A Theory of Buyer Fragmentation: Divide and Conquer Intensifies Competition

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Theory of Buyer Fragmentation: Divide and Conquer Intensifies Competition"

Transcription

1 TSE 543 November 2014 A Theory of Buyer Fragmentation: Divide and Conquer Intensifies Competition Doh Shin Jeon and Domenico Menicucci

2 A Theory of Buyer Fragmentation: Divide-and-Conquer Intensifies Competition Doh-Shin Jeon and Domenico Menicucci November 26, 2014 Abstract It is well-known from Innes and Sexton (1993, 1994) that divide-and-conquer contracts allow an incumbent facing a potential entrant to extract more surplus from buyers and hence buyers suffer from the strategy. In this paper, we show that when sellers compete by offering personalized non-linear tariffs, divide-and-conquer strategies intensify competition among sellers in the presence of indirect contracting externalities. Therefore, buyers prefer remaining fragmented to forming a buyer group. When buyer group formation is decided before the entry of an entrant, our result implies that buyers may deliberately induce a socially suboptimal entry by remaining fragmented in order to benefit from more intense competition upon the entry. Keywords: Divde-and-Conquer, Buyer Group, Indirect Contracting Externalities, Common Agency, Competition in Non-linear Tariffs, Multimarket Contact. JEL numbers: D4, K21, L41, L82 We thank Zhiun Chen, Jay Pil Choi, Vincenzo Denicolo and the audience who attended our presentations at EARIE, EEA-ESEM, Postal Economics Conference on "E-commerce, Digital Economy and Delivery Services" (Toulouse, 2014), Yonsei University. Toulouse School of Economics (GREMAQ, IDEI) and CEPR. dohshin.eon@gmail.com Università degli Studi di Firenze, Italy. domenico.menicucci@dmd.unifi.it

3 1 Introduction In many sectors, buyers purchasing multiple products can form a buyer group. Examples of buyer groups abound in retailing, health care, agriculture, academic ournals, etc. In addition, existing buyer groups can expand their size by merging with other groups. Understanding how buyer group affects buyer power is very important given the increasing policy makers concerns about buyer power (European Commission, 1999 and OECD, 2008). 1 In this paper, we study how the formation of a buyer group affects the total payoff of the buyers and each seller s payoff. We investigate this question in a situation when multiple sellers compete by offering personalized non-linear tariffs and each buyer (and buyer group) is interested in buying a positive quantity from each seller. More precisely, the case of buyer group is modelled as a common agency à la Bernheim and Whinston (1986, 1998). For the case of no buyer group, we consider a natural extension of the common agency to multiple buyers in which each buyer operates in a separate market. We show that buyers prefer to remain fragmented since then each seller can use divide-andconquer strategies, which intensify competition among sellers in the presence of indirect contracting externalities among buyers. 2 We consider a model of two sellers and two buyers. In the absence of the buyer group, the indirect contracting externalities between the buyers exist if the modification of the vertical contract between seller and buyer i creates an incentive for seller to modify its contract offer to buyer h ( i). For instance, when the sellers costs are convex, the contracting externalities exist. In addition, without buyer group, seller can deviate with a divide-and-conquer strategy, which means that he induces one buyer to buy exclusively from seller, but induces the other buyer to buy from both seller and seller k ( ). 3 When seller k s offer is given, sometimes a divide-and-conquer strategy allows seller to obtain a strictly higher profit than the profit it can realize otherwise. This captures the conventional wisdom that a monopolist facing buyers with exogenously given outside offers can realize a higher profit with the divide-and-conquer strategy (Innes and Sexton, 1993, 1994). However, when sellers compete, seller k s offer cannot be an equilibrium offer if seller s best response consists in divide-and-conquer. 4 1 In US, the Federal Trade Commission organized a workshop on slotting allowances in 2000, a maor buyer power issue in grocery retailing. See Chen (2007) for a survey of the literature on buyer power and antitrust policy implications. 2 Note that in our model, there is no direct contracting externalities among buyers since each buyer operates in a separate market. 3 We use "he" for a seller and "she" for a buyer. 4 We assume that social welfare maximization requires each buyer to buy a positive quantity from each seller and show that all equilibria are effi cient regardless of whether or not the buyers form a group. 1

4 Hence in equilibrium seller k provides a more attractive offer which can resist the divideand-conquer strategy of seller, and the same reasoning applies to seller s offer with respect to the divide-and-conquer strategy of seller k. Therefore, divide-and-conquer strategies intensify competition between the sellers. In order to benefit from this intense competition, the buyers have an incentive to remain fragmented. However, if there are no indirect contracting externalities, which occurs if the marginal costs are constant, there is no link between buyer i s market and buyer h( i) s market as long as the sellers sell substitutes. Therefore, in this case, divide-and-conquer strategies have no bite and buyer group affects no player s payoff with respect to no buyer group. Examples in which buyers (or buyer group) buy multiple products from multiple sellers and sellers compete by offering personalized non-linear tariffs abound. Hospitals (or groups of hospitals) buy different drugs or vaccines from multiple pharmaceutical firms, and the latter often offer different non-linear tariffs to different hospitals (or cooperatives). 5 Similarly, in the case of the market for academic ournals, each library (or library consortium) buys subscriptions to distinct academic ournals from multiple publishers, and publishers provide personalized prices to different libraries (or library consortia). 6 As long as each buyer participating in a buyer group is a firm, it is very natural to consider that each buyer buys multiple inputs from multiple sellers, and that these sellers compete by offering personalized non-linear tariffs. However, the existing literature on buyer group studies only situations in which each buyer or buyer group buys exclusively from one among competing sellers: see in particular Inderst and Shaffer (2007) and Dana (2012). 7 Although exclusive purchase is often practiced, non-exclusive purchase should be the norm when firms buy diverse inputs which are not very close substitutes. We add some novel insights to the literature on buyer group by analyzing the situation of non-exclusive purchases. For the most part of the paper, we assume that the two products offered by the sellers are strict substitutes (and we consider independent products as a benchmark and in Section 6.3 allow for complements). We consider tariffs such that what buyer i pays to seller depends only on the quantity that the buyer purchases from seller, not on the quantity it purchases from seller k ( ). In addition, we assume that each buyer s 5 See for instance the French antitrust case against GlaxoSmithKline France (Autorité de Concurrence, 2007) in which GlaxoSmithKline offered different non-linear prices to different hospitals or groups of hospitals. In the U.S., Tyco Health Care has been accused of entering into contracts requiring miniumshare with group-purchasing organizations (Masimo v. Tyco Health Care, Case No. CV , Lexis (CD Cal. Mar 2006). 6 According to Derk Haank (2001), CEO of Elsevier Science What we are basically doing is to say that you pay depending on how useful the publication is for you - estimated by how often you use it. 7 An exception is our paper on the library consortium (Jeon and Menicucci, 2014): see the literature review in Section 1.1 for more details. 2

5 utility function is strictly concave and each seller cost function is either linear or strictly convex. In the case of buyer group, we start with the sell-out equilibrium, which achieves the effi cient allocation (Bernheim and Whinston, 1986, 1998). We also show that there exists an effi cient two-part tariff equilibrium and, furthermore that any convex combination of the sell-out strategy and the two-part tariff constitutes an equilibrium tariff. We remind the result from Bernheim and Whinston (1998) that in no equilibrium a seller can obtain a payoff strictly higher than the payoff he obtains in the sell-out equilibrium. We also show that under our assumption of concave utility and convex cost, all equilibria are effi cient. 8 In the case of no buyer group, we first show that all equilibria are effi cient and that in no equilibrium a seller can obtain a payoff strictly higher than the payoff he obtains in the sell-out equilibrium under buyer group. These results imply also that in no equilibrium the buyers can obtain a total payoff strictly lower than the payoff they obtain in the sell-out equilibrium under buyer group. Given these first results on the case of no buyer group, we first show two different conditions for buyer group neutrality (i.e., buyer group affects neither any seller s payoff nor the total payoff of the buyers). First, when the products have independent values, each seller is a monopolist. Then each seller can realize the monopoly profit regardless of whether or not the buyers form a group. Second, when costs are linear, there is no indirect contracting externality in the sense that when seller and buyer i modify the quantity they trade, it has no impact on the marginal cost of seller and hence seller has no incentive to modify its contract offer to buyer h ( i). Therefore each buyer s market can be studied in isolation. The main case of interest is when the products are strict substitutes and the sellers costs are strictly convex. In this case, there exist indirect contracting externalities. We first show that the sell-out equilibrium does not exist because of the divide-and-conquer strategy which exploits the indirect contracting externalities. However, an effi cient twopart tariff equilibrium always exists. As the main result, we show that each seller s highest equilibrium payoff without buyer group is strictly lower than the payoff in the sell-out equilibrium under buyer group, which implies that the lowest total equilibrium payoff of the buyers is strictly larger than their payoff in the sell-out equilibrium under buyer group. To gain further insight, we consider the setting of symmetric buyers and show that 8 This is because in any equilibrium, given the output that the buyer group buys from seller k( ), seller chooses its output to maximize the oint surplus from the trade with the group. Therefore, the first-order conditions for each seller s profit maximization problem are identical to those of a benevolent social planner, and they are suffi cient for maximization of social welfare given our assumptions of concave utility functions and convex cost functions. 3

6 starting from any equilibrium tariffs under buyer group, we can find tariffs that implement the same outcome as an equilibrium without buyer group if divide-and-conquer strategies are prohibited. This shows that it is essentially the divide-and-conquer strategy that creates the difference between the case with buyer group and the case without group. In addition, in the symmetric setting (i.e., buyers and sellers are symmetric), when we consider the convex combination of sell-out strategy and effi cient two-part tariff, we find that there is a cut-off weight (strictly smaller than one) on the sell-out strategy such that the convex combination constitutes an equilibrium under no buyer group only if the weight is smaller than the cut-off. Given that the sellers extract more surplus from the buyers as the weight increases, this result shows that in equilibrium a seller cannot extract too high surplus under no buyer group since otherwise the other seller could profitably deviate by using the divide-and-conquer strategy. In Section 6.3, we consider the case in which the two products can be substitutes or complements while the cost functions are linear (hence there is no indirect contracting externalities). Then, buyer group has no effect on any player s payoff if the products sold by the sellers are complements to both buyers (or substitutes to both buyers). But if the products are strict substitutes for buyer 1, say, and strict complements for buyer 2, then buyer group reduces the buyers total payoff. 9 This is because the sellers have some residual market power with respect to buyer, as each seller charges less than the incremental value of its product because charging the incremental value leads to a strictly negative payoff for buyer 2. Buyer group allows the sellers to transfer the residual market power to buyer 1 in the same way as multi-market contact facilitates collusion by transferring residual collusive power from one market to another (Bernheim and Whinston, 1990). 10 Finally, we apply our insight to the situation in which one seller s entry is endogenous and the buyers decide whether or not to form a group before the entry decision. The entrant has to incur a fixed cost of entry, which is a random draw from a (commonly known) distribution as in Aghion and Bolton (1987), Chen and Shaffer (2014) and Innes and Sexton (1994). When the buyers decide to form a group or not, they do not know the fixed cost of entry. In this situation, the buyers face a clear trade-off. Formation of the buyer group increases the probability of entry but reduces the total payoff of the buyers conditional on entry. In particular, if we assume that the sellers play the Pareto-superior equilibrium, then the private decision of entry coincides with the socially optimal one under buyer group since the entrant captures the social incremental value of his product in the sell-out equilibrium. This suggests that whenever the buyers decide 9 As an example, a car and an airplane can be substitutes for a traveller of short distance but complements for a traveller of long distance. 10 Inderst and Shaffer (2007) and Dana (2012) do not find this result because they do not allow for complementary products. 4

7 to remain fragmented, there is a socially suboptimal entry. The existing literature on exclusion has explained suboptimal entry either by focusing on the incumbent s extracting surplus from the entrant (Aghion and Bolton, 1987) or the incumbent s taking advantage of coordination failure among buyers (Rasmusen, Ramseyer and Wiley 1991, Segal and Whinston, 2000, Chen and Shaffer, 2014). We provide an alternative explanation for the insuffi cient entry from the self-interest of buyers. The paper is organized as follows. Section 1.1 presents a review of the related literature. Section 2 introduces our model and Section 3 illustrates our main results through a simple quadratic setting. Section 4 studies the case of buyer group, Section 5 studies the case of no buyer group and Section 6 compares the two cases. Section 7 analyzes endogenous entry and Section 8 provides concluding remarks. 1.1 Literature review Divide-and-conquer contracts were first studied by Innes and Sexton (1993, 1994). They analyze the situation in which a monopolist seller faces identical buyers who may form a coalition to introduce a rival seller by sharing a fixed cost. They show that when buyers make acceptance decisions sequentially, the monopolist finds it optimal to discriminate the buyers by using the divide-and-conquer strategy: it makes a higher compensation to early buyers than to late buyers since once the former accepted the contract, the latter can share the fixed cost among a smaller number of buyers and hence has a weaker outside option. Therefore, the divide-and-conquer strategy hurts the buyers since it allows the monopolist to extract more surplus. 11 By contrast, we show that when sellers compete, buyers can benefit from divide-and-conquer strategy by remaining fragmented since divide-and-conquer strategy intensifies competition among sellers. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to analyze the effect of buyer group in a framework that extends the common agency (Bernheim and Whinston, 1986, 1998) to multiple buyers. Prat and Rustichini (2003) analyze a more general framework than ours that has multiple sellers and buyers and prove the existence of an effi cient equilibrium, under the assumptions that buyers utility functions are concave and sellers cost functions are convex, by allowing for more complex tariffs than ours. Precisely, Prat and Rustichini (2003) allow seller to make buyer i s payment depend on the whole vector of i s purchases such that the payment depends on q i and also on qk i for each seller k different from. However, they do not specify the equilibrium strategies and do not compare the case of buyer group with the case of no group. In our two-buyer-two-seller setting, we consider tariff such that the payment of each buyer i to each seller only depends on q, i the 11 The divide-and-conquer idea has been subsequently used in the literature on two-sided markets (Caillaud and Jullien, 2001, 2003 and Jullien 2011). 5

8 quantity buyer i buys from seller. Under the assumption of substitute goods and convex cost functions, we show that two-part tariffs constitute an effi cient equilibrium. We show additional results by considering the class of tariffs composed of a convex combination of sell-out strategy and two-part tariff. Jeon and Menicucci (2012) extends the common agency to competition between portfolios in the presence of the buyer s slot constraint and provide conditions to make the "sell-out equilibrium" the unique equilibrium. 12 Our paper is related to the papers that study buyer group when sellers compete: Inderst and Shaffer (2007), Marvel and Yang (2008), Dana (2012), Chen and Li (2013). 13 Among those paper, our paper is more closely related to Inderst and Shaffer (2007) and Dana (2012) since they assume that sellers have complete information on buyers preferences and hence can offer personalized tariffs, regardless of whether or not buyers form a group. 14 Although the two papers differ in the way they generalize their results, 15 the main insight can be obtained by considering a two-seller-two-buyer setting in which each buyer buys one unit from only one of the two sellers. They assume that the buyer group makes exclusive purchase commitment and that sellers make a take-it-or-leave-it offer. In this setup, a buyer group never decreases its members total payoffs: it strictly increases the members total payoffs unless they have identical preferences; it has no impact on the members payoffs in case of identical preferences. There are three main differences between our paper and Inderst and Shaffer (2007) and Dana (2012). First, in our paper, 12 Contrary to what happens under slot constraint, Jeon and Menicucci (2006) show that in the presence of the buyer s budget constraint, the well-known result in the common agency literature that competition between sellers achieves the outcome that maximizes all parties oint payoff fails to hold. 13 Some papers study buyer coalition in a monopoly setting. Chipty and Snyder (1999) and Inderst and Wey (2007) consider some specific bargaining models and find that a convex cost function for the seller helps to make profitable the formation of a buyer group. This occurs because the incremental costs to serve the group is lower than the sum of the incremental cost to serve each member, and buyers are assumed to have some bargaining power. Since we consider take-it-leave-it offers from sellers, this effect is absent in our setting. Alger (1999) studies a monopolist s optimal menu of price-quantity pairs when (a continuum of) consumers can purchase multiple times and/or ointly in a two-type setting. While the previous papers consider buyer coalition formation under complete information, Jeon and Menicucci (2005) study a monopolist s optimal menu of price-quantity pairs when buyers form a coalition under asymmetric information between themselves. 14 For instance, in Marvel and Yang (2008) and Chen and Li (2013), buyers are located on the Hotelling line and each seller makes the same price offer to all buyers in the absence of buyer group. However, Marvel and Yang (2008) and our paper are similar in one aspect: when buyers form a group, sellers propose non-linear tariffs and the group can buy a positive quantity from both sellers. 15 Inderst and Shaffer (2007) consider competition in non-linear tariff between the two sellers and extend their result to a bargaining setup. They also make each seller s choice of product characteristics endogenous. Dana (2012) considers n sellers, a continuum of buyers, and allows that different buyer groups are formed. He proves that the grand coalition is a coalition-proof subgame perfect equilibrium when there are two sellers. 6

9 the buyer group does not make exclusive purchase commitment and each buyer and buyer group can buy multiple units from both sellers. Second, in their models, there is no indirect contracting externalities when buyers are not integrated. Last, contrary to what happens in their papers, in our paper, buyers never gain by forming a buyer group. Our paper is closely related to our companion paper (Jeon and Menicucci, 2014) which studies library consortium in the market for academic ournals. Each seller (i.e., publisher) is a monopolist of its ournals and sells a bundle of its electronic academic ournals at personalized price(s). However, there are no indirect contracting externalities such that in the absence of buyer group (i.e., library consortium), each library s market can be studied in isolation. Competition among sellers occurs because of the budget constraint of each buyer. We find that depending on the degree of correlation between each member library s preferences, building a library consortium can increase or reduce the total payoffs of the buyers. 16 Contracting externalities have been studied in several papers such as Hart and Tirole (1990), Bernheim and Whinston (1998), Segal (1999) etc. However, all these papers deal with direct contracting externalities that arise for instance when buyers compete in product market or sellers compete in input market. Since we assume away any such direct interactions between buyers in the product market or between sellers in the input market, there is no direct contracting externalities in our paper. Instead, the existence of indirect contracting externalities is a necessary condition for the divide-and-conquer strategy to create a difference between the case of buyer group and the case of no group. 2 The Model There are two sellers, A and B, and two buyers, 1 and 2. Let q i 0 represent the quantity of the product that buyer i (= 1, 2) buys from seller (= A, B). For each buyer i, the gross utility from consuming (qa i, qi B ) is given by U i (qa i, qi B ), with U i strictly increasing and strictly concave in (qa i, qi B ); precisely, we suppose that U i / q i 0 as q i +, and that the Hessian matrix of U i is negative definite at any (qa i, qi B ). Moreover, we assume that the two goods are substitutes for each buyer i: 2 U i / qa i qi B 0 at any point.17 For each seller, the cost of serving the buyers is C (q 1 + q 2 ), with C convex and strictly increasing. Each seller offers a non-linear tariffto each buyer (or to the buyer group). In particular, we consider tariffs such that what buyer i pays to seller depends only on the quantity that the buyer purchases from seller, not on the quantity she purchases from the other 16 Therefore, in terms of the results, the companion paper is situationed between Inderst and Shaffer (2007) and Dana (2012), on the one hand, and the current paper, on the other hand. 17 We consider a case with complementary goods in Proposition 8. 7

10 seller. When there is no buyer group, we allow each seller to offer personalized non-linear tariffs: the tariff offered by seller to buyer i is denoted by T i (q) (with T i (0) = 0), and can be different from the tariff seller offers to buyer h ( i). After seeing the tariffs, buyer i chooses (qa i, qi B ) in order to maximize U i (qa i, qi B ) T A i (qi A ) T B i (qi B ). When the buyers form a buyer group, the sellers compete for serving the group. Let G denote the buyer group, q G the quantity G buys from seller, and T G (q) the non-linear tariff that seller offers to G (with T G (0) = 0). We define U G (qa G, qg B ) as follows: U G (q G A, q G B) max U 1 (qa, 1 qb) 1 + U 2 (qa, 2 qb) 2 (1) qa 1,q1 B,q2 A,q2 B subect to q 1 A + q 2 A = q G A, q 1 B + q 2 B = q G B. (2) Thus U G (qa G, qg B ) is the group s gross utility from buying ( qa G, B) qg, as it results from the optimal allocation of ( qa G, B) qg between the two buyers. Hence, after seeing the tariffs, G chooses ( qa G, B) qg in order to maximize U G (qa G, qg B ) T A G(qG A ) T B G(qG B ). For expositional facility, we will consider sometimes two special settings: the setting of symmetric buyers, and the symmetric setting. The setting of symmetric buyers is such that U 1 ( ) = U 2 ( ) = U( ). The symmetric setting is such that U 1 ( ) = U 2 ( ) = U( ), U(q A, q B ) = U(q B, q A ), and C A ( ) = C B ( ) C( ). Define q (qa 1, q1 B, q2 A, q2 B ) as the unique allocation vector that maximizes social welfare, 18 and VAB G as the social welfare in the first-best allocation q : q arg max (q 1 A,q1 B,q2 A,q2 B) U 1 (q 1 A, q 1 B) + U 2 (q 2 A, q 2 B) C A (q 1 A + q 2 A) C B (q 1 B + q 2 B) (3) V G AB U 1 (q 1 A, q 1 B ) + U 2 (q 2 A, q 2 B ) C A (q 1 A + q 2 A ) C B (q 1 B + q 2 B ). (4) We say that an equilibrium is effi cient if the equilibrium allocation is q. From Proposition 4 to Proposition 9, we assume that each buyer buys a positive quantity from each seller in the first best allocation: q i > 0 for i = 1, 2 and = A.B. We consider a game with the following timing: Stage 0: The buyers decide whether they will form a group or not. Stage 1: When there is no buyer group, each seller (= A, B) simultaneously chooses T i (q) for i = 1, 2. When the buyer group is formed, each seller (= A, B) simultaneously chooses T G (q). Stage 2: Each buyer i, or the buyer group, makes purchase decisions. At stage 0, the buyers form a group if and only if this leads to a higher oint payoff than under no group. 18 Our assumptions imply that for each maximization problem below, a maximizer exists and is unique, since the obective function is strictly concave. 8

11 3 A simple illustrative example Before describing our analysis, we here illustrate our main results through a simple quadratic example. Consider a specific symmetric setting described by U i (q i A, q i B) = q i A + q i B 1 2 (qi A) (qi B) qi Aq i B for i = 1, 2; (5) C (q) = 1 2 q2 for = A, B, (6) where 1/2 in 1 2 qi A qi B is a parameter of substitution. In the effi cient allocation, each buyer buys quantity q 2 from each seller and the marginal cost at the effi cient quantity is 7 C (2q ) = 4. We below present a number of results with explanations. 7 Result 1: All equilibria are effi cient regardless of whether the buyers form a group or not. This result comes from the concavity of the utility functions and the convexity of the cost functions. Result 2: Under buyer group, for any β [0, 1], there exists an equilibrium with TA G(q) = T B G(q) = F + 4(1 β)q + β 7 2 q2 where F = (4β+1)(4β+3). The buyer group s 49(2β+1) payoff decreases (and each seller s payoff increases) with β. β = 1 corresponds to the sell-out equilibrium (Bernheim and Whinston 1986, 1998): see the next section for the details. β = 0 corresponds to a two-part tariff equilibrium. Hence, according to Result 2, any convex combination of the sell-out strategy and the two-part tariff constitutes an equilibrium under buyer group. In equilibrium, the buyer group is indifferent between trading with both sellers and trading with only one seller. When the group trades with only seller, the payoff it obtains strictly decreases with β as the marginal price increases with β for any q G > 2q. Therefore, the buyer group s payoff decreases (and each seller s payoff increases) with β. When there is no buyer group, given seller k s offer, we can distinguish three deviations of seller ( k) depending on the number of buyers who are induced to keep buying from seller k. This number can vary from zero to two. In particular, the deviation inducing only one buyer to keep buying from the rival (while the other buyer buys uniquely from seller ) can be made only when there is no buyer group. We define this deviation as the divide-and-conquer strategy, as it essentially treats the two buyers differently. Result 3: When we neglect the divide-and-conquer strategy, the case of buyer group is equivalent to the case of no group: starting from any equilibrium under 9

12 buyer group TA G, T B G, we can construct an equilibrium without buyer group in which T i (q) = 1T G 2 (2q) for each i = 1, 2 and = A, B, which generates the same payoff for each player. Hence, this result shows that essentially what creates a difference between the two cases is the divide-and-conquer strategy. Result 4: Fix seller B s offer such that he offers TB G(q) = F + 4(1 β)q + β 7 2 q2 with F = (4β+1)(4β+3) under buyer group, and T i 49(2β+1) B (q) = 1T G 2 B (2q) without group. Then, seller A s payoff under no group is the same as under buyer group for β [0, 0.226], but the former is strictly higher than the latter for β (0.226, 1]. This result captures the conventional wisdom that a monopolist facing buyers who have a fixed outside option does better when buyers are divided than when they are integrated. 19 In particular, A s deviation using the divide-and-conquer strategy is profitable only when the buyers outside option is relatively weak (i.e., for β > 0.226). This in turn implies that for β > 0.226, B s offer cannot constitute an equilibrium when B can choose its offer. Therefore, we have: Result 5: Without buyer group, T i (q) = 1T G 2 (2q) (where T G (q) = F + 4(1 7 β)q + β 2 q2 with F = (4β+1)(4β+3) ) constitutes an equilibrium only for β [0, 0.226]. 49(2β+1) Therefore, when we consider the class of tariffs composed by a convex combination of the sell-out strategy and the two-part tariff, the lowest payoff for each buyer without buyer group is strictly larger than the lowest payoff under buyer group and the highest payoff for each seller without buyer group is strictly lower than the highest payoff under buyer group. Our main result (Proposition 7) shows that the above payoff comparison extends very generally to asymmetric setting (and beyond the case of quadratic utilities and costs) in which sellers can use any non-linear tariffs, as long as the cost functions are strictly convex and the products are strict substitutes. 4 Buyer group: Common agency Since the setting with the buyer group is essentially an environment with a unique buyer, our model is a model of common agency (Bernheim and Whinston 1986, 1998). Hence, it is natural to start the analysis with the so-called sell-out equilibrium (Bernheim and 19 However, the buyers are not hurt by not forming a group, since their payoff is determined by the outside option which is the same regardless of they form a group or not since T i B (q) = 1 2 T G B (2q). 10

13 Whinston 1998). In order to determine the equilibrium strategies, we need to study the case in which G trades only with one seller, for instance only with seller : ) 1 ( q, q 2 arg max U 1 (q 1, 0) + U 2 (q 2, 0) C (q 1 + q 2 ) (7) q 1,q2 V G U 1 ( q 1, 0) + U 2 ( q 2, 0) C ( q 1 + q 2 ) (8) Hence V G is the maximal social welfare when G trades with seller, but not with the other seller. A sell-out strategy for seller is defined as T G (q) = F G + C (q) for any q > 0. Given this strategy, G is required to pay the fixed fee F G for the right to buy any quantity from seller at cost. When each seller uses a sell-out strategy, the first-best allocation is achieved (provided that FA G and F B G are not too high) since G will buy qg q 1 +q 2 from each seller and allocate ( ) q 1, q 2 to the buyers. This is because after paying the fixed fees, G becomes the residual claimant over social welfare. In equilibrium it is necessary that 20 V G AB F G A F G B = V G A F G A = V G B F G B. (9) The sell-out equilibrium is given by the sell-out strategies with the fixed fees obtained from (9): FA G = VAB G VB G, FB G = VAB G VA G. The group s payoff is u G VA G +V B G V AB G, and ug 0 since goods are substitutes for each buyer. The profit π G of seller is given by F G, which is the marginal contribution to social welfare of seller, that is the first best social welfare minus the social welfare that is generated when G trades only with the other seller k( ). The sell-out equilibrium is not the unique equilibrium in the game of competition for G. For instance, a two-part tariff equilibrium exists in which each seller proposes a tariff given by T G (q) = F G + α q for any q > 0, with α = C (q G ). (10) This tariff is such that the buyer group is required to pay the fixed fee F G for the right to buy any quantity from seller at the constant marginal price α, which is the marginal cost of seller at the first best allocation q. When both sellers use tariffs of this kind, the group buys ( qa G, ) qg B and the allocation q is achieved. In fact, the next proposition shows that any convex combination of the sell-out strategy and the two-part tariff is an equilibrium tariff, and implements the allocation q. In addition, the proposition highlights two properties that any equilibrium satisfies. 20 For instance, if VAB G F A G F B G > V A G F A G, then seller B can increase his own profit by slightly increasing FB G as G will still buy from seller B. 11

14 Proposition 1 (buyer group) Suppose that the buyers have formed a group. (i) Any convex combination of the sell-out strategy and the two-part tariff (with seller s marginal price equal to α ) constitutes an equilibrium tariff: for any β [0, 1], there exists an equilibrium with tariffs T G (q) = F G + βc (q) + (1 β)α q, and a suitable F G, for = A, B. (ii) In no equilibrium, seller (=A,B) obtains a strictly higher payoff than in the sell-out equilibrium (Bernheim and Whinston 1998). (iii) Any equilibrium is effi cient. Proof. The proof of (i) is in the Appendix. Below we provide the proof of (ii) and a part of the proof of (iii) the remaining part is in the Appendix. About Proposition 1(i), notice that if C is strictly convex and β [0, 1), then the marginal price in T G for q > q G is smaller than in the sell-out strategy of seller. This matters when products are substitutes, as it increases the payoff G obtains by trading only with seller, and forces seller k to leave a higher payoff to G than in the sell-out equilibrium. This reduces the profit of seller k, and a similar argument applies to seller. In fact, each seller s profit is increasing in β. Proposition 1(ii), proved in Bernheim and Whinston (1998), applies to any equilibrium (not only to those described in Proposition 1(i)) and is based on a simple remark which we now describe. In any equilibrium, the sum of the buyer group s payoff and the profit of seller cannot be smaller than V G, otherwise seller may deviate by offering to G a suitable trade, in which G buys only from : see (7) and (8). This implies that in any equilibrium the profit of seller k( ) is at most VAB G V G, i.e., it is weakly smaller than ( ) π G k = F G k. Proposition 1(iii) is a consequence of Proposition 1 in O Brien and Shaffer (1997), which implies that in any equilibrium under buyer group, the equilibrium quantities, denoted by ( qa Ge, ) qge B, are such that q Ge A ( arg max U G (qa, G q Ge qa G B ) C A (qa) ) G, q Ge B ( arg max U G (q Ge qb G A, qb) G C B (qb) ) G. This means that qa Ge maximizes the sum of G s payoff and firm A s profit, given qg B = qge and an analogous property holds for qb Ge. Therefore { UA G(qGe A, qge B ) C A (qge A ), with equality if qge A > 0; UB G(qGe A, qge B ) C B (qge B ), with equality if qge B > 0. (11) Since U 1 and U 2 are concave, it follows that U G is concave and therefore social welfare U G (q G A, qg B ) C A(q G A ) C B(q G B ) is a concave function of ( q G A, qg B). The conditions in (11) are the necessary first order conditions for maximization of social welfare, and moreover they B, 12

15 are suffi cient since social welfare is concave. Hence ( qa Ge, ) qge B maximizes social welfare, that is q Ge A = q1 A + q2 A, qge B = q1 B + q2 B.21 5 No buyer group In this section, we study what happens when there is no buyer group. 5.1 Preliminaries When there is no buyer group, we restrict attention to non-linear tariffs such that what buyer i pays to seller depends only on what i buys from, but not on what i buys from the other seller, k. In this setting we find a result analogous to Proposition 1(ii) and (iii): Proposition 2 Suppose that there is no buyer group. (i) Any equilibrium is effi cient. (ii) In any equilibrium, seller (=A,B) obtains a weakly lower payoff than in the sell-out equilibrium under buyer group. (iii) In any equilibrium, the buyers obtain a weakly higher total payoff than in the sell-out equilibrium under buyer group. The intuition for Proposition 2(i) is similar to the intuition for Proposition 1(iii): We can prove that in any equilibrium, the equilibrium quantities (qa 1e, q1e B, q2e A, q2e B ) are such that { (qa 1e, q2e A ) arg max qa 1 (U 1 (q 1,q2 A A, q1e B ) + U 2 (qa 2, q2e B ) C A(qA 1 + q2 A )) ; (qb 1e, q2e B ) arg max qb 1 (U 1 (q 1e,q2 B A, q1 B ) + U 2 (qa 2e, q2 B ) C B(qB 1 + q2 B )). (12) This means that (qa 1e, q2e A ) maximizes the sum of the buyers total payoff and firm A s profit, given (qb 1, q2 B ) = (q1e B, q2e B ), and an analogous property holds for (q1e B, q2e B ). Since social welfare U 1 (qa 1, q1 B )+U2 (qa 2, q2 B ) C A(qA 1 +q2 A ) C B(qB 1 +q2 B ) is a concave function, it follows from (12) that (qa 1e, q1e B, q2e A, q2e B ) maximizes social welfare, that is (q1e A, q1e B, q2e A, q2e B ) = (qa 1, q1 B, q2 A, q2 B ). The intuition for Proposition 2(ii) is similar to the intuition for Proposition 1(i). Regardless of whether or not the buyers form a group, the sum of seller s payoff and the total payoff of the buyers cannot be strictly smaller than V G ; otherwise, seller can profitably deviate by proposing all buyers to exclusively deal with him. Hence, seller k s profit is weakly lower than π G k. 21 O Brien and Shaffer (1997) exhibit a setting in which an ineffi cient equilibrium exists, but that setting has discontinuous cost functions for sellers (because of a fixed cost each seller bears for each positive quantity produced). Therefore the social welfare function is not concave. 13

16 Proposition 2(iii) is a consequence of Proposition 2(i) and (ii). This result is interesting since in Inderst and Shaffer (2007) and Dana (2012), buyers never lose from building a group. This contrast in the results arises since in their papers, the buyer group commits to purchasing from a single seller, whereas in our paper there is no such commitment. 5.2 Divide-and-conquer In this subsection, we introduce the definitions of the core concepts for our analysis. We first define divide-and-conquer strategies: Definition 1 Divide-and-conquer: Suppose that there is no buyer group. A seller uses a divide-and-conquer strategy if he induces one buyer to buy exclusively from him and induces the other buyer to buy from both sellers. Definition 2 A simple divide-and-conquer strategy is a divide-and-conquer strategy such that the deviating seller deviates only in one market by inducing the buyer of the market to buy exclusively from him. We now define indirect contracting externalities: Definition 3 Indirect contracting externalities: Given (qa h, qh B ) with h {1, 2}, suppose that (q i A, q i B) with i {1, 2} and i h maximizes the surplus from the multilateral trade among seller A, seller B and buyer i. We say that there are no indirect contracting externalities if (q i A, q i B) is the same for any possible (qa h, qh B ) R2 +. We say that there are indirect contracting externalities if a change in q h for = A, B induces a change in q i. As will be clear in the next subsection, the divide-and-conquer strategy has no bite if there are no indirect contracting externalities. Direct contracting externalities (Segal, 1999) exist when the utility of buyer i directly depends on (qa h, qh B ) with h i. This can occur if the buyers compete in the same market as in Hart and Tirole (1990). In our model, there is no direct contracting externalities between the two buyers since each buyer s utility function depends only on the pair of quantities she buys, and the tariff she pays to a seller depends only on the quantity she buys from the seller. However, there can be indirect contracting externalities in the sense that a change in (qa h, qh B ) indirectly affects the payoff of buyer i ( h). This can occur if the change modifies a seller s marginal cost such that the seller in turn modifies his offer to buyer i. This is the case if sellers have strictly convex cost functions, but not if the cost functions are linear. Some analogy can be made to the distinction between direct network externalities and indirect network externalities. Direct network externalities exist if a consumer s consumption utility directly depends on the number of other consumers using the same 14

17 good (say, hardware). Even if direct network externalities do not exist, indirect network externalities exist if an increase in the number of consumers using the same hardware modifies the number of applications that can be used with the hardware. 5.3 Buyer group neutrality Proposition 2 reveals that the buyers never gain strictly by forming a group. We now show two different conditions for buyer group neutrality, which means that buyer group affects neither the buyers total payoff nor any seller s payoff. We say that products have independent values if there exist functions U i A, U i B such that U i (q i A, qi B ) = U i A (qi A )+U i B (qi B ). Proposition 3 (buyer group neutrality) Buyer group affects neither the buyers total payoff nor any seller s payoff if either of the following conditions is satisfied: (i) the products have independent values; (ii) the sellers costs are linear and the products are substitutes. When the products have independent values as in Proposition 3(i), each seller behaves like a perfectly discriminating monopolist because each buyer s valuation for seller s products does not depend on the quantity the buyer buys from the other seller. Therefore, seller can fully extract the buyers surplus regardless of whether or not they form a group. When the sellers cost functions are linear, there are no indirect contracting externalities since the effi cient allocation in market i does not depend on the allocation implemented in market h. More precisely, (q i ) is defined as follows: A, qi B (q i A, q i B ) arg max (q i A,qi B) U i (q i A, q i B) c A (q i A + q h A) c B (q i B + q h B), where c is the constant marginal cost of seller. Therefore, (qa i, qi B ) does not depend on ( qa h, B) qh. As there exist no links between competition for buyer 1 and competition for buyer 2, we can study each market in isolation and the divide-and-conquer strategy has no bite. There exists a sell-out equilibrium in each market such that without buyer group, each seller obtains the same payoff as in the sell-out equilibrium under buyer group and the buyers obtain the same total payoff as in the sell-out equilibrium under buyer group. 5.4 Indirect contracting externalities and non-existence of the sell-out equilibrium In this subsection, we consider the case in which the sellers cost functions are strictly convex and the products are strict substitutes. Therefore, indirect contracting externalities exist when there is no buyer group: an increase in qa h, for instance, increases A s 15

18 marginal cost and hence creates an incentive for A to modify the terms of its offer to buyer i ( h). We show that no sell-out equilibrium exists when there is no buyer group and q i > 0 for i = 1, 2 and = A, B. 22 As a generalization of the sell-out equilibrium to the case of two buyers, it seems natural to consider tariffs such that the tariff offered by seller to buyer i is given by a fixed fee plus the incremental cost for seller of serving buyer i given that it serves the effi cient quantity to buyer h (recall that any equilibrium is effi cient from Proposition 2(i)). More precisely, we consider the following tariffs: T i (q) = F i +C (q+q h ) C (q h ) for any q > 0, for each i = 1, 2 and = A, B. (13) The term C (q + q h ) C (q h ) is the incremental cost for seller to produce q for buyer i, given that already accepted to produce q h for buyer h.( i) The tariff in (13) is such that buyer i is required to pay the fixed fee F i for the right to buy any quantity from seller at the incremental cost incurred by. If the other seller uses a tariff analogous to (13), then each buyer i buys (qa i, qi B ) and the first-best allocation q is realized. Since it is important to understand how divide-and-conquer strategies in the presence of indirect contracting externalities make this equilibrium not exist, we below provide an explanation for the symmetric setting. 23 Suppose U 1 ( ) = U 2 ( ) U( ) with U( ) symmetric and C A ( ) = C B ( ) C( ). This implies qa 1 = q2 A = q1 B = q2 B q. Let U U(q, q ) and C C(2q ). We consider a symmetric strategy profile (i.e., each seller offers the same tariff T (q) to each buyer) that implements the first best allocation, as it occurs in any equilibrium. Let T TA 1(q ) = TA 2(q ) = TB 1(q ) = TB 2(q ). Therefore, the profit of each seller is π = 2T C. The payoff of each buyer is U 2T, which is equal to the payoff u each buyer can obtain from trading with a single seller, u max q [U(q, 0) T (q)] = U 2T. Suppose now that seller A uses a simple divide-and-conquer strategy. Namely, in market 1, A makes a take-it-or-leave-it offer (q, t) to induce buyer 1 to buy only from A (i.e., (q, t) satisfying U(q, 0) t u ) but A does not deviate in market 2. Since A still has revenue T from buyer 2, his profit from the deviation is U(q, 0) u +T C(q +q ), and therefore the deviation is profitable for A if and only if max [U(q, 0) u + T C(q + q )] > 2T C. (14) q This inequality can be simply interpreted as the condition that the deviation increases the sum of seller A and buyer 1 s payoffs 24, and is equivalent to max q [U(q, 0) (C(q + q ) C )] > max [U(q, 0) (T (q) T )]. (15) q 22 For instance, if qa 1 > 0, q1 B > 0 and q2 A = q2 B = 0 then Proposition 4 below does not hold. 23 In the Appendix, we provide a general proof: see the proof of Proposition For this interpretation, write (14) as max q [U(q, 0) + T C(q + q )] > u + 2T C. 16

19 In the case of the sell-out contract, we have T (q) = F + C(q + q ) C(q ) as in (13) and we find that the left hand side in (15) is equal to the right hand side. Hence, A is indifferent between not deviating at all and deviating only in market 1. However, after the deviation, A supplies buyer 1 some quantity larger than qa 1 because the products are strict substitutes. This increases A s marginal cost and creates an opportunity to profitably deviate in market 2 by selling qa 2 (< q2 A ) to buyer 2. Hence, indirect contracting externalities imply that A can find a suitable divide-and-conquer strategy to profitably deviate in both markets. This implies that no sell-out equilibrium exists. Proposition 4 (non-existence of the sell-out equilibrium) Suppose that there is no buyer group, that the cost functions are strictly convex, and that the products are strict substitutes. Then no sell-out equilibrium exists. Since products are strict substitutes, what really matters for the result is the comparison between T (q) T and C(q + q ) C for q > q in (15). In order to have an equilibrium, it is necessary that the left hand side in (15) is smaller than the right hand side, and this is achieved if T (q) T < C(q + q ) C for q > q. The result in the next subsection relies on this insight. Remark: In Subsection 6.1 we consider the symmetric setting in which each seller (= A, B) offers T i (q) = F + 1 C(2q) for i = 1, 2 and find that (15) is satisfied as 2 T (q) T = 1C(2q) C is greater than C(q + q ) C for q > q. Hence, no equilibrium exists such that each seller offers the tariff T (q) = F + 1 C(2q) to each buyer Two-part tariff equilibrium In this subsection we show that a two-part tariff equilibrium exists. Precisely, the tariff seller offers to buyer i is: T i (q) = F i +α q for any q > 0, with α = C (q i +q h ), for any i = 1, 2 and = A, B. (16) This tariff is analogous to the two-part tariff we have introduced in (10) under buyer group. In order to determine the equilibrium fees, we define VAB i, qi, V i as follows: q i arg max q i VAB i = U i (qa i, qb i ) α A qa i α B qb i ; (17) ( U i (q, i 0) α q) i and V i U i ( q i, 0) α q i. (18) Thus VAB i is the payoff of buyer i (gross of the fixed fees) if she buys (qi A, qi B ); V i is the payoff of buyer i (gross of the fixed fee) if she trades only with seller, and q i is the 17

20 payoff-maximizing quantity in that case. As in the case of buyer group, in equilibrium it is necessary that VAB i F A i F B i = V A i F A i = V B i F B i, and from these equalities we obtain the equilibrium fees: F i A = V i AB V i B, F i B = V i AB V i A, for i = 1, 2. (19) Proposition 5 (equilibrium with two-part tariffs) Suppose that there is no buyer group and that the cost functions are strictly convex and the products are strict substitutes. The tariffs described by (16) and (19) constitute an equilibrium. The intuition for why the two-part tariffs constitute an equilibrium can be given by considering simple divide-and-conquer strategies. For the symmetric setting, we have proved that for seller A, a simple divide-and-conquer strategy is profitable if and only if (15) is satisfied. When T (q) = F + αq, with α = C (2q ) as in (16), we find that (15) is violated because T (q) T is smaller (i.e., grows less quickly) than C(q + q ) C for q > q. Therefore, no simple hybrid deviation is profitable. Although indirect contracting externalities suggest that more powerful deviations involving both markets exist, the proof of Proposition 5 establishes that no profitable deviation exists. 6 Comparison between buyer group and no group In this section, we show that buyer group reduces the buyers payoffs. In the first two subsections, we consider the case in which the cost functions are strictly convex and the products are strict substitutes, and show that divide-and-conquer intensifies competition between sellers, to the benefit of buyers. In the last subsection, we consider a setting without indirect contracting externalities in which we relax the assumption of substitute goods. We show a mechanism, different from divide-and-conquer, which makes buyers lose from building a group. 6.1 Symmetric buyers We first consider the setting of symmetric buyers. Starting from tariffs TA G, T B G which are an equilibrium under buyer group, we consider the following tariffs under no group: T 1 A(q) = T 2 A(q) = 1 2 T G A (2q), T 1 B(q) = T 2 B(q) = 1 2 T G B (2q). (20) These tariffs help us to understand how competition changes when moving from buyer group to no buyer group. Precisely, if sellers offer the tariffs in (20) under no buyer group, then we can prove that buyers purchases are the same as under buyer group, and each seller and the buyers have the same payoff as under buyer group. Moreover, the payoff 18

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations Leslie M. Marx Duke University Greg Shaffer University of Rochester December 2006 Abstract When two sellers negotiate terms of trade with a common buyer, the

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

Entry Barriers. Özlem Bedre-Defolie. July 6, European School of Management and Technology

Entry Barriers. Özlem Bedre-Defolie. July 6, European School of Management and Technology Entry Barriers Özlem Bedre-Defolie European School of Management and Technology July 6, 2018 Bedre-Defolie (ESMT) Entry Barriers July 6, 2018 1 / 36 Exclusive Customer Contacts (No Downstream Competition)

More information

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion?

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion? Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion? Patrick Rey and Michael D. Whinston 1 Introduction In a recent paper, Marx and Shaffer (2007) study a model of vertical contracting between a manufacturer and two

More information

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2013 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercise - Quantity competition 1 Take firm 1 s perspective Total revenue is R(q 1 = (4 q 1 q q 1 and, hence, marginal revenue is MR 1 (q 1 = 4 q 1 q Marginal cost is MC

More information

International Journal of Industrial Organization

International Journal of Industrial Organization International Journal of Industrial Organization 8 (010) 451 463 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect International Journal of Industrial Organization journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ijio

More information

Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities

Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities Alberto Galasso September 2, 2007 Abstract Building on Genicot and Ray (2006) we develop a model of non-cooperative bargaining that combines

More information

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE Problem Set 1 These questions will go over basic game-theoretic concepts and some applications. homework is due during class on week 4. This [1] In this problem (see Fudenberg-Tirole

More information

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades Loss-leader pricing and upgrades Younghwan In and Julian Wright This version: August 2013 Abstract A new theory of loss-leader pricing is provided in which firms advertise low below cost) prices for certain

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

LI Reunión Anual. Noviembre de Managing Strategic Buyers: Should a Seller Ban Resale? Beccuti, Juan Coleff, Joaquin

LI Reunión Anual. Noviembre de Managing Strategic Buyers: Should a Seller Ban Resale? Beccuti, Juan Coleff, Joaquin ANALES ASOCIACION ARGENTINA DE ECONOMIA POLITICA LI Reunión Anual Noviembre de 016 ISSN 185-00 ISBN 978-987-8590-4-6 Managing Strategic Buyers: Should a Seller Ban Resale? Beccuti, Juan Coleff, Joaquin

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2015

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2015 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2015 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1 Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose,

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights? Leonardo Felli 15 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5 Property Rights Theory The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights? For an answer we need to distinguish

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to GAME THEORY PROBLEM SET 1 WINTER 2018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to andrey.zhukov@aalto.fi. Materials from Osborne and Rubinstein

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH http://www.kier.kyoto-u.ac.jp/index.html Discussion Paper No. 657 The Buy Price in Auctions with Discrete Type Distributions Yusuke Inami

More information

Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game

Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game Parkash Chander * and Myrna Wooders May 1, 2011 Abstract We propose a new concept of core for games in extensive form and label it the γ-core of an extensive

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

Can Naked Exclusion Be Procompetitive?

Can Naked Exclusion Be Procompetitive? Can Naked Exclusion Be Procompetitive? Linda Gratz and Markus Reisinger This version: August 2011 Abstract Antitrust scholars have argued that exclusive contracting has anticompetitive, or at best neutral

More information

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems Microeconomics II CIDE, MsC Economics List of Problems 1. There are three people, Amy (A), Bart (B) and Chris (C): A and B have hats. These three people are arranged in a room so that B can see everything

More information

Secret Contracting and Interlocking Relationships. Bergen Competition Policy Conference - April 24, 2015

Secret Contracting and Interlocking Relationships. Bergen Competition Policy Conference - April 24, 2015 Secret Contracting and Interlocking Relationships Patrick Rey (TSE) Thibaud Vergé (ENSAE and BECCLE) Bergen Competition Policy Conference - April 24, 2015 Vertical restraints : theory vs practice Literature

More information

Games Played in a Contracting Environment

Games Played in a Contracting Environment Games Played in a Contracting Environment V. Bhaskar Department of Economics University of Essex Wivenhoe Park Colchester CO4 3SQ Email: vbhas@essex.ac.uk March 2005 Abstract We analyze situations where

More information

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I Homework 1, due in recitation on 10/18/2018. 1. Consider the following strategic game: player 1/player 2 L R U 1,1 0,0 D 0,0 3,2 Any NE can be

More information

The Strength of the Waterbed Effect Depends on Tariff Type

The Strength of the Waterbed Effect Depends on Tariff Type The Strength of the Waterbed Effect Depends on Tariff Type Steffen Hoernig 14 May 2014 Abstract We show that the waterbed effect, ie the pass-through of a change in one price of a firm to its other prices,

More information

Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets

Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets The E. Glen Weyl Department of Economics Princeton University Fundação Getulio Vargas August 3, 2007 Definition of a two-sided market 1 Two groups of consumers 2 Value from connecting (proportional to

More information

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly Prerequisites Almost essential Monopoly Useful, but optional Game Theory: Strategy and Equilibrium DUOPOLY MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell 1 Overview Duopoly Background How the basic

More information

On two-part tariff competition in a homogeneous product duopoly

On two-part tariff competition in a homogeneous product duopoly On two-part tariff competition in a homogeneous product duopoly Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas May 01 Abstract We explore the nature of two-part tariff competition between duopolists providing a homogeneous

More information

A Theory of Favoritism

A Theory of Favoritism A Theory of Favoritism Zhijun Chen University of Auckland 2013-12 Zhijun Chen University of Auckland () 2013-12 1 / 33 Favoritism in Organizations Widespread favoritism and its harmful impacts are well-known

More information

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership Attila Tasnádi Department of Mathematics, Budapest University of Economic Sciences and Public Administration, H-1093 Budapest, Fővám tér 8, Hungary

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. (a) The monopolist solves: The first order condition is max Π(Q) = Q(a bq) cq. Q a Q c = 0, or equivalently, Q = a c, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions 1. (45 points) Consider the following normal form game played by Bruce and Sheila: L Sheila R T 1, 0 3, 3 Bruce M 1, x 0, 0 B 0, 0 4, 1 (a) Suppose

More information

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations? Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 7, 0. Consider an individual faced with two job choices: she can either accept a position with a fixed annual salary of x > 0 which requires L x units of labor

More information

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations 19.1: Introduction This chapter is interesting and important. It also helps to answer a question you may well have been asking ever since we studied quasi-linear

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Location, Productivity, and Trade

Location, Productivity, and Trade May 10, 2010 Motivation Outline Motivation - Trade and Location Major issue in trade: How does trade liberalization affect competition? Competition has more than one dimension price competition similarity

More information

Platform Price Parity Clauses and Direct Sales

Platform Price Parity Clauses and Direct Sales Platform Price Parity Clauses and Direct Sales Bjørn Olav Johansen (University of Bergen and BECCLE) Thibaud Vergé (ENSAE and Norwegian School of Economics / BECCLE) 9 th Postal Economics Conference, TSE

More information

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Corporate Control Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Managerial Discipline and Takeovers Managers often don t maximize the value of the firm; either because they are not capable

More information

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy Yangbo Song Economics Department, UCLA June 30, 2014 Yangbo Song UCLA June 30, 2014 1 / 31 Game theory Game theory is a methodology used to analyze strategic situations in

More information

Vertical limit pricing

Vertical limit pricing Vertical limit pricing Aggey Semenov and Julian Wright Abstract A new theory of limit pricing is provided which works through the vertical contract signed between an incumbent manufacturer and a retailer.

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017 Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 017 1. Sheila moves first and chooses either H or L. Bruce receives a signal, h or l, about Sheila s behavior. The distribution

More information

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by Ioannis Pinopoulos 1 May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract A well-known result in oligopoly theory regarding one-tier industries is that the

More information

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information November 25, 2013 1 Single-Agent Problems 1. Nonlinear Pricing with Two Types Suppose a seller of wine faces two types of customers, θ 1 and θ 2, where θ 2 >

More information

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Juyan Zhang and Yi Zhang December 20, 2010 Abstract We investigate hold-up with simultaneous and sequential investment. We show that if the encouragement

More information

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE Answers to Problem Set [] In part (i), proceed as follows. Suppose that we are doing 2 s best response to. Let p be probability that player plays U. Now if player 2 chooses

More information

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally. AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July 2017 time : 1 hour Do all 4 questions. All count equally. Q1. Monopoly is inefficient because the monopoly s owner makes high profits, and the monopoly s

More information

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers WP-2013-015 Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers Amit Kumar Maurya and Shubhro Sarkar Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai August 2013 http://www.igidr.ac.in/pdf/publication/wp-2013-015.pdf

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017 Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 07. (40 points) Consider a Cournot duopoly. The market price is given by q q, where q and q are the quantities of output produced

More information

Allocating and Funding Universal Service Obligations in a Competitive Network Market

Allocating and Funding Universal Service Obligations in a Competitive Network Market Allocating and Funding Universal Service Obligations in a Competitive Network Market Philippe Choné, Laurent Flochel, Anne Perrot October 1999 Abstract We examine, in a network market open to competition,

More information

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis EC 202 Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I George Symeonidis Oligopoly When only a small number of firms compete in the same market, each firm has some market power. Moreover, their interactions cannot be ignored.

More information

Bilateral monopoly in telecommunications: bargaining over fixed-to-mobile termination rates

Bilateral monopoly in telecommunications: bargaining over fixed-to-mobile termination rates Bilateral monopoly in telecommunications: bargaining over fixed-to-mobile termination rates Tommaso Majer Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona October 2009 Abstract It is broadly accepted that mobile network

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 22 COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY Correlated Strategies and Correlated

More information

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Journal of Economics and Finance Volume 24 Number 1 Spring 2000 Pages 56-63 Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Veronika Grimm and Ulrich Schmidt* Abstract This paper considers the classical independent

More information

Online Appendix for: Discounts as a Barrier to Entry

Online Appendix for: Discounts as a Barrier to Entry Online Appendix for: Discounts as a arrier to Entry Enrique Ide, Juan-Pablo Montero and Nicolás Figueroa November 9, 2015 Abstract There are seven sections in this online Appendix (all references are in

More information

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts 6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts Asu Ozdaglar MIT February 9, 2010 1 Introduction Outline Review Examples of Pure Strategy Nash Equilibria

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Leonardo Felli 7 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Contract Theory has become only recently a subfield of Economics. As the name suggest the main object of the analysis is a contract. Therefore

More information

Payment card interchange fees and price discrimination

Payment card interchange fees and price discrimination Payment card interchange fees and price discrimination Rong Ding Julian Wright April 8, 2016 Abstract We consider the implications of platform price discrimination in the context of card platforms. Despite

More information

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 and 2 in the first Blue Book and Problems 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

Competitive Outcomes, Endogenous Firm Formation and the Aspiration Core

Competitive Outcomes, Endogenous Firm Formation and the Aspiration Core Competitive Outcomes, Endogenous Firm Formation and the Aspiration Core Camelia Bejan and Juan Camilo Gómez September 2011 Abstract The paper shows that the aspiration core of any TU-game coincides with

More information

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich 1 Motivation How does an industry with successive oligopolies work? How do upstream

More information

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals. Chapter 3 Oligopoly Oligopoly is an industry where there are relatively few sellers. The product may be standardized (steel) or differentiated (automobiles). The firms have a high degree of interdependence.

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

HW Consider the following game:

HW Consider the following game: HW 1 1. Consider the following game: 2. HW 2 Suppose a parent and child play the following game, first analyzed by Becker (1974). First child takes the action, A 0, that produces income for the child,

More information

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1 Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory Practice Exam 2 with Solutions Chapter 10, Question 1 Which of the following is not a condition for perfect competition? Firms a. take prices as given b. sell a standardized

More information

Outsourcing under Incomplete Information

Outsourcing under Incomplete Information Discussion Paper ERU/201 0 August, 201 Outsourcing under Incomplete Information Tarun Kabiraj a, *, Uday Bhanu Sinha b a Economic Research Unit, Indian Statistical Institute, 20 B. T. Road, Kolkata 700108

More information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information - preliminary and incomplete, please do not cite - Working Paper R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information Andreas Frick Heidrun C. Hoppe-Wewetzer Georgios Katsenos June 28, 2016 Abstract

More information

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec pp. ec1 ec23

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec pp. ec1 ec23 MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi 101287/mnsc10800894ec pp ec1 ec23 e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM informs 2008 INFORMS Electronic Companion Strategic Inventories in Vertical Contracts by Krishnan

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs

Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs Daniel Müller and Patrick W. Schmitz 207 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/90784/ MPRA

More information

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Davit Khantadze September 30, 017 Abstract We are interested in optimal signals for the sender when the decision maker (receiver) has to make two separate decisions.

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 9 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3 Consider now a different cause for the failure of the Coase Theorem: the presence of transaction costs. Of course for this to be an interesting

More information

Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot

Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot Sang-Ho Lee* 1, Dmitriy Li, and Chul-Hi Park Department of Economics, Chonnam National University Abstract We examine the

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus Summer 2009 examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2008/2009 syllabus Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours. This paper contains nine questions in three sections. Answer question one

More information

Emission Permits Trading Across Imperfectly Competitive Product Markets

Emission Permits Trading Across Imperfectly Competitive Product Markets Emission Permits Trading Across Imperfectly Competitive Product Markets Guy MEUNIER CIRED-Larsen ceco January 20, 2009 Abstract The present paper analyses the efficiency of emission permits trading among

More information

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Static Games and Cournot. Competition Static Games and Cournot Competition Lecture 3: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Introduction In the majority of markets firms interact with few competitors oligopoly market Each firm has to consider

More information

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours YORK UNIVERSITY Faculty of Graduate Studies Final Examination December 14, 2010 Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics S. Bucovetsky time=2.5 hours Do any 6 of the following 10 questions. All count

More information

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment University of Konstanz Department of Economics Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment Florian Baumann and Tim Friehe Working Paper Series 2011-08 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/workingpaperseries

More information

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Those taking the FINAL have THREE hours Part A (Glaeser): 55

More information

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1 M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term.. Private Provision of Public Good. Consider the following public good game:

More information

2009 Far East and South Asia Meeting of the Econometrics Society (FESAMES 2009), Tokyo, Japan, 3-5 August 2009.

2009 Far East and South Asia Meeting of the Econometrics Society (FESAMES 2009), Tokyo, Japan, 3-5 August 2009. Title Commission sharing among agents Author(s) Xu, Z Citation 2009 Far East and South Asia Meeting of the Econometrics Society (FESAMES 2009), Tokyo, Japan, 3-5 August 2009. Issued Date 2009 URL http://hdl.handle.net/10722/130273

More information

Challenge to Hotelling s Principle of Minimum

Challenge to Hotelling s Principle of Minimum Challenge to Hotelling s Principle of Minimum Differentiation Two conclusions 1. There is no equilibrium when sellers are too close i.e., Hotelling is wrong 2. Under a slightly modified version, get maximum

More information

Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons

Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons Andrea Attar Thomas Mariotti François Salanié October 2007 Abstract In order to check the impact of the exclusivity regime on equilibrium allocations,

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Juyan Zhang and Yi Zhang February 20, 2011 Abstract We investigate hold-up in the case of both simultaneous and sequential investment. We show that if

More information

Competition for goods in buyer-seller networks

Competition for goods in buyer-seller networks Rev. Econ. Design 5, 301 331 (2000) c Springer-Verlag 2000 Competition for goods in buyer-seller networks Rachel E. Kranton 1, Deborah F. Minehart 2 1 Department of Economics, University of Maryland, College

More information

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015 Best-Reply Sets Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis This version: May 2015 Introduction The best-reply correspondence of a game the mapping from beliefs over one s opponents actions to

More information

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition Kai Hao Yang /2/207 In this lecture, we will apply the concepts in game theory to study oligopoly. In short, unlike

More information

E ciency Gains and Structural Remedies in Merger Control (Journal of Industrial Economics, December 2010)

E ciency Gains and Structural Remedies in Merger Control (Journal of Industrial Economics, December 2010) E ciency Gains and Structural Remedies in Merger Control (Journal of Industrial Economics, December 2010) Helder Vasconcelos Universidade do Porto and CEPR Bergen Center for Competition Law and Economics

More information

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY ECONS 44 STRATEGY AND GAE THEORY IDTER EXA # ANSWER KEY Exercise #1. Hawk-Dove game. Consider the following payoff matrix representing the Hawk-Dove game. Intuitively, Players 1 and compete for a resource,

More information

Multiproduct Pricing Made Simple

Multiproduct Pricing Made Simple Multiproduct Pricing Made Simple Mark Armstrong John Vickers Oxford University September 2016 Armstrong & Vickers () Multiproduct Pricing September 2016 1 / 21 Overview Multiproduct pricing important for:

More information

Game Theory Fall 2003

Game Theory Fall 2003 Game Theory Fall 2003 Problem Set 5 [1] Consider an infinitely repeated game with a finite number of actions for each player and a common discount factor δ. Prove that if δ is close enough to zero then

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012 The Revenue Equivalence Theorem Note: This is a only a draft

More information

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization 12 December 2006. 0.1 (p. 26), 0.2 (p. 41), 1.2 (p. 67) and 1.3 (p.68) 0.1** (p. 26) In the text, it is assumed

More information

Chapter 1: Monopoly II

Chapter 1: Monopoly II Notes on Chapter : Microeconomic Theory IV 3º - LE-: 008-009 Iñaki Aguirre Departamento de Fundamentos del Análisis Económico I Universidad del País Vasco .5. Price discrimination..6. First-degree price

More information

The Competition Effects of Industry-wide RPM under Two-Part

The Competition Effects of Industry-wide RPM under Two-Part The Competition Effects of Industry-wide RPM under Two-Part Tariffs Duarte Brito Universidade Nova de Lisboa and CEFAGE-UE Helder Vasconcelos Faculdade de Economia, Universidade do Porto and CEF.UP July

More information

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory Practice Exam 2 with Solutions Chapter 10, Question 1 Which of the following is not a condition for perfect competition? Firms a. take prices as given b. sell a standardized

More information