriction to finite sequences of n components, or to polynomials of degree less than or equal to n, is an n-dimensional vector space denoted by Seq n, which may be identified with the subspace of Seq having zero components for r > n In Seq n the product 1 + (f g)(ξ) is the restriction of the polynomial product (1 + f(ξ))(1 + g(ξ)) to terms of degree n, so that (f g) r = 0 for r > n Likewise for α f This restriction by polynomial degree is a linear projection Seq Seq n, ie, it commutes with vector-space operations By a homomorphism, we mean a linear transformation T : Seq Seq that also acts on the finite-dimensional restrictions, ie T Seq n Seq n The set of such linear transformations is itself a vector space, closed under addition and scalar multiplication It is readily seen that the logarithmic transformation acting on polynomials 1+f(ξ) log(1+f(ξ)) carries polynomials in Seq to polynomials in Seq, and also carries Seq n to Seq n preserving 21 g #b

22 vector-space operations It is also apparent that there is essentially only one such transformation Thus Hom(Seq, Seq) is the one-dimensional space of linear transformations that are scalar multiples of (T g) 1 = g 1 (T g) 2 = g 2 g 2 1 (T g) 3 = g 3 3g 2 g 1 + 2g1 3 (T g) n = m #σ σ Pn where m r = ( 1) r 1 (r 1)! is the coefficient defining the logarithmic function m(t) = log(1+t) This T is of course, the transformation that generates cumulants from moments Despite the occurrence of multiplicative terms, T is a linear transformation Seq Seq on vector spaces b σ g #b 3 Approximation of distributions 31 Edgeworth approximation 32 Saddlepoint approximation 4 Samples and sub-samples A function f: R n R is symmetric if f(x 1,, x n ) = f(x P(1),, x P(n) ) for each permutation P of the arguments For example, the total T n = x x n, the average T n /n, the min, max and median are symmetric functions, as are the sum of squares S n = x 2 i, the sample variance s2 n = (S n T 2 n/n)/(n 1) and the mean absolute deviation x i x j /(n(n 1)) A vector x in R n is an ordered list of n real numbers (x 1,, x n ) or a function x: [n] R where [n] = {1,, n} For m n, a 1 1 function ϕ: [m] [n] is a sample of size m, the sampled values being xϕ = (x ϕ(1),, x ϕ(m) ) All told, there are n(n 1) (n m + 1) distinct samples of size m that can be taken from a list of length n A sequence of functions f n : R n R is consistent under subsampling if, for each f m, f n, f n (x) = ave ϕ f m (xϕ), where ave ϕ denotes the average over samples of size m For m = n, this condition implies only that f n is a symmetric function Although the total and the median are both symmetric functions, neither is consistent under subsampling For example, the median of the numbers 22

23 (0, 1, 3) is one, but the average of the medians of samples of size two is 4/3 However, the average x n = T n /n is sampling consistent Likewise the sample variance s 2 n = (x i x) 2 /(n 1) with divisor n 1 is sampling consistent, but the mean squared deviation (x i x n ) 2 /n with divisor n is not Other sampling consistent functions include Fisher s k-statistics, the first few of which are k 1,n = x n, k 2,n = s 2 n for n 2, k 3,n = n (x i x n ) 3 /((n 1)(n 2)) k 4,n = defined for n 3 and n 4 respectively For a sequence of independent and identically distributed random variables, the k-statistic of order r n is the unique symmetric function such that E(k r,n ) = κ r Fisher (1929) derived the variances and covariances The connection with finite-population sub-sampling was developed by Tukey (1954) 23

The rth moment of a real-valued random variable X with density f(x) is. x r f(x) dx

The rth moment of a real-valued random variable X with density f(x) is. x r f(x) dx 1 Cumulants 1.1 Definition The rth moment of a real-valued random variable X with density f(x) is µ r = E(X r ) = x r f(x) dx for integer r = 0, 1,.... The value is assumed to be finite. Provided that

More information

Notes on the symmetric group

Notes on the symmetric group Notes on the symmetric group 1 Computations in the symmetric group Recall that, given a set X, the set S X of all bijections from X to itself (or, more briefly, permutations of X) is group under function

More information

Cumulants and triangles in Erdős-Rényi random graphs

Cumulants and triangles in Erdős-Rényi random graphs Cumulants and triangles in Erdős-Rényi random graphs Valentin Féray partially joint work with Pierre-Loïc Méliot (Orsay) and Ashkan Nighekbali (Zürich) Institut für Mathematik, Universität Zürich Probability

More information

LECTURE 3: FREE CENTRAL LIMIT THEOREM AND FREE CUMULANTS

LECTURE 3: FREE CENTRAL LIMIT THEOREM AND FREE CUMULANTS LECTURE 3: FREE CENTRAL LIMIT THEOREM AND FREE CUMULANTS Recall from Lecture 2 that if (A, φ) is a non-commutative probability space and A 1,..., A n are subalgebras of A which are free with respect to

More information

Yao s Minimax Principle

Yao s Minimax Principle Complexity of algorithms The complexity of an algorithm is usually measured with respect to the size of the input, where size may for example refer to the length of a binary word describing the input,

More information

The illustrated zoo of order-preserving functions

The illustrated zoo of order-preserving functions The illustrated zoo of order-preserving functions David Wilding, February 2013 http://dpw.me/mathematics/ Posets (partially ordered sets) underlie much of mathematics, but we often don t give them a second

More information

ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS

ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS QRMC07 9/7/0 4:45 PM Page 5 CHAPTER SEVEN ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS 7. AN INTRODUCTION TO MATRICES Investors frequently encounter situations involving numerous potential outcomes, many discrete periods

More information

MAT 4250: Lecture 1 Eric Chung

MAT 4250: Lecture 1 Eric Chung 1 MAT 4250: Lecture 1 Eric Chung 2Chapter 1: Impartial Combinatorial Games 3 Combinatorial games Combinatorial games are two-person games with perfect information and no chance moves, and with a win-or-lose

More information

Asymptotic Notation. Instructor: Laszlo Babai June 14, 2002

Asymptotic Notation. Instructor: Laszlo Babai June 14, 2002 Asymptotic Notation Instructor: Laszlo Babai June 14, 2002 1 Preliminaries Notation: exp(x) = e x. Throughout this course we shall use the following shorthand in quantifier notation. ( a) is read as for

More information

Version A. Problem 1. Let X be the continuous random variable defined by the following pdf: 1 x/2 when 0 x 2, f(x) = 0 otherwise.

Version A. Problem 1. Let X be the continuous random variable defined by the following pdf: 1 x/2 when 0 x 2, f(x) = 0 otherwise. Math 224 Q Exam 3A Fall 217 Tues Dec 12 Version A Problem 1. Let X be the continuous random variable defined by the following pdf: { 1 x/2 when x 2, f(x) otherwise. (a) Compute the mean µ E[X]. E[X] x

More information

A relation on 132-avoiding permutation patterns

A relation on 132-avoiding permutation patterns Discrete Mathematics and Theoretical Computer Science DMTCS vol. VOL, 205, 285 302 A relation on 32-avoiding permutation patterns Natalie Aisbett School of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Sydney,

More information

Quadrant marked mesh patterns in 123-avoiding permutations

Quadrant marked mesh patterns in 123-avoiding permutations Quadrant marked mesh patterns in 23-avoiding permutations Dun Qiu Department of Mathematics University of California, San Diego La Jolla, CA 92093-02. USA duqiu@math.ucsd.edu Jeffrey Remmel Department

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Option Pricing. Chapter Discrete Time

Option Pricing. Chapter Discrete Time Chapter 7 Option Pricing 7.1 Discrete Time In the next section we will discuss the Black Scholes formula. To prepare for that, we will consider the much simpler problem of pricing options when there are

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

CATEGORICAL SKEW LATTICES

CATEGORICAL SKEW LATTICES CATEGORICAL SKEW LATTICES MICHAEL KINYON AND JONATHAN LEECH Abstract. Categorical skew lattices are a variety of skew lattices on which the natural partial order is especially well behaved. While most

More information

Statistics for Business and Economics

Statistics for Business and Economics Statistics for Business and Economics Chapter 5 Continuous Random Variables and Probability Distributions Ch. 5-1 Probability Distributions Probability Distributions Ch. 4 Discrete Continuous Ch. 5 Probability

More information

Higher Order Freeness: A Survey. Roland Speicher Queen s University Kingston, Canada

Higher Order Freeness: A Survey. Roland Speicher Queen s University Kingston, Canada Higher Order Freeness: A Survey Roland Speicher Queen s University Kingston, Canada Second order freeness and fluctuations of random matrices: Mingo + Speicher: I. Gaussian and Wishart matrices and cyclic

More information

CS134: Networks Spring Random Variables and Independence. 1.2 Probability Distribution Function (PDF) Number of heads Probability 2 0.

CS134: Networks Spring Random Variables and Independence. 1.2 Probability Distribution Function (PDF) Number of heads Probability 2 0. CS134: Networks Spring 2017 Prof. Yaron Singer Section 0 1 Probability 1.1 Random Variables and Independence A real-valued random variable is a variable that can take each of a set of possible values in

More information

ROM SIMULATION Exact Moment Simulation using Random Orthogonal Matrices

ROM SIMULATION Exact Moment Simulation using Random Orthogonal Matrices ROM SIMULATION Exact Moment Simulation using Random Orthogonal Matrices Bachelier Finance Society Meeting Toronto 2010 Henley Business School at Reading Contact Author : d.ledermann@icmacentre.ac.uk Alexander

More information

SYLLABUS AND SAMPLE QUESTIONS FOR MSQE (Program Code: MQEK and MQED) Syllabus for PEA (Mathematics), 2013

SYLLABUS AND SAMPLE QUESTIONS FOR MSQE (Program Code: MQEK and MQED) Syllabus for PEA (Mathematics), 2013 SYLLABUS AND SAMPLE QUESTIONS FOR MSQE (Program Code: MQEK and MQED) 2013 Syllabus for PEA (Mathematics), 2013 Algebra: Binomial Theorem, AP, GP, HP, Exponential, Logarithmic Series, Sequence, Permutations

More information

Probability. An intro for calculus students P= Figure 1: A normal integral

Probability. An intro for calculus students P= Figure 1: A normal integral Probability An intro for calculus students.8.6.4.2 P=.87 2 3 4 Figure : A normal integral Suppose we flip a coin 2 times; what is the probability that we get more than 2 heads? Suppose we roll a six-sided

More information

Non replication of options

Non replication of options Non replication of options Christos Kountzakis, Ioannis A Polyrakis and Foivos Xanthos June 30, 2008 Abstract In this paper we study the scarcity of replication of options in the two period model of financial

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V Hariharan Narayanan December 7, 2014 Martingales 1 Introduction Martingales were originally introduced into probability theory as a model for fair betting games. Essentially

More information

Permutation Factorizations and Prime Parking Functions

Permutation Factorizations and Prime Parking Functions Permutation Factorizations and Prime Parking Functions Amarpreet Rattan Department of Combinatorics and Optimization University of Waterloo Waterloo, ON, Canada N2L 3G1 arattan@math.uwaterloo.ca June 10,

More information

Laurence Boxer and Ismet KARACA

Laurence Boxer and Ismet KARACA SOME PROPERTIES OF DIGITAL COVERING SPACES Laurence Boxer and Ismet KARACA Abstract. In this paper we study digital versions of some properties of covering spaces from algebraic topology. We correct and

More information

Random variables. Contents

Random variables. Contents Random variables Contents 1 Random Variable 2 1.1 Discrete Random Variable............................ 3 1.2 Continuous Random Variable........................... 5 1.3 Measures of Location...............................

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

TABLEAU-BASED DECISION PROCEDURES FOR HYBRID LOGIC

TABLEAU-BASED DECISION PROCEDURES FOR HYBRID LOGIC TABLEAU-BASED DECISION PROCEDURES FOR HYBRID LOGIC THOMAS BOLANDER AND TORBEN BRAÜNER Abstract. Hybrid logics are a principled generalization of both modal logics and description logics. It is well-known

More information

Chapter 5. Continuous Random Variables and Probability Distributions. 5.1 Continuous Random Variables

Chapter 5. Continuous Random Variables and Probability Distributions. 5.1 Continuous Random Variables Chapter 5 Continuous Random Variables and Probability Distributions 5.1 Continuous Random Variables 1 2CHAPTER 5. CONTINUOUS RANDOM VARIABLES AND PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTIONS Probability Distributions Probability

More information

Higher Order Freeness: A Survey. Roland Speicher Queen s University Kingston, Canada

Higher Order Freeness: A Survey. Roland Speicher Queen s University Kingston, Canada Higher Order Freeness: A Survey Roland Speicher Queen s University Kingston, Canada Second order freeness and fluctuations of random matrices: Mingo + Speicher: I. Gaussian and Wishart matrices and cyclic

More information

START HERE: Instructions. 1 Exponential Family [Zhou, Manzil]

START HERE: Instructions. 1 Exponential Family [Zhou, Manzil] START HERE: Instructions Thanks a lot to John A.W.B. Constanzo and Shi Zong for providing and allowing to use the latex source files for quick preparation of the HW solution. The homework was due at 9:00am

More information

Financial Risk Forecasting Chapter 9 Extreme Value Theory

Financial Risk Forecasting Chapter 9 Extreme Value Theory Financial Risk Forecasting Chapter 9 Extreme Value Theory Jon Danielsson 2017 London School of Economics To accompany Financial Risk Forecasting www.financialriskforecasting.com Published by Wiley 2011

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Counting Basics. Venn diagrams

Counting Basics. Venn diagrams Counting Basics Sets Ways of specifying sets Union and intersection Universal set and complements Empty set and disjoint sets Venn diagrams Counting Inclusion-exclusion Multiplication principle Addition

More information

Notation, Conventions, and Conditional Expectations

Notation, Conventions, and Conditional Expectations Notation, Conventions, and Conditional Expectations A. General Variables and Indexes Notation in italics represents a scalar; notation in bold italics represents a vector or matrix. Uppercase notation

More information

THE NUMBER OF UNARY CLONES CONTAINING THE PERMUTATIONS ON AN INFINITE SET

THE NUMBER OF UNARY CLONES CONTAINING THE PERMUTATIONS ON AN INFINITE SET THE NUMBER OF UNARY CLONES CONTAINING THE PERMUTATIONS ON AN INFINITE SET MICHAEL PINSKER Abstract. We calculate the number of unary clones (submonoids of the full transformation monoid) containing the

More information

STAT 830 Convergence in Distribution

STAT 830 Convergence in Distribution STAT 830 Convergence in Distribution Richard Lockhart Simon Fraser University STAT 830 Fall 2013 Richard Lockhart (Simon Fraser University) STAT 830 Convergence in Distribution STAT 830 Fall 2013 1 / 31

More information

Course information FN3142 Quantitative finance

Course information FN3142 Quantitative finance Course information 015 16 FN314 Quantitative finance This course is aimed at students interested in obtaining a thorough grounding in market finance and related empirical methods. Prerequisite If taken

More information

ROM Simulation with Exact Means, Covariances, and Multivariate Skewness

ROM Simulation with Exact Means, Covariances, and Multivariate Skewness ROM Simulation with Exact Means, Covariances, and Multivariate Skewness Michael Hanke 1 Spiridon Penev 2 Wolfgang Schief 2 Alex Weissensteiner 3 1 Institute for Finance, University of Liechtenstein 2 School

More information

EVA Tutorial #1 BLOCK MAXIMA APPROACH IN HYDROLOGIC/CLIMATE APPLICATIONS. Rick Katz

EVA Tutorial #1 BLOCK MAXIMA APPROACH IN HYDROLOGIC/CLIMATE APPLICATIONS. Rick Katz 1 EVA Tutorial #1 BLOCK MAXIMA APPROACH IN HYDROLOGIC/CLIMATE APPLICATIONS Rick Katz Institute for Mathematics Applied to Geosciences National Center for Atmospheric Research Boulder, CO USA email: rwk@ucar.edu

More information

Stochastic Programming and Financial Analysis IE447. Midterm Review. Dr. Ted Ralphs

Stochastic Programming and Financial Analysis IE447. Midterm Review. Dr. Ted Ralphs Stochastic Programming and Financial Analysis IE447 Midterm Review Dr. Ted Ralphs IE447 Midterm Review 1 Forming a Mathematical Programming Model The general form of a mathematical programming model is:

More information

Collinear Triple Hypergraphs and the Finite Plane Kakeya Problem

Collinear Triple Hypergraphs and the Finite Plane Kakeya Problem Collinear Triple Hypergraphs and the Finite Plane Kakeya Problem Joshua Cooper August 14, 006 Abstract We show that the problem of counting collinear points in a permutation (previously considered by the

More information

Sampling Distribution

Sampling Distribution MAT 2379 (Spring 2012) Sampling Distribution Definition : Let X 1,..., X n be a collection of random variables. We say that they are identically distributed if they have a common distribution. Definition

More information

1102 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON INFORMATION THEORY, VOL. 51, NO. 3, MARCH Genyuan Wang and Xiang-Gen Xia, Senior Member, IEEE

1102 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON INFORMATION THEORY, VOL. 51, NO. 3, MARCH Genyuan Wang and Xiang-Gen Xia, Senior Member, IEEE 1102 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON INFORMATION THEORY, VOL 51, NO 3, MARCH 2005 On Optimal Multilayer Cyclotomic Space Time Code Designs Genyuan Wang Xiang-Gen Xia, Senior Member, IEEE Abstract High rate large

More information

DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION

DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION APPENDIX DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION PART 1 SUMMARIZATION 1: BUILDING BLOCKS OF DATA ANALYSIS 294 PART 2 PART 3 PART 4 VISUALIZATION: GRAPHS AND TABLES FOR SUMMARIZING AND ORGANIZING DATA 296

More information

Mean-Variance Analysis

Mean-Variance Analysis Mean-Variance Analysis Mean-variance analysis 1/ 51 Introduction How does one optimally choose among multiple risky assets? Due to diversi cation, which depends on assets return covariances, the attractiveness

More information

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon basso@unive.it, mnardon@unive.it Department of Applied Mathematics University Ca Foscari Venice Brownian motion p. 1 Brownian motion Brownian motion plays

More information

Modular and Distributive Lattices

Modular and Distributive Lattices CHAPTER 4 Modular and Distributive Lattices Background R. P. DILWORTH Imbedding problems and the gluing construction. One of the most powerful tools in the study of modular lattices is the notion of the

More information

1 Shapley-Shubik Model

1 Shapley-Shubik Model 1 Shapley-Shubik Model There is a set of buyers B and a set of sellers S each selling one unit of a good (could be divisible or not). Let v ij 0 be the monetary value that buyer j B assigns to seller i

More information

Quality Sensitive Price Competition in. Secondary Market Spectrum Oligopoly- Multiple Locations

Quality Sensitive Price Competition in. Secondary Market Spectrum Oligopoly- Multiple Locations Quality Sensitive Price Competition in 1 Secondary Market Spectrum Oligopoly- Multiple Locations Arnob Ghosh and Saswati Sarkar arxiv:1404.6766v3 [cs.gt] 11 Oct 2015 Abstract We investigate a spectrum

More information

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright Faculty and Institute of Actuaries Claims Reserving Manual v.2 (09/1997) Section D7 [D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright 1. Introduction

More information

Applications of Good s Generalized Diversity Index. A. J. Baczkowski Department of Statistics, University of Leeds Leeds LS2 9JT, UK

Applications of Good s Generalized Diversity Index. A. J. Baczkowski Department of Statistics, University of Leeds Leeds LS2 9JT, UK Applications of Good s Generalized Diversity Index A. J. Baczkowski Department of Statistics, University of Leeds Leeds LS2 9JT, UK Internal Report STAT 98/11 September 1998 Applications of Good s Generalized

More information

Supplementary Material for Combinatorial Partial Monitoring Game with Linear Feedback and Its Application. A. Full proof for Theorems 4.1 and 4.

Supplementary Material for Combinatorial Partial Monitoring Game with Linear Feedback and Its Application. A. Full proof for Theorems 4.1 and 4. Supplementary Material for Combinatorial Partial Monitoring Game with Linear Feedback and Its Application. A. Full proof for Theorems 4.1 and 4. If the reader will recall, we have the following problem-specific

More information

Exam M Fall 2005 PRELIMINARY ANSWER KEY

Exam M Fall 2005 PRELIMINARY ANSWER KEY Exam M Fall 005 PRELIMINARY ANSWER KEY Question # Answer Question # Answer 1 C 1 E C B 3 C 3 E 4 D 4 E 5 C 5 C 6 B 6 E 7 A 7 E 8 D 8 D 9 B 9 A 10 A 30 D 11 A 31 A 1 A 3 A 13 D 33 B 14 C 34 C 15 A 35 A

More information

UQ, STAT2201, 2017, Lectures 3 and 4 Unit 3 Probability Distributions.

UQ, STAT2201, 2017, Lectures 3 and 4 Unit 3 Probability Distributions. UQ, STAT2201, 2017, Lectures 3 and 4 Unit 3 Probability Distributions. Random Variables 2 A random variable X is a numerical (integer, real, complex, vector etc.) summary of the outcome of the random experiment.

More information

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice Prof. Massimo Guidolin Portfolio Management Spring 2016 Overview The inputs of portfolio problems Using the single index model Multi-index models Portfolio

More information

ME3620. Theory of Engineering Experimentation. Spring Chapter III. Random Variables and Probability Distributions.

ME3620. Theory of Engineering Experimentation. Spring Chapter III. Random Variables and Probability Distributions. ME3620 Theory of Engineering Experimentation Chapter III. Random Variables and Probability Distributions Chapter III 1 3.2 Random Variables In an experiment, a measurement is usually denoted by a variable

More information

Decision theoretic estimation of the ratio of variances in a bivariate normal distribution 1

Decision theoretic estimation of the ratio of variances in a bivariate normal distribution 1 Decision theoretic estimation of the ratio of variances in a bivariate normal distribution 1 George Iliopoulos Department of Mathematics University of Patras 26500 Rio, Patras, Greece Abstract In this

More information

Robustness, Canalyzing Functions and Systems Design

Robustness, Canalyzing Functions and Systems Design Robustness, Canalyzing Functions and Systems Design Johannes Rauh Nihat Ay SFI WORKING PAPER: 2012-11-021 SFI Working Papers contain accounts of scientific work of the author(s) and do not necessarily

More information

Determining source cumulants in femtoscopy with Gram-Charlier and Edgeworth series

Determining source cumulants in femtoscopy with Gram-Charlier and Edgeworth series Determining source cumulants in femtoscopy with Gram-Charlier and Edgeworth series M.B. de Kock a H.C. Eggers a J. Schmiegel b a University of Stellenbosch, South Africa b Aarhus University, Denmark VI

More information

Risk management. Introduction to the modeling of assets. Christian Groll

Risk management. Introduction to the modeling of assets. Christian Groll Risk management Introduction to the modeling of assets Christian Groll Introduction to the modeling of assets Risk management Christian Groll 1 / 109 Interest rates and returns Interest rates and returns

More information

Gamma Distribution Fitting

Gamma Distribution Fitting Chapter 552 Gamma Distribution Fitting Introduction This module fits the gamma probability distributions to a complete or censored set of individual or grouped data values. It outputs various statistics

More information

Central limit theorems

Central limit theorems Chapter 6 Central limit theorems 6.1 Overview Recall that a random variable Z is said to have a standard normal distribution, denoted by N(0, 1), if it has a continuous distribution with density φ(z) =

More information

Probability and distributions

Probability and distributions 2 Probability and distributions The concepts of randomness and probability are central to statistics. It is an empirical fact that most experiments and investigations are not perfectly reproducible. The

More information

I. Time Series and Stochastic Processes

I. Time Series and Stochastic Processes I. Time Series and Stochastic Processes Purpose of this Module Introduce time series analysis as a method for understanding real-world dynamic phenomena Define different types of time series Explain the

More information

On Complexity of Multistage Stochastic Programs

On Complexity of Multistage Stochastic Programs On Complexity of Multistage Stochastic Programs Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia 30332-0205, USA e-mail: ashapiro@isye.gatech.edu

More information

Saddlepoint Approximation Methods for Pricing. Financial Options on Discrete Realized Variance

Saddlepoint Approximation Methods for Pricing. Financial Options on Discrete Realized Variance Saddlepoint Approximation Methods for Pricing Financial Options on Discrete Realized Variance Yue Kuen KWOK Department of Mathematics Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Hong Kong * This is

More information

Contents. An Overview of Statistical Applications CHAPTER 1. Contents (ix) Preface... (vii)

Contents. An Overview of Statistical Applications CHAPTER 1. Contents (ix) Preface... (vii) Contents (ix) Contents Preface... (vii) CHAPTER 1 An Overview of Statistical Applications 1.1 Introduction... 1 1. Probability Functions and Statistics... 1..1 Discrete versus Continuous Functions... 1..

More information

Algebra and Number Theory Exercise Set

Algebra and Number Theory Exercise Set Algebra and Number Theory Exercise Set Kamil Niedzia lomski 1 Algebra 1.1 Complex Numbers Exercise 1. Find real and imaginary part of complex numbers (1) 1 i 2+i (2) (3 + 7i)( 3 + i) (3) ( 3+i)( 1+i 3)

More information

Introduction Recently the importance of modelling dependent insurance and reinsurance risks has attracted the attention of actuarial practitioners and

Introduction Recently the importance of modelling dependent insurance and reinsurance risks has attracted the attention of actuarial practitioners and Asymptotic dependence of reinsurance aggregate claim amounts Mata, Ana J. KPMG One Canada Square London E4 5AG Tel: +44-207-694 2933 e-mail: ana.mata@kpmg.co.uk January 26, 200 Abstract In this paper we

More information

Random Variables Handout. Xavier Vilà

Random Variables Handout. Xavier Vilà Random Variables Handout Xavier Vilà Course 2004-2005 1 Discrete Random Variables. 1.1 Introduction 1.1.1 Definition of Random Variable A random variable X is a function that maps each possible outcome

More information

Dynamic Programming: An overview. 1 Preliminaries: The basic principle underlying dynamic programming

Dynamic Programming: An overview. 1 Preliminaries: The basic principle underlying dynamic programming Dynamic Programming: An overview These notes summarize some key properties of the Dynamic Programming principle to optimize a function or cost that depends on an interval or stages. This plays a key role

More information

Order book resilience, price manipulations, and the positive portfolio problem

Order book resilience, price manipulations, and the positive portfolio problem Order book resilience, price manipulations, and the positive portfolio problem Alexander Schied Mannheim University PRisMa Workshop Vienna, September 28, 2009 Joint work with Aurélien Alfonsi and Alla

More information

Construction and behavior of Multinomial Markov random field models

Construction and behavior of Multinomial Markov random field models Graduate Theses and Dissertations Iowa State University Capstones, Theses and Dissertations 2010 Construction and behavior of Multinomial Markov random field models Kim Mueller Iowa State University Follow

More information

symmys.com 3.2 Projection of the invariants to the investment horizon

symmys.com 3.2 Projection of the invariants to the investment horizon 122 3 Modeling the market In the swaption world the underlying rate (3.57) has a bounded range and thus it does not display the explosive pattern typical of a stock price. Therefore the swaption prices

More information

On the Degeneracy of N and the Mutability of Primes

On the Degeneracy of N and the Mutability of Primes On the Degeneracy of N and the Mutability of Primes Jonathan Trousdale October 9, 018 Abstract This paper sets forth a representation of the hyperbolic substratum that defines order on N. Degeneracy of

More information

Slides for Risk Management

Slides for Risk Management Slides for Risk Management Introduction to the modeling of assets Groll Seminar für Finanzökonometrie Prof. Mittnik, PhD Groll (Seminar für Finanzökonometrie) Slides for Risk Management Prof. Mittnik,

More information

Asymptotic methods in risk management. Advances in Financial Mathematics

Asymptotic methods in risk management. Advances in Financial Mathematics Asymptotic methods in risk management Peter Tankov Based on joint work with A. Gulisashvili Advances in Financial Mathematics Paris, January 7 10, 2014 Peter Tankov (Université Paris Diderot) Asymptotic

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

The finite lattice representation problem and intervals in subgroup lattices of finite groups

The finite lattice representation problem and intervals in subgroup lattices of finite groups The finite lattice representation problem and intervals in subgroup lattices of finite groups William DeMeo Math 613: Group Theory 15 December 2009 Abstract A well-known result of universal algebra states:

More information

Normal distribution Approximating binomial distribution by normal 2.10 Central Limit Theorem

Normal distribution Approximating binomial distribution by normal 2.10 Central Limit Theorem 1.1.2 Normal distribution 1.1.3 Approimating binomial distribution by normal 2.1 Central Limit Theorem Prof. Tesler Math 283 Fall 216 Prof. Tesler 1.1.2-3, 2.1 Normal distribution Math 283 / Fall 216 1

More information

Chapter 1 Additional Questions

Chapter 1 Additional Questions Chapter Additional Questions 8) Prove that n=3 n= n= converges if, and only if, σ >. nσ nlogn) σ converges if, and only if, σ >. 3) nlognloglogn) σ converges if, and only if, σ >. Can you see a pattern?

More information

Conformal Invariance of the Exploration Path in 2D Critical Bond Percolation in the Square Lattice

Conformal Invariance of the Exploration Path in 2D Critical Bond Percolation in the Square Lattice Conformal Invariance of the Exploration Path in 2D Critical Bond Percolation in the Square Lattice Chinese University of Hong Kong, STAT December 12, 2012 (Joint work with Jonathan TSAI (HKU) and Wang

More information

Hints on Some of the Exercises

Hints on Some of the Exercises Hints on Some of the Exercises of the book R. Seydel: Tools for Computational Finance. Springer, 00/004/006/009/01. Preparatory Remarks: Some of the hints suggest ideas that may simplify solving the exercises

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION

UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION 1. George cantor is the School of Distance Education UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION General (Common) Course of BCom/BBA/BMMC (2014 Admn. onwards) III SEMESTER- CUCBCSS QUESTION BANK

More information

Secant Varieties, Symbolic Powers, Statistical Models

Secant Varieties, Symbolic Powers, Statistical Models Secant Varieties, Symbolic Powers, Statistical Models Seth Sullivant North Carolina State University November 19, 2012 Seth Sullivant (NCSU) Secant Varieties, etc. November 19, 2012 1 / 27 Joins and Secant

More information

Chapter 4 Continuous Random Variables and Probability Distributions

Chapter 4 Continuous Random Variables and Probability Distributions Chapter 4 Continuous Random Variables and Probability Distributions Part 2: More on Continuous Random Variables Section 4.5 Continuous Uniform Distribution Section 4.6 Normal Distribution 1 / 28 One more

More information

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance Chapter 8 Markowitz Portfolio Theory 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance The main question in portfolio theory is the following: Given an initial capital V (0), and opportunities (buy or sell) in N securities

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

Discrete Random Variables and Probability Distributions. Stat 4570/5570 Based on Devore s book (Ed 8)

Discrete Random Variables and Probability Distributions. Stat 4570/5570 Based on Devore s book (Ed 8) 3 Discrete Random Variables and Probability Distributions Stat 4570/5570 Based on Devore s book (Ed 8) Random Variables We can associate each single outcome of an experiment with a real number: We refer

More information

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California Santa Barbara Joint work with R. Sircar (Princeton) and K. Sølna (UC Irvine) Special Semester on Stochastics with Emphasis

More information

On the Optimality of a Family of Binary Trees Techical Report TR

On the Optimality of a Family of Binary Trees Techical Report TR On the Optimality of a Family of Binary Trees Techical Report TR-011101-1 Dana Vrajitoru and William Knight Indiana University South Bend Department of Computer and Information Sciences Abstract In this

More information

Logit Models for Binary Data

Logit Models for Binary Data Chapter 3 Logit Models for Binary Data We now turn our attention to regression models for dichotomous data, including logistic regression and probit analysis These models are appropriate when the response

More information

3.1 Measures of Central Tendency

3.1 Measures of Central Tendency 3.1 Measures of Central Tendency n Summation Notation x i or x Sum observation on the variable that appears to the right of the summation symbol. Example 1 Suppose the variable x i is used to represent

More information

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES D. S. SILVESTROV, H. JÖNSSON, AND F. STENBERG Abstract. A general price process represented by a two-component

More information

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis 16 MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis Contents 2 Interest Rates 16 2.1 Definitions.................................... 16 2.1.1 Rate of Return..............................

More information

Subject CS1 Actuarial Statistics 1 Core Principles. Syllabus. for the 2019 exams. 1 June 2018

Subject CS1 Actuarial Statistics 1 Core Principles. Syllabus. for the 2019 exams. 1 June 2018 ` Subject CS1 Actuarial Statistics 1 Core Principles Syllabus for the 2019 exams 1 June 2018 Copyright in this Core Reading is the property of the Institute and Faculty of Actuaries who are the sole distributors.

More information

Basic Procedure for Histograms

Basic Procedure for Histograms Basic Procedure for Histograms 1. Compute the range of observations (min. & max. value) 2. Choose an initial # of classes (most likely based on the range of values, try and find a number of classes that

More information