A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition"

Transcription

1 A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition Markus Reisinger and Monika Schnitzer November 2007 Abstract This paper develops a model of successive oligopolies with endogenous market entry. We allow for varying degrees of product differentiation and entry cost to capture how the competitive environment in upstream and downstream markets interact. In particular, we show that the overall market outcome is dominated by the competitive conditions of the downstream market and we characterize conditions under which deregulation is more effective in the downstream market than in the upstream market and vice versa. Furthermore, we analyze how different forms of vertical restraints affect the market structure and provide conditions under which they are welfare reducing. JEL classification: L13, D43, L40, L50 Keywords: Deregulation, Free Entry, Price Competition, Product Differentiation, Successive Oligopolies, Two-Part Tariffs, Vertical Restraints We like to thank Gergely Csorba, Simon Lörtscher, Salvatore Piccolo, Rey Rees, Patrick Rey and participants at the Universities of Mannheim, Melbourne, Munich and Toulouse, at the Swiss IO Day 2007 (Bern), ESEM 2007 (Budapest), and E.A.R.I.E (Valencia) for very helpful comments and suggestions. Both authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft through SFB/TR 15. During part of this project Reisinger visited the IDEI in Toulouse, which he thanks for the hospitality. Department of Economics, University of Munich, Kaulbachstr. 45, Munich, Germany, markus.reisinger@lrz.uni-muenchen.de. Department of Economics, University of Munich, Akademiestr. 1/III, Munich, Germany, schnitzer@lrz.uni-muenchen.de

2 1 Introduction The structure of input and output markets varies a lot between different industries. In some industries, input suppliers operate in a very competitive environment while output producers do not, 1 in others it is the other way round. 2 others have oligopolistic structures with a small number of firms in both the input and output market. 3 Still Yet, there is little knowledge about how these competitive structures evolve and, in particular, how the competitive environment in output markets affects competition in the input market and vice versa. Understanding this interaction between upstream and downstream markets is important for a variety of policy issues. Consider for example a policy maker who is concerned about the overall market outcome and who needs to decide which market to deregulate, input or output market, in order to best promote competition. 4 The answer seems straightforward if the competitive structures upstream and downstream differ a lot, but it is much less obvious if both input and output markets are oligopolistically structured. While there are a number of studies about the effects of deregulation in the product market, none of these studies addresses explicitly the question at which market level deregulation would be most effective. Similarly, there is concern about the welfare implications of different forms of vertical restraints. Yet, the existing literature studies this issue focussing on a given market structure neglecting potential feedback effects these practices may 1 Examples are the automobile and aviation industry where for almost all components a large number of suppliers exist that are confronted with only a small number of final good producers. 2 An example is the market for micro processors of personal computers. Almost all micro processors that are used in personal computers are produced by only two firms, Intel Corporation and Advanced Micro Devices, Inc. (AMD), while there is a much larger number of producers of personal computers. Another example is the market for refined platinum. Due to the highly concentrated location of platinum in South Africa (more that 79% of world s supply), the two biggest suppliers of refined platinum have together a world market share of more than 60% (see Competition Tribunal, Republic of South Africa, Case Nr: 55/LM/Aug02). On the demand side, over 40% of refined platinum are sold to jewelry manufacturers that are widespread in every country. 3 Examples here are the electricity or gas markets. After deregulation of these markets consumers in many US and European regions can choose between a few electricity or gas suppliers. These suppliers in turn buy from the big electricity producing companies. 4 Recent empirical studies find that governments in all OECD countries pursue a policy of deregulation during the last decade (see e.g. Nicoletti and Scarpetta (2003)). Also, the World Bank report "Doing Business 2007" (available at: documents that from 2003 till 2007, in 175 countries 238 market reforms were taken under way out of which 213 facilitate doing business. 1

3 have on market entry. Policy recommendations that do not take these feedback effects into account may be misguided. Thus, for these and other related questions a model is required that looks at the larger picture of both upstream and downstream markets and that allows to study how different competitive environments, pricing strategies and policy choices affect the overall market outcome when the market structures upstream and downstream evolve endogenously. In this paper we provide such a model of successive oligopolies with endogenous market entry. We allow for varying degrees of product differentiation as well as different entry cost, reflecting different competitive environments in both markets. Thus, we can use the model to explore the endogenous two-tier market structure as a function of both product differentiation and entry cost in both markets for different forms of vertical contracts. An advantage of our model is that despite being more general in this respect than existing models, it can still be solved analytically rather than having to resort to numerical solutions. The idea of our theoretical approach is to model each market like a Salop circle with free entry, where transportation cost reflect different degrees of product differentiation in each market. Such a model is straightforward to analyze if market demand can be assumed to be continuous. For downstream firms selling to a large number of consumers this assumption is innocuous. Yet, the analysis is less straightforward for the upstream market, where demand is generated only by a finite number of input buyers, as this may give rise to potential discontinuities in the demand function. The theoretical innovation of our model is to find a specification that makes demand in the upstream market continuous. We achieve this goal by introducing uncertainty about the location of buyers. An upstream firm sells to every downstream firm with positive probability, and this probability is continuously decreasing in its price. Although solving the model analytically is complicated, the solutions are remarkably simple and intuitive. With this model we are able to investigate how the interaction between upstream and downstream market affects the overall two tier market structure. Prima facie, this interaction could give rise to multiple equilibria, because the free entry condition can be fulfilled with both a large and a small number of firms in both 2

4 markets. Interestingly, we find that there exists a unique equilibrium under any form of vertical contracting, i.e. the overall two-tier market structure is uniquely determined by the degree of product differentiation, the entry costs and the respective pricing strategies. This allows us to give clear comparative static predictions, and, most importantly, it enables us to provide welfare comparisons between linear pricing and vertical restraints. We start by exploring the comparative statics of this endogenous two-tier market structure under linear pricing 5 and find that upstream and downstream markets interact asymmetrically. For example, a higher number of upstream firms (caused by a reduction of market entry cost) leads to a higher number of downstream firms because costs of buying inputs decrease while the reverse does not hold true. We also find that one tends to misjudge the impact of an exogenous parameter change on the overall market structure when ignoring the interaction between the two markets, the more so when competition is low in the upstream market and high in the downstream market. We show further that the overall market prices are dominated by the competitive conditions in the downstream market. The intuition is that the degree of downstream competition confines the upstream prices to a larger extent than the other way round. If downstream competition is fierce, an upstream firm that charges a higher price than its rivals can attract only little demand since the competitive disadvantage of a downstream firm is severe if it buys the input at a high price. On the other hand, fierce competition upstream does not prevent high final good prices if the degree of competition downstream is low. Finally, we use the model to study two policy issues, namely the welfare implications of different vertical restraints and the relative effectiveness of different deregulations strategies. For this purpose, we compare the market outcome under two different vertical contracts, two-part tariffs and resale price maintenance, to that under linear pricing. Our analysis shows that the welfare effects under exoge- 5 There are two reasons to analyze the case of linear pricing in more detail. First, in many vertical structures linear pricing is a prevalent praxis. For example, Smith and Thanassoulis (2007) in a study of the industry for liquid milk in the UK report that suppliers only charge a per-unit price without a fixed element. Second, linear pricing is a useful benchmark against which to compare the welfare consequences of more elaborate vertical contracts. 3

5 nously given market structures can differ substantially from those under endogenously evolving ones. In particular, we find that in our model with endogenous market entry welfare under linear pricing can be higher than under two-part tariffs, even though, as is commonly known (see e.g. Villas-Boas (2007)), the latter avoids double marginalization. This is due to the fact that entry in the downstream market is larger under linear pricing and so downstream competition is fiercer. Moreover, we show that welfare under two-part tariffs is always larger than under resale price maintenance although the latter induces more market entry. Here, the effect of avoiding double marginalization dominates. For our second policy issue, the relative effectiveness of different deregulation strategies, we find clear cut policy results, even if both upstream and downstream markets have rather similar competitive conditions. Our analysis reveals that if the overall number of firms is small, deregulation downstream is more effective. This is due to the fact that reducing entry barriers downstream has a positive effect on the number of upstream firms if the number of downstream firms is small, thereby reinforcing the decrease in final good prices via reduced input prices. If, on the other hand, the overall number of firms is large, upstream deregulation is preferable because upstream deregulation decreases the input price and this decrease carries over more strongly to final good prices if downstream competition is fiercer, i.e. if the number of firms is larger. The existing literature that deals with vertical market structures is mostly interested in the question under which conditions different forms of vertical relations, like vertical integration or different forms of vertical contracts, arise and whether they are welfare enhancing or reducing. To this end a realistic description of successive markets is needed. Yet, in the vast majority of this literature the basic markets are modelled in a simplified way, with an exogenous number of firms in each market, often only at most two firms upstream and downstream, and homogeneous products in at least one market. For example, Greenhut and Ohta (1979), Salinger (1988), Gaudet and van Long (1996), or Abiru, Nahata, Raychaudhuri, and Waterson (1998) analyze markets with homogeneous goods and competition à la Cournot to assess the implications of vertical mergers. Yet, due to 4

6 the Cournot assumption they are not able to provide welfare implications about more ornate contracts than linear pricing schemes. 6 Ordover, Saloner and Salop (1990) and Chen (2001) allow for price competition in a framework with vertical integration. To keep the model simple, they firstly assume homogeneous products in the upstream market resulting in perfect Bertrand competition and secondly restrict the number of downstream firms to two. They show that in this framework it is possible to generate asymmetric equilibria in which one firm is integrated and the other one not. There are several papers that deal with vertical contracting issues and their welfare implications, e.g. Hart and Tirole (1990), McAfee and Schwartz (1992) or White (2007). These studies mainly assume a monopolistic upstream supplier and analyze if it is able to extract monopoly rents on the downstream market where a given number of firms compete. In contrast to these papers, our focus is on endogenously determining the market structure in a vertical relation in order to show how the possibility of different forms of contracts affects the overall structure and to give policy implications whether these forms of contracts should be banned. A recent paper that analyzes a similar market structure as ours, with oligopolistic competition upstream and downstream, is Hendricks and McAfee (2007). They assume Cournot competition with homogeneous goods and allow for a general number of firms. Additionally, due to uncertainty about cost and demand realizations, firms in the downstream market can exert market power both upstream and downstream. In order to get explicit results, they employ a supply function approach, where upstream firms can overstate their costs and downstream firms can understate their valuations. In contrast to our paper, Hendricks and McAfee (2007) allow for oligopsonistic power of the downstream firms in the input market but, due to their assumption of homogeneous products and Cournot competition, they cannot determine how the market structure evolves endogenously under varying degrees of substitutability and differing entry costs. It is also not possible in their framework to compare the welfare implications of different forms of vertical con- 6 For a paper that is not interested in vertical integration but also assumes Cournot competition and considers different brands in the upstream market, see Belleflamme and Toulemonde (2003). 5

7 tracts. 7 To sum up, the literature about vertical market structure so far usually supposes very specific market conditions and often quantity competition with homogenous goods. There does not exist a general framework to deal with the question how vertically interrelated oligopolies work and to assess the welfare consequences of vertical restraints that can change the market structure. One of the reasons for this lack of more generality is that such models quickly become very complicated. The main contribution of this paper is to provide such a general model that can serve as a framework to address a variety of questions. In this paper we use it to compare the welfare implications of different pricing regimes. Other applications could be the analysis of supply chains or vertical integration. 8 The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next Section sets out the model. In Section 3 we solve for the subgame perfect equilibrium of the model with linear pricing. Section 4 studies the interplay of the upstream and the downstream market, providing comparative statics for the two-tier market structure and exploring the relative importance of the upstream and downstream market for prices and overall welfare. In Section 5 we study the model under two forms of vertical restraints, two-part tariffs and resale price maintenance, focussing in particular on the welfare implications of these regimes. Section 6 concludes. 2 The Model Consider an industry with two successive oligopolies, an upstream and a downstream market. In the upstream market each firm produces an intermediate good at marginal cost that is normalized to zero. The upstream firms sell the intermedi- 7 Ghosh and Morita (2007) also analyze a model with homogenous goods and Cournot competition. They study endogenous entry in the upstream sector and compare it with the socially optimal number of firms. They find that insufficient entry may arise, because part of the profit of an upstream firm is captured by the downstream firms. Eső, Nocke and White (2007) consider a different but related question. They analyze a downstream industry in which firms compete for a scarce input good. They show that if the supply of this input good is large enough, the resulting industry structure is asymmetric with one firm being larger than the others. In contrast to our paper, they do not model the upstream market explicitly but rather assume that the input is allocated efficiently from the perspective of the downstream firms. As a consequence, in their model the interrelation between the two markets is not present. 8 See the conclusion for a discussion of these issues. 6

8 ate goods to the downstream firms, the producers of the final good. Downstream firms transform the intermediate goods on a one-to-one basis into output at zero costs. 9 There is free entry in both markets but all firms that enter in the upstream market must incur a fixed set-up cost of F u > 0 while firms entering in the downstream market must incur a fixed set-up cost F d > 0. We will determine the number of firms that enter in each market and denote the number of upstream firms by m and the number of downstream firms by n. For simplicity, we treat n and m as continuous variables. This implies that in equilibrium the profit of each firm net of set-up cost is zero. An upstream firm i sells its intermediate good to the downstream firms at a price per unit that is denoted by r i, i (1,..., m). 10 Similarly, we denote a downstream firm j s final good price by p j, j (1,..., n). First we describe the downstream market. We model the downstream market in a similar way as Salop (1979). There exists a continuum of consumers of mass 1 that is uniformly distributed on a circle with unit circumference. A consumer who is located at z and purchases the good from firm j located at z j incurs total cost of p j + t d (z z j ) 2. We assume that the gross utility of consuming this good is sufficiently high, such that all consumers buy for the range of prices considered. t d (z z j ) 2 is the disutility that a consumer incurs if she does not buy her most preferred variety. This disutility is assumed to be quadratic in the distance between the consumer and the firm. 11 The n downstream firms are equidistantly distributed. So the marginal consumer between firm j and j + 1 lies at distance z m from firm j, with z m = 1 2n + n(p j+1 p j ) 2t d. 9 The normalization of zero marginal cost in the upstream and the downstream sector is without loss of generality. If we assume constant marginal costs of c u > 0 and/or c d > 0 instead, the qualitative results remain unchanged. 10 In Section 5 we extend the model and allow for more elaborate pricing schemes. 11 With this assumption, we avoid the well-known problem that the profit function of firm j becomes discontinuous if its price is low enough such that the consumer located exactly at the position of its neighboring firm j 1 or j + 1 prefers to buy from firm j rather than from firm j 1 or j + 1. All our results also hold for the case of linear transport costs under the additional assumption that t d is sufficiently high. 7

9 We now turn to the upstream market. Here again, we consider a Salop circle on which the upstream firms are located with equal distance from each other. The buyers in the upstream market are the downstream firms. We first specify the costs a downstream firm incurs when buying its intermediate goods. Then we describe the location of the downstream firms as customers in the upstream market. When buying from upstream firm i, a downstream firm j faces per unit cost of r i for the intermediate good and additionally a fixed cost that is given by t u (x j x i ) 2, where t u is transportation cost in the upstream market and (x j x i ) 2 is the shortest arc length between the location of firm j and the location of firm i in the upstream market. These fixed cost reflects how well the intermediate goods fit the particular needs of the final good producer. For instance, the characteristics of the intermediate good provided by firm i may not exactly fit the technology of firm j and so firm j must costly reposition its machine. One can also imagine that firm i is a producer from abroad, and so firm j needs some instructions to correctly handle the input that results in additional costs for firm j. In contrast to the downstream market there is only a finite amount of buyers in the upstream market instead of a continuum. This could potentially lead to discontinuities in the demand curve of an upstream firm. 12 In order to deal with this problem, we suppose that at the time when upstream firm i decides about its price for the intermediate good, it does not know the locations of the downstream firms in the upstream market. Instead, it expects that each location of a downstream firm along the upstream circle is equally likely, i.e. it is uniformly distributed over the upstream circle. With this specification demand functions are continuous. We also assume that when choosing its input supplier each downstream firm knows its own location in the upstream market but does not observe the location of other downstream firms. Instead, like an upstream firm, it expects the location of every other downstream firm to be uniformly distributed on the upstream circle. An implication of this assumption is that the location of a downstream firm on the upstream market is independent from its location in the downstream market. This reflects the idea that different locations of downstream firms in the upstream 12 For an in-depth discussion of that problem, see e.g. Gabszewicz and Thisse (1986). 8

10 market stem from different technologies while a difference in the locations in the downstream market emerges due to production of different varieties or represents a geographic distance. 13 As a consequence of this assumption, a downstream firm cannot observe the input suppliers from which its rival downstream firms are buying and so it does not observe their input prices. Thus, after having observed the upstream price vector r downstream firm j forms expectations about the profit it earns in the product market, E[Π j (r)], dependent on the input supplier it chooses. As a consequence, firm j buys from upstream firm i if 14 E[Π i j(r i, r i )] t u (x j x i ) 2 E[Π k j (r k, r k )] t u (x j x k ) 2 k i. It follows that the probability that firm j buys its intermediate good from firm i is given by 15 ( 1 qi = m + m(2e[πi j] E[Π i 1 j ] E[Π i+1 ) j ]). (1) 2t u To make the problem interesting, we finally assume that the fixed set-up costs are low enough such that in both sectors at least two firms enter. It turns out that this is fulfilled if 16 F d < 1 8 ( td t ) u 6 and F u < t u 3(t u + 12F d ) 3 48(48F d + t u ) 2. (2) We consider the following three stage game. In the first stage a large number of firms can enter either in the upstream or in the downstream market at the respective entry costs F u or F d. After entry, both upstream and downstream firms are symmetrically distributed in their respective markets. The location of the downstream firms as customers in the upstream market is uncertain and each down- 13 For example, in the market for batteries Duracell and Valance Technologies are close competitors. Yet, Valance Technologies is doing R & D to improve the performance of its batteries and uses a completely different technology than Duracell which does not engage in R & D. Therefore, the two firms are not closely located to each other in the input market. 14 Here and in the following r i denotes the prices of all upstream firms but firm i, {r 1,..., r i 1, r i+1,..., r m }. 15 For the sake of notation we abbreviate E[Π i j (p j, r i, r i )] by E[Π i j ]. 16 Footnote 14 explains how these conditions are derived. 9

11 stream firm can be distributed over the whole circle with equal probability. In the second stage, upstream firms set their prices r i. Afterwards downstream firms learn their position in the upstream market and choose their preferred supplier of the intermediate good but they do not learn the positions of all rival downstream firms. In stage three, downstream firms set prices in the downstream market. 3 Equilibrium to the Model In this section we describe the solution of the three stage game. We solve the game by backward induction. We determine the equilibrium upstream and downstream prices and the number of firms that enter in both markets. A rigorous proof of the results can be found in Appendix A. Downstream Market In the third stage each downstream firm decides about its final good price knowing the number of its competitors and the upstream price vector r. When setting its price p j, firm j does not observe from which upstream firms its two neighboring downstream firms buy the intermediate good, and so it does not observe their input prices. Since input prices influence final good prices, downstream firms that buy from different upstream firms might set different final good prices. However, in equilibrium firm j knows the expected input price of its rival. Anticipating that in equilibrium all competitors with the same input price will charge the same output price, it also knows the expected output price. 17 As a consequence, the expected profit of firm j (net of fixed costs) when buying its input from upstream firm i can be written as ( 1 E[Π i j(p j, r i, p j 1, p j+1 )] = (p j r i ) n + n(e[p ) j 1] + E[p j+1 ] 2p j ). 2t d This maximization problem is identical for all downstream firms with the exception that they potentially buy their intermediate goods at different prices. Thus, there can be at most m different downstream prices. Since its expectation about 17 For models with a similar structure, see Raith (2003), Aghion and Schankerman (2004), or Syverson (2004). 10

12 the upstream location of its two neighbors is the same, firm j s expectation about E[p j 1 ] and E[p j+1 ] is the same and is given by m q k p k, where p k is the price that a downstream firm charges when buying the input from upstream firm k. 18 expected profit of firm j when facing an input price of r i can then be written as k=1 ( m ) ( n q 1 k p k p j ) E[Π i j(p j, r i, p j )] = (p j r i ) n + k=1. t d Differentiating the last equation with respect to p j and setting the results equal to zero gives a system of m equations because there can be potentially m different input prices. Solving this system for p j gives The p j = 1 2( ri + m k=1 q k r k + 2t d n 2 ), i {1,...m}. Plugging these prices back into the respective profit functions gives the expected profit of all downstream firms dependent on r i and q i, i {1,..., m}. Since the probabilities are functions of the downstream profits, we can solve for these probabilities via plugging the profits into (1). The general formula for q i is given by (19) in Appendix A for the case of m = 2 and by (18) for the case m 3. Inserting this formula back into the profit function, we can derive the quantity that downstream firm j buys from upstream firm i, denoted by y i (r i, r i ), and the price that downstream firm j charges, p j (r i, r i ). These expressions are given by equations (23) and (21) in Appendix A for the case m = 2 and (22) and (20) for the case m 3. Having solved the third stage of the game, we now proceed to the second stage, the upstream market. Upstream market Since production costs are equal to zero, the profit of an upstream firm i can be written as the probability that it sells to exactly one downstream firm multiplied with the revenue from selling, r i y i (r i, r i ), plus the probability that it sells to exactly two downstream firms multiplied with two times the revenue and so forth. 18 Recall that q k is the probability that a downstream firm buys from upstream firm k. 11

13 This can be written as 19 (( ) ( ) n n E[P i (r i, r i )] = r i y i q i (1 q i ) n qi 2 (1 q i ) n 2 + (3) 1 2 ( ) ) n + + (n 1) qi n 1 (1 q i ) + nqi n. n 1 The intuition behind this equation is probably easiest to grasp when considering the case n = 2. In this case, (1 q i ) 2 is the probability that no downstream firm buys from upstream firm i. The probability that exactly one firm buys is given by 2q i (1 q i ) and the probability that both downstream firms buy is given by q 2 i. In this last case firm i sells two times y i. Extending this line of reasoning to the case of n firms yields the right hand side of (3). Using a modification of the Binomial Theorem, the profit function simplifies to E[P i (r i, r i )] = r i y i nq i. (4) We can now substitute the respective expressions for y i and q i that we determined in the third stage and differentiate (4) with respect to r i and set the result equal to zero. Since the profit function is the same for all upstream firms we get that the equilibrium is symmetric. The formula for the equilibrium upstream prices is remarkably simple and is given by r = 2t u t d mn t u n 3 (m 1) + 2m 3 t d. (5) The equilibrium upstream prices can now be inserted into the formula for the downstream prices to get p = t d(2m 3 t d + t u n 3 (3m 1)) n 2 (2m 3 t d + t u n 3 (m 1)). (6) Having solved for the equilibrium prices in both stages, we can now proceed to the first stage and determine the equilibrium number of firms in both markets. Entry Decision 19 For notational simplicity we suppress the dependence of y i and q i on r i and r i. 12

14 Inserting the equilibrium prices in the profit functions yields that the expected profit of a downstream firm is given by E[Π] = t d /n 3 t u /(12m 2 ) F d and the expected profit of an upstream firm is given by E[P ] = r /m F u = (2t u t d n)/(t u n 3 (m 1) + 2m 3 t d ) F u. As a consequence, the equilibrium number of firms, n and m, simultaneously solve the two equations t d (n ) 3 t u 12(m ) 2 F d = 0 (7) and 2t u t d n t u (n ) 3 (m 1) + 2(m ) 3 t d F u = 0. (8) Given our assumptions on F d and F u above, it is always optimal for at least two firms to enter in each market. Thus, we can be sure that there is always an equilibrium in which at least two firms are active in both markets. It is more interesting to examine whether or not the equilibrium is indeed unique. For this purpose, we use the the iso-profit-lines of a downstream and an upstream firm, as determined by the zero profit conditions (7) and (8). For a downstream firm, the slope of the iso-profit line is given by n m = t u(n) 4 18t d (m) 3 > 0 (9) This means that the equilibrium number of downstream firms increases with the number of upstream firms. The intuition for this is simple. If the number of upstream firm increases, downstream firms benefit from lower input prices and expect to face a lower travel distance to their nearest upstream firm. As a consequence, more firms enter the downstream market. This is depicted by the isoprofit-line I D in Figure 1. It shows that the zero profit condition in the downstream market could be achieved by e.g. many upstream and downstream firms, but also by few upstream and downstream firms. For an upstream firm the slope of the iso-profit-line is given by m n = 2 ( (m) 3 t d (n) 3 (m 1) ). (10) n(t u (n) 3 + 6t d (m) 2 ) 13

15 Here the sign is ambiguous. Inspection of (10) reveals that the sign of the isoprofit line depends on n. If n 3 (2t d m)/(t u (m 1))m, it is negative, while it is positive if the reverse holds true. The reason for this ambiguity is that a larger number of downstream firms has two effects on the profit of an upstream firm. Since the downstream firms compete against each other, a larger number of downstream firms implies a larger number of marginal consumers in the output market. If an upstream firm i lowers its price r i, each downstream firm that buys from upstream firm i sells a higher quantity. But since there are more marginal consumers, upstream firm i receives a bigger quantity increase if more downstream firms are present. Thus, each upstream firm has a bigger incentive to lower its price and this increased competition effect lowers profits upstream. 20 On the other hand, an increase in the number of downstream firms has also a positive effect on upstream prices. With a larger number of downstream firms each upstream firm faces more potential buyers. Thus, the probability to sell to at least one downstream firm increases. But the profit that an upstream firm receives with its first buyer is larger than the one with its second buyer and so on. The reason is that an upstream firm potentially cannibalizes itself with a price reduction given it already has several buyers. This is due to the fact that with some probability these buyers are neighbors in the product market and so the demand of the upstream firm does not increase. As a consequence, upstream firms compete fiercest to get at least one buyer. If now the number of downstream firms increase, the probability to serve at least one increases and this dampens the pressure on upstream prices. Naturally, this effect is stronger if there are only two downstream firms present compared to the case with already several downstream firms. As a consequence, this second effect dominates if n is small, while the first one dominates for a large n. So m increases in n if n is small and it decreases in n if n is large. This is shown by the iso-profit-line I U -curve in Figure 1. Thus, for the upstream market we find 20 The result that upstream profits decrease in the number of downstream firms also arises in Rey and Tirole (2007). They consider a monpolistic upstream suppliers that is able to use non-linear tariffs. The monopolist faces a commitment problem that gets more severe the more downstream firms are present. Instead, our result does not rely on a commitment effect but on increased competition that carries over to the upstream market. So the results can be seen as complementary to each other. 14

16 n I D n I U m m Figure 1: Equilibrium number of firms, n and m that the same number of upstream firms can be part of an equilibrium with both a low and a high number of downstream firms. 21 This non-monotonicity of the equilibrium number of upstream firms as a function of downstream firms raises the issue of potential multiplicity of equilibria. Multiple equilibria could exist if the two functions crossed more than once. For this to happen the slope of the iso-profit-line of a downstream firm needs to be steeper than the one of an upstream firm in the region in which the latter increases, i.e. n < (2t 3 d m)/(t u (m 1))m. However, it is easy to show that this can never be the case for the relevant parameter range. Thus, the equilibrium is unique. The following Proposition summarizes the equilibrium. Proposition 1 There exists a unique symmetric subgame perfect equilibrium of the three stage game. In this equilibrium, the number of entering upstream and downstream firms, n and m, is implicitly defined by t d (n ) 3 t u 12(m ) 2 = F d 21 The restrictions on F d and F u in (2) are derived from the preceding analysis. Since n is increasing in m, the condition on F d assures that at least two downstream frims enter given that there are only two upstream firms. The condition on F u is derived by solving (7) for n, plugging this into (8) and setting m = 2. 15

17 and 2t u t d n t u (n ) 3 (m 1) + 2(m ) 3 t d = F u. Upstream firms charge a price of r = while downstream firms charge a price of 2t u t d m n t u (n ) 3 (m 1) + 2(m ) 3 t d, p = t d(2(m ) 3 t d + t u (n ) 3 (3m 1)) (n ) 2 (2(m ) 3 t d + t u (n ) 3 (m 1)). Proof: See Appendix A. 4 Interplay between Upstream and Downstream Market In this section we study in more detail the interplay between upstream and downstream market. In particular, we explore the comparative statics of the endogenous two tier market structure and compare this with the comparative statics of a single market model. Furthermore, we determine which market conditions matter more for market prices. Finally, we compare the welfare implications of deregulating upstream versus downstream markets. 4.1 Comparative Static Results for the Two Tier Market Structure In this section we analyze how a change in the set-up costs and in the degree of competition affects the overall market structure. We are particularly interested in finding out whether changes in the upstream and in the downstream market have symmetric or asymmetric effects on each other. Consider first the set-up costs. 16

18 Proposition 2 (i) The equilibrium number of upstream and downstream firms, n and m, is decreasing in F u. (ii) The equilibrium number of downstream firms, n, is decreasing in F d. There exists an F d, such that the equilibrium number of upstream firms, m, is increasing in F d if F d < F d, and decreasing in F d if F d > F d. Proof: See Appendix B. Note that a change in F k, k {u, d}, has a direct effect on the number of firms in market k and because of that an indirect effect on the number of firms in market k. The proposition shows that an increase of the set-up costs in the upstream market reduces the number of firms in both markets while the same does not necessarily hold true for an increase of the set-up costs in the downstream market. Both results are easy to understand given the insights derived for Proposition 1. A change in the set-up cost F u has a symmetric effect on the number of firms entering in both markets. If F u increases, the number of upstream firms decreases and so does the number of downstream firms because their expected travel cost rise. Graphically, an increase in the upstream set-up cost shifts the I U -curve to the left. This is depicted by the left hand side of Figure 2. If F d increases instead, the number of downstream firms decreases, but this can have either a positive or a negative impact on m, the number of upstream firms. This is due to the fact that, as shown in the last section, m does not change monotonically with n. If the number of downstream firms is low, i.e. F d > F d, m decreases as F d increases, and vice versa if the number of downstream firms is high, i.e. F d < F d. The right hand side of Figure 2 displays an increase in the downstream entry costs which results in a downward shift of the I D -curve. In this example, the intersection occurs in the increasing part of the I U curve, which means that the number of upstream firms decreases as a result of F d increasing. We now turn to the case of differing degrees of competition. Proposition 3 17

19 n n I U n n I D n I D I U n I D I U m m m m m m Figure 2: Increase in F u (left) and increase in F d (right) (i) The equilibrium number of upstream and downstream firms, n and m, are both increasing in t d. (ii) The equilibrium number of upstream firms m is increasing in t u while the equilibrium number of downstream firms n is decreasing in t u. Proof: See Appendix B. In contrast to a change in entry costs, a change in transportation costs has a direct effect only on prices and with that indirectly affects the equilibrium number of firms. Consider first an increase in t d, which means less competition in the downstream market. This results in higher prices and hence in a larger equilibrium number of downstream firms. At the same time, upstream firms increase their prices as well, as can be seen from (5). An upstream firm can charge a higher price without losing much demand because the disadvantage for a downstream firm that buys from this upstream firm is less severe if competition in the downstream market is less fierce. With higher upstream prices and higher upstream profits there is more entry in the upstream market. This direct price effect dominates any countervailing effect that the resulting increase of n could have on m. The increase in m, on the other hand, reinforces entry in the downstream market. The result is displayed graphically by the left hand side of Figure 3. 18

20 n n n n I D I D n n I D I D I U I U I U I U m m m m m m Figure 3: Increase in t d (left) and increase in t u (right) On the other hand, less competition in the upstream market leads to an increase in the number of upstream firms but to a decrease in the number of downstream firms. This is intuitive: if competition in the upstream market becomes less fierce higher profits can be reaped in the upstream market and so more firms enter. But if t u increases, transportation costs of a downstream firm increase. This effect is partly offset by the increase in upstream firms that reduces the travel distance. But the direct effect of increased transportation costs dominates and so fewer downstream firms enter the market (see the right hand side of Figure 3). This shows that the degree of competition in the downstream market affects the number of firms in both markets in the same direction while the opposite holds true for the degree of competition in the upstream market. The reason is that the level of downstream competition crosses over from the downstream market to the upstream market and enters the pricing formula of upstream firms positively. Conversely, the level of upstream competition enters the cost function of downstream firms and so reduces their profits. Put differently, the level of downstream competition affects the overall profitability of the two tier market structure and thus affects both markets in a similar way. The level of upstream competition, on the other hand, affects mostly the distribution of the overall profits between upstream and downstream markets. 19

21 4.2 Comparison with the Single Market Model Economic models very often analyze only the downstream market in which the final products are sold to consumers completely ignoring the upstream market. It is therefore of interest to find out how large the mistake is that one makes when ignoring the upstream market. This is characterized in the next proposition. Proposition 4 (i) The magnitude of (dn )/(dt d ) is always undervalued when one ignores the upstream market. (ii) The magnitude of (dn )/(df d ) can either be over- or undervalued when one ignores the upstream market. There exists an F d such that for F d > F d, it is undervalued while for F d < F d it is overvalued. Proof: See Appendix C. The first result shows that the effects of a changing degree of competition is always underestimated when one ignores the upstream market. The intuition is easy to grasp from Proposition 3. Since the degree of competition in the downstream market also affects upstream prices and profits, it changes the number of upstream firms. If downstream competition becomes fiercer, i.e. if t d is reduced, this crosses over to the upstream market in which fewer firms enter. This in turn increases the transportation costs for downstream firms and reinforces the effect of lower entry. Our second result shows that the effect of varying downstream set-up costs can be over- or underestimated when ignoring the downstream market. It is underestimated if we are in the increasing part of the I U -curve in Figure 1, because here the change in m goes in the same direction as the change in n and so reinforces the latter while it is overestimated if m and n change in opposite directions, as they do in the decreasing part of the I U -curve. Concerning the first result, it is interesting to explore under which conditions the underestimate is especially high. The answer is given in the following corollary. 20

22 Corollary 1 The magnitude of the underestimation of (dn )/(dt d ) is increasing in t u and decreasing in t d and m. Proof: See Appendix C. The results with respect to m and t u are intuitive. If competition in the upstream market is low, which means that either m is small or that t u is high, the upstream market matters a lot for the competitive conditions in the downstream market. Thus, the mistake that one makes when ignoring the upstream market is big. On the other hand, this mistake is also big when the degree of downstream competition is high which means a small t d. The reason is that since competition is fierce, a change in the upstream price is passed over almost one by one on the downstream price. To the contrary, if t d is high, the mistake of ignoring the upstream market is small since the equilibrium number of downstream firms is mainly determined by t d and not by the upstream market conditions. The analysis shows that there is generally a problem when one looks only at the downstream markets ignoring previous layers in the production chain. Especially, if the upstream market exhibits a low degree of competition, the feed back effects on the downstream market are large and one should take them into account. 4.3 Competitive Conditions and their Impact on Market Prices We now turn to the question which market conditions matter more for the overall market outcome, those of the upstream or those of the downstream market. For this purpose we examine how equilibrium market prices are affected by the competitive conditions in the two markets. We are interested if the conditions in the upstream or in the downstream market are more important for determining upstream and downstream prices. A first guess would probably be that a market s own condition should matter more for the respective price. We will see that this is true for the downstream market but need not be true for the upstream market. To this end, consider two different scenarios. In scenario (i) the degree of competition, captured by the transport costs, in the downstream market is lower than 21

23 in the upstream market, i.e. t d = t < t = t u, while in situation (ii) the reverse holds, t d = t > t = t u. To focus on the pure effect of the degree of competition we suppose that the equilibrium number of firms is the same in both situations, i.e. n (i) = n (ii) = n and m (i) = m (ii) = m. Implicitly, this means that set-up costs differ between the two situations in such a way that the number of firms is the same. Prima facie, it is not obvious if, for example, the downstream price in one or the other scenario is higher because a high t u results in a high input price and thus also in a high output price while a low t d puts downward pressure on the output prices. A similar logic holds for upstream prices. Yet, we get the following result. Proposition 5 Independent of the equilibrium number of firms, the downstream price is lower in scenario (i) than in scenario (ii). The upstream price is higher in scenario (i) than in scenario (ii) if and only if n 3 2 m 1 m. Proof: See Appendix B. This result shows that the degree of competition in the downstream market matters more for downstream prices than the degree of competition in the upstream market while the reverse is not necessarily true. 22 Intuitively, if t u is low and so upstream prices are close to marginal costs, consumer prices can still be well above marginal costs if the degree of downstream competition is small. In this case, downstream firms demand high margins. Conversely, if t d is low, downstream competition is fierce and this heavily influences upstream prices. A downstream firm that pays a higher input price than its neighbors, must also demand a higher final good price and gets only little demand. But this leaves an upstream firm that charges a high input price also with low demand. Thus, it has an incentive to lower its price. As a consequence, in equilibrium upstream prices are low 22 Note that 3 2/(m 1) 1 for m 3. Thus, the condition is never fulfilled for n > m 3. 22

24 as well. 4.4 Upstream vs. Downstream Deregulation We now turn to the question in which market it is more effective to deregulate in order to spur competition. The answer seems straightforward if upstream and downstream markets are very asymmetric, one being very competitive while the other one being very little competitive. And indeed, one can show in our model that in such cases it is most effective to intervene in the less competitive market. The answer is no longer obvious if both markets are similarly competitive. Previous models have analyzed the effects of deregulations but focussed only on the product market alone due to the lack of a model that is able to deal with an endogenous structure in both markets. The aim of this analysis is to explicitly differentiate between deregulation in the output and in the input market and give policy implications where intervention is more effective. A policy maker can control two variables to foster competition. She can decrease entry barriers, for example, by reducing red tape to start up new businesses or by making access to the home market easier for foreign firms. In our model, this corresponds to a decrease in firms set-up costs, F u or F d. Another possibility is to increase the degree of competition directly, e.g. by the introduction of standardization measures making it easier for consumers to compare products or by investing in infrastructure that decreases transport or communication costs. This corresponds to a decrease in t d or t u. 23 We first look at the case of a decrease in set-up costs. Since profits are zero in equilibrium, welfare and consumer surplus coincide. Let a denote a consumer s 23 t d and t u were formally introduced as preference resp. technology parameters. To think about a decrease in t d or t u as the result of deregulation, one can interpret the specification of consumer utility resp. downstream firms production function as reduced form. There, t d reflects higher product substitutability while t u reflects higher input substitutability. For a similar exercise and a discussion of this interpretation, see Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003). 23

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich 1 Motivation How does an industry with successive oligopolies work? How do upstream

More information

Markus Reisinger; Monika Schnitzer: A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition

Markus Reisinger; Monika Schnitzer: A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition Markus Reisinger; Monika Schnitzer: A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition Munich Discussion Paper No. 2008-8 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität

More information

Successive Oligopolies with Differentiated Firms and Endogenous Entry

Successive Oligopolies with Differentiated Firms and Endogenous Entry Successive Oligopolies with Differentiated Firms and Endogenous Entry Markus Reisinger and Monika Schnitzer December 2009 Abstract This paper develops a model of successive oligopolies with endogenous

More information

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by Ioannis Pinopoulos 1 May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract A well-known result in oligopoly theory regarding one-tier industries is that the

More information

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercise - Quantity competition 1 Take firm 1 s perspective Total revenue is R(q 1 = (4 q 1 q q 1 and, hence, marginal revenue is MR 1 (q 1 = 4 q 1 q Marginal cost is MC

More information

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains Maria-Augusta Miceli University of Rome Sapienza Claudia Nardone University of Rome Sapienza October 8, 06 Abstract We here want to analyze how the imperfect competition

More information

STRATEGIC VERTICAL CONTRACTING WITH ENDOGENOUS NUMBER OF DOWNSTREAM DIVISIONS

STRATEGIC VERTICAL CONTRACTING WITH ENDOGENOUS NUMBER OF DOWNSTREAM DIVISIONS STRATEGIC VERTICAL CONTRACTING WITH ENDOGENOUS NUMBER OF DOWNSTREAM DIVISIONS Kamal Saggi and Nikolaos Vettas ABSTRACT We characterize vertical contracts in oligopolistic markets where each upstream firm

More information

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry Lin, Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 7(2), December 2014, 17-31 17 Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically

More information

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization ECON/MGMT 115 Industrial Organization 1. Cournot Model, reprised 2. Bertrand Model of Oligopoly 3. Cournot & Bertrand First Hour Reviewing the Cournot Duopoloy Equilibria Cournot vs. competitive markets

More information

Countervailing power and input pricing: When is a waterbed effect likely?

Countervailing power and input pricing: When is a waterbed effect likely? DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 1441-5429 DISCUSSION PAPER 27/12 Countervailing power and input pricing: When is a waterbed effect likely? Stephen P. King 1 Abstract A downstream firm with countervailing

More information

Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration with Downstream Oligopsony and Oligopoly

Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration with Downstream Oligopsony and Oligopoly Discussion Paper No. 278 Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration with Downstream Oligopsony and Oligopoly Simon Loertscher* Markus Reisinger** * City Department of Economics, University of Melbourne,

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price

Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price Vol. 7, 2013-6 February 20, 2013 http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2013-6 Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price Henrik Vetter Abstract A digressive tax such as a variable rate

More information

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Managerial Economics November 16, 2012 Prof. Dr. Sebastian Rausch Centre for Energy Policy and Economics Department of Management, Technology and Economics ETH Zürich

More information

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly Volume 9, Issue Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo Daisuke Shimizu Faculty of Economics, Gakushuin

More information

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion?

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion? Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion? Patrick Rey and Michael D. Whinston 1 Introduction In a recent paper, Marx and Shaffer (2007) study a model of vertical contracting between a manufacturer and two

More information

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. 1 Oligopoly The key feature of the oligopoly (and to some extent, the monopolistically competitive market) market structure is that one rm

More information

Market Structure and the Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration

Market Structure and the Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration Market Structure and the Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration Simon Loertscher and Markus Reisinger October 31, 2011 Abstract We analyze the competitive effects of backward vertical integration

More information

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model Economics Letters 60 (998) 55 6 Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model X. Henry Wang* Department of Economics, University of Missouri, Columbia, MO 65, USA Received 6 February 997; accepted

More information

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Static Games and Cournot. Competition Static Games and Cournot Competition Lecture 3: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Introduction In the majority of markets firms interact with few competitors oligopoly market Each firm has to consider

More information

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis EC 202 Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I George Symeonidis Oligopoly When only a small number of firms compete in the same market, each firm has some market power. Moreover, their interactions cannot be ignored.

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Entry Barriers. Özlem Bedre-Defolie. July 6, European School of Management and Technology

Entry Barriers. Özlem Bedre-Defolie. July 6, European School of Management and Technology Entry Barriers Özlem Bedre-Defolie European School of Management and Technology July 6, 2018 Bedre-Defolie (ESMT) Entry Barriers July 6, 2018 1 / 36 Exclusive Customer Contacts (No Downstream Competition)

More information

This is Interest Rate Parity, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0).

This is Interest Rate Parity, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0). This is Interest Rate Parity, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0). This book is licensed under a Creative Commons by-nc-sa 3.0 (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/

More information

Innovation and Adoption of Electronic Business Technologies

Innovation and Adoption of Electronic Business Technologies Innovation and Adoption of Electronic Business Technologies Kai Sülzle Ifo Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich & Dresden University of Technology March 2007 Abstract This paper

More information

Secret Contracting and Interlocking Relationships. Bergen Competition Policy Conference - April 24, 2015

Secret Contracting and Interlocking Relationships. Bergen Competition Policy Conference - April 24, 2015 Secret Contracting and Interlocking Relationships Patrick Rey (TSE) Thibaud Vergé (ENSAE and BECCLE) Bergen Competition Policy Conference - April 24, 2015 Vertical restraints : theory vs practice Literature

More information

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Trading Company and Indirect Exports Trading Company and Indirect Exports Kiyoshi Matsubara June 015 Abstract This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation. In the model, manufacturing firm(s) wanting to export their products

More information

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly Working Paper Series No. 09007(Econ) China Economics and Management Academy China Institute for Advanced Study Central University of Finance and Economics Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective

More information

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit Homework #5 - Econ 57 (Due on /30) Answer Key. Consider a Cournot duopoly with linear inverse demand curve p(q) = a q, where q denotes aggregate output. Both firms have a common constant marginal cost

More information

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries Munich Discussion Paper No. 2006-30 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität

More information

On supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly

On supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive On supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly Carlos Gutiérrez-Hita and José Vicente-Pérez University of Alicante 7 January 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/83792/

More information

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions Journal of Economics and Management, 2018, Vol. 14, No. 1, 1-31 License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions Masahiko Hattori Faculty

More information

Forward Contracts and Generator Market Power: How Externalities Reduce Benefits in Equilibrium

Forward Contracts and Generator Market Power: How Externalities Reduce Benefits in Equilibrium Forward Contracts and Generator Market Power: How Externalities Reduce Benefits in Equilibrium Ian Schneider, Audun Botterud, and Mardavij Roozbehani November 9, 2017 Abstract Research has shown that forward

More information

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium 2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium Partial equilibrium tax incidence misses out on a lot of important aspects of economic activity. Among those aspects : markets are interrelated, so that prices of

More information

9 D/S of/for Labor. 9.1 Demand for Labor. Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009

9 D/S of/for Labor. 9.1 Demand for Labor. Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009 Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009 9 D/S of/for Labor 9.1 Demand for Labor Demand for labor depends on the price of labor, price of output and production function. In optimum a firm employs

More information

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly 1. Competition by Quantity? Or by Price? By what do firms compete with each other? Competition by price seems more reasonable. However, the Bertrand model (by price) does not

More information

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t)

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t) Problem Set 3. Pay-off functions are given for the following continuous games, where the players simultaneously choose strategies s and s. Find the players best-response functions and graph them. Find

More information

On the Countervailing Power of Large Retailers When Shopping Costs Matter

On the Countervailing Power of Large Retailers When Shopping Costs Matter On the Countervailing Power of Large Retailers When hopping Costs Matter téphane Caprice hiva hekhar March 2017 Abstract We consider a set-up with vertical contracting between a supplier and a retail industry

More information

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach Toyokazu Naito and Stephen Polasky* Oregon State University Address: Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics Oregon

More information

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Transport Costs and North-South Trade Transport Costs and North-South Trade Didier Laussel a and Raymond Riezman b a GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II b Department of Economics, University of Iowa Abstract We develop a simple two country

More information

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment University of Konstanz Department of Economics Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment Florian Baumann and Tim Friehe Working Paper Series 2011-08 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/workingpaperseries

More information

research paper series

research paper series research paper series Research Paper 00/9 Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market by A. Mukherjee The Centre acknowledges financial support from The

More information

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1 Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose,

More information

GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION GEABA DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT

GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION GEABA DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT Tax and Managerial Effects of Transfer Pricing on Capital and Physical Products Oliver Duerr, Thomas Rüffieux Discussion Paper No. 17-19 GERMAN ECONOMIC

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 More on strategic games and extensive games with perfect information Block 2 Jun 11, 2017 Auctions results Histogram of

More information

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS ECO410H: Practice Questions SOLUTIONS 1. (a) The unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is s = (M, M). (b) The unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is s = (R4, C3). (c) The two Nash equilibria are

More information

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market Arijit Mukherjee University of Nottingham and The Leverhulme Centre for Research in Globalisation and Economic

More information

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies? Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies? Moonsung Kang Division of International Studies Korea University Seoul, Republic of Korea mkang@korea.ac.kr Abstract

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers

Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers Vasileios Zikos University of Surrey Dusanee Kesavayuth y University of Chicago-UTCC Research Center

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 07/05 Firm heterogeneity, foreign direct investment and the hostcountry welfare: Trade costs vs. cheap labor By Arijit Mukherjee

More information

Market Structure and the Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration

Market Structure and the Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration Market Structure and the Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration Simon Loertscher and Markus Reisinger February 12, 2014 Abstract We analyze the competitive effects of backward vertical integration

More information

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games Economics Letters 6 (999) 9 6 A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games Michael R. Baye *, John Morgan a, b a Indiana University, Kelley School of Business, 309 East Tenth St., Bloomington, IN 4740-70,

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati. Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati. Module No. # 06 Illustrations of Extensive Games and Nash Equilibrium

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets Chapter 5 Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets Introduction In the majority of markets firms interact with few competitors In determining strategy each firm has to consider rival s reactions strategic

More information

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes James E. Anderson February 6, 2009 These notes derive the useful concepts of trade expenditure functions, the closely related trade indirect utility

More information

Cross-border Mergers and Hollowing-out

Cross-border Mergers and Hollowing-out Cross-border Mergers and Hollowing-out Oana Secrieru Marianne Vigneault December 19, 2008 Abstract The purpose of our paper is to examine the profitability and social desirability of both domestic and

More information

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Journal of Economic Integration 20(4), December 2005; 631-643 Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Noritsugu Nakanishi Kobe University Toru Kikuchi Kobe University

More information

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. You have 3 hours to answer the questions in the final exam. We will collect the exams at 2.30 sharp. Show your work, and good luck! Problem 1. Utility Maximization.

More information

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out Kiyoshi Matsubara August 2005 Abstract This article addresses the decision of plant location by a home firm and its impact on the home economy, especially through

More information

Environmental Tax Burden in a Vertical Relationship with Pollution-Abatement R&D

Environmental Tax Burden in a Vertical Relationship with Pollution-Abatement R&D Journal of Management and Sustainability; Vol. 4, No. 1; 2014 ISSN 1925-4725 E-ISSN 1925-4733 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Environmental Tax Burden in a Vertical Relationship with

More information

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms 17 RESEARCH ARTICE Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between irms Yordying Supasri and Makoto Tawada* Abstract This paper examines optimal trade policies

More information

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition Kai Hao Yang /2/207 In this lecture, we will apply the concepts in game theory to study oligopoly. In short, unlike

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Module No. # 03 Illustrations of Nash Equilibrium Lecture No. # 02

More information

Price discrimination in asymmetric Cournot oligopoly

Price discrimination in asymmetric Cournot oligopoly Price discrimination in asymmetric Cournot oligopoly Barna Bakó Corvinus University of Budapest e-mail: Department of Microeconomics Fővám tér 8 H-1085 Budapest, Hungary, barna.bako@uni-corvinus.hu Abstract

More information

Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach

Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach Volker Nocke 1 Nicolas Schutz 2 1 UCLA 2 University of Mannheim ASSA ES Meetings, Philadephia, 2018 Nocke and Schutz (UCLA &Mannheim) Multiproduct-Firm

More information

Outsourcing under Incomplete Information

Outsourcing under Incomplete Information Discussion Paper ERU/201 0 August, 201 Outsourcing under Incomplete Information Tarun Kabiraj a, *, Uday Bhanu Sinha b a Economic Research Unit, Indian Statistical Institute, 20 B. T. Road, Kolkata 700108

More information

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly Choi, Kangsik 22. January 2010 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/20205/

More information

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1 University of California, Merced EC 121-Money and Banking Chapter 5 Lecture otes Professor Jason Lee I. Introduction Figure 1 shows the interest rates for 3 month treasury bills. As evidenced by the figure,

More information

Endogenous choice of decision variables

Endogenous choice of decision variables Endogenous choice of decision variables Attila Tasnádi MTA-BCE Lendület Strategic Interactions Research Group, Department of Mathematics, Corvinus University of Budapest June 4, 2012 Abstract In this paper

More information

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service Fall 2009 ECO401 (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service To Join Simply send following detail to bilal.zaheem@gmail.com Full Name Master Program (MBA, MIT or

More information

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Trading Company and Indirect Exports Trading Company and Indirect Exports Kiyoshi atsubara August 0 Abstract This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation. In the model, two manufacturing firms that want to export their

More information

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades Loss-leader pricing and upgrades Younghwan In and Julian Wright This version: August 2013 Abstract A new theory of loss-leader pricing is provided in which firms advertise low below cost) prices for certain

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions Open economies review 14: 5 9, 2003 c 2003 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in The Netherlands. Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions TORU KIKUCHI kikuchi@econ.kobe-u.ac.jp Graduate School of Economics,

More information

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership Attila Tasnádi Department of Mathematics, Budapest University of Economic Sciences and Public Administration, H-1093 Budapest, Fővám tér 8, Hungary

More information

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS Determination of Income and Employment Chapter 4 We have so far talked about the national income, price level, rate of interest etc. in an ad hoc manner without investigating the forces that govern their

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals. Chapter 3 Oligopoly Oligopoly is an industry where there are relatively few sellers. The product may be standardized (steel) or differentiated (automobiles). The firms have a high degree of interdependence.

More information

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy We now proceed to study optimal fiscal policy. We should make clear at the outset what we mean by this. In general, fiscal policy entails the government choosing its spending

More information

So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed).

So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed). Chapter 6: Labor Market So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed). Key idea: In the medium run, rising GD will lead to lower unemployment rate (more

More information

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 and 2 in the first Blue Book and Problems 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A

More information

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Journal of Economics and Finance Volume 24 Number 1 Spring 2000 Pages 56-63 Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Veronika Grimm and Ulrich Schmidt* Abstract This paper considers the classical independent

More information

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions? March 3, 215 Steven A. Matthews, A Technical Primer on Auction Theory I: Independent Private Values, Northwestern University CMSEMS Discussion Paper No. 196, May, 1995. This paper is posted on the course

More information

Answers to Problem Set 4

Answers to Problem Set 4 Answers to Problem Set 4 Economics 703 Spring 016 1. a) The monopolist facing no threat of entry will pick the first cost function. To see this, calculate profits with each one. With the first cost function,

More information

Pure Strategies and Undeclared Labour in Unionized Oligopoly

Pure Strategies and Undeclared Labour in Unionized Oligopoly Pure Strategies and Undeclared Labour in Unionized Oligopoly Minas Vlassis ǂ Stefanos Mamakis ǂ Abstract In a unionized Cournot duopoly under decentralized wage bargaining regime, we analyzed undeclared

More information

Welfare in a Unionized Bertrand Duopoly. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* and Sudeshna C. Bandyopadhyay

Welfare in a Unionized Bertrand Duopoly. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* and Sudeshna C. Bandyopadhyay Welfare in a Unionized Bertrand Duopoly Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* and Sudeshna C. Bandyopadhyay Department of Economics, West Virginia University, Morgantown, WV-26506-6025. November, 2000 Abstract This paper

More information

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY ECONS 44 STRATEGY AND GAE THEORY IDTER EXA # ANSWER KEY Exercise #1. Hawk-Dove game. Consider the following payoff matrix representing the Hawk-Dove game. Intuitively, Players 1 and compete for a resource,

More information

Sequential Auctions and Auction Revenue

Sequential Auctions and Auction Revenue Sequential Auctions and Auction Revenue David J. Salant Toulouse School of Economics and Auction Technologies Luís Cabral New York University November 2018 Abstract. We consider the problem of a seller

More information

Competition in successive markets: entry and mergers

Competition in successive markets: entry and mergers Competition in successive markets: entry and mergers Jean J. Gabszewicz and Skerdilajda Zanaj Center for operations research and econometrics CORE Discussion Paper 2006/97 October 18, 2006 Abstract This

More information

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. 1 Market Demand Assume that there are only two goods (x and y)

More information

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma RESEARCH ARTICLE A MODEL OF COMPETITION BETWEEN PERPETUAL SOFTWARE AND SOFTWARE AS A SERVICE Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma School of Information Systems, Singapore Management University, 80 Stanford Road, Singapore

More information

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity *

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity * Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity * Index Section 1: High bargaining power of the small firm Page 1 Section 2: Analysis of Multiple Small Firms and 1 Large

More information

How to Supply Safer Food: A Strategic Trade Policy Point of View

How to Supply Safer Food: A Strategic Trade Policy Point of View How to Supply Safer Food: A Strategic Trade Policy Point of View Sayaka Nakano University of Hyogo June 2 2010 Abstract This paper examines how a tariff affects firms efforts to produce safer foods that

More information

Perfect competition and intra-industry trade

Perfect competition and intra-industry trade Economics Letters 78 (2003) 101 108 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase Perfect competition and intra-industry trade Jacek Cukrowski a,b, *, Ernest Aksen a University of Finance and Management, Ciepla 40,

More information