An Empirical Analysis of the Benefits of Inflation-Linked Bonds, Real Estate and Commodities for Long-Term Investors with Inflation-Linked Liabilities

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "An Empirical Analysis of the Benefits of Inflation-Linked Bonds, Real Estate and Commodities for Long-Term Investors with Inflation-Linked Liabilities"

Transcription

1 An Empirical Analysis of the Benefits of Inflation-Linked Bonds, Real Estate and Commodities for Long-Term Investors with Inflation-Linked Liabilities Lionel Martellini and Vincent Milhau January 25, 2013 Abstract This paper proposes an empirical analysis of the welfare gains involved in introducing various assets with attractive inflation-hedging properties for long-term investors facing inflation-linked liabilities. Using formal intertemporal spanning tests, we find that interest rate risk dominates inflation risk so dramatically within instantaneous liability risk that introducing inflation-linked bonds, commodities or real estate within the liability-hedging portfolio has relatively little impact on investors welfare from a shortterm perspective. This holds true in spite of the attractive (in the case of real assets) and even perfect (in the case of inflation-linked bonds) inflation-hedging benefits of these asset classes. On the other hand, substantial welfare gains are obtained as the investment horizon converges towards the liability maturity date. Even more substantial utility gains are obtained if these asset classes are also used in the performance-seeking portfolio, where they provide diversification benefits with respect to bond and equity returns. Lionel Martellini is aprofessor of finance at EDHEC Business School and the Scientific Director of EDHEC- Risk Institute. Vincent Milhau is the Deputy Scientific Director of EDHEC-Risk Institute. The author for correspondence is Lionel Martellini. He can be reached at EDHEC-Risk Institute, 400 Promenade des Anglais, BP 3116, Nice Cedex 3 France. Ph: +33 (0) Fax: +33 (0) lionel.martellini@edhec.edu. This research has benefitted from the support of the Advanced Investment Solutions for Liability Hedging for Inflation Risk research chair, supported by Ontario Teachers Pension Plan. We are grateful to Bernd Scherer for useful comments, and to Andrea Tarelli for helpful research assistance. 1

2 1 Introduction A recent surge in inflation uncertainty has increased the need for investors to hedge against unexpected changes in price levels. Inflation hedging is a concern of particularly critical importance for pension funds, in situations when pension payments are indexed with respect to consumer price or wage level indexes. The implementation of inflation-hedging portfolios has become relatively straightforward in specific contexts where either cash instruments (inflation-linked bonds, such as Treasury inflation protected securities, or TIPS) or dedicated OTC derivatives (such as inflation swaps) can be used to achieve effective inflation hedging. More generally, however, the lack of capacity for inflation-linked cash instruments and the increasing concern over counterparty risk for derivatives-based solutions leave most investors with the presence of non-hedgeable inflation risk. In this context, a variety of financial asset classes (stocks and bonds) and real asset classes (commodities or real estate in particular) have been analyzed in terms of their ability to provide attractive inflation-hedging benefits. The results of such empirical investigations, however, have been mixed. On the one hand, starting with traditional asset classes, stock investments appear as relatively poor inflation hedging vehicles from a short-term perspective (see Fama and Schwert (1977), Fama (1981), Gultekin (1983) and Kaul (1987) among others). On the other hand, stocks appear to offer significant inflation protection over long horizons (Boudoukh and Richardson (1993) or Schotman and Schweitzer (2000)). This property is a priori particularly appealing for long-term investors such as pension funds, who need to match increases in price level at the horizon, but not necessarily on a monthly basis. A similar discrepancy between short-term and long-term inflation-hedging properties is expected for bond returns. Moving beyond stocks and bonds, recent academic research has also suggested that alternative forms of investments may offer attractive inflation-hedging benefits. Commodity prices, in particular, have been found to be leading indicators of inflation in that they are quick to respond to economy-wide shocks to demand (see e.g. Gorton and Rouwenhorst (2006)). In the same spirit, it has also been found that commercial and residential real estate provide at least a partial hedge against inflation, an effect that seems to be particularly significant over long-horizons (see Fama and Schwert (1977), Hartzell et al. (1987), Rubens et al. (1989) or Anari and Kolari (2002)). The implications of such findings for asset-liability management(alm) have been discussed by Hoevenaars et al. (2008), who construct optimal mean-variance portfolios with respect to inflation-driven liabilities. In this paper, we argue that what should matter to investors endowed with liability objectives is not the inflation-hedging property of an asset class, but rather its ability to hedge liability risk. The two concepts are in general not equivalent, and they actually coincide only at the date when liabilities are paid. Indeed, the present value of inflation-indexed liabilities is impacted by both inflation risk and interest rate risk, through the discount factor. It turns out 2

3 that for reasonable parameter values, short-term (instantaneous) liability risk consists mostly of interest rate risk, especially if liabilities have a long duration. As a consequence, for our calibrated parameter values, a liability-hedging portfolio solely invested in nominal bonds already spans close to 90% of the instantaneous variance of 5-year inflation-indexed liabilities, a percentage that grows to 95% or 97% when maturity is extended to 10 or 15 years. In view of the low residual variances, introducing assets such as inflation-linked bonds or real assets can merely increase by a few percents the proportion of the variance of the liabilities that can be hedged by the liability-hedging portfolio. It is only for short horizons (e.g., a year) that the relative importance of inflation risk versus interest rate risk becomes substantial within total liability risk. While inflation risk hedging is not a meaningful problem from the short-term perspective, one would indeed expect its importance to increase substantially while getting close to horizon. At maturity, of course, exposure to interest rate risk is zero, which leaves inflation risk remain as the sole source of uncertainty. 1 As a result, nominal bonds, while extremely efficient at hedging liability risk from the short-term perspective, turn out to be extremely ill-suited from the long-term perspective. Therefore, it remains to measure the utility gains achieved by introducing various asset classes with attractive (real estate and commodities) or even perfect (inflation-linked bonds) in the liability-hedging portfolio. Our paper provides a quantitative measure of these gains, in the context of a formal long-term investment model. Our paper is of course not the first to analyze the long-term investment problem in the presence of inflation risk. In a continuous-time model similar to ours, Brennan and Xia (2002) show by mathematical arguments that the introduction of inflation-indexed bonds increases investor s welfare. In a discrete-time VAR model, Campbell et al. (2003) show that investors with infinite risk aversion and recursive utility from consumption hold only perpetual real bonds. Campbell et al. (2009) argue that inflation-linked bonds allow investors endowed with real liabilities to reduce the long-term risk of their portfolio more substantially than other asset classes would do. On a different note, they also point out that inflation-indexed bond prices provide information that are useful to infer inflation expectations, which is of interest for monetary authorities. 2 Other papers have studied the benefits of adding real assets to a portfolio of stocks and bonds. Froot (1995) defines real assets as assets that tend to increase in nominal value in the face of inflation and notes that commodities are good at diversifying stocks and nominal bonds. Using a discrete-time VAR, Hoevenaars et al. (2008) examine the properties of alternative classes such as commodities and real estate. They report that commodities have 1 We assume away longevity risk in this discussion, as in the rest of the paper. 2 Althoughcluesaboutinflationexpectationsaboundinfinancialmarkets, inflation-indexedsecuritieswould appear to be the most direct source of information about inflation expectations and real interest rates (Governor Ben S. Bernanke before the Investment Analysts Society of Chicago, April 15, Also quoted in Grishchenko and Huang (2008)). 3

4 both attractive inflation-hedging properties and low correlation with stocks and bonds, which make them well-suited for diversifying a portfolio. We complement these papers in several directions. First, our analysis is done in a continuoustime model with stochastic investment opportunities which allows for an analytical derivation of the optimal strategy. This model and its solution are not new (see e.g. Munk et al. (2004)), but we use them to derive term structures of inflation and liability-hedging qualities. The advantage of a continuous-time model over a VAR model as in Campbell et al. (2003) is that it allows to incorporate no-arbitrage restrictions and involves only interpretable parameters, while coefficients of VAR models lack interpretability. Second, we provide for the first time, based on reasonable parameter values calibrated to US data, a quantitative estimate of the welfare loss induced by removing inflation-indexed bonds from the liability-hedging portfolio, as opposed to analyzing the question from an asset-only perspective. This allows us to perform an independent analysis of the benefits of inflation-linked bonds, commodities or real estate for liability hedging purposes versus diversification purposes. The computation of welfare gains is based on the strategy that is optimal in the presence of the stochastic opportunity set, so that we do not have to assume a fixed-mix. Third, we assess the benefits of introducing real assets such as real estate and commodities, which have attractive but imperfect, inflationhedging properties. We also provide a detailed analysis of the term structure of welfare gains, which sheds new light on the conflicting results obtained when addressing the question of liability-hedging from a short-term or a long-term perspective. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we introduce the model and we calibrate it to market data. In Section 3 we analyze the welfare losses related to removing inflation-linked bonds from liability-hedging portfolios. In Section 4, we extend the analysis to real estate and commodities, which are found to have attractive, albeit imperfect, inflation hedging properties. Section 5 concludes and proposes a number of suggestions for further research. Technical details are relegated to a dedicated appendix. 2 The Model In this section, we present the model and the notation and we derive the optimal portfolio strategy. 2.1 Financial Variables Uncertainty in the economy is modeled by a standard probability space (Ω, A,P). The finite time span if [0,τ L ], where τ L is the maturity of liabilities. Innovations are modelled as the innovations to a 5-dimensional Brownian motion z. 4

5 The nominal short-term rate evolves as (Vasicek, 1977): dr t = a(b r t )dt+σ rdz t, (2.1) where z r is a Brownian motion. There exists a locally risk-free asset, the bank account, whose value is St 0 = e t 0 rsds. The zero-coupon yield of maturity τ is given by: y(t,τ) = D(τ) τ where b = b σrλr a, λ r is the price of interest rate risk, and: D(τ) = 1 e aτ a r t C(τ), (2.2) τ ], C(τ) = b[d(τ) τ]+ σ2 r [τ 2D(τ)+ 1 e 2aτ. (2.3) 2a 2a The investor has access to a constant-maturity bond index with maturity τ B = 10 years, whose price evolves as: db t B t = [r t D(τ B )σ r λ r ] dt D(τ B )σ rdz t. (2.4) In addition to the bond index, the investor can also trade in a stock index S with stochastic Sharpe ratio (Kim and Omberg, 1996): ds t = [ ] r t +σ S λ S t dt+σs dzt S, (2.5) S t dλ S t = κ ( ) λ λ S t dt+σ λ σ λdz t. (2.6) The real asset Y (real estate or commodity) evolves as: and the stochastic price index as: dy t Y t = [r t +σ Y λ Y ] dt+σ Y dz t, dφ t Φ t = πdt+σ Φdz t. (2.7) Liabilities are represented by an inflation-indexed zero-coupon bond(as in Hoevenaars et al. (2008) and Detemple and Rindisbacher (2008)), that is a zero-coupon that pays Φ τl at the maturity date τ L. From Martellini and Milhau (2012), the value of liabilities is: [ ] MτL L t = E t Φ τl = Φ t exp[ D(τ L t)r t +E(τ L t)], t τ L, (2.8) M t 5

6 with: E(u) = ( b σ ) rλ r [D(u) u]+(π σ Φ λ Φ )u σ rσ Φ ρ rφ a a + σ2 r 2a 2 [u 1 e au a ] [u 2 1 e au a ] + 1 e 2au. 2a More generally, we denote with I(t,τ) the price at date t of an indexed bond maturing at date τ. A straightforward application of Ito s lemma to (2.8) shows that the dynamics of L is: dl t L t = [r t D(τ L t)σ r λ r +σ Φ λ Φ ] dt D(τ L t)σ rdz t +σ Φdz t. (2.9) Hence the volatility vector of liabilities is σ L (τ L t) = D(τ L t)σ r +σ Φ. The volatility matrix σ collects the volatility vectors of all traded assets (except cash, which is locally risk-free). Thus, it depends on the investment universe. In this paper, we shall consider various investment universes, but all of them contain at least the nominal bond. The spanned price of risk vector λ also depends on the investment universe considered, but it can always be written as an affine function of the stochastic Sharpe ratio: λ t = Λ 1 +λ S t Λ 2, t 0. The market is in general incomplete, because of the presence of unspanned sources of risk (Sharpe ratio risk and/or inflation risk). Hence, there exist infinitely many price of risk vectors, which are those vectors of the form λ+ν, where ν satisfies σ ν t = 0 for all date t. Each of them gives rise to a pricing kernel: [ t M t = exp 0 (r s + λ ) s 2 + ν s 2 ds Optimal Portfolio Choice t 0 (λ s +ν s ) dz s ], t 0. (2.10) We now solve for the optimal portfolio policy for an investor facing the opportunity set described in section 2. The portfolio is self-financed, so the strategy is completely characterized by the vector w t that collects the weights allocated to the locally risky assets at time t. If the weights do not sum up to one, cash is used to make the balance. Thus, the value A of a portfolio evolves according to the following budget equation: da t A t = (r t +w tσ λ t ) dt+w tσ dz t. 6

7 The investor has horizon T, which we assume to be less than or equal to the maturity of liabilities (T τ L ). He is not explicitly concerned with asset value at date T, but instead with asset value relative to liability value L T. Different strategies are therefore compared on the basis of the expected utility from the terminal funding ratio A T /L T. In this paper, we will consider the Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA) utility function: U(x) = x1 γ 1 γ, x > 0. With these specifications, the portfolio choice problem can be written as the problem of maximizing expected utility from terminal real wealth: [ ( )] max E AT U. (2.11) w L T To solve this problem, we follow the related literature that considers the problem of maximizing expected utility from real wealth (see e.g. Brennan and Xia (2002), Munk et al. (2004) and Sangvinatsos and Wachter(2005)). The solution technique is the martingale approach, which is based on the equivalence between the dynamic problem (2.11) and a static problem where the control variable is the terminal wealth. As shown by He and Pearson (1991), in an incomplete market, the solution involves the minimax pricing kernel, which is the pricing kernel obtained with a special ν denoted ν in (2.10). The following proposition gives a description of the solution. The derivation of a similar result can be found in Martellini and Milhau (2010). Proposition 1 wt = λpsp t where: γσt PSP The optimal portfolio rule is given by: ( wt PSP ) ( βt L wt LHP 1 1 γ γ ) [C2 ] (T t)+c 3 (T t)λ S t β λ w λ, wt PSP 1 = (σ σ) 1 σ λ 1 (σ σ) 1 σ t, λ t wt LHP 1 = 1 (σ σ) 1 σ σ L (τ L t) (σ σ) 1 σ σ L (τ L t), w λ 1 = σ) 1 σ σ λ, 1 (σ σ) 1 σ σ λ(σ The functions C 1, C 2 and C 3 are solutions to ordinary differential equations: Ċ 3 = 1 γ γ (2.12) [ [ ] σ 2 λ (1 γ)σ λnσ λ C κ 1 γ γ σ λλ 2 ]C 3 + Λ 2 2, (2.13) γ 7

8 Ċ 2 = Λ 2σ L (τ L T + )+ Λ 2[Λ 1 σ L (τ L T + )] γ + 1 γ [ ] σ 2 γ λ (1 γ)σ λnσ λ C2 C 3 + [ κλ+ 1 γ γ σ λ[λ 1 σ L (τ L T + )]+ (1 γ)2 γ [ κ 1 γ ] γ σ λλ 2 C 2 ] σ λnσ L (τ L T + ) C 3, (2.14) Ċ 1 = D(τ L T + )σ r λ r σ Φ λ Φ +Λ 1σ L (τ L T + )+ Λ 1 σ L (τ L T + ) 2 + [ κλ+ 1 γ (1 γ)2 σ L (τ L T + ) Nσ L (τ L T + )+ 1 2γ 2 σ2 λc 3 [ ] σ 2 λ (1 γ)σ λnσ λ C γ 2γ γ σ λ[λ 1 σ L (τ L T + )]+ (1 γ)2 γ 2γ ] σ λnσ L (τ L T + ) C 2, (2.15) with N being the matrix of the projection onto the orthogonal space of the columns of σ: N = I σ(σ σ) 1 σ. The decomposition (2.12) is standard, in view of the results of Detemple and Rindisbacher (2010), who establish a general separation formula for optimal portfolios, and of those of Munk et al. (2004), who study a model close to ours. The first building block is the performanceseeking portfolio (PSP). The allocation to this block is increasing in its Sharpe ratio, and decreasing in its volatility and in the risk aversion. The second building block is the liabilityhedging portfolio (LHP), which, by construction, has the highest squared correlation with innovations to the liability value. This maximum correlation is equal to one only if liability risk is spanned, which is equivalent here to saying that inflation risk is spanned (interest rate risk is already spanned by the nominal bond). The allocation to the LHP is increasing in the risk aversion, which makes sense since risk-averse investors seek to reduce the volatility of their funding ratio. It is also increasing in the beta of liabilities with respect to the LHP, a parameter that measures how well the LHP replicates liabilities. The third building block is the Sharpe ratio-hedging portfolio, that is the portfolio that best hedges unexpected changes in the Sharpe ratio. The allocation to this block is decreasing, as opposed to increasing, in the beta, since the investor prefers to hold assets that are negatively correlated with the Sharpe ratio. In practice, this portfolio is mostly invested in stocks, because of their strongly negative correlation with Sharpe ratio (see Barberis (2000), Xia (2001) and our own calibration in Subsection 2.4 below). 8

9 2.3 Expected Utility for the Class of Affine Strategies In the empirical sections (3 and 4) of this paper, we will compute the expected utility of various portfolio strategies based on different investment universes. For computational efficiency, it is of high interest to have closed-form expressions for these expected utilities. 3 As shown in the next proposition, quasi-analytical expressions can be derived for strategies such that the volatility vector of wealth is affine in the Sharpe ratio λ S : σw t = H 1 (T t)+λ S t H 2 (T t), (2.16) where H 1 and H 2 are functions of the time-to-horizon T t. Note that the optimal strategy (2.12) fits into this category. The next proposition gives a quasi-analytical expression for the expected utility. It extends a similar result established by Sangvinatsos and Wachter (2005) to the case where not all state variables are spanned by traded assets. Proposition 2 Assume that the vector of weights is of the form (2.16). Then the expected utility from terminal funding ratio is given by: E t [U ( AT L T )] = U ( At L t ) h(t,λ S t ) γ, where: [ [ 1 γ h(t,λ S t ) = exp E 1 (T t)+e 2 (T t)λ S t + 1 γ 2 E 3(T t) ( ]] ) λ S 2 t, and the functions E 1, E 2 and E 3 are solutions to the following ODEs: E 3 = (1 γ)σ 2 λe [(1 γ)σ λh 2 κ]e 3 +2H 2Λ 2 γ H 2 2, E 2 = H 1Λ 2 +H 2[Λ 1 +(1 γ)σ L (τ L T + )] γh 1H 2 +(1 γ)σ 2 λe 2 E 3 + [ κλ+(1 γ)[h 1 σ L (τ L T + )] σ λ ] E3 +[ κ+(1 γ)h 2σ λ ]E 2, 3 In the absence of such expressions, expected utility can be computed with Monte-Carlo simulations, which increases computation time. 9

10 E 1 = D(τ L T + )σ r λ r σ Φ λ Φ +H 1Λ 1 (1 γ)h 1σ L (τ L T + ) γ 2 H γ 2 σ L (τ L T + ) γ σ 2 2 λe σ2 λe 3 + [ κλ+(1 γ)σ λ[h 1 σ L (τ L T + )] ] E 2. This result will allow us to compute the Monetary Utility Loss of using a strategy (a) as opposed to a strategy (b): by definition, the MUL is the capital that must be invested in (a) in addition to A 0 in order to achieve the same expected utility as by investing A 0 in (b). It follows from the previous proposition that the MUL can be computed in quasi-closed form, and is given by: MUL A 0 = [ ] h (b) (0,λ S 0) γ 1 γ h (a) (0,λ S 0) In particular, the ratio MUL A 0 is independent from A Model Calibration 1. (2.17) We calibrate the model to quarterly US data. For the nominal term structure, we use nominal yields on 3-month T-bills and on Government Bonds of maturities 1 year, 3 years, 5 years and 10 years, which are available from Bloomberg over the period Q to Q The US Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers is obtained from the Federal Reserve Economic Database, for the period from Q to Q The stock index is represented by the S&P500, which is available from CRSP over the period Q to Q Since the Sharpe ratio is not directly observable, we relate it to an observable predictor of stock returns, as is usual in the literature on stock return predictability. Following Campbell and Viceira (1999), we assume that the expected excess return on the index is an affine function of the dividend yield, computed as the sum of dividends paid over the last four quarters, divided by the current index value: [ E t log S ] t+ t ( t)y(t, t) = mdy t +p, (2.18) S t It can be shown that this equality implies an affine relationship between the Sharpe ratio and the dividend yield, λ S t = mdy t + p. Finally we consider real estate and commodities in the real asset class. The real estate index used is the National Council of Real Estate Investment Fiduciaries Property Index (NCREIF), available from Bloomberg from Q to Q1.2011: a non-reits index has been chosen so as to avoid artificial exposure to the stock market. Commodities are represented by the S&P Goldman Sachs Commodity Index (GSCI), available from Q to Q We estimate model parameters by maximizing the likelihood of observations, except for 10

11 the price of inflation risk, λ Φ, which we estimate from breakeven inflation rates: BEI(t,τ) = y(t,τ) y I (t,τ), where y I (t,τ) denotes the real yield of maturity τ. Real yields with maturities τ = 10, 20 and 30 years are available from Bloomberg over Q to Q It follows from the expression of an indexed zero-coupon price (see e.g. Martellini and Milhau (2012)) that: BEI(t,τ) = π σ Φ λ Φ σ rσ Φ ρ rφ a The price of inflation risk can then be approximated as: λ Φ 1 σ Φ 1 n [1 1 e aτ aτ n [BEI(t i,τ) π ti ], i=1 and we take the University of Michigan Inflation Expectation, available in the Federal Reserve Economic Database, as a proxy for the expected inflation rate π ti. This implies λ Φ =65.25% for τ = 5 years, 61.10% for τ = 10 years and 53.33% for τ = 30 years. We retain a value of 60%. Results are shown in Table 1, together with the standard errors of estimators. Unsurprisingly, parameters that relate to risk premia (λ r, λ Y, m and p) are estimated with relatively low precisions, with standard deviations representing approximately 30% to 100% of the point estimate. Figure 1 shows the Sharpe ratio implied by the postulated relation between expected returns and the dividend yield. ]. 3 Is Inflation Risk Prominent in Liability Risk? The volatility vector of liabilities can be broken down into a contribution of interest rate and a contribution of inflation: σ L (τ L t) = D(τ L t)σ r +σ Φ. In this section we give a quantitative measure of the relative importance of interest rate risk and inflation risk. 3.1 Short-Term Liability Risk To illustrate that interest rate risk is dominant from a short-term perspective when the maturity of liabilities is sufficiently large, we compute absolute value of the instantaneous correlation 11

12 between LHP and liabilities, which is the ratio: σ(σ σ) 1 σ σ L (τ L t). (3.1) σ L (τ L t) The square of the ratio(3.1) can be interpreted as a percentage of total variance of liabilities that is explained by the traded assets. In Table 2 we consider various investment universes, which lead to different LHPs. In this table and in the following figures, I denotes an inflationlinked of constant maturity equal to ten years. As this bond has a constant duration, it does not perfectly replicate the value of liabilities, which have a decreasing duration. We also consider different values for the time to maturity τ L t, namely 1, 5, 10 and 15 years. It turns out that the correlation is already greater than 98% for a LHP of nominal bonds only and a horizon of five years or more. In these conditions, the marginal benefits of incorporating stocks and/or real assets into the LHP can only be marginal: at most 10 bp of correlation are gained. Another salient feature is that asset classes such as equity, real estate and commodities have low instantaneous correlations with liabilities: they are lower than 10% for stocks for all maturities, and they slightly exceed 50% only for real estate. It is clear from the numbers reported that nominal bonds are needed in order to attain a high correlation with liabilities. A perfect instantaneous correlation can be achieved in only two situations: either the LHP contains only an inflation-linked bond with the same maturity as the liability, or the LHP contains both an indexed bond of any maturity, and a nominal bond. Indeed, if the maturity of liability differs from that of the indexed bond, a duration adjustment is needed so as to match the respective exposures to interest rate risk of the LHP and the liabilities. 3.2 Long-Term Analysis As long-term correlations between LHPs and liabilities can differ substantially from short-term ones, we now turn to a long-term analysis. We consider the following portfolio strategy, that is obtained by deleting the demands for the PSP and for the Sharpe ratio-hedging portfolio in (2.12): w t = β L t w LHP t. The correlation between the wealth generated by this strategy and liabilities, to which we shall simply refer as the correlation between the LHP and liabilities, can be derived in closed form for various investment horizons. Figure 2 displays the term structure of correlations for four different LHPs (nominal bonds only, and nominal bonds with either real estate, commodities or inflation-indexed bonds), and the two extreme maturities for liabilities (1 year and 15 years). Unsurprisingly, the correlation increases in the number of assets, because the relative importance of the unhedgeable part in liability risk decreases. When inflation-linked bonds 12

13 are included together with nominal bonds, a perfect correlation is achieved at all horizons. For imperfect LHPs, the correlation is always much larger at short horizons than at maturity. It is also interesting to note that for liability maturities of five to fifteen years, the correlation stays between 90% and 100% for horizons comprised between one quarter and about two thirds of the maturity, and then rapidly decreases. Then it reaches a minimum, and then starts to grow just before maturity, but the increase does not make up for the previous decrease and the correlation levels observed at short horizons are never recovered at maturity. Overall, it turns out that a LHP that does not contain inflation-indexed bonds has a rather low correlation with liabilities, always less than 50%, over investment periods that have the same length as the maturity of liabilities. 3.3 Utility Cost of Imperfect Inflation Hedging The correlation between wealth and liabilities provides a measure of the fraction of longterm liability risk that is hedged by traded assets, but it does not fully represent investor s preferences. Instead, the utility of the terminal funding ratio A T /L T measures the welfare generated by a given allocation strategy. To assess the welfare loss induced by the impossibility to hedge completely liability risk, we compute the Monetary Utility Loss (MUL) of a strategy that employs only nominal bonds or only nominal bonds and stocks in the LHP, with respect to a strategy that also uses inflation-indexed bonds. In order to isolate the benefits of inflation-indexed bonds from a liability-hedging perspective, we keep the composition of the PSP and of the Sharpe ratio-hedging portfolio constant. Formally, we denote with Wt PSP and W λ these portfolios when they are computed with nominal bonds and stocks only, and we consider two LHPs: W LHP,(a1) t is invested in nominal bonds and stocks only, while W LHP,(b1) t also contains indexed bonds. The compositions of these portfolios are obtained by using the expressions of Proposition 1, where the volatility matrix σ and the price of risk vector λ are adapted to the investment universe. We then consider strategies (a1) and (b1): wt i = λpsp t γσt PSP ( Wt PSP ) β L,i γ t W LHP,i t ( 1 1 γ ) [C2 ] (T t)+c 3 (T t)λ S t β λ W λ, (3.2) where i = (a1) or (b1). Note that the beta of liabilities with respect to the LHP depends on the LHP considered. 4 We compute the MUL of strategy (a) with respect to (b), using (2.17). Since the utility cost depends on the risk aversion γ, which is not observable, we set 4 Functions C 2 and C 3 are obtained by numerically solving the ODEs of Proposition 1. In order to have the same values of C 2 (T t) and C 3 (T t) for both strategies (a) and (b), we solve the ODEs under the assumption that the investment universe contains the three asset classes (recall that the investment universe has an impact on C 2 and C 3 through the matrices Λ 1, Λ 2 and N). 13

14 this parameter so as to achieve target allocations to the PSP at date 0 of 75%, 30% and 15% respectively: the implied (rounded) values of γ are 6, 15 and 30. The corresponding allocations to stocks at date 0, which can also be computed from (2.12), are %, 68.51% and 36.96%. Utility losses of removing indexed bonds from the LHP are reported in Figure 3. The MUL appears to be increasing in the risk aversion parameter, which happens for two reasons. First, with a higher γ, the investor allocates more to the LHP. Any change in the composition of the LHP will thus have a greater impact. Second, a higher γ means that the investor penalizes more the uncertainty in the final funding ratio. The MUL also appears to be increasing in the investment horizon, which is a straightforward effect since a longer horizon magnifies the effects of imperfect liability hedging. Overall, the MULs reported in Figure 3 do not seem prohibitively high over short-horizons, but more substantial welfare gains/losses are obtained as the time-horizon converges towards the liability maturity date. For example, if γ = 30 (which corresponds to a conservative initial allocation of about 15% in the PSP), the MULs are less than 2% of initial wealth for a liability maturity of one year, but they reach 24% at horizon for a maturity of 15 years. In an attempt to assess the economic significance of these utility costs, we have computed, for comparison purposes, the cost of ignoring predictability in stock returns. In this exercise, we have assumed that the investor has access only to nominal bonds, stocks and cash, and has the choice between the following two options: (a2) ignore the predictability in excess stock returns and treat λ S as if it was a constant parameter equal to λ; (b2) follow the strategy that is actually optimal in the presence of stochastic interest rate and stochastic equity risk premium, as described in Proposition 1. With the former strategy, the hedging demand against equity risk premium risk becomes zero, and the PSP is a fixed-mix portfolio. Figure 4 shows the MULs for different investment horizons and different levels of risk aversion. Of course, the utility cost of treating the Sharpe ratio as a constant is virtually zero for a horizon as short as one year, because mean reversion is a long-term phenomenon. Moreover, this cost is decreasing in the risk aversion because ignoring predictability hurts less investors who have only a small fraction of their holdings invested in stocks. Comparing these utility losses with those induced by imperfect liability hedging, it can be seen that the utility cost of ruling out inflation-indexed bonds from the LHP is larger than that of ignoring predictability for highly risk-averse investors (γ = 30) and a liability maturity of 1 year. For the 15-year liabilities, the utility cost of imperfect hedging is larger, except when the investment horizon approaches 15 years, but the two costs at the horizon are similar to each other (24.03% for imperfect hedging vs 26.16% for predictability). On the other hand, for little risk averse investors, who initially invest 50% or 75% of their wealth in the PSP, the utility cost of ignoring predictability is larger. These results show that perfectly hedging liability risk is more important than taking into account predictability for highly risk-averse investors, but that it is less important for 14

15 investors with low or medium risk aversion. 4 Benefits of Real Assets for Liability Hedging and Diversification Purposes In this section, we measure the benefits of real estate and commodities both from a liabilityhedging perspective and from a global perspective, that encompasses both their diversification properties and their ability to hedge inflation risk and equity premium risk. 4.1 Utility Cost (Gain) of Excluding (Including) Real Assets from (in) the LHP We first measure the utility cost of excluding real assets from the LHP, in the same way as we computed the utility cost of excluding indexed bonds in Subsection 3.3. We still assume that the PSP and the Sharpe ratio-hedging portfolio are invested in nominal bonds and stocks only (portfolios denoted with Wt PSP and W λ in Subsection 3.3). But there are two versions of the LHP: a LHP of nominal bonds and stocks only, denoted with W LHP,(a3) t, and a LHP invested in nominal bonds, stocks and one real asset class (commodities or real estate), denoted with W LHP,(b3) t. The three building blocks are combined as in (3.2). Figure 5 shows the MUL of strategy (a3) with respect to (b3), that is the utility cost of removing commodities from the LHP. Figure 6 reports similar results for the real estate class. These utility losses never exceed 3% of initial wealth, and are in all cases significantly smaller than those reported in Figure 3. Hence the marginal gains of adding real assets to a LHP of nominal bonds and stocks are far smaller than those of including inflation-linked bonds in the LHP. As a result, a LHP composed of nominal bonds, stocks and commodities or real estate does not represent a significant improvement over a LHP made of nominal bonds and stocks only. 4.2 Utility Cost (Gain) of Excluding (Including) Real Assets from (in) All Building Blocks Beyond their usefulness, or lack thereof, for liability-hedging purposes, real assets may also be useful in the performance-seeking component of investors portfolios due to their positive risk premia and their relatively low correlations with stocks and bonds, which makes them attractive for diversification purposes. To investigate more formally the benefits of including real assets in the PSP, we compute the utility loss of the optimal strategy that uses nominal bonds and stocks with respect to the optimal strategy invested in these two classes plus one 15

16 real asset class. This MUL aggregates the benefits of real asset in terms of liability hedging, diversification (within the PSP), as well as possibly Sharpe-ratio risk hedging within the dedicated intertemporal hedging demand. Results are shown in Figures 7 and 8. A first observation is that the MUL is now higher for more aggressive investors (γ = 6 or 15) than for conservative ones (γ = 30), which contrasts with Figure 3, where the MUL was increasing in the risk aversion. In other words, the MUL of excluding commodities or real estate from the investment universe is higher for investors who allocate a significant fraction of wealth (here 75% or 50%) to the PSP than for those who invest mainly in the LHP (15% in the PSP). This result suggests that the benefits of real assets are in fact to be found in the PSP more than in the LHP. For liabilities of maturity 15 years, the least risk-averse investor must invest 13% more in stocks and bonds to achieve the same expected utility as with these two classes plus commodities after 15 years, and 23% more to achieve the same expected utility as with the two traditional classes and real estate. These utility costs are substantial, although they are still much lower than the utility cost of ignoring predictability, which reaches 91.6% for the same investor. Nevertheless, they are much higher than the utility costs of excluding real assets from the LHP only, which hardly reach 3%. These results therefore suggest that real assets provide benefits to long-term investors, even in situations where their usefulness is limited in terms of inflation and liability hedging purposes. 5 Conclusion This paper proposes an empirical analysis of the opportunity costs involved in removing various financial and real assets with attractive inflation-hedging properties for long-term investors facing inflation-linked liabilities. We find that instantaneous liability risk is srongly dominated by interest rate risk, due to the discount factor, so that a liability-hedging portfolio of nominal bonds only provides already a very high correlation with liabilities. In this context, the gain in correlation of introducing inflation-indexed bonds or real assets is only marginal. On the long run, the perspective is different, since inflation risk becomes relatively more important, and in fact remains the only source of uncertainty at the date liabilities are paid off. Nevertheless, we find that for reasonable parameter values, the utility cost of excluding inflation-indexed bonds from the liability-hedging portfolio is lower than that of ignoring predictability in stock returns, except for very conservative investors. Finally, we analyze the utility cost of excluding real estate and commodities either from the liability-hedging portfolio only, or from all building blocks. The cost of giving up real assets in the liability-hedging portfolio only is found to be very low, but the cost of excluding them from all building blocks appears to be much more substantial. The added value of these asset classes thus appears to come mainly from their diversification benefits with respect to equities and bonds. 16

17 Our work could be extended in several dimensions. One important extension would be to analyze how our results might be affected by the introduction of a stochastic expected inflation component. One key concern relates in particular to a possible increase in expected inflation, which would lead to a drop in nominal bond prices without a corresponding impact on liability values, thus weakaning the performance of nominal bonds in hedging short-term rrisk for longterm inflation-linked liabilities. 5 Finally, the analysis in this paper does not tell us what would be the marginal welfare impact of improving inflation/liability hedging properties of asset classes that are substantial ingredients in the performance-seeking portfolio. In particular, we leave for further research an analysis of the welfare benefits of equity portfolios constructed to have improved long-term liability hedging properties (see for example Ang et al. (2012) for an analysis of the crosss-sectional dispersion in inflation betas within the equity universe). 5 A long-only position in nominal bonds will always have a negative exposure to changes in unexpected inflation. On the other hand, it is possible in principle to design a long-short nominal bonds portfolio strategy that achieves zero exposure to changes in unexpected inflation, while having an exposure to changes in real rate equal to that of the liabilities. Implementing such portfolio strategies, however, may not be feasible for investors subject to no shortsales constraints. 17

18 Table 1: Maximum Likelihood estimates. Nominal short-term rate: dr t = a(b r t )dt+σ rdz t. Estimate. Standard deviation. a b σ r λ r Stock price process: ds t /S t = [ ] r t +σ S λ S t dt+σ S dz t. Estimate. Standard deviation. σ S Sharpe ratio: dλ S t = κ ( ) [ λ λ S t dt+σ λ dz t, E t log St+ t S t ] ( t)y(t, t) = mdy t +p. Estimate. Standard deviation. κ λ σ λ m p Price index process: dφ t /Φ t = πdt+σ Φ dzφ t. Estimate. Standard deviation. π σ Φ λ Φ Real asset process: dy t /Y t = ( r t +σ Y λ Y) dt+σ Y dz t. Real estate. Commodities. Estimate. Standard deviation. Estimate. Standard deviation. σ Y λ Y Correlations. Estimate. Standard deviation. ρ rs ρ rλ ρ rφ ρ Sλ ρ SΦ ρ λφ Real estate. Commodities. Estimate. Standard deviation. Estimate. Standard deviation. ρ SY ρ ry ρ λy ρ ΦY Volatilities of residuals in bond yields. Estimate. Standard deviation. s 1Y < s 3Y < s 5Y < s 10Y < Estimates for all parameter values except λ Φ have been obtained by maximizing the log-likelihood of quarterly observations on US market. Standard deviations have been computed by taking the square roots of diagonal elements of the inverse of Fisher s information matrix.

19 Table 2: Decomposition of liability risk into spanned risk and unspanned risk. Time-to-maturity (years) LHP Corr. % Var. Corr. % Var. Corr. % Var. Corr. % Var. B S 0.43 < < < Com RE I B, S B, Com B, RE B, S, Com B, S, RE B, I This table shows the absolute value of the correlation between LHP and liability (column Corr.), as well as the percentage of the total variance of liabilities that is explained by the base assets (column % Var.). Eleven LHPs are considered, based on the following assets: nominal bonds of constant maturity 10 years (B), stocks (S), commodities (Com), real estate (RE) and indexed bonds of constant maturity 10 years (I). Parameter values are taken from Table 1. 19

20 Figure 1: Implied Sharpe ratio and total return index. 200 Sharpe ratio (%) Sharpe ratio Index Total return index ($) 80 Q Q Q The instantaneous Sharpe ratio of the S&P 500 index is estimated from the dividend yield, with the relationship λ S t = mdy t + p, where m and p are estimated by analyzing quarterly data over the period Q to Q The total return index series of the of S&P 500 is also obtained from CRSP. Its value is taken equal to $ 1 on January 1st, Figure 2: Term structures of correlation of liability-hedging portfolios with liabilities. (a) Liability maturity 1 year. (b) Liability maturity 15 years. Correlation B B, RE B, Com B, I 1/4 1/2 3/4 1 Horizon (years) Correlation B B, RE B, Com B, I Horizon (years) This figure shows the model-implied correlations between the wealth generated by a strategy that fully invests in the LHP and the cash, and the liabilities. Liabilities are represented by an inflation-indexed bond with initial maturity τ L equal to 1 or 15 years. The LHP is computed over one of the following four investment universes: nominal bonds and stocks (B, S); nominal bonds and real estate (B, RE); nominal bonds and commodities (B, Com); nominal bonds and inflation-indexed bonds (B, I). Parameters are set to the calibrated values (see Table 1). 20

21 Figure 3: Utility cost of giving up indexed bonds in the liability-hedging portfolio. (a) Liability maturity 1 year. (b) Liability maturity 15 years MUL (%) γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = 30 1/4 1/2 3/4 1 Investment horizon (years) MUL (%) γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = Investment horizon (years) Monetary utility loss (MUL) is expressed as the percentage by which initial capital must be increased for the investor to be willing to give up inflation-indexed bonds in the LHP, which leaves only stocks and nominal bonds in the LHP. Liabilities are represented by an inflation-indexed bond with initial maturity τ L equal to 1 or 15 year(s), and the investment horizon varies from one quarter to τ L. We consider three values for the risk aversion γ. Other parameters are set to the calibrated values (see Table 1), and the initial values r 0 and λ 0 are taken equal to the long-term means b and λ. Figure 4: Utility cost of ignoring predictability in stock returns. (a) Liability maturity 1 year. (b) Liability maturity 15 years γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = 30 MUL (%) MUL (%) /4 1/2 3/4 1 Investment horizon (years) Investment horizon (years) Monetary utility loss (MUL) is expressed as the percentage by which initial capital must be increased for the investor to be willing to ignore time variation in the Sharpe ratio of the stock index. The suboptimal strategy assumes a constant Sharpe ratio and ignores the hedging demand against changes in this parameter. Liabilities are represented by an inflation-indexed bond with initial maturity τ L equal to 1 or 15 year(s), and the investment horizon varies from one quarter to τ L. We consider three values for the risk aversion γ. Other parameters are set to the calibrated values (see Table 1), and the initial values r 0 and λ 0 are taken equal to the long-term means b and λ. 21

22 Figure 5: Utility cost of excluding commodities from the liability-hedging portfolio. (a) Liability maturity 1 year. (b) Liability maturity 15 years. MUL (%) γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = 30 1/4 1/2 3/4 1 Investment horizon (years) MUL (%) γ = γ = 15 γ = Investment horizon (years) Monetary utility loss (MUL) is expressed as the percentage by which initial capital must be increased for the investor to be willing to replace a LHP of nominal bonds, stocks and commodities by a LHP of nominal bonds and stocks only. Liabilities are represented by an inflation-indexed bond with initial maturity τ L equal to 1 or 15 year(s), and the investment horizon varies from one quarter to τ L. We consider three values for the risk aversion γ. Other parameters are set to the calibrated values (see Table 1), and the initial value λ S 0 is taken equal to the long-term mean λ. Figure 6: Utility cost of excluding real estate from the liability-hedging portfolio. (a) Liability maturity 1 year. (b) Liability maturity 15 years MUL (%) MUL (%) γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = 30 1/4 1/2 3/4 1 Investment horizon (years) 0.5 γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = Investment horizon (years) Monetary utility loss (MUL) is expressed as the percentage by which initial capital must be increased for the investor to be willing to replace a LHP of nominal bonds, stocks and real estate by a LHP of nominal bonds and stocks only. Liabilities are represented by an inflation-indexed bond with initial maturity τ L equal to 1 or 15 year(s), and the investment horizon varies from one quarter to τ L. We consider three values for the risk aversion γ. Other parameters are set to the calibrated values (see Table 1), and the initial value λ S 0 is taken equal to the long-term mean λ. 22

23 Figure 7: Utility cost of excluding commodities from all building blocks. (a) Liability maturity 1 year. (b) Liability maturity 15 years γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = /4 1/2 3/4 1 Investment horizon (years) Investment horizon (years) Monetary utility loss (MUL) is expressed as the percentage by which initial wealth must be increased for the investor to be willing to exclude commodities from the investment universe when he has the opportunity to invest in nominal bonds, stocks, commodities and cash. We consider three levels of risk aversion γ. The liability portfolio is a fixed-maturity indexed bond of initial maturity τ L equal to 1 or 15 year(s), and we let the investment horizon vary from one quarter to τ L. We consider three values for the risk aversion γ. Other parameters are set to the calibrated values (see Table 1), and the initial value λ S 0 is taken equal to the long-term mean λ. Figure 8: Utility cost of excluding real estate from all building blocks. (a) Liability maturity 1 year. (b) Liability maturity 15 years γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = γ = 6 γ = 15 γ = /4 1/2 3/4 1 Investment horizon (years) Investment horizon (years) Monetary utility loss (MUL) is expressed as the percentage by which initial wealth must be increased for the investor to be willing to exclude real estate from the investment universe when he has the opportunity to invest in nominal bonds, stocks, commodities and cash. We consider three levels of risk aversion γ. The liability portfolio is a fixed-maturity indexed bond of initial maturity τ L equal to 1 or 15 year(s), and we let the investment horizon vary from one quarter to τ L. We consider three values for the risk aversion γ. Other parameters are set to the calibrated values (see Table 1), and the initial value λ S 0 is taken equal to the long-term mean λ. 23

Life-Cycle Investing in Private Wealth Management

Life-Cycle Investing in Private Wealth Management An EDHEC-Risk Institute Publication Life-Cycle Investing in Private Wealth Management October 2011 with the support of Institute Table of Contents Executive Summary 5 1. Introduction 7 2. Optimal Allocation

More information

Labor income and the Demand for Long-Term Bonds

Labor income and the Demand for Long-Term Bonds Labor income and the Demand for Long-Term Bonds Ralph Koijen, Theo Nijman, and Bas Werker Tilburg University and Netspar January 2006 Labor income and the Demand for Long-Term Bonds - p. 1/33 : Life-cycle

More information

Analysing and Decomposing the Sources of Added-Value of Corporate Bonds Within Institutional Investors Portfolios

Analysing and Decomposing the Sources of Added-Value of Corporate Bonds Within Institutional Investors Portfolios An EDHEC-Risk Institute Publication Analysing and Decomposing the Sources of Added-Value of Corporate Bonds Within Institutional Investors Portfolios August 2013 with the support of Institute Table of

More information

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle Resolution of a Financial Puzzle M.J. Brennan and Y. Xia September, 1998 revised November, 1998 Abstract The apparent inconsistency between the Tobin Separation Theorem and the advice of popular investment

More information

Portfolio Selection with Randomly Time-Varying Moments: The Role of the Instantaneous Capital Market Line

Portfolio Selection with Randomly Time-Varying Moments: The Role of the Instantaneous Capital Market Line Portfolio Selection with Randomly Time-Varying Moments: The Role of the Instantaneous Capital Market Line Lars Tyge Nielsen INSEAD Maria Vassalou 1 Columbia University This Version: January 2000 1 Corresponding

More information

Equity Portfolios with Improved Liability-Hedging Benefits

Equity Portfolios with Improved Liability-Hedging Benefits An EDHEC-Risk Institute Publication Equity Portfolios with Improved Liability-Hedging Benefits December 2014 with the support of Institute 2 Printed in France, December 2014. Copyright EDHEC 2014. The

More information

Asset-Liability Management in Private Wealth Management

Asset-Liability Management in Private Wealth Management An EDHEC-Risk Publication Asset-Liability Management in Private Wealth Management September 2009 with the support of Table of Contents Executive Summary...5 Introduction...9 1. A Formal Model of Asset-Liability

More information

Modeling Yields at the Zero Lower Bound: Are Shadow Rates the Solution?

Modeling Yields at the Zero Lower Bound: Are Shadow Rates the Solution? Modeling Yields at the Zero Lower Bound: Are Shadow Rates the Solution? Jens H. E. Christensen & Glenn D. Rudebusch Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Term Structure Modeling and the Lower Bound Problem

More information

Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques

Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques Day 1: Equilibrium Models and the Dynamics of Bond Returns Pietro Veronesi Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago CEPR, NBER Bank

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Dynamic Relative Valuation Dynamic Relative Valuation Liuren Wu, Baruch College Joint work with Peter Carr from Morgan Stanley October 15, 2013 Liuren Wu (Baruch) Dynamic Relative Valuation 10/15/2013 1 / 20 The standard approach

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes Stochastics & Computational Finance 2015 Xuecan CUI Jang SCHILTZ University of Luxembourg July 9, 2015 Xuecan CUI, Jang SCHILTZ University

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios

Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios Matti Koivu Teemu Pennanen June 19, 2013 Abstract Bond returns are known to exhibit mean reversion, autocorrelation and other dynamic properties that differentiate

More information

Measuring the Benefits of Dynamic Asset Allocation Strategies in the Presence of Liability Constraints

Measuring the Benefits of Dynamic Asset Allocation Strategies in the Presence of Liability Constraints An EDHEC Risk and Asset Management Research Centre Publication Measuring the Benefits of Dynamic Asset Allocation Strategies in the Presence of Liability Constraints March 2009 in partnership with Table

More information

Vayanos and Vila, A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Stru. the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Vayanos and Vila, A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Stru. the Term Structure of Interest Rates Vayanos and Vila, A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates December 4, 2007 Overview Term-structure model in which investers with preferences for specific maturities and arbitrageurs

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II Dynamic Portfolio Choice II Dynamic Programming Leonid Kogan MIT, Sloan 15.450, Fall 2010 c Leonid Kogan ( MIT, Sloan ) Dynamic Portfolio Choice II 15.450, Fall 2010 1 / 35 Outline 1 Introduction to Dynamic

More information

A THREE-FACTOR CONVERGENCE MODEL OF INTEREST RATES

A THREE-FACTOR CONVERGENCE MODEL OF INTEREST RATES Proceedings of ALGORITMY 01 pp. 95 104 A THREE-FACTOR CONVERGENCE MODEL OF INTEREST RATES BEÁTA STEHLÍKOVÁ AND ZUZANA ZÍKOVÁ Abstract. A convergence model of interest rates explains the evolution of the

More information

Dynamic Asset-Liability Management with Inflation Hedging and Regulatory Constraints

Dynamic Asset-Liability Management with Inflation Hedging and Regulatory Constraints Dynamic Asset-Liability Management with Inflation Hedging and Regulatory Constraints Huamao Wang, Jun Yang Kent Centre for Finance, University of Kent, Canterbury, Kent CT2 7NZ, UK. Abstract We examine

More information

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle Tolga Cenesizoglu March 1, 2016 Cenesizoglu Return Decomposition & the Business Cycle March 1, 2016 1 / 54 Introduction Stock prices depend on investors expectations

More information

Institute. Yale School of Management EDHEC-Risk Institute Strategic Asset Allocation and Investment Solutions Seminar

Institute. Yale School of Management EDHEC-Risk Institute Strategic Asset Allocation and Investment Solutions Seminar Institute Yale School of Management EDHEC-Risk Institute Strategic Asset Allocation and Investment Solutions Seminar November 12-13, 2013, Yale Campus (New Haven, CT) - USA Yale SOM EDHEC-Risk Strategic

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles : A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles, JF (2004) Presented by: Esben Hedegaard NYUStern October 12, 2009 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Long-Run Risk Solving the 3 Data and Calibration Results

More information

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Hans U. Gerber and Gérard Pafumi Switzerland Abstract In the first part of the paper the surplus of a company is modelled by a Wiener process.

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University November 2007 Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance measurement of investment strategies 2 Market

More information

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets M. Grasselli Mathematics and Statistics McMaster University IMPA - June 28, 2006 Strategic Decision Making Suppose we want to assign monetary values to

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes A Simple Martingale Method Approach Frank Thomas Seifried University of Kaiserslautern March 20, 2009 F. Seifried (Kaiserslautern) Deferred Capital

More information

A Multifrequency Theory of the Interest Rate Term Structure

A Multifrequency Theory of the Interest Rate Term Structure A Multifrequency Theory of the Interest Rate Term Structure Laurent Calvet, Adlai Fisher, and Liuren Wu HEC, UBC, & Baruch College Chicago University February 26, 2010 Liuren Wu (Baruch) Cascade Dynamics

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

The Evolution of Value-Added in Private Wealth Management and the Asset-Liability Management Approach

The Evolution of Value-Added in Private Wealth Management and the Asset-Liability Management Approach The Evolution of Value-Added in Private Wealth Management and the Asset-Liability Management Approach London-Zürich-Luxembourg, September 28 th -30 th, 2010 Noël Amenc, PhD. Director, EDHEC-Risk Institute

More information

Operational Risk. Robert Jarrow. September 2006

Operational Risk. Robert Jarrow. September 2006 1 Operational Risk Robert Jarrow September 2006 2 Introduction Risk management considers four risks: market (equities, interest rates, fx, commodities) credit (default) liquidity (selling pressure) operational

More information

Life-Cycle Models with Stock and Labor Market. Cointegration: Insights from Analytical Solutions

Life-Cycle Models with Stock and Labor Market. Cointegration: Insights from Analytical Solutions Life-Cycle Models with Stock and Labor Market Cointegration: Insights from Analytical Solutions Daniel Moos University of St. Gallen This Version: November 24, 211 First Version: November 24, 211 Comments

More information

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice 1/ 57 Introduction Assuming that asset prices follow di usion processes, we derive an individual s continuous

More information

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives John Crosby Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Presentation at Baruch College, in New York, 16th November 2010

More information

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Martin Schenk Actuarial & Insurance Solutions SAV 7 March 2014 Agenda Introduction Deterministic vs. stochastic approach Mathematical model Application

More information

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Jerry Tsai University of Oxford Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania December 12, 2014 and NBER A The iid model This section

More information

Does the Failure of the Expectations Hypothesis Matter for Long-Term Investors?

Does the Failure of the Expectations Hypothesis Matter for Long-Term Investors? THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LX, NO. FEBRUARY 005 Does the Failure of the Expectations Hypothesis Matter for Long-Term Investors? ANTONIOS SANGVINATSOS and JESSICA A. WACHTER ABSTRACT We solve the portfolio

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

Currency Hedging for Long Term Investors with Liabilities

Currency Hedging for Long Term Investors with Liabilities Currency Hedging for Long Term Investors with Liabilities Gerrit Pieter van Nes B.Sc. April 2009 Supervisors Dr. Kees Bouwman Dr. Henk Hoek Drs. Loranne van Lieshout Table of Contents LIST OF FIGURES...

More information

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing /49 Introduction We present models of asset pricing where investors preferences are subject to psychological biases or where investors

More information

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1 Computational Finance Computational Finance p. 1 Outline Binomial model: option pricing and optimal investment Monte Carlo techniques for pricing of options pricing of non-standard options improving accuracy

More information

SUPPLEMENT TO THE LUCAS ORCHARD (Econometrica, Vol. 81, No. 1, January 2013, )

SUPPLEMENT TO THE LUCAS ORCHARD (Econometrica, Vol. 81, No. 1, January 2013, ) Econometrica Supplementary Material SUPPLEMENT TO THE LUCAS ORCHARD (Econometrica, Vol. 81, No. 1, January 2013, 55 111) BY IAN MARTIN FIGURE S.1 shows the functions F γ (z),scaledby2 γ so that they integrate

More information

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management Omar El Euch and Mathieu Rosenbaum École Polytechnique 4 October 2017 Omar El Euch and Mathieu Rosenbaum

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1) Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1) Part I: Discrete-time finance Exercise 1 (20 points) a. Provide the definition of the pricing kernel k q. Relate this pricing kernel to the set of discount factors D

More information

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model Chapter Portfolio Selection The theory of option pricing is a theory of deterministic returns: we hedge our option with the underlying to eliminate risk, and our resulting risk-free portfolio then earns

More information

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class March 30, 2015 1. (20 points) An agent has Y 0 = 1 to invest. On the market two financial assets exist. The first one is riskless.

More information

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default T. Bielecki, M. Jeanblanc and M. Rutkowski Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, 6 February 2006 1 Based on N. Vaillant (2001) A

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Pricing Unexpected Growth Fluctuations Lars Peter Hansen 1 2007 Nemmers Lecture, Northwestern University 1 Based in part joint work with John Heaton, Nan Li,

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations?

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations? What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations? Bernard Dumas INSEAD, Wharton, CEPR, NBER Alexander Kurshev London Business School Raman Uppal London Business School,

More information

Interest rate models and Solvency II

Interest rate models and Solvency II www.nr.no Outline Desired properties of interest rate models in a Solvency II setting. A review of three well-known interest rate models A real example from a Norwegian insurance company 2 Interest rate

More information

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios A Martingale Approach Frank Thomas Seifried Department of Mathematics, University of Kaiserslautern June 23, 2010 (Bachelier 2010) Worst-Case Portfolio

More information

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling Interest rate modeling Abstract In this paper, three models were used to forecast short term interest rates for the 3 month LIBOR. Each of the models, regression time series, GARCH, and Cox, Ingersoll,

More information

Supplementary online material to Information tradeoffs in dynamic financial markets

Supplementary online material to Information tradeoffs in dynamic financial markets Supplementary online material to Information tradeoffs in dynamic financial markets Efstathios Avdis University of Alberta, Canada 1. The value of information in continuous time In this document I address

More information

An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model

An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model I. Assumptions Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Notes on An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model These notes are based on the article Robert C. Merton (1973) An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing

More information

Variable Annuity and Interest Rate Risk

Variable Annuity and Interest Rate Risk Variable Annuity and Interest Rate Risk Ling-Ni Boon I,II and Bas J.M. Werker I October 13 th, 2017 Netspar Pension Day, Utrecht. I Tilburg University and Netspar II Université Paris-Dauphine Financial

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

Market interest-rate models

Market interest-rate models Market interest-rate models Marco Marchioro www.marchioro.org November 24 th, 2012 Market interest-rate models 1 Lecture Summary No-arbitrage models Detailed example: Hull-White Monte Carlo simulations

More information

Linearity-Generating Processes, Unspanned Stochastic Volatility, and Interest-Rate Option Pricing

Linearity-Generating Processes, Unspanned Stochastic Volatility, and Interest-Rate Option Pricing Linearity-Generating Processes, Unspanned Stochastic Volatility, and Interest-Rate Option Pricing Liuren Wu, Baruch College Joint work with Peter Carr and Xavier Gabaix at New York University Board of

More information

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems M.I.T. 15.450-Fall 2010 Sloan School of Management Professor Leonid Kogan Practice Problems 1. Consider a 3-period model with t = 0, 1, 2, 3. There are a stock and a risk-free asset. The initial stock

More information

Global Currency Hedging

Global Currency Hedging Global Currency Hedging JOHN Y. CAMPBELL, KARINE SERFATY-DE MEDEIROS, and LUIS M. VICEIRA ABSTRACT Over the period 1975 to 2005, the U.S. dollar (particularly in relation to the Canadian dollar), the euro,

More information

Risk Neutral Valuation

Risk Neutral Valuation copyright 2012 Christian Fries 1 / 51 Risk Neutral Valuation Christian Fries Version 2.2 http://www.christian-fries.de/finmath April 19-20, 2012 copyright 2012 Christian Fries 2 / 51 Outline Notation Differential

More information

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model (joint work with J. Dong and L. Korobenko) A. Deniz Sezer University of Calgary April 28, 2016 Merton s model of corporate debt A corporate bond is a contingent

More information

Hedging Derivative Securities with VIX Derivatives: A Discrete-Time -Arbitrage Approach

Hedging Derivative Securities with VIX Derivatives: A Discrete-Time -Arbitrage Approach Hedging Derivative Securities with VIX Derivatives: A Discrete-Time -Arbitrage Approach Nelson Kian Leong Yap a, Kian Guan Lim b, Yibao Zhao c,* a Department of Mathematics, National University of Singapore

More information

How to Time the Commodity Market

How to Time the Commodity Market EDHEC RISK AND ASSET MANAGEMENT RESEARCH CENTRE 393-400 promenade des Anglais 06202 Nice Cedex 3 Tel.: +33 (0)4 93 18 32 53 E-mail: research@edhec-risk.com Web: www.edhec-risk.com How to Time the Commodity

More information

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk Portfolio optimization problem with default risk M.Mazidi, A. Delavarkhalafi, A.Mokhtari mazidi.3635@gmail.com delavarkh@yazduni.ac.ir ahmokhtari20@gmail.com Faculty of Mathematics, Yazd University, P.O.

More information

Financial Risk Management

Financial Risk Management Financial Risk Management Professor: Thierry Roncalli Evry University Assistant: Enareta Kurtbegu Evry University Tutorial exercices #3 1 Maximum likelihood of the exponential distribution 1. We assume

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU CBOE Conference on Derivatives and Volatility, Chicago, Nov. 10, 2017 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 11/10/2017 1 / 33 Interest Rates

More information

Estimation of dynamic term structure models

Estimation of dynamic term structure models Estimation of dynamic term structure models Greg Duffee Haas School of Business, UC-Berkeley Joint with Richard Stanton, Haas School Presentation at IMA Workshop, May 2004 (full paper at http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/duffee)

More information

Investment, Income, and Incompleteness

Investment, Income, and Incompleteness Investment, Income, and Incompleteness February 15, 2009 The paper contains graphs in color. Use color printer for best result. Björn Bick a email: bick@finance.uni-frankfurt.de Department of Finance,

More information

A Robust Quantitative Framework Can Help Plan Sponsors Manage Pension Risk Through Glide Path Design.

A Robust Quantitative Framework Can Help Plan Sponsors Manage Pension Risk Through Glide Path Design. A Robust Quantitative Framework Can Help Plan Sponsors Manage Pension Risk Through Glide Path Design. Wesley Phoa is a portfolio manager with responsibilities for investing in LDI and other fixed income

More information

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models David Prager 1 1 Associate Professor of Mathematics Anderson University (SC) Based on joint work with Professor Qing Zhang,

More information

Implementing an Agent-Based General Equilibrium Model

Implementing an Agent-Based General Equilibrium Model Implementing an Agent-Based General Equilibrium Model 1 2 3 Pure Exchange General Equilibrium We shall take N dividend processes δ n (t) as exogenous with a distribution which is known to all agents There

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets René Garcia Edhec Business School, Université de Montréal, CIRANO and CIREQ Georges Tsafack Suffolk University Measuring

More information

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model he Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model Vladimir Vovk he Game-heoretic Probability and Finance Project Working Paper #39 September 6, 011 Project web site: http://www.probabilityandfinance.com

More information

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing Nicola Pavoni October 21, 2016 The Lucas Tree Model This is a general equilibrium model where instead of deriving properties of

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns 1/ 38 Introduction We analyze the Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model (ICAPM) of Robert Merton (1973). The standard single-period CAPM holds when

More information

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Eni Musta Università degli studi di Pisa San Miniato - 16 September 2016 Overview 1 Self-financing portfolio 2 Complete

More information

EDHEC-Risk Days Europe 2015

EDHEC-Risk Days Europe 2015 EDHEC-Risk Days Europe 2015 Bringing Research Insights to Institutional Investment Professionals 23-25 Mars 2015 - The Brewery - London The valuation of privately-held infrastructure equity investments:

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

2.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing

2.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing Chapter Monte-Carlo Simulation.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing Suppose that F T is the payoff at T for a European-type derivative f. Then the price at times t before T is given by f t = e r(t

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Macro II Chapter 5 Macro and Finance 1 Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Main references : - L. Ljundqvist and T. Sargent, Chapter 7 - Mehra and Prescott 1985 JME paper - Jerman 1998 JME paper - J.

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 Stochastic Financial Modelling Time allowed: 2 hours Candidates should attempt all questions. Marks for each question

More information

Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING. Agenda. Agenda (Cont.) Traditional Measures of Market Risk

Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING. Agenda. Agenda (Cont.) Traditional Measures of Market Risk Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING Agenda The Notional Amount Approach Price Sensitivity Measure for Derivatives Weakness of the Greek Measure Define Value at Risk 1 Day to VaR to 10 Day

More information

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén PORTFOLIO THEORY Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Portfolio Theory Investments 1 / 60 Outline 1 Modern Portfolio Theory Introduction Mean-Variance

More information

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY 4 th World Congress Tokyo, 26 Investments and forward utilities Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 Topics Utility-based measurement of performance Utilities

More information