Nominal Exchange Rate Volatility, Default Risk and Reserve Accumulation

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Nominal Exchange Rate Volatility, Default Risk and Reserve Accumulation"

Transcription

1 Nominal Exchange Rate Volatility, Default Risk and Reserve Accumulation Siqiang Yang Feb 2017 Abstract The paper investigates how the nominal exchange rate volatility affects a sovereign s default risk and the incentive to accumulate reserves. The model considers an environment where the sovereign faces a currency mismatch problem. That is, the sovereign has income in domestic currency, but can only borrow in foreign currency. Moreover, the sovereign is subject to volatile exchange rate fluctuations. Whenever the exchange rate depreciates, the debt burden in terms of domestic currency increases, leading to a higher default risk and borrowing cost. To insure the risk, the sovereign optimally accumulates foreign reserves to smooth consumption, to hedge against the depreciation of the exchange rate, and to stabilize the fluctuations of the exchange rate. Quantitatively the model can generate more than half of the reserve holdings.. Keywords: Sovereign Default, Foreign Reserves, Nominal Exchange Rates Volatility JEL Codes: F32, F34, H63 University of Pittsburgh, Department of Economics, siy10@pitt.edu. I am grateful to Dani Coen-Pirani and Sewon Hur for advising me on this paper. I would also like to thank Marla Ripoll, Douglas Hanley and seminar participants at the University of Pittsburgh for useful comments. 1

2 1 Introduction During the last thirty years, with rapid financial integration, emerging countries have borrowed extensively from international financial markets. However, most of emerging countries external debt are denominated in foreign currency 1, while most of their income are denominated in domestic currency. This gives rise to a currency mismatch problem. The problem can make a country vulnerable to volatile exchange rate fluctuations. That is, whenever its nominal exchange rate depreciates, the foreign debt burden in terms of domestic currency increases, making the country harder to repay the debt and rising the default risk. The potential vulnerability resulting from foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility creates the need for precautionary measures. On the other hand, since the 21th century, emerging countries have accumulated foreign reserves fasterly. The paper argues that the large reserve accumulation is the natural response to the precautionary demand to insure the risk resulting from foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility. Moreover, the paper aims to investigate how the interaction between foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility affects a sovereign s default risk, interest spread and debt dynamics, and whether it can generate large reserve accumulation observed in the data. To explore the logic, the paper extends the classic Eaton and Gersovitz (1981) sovereign default model to study an environment where the sovereign can borrow long-term foreign currency debt, save in short-term liquid foreign reserves. Moreover, the sovereign faces exogenous output shock and nominal exchange rate shock. In this context, whether increasing reserve holdings is a tradeoff between the insurance benefit of reserves and the larger gross debt positions as in Bianchi et al. (2016). Particularly, the paper provides three channels through which large reserve holdings can be rationalized. The first is the consumption smoothing channel. Because of the different maturity of debt and reserve, the sovereign can borrow long-term debt and save in short-term reserves to insure the bad states where borrowing is very costly. The second is the currency hedging channel. Since both debts and reserves are denominated in foreign currency, whenever exchange rate depreciates, debt 1 The situations where countries are not able to borrow in their domestic currency is described as the Original Sin by Eichengreen et al. (2007). 2

3 payments in domestic currency increases, but at the same time reserves in domestic currency also increases which alleviates the effect of depreciation. Thirdly if reserves can be used to stabilize the exchange rate fluctuations, then larger reserve holdings will reduce the volatility of exchange rate and lead to a lower default risk and spread. To test the mechanisms, the paper calibrates the model for quantitative exercises. The first exercise looks at how exchange rate volatilities affect the default risk, borrowing and reserve accumulation decisions. The result shows that with more volatile exchange rate, the default risk is higher, and the sovereign optimally reduces the debt exposures and increases the reserve holdings. The second exercise aims to investigate whether the incentive for reserve accumulation is stronger if larger reserve holdings can reduce the exchange rate volatility. The result confirms that the exchange rate stabilization role of reserves is quantitatively important. The reserve holdings increases from baseline 4 percent to 5.5 percent, where the data counterpart is 9 percent. Related Literature. The paper is related to two different literatures. The first is the sovereign default literature. The main theoretical background is established by Eaton and Gersovitz (1981). The later quantitative exercises are developed by Arellano (2008). Hatchondo and Martinez (2009) and Chatterjee and Eyigungor (2013) extend the Arellano (2008) to incorporate different durations of long-term sovereign bond instead of only one period short-term bond. The model setup in this paper is based on the long-term bond sovereign default model. The novel difference is that the paper considers the foreign currency denominated nominal bond instead of commonly used real bond. By incorporating the foreign currency nominal bond, the paper contributes to the literature by pointing out the exchange rate volatility could be an important channel that affect emerging countries default risk and borrowing decisions. The paper also quantitatively investigate how different exchange rate volatilities will affect their borrowing decisions and the bond spread. The paper is also closely linked to the reserve accumulation literature. This literature tries to explain why emerging countries hold large amount of foreign reserves. There are two popular views in this literature. The first is the mercantilism view, which suggests that reserve accumulation can promote export growth by preventing appreciation (Dooley et al. (2004)). The second is the precautionary view, which argues that reserves can act 3

4 as a self-insurance against future sudden stop events (Alfaro and Kanczuk (2009), Bianchi et al. (2016), Hur and Kondo (2016) and Jeanne and Rancière (2011)). The sudden stop events is known as the quick and sharp reversal of private capital flows in emerging market economies. It is usually modeled as an exogenous event that happens with certain probability. For instance, in Bianchi et al. (2016), the sudden stop is modeled as an exogenous situation where countries are not able to borrow external debts. This paper also illustrates the precautionary motives for reserve accumulation, but in the presence of currency mismatch and volatile exchange rate fluctuations. This two features with defaultable debts can endogenously generate tight borrowing constraint, which provides a micro foundation for the exogenous sudden stop events. Moreover, the paper contributes to the literature by arguing that the exchange rate volatility is an essential factor that increasing the precautionary demand for reserve holdings, and the paper proposes three channels through which large reserve holdings can be rationalized. The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 illustrates the empirical motivation, section 3 presents the model and section 4 shows the quantitative results. Section 5 concludes. 2 Empirical Motivation This section aims to establish that foreign currency debt exposure and exchange rate volatility are associated with severe default risk, which naturally incentives precautionary reserve accumulation. To illustrate the point, I collect relevant information 2 on 19 emerging countries from various sources of data 3. The reason for focusing on emerging countries is that most of their external debt is in foreign currency and they also experience volatile exchange rate movements, which is consistent with the key features that this paper emphasize on. The final data I used consist constitutes an unbalanced panel which includes 19 countries and spans from the fourth quarter of 1993 to the last quarter of The nominal exchange rate and foreign reserves data are from International Financial Statistics. The external debt information is from World Development Indicators, and the sovereign bond spread is from JPMorgan Emerging Market Bond Index (EMBI). 3 The emerging countries in our sample include: Argentina, Brazil, China, Colombia, Egypt, Indonesia, Lebanon, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, Russia, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, Ukraine, Venezuela. 4

5 Average FC Composition of External Public Debt Average Interest Rate Spread Fitted Values Averge Exchange Rate Volatility Average Interest Rate Spread Fitted Values Figure 1: Spread, FC Debt Ratio and ExRate Volatility Before going to the analysis, I first explain the measure I used for the important variables. The exchange rate volatility is defined as the standard deviation of quarterly changes of the natural logarithm of the nominal exchange rate within a year, which captures how volatile the depreciation or appreciation is in a given year. Since I am interested in how short-run sudden changes of exchange rate affects default risk, a shorter time window is preferred, and later I will also show that my results are robust to 1.5 years and 2 years window of calculating exchange rate volatility. For the measure of foreign currency debt exposure, in Figure 1, I use the foreign currency composition of external public long-term debt, which directly links to the currency mismatch problem and indicates how much external debt is borrowed in foreign currency. In the regressions shown in Table 1 and 2, I use the ratio of foreign currency external public long-term debt on GDP, which emphasizes on whether the foreign currency debt exposure is large in terms of GDP. For the measure of default risk, I use the EMBI interest spread, which is common in the sovereign default literature. Figure 1 shows the long-run pattern between average spread 4, exchange rate volatility and foreign currency share of external public long-term debt for each country 5. It also provides descriptive statistics about the key variables for each countries. Note that during the time interval 1993Q4 to 2014Q4, most countries borrow over 90% of their long-term public debt 4 In Figure 1, I scale the spread basis point and divide each by 10 4, so that it is comparable to the other two measures. In later regressions, I use the basis point measure. 5 The World Development Indicators only provides the currency composition of external long-term public debt. There is no currency composition information for private and short-term debt 5

6 in foreign currency, and this value is positively related to the interest rate spread. the other graph, we can see that there is also a strong association between exchange rate volatility and interest spread. These two positive relationships are consistent with the idea that higher foreign currency debt ratio and more volatile exchange movements can lead to larger foreign currency debt burden in domestic currency when exchange rate depreciates, which increases the default risk. On However, the associations between the variables might be driven by other common factors that affect spread, exchange rate volatility and foreign currency debt ratio. Moreover, I am more interested in how the interaction between foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility increases the default risk 6. Therefore, I turn to linear regression analysis to control for potential common factors and explicitly consider the interaction between foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility. Table 1 shows the coefficients obtained by regressing the interest spread on foreign currency long-term public debt-to-gdp ratio, exchange rate volatility, their interaction term and other controls. All the variables are calculated in a one year rolling window centered at current time period. Except for the exchange rate volatility measures, all other variables indicates the average value in the rolling window. Since both exchange rate volatility and foreign currency public debt-to-gdp ratio are continuos variables instead of dummy variables, the coefficient on the interaction term is not easy to interpret. To help interpret the coefficient, I calculate the difference to the mean value for the variables related to foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility for each country, which have additional (DM) notations in Table 1 and 2. In this way, it is much easier to interpret the coefficient especially when one of the variables is at the mean level. On all the specifications, I control for all other components of external debt, so that the coefficient on the foreign currency public long-term debt ratio is not interpreted as how total external debt affects spread. On the first two specifications (1), (2), without controlling for country fixed effect, all the variables are significant. Specifically, the interaction between foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility is significantly positive correlated with the spread. On the other hand, the reserves to short-term debt ratio, which captures whether reserves is enough 6 For instance, if there is no foreign currency debt, then volatile exchange rate movement will not increase the default risk through the currency mismatch channel. Similarly, when the exchange rate is fixed, foreign currency debt will be similar to local currency debt. 6

7 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Spread Spread Spread Spread Spread Spread Variables 1 Year RW 1 Year RW 1 Year RW 1 Year RW 1.5 Yrs RW 2 Yrs RW FC Public Debt-to-GDP(DM) 1,988*** 2,022*** 2,606** 3,576** 3,358** 3,129** (348.0) (347.8) (1,223) (1,434) (1,348) (1,223) ExRateVolatility(DM) 811.5* 798.1* 1,687*** 1,563** 1,621** 1,812*** (434.3) (424.9) (576.8) (585.9) (584.0) (572.1) FC Public Debt-to-GDP(DM) 29,454*** 29,332*** 19,161*** 15,626*** 17,165*** 18,857*** ExRateVolatility(DM) (2,789) (2,745) (4,765) (4,738) (4,504) (4,092) Res-to-STDebt *** (4.124) (5.240) (3.781) (4.478) (4.970) RGDP Growth ,947 1,775 (2,283) (3,911) (4,739) CA-to-GDP (985.9) (1,035) (1,107) Inflation ** *** *** (0.0961) (0.112) (0.125) Trade Openness (2.319) (2.282) (2.168) Financial Openness *** *** *** (149.3) (146.1) (145.7) LC Public Debt-to-GDP -3,449*** -3,039*** -1,576-2,553-2,408-2,257 (374.8) (352.4) (2,063) (2,513) (2,419) (2,292) Private Debt-to-GDP (177.4) (177.9) (643.3) (550.5) (556.8) (568.0) Short Term Debt-to-GDP 936.8*** ,601 1,612 1,603 1,627 (328.2) (331.0) (1,539) (1,297) (1,259) (1,219) Constant ** (145.1) (140.1) (237.3) (268.8) (272.6) (254.9) Observations 1,328 1,328 1,328 1,313 1,313 1,313 R-squared Country FE NO NO YES YES YES YES Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES Number of Countries Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Table 1: Spread, FC Debt Exposure and ExRate Volatility 7

8 to cover the recent debt payment, is significantly negative correlated with the spread. If the country fixed effect is included in specification (3), the coefficient of reserves to short-term debt ratio is still negative but less significant. If we look at the interaction between foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility, it can still significantly increases the spread. Its significantly positive association with the spread is preserved even if I control for other fundamentals 7 as in (4) or run the regressions in longer rolling windows as in (5) and (6). The take-way from the above regression analysis is that there is a strong and robust positive relationship between the sovereign spread, and the interaction of foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility. The finding is consistent with the currency mismatch problem that when exchange rate volatility is higher, a more likely larger currency depreciation increases the domestic debt burden, and makes the sovereign harder to repay the debt. If the international financial markets cannot help the sovereign perfectly insure the risk, the sovereign could self-insure by precautionary saving through accumulating reserves 8. Note that the precautionary demand for reserves could correlate exchange rate volatility with different signs. On the one hand, a higher exchange rate volatility can lead to higher precautionary saving to help repay foreign currency debt when output is low or exchange rate depreciates, which gives a positive association. On the other hand, a higher reserves holding can reduce the likelihood of currency crises, sudden stop or exchange rate volatility, which gives a negative sign 9. Or a higher reserves can signal a stronger commitment to smooth the exchange rate volatility through foreign exchange intervention, which also gives a negative sign 10. Which sign is observed in the data not only implies which precautionary motive dominates, but also provides guide on which precautionary channels should be in the structural model. Specifically, since the buffer stock precautionary motive is usually present in the incomplete market model with uninsurable shocks, if the sign observed in the data is negative, which suggests that the channel of having more reserves to reduce the exchange 7 The financial openness is taken from the Chinn-Ito index. The rest control variables are taken from World Development Indicators. 8 Similarly, Fogli and Perri (2015) shows how output volatility increases net foreign assets position through precautionary motives. Bianchi et al. (2016) shows with long-term debt setting, sovereign optimally accumulate large reserves to insure the output fluctuations. 9 Hur and Kondo (2016) shows how higher reserves can reduce the sudden stop probability. 10 Hviding et al. (2004) documents how the signalling effect of higher reserves can reduce the exchange rate volatility. 8

9 Averge Reserve-to-GDP Fitted Values 45 Degree Line Average FC Public Long-Term Debt-to-GDP Average Exchange Rate Volatility Averge Reserve-to-GDP Fitted Values Figure 2: Reserves, FC Debt-to-GDP and ExRate Volatility rate volatility is stronger, then this additional channel should be in the model. Figure 2 shows the descriptive statistics and long-run pattern between reserves-to-gdp, foreign currency long-term public external debt-to-gdp and exchange rate volatility. On the first graph, we can see that all the countries borrow external foreign currency debt and save in reserves at the same time, and most of countries borrow more than they saved. On the second graph, there is a negative association between reserves and exchange rate volatility, which suggests that the channel of using reserves to reduce exchange rate dominates. However, a more robust implication should control for confounding factors. So I turn to the linear regression reported in Table 2. Table 2 reports the coefficients obtained by regressing the reserves-to-gdp ratio on foreign currency long-term public debt-to-gdp ratio, exchange rate volatility, their interaction term and other controls. On specifications (1), (5) and (6), we can see that without controlling for country fixed effect, given the external debt structure, there is a robust negative correlation between reserves and exchange rate volatility on different rolling windows. It is consistent with the argument that for certain countries, the negative relationship of using reserves to reduce exchange rate volatility is stronger than the positive relationship of using reserves as a buffer for uncertain exchange rate realizations. On specifications (2) and (3), with country fixed effect and same fundamental control variables, we can see that the coefficient on the exchange rate volatility alone is still negative, but less significant, which is consistent with previous argument. However, the coefficient on the interaction term becomes positive with 9

10 (1) ResGDP (2) ResGDP (3) ResGDP (4) ResGDP (5) ResGDP (6) ResGDP Variables 1 Year RW 1 Year RW 1 Year RW 1 Year RW 1.5 Yrs RW 2 Yrs RW FC Public Debt-to-GDP(DM) 0.260*** 0.162* *** 0.277*** (0.0502) (0.0898) (0.123) (0.133) (0.0506) (0.0512) ExRateVolatility(DM) ** * *** *** *** (0.0383) (0.0701) (0.0786) (0.0386) (0.0383) FC Public Debt-to-GDP(DM) *** *** *** ExRateVolatility(DM) (0.259) (0.268) (0.439) (0.265) (0.292) Lagged ExRateVolatility(DM) * (0.0724) FC Public Debt-to-GDP(DM) Lagged ExRateVolatility(DM) (0.423) RGDP Growth * (0.341) (0.365) CA-to-GDP 0.344** 0.354** (0.132) (0.136) Inflation 1.02e e-06 (1.25e-05) (1.13e-05) Trade Openness ** ** ( ) ( ) Financial Openness (0.0345) (0.0376) LC Public Debt-to-GDP 0.416*** *** 0.408*** (0.123) (0.434) (0.335) (0.317) (0.123) (0.124) Private Debt-to-GDP *** *** *** (0.0615) (0.128) (0.146) (0.150) (0.0614) (0.0615) Short Term Debt-to-GDP 1.136*** * 0.309* 1.135*** 1.132*** (0.0811) (0.180) (0.172) (0.178) (0.0810) (0.0810) Constant ** *** ** ** (0.0126) (0.0207) (0.0495) (0.0526) (0.0125) (0.0124) Observations 1,760 1,760 1,706 1,664 1,760 1,760 R-squared Country FE NO YES YES YES NO NO Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES Number of Countries Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Table 2: Reserves, FC Debt Exposure and ExRate Volatility 10

11 less significance. The positive association is consistent with the positive precautionary motive that when country borrows in foreign currency, higher exchange rate volatility can lead to more reserve holdings as a buffers for higher domestic debt repayment with depreciated exchange rate. On specification (4), I change the regressors of exchange rate volatility to 1 year lagged exchange rate volatility. The idea is that if higher reserves can reduce the current exchange rate volatility, it is less likely that it can affect exchange rate volatility 1 year before, so that the link between lagged volatility and reserves reflects more of the positive precautionary motive. I use 1 year lag so that there is no intersection between lagged volatility and current reserves in the 1 year rolling window. The finding is similar that lagged exchange rate along is still significantly negative correlated with reserves, but the interaction term has a positive association with reserves. The main message from Table 2 is that there is a significant and robust negative relationship between reserves and exchange rate volatility along (without the interaction term), which motives the need to consider this channel in a quantitative structural model. Combing the information from Table 1, the empirical evidence is consistent with the argument that the interaction between foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility can increase the sovereign s default risk and borrowing cost, which incentives the precautionary demand for reserve accumulation. Next I will build a sovereign default model to discuss how the interaction between foreign currency debt and exchange rate volatility can give rise to a severe default risk, and through which channels reserve accumulation can help the sovereign insures this risk. 3 Model 3.1 Framework The empirical section shows that emerging countries borrow extensively in foreign currency, which expose them to the risk of large exchange rate depreciation. Whenever exchange rate depreciates, the foreign debt burden in terms of domestic currency increases, making them harder to repay the debt. This potential vulnerability can provide precautionary demand for 11

12 reserve accumulation. To capture the currency mismatch problem and its link to the reserve accumulation, I construct a sovereign default model with following three novel features. Firstly I introduce nominal foreign currency assets. That is, the sovereign can only borrow long-term foreign currency bonds, and save in one-period liquid foreign currency reserves. Since the sovereign s endowment is in domestic currency, and its domestic price level is assumed to remain unchanged over time, the sovereign is exposed to the currency mismatch problem. Secondly, I add an exogenous nominal exchange rate shock to the model in addition to the standard output shock, which stochastically moves the sovereign s domestic currency value of its foreign currency debt and creates a currency risk to the sovereign through the currency mismatch problem. Thirdly I introduce an exogenously estimated link between reserves and exchange rate volatility, which captures the negative association between them in the data, and also allows the sovereign accumulating more reserves to reduce the exchange rate volatility and mitigate the currency mismatch problem. Next, I will present the detailed description of the model. 3.2 Environment Endowment Time is discrete and indexed by t = 0, 1, 2,... The endowment of representative agent is stochastic, which follows the standard AR(1) process as in quantitative sovereign default models: log y t = (1 ρ)µ + ρ log y t 1 + ε t, ρ < 1, ε t N(0, σ 2 ε). Here the endowment is in real value Preference Preference of the representative agent or the sovereign is given by: E t j=t β j t u(c j ), 12

13 where E is the expectation operator, β is the subjective discount factor, and c is the sovereign s real consumption. The utility function is strictly increasing and concave. The interpretation here is that the benevolent sovereign can borrow and lend from international financial markets, and then make transfer to its domestic hand-to-mouth agents to help them smooth consumption Nominal Exchange Rate Shock To make the balance sheet effect work through the currency mismatch problem, the exogenous nominal exchange rate shock ξ is introduced. The shock ξ aims to capture the short-run unanticipated movements of nominal exchange rate, which can increase or decrease domestic value of foreign currency debt. The exchange rate process is assumed to be exogenously determined, the reason is that since the dynamics of nominal exchange rate is disconnected from the fundamentals in the short-run 11, it is hard to endogenize the short-run exchange rate based only on the output shock. Instead of adding other shocks to determine the exchange rate, I choose to directly estimated the process of nominal exchange rate from the data. Moreover, since the empirical section documents a robust negative relationship between reserves and nominal exchange rate volatility. The volatility of nominal exchange rate is assumed to be determined by the foreign reserves level, which is time-varying. The time-varying feature of the nominal exchange rate volatility is consistent with the empirical estimation and forecasting of nominal exchange rate 12. The nominal exchange rate shock ξ t is defined as the net percentage depreciation of current nominal exchange rate compared with last period nominal exchange rate. Mathematically ξ t = e t e t 1 1, where e t denotes the nominal exchange rate, which is domestic currency value of 1 unit of foreign currency. If the exchange rate depreicates at time t, that is e t > e t 1 and ξ t > 0. Then 1 unit of foreign currency becomes more valuable in terms of domestic currency and 11 Gabaix and Maggiori (2015) summarizes the literature related to the exchange rate disconnect. 12 Erdemlioglu et al. (2012) provides a comprehensive summary of recent 30 years of different econometric specifications for estimating exchange rate process. Almost every specifications allow the volatility of exchange rate to be time-varying. 13

14 vice versa. Therefore the exchange rate shock ξ t can randomly fluctuate domestic value of foreign currency assets. The shock ξ t will be estimated as a AR(1) process with time-varying volatility. ξ t = ρ ξ ξ t 1 + υ t, ρ ξ < 1, υ t N(0, σ 2 t ), σ 2 t = exp(α 1 + α 2 ResPerGDP t ), where ResPerGDP t denotes the ratio between foreign reserves and GDP at the beginning of period t. In my calibration later, each period corresponds to a quarter, so 4 periods correspond to a year. Based on my estimation which is reported in the calibration section, the parameter α 2 is negative, which means that larger reserves can reduce the exchange rate volatility International Financial Markets The sovereign can issue long-term bonds from foreign investors, but only in foreign currency. To model the long-term bonds in a tractable way, I follow Aguiar et al. (2016), Hatchondo and Martinez (2009), and Chatterjee and Eyigungor (2013). Specifically, each long-term bond will pay a coupon every period up to and including the period of maturity. Without loss of generality, the coupon payment is normalized to the risk-free nominal interest rate r per unit of face value as in Aguiar et al. (2016). The benefit is that with this normalization, a unit of risk-free long-term bond will have a price of one. The long-term bond is assumed to mature randomly at probability δ [0, 1]. That is, for an outstanding long-term bond of measure b, a δ fraction b will mature this period and the associated debt repayment is (r + δ)b. The continuation face value of the long-term bond is (1 δ)b. If the sovereign changes its outstanding debt level at the end of this period to b. Then the net issuance this period is b (1 δ)b. With this setup, the expected maturity of the long-term bond is 1. The sovereign also has access to a one-period risk-free foreign δ currency reserves, that pays 1 + r each period. 14

15 3.2.5 Budget Constraints Firstly let me discuss the assumption on the domestic price level. Define the foreign price level p as the numeraire, therefore p t = 1 for all t. To model the currency mismatch problem, I assume that in the short run, domestic price is predetermined, that is, they are set a period in advance but can be adjusted fully after one period. Mathematically, it means that at the beginning of the period t, p t = p t 1. Only at the end of the period t, p t = p t e t according to the purchasing power parity. Under the setting, when the nominal exchange rate changes, the domestic currency value of foreign currency assets will change. Since domestic price level is fixed, the nominal change of foreign assets in domestic value will result in real change of foreign assets in terms of goods, which exactly replicates the currency mismatch. However, by setting a sticky domestic price, the purchasing power parity p t = p t e t does not always hold. There are two reasons for not imposing the purchasing power parity here. Firstly the model studies how short-run unanticipated exchange rate movements affect the sovereign s default risk, however, the purchasing power parity only approximately holds in the long-run instead of short-run, so it is reasonable to deviate from the purchasing power parity. Secondly since financial markets clear faster than good markets as in Dornbusch (1976), the short-run movements of nominal exchange rate can result in immediate change of foreign currency assets, however, the domestic price level can be sticky for a longer time. Next, I will present the budget constraints in both nominal and real term. Denote b t 0 as the measure of outstanding foreign currency long-term bond, ã t 0 as the measure of foreign currency reserves. Then without default, the nominal budget constraint is p t c t = p t y t (r + δ) b t e t + q t e t ( b t+1 (1 δ) b t ) + ã t e t ãt+1e t 1 + r, where q t is the foreign currency nominal price of the bond issued by the sovereign, (r + δ) b t is the foreign currency coupon payments and debt payments due, and all the terms are in nominal domestic currency. Now define b t+1 = b t+1 e t p t, a t+1 = ãt+1e t p t as the real value of foreign currency debt and reserves in terms of goods value at period t, when they are issued. The associated real 15

16 budget constraint is c t = y t (r + δ) b t e t 1 p t 1 Since ξ t = p t 1 e t + q t b t+1 e t q t(1 δ) b t e t 1 p t 1 e t + ãte t 1 p t 1 e t p t e t 1 p t p t 1 p t e t 1 p t 1 p t e t 1 et e t 1 1 and domestic price level is constant p t = p t 1, we have c t = y t (1 + ξ t )(r + δ)b t + q t (b t+1 (1 + ξ t )(1 δ)b t ) + (1 + ξ t )a t a t r, ãt+1e t (1 + r)p t. where all the terms are in real value now, and we can see that nominal exchange rate depreciation ξ t > 0 can result in real increase in foreign currency outstanding debt b t and also foreign currency reserves a t. Next, I will present the real budget constraint when the sovereign defaults. When the sovereign defaults, it does so on all current and future debt obligations. A default triggers exclusion from borrowing in credit markets for a stochastic number of periods. The sovereign will regain access to credit markets with a constant probability θ [0, 1]. In every period where the sovereign is excluded from credit markets, there is a real output loss of φ(y), which is important to help the model match the statistics on debt ratio and interest spread. In addition, I assume that during the default periods, there is no effect of using reserves to reduce exchange rate volatility α 2 = 0, and the exchange rate volatility will remain the highest value exp(α 1 ) until it regains access to credit markets. This assumption is consistent with the fact that during financial crisis, the exchange rate volatility shoots high, and the emerging countries does not primarily rely on reserves and foreign exchange interventions to absorb the shock (see Aizenman and Hutchison (2012)) 13. In case of default, the sovereign will still retain the control of their foreign reserves. Therefore the real budget constraint can be derived similarly c t = y t φ(y) + (1 + ξ t )a t a t r, where the sovereign can only save in reserves to smooth consumption. 13 Aizenman and Hutchison (2012) documents the fact and denotes the behavior as Fear of reserve loss. 16

17 3.2.6 Timing The timing within each period is as follows: First, the output shock and exchange rate shock are realized, where the variance of the exchange rate shock depends on the reserves at the beginning of the period. After observing these shocks, the sovereign chooses whether to default on its debt and then makes its borrowing and saving decisions. 3.3 Recursive Formulation The recursive formulation of the sovereign s problem is described here. The sovereign cannot commit to repay the debt. So in each period, the sovereign will compare the value of repayment and the value of default to make its repayment decision. Let V indicate the value function of a sovereign that is not in default. For any bond price function q, the function V satisfies the following functional equation: V (b, a, y, ξ) = max{v R (b, a, y, ξ), V D (a, y, ξ)}, (1) where the sovereign s value of repayment is given by subject to V R (b, a, y, ξ) = max {u(c) + βe a 0,b (y 0,c,ξ ) (y,ξ)v (b, a, y, ξ )}, (2) c = y (1 + ξ)(r + δ)b + q(b (1 + ξ)(1 δ)b) + (1 + ξ)a a 1 + r. The value of defaulting is given by: subject to V D (a, y, ξ) = max a 0,c u(c) + βe (y,ξ ) (y,ξ)[(1 θ)v D (a, y, ξ ) + θv (0, a, y, ξ )], (3) c = y φ(y) + (1 + ξ)a a 1 + r. The solution to the sovereign s problem gives the decision rules for default ˆd(b, a, y, ξ), debt 17

18 ˆb(b, a, y, ξ), reserves in default â D (a, y, ξ), reserves when not in default â R (b, a, y, ξ), consumption in default ĉ D (a, y, ξ), and consumption when not in default ĉ R (b, a, y, ξ). The default rule ˆd is equal to 1 if the sovereign defaults, and is equal to 0 otherwise. 3.4 Bond Prices Sovereign bonds and reserves are priced in a competitive market inhabited by a large number of identical risk-neutral international investors. Investors discount future payoffs at the riskfree rate 1 + r. This implies that in equilibrium the bond-price function solves the following functional equation: q(b, a, y, ξ)(1 + r) = E (y,ξ ) (y,ξ)[(1 ˆd(b, a, y, ξ ))(r + δ + (1 δ)q(b, a, y, ξ ))], (4) where b = ˆb(b, a, y, ξ ) a = â R (b, a, y, ξ ). This means that, in equilibrium, a risk-neutral investor is indifferent between selling a bond today, and keeping the bond to the next period. If the investor keeps the bond and the sovereign does not default in the next period, he will receive the coupon and the debt repayments (r + δ). In addition, his continuation value of bond worth (1 δ) times the price of a bond issued in the next period. 3.5 Recursive Equilibrium I emphasis on the Markov Perfect Equilibrium. That is, in each period the sovereign s equilibrium default, borrowing, and saving decisions depend only on the payoff-relevant state variables. Then a Markov Perfect Equilibrium is defined by a set of value functions V, V R and V D, rules for default ˆd, borrowing ˆb, reserves {â R, â D }, and consumption {ĉ R, ĉ D }, and a bond price function q, such that: (i) given a bond price function q, the policy functions ˆd, ˆb, â R, â D, ĉ R, ĉ D, and the value functions V, V R, V D solve the Bellman equations (1), (2), 18

19 and (3). (ii) given the sovereign s policies, the bond price function q satisfies condition (4). 4 Quantitative Results 4.1 Calibration and Function Form For the function form, the utility function displays a constant coefficient of relative risk aversion, u(c) = c1 γ 1, with γ 1. 1 γ The endowment shock follows the standard AR(1) process : log y t = (1 ρ)µ + ρ log y t 1 + ε t, ρ < 1, ε t N(0, σ 2 ε). At current stage, I let the nominal exchange rate shock follow another independent AR(1) process with constant variance σ 2 υ. ξ t = ρ ξ ξ t 1 + υ t, ρ ξ < 1, υ t N(0, σ 2 υ). For the default cost function, I follow Chatterjee and Eyigungor (2013). That is φ(y) = max{0, d 0 y + d 1 y 2 }, so that it is asymmetrically more costly to default in good times. For the calibration, the paper targets Mexico as the benchmark economy, since Mexico is a common reference for studies on emerging economics. The data for Mexico is mainly taken from International Financial Statistics and EMBI spread dataset from 1993Q4 to 2014Q4. Since the calibration uses quarterly data, a period in the model will correspond to a quarter in the data. There are total twelve parameters that need to be determined. The first three parameters discount factor β,default cost d 0, d 1 will be jointly calibrated to match three moments. These are the mean external debt-to-gdp ratio, the mean interest spread and the standard deviation of consumption over the standard deviation of output. 19

20 Four parameter values will be set directly. The risk aversion γ will be set to 2 as in the sovereign default literature. The risk-free rate r will be set to 1% to match the three-month US treasury bill real return. The probability of reentry θ will be set to to reflect that on average it takes three years for countries to regain access to credit markets after default. The debt duration δ will be set to 0.05 to match the 5 years average bond duration in Mexico as in Broner et al. (2013) The remaining five parameters µ, ρ, σ 2 ε, ρ ɛ, σ 2 υ for output shock and nominal exchange rate shock will be estimated based on the HP-filtered Mexico real output and the raw nominal exchange rate data from 1993Q4 to 2014Q4. The benchmark calibration result is shown in Table 3. Table 3: Parameter Values Discount factor β Output cost of defaulting d Output cost of defaulting d Risk aversion γ 2 Risk-free rate r 1% Probability of reentry after default θ Debt duration δ 0.05 Output autocorrelation coefficient ρ 0.94 Depreciation autocorrelation coefficient ρ υ 0.21 Standard deviation of innovations for output σ 1.5% Standard deviation of innovations for depreciation σ υ 8.18% Mean log output µ (1/2)σ 2 ε The interest spread can be calculated as follows. Firstly the yield i is calculated, which is defined as the return an investor would earn if he holds the bond to maturity and no default is declared. This yield satisfies i = r + δ q (1 δ) The sovereign spread is then computed as the difference between the yield i and the risk-free rate r. The annualized spread is used here: r s t = ( 1 + i 1 + r )4 1 20

21 4.2 Simulation Results Matching Moments In this section, the paper will firstly show how the model s calibration result matches the targeted and non-targeted moments. illustrate the mechanisms of the model. Then there will be three quantitative exercises to Table 4 shows that the model exactly matches the three targeted moments. For the nontargeted moments, the model also closely matches the standard deviation of trade balance, the correlation of consumption and output and the correlation of interest spread and output. Moreover, the model also generate reasonable 4% of reserve holdings. For the remaining nontargeted moments, the model is able to give the correct sign as in the data. Table 4: Simulation Statistics Model Data Mean Debt-to-GDP Mean r s σ(c)/σ(y) σ(r s ) σ(tb) ρ(c, y) ρ(r s, y) Mean Reserve-to-GDP ρ( a, y) ρ( a, r s ) The Role of Reserve Accumulation This section will illustrate the role of reserve accumulation. The tradeoff of reserve holdings is whether using the reserves to run down the debt exposures or increasing both debt and reserve level to capture the insurance benefit of reserves. The budget constraint can help understand the tradeoff. c = y (1 + ξ)(r + δ)b + q(b (1 + ξ)(1 δ)b) + (1 + ξ)a a 1 + r 21

22 With no new debt issuing, the future debt payment is b = (1 + ξ)(1 δ)b. Therefore, the exchange rate shock not only affect current debt and reserve level (1 + ξ)b, (1 + ξ)a, but also affect future debt payment (1 + ξ)(1 δ)b. A large depreciation will also push up future debt payment, resulting in higher future default probability, which results in a higher current borrowing cost. Therefore, with no reserve holdings, when borrowing is costly, the sovereign has to choose either repaying the debt and suffering large drop in consumption, or defaulting. Since the debt is long-term, the sovereign can increase the total debt exposures without increasing debt payments due in each period much, and save part of the borrowing as reserves. In this case, reserves can help smooth consumption when facing tight borrowing constraint. Another important role of reserve holdings is the currency hedging. Since both debt and reserves are denominated in foreign currency, even if large depreciation happens, the increase in reserve (1 + ξ)a can help increase the consumption. The last role of reserves to stabilize exchange rate volatility will be discussed in later quantitative exercise The Effects of Exchange Rate Volatility Table 5: The Effects of Exchange Rate Volatility Std(ɛ t ) Mean Debt-to-GDP Mean Reserve-to-GDP Mean r s Default Rate per 100 Years Table 5 illustrates how different exchange rate volatility will affect sovereign s borrowing and reserve accumulation decisions. Here the exchange rate shocks take the calibrated persistent value of 0.21, but vary with different standard deviations: ξ t = 0.21ξ t 1 + υ t, υ t N(0, σ 2 υ). The result shows a clear pattern that more volatile exchange rate process will lead to less 22

23 borrowing, more reserve accumulation, higher spread and higher default probability. The intuition is that as the exchange rate becomes more volatile, a shock with larger depreciation becomes more likely, increasing the current and future debt burden in terms of domestic currency. Moreover, a larger future debt payments suggest higher chance of default in the future, which reflects as a higher borrowing cost today. If it is expensive to borrow today to rollover the debt, the sovereign will suffer the large drop in consumption or the default output cost. To get less exposure to the shock, the sovereign optimally choose to reduce borrowing. The quantitative exercises also generate large reserve holdings and it increases with exchange rate volatility. The idea is that since sovereign issues long-term debt, large reserves accumulation will increase the total debt payment, but not much increase in the debt payments due in each period. Therefore, the sovereign can accumulate reserves to smooth consumption against bad shocks and tighter borrowing conditions, and also hedge against depreciation in exchange rate. As the exchange rate becomes more volatile, the demand for precautionary safe assets increases Reserve Accumulation for Less Exchange Rate Volatility Here I allow the reserves to reduce the exchange rate volatility. simple way, the paper uses the following exchange rate process: To implement this in a ξ t = 0.21ξ t 1 + υ t, std(ξ t ) = if Res < 0.09 std(ξ t ) = 0.04 if Res > 0.09 where Res indicates the Res-to-GDP ratio. The 9% cutoff value reflects the mean Res-to- GDP ratio observed in the Mexico s data. The two different exchange rate standard deviation value are calculated separately for the period when the Res is above and below the cutoff. The result in Table 6 shows that if larger reserve holdings can reduce the exchange rate volatility, there will be stronger incentive to accumulate the reserves. In addition, the associated exchange rate volatility will also be lower. This is consistent with the empirical pattern 23

24 Table 6: Simulation Results Mean Debt-to-GDP Mean Reserve-to-GDP 5.5 4,0 Mean r s ρ(exvol,reserve) ρ(exvol,spread) ExVol that there is a robust negative association between reserves and exchange rate volatility. 5 Conclusion The paper investigates how the exchange rate volatility affects the sovereign s default risk and the incentive to accumulate reserves. The benchmark model considers an environment where the sovereign can only borrow external debt in foreign currency and subject to volatile exchange rate fluctuations. Whenever the exchange rate depreciates, the debt burden in terms of domestic currency increases, leading to a higher default risk and borrowing cost. The paper proposes three channels through which reserve accumulation can insure against volatile exchange rates. Specifically, it can help smooth consumption when rollover debts becomes costly, hedge against depreciation in exchange rate, and stabilize the fluctuations in exchange rate. Moreover, in the quantitative exercises, the baseline model can generate half of the reserve holdings. If reserves can reduce the volatility of exchange rate, the model can generate 60 percent of actual reserve holdings. 24

25 References Aguiar, Mark, Satyajit Chatterjee, Harold Cole, and Zachary Stangebye, Quantitative Models of Sovereign Debt Crises, Mar 2016, (22125). Aizenman, Joshua and Michael M. Hutchison, Exchange market pressure and absorption by international reserves: Emerging markets and fear of reserve loss during the crisis, Journal of International Money and Finance, 2012, 31 (5), Alfaro, Laura and Fabio Kanczuk, Optimal reserve management and sovereign debt, Journal of International Economics, 2009, 77 (1), Arellano, Cristina, Default risk and income fluctuations in emerging economies, American Economic Review, 2008, pp Bianchi, Javier, Juan Carlos Hatchondo, and Leonardo Martinez, International Reserves and Rollover Risk, November 2016, (735). Broner, Fernando A., Guido Lorenzoni, and Sergio L. Schmukler, WHY DO EMERGING ECONOMIES BORROW SHORT TERM?, Journal of the European Economic Association, 2013, 11, Chatterjee, Satyajit and Burcu Eyigungor, Maturity, Indebtedness, and Default Risk, American Economic Review, 2013, 102 (6), Dooley, Michael P., David Folkerts-Landau, and Peter Garber, The revived Bretton Woods system, International Journal of Finance and Economics, 2004, 9 (4), Dornbusch, Rudiger, Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal of Political Economy, 1976, 84 (6), Eaton, Jonathan and Mark Gersovitz, Debt with potential repudiation: Theoretical and empirical analysis, Review of Economic Studies, 1981, 48 (2),

26 Eichengreen, Barry, Ricardo Hausmann, and Ugo Panizza, Currency Mismatches, Debt Intolerance, and the Original Sin: Why They Are Not the Same and Why It Matters, May 2007, pp Erdemlioglu, Deniz, Sébastien Laurent, and Christopher J. Neely, Econometric modeling of exchange rate volatility and jumps, 2012, ( ). Fogli, Alessandra and Fabrizio Perri, Macroeconomic volatility and external imbalances, Journal of Monetary Economics, 2015, 69, Gabaix, Xavier and Matteo Maggiori, International Liquidity and Exchange Rate Dynamics *, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2015, 130 (3), Hatchondo, Juan Carlos and Leonardo Martinez, Long-duration bonds and sovereign defaults, Journal of International Economics, 2009, 79 (1), Hur, Sewon and Illenin O. Kondo, A theory of rollover risk, sudden stops, and foreign reserves, Journal of International Economics, 2016, 103, Hviding, Ketil, M. Nowak, and Luca A Ricci, Can Higher Reserves Help Reduce Exchange Rate Volatility?, October 2004, (04/189). Jeanne, Olivier and Romain Rancière, The Optimal Level of International Reserves For Emerging Market Countries: A New Formula and Some Applications, The Economic Journal, 2011, 121 (555),

Sudden stops, time inconsistency, and the duration of sovereign debt

Sudden stops, time inconsistency, and the duration of sovereign debt WP/13/174 Sudden stops, time inconsistency, and the duration of sovereign debt Juan Carlos Hatchondo and Leonardo Martinez 2013 International Monetary Fund WP/13/ IMF Working Paper IMF Institute for Capacity

More information

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults. June 3, 2009

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults. June 3, 2009 Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan C. Hatchondo Richmond Fed Leonardo Martinez Richmond Fed June 3, 2009 1 Business cycles in emerging economies Emerging Economies Developed Economies σ(gdp)

More information

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk Javier Bianchi 1 César Sosa-Padilla 2 2018 SED Annual Meeting 1 Minneapolis Fed & NBER 2 University of Notre Dame Motivation EMEs with

More information

Reserves and Sudden Stops

Reserves and Sudden Stops Reserves and Sudden Stops Sewon Hur University of Pittsburgh February 26, 2015 International Finance (Sewon Hur) Lecture 5 February 26, 2015 1 / 57 Sovereign Debt, Financial Crises, Sudden Stops Gourinchas

More information

Sovereign default and debt renegotiation

Sovereign default and debt renegotiation Sovereign default and debt renegotiation Authors Vivian Z. Yue Presenter José Manuel Carbó Martínez Universidad Carlos III February 10, 2014 Motivation Sovereign debt crisis 84 sovereign default from 1975

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

Liquidity Crises, Liquidity Lines and Sovereign Risk

Liquidity Crises, Liquidity Lines and Sovereign Risk Liquidity Crises, Liquidity Lines and Sovereign Risk Yasin Kürşat Önder Central Bank of Turkey February 3, 2016 Abstract This paper delivers a framework to quantitatively investigate the introduction of

More information

Sovereign Default and the Choice of Maturity

Sovereign Default and the Choice of Maturity Sovereign Default and the Choice of Maturity Juan M. Sanchez Horacio Sapriza Emircan Yurdagul FRB of St. Louis Federal Reserve Board Washington U. St. Louis February 4, 204 Abstract This paper studies

More information

Sovereign Debt Crises: Some Data and Some Theory

Sovereign Debt Crises: Some Data and Some Theory Sovereign Debt Crises: Some Data and Some Theory Harold L. Cole PIER Lecture 1 / 57 Debt Crises Debt Crises = government has trouble selling new debt. Trouble selling includes large jump in the spread

More information

Sovereign Default Risk with Working Capital in Emerging Economies

Sovereign Default Risk with Working Capital in Emerging Economies Sovereign Default Risk with Working Capital in Emerging Economies Kiyoung Jeon Zeynep Kabukcuoglu January 13, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract What is the role of labor markets in the default

More information

Did the 1980s in Latin America Need to Be a Lost Decade?

Did the 1980s in Latin America Need to Be a Lost Decade? Did the 1980s in Latin America Need to Be a Lost Decade? Victor Almeida Carlos Esquivel Timothy J. Kehoe Juan Pablo Nicolini Ÿ February 15, 2018 Abstract In 1979, the Federal Reserve Board, led by Chairman

More information

Maturity Structure of Haircut of Sovereign Bonds

Maturity Structure of Haircut of Sovereign Bonds Maturity Structure of Haircut of Sovereign Bonds Kenji Wada Graduate School of Economics, Hitotsubashi University Preliminary and incomplete Current Draft: March 19, 2017 Abstract Why does haircuts of

More information

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis Luigi Bocola Gideon Bornstein Alessandro Dovis ISOM Conference June 2018 This Paper Use Eaton-Gersovitz model to study European debt crisis

More information

Default risk and risk averse international investors

Default risk and risk averse international investors Default risk and risk averse international investors By Sandra Lizarazo Journal of International Economics, 2013 Presented by Danilo Aristizabal June 14, 2017 Sandra Lizarazo Default risk and risk averse

More information

Towards a General Equilibrium Foundation for the Observed Term Structure and Design in Sovereign Bonds

Towards a General Equilibrium Foundation for the Observed Term Structure and Design in Sovereign Bonds 1 / 34 Towards a General Equilibrium Foundation for the Observed Term Structure and Design in Sovereign Bonds K. Wada 1 1 Graduate School of Economics, Hitotsubashi University November 4, 2017 @HIAS. IER,

More information

Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks

Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks Ricardo Reyes-Heroles Federal Reserve Board Gabriel Tenorio The Boston Consulting Group IEA World Congress 2017 Mexico City, Mexico June 20, 2017

More information

Heterogeneous borrowers in quantitative models of sovereign default

Heterogeneous borrowers in quantitative models of sovereign default Heterogeneous borrowers in quantitative models of sovereign default J.C. Hatchondo, L. Martinez and H. Sapriza October, 2012 1 / 25 Elections and Sovereign Bond in Brasil 2 / 25 Stylized facts Declaration

More information

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default Private Leverage and Sovereign Default Cristina Arellano Yan Bai Luigi Bocola FRB Minneapolis University of Rochester Northwestern University Economic Policy and Financial Frictions November 2015 1 / 37

More information

GDP-indexed bonds in perpetuity and sovereign default

GDP-indexed bonds in perpetuity and sovereign default GDP-indexed bonds in perpetuity and sovereign default Yasin Kürşat Önder April 4, 2017 Abstract This paper analyzes the gains of introducing GDP-indexed bonds in an equilibrium sovereign default model

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERNATIONAL RESERVES AND ROLLOVER RISK. Javier Bianchi Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERNATIONAL RESERVES AND ROLLOVER RISK. Javier Bianchi Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERNATIONAL RESERVES AND ROLLOVER RISK Javier Bianchi Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez Working Paper 18628 http://www.nber.org/papers/w18628 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez January 15, 2009 Abstract This paper extends the baseline framework used in recent quantitative studies of sovereign default

More information

Sovereign cocos and the reprofiling of debt payments

Sovereign cocos and the reprofiling of debt payments Sovereign cocos and the reprofiling of debt payments Juan Carlos Hatchondo Indiana U. Yasin Kürşat Önder Central Bank of Turkey Leonardo Martinez IMF Francisco Roch IMF VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE

More information

Debt dilution and sovereign default risk

Debt dilution and sovereign default risk Debt dilution and sovereign default risk Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez César Sosa Padilla December 13, 2010 Abstract We propose a sovereign default framework that allows us to quantify the importance

More information

Identifying the exchange-rate balance sheet effect over firms

Identifying the exchange-rate balance sheet effect over firms Identifying the exchange-rate balance sheet effect over firms CÉSAR CARRERA Banco Central de Reserva del Perú Abstract: This version: May 2014 I use firm-level data on investment and evaluate the balance

More information

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Yan Bai University of Rochester NBER Dan Lu University of Rochester Xu Tian University of Rochester February

More information

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks Princeton University Press, 217 Motivation Interest-rate shocks are generally believed to be a major source of fluctuations for emerging countries. The next slide

More information

Reputational Effects in Sovereign Default

Reputational Effects in Sovereign Default Reputational Effects in Sovereign Default Konstantin Egorov 1 Michal Fabinger 2 1 Pennsylvania State University 2 University of Tokyo OAP-PRI Economic Workshop Konstantin Egorov, Michal Fabinger Reputational

More information

Growth Regimes, Endogenous Elections, and Sovereign Default Risk

Growth Regimes, Endogenous Elections, and Sovereign Default Risk Growth Regimes, Endogenous Elections, and Sovereign Default Risk Satyajit Chatterjee and Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2016 Abstract A model in which the sovereign derives

More information

Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi

Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi Alessandra Vincenzi VR 097844 Marco Novello VR 362520 The paper is focus on This paper deals with the empirical

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Quantitative Models of Sovereign Default on External Debt

Quantitative Models of Sovereign Default on External Debt Quantitative Models of Sovereign Default on External Debt Argentina: Default risk and Business Cycles External default in the literature Topic was heavily studied in the 1980s in the aftermath of defaults

More information

Enrique Martínez-García. University of Texas at Austin and Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

Enrique Martínez-García. University of Texas at Austin and Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Discussion: International Recessions, by Fabrizio Perri (University of Minnesota and FRB of Minneapolis) and Vincenzo Quadrini (University of Southern California) Enrique Martínez-García University of

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research 1. Introduction

More information

Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default

Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default RESEARCH SEMINAR IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy The University of Michigan Ann Arbor, Michigan 48109-3091 Discussion Paper No. 596 Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized

More information

International Reserves Management in a Model of Partial Sovereign Default

International Reserves Management in a Model of Partial Sovereign Default Department of Economics- FEA/USP International Reserves Management in a Model of Partial Sovereign Default RICARDO SABBADINI WORKING PAPER SERIES Nº 2018-14 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FEA-USP WORKING PAPER

More information

Quantitative Models of Sovereign Debt Crises

Quantitative Models of Sovereign Debt Crises Quantitative Models of Sovereign Debt Crises Mark Aguiar Princeton University Satyajit Chatterjee Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Harold Cole University of Pennsylvania Zachary Stangebye University

More information

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez January 30, 2009 Abstract This paper extends the baseline framework used in recent quantitative studies of sovereign default

More information

Precautionary Demand for Foreign Assets in Sudden Stop Economies: An Assessment of the New Mercantilism

Precautionary Demand for Foreign Assets in Sudden Stop Economies: An Assessment of the New Mercantilism Precautionary Demand for Foreign Assets in Sudden Stop Economies: An Assessment of the New Mercantilism Ceyhun Bora Durdu Enrique G. Mendoza Marco E. Terrones Board of Governors of the University of Maryland

More information

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES KRISTOFFER P. NIMARK Lucas Island Model The Lucas Island model appeared in a series of papers in the early 970s

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

Asymmetric Stabilizing Impact of International Reserves

Asymmetric Stabilizing Impact of International Reserves Asymmetric Stabilizing Impact of International Reserves Kyungkeun Kim and Dongwon Lee, a The Bank of Korea, 39 Namdaemun-ro, Jung-gu, Seoul, 04531, Republic of Korea b Department of Economics, University

More information

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Nicolas Coeurdacier (SciencesPo & CEPR) Helene Rey (LBS & NBER & CEPR) Pablo Winant (PSE) Barcelona June 2013 Coeurdacier, Rey, Winant Financial Integration...

More information

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES Mahir Binici Central Bank of Turkey Istiklal Cad. No:10 Ulus, Ankara/Turkey E-mail: mahir.binici@tcmb.gov.tr

More information

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Leonid Kogan 1 Dimitris Papanikolaou 2 1 MIT and NBER 2 Northwestern University Boston, June 5, 2009 Kogan,

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending Michael Reiter 1 Leopold Zessner 2 1 Instiute for Advances Studies, Vienna 2 Vienna Graduate School of Economics Barcelona GSE Summer Forum ADEMU,

More information

The sovereign default puzzle: A new approach to debt sustainability analysis

The sovereign default puzzle: A new approach to debt sustainability analysis The sovereign default puzzle: A new approach to debt sustainability analysis Frankfurt joint lunch seminar Daniel Cohen 1 Sébastien Villemot 2 1 Paris School of Economics and CEPR 2 Dynare Team, CEPREMAP

More information

Working Paper Series Long-Duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults WP 08-02R

Working Paper Series Long-Duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults WP 08-02R Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/economic_ research/working_papers/index.cfm Long-Duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan

More information

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis Luigi Bocola Gideon Bornstein Alessandro Dovis August 23, 2018 Abstract A large literature has developed quantitative versions of the

More information

Voluntary Debt Exchanges in Sovereign Debt Markets

Voluntary Debt Exchanges in Sovereign Debt Markets Voluntary Debt Exchanges in Sovereign Debt Markets Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez César Sosa Padilla Indiana University and Richmond Fed IMF McMaster University PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract

More information

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop, Mendoza (AER) Sudden Stop facts 1. Large, abrupt reversals in capital flows 2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic production, absorption, asset prices, credit & leverage 3. Capital,

More information

Threats to Financial Stability in Emerging Markets: The New (Very Active) Role of Central Banks. LILIANA ROJAS-SUAREZ Chicago, November 2011

Threats to Financial Stability in Emerging Markets: The New (Very Active) Role of Central Banks. LILIANA ROJAS-SUAREZ Chicago, November 2011 Threats to Financial Stability in Emerging Markets: The New (Very Active) Role of Central Banks LILIANA ROJAS-SUAREZ Chicago, November 2011 Currently, the Major Threats to Financial Stability in Emerging

More information

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez February 6, 2009 Abstract This paper extends the baseline framework used in recent quantitative studies of sovereign default

More information

International recessions

International recessions International recessions Fabrizio Perri University of Minnesota Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California July 16, 2010 Abstract The 2008-2009 US crisis is characterized by un unprecedent degree

More information

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis Luigi Bocola Gideon Bornstein Alessandro Dovis December 23, 2018 Abstract A large literature has developed quantitative versions of the

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Information Processing and Limited Liability Information Processing and Limited Liability Bartosz Maćkowiak European Central Bank and CEPR Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University January 2012 Abstract Decision-makers often face limited liability

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

Macro-hedging and sovereign default for commodity exporters

Macro-hedging and sovereign default for commodity exporters Macro-hedging and sovereign default for commodity exporters Chang Ma Johns Hopkins University Fabián Valencia International Monetary Fund This draft: January 31, 2017 Abstract Motivated by Mexico s oil

More information

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies Tarishi Matsuoka Tokyo Metropolitan University May, 2015 Tarishi Matsuoka (TMU) Banking Crises in Emerging Market Economies May, 2015 1 / 47 Introduction

More information

Lecture 4. Extensions to the Open Economy. and. Emerging Market Crises

Lecture 4. Extensions to the Open Economy. and. Emerging Market Crises Lecture 4 Extensions to the Open Economy and Emerging Market Crises Mark Gertler NYU June 2009 0 Objectives Develop micro-founded open-economy quantitative macro model with real/financial interactions

More information

Government spending and firms dynamics

Government spending and firms dynamics Government spending and firms dynamics Pedro Brinca Nova SBE Miguel Homem Ferreira Nova SBE December 2nd, 2016 Francesco Franco Nova SBE Abstract Using firm level data and government demand by firm we

More information

Commodity Prices and Sovereign Default: A New Perspective on the Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Effect

Commodity Prices and Sovereign Default: A New Perspective on the Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Effect Commodity Prices and Sovereign Default: A New Perspective on the Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Effect Franz Hamann 1 Enrique G. Mendoza 2 Paulina Restrepo-Echavarria 3 ASSA Meetings, Philadelphia 2018 Introduction

More information

A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade

A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade Grace W. Gu February 12, 2015 (click here for the latest version) Abstract This paper explores the impacts of sovereign defaults on

More information

Volatility Risk Pass-Through

Volatility Risk Pass-Through Volatility Risk Pass-Through Ric Colacito Max Croce Yang Liu Ivan Shaliastovich 1 / 18 Main Question Uncertainty in a one-country setting: Sizeable impact of volatility risks on growth and asset prices

More information

Foreign Currency Debt, Financial Crises and Economic Growth : A Long-Run Exploration

Foreign Currency Debt, Financial Crises and Economic Growth : A Long-Run Exploration Foreign Currency Debt, Financial Crises and Economic Growth : A Long-Run Exploration Michael D. Bordo Rutgers University and NBER Christopher M. Meissner UC Davis and NBER GEMLOC Conference, World Bank,

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

A simple wealth model

A simple wealth model Quantitative Macroeconomics Raül Santaeulàlia-Llopis, MOVE-UAB and Barcelona GSE Homework 5, due Thu Nov 1 I A simple wealth model Consider the sequential problem of a household that maximizes over streams

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 2013 North American Summer Meeting Ralph Lütticke 13.06.2013 1 Joint-work with Christian Bayer, Lien Pham, and Volker Tjaden 1 / 30 Research

More information

Deflation, Credit Collapse and Great Depressions. Enrique G. Mendoza

Deflation, Credit Collapse and Great Depressions. Enrique G. Mendoza Deflation, Credit Collapse and Great Depressions Enrique G. Mendoza Main points In economies where agents are highly leveraged, deflation amplifies the real effects of credit crunches Credit frictions

More information

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from: Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez Federal

More information

Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default

Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default Yun Jung Kim Jing Zhang University of Michigan University of Michigan February 3, 212 Abstract In the past, foreign borrowing by developing countries was

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007 Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert February 15, 2007 Abstract In this paper we use a simple model with a single Cobb Douglas firm and a consumer with

More information

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility Current Account Balances and Output Volatility Ceyhun Elgin Bogazici University Tolga Umut Kuzubas Bogazici University Abstract: Using annual data from 185 countries over the period from 1950 to 2009,

More information

A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade

A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade Grace W. Gu February 22, 2015 (click here for the latest version) Abstract This paper explores the impacts of sovereign defaults on

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno Fabrizio Perri Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR fperri@umn.edu December

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Part A (Prof. Laibson): 60 minutes Part B (Prof. Barro): 60

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Mitsuru Katagiri International Monetary Fund October 24, 2017 @Keio University 1 / 42 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of

More information

Demand Effects and Speculation in Oil Markets: Theory and Evidence

Demand Effects and Speculation in Oil Markets: Theory and Evidence Demand Effects and Speculation in Oil Markets: Theory and Evidence Eyal Dvir (BC) and Ken Rogoff (Harvard) IMF - OxCarre Conference, March 2013 Introduction Is there a long-run stable relationship between

More information

Debt Denomination and Default Risk in Emerging Markets

Debt Denomination and Default Risk in Emerging Markets Debt Denomination and Default Risk in Emerging Markets Inci Gumus Sabanci University Abstract The inability of emerging market economies to borrow in domestic currency in international financial markets

More information

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel Martin Eichenbaum, Sergio Rebelo, and Arlene Wong May 2018 Motivation In the US, bulk of household borrowing is in fixed rate mortgages with

More information

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Sudden Stops and Output Drops Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 353 January 2005 Sudden Stops and Output Drops V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Patrick J.

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A SOLUTION TO THE DISCONNECT BETWEEN COUNTRY RISK AND BUSINESS CYCLE THEORIES. Enrique G. Mendoza Vivian Z.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A SOLUTION TO THE DISCONNECT BETWEEN COUNTRY RISK AND BUSINESS CYCLE THEORIES. Enrique G. Mendoza Vivian Z. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A SOLUTION TO THE DISCONNECT BETWEEN COUNTRY RISK AND BUSINESS CYCLE THEORIES Enrique G. Mendoza Vivian Z. Yue Working Paper 13861 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13861 NATIONAL BUREAU

More information

1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1

1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1 Contents Preface xvii 1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1 1.1 Measuring Business Cycles 1 1.2 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 4 1.3 Business Cycles in Poor, Emerging, and Rich Countries 7 1.4

More information

Optimal Devaluations

Optimal Devaluations Optimal Devaluations Constantino Hevia World Bank Juan Pablo Nicolini Minneapolis Fed and Di Tella April 2012 Which is the optimal response of monetary policy in a small open economy, following a shock

More information

On the Welfare Losses from External Sovereign Borrowing

On the Welfare Losses from External Sovereign Borrowing On the Welfare Losses from External Sovereign Borrowing Mark Aguiar Princeton University Manuel Amador Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and University of Minnesota Stelios Fourakis University of Minnesota

More information

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession The Lost Generation of the Great Recession Sewon Hur University of Pittsburgh January 21, 2016 Introduction What are the distributional consequences of the Great Recession? Introduction What are the distributional

More information

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Advanced Macroeconomics II Professor Lorenza Rossi/Jordi Gali T.A. Daniël van Schoot, daniel.vanschoot@upf.edu Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Schedule: 28th of May (seminar 4): Exercises 1, 2 and

More information

On the Optimality of Financial Repression

On the Optimality of Financial Repression On the Optimality of Financial Repression V.V. Chari, Alessandro Dovis and Patrick Kehoe Conference in honor of Robert E. Lucas Jr, October 2016 Financial Repression Regulation forcing financial institutions

More information

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Policy Research Working Paper 6525 Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in

More information

Commodity price movements and monetary policy in Asia

Commodity price movements and monetary policy in Asia Commodity price movements and monetary policy in Asia Changyong Rhee 1 and Hangyong Lee 2 Abstract Emerging Asian economies typically have high shares of food in their consumption baskets, relatively low

More information

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013 Comprehensive Exam August 19, 2013 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question. Good luck! 1 1 Menu

More information