Government decisions on income redistribution and public production Drissen, H.P.C.

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Government decisions on income redistribution and public production Drissen, H.P.C."

Transcription

1 UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Government decisions on income redistribution and public production Drissen, H.P.C. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Drissen, H. P. C. (1999). Government decisions on income redistribution and public production Amsterdam: Thesis Publishers General rights It is not permitted to download or to forward/distribute the text or part of it without the consent of the author(s) and/or copyright holder(s), other than for strictly personal, individual use, unless the work is under an open content license (like Creative Commons). Disclaimer/Complaints regulations If you believe that digital publication of certain material infringes any of your rights or (privacy) interests, please let the Library know, stating your reasons. In case of a legitimate complaint, the Library will make the material inaccessible and/or remove it from the website. Please Ask the Library: or a letter to: Library of the University of Amsterdam, Secretariat, Singel 425, 1012 WP Amsterdam, The Netherlands. You will be contacted as soon as possible. UvA-DARE is a service provided by the library of the University of Amsterdam ( Download date: 30 Nov 2018

2 5 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 5.1 Introduction The more general character of the model presented in the previous chapter opens the opportunity to reexamine the robustness of some results with respect to income redistribution and public consumption that were put forward in Chapter 2. In that chapter the impact of the political influence structure and of the consumers' preferences on the redistribution of welfare and on public consumption was analyzed. In this chapter it is, first, analyzed whether the strong result that private and public production levels are not affected by a change in the political influence structure if all individuals have identical preferences, still holds. Second, the result that the impact of changes in political influence are rather indeterminate if workers have a higher preference for public consumption goods than capital owners is reexamined. The impact of political influence for this preference structure is particularly interesting, because empirical research suggests that workers have a stronger preference for public consumption than entrepreneurs [see SCHRAM AND VAN WINDEN (1989) and SCHRAM (1990)]. An argument for the result in Chapter 2 that a change in the political influence structure does not affect private and public production levels, if individuals have identical preferences, may be due to the utility function that was used in that chapter. The Cobb-Douglas specification that was used in Chapter 1 is a special case of the CES utility function in the model of Chapter 4, where the Cobb- Douglas function arises if the elasticity of substitution is equal to one. Although a function of the CES type is more flexible than the Cobb-Douglas function, it still assumes homothetic preferences. A further relaxation of the preference structure is obtained by specifying a quasi-homothetic function. A quasi-homothetic utility function is obtained if the subsistence quantities in the utility function that was presented in Chapter 4 [cf. eqs. (4.12) - (4.14)] have a positive value. The features of the choice of the functional form will be further discussed in this chapter. The organization of this chapter is as follows. Section 5.2 discusses the impact of the political influence structure on the distribution of income and consumption for the distinguished social groups. This is done under different assumptions with respect to preferences. This subsection only focuses on redistribution and consumption effects. The production effects of the political influence structure will be investigated in the next chapter. The impact of changes in preferences is studied

3 188 Chapter 5 in Section 5.3. This subsection offers a sensitivity analysis concerning the preference weights, the substitution possibilities and subsistence levels. For the sensitivity analyses in Section 5.2 and 5.3, the results in the initial steady state are compared with the results in the new steady state after a parameter change. Section 5.4 discusses the transition effects of changes in the political influence structure and changes in preferences. Section 5.5 concludes. 5.2 Distributive effects of political influence Introduction In this section the impact of political influence on income, consumption and utility is discussed. First, in Section 5.2.2, the consequences of changes in the political influence structure are analyzed for the base case preference parameters presented in Section 4.5. In that case, all individuals have the same, homothetic, preferences. To investigate the restrictiveness of homothetic preferences and of identical preferences, a similar sensitivity analysis is undertaken for the situation that preferences are not homothetic and for the case that workers have stronger preferences for the public consumption good and for leisure than capital owners. In Section the restrictiveness of homothetic preferences is discussed, while Section goes into the effects of changes in the political influence structure if individuals have different preferences. The parameter values for these analyses are presented in the appendix of this chapter Identical preferences The effects of changes in the political influence structure in case that all individuals have the same preferences, are given in Tables The first row in these tables, as for most of the other tables that will be presented in the Chapters 5, 6 and 7, gives the results for the initial steady state that was discussed in Section 4.6. Tables show that changes in the political influence structure hardly alter production levels, the levels of capital and labor inputs, prices, and the income tax rate. The effects on the distribution of private goods, leisure, and, consequently, on the utility levels are substantial, however. Thus, if individuals have identical, homothetic preferences, changes in political influence have strong redistributive effects, while the production effects are limited. Apart from the restrictions on

4 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 189 preferences, the small production effects are due to the fact that income is redistributed through a lump-sum transfer system (compare the production effects for a tax system without a transfer system in Section 7.4). Although the production effects are negligible, it is of interest to analyze why they occur at all. From the analytical model investigated in Chapters 2 and 3 it was obtained that public and private production do not depend on the political influence structure if consumers have identical preferences. This result appears to follow from the Cobb-Douglas specification that was chosen for the utility function in combination with the assumption that the redistribution system is a self-financing lump-sum tax-transfer system. If the utility function is of the Cobb-Douglas type, consumers do not alter the share of their (after-tax) full income that is spent on each private good and leisure if their full income changes, because preferences are homothetic. If individuals have identical preferences, these shares have the same value for every individual. A redistribution of income, that follows from a change in the political influence structure, has no effect on total demand for the different private commodities and leisure in that case, but only affects the distribution of these goods. Also, a change in the political influence structure does not affect the production level of the public consumption good if preferences are identical and represented by a Cobb-Douglas function. This follows immediately from the marginal value of the political interest function with respect to public commodities (which is equal to the sum of the marginal individual benefits). For the public consumption good, this marginal value in case of the CES utility function equals ~ = E, **,«* G s (tr l U^ty" Pit) (5.1) In the Cobb-Douglas case (7, = 0) utility Ufi) drops out of this equation. If preferences are identical, only the political influence weights are group specific. Because these weights sum up to unity, it follows from eq. (5.1) that under these restrictions the marginal value of the political interest function with respect to the public consumption good does not depend on the political influence structure. Consequently, this structure has no effect on the production levels in the private and the public sectors if individuals have identical preferences and these preferences are specified by a Cobb-Douglas function. Generalization of the utility function to a (nested) CES utility function still gives the result that the political influence structure does not influence production, as long as the preference weights with respect to the public consumption good (a a )

5 190 Chapter 5 Table 5.1 Effects on capital and shadowprices of capital Change in political influence, identical homothetic preferences /*cl' /*c2' ^w K, K 2 K s Kp qi = q2 q P = q* 0.10,0.10, ,0.15, ,0.25, ,0.05, ,0.15, Table 5.2 Effects on labor demand and leisure Change in political influence, identical homothetic preferences /*cl> Mc2- Mw L, U L s L P '.i '* K 0.10,0.10, ,0.15, ,0.25, ,0.05, ,0.15, Table 5.3 Effects on production and commodity prices Change in political influence, identical homothetic preferences /*cl. /*c2> Mw x, x. G s Gp Pi P2 0.10,0.10, ,0.15, ,0.25, ,0.05, ,0.15, Table 5.4 Effects on special provisions and utility Change in political influence, identical homothetic preferences Mcl> Mc2> /*w <*cl»c2 <T W u c, u c2 u w 0.10,0.10, ,0.15, ,0.25, ,0.05, ,0.15,

6 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 191 Table 5.5 Effects on dividend, wage rate, taxes and value of the political interest function Change in political influence, identical homothetic preferences ^ ci' f-a< Mw d, d 2 PL Th T P 0.10,0.10, ,0.15, ,0.25, ,0.05, ,0.15, are zero. Otherwise, private and public production are affected by the political influence structure. This follows from eq. (5.1), where utilities do not vanish for a CES utility function. Political influences are then 'weighted' with the reciprocal of the utility levels ( Up 1 ), and affect the marginal value of the political interest function, even if consumers' preferences are identical. A similar weighting of political influences holds for the marginal value of the political interest function with respect to the public production good. The marginal individual benefits of the production good follow indirectly from dividend income and the public consumption good that depend on the level of the public production good. 1 Although a change in the political influence structure affects private and public production levels, the effects are very small, compared to the distribution effects. The production effect, that follows from the change in the level of the public production good will be discussed in Section In this section the redistribution effects and the production effect that follow from changes in the production of private and public consumption goods are examined. The redistribution effects are easily explained. If the political influence of workers increases, more income will be transferred to workers, at the cost of the income of capital owners. The consumption of private goods and leisure by workers increases, while capital owners will consume less. The redistribution of private 1 Note that in case of Cobb-Douglas utilities the marginal value of the political interest function with respect to a production good still depends on the political influence structure, because not all groups benefit from this good through dividend income. Eq. (5.1) contains, therefore, only marginal individual benefits from dividend income for the social groups that receive such income. If the sum of the influence weights of these groups changes, the marginal value of the political interest function will change as well, leading to a change in the production level of the public production good.

7 192 Chapter 5 consumption leads to a higher utility level for workers and to a lower utility level for capital owners. The value of the political interest function (P) is, however, hardly affected by the redistribution of private consumption. The effect of a change in the political influence structure on the value of the political interest function is dominated by the production effects. It can be read from Table 5.5, that the value of the political interest function increases if the political influence is distributed more unequally over the social groups. To see this, eq. (5.1) is a good device. It follows from this equation that a social group has a higher weight in the marginal value of the political interest functions with respect to the public consumption good if ftjt/, " increases. Although an increase in political influence (/*,) leads to an increase in utility, it turns out that this weight increases if the political influence of a social group increases. It can be shown, however, that the sum of the weights l lx i U i decreases if political influence is distributed more unequally. The marginal value of the political interest function with respect to the public consumption good is, thus, at a maximum if the political influence weights are in accordance with the numerical strengths. For this political influence structure public consumption reaches the highest level. The higher level of public consumption increases the value of the political interest function, for its marginal value is positive. However, the extra government expenditure for the additional public production is financed with a distortionary tax, which has a negative effect on the value of the political interest function. It turns out that this negative effect on the political interest function exceeds the positive public consumption effect. Therefore, the public consumption good reaches the highest level if the political influence structure corresponds to the numerical strengths, while the value of the political interest function is at the lowest level at this point. The economic interpretation of this result is that a representative individual of a social group is willing to offer a smaller share of its income for the finance of a public consumption good if income increases. The larger political influence of the individual's social group enables the members of this group to let the government produce a lower level of the public consumption good. 2 2 Note that it is important that production levels and tax rates are both endogenously determined, to obtain a change in the value of the political interest function if the political influence structure changes. This value is not affected by a change in political influence if the government has to collect taxes for the finance of an exogenously given expenditure level. The mechanisms discussed in this respect still hold if the utility function is of the quasi-homothetic type that will be discussed at the end of this section.

8 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 193 The discussion thusfar focused on a shift in political influence between capital owners and workers. The same mechanisms are at work, however, if one group of capital owners is able to increase its political influence at the cost of the other group, while workers' political influence does not change. The results of such a political change are given in the last lines of Tables The absence of large effects on production levels for homothetic utility functions is a consequence of the constant shares of disposable full income a consumer spends on the different private commodities and leisure. A redistribution of income has no effect on private production in that case, as long as total income does not change, all consumers have the same preferences, there are no public goods, and the redistribution is through a lump-sum transfer system. In the model at hand, only the absence of public goods does not apply. The presence of public goods causes the small changes in the production levels that occur if the political influence structure changes. The utility function can be made more flexible by introducing subsistence levels, as in eqs. (4.12) and (4.14). We also investigated the effects of a change in the political influence structure for such a utility function. The values of the subsistence levels can be found in Table 5.A.2 of Appendix 5.A. It appeared, however, that the production effects of a change in the political influence structure are still negligible if subsistence levels are introduced in the utility functions. The reason for these small effects is that, although the introduction of subsistence levels makes the utility function non-homofhetic, the function is still quasi-homothetic. 3 This implies that the share of the excess budget (disposable income minus expenditures on the subsistence levels) that is spent on a particular commodity does not change if disposable income changes. Redistribution of income that follows from the change in the political influence structure has, therefore, only a small effect on production levels if utilities are quasi-homothetic. The effects of a change in the political influence structure are now easily understood with the arguments already provided and will, therefore, not be discussed here. It is beyond the scope of this thesis to investigate whether a further generalization of the utility function does lead to substantial changes in production levels if the political influence structure changes. Examples of non-homothetic utility functions are the generalized Gorman polar form as presented in BLUNDELL AND RAY (1982, 1984) and the translog demand functions as used in JORGENSON (1984). For these 3 Quasi-homothetic preferences give linear Engel curves. The difference with homothetic preferences is that the Engel curves do not start from the origin.

9 194 Chapter 5 utility functions, the demand function is nonlinear in income. In that case aggregate demand is not a function of aggregate income. Note that this would put a strong burden on the use of the concept of a representative individual. Under nonhomothetic preferences a representative individual only exists if all individuals in the social group are equal Different preferences An important result that follows from the previous analysis is that the value of the political interest function increases the more the political influence weights deviate from the numerical strengths of the social groups. In this section it will be examined whether this conclusion still holds if individuals of different social groups have different preferences. It is assumed that workers have a higher preference for leisure and for the public consumption commodity than capital owners. Capital owners in sector 1 and sector 2 have identical preferences. The values of the utility parameters are presented in Appendix 5.A. The steady state results for different political influence structures can be found in Tables If the political influence of workers rises, the government increases the transfers (special provisions) to workers at the cost of the income of capital owners. The redistribution of income from capital owners to workers leads to lower private consumption, because workers are willing to spend a larger share of their income for the finance of the public consumption good than capital owners. Although the level of the public consumption good increases, if workers' political influence increases, the change in this production level is not substantial when compared with the changes in the other production levels. This is due to the fact that the government can more effectively redistribute income through special provisions than through changes in public consumption. Therefore, the optimal level of public consumption is hardly affected by the political influence structure, as long as the government is able to redistribute income through special provisions. The consequences of a greater political influence of workers on production, capital formation and labor demand in the private sectors and the public consumption sector, can now easily be deduced from the effects on private and public consumption. The changes in the public production sector will be explained in Section

10 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 195 Table 5.6 Effects on capital and shadowprices of capital Change in political influence while workers have a stronger preference for leisure and the public consumption good than capital owners /*cl> A*-c2> A'w K, K 2 K s Kp q. = <b qp = <h 0.10,0.10, ,0.15, ,0.25, ,0.05, ,0.15, Table 5.7 Effects on labor demand and leisure Change in political influence while workers have a stronger preference for leisure and the public consumption good than capital owners /*cl- Mc2> Mw L, U L s Lp *.i la K 0.10,0.10, ,0.15, ,0.25, ,0.05, ,0.15, Table 5.8 Effects on production and commodity prices Change in political influence while workers have a stronger preference for leisure and the public consumption good than capital owners Mcl> Mc2' Mw x, X 2 G s G P Pi P ,0.10, ,0.15, ,0.25, ,0.05, ,0.15, A less straightforward result is the decrease in the value of the political interest function if there is a moderate increase in the political influence of capital owners (the political influence weight for each group of capital owners increases from 0.10 to 0.15, while the workers' political influence weight decreases from 0.80 to 0.70; see the second line in Table 5.10). This decrease is in contrast with the finding in the previous section where the value of this function appeared to increase if the

11 196 Chapter 5 Table 5.9 Effects on special provisions and utility Change in political influence while workers have a stronger preference for leisure and the public consumption good than capital owners Mel. Mc2> /*w cl CC2 <?w u c, u c2 u w 0.10,0.10, ,0.15, ,0.25, ,0.05, ,0.15, Table 5.10 Effects on dividend, wage rate, taxes and value of the political interest function Change in political influence while workers have a stronger preference for leisure and the public consumption good than capital owners f*cl> Mc2> Mw d, d 2 PL T h T P 0.10,0.10, ,0.15, ,0.25, ,0.05, ,0.15, political influence weights depart more from the numerical strengths of the social groups. The reason is the difference in preferences with respect to public consumption. The utility a worker attains from the public consumption good is higher than the utility attained by capital owners. If the political influence of capital owners increases, the lower utility of capital owners is relatively more strongly valued, which has a negative effect on the value of the political interest function. It mms out that the positive change in private consumption does not outweigh this negative effect if the increase in the political influence of capital owners is moderate, while it does if the increase is strong (the latter can be read from the third line in Table 5.10). Although the effect on the value of the political interest function is negative, even a moderate increase in the political influence of capital owners has economic effects that are commonly regarded as positive: production, employment (labor demand) and investments increase in the private sectors, as well as exports, while prices, the income tax rate, and tax revenues decrease. This shows the importance of a more comprehensive evaluation of political economic outcomes.

12 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption Effect of changes in preferences Introduction Apart from the political influence structure, redistribution of income and public consumption depends on the consumers' preferences, as specified by the utility functions. The utility functions in the model presented in Chapter 4 contain three types of parameters: preferences weights, substitution elasticities and subsistence levels. In this section we analyze the effects of a change in the aforementioned preference parameters. The analysis starts, in Section 5.3.2, with a discussion of changes in the preference weights. The impact of substitution elasticities is studied in Section We also studied the effects of a change in the subsistence levels. It followed, however, that these effects were rather straightforward. A higher subsistence level increases the marginal utility of a particular consumption level. An increase in the subsistence level has, therefore, a positive effect on the consumption level of that good. The results of a higher subsistence level can now easily be obtain if this mechanism is taken into account. Therefore, the effects of a change in the subsistence levels are not discussed here The impact of changes in the preference weights of all groups Preferences are represented by a nested utility function with a constant elasticity of substitution between commodities that are in the same nest (see Section 4.3). Preference weights represent preferences with respect to the components of a composite commodity in a particular nest. The aggregated preference weight of a commodity is then equal to the product of the preference weight on the lowest level that the commodity appears and the appropriate preference weights on all higher levels in the utility tree. In this section, the focus is not on these aggregate preference weights, but on the preference weights as presented in Section 4.3. The sensitivity analysis with respect to the preference weights concentrates on the steady state effects. It is assumed that the preference change is equal for all individuals. 4 The main results are presented in Tables We also studied a change in the preference weights of workers while preferences of capital owners did not change. Compared to a change in the preference weights of all individuals, the effects on production of such a change were different in magnitude, but rather similar in sign. The effects on the distribution of income were different, but these differences are rather straightforward. Therefore, this analysis is not presented here.

13 198 Chapter 5 Table 5.11 Effects on capital and shadowprices of capital Change in preference weights of all individuals <* ci, «H. <*Gi K, K 2 K s Kp qi = <h q P = q* 0.7,0.2, ,0.2, ,0.1, ,0.3, Table 5.12 Effects on labor demand, leisure and the wage rate Change in preference weights of all individuals «ci. «(i> «Gi L, L 2 L s Lp 'i PL 0.7,0.2, ,0.2, ,0.1, ,0.3, Table 5.13 Effects on production and commodity prices Change in preference weights of all individuals a ci, a H, <*Gi x, X 2 G s Gp Pi P2 0.7,0.2, ,0.2, ,0.1, ,0.3, Table 5.14 Effects on special provisions, utility, the value of the political interest function and taxes Change in preference weights of all individuals <*ci> «f,> <*Gi»cl <*c2 ff U,=P Th T 0.7,0.2, ,0.2, ,0.1, ,0.3,

14 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 199 Table 5.15 Effects on private demand and dividends Change in preference weights of all individuals «ci. ««. «Gi Cd» c fli C d2i C Oi d, d 2 0.7,0.2, ,0.2, ,0.1, ,0.3, At the highest level, utility is determined by the consumption of private commodities, leisure and the public consumption good. The discussion starts with a change in the preference weights on this level. A higher preference for the public consumption good (a Gi increases) that goes at the cost of the preference for private commodities (a ci decreases), leads to a higher production level of the public consumption good, while private production decreases (see the second line in the tables). The increase in public consumption boosts public expenditures, which causes the tax rate to rise. The increase in the tax rate lowers the shadowprice of leisure, which has a negative effect on labor supply. Although the decrease in private production diminishes the demand for labor, the decline in labor supply pushes up the wage rate. This leads to higher production costs and, consequently to higher commodity prices of the domestic commodities. An additional effect on commodity prices originates from the foreign sector. The weaker preferences for private commodities lead to a decrease in the demand for foreign goods, which causes the exchange rate to decline. The exchange rate being the numéraire, this entails an increase in the domestic commodity prices. Consequently, investment goods, produced in sector 1, become more expensive. In the steady state, the shadowprice of private capital depends on the tax rate and the price of investment goods [see eq. (4.34)]. Although the latter increases, its effect on the shadowprice of capital is dominated by the negative effect of the higher tax rate. In the public sectors, the shadowprice of capital depends on the marginal social costs and the price of investment goods [see eq. (4.35)]. The higher preference for public consumption increases the marginal social costs. As a result, the shadowprice of public capital increases because the price of investment goods also increases. Higher production costs and the lower production levels in the private sectors have a negative effect on profits. The decrease in profits leads to smaller dividend payments. This reduces the difference in income between capital owners and workers. Because the political influence weights are equal to the

15 200 Chapter 5 numerical strengths of the social groups and preferences are identical, the government tries to equate after-tax income, which leads to a reduction in transfers to workers, compared to the initial steady state. If the stronger preference for public consumption is accompanied by a decrease in the preference for leisure (a G, increases and a f, decreases), labor supply will increase (see the third line in the tables). The positive effect on labor supply of the lower preference for leisure dominates the negative effect on labor supply that follows from the higher income tax, that is necessary for the finance of the extra government expenditures on the public consumption good. Compared with the earlier change, the government can now employ more public sector workers for the production of the public goods. The government is even willing to pay them a higher wage, because the higher demand for public goods positively influences the marginal benefits of labor input. The increase in the level of the public consumption good is, therefore, much stronger in this case. The strong increase in the production of the public consumption good has a positive effect on the production of the public production good. An expansion of the public production good can now be observed, which is not only the consequence of the strong increase in the level of the public consumption good, but also of the fact that private consumption decreases only moderately. The lower private consumption level leads to a decrease in imports and a smaller production level in private sector 2. Production in sector 1 increases, however, because of the increased government demand for investment goods (recall that the goods that are produced in this sector can be used for investment as well as consumption purposes). Labor demand decreases in both private sectors, however, which is due to the higher wage rate. The increase in commodity prices originates again in the foreign sector, as discussed above. The increase in production in private sector 1 has a positive influence on profits, while the decrease in production in private sector 2 negatively affects the profits in this sector. Consequently, dividend payments increase in sector 1 and decrease in sector 2. The impact on the redistribution of income through special provisions is now straightforward. From a comparison of the above results with the results presented in Chapter 2 for an identical change in the preference weights, it follows that the effect on private production differs. The increase in the preference weight for the public consumption good and the simultaneous decrease in the preference weight for leisure led in Chapter 2 to an increase in private consumption (see the last columns

16 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 201 in Tables 2.2 and 2.3). 5 For the model that is used in this chapter, the similar change in preference weights gives, in contrast, a decrease in private consumption. Production in private sector 1 only increases because the decrease in the consumer demand for this commodity is outweighed by the increase in investment demand. The third preference change that is investigated concerns a higher preference for leisure (a (l increases) with a simultaneous decrease in the preference for private commodities (a ci decreases). This preference change leads to a decrease in demand for private commodities and in labor supply (see the last line in the tables). The lower demand for private commodities leads to a decrease in private production and imports. Again, the reduced imports and the fixed exchange rate (the numéraire) push up the domestic commodity prices. Moreover, the lower labor supply boosts the wage rate. This leads to a decrease in the demand for labor in the public sectors, which negatively affects public production. There is an additional negative effect on public production that is less obvious. The preference weights are adjusted with the substitution parameters, as shown by eq. (4.12). This implies that, although the preference weights sum up to one, the adjusted preference weights do not necessarily do so. The preference change from private commodities to leisure leads to an increase in the sum of the adjusted preference weights. Therefore, the relative adjusted preference weight for public consumption decreases, although the preference weight for public consumption does not change. This has a negative effect on the level of the public consumption good. The other effects can now easily be understood. The above results of a higher preference for leisure and an accompanying lower preference for private commodities differ in two respects from the results of a similar change in preferences that was investigated in Chapter 2. First, the commodity price decreases relative to the wage rate in Chapter 2, while it relatively increases in this chapter. In this chapter, the lower preference for private commodities reduces the demand for foreign commodities. The lower import of commodities goes with a lower export of commodities, which is realized by an increase in the prices for domestic commodities. This effect is absent in the model 5 In Chapter 2 the effects were analyzed for a change in preference weights for one social group, while the preferences of the other social group did not change, while the preference change that is analyzed in this chapter holds for all social groups. If, however, only the preference weights of workers are altered, the effects on production and input levels have the same sign as they have if the change in preference weights occurs for all social groups.

17 202 Chapter 5 for a closed economy of Chapter 2. Second, the change in preference weights has no effect on the tax rate in the model of Chapter 2, while it has a negative effect on the tax rate in this chapter. 6 Because the change in preferences does not affect the preference weight for public consumption, this change does not alter the share of income that consumers are willing to spend on public consumption in the model of Chapter 2. In the model of this chapter, the decrease in the preferences for private commodities has a negative effect on the level of the public production good. The decrease in the production of this good is stronger than the decrease in the public consumption good. Furthermore, public consumption faced, compared with Chapter 2, an additional negative effect, because of the aforementioned decrease in the relative adjusted preference weight for public consumption. These two effects make that the change in the preference weights leads to a decrease in the tax rate. At the next level in the utility tree, private commodities are split up in commodities of type 1 and commodities of type 2. The results of a change in the preference weights concerning these two types of commodities is rather straightforward and will, therefore, not be reproduced in the tables. The main effects can be summarized as follows. A higher preference for commodities of type 2 (a 2, increases) at the cost of the preference for commodities of type 1 (a u decreases), leads to an increase in the demand for domestic and foreign commodities of type 2 and a decrease in the demand for domestic and foreign commodities of type 1. The price of commodity 2 then increases and the price of commodity 1 decreases. These changes in prices positively affect the export of domestic commodity 1, while the export of the other commodity is negatively affected. Furthermore, the lower price of commodity 1 makes investment goods cheaper. Labor will then be substituted by capital, which is, in particular, notable in the public production sectors. The production levels in these sectors increase a little, but the increase in capital stocks and decrease in labor demand is more substantial. The lower investment costs make a reduction of the tax rate possible. The decrease in the production level and in the commodity price of sector 1 leads to lower profits and dividend payments in this sector. For sector 2 the opposite holds. More income from capital owners in sector 2 and less income from capital owners in sector 1 is then transferred to workers through special provisions. 6 The negative signs for the effect on the tax rate in Tables 2.2 and 2.3 go to zero if the change in preference weights does not affect the preference weight for the public consumption good, as can easily be obtained from eq. (2.23).

18 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 203 The lowest level of the utility tree decomposes the commodity bundles of type 1 and type 2 into a domestic commodity and a foreign commodity. A higher preference for a domestic commodity at the cost of the preference for the foreign commodity of the same type pushes up the prices of both domestic commodities. The higher price of commodity 1 leads to an increase in investment costs, which reduces the public capital stocks. Public production levels are, however, hardly affected by the change in preference weights on the lowest level of the utility tree. The higher domestic commodity prices have, furthermore, a positive effect on profits, that offsets the negative effect on profits of the higher per capita costs of labor and investments. The concomitant increase in dividend payments in both sectors induces the government to transfer more income from entrepreneurs to workers in order to equalize disposable income The impact of changes in the substitution elasticities of all groups As noticed in Section 4.2, an interesting feature of a nested utility function is the possibility to allow for differences in substitutability between goods. The utility function used in this chapter comprises three different substitution parameters: 7,, specifying the substitutability between private commodities, leisure and the public good; y ci, specifying the substitutability between private commodities of type 1 and of type 2; and y cji, specifying the substitutability between domestic and foreign commodities of type j. In this section the impact of the distinct substitution parameters is discussed. This is done by analyzing the effects of a change in substitution parameters that is identical for all (representative individuals of) social groups. 7 The results for the different cases that are studied are summarized in Tables An increase in the substitution elasticities makes the demand for commodities more sensitive to prices. From the demand equations it can be derived that such an increase leads to an increase (decrease) in the demand for a commodity if the price of this commodity is low (high), relative to the prices of the other commodities. 7 As for the preference weights, it was also analyzed what the effects are if only the substitution parameters for workers alter. The effects on production from this change differ only in magnitude from the effects of a change in the substitution parameters for all social groups, while the differences in the redistribution of income are straightforward. Therefore, the effects of a change in the substitution parameters for workers can easily be obtained from the analysis of a change in the substitution parameters for all social groups.

19 204 Chapter 5 Table 5.16 Effects on capital, shadowprices of capital and price of commodity 1 Changes in substitution elasticities /i» Ten Tcji K, K 2 K s Kp qi=q 2 q s =q P Pi 0.1, 0.1, , 0.1, , 0.3, , 0.3, , 0.3, , 0.2, Table 5.17 Effects on production, exports and price of commodity 2 Changes in substitution elasticities Yi, Tci, Tcji x, X 2 G s Gp E, E 2 P2 0.1, 0.1, , 0.1, , 0.3, , 0.3, , 0.3, ,0.2, Table 5.18 Effects on private demand, leisure, utility, the value of the political interest function and the wage rate Changes in substitution elasticities Ti> Tci' Tcji C dli Cfli C d2i Cf2i i; U,=P PL 0.1, 0.1, , 0.1, , 0.3, , 0.3, , 0.3, , 0.2,

20 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 205 Table 5.19 Effects on dividends, special provisions and taxes Changes in substitution elasticities Ti' Tci' Ycji d, d 2 Th T ^cl "c2 CT W 0.1, 0.1, , 0.1, , 0.3, , 0.3, , 0.3, , 0.2, Consider first an increase in the substitution parameter y cji (see the second line in each table), and, thus, in the substitution elasticity between domestic and foreign goods of type 1 and of type 2. 8 This leads to an increase in the demand for the two domestic commodities and to a decrease in the demand for the two foreign commodities, because the domestic commodity prices are lower than the foreign prices (which are equal to one). The larger demand for domestic commodities leads to an increase in the domestic commodity prices, which has a negative effect on exports. The decrease in exports of commodities produced in sector 1 is so strong that it dominates the extra domestic demand for this good, which leads to a lower production in this sector. For sector 2 the extra domestic demand dominates, leading to a higher production level in sector 2. The higher prices for the domestic commodities have a positive effect on profits, allowing the firms to increase their dividend payments. Although the smaller production in sector 1 has a negative effect on labor demand, total labor demand increases, because this negative effect is outweighted by the extra labor demand in the more labor intensive sector 2. The impact of the change in the substitution elasticity between domestic and foreign goods of type 1 and of type 2 on public production is negligible. If, in addition, the substitution elasticity between private commodities of type 1 and type 2 increases, a similar effect is observed. The demand for the composite good with the higher price (good 2) decreases in favor of the demand for the composite good with the lower price (good 1). Also the effect on prices is analogous: the 8 Recall that the relation between the substitution elasticity a and the substitution parameter y is given by a = l/(l-y). Nonnegativity of the substitution elasticity requires that 7 < 1.

21 206 Chapter 5 difference between the price of composite good 1 and composite good 2 is reduced. More specifically, the price of domestic commodity 1 increases, while the price of domestic commodity 2 decreases. The higher price of commodity 2 has a positive effect on the sector's profits, while the lower price of commodity 1 reduces the profits in sector 1. Although the lower price of domestic commodity 2 has a positive effect on export, production in sector 2 decreases, which leads to a decrease in labor demand. The extra labor demand in sector 1 cannot prevent total labor demand from falling. Leisure then increases. The impact on public production is not substantial. The changes in the substitution parameters discussed so far particularly affected the demand for private commodities and prices. The impact on the labor market and on public production was not substantial. This changes if, in addition, the substitution parameter on the highest level of the utility tree increases (y, increases: see the fourth line in the tables). The higher substitution elasticity leads, again, to an increase in the consumption of the commodity with the lowest price. The public consumption good has the lowest (shadow-)price. An immense increase in the level of the public consumption good can be observed. The demand for private goods decreases enormously, because the composite of private goods has the highest price. The reduction in price differences can also be observed for this case. The prices of the domestic private goods do increase, but the initially lower price of the public consumption good increases much stronger. The strong increase in the income tax rate cuts, however, the shadowprice of leisure, which is equal to (l-t h )p L. Labor supply then decreases, but total labor demand also falls because of the immense reduction in private production which is due to the strong decrease in the demand for private commodities. The decrease in the production levels has, furthermore, a negative effect on profits, which cannot be offset by the higher commodity prices. The lower profits reduce the dividend payments. To achieve the desired distribution of incomes, lower special provisions will suffice. Utilities are positively influenced by the change in the substitution parameter on the highest level of the utility tree. Substitution between (composite) goods was, in the above cases, easier between commodities on a lower level of the utility tree. An increase in the substitution parameter led to an increase in the consumption of the commodity with the lowest price. It appears that this mechanism is still at work if the values of the substitution parameters are larger at a higher level of the utility tree. If, for example, the values of the substitution parameters between domestic and foreign commodities

22 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 207 decrease, for type 1 and type 2 commodities, and become smaller than the values of the substitution parameters for the higher levels on the utility tree (y cli and y c2i become smaller than y d and y t : see the fifth line in the tables), consumption of the commodity with the lowest price decreases, while the consumption of the commodity with the highest price increases. The foreign commodities are cheaper than the domestic commodities, which leads to a lower demand for foreign commodities. The resulting decrease in exports is so strong that it outweighs the increased domestic demand for this good, and causes production in sector 1 to decrease. As a consequence, the price of commodity 1 increases, which leads to an increase in the difference between the domestic and foreign commodity of type 1. The decrease in exports of commodity 2 does not outweigh the higher domestic demand for commodity 2. Production in sector 2 increases, which leads to a decrease in its price. The higher revenues that are obtained in both private sectors have a positive influence on profits and dividends. The higher revenues, furthermore, allow for a higher wage rate, because the Cobb-Douglas production function implies a constant expenditure share for labor costs in both sectors. The substitution parameters in the above cases were all positive, which gives substitution elasticities between commodities in the same nest that are greater than one. Substitution elasticities greater than one do not guarantee that commodities, that are not on the same level of the utility tree, are (gross) substitutes. However, it can be shown [see e.g. KELLER (1976)], that all commodities are gross substitutes if the substitution elasticity on the highest level is greater than, or equal to, one and the substitution elasticity does not decrease if a lower level on the utility tree is reached. 9 Analogously, sufficient conditions for complementarity are a substitution elasticity smaller than or equal to one at the highest level together with a smaller substitution elasticity for the lower levels. 10 It turns out that the effects of a decrease in the Subsumtion elasticities to a value smaller than one (to negative values of the substitution parameters) are still dominated by the mechanism that a decrease in the substitution elasticity leads to a decrease in the consumption of the commodity with the lower price. These effects are now rather straightforward and are, therefore, not further discussed here. 9 The condition on the substitution parameters for gross substitutability is, thus, 0 < 7, < y ci < y ci, j = 1, 2, where at least one strict inequality must apply. 10 Complementarity is obtained if the following conditions for the substitution parameters are fulfilled: y cß < y d < T, ^ 0, j = 1, 2, where one strict inequality must hold.

23 208 Chapter Transition effects of changes in political influence and preferences Introduction The analyses of changes in the political influences structure and preferences, as discussed in the previous sections, concentrated on the long run effects. These effects were obtained by comparing the steady state solution for the initial parameter set with the steady state solution that holds for the changed parameter set. In this section, the focus is on the transition path that the economy follows before it reaches the new steady state. In the steady state future values of variables are equal to their present values. Therefore, expected values of variables can be set equal to the present values. Along the transition path, future and present values of variables are not necessarily equal. An expectation rule must be defined before the dynamic paths can be solved. Although steady state outcomes do not depend on the expectation rule that agents have (see Section 4.7), the transition path does depend on the expectation rule agents have with respect to future variables that influence current decisions. In the model presented here, the investment decisions of entrepreneurs and the government depend on the expected benefits of investments. These expectations are reflected by the shadowprice of capital for the next period (q/t+l), j = 1, 2, p, s). These shadowprices are the only variables for which agents must hold expectations. It is assumed here that agents have static expectations, given by: Efe/f+1), t] = qff), j = 1, 2, p, s (5.2) where the expectations indicator refers to the value of variable q } in period f+7 as it is expected in period t. In Section 4.7 we compared the static expectation rule with other expectation rules. In this chapter, as well as in Chapters 6 and 7, we will only give transition effects for the static expectation rule. The transition effects for other expectation rules can easily be obtained with the results given in this section and Section 4.7. We concluded in Section 5.2, that changes in political influence hardly affect the private and public production levels if individuals have identical preferences. Significant effects on production can be obtained, however, if differences in preferences are allowed. In order to get an interesting analysis of transition paths, the original parameter set is adapted in this way. A second change in the parameter set concerns a stronger impact of the public production good (infrastructure) on the

24 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 209 production in private sector 1. The complete parameter set that is used in this section is given in Appendix 5.A.2. Transition effects will be investigated for three different parameter changes. Section discusses the effects of a change in the political influence structure, implying a rise in the influence of workers, at the cost of the political influence of both groups of capital owners. In Section we investigate the transition path after a change in the preferences of workers, which involves an increase in their preference for the public consumption good. Finally, the effects of a simultaneous change in the political influence and preferences of workers is discussed in Section Change in political influence structure The transition paths of the key variables are presented in Figures These figures show the deviations from the initial steady state values. Using deviations gives us the opportunity to present the transition paths of several variables in one figure. The discussion of the transitional effects of a change in the political influence structure starts with the initial effects that immediately follows the change in influence. The increase in political influence of workers leads to a change in the redistribution of income by the government, in favor of the workers. 11 Workers have a stronger preference for the public consumption good than capital owners and are, consequently, willing to pay higher taxes for the finance of extra production of this good. This induces the government to increase the production of the public consumption good (cf. Figure 5.3). The higher production level requires an increase in labor and capital input, and an expansion of the public production good (infrastructure). The adjustment of the level of the capital stock and of infrastructure takes some time. However, the government can increase the production of public consumption immediately by employing more workers (cf. Figures 5.1 and 5.2; the development of the labor-capital ratio is presented in Figure 5.6, while Figure 5.7 gives the development of labor productivity). In 11 The shock that is discussed here implies a strong change in the political influence weights, leading to new weights that are equal to ^w = 0.96 (instead of 0.80) and fi ci = 0.02 (instead of 0.10) for j = 1,2.

25 210 Chapter 5 Figure 5.1 Transition effects on capital stocks if political influence of workers increases i Index Period 100 Figure 5.2 Transition effects on labor demand if political influence of workers increases , Index Sector 1 Sector 2 Sector s Sector p 60 Period 100

26 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 211 Figure 53 Transition effects on production if political influence of workers increases i Index r Sector 1 Sector s Sector 2 - Sector p T Period Figure 5.4 Transition effects on shadowprice of capital if political influence of workers increases 1.6 -i Index rrr^ f / / s f =_ " V^-^s / n f, - oeciui s Sectui 2 Sector p ' 1 ' Period

27 212 Chapter 5 Figure 5.5 Transition effects on investment-capital ratio if political influence of workers increases "-. Value Sector 1 Sector s - Sector 2 - Sector p Period 1Q0 Figure 5.6 Transition effects on labor-capital ratio if political influence of workers increases Index Sector 1 Sector s Sector 2 - Sector p Period 100

28 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 213 Figure 5.7 Transition effects on labor productivity if political influence of workers increases 1,04 T-i Index Sector 1 Sector 2 Sector s Sector p Period i( Figure 5.8 Transition effects on utility levels and value of political interest function (P) if political influence of workers increases 1.4 i Index Cap. owners 1 Cap. owners 2 Workers Value P Period 100

29 214 Chapter 5 addition, the government raises investments in the capital stock that is needed for the production of the public consumption good (Figure 5.5). For these extra investments the government is willing to pay a higher price, which shows up in the higher shadowprice of capital (q s ; cf. Figure 5.4). The higher production level of the public consumption good is accompanied by a demand for an expansion of infrastructure, because the benefits from infrastructure increase [cf. eq. (4.22) and Figure 5.3]. However, this expansion does not take place, because the increase in the political influence of workers not only leads to a higher demand for the public consumption good, but also to a decrease in the demand for private goods. The concomitant decrease in private production leads to a lower demand for labor in the private sectors, which outweighs the increased demand for labor by the government. Furthermore, it leads to a smaller demand for private capital and a decrease in the benefits that private sectors obtain from infrastructure. In spite of this decrease in labor demand, total labor demand tends to increase. This is due to the fact that the public consumption sector, where labor demand increases, is the most labor intensive sector. The smaller benefits from infrastructure in private production outweigh the larger benefits in the production of the public consumption good, which causes the level of the public production good to decrease. The smaller need for capital in the two private sectors leads to a decrease in the shadowprices of the capital stocks (q 2 and q 2 ; cf. Figure 5.4). The shadowprice of capital in the public production sector (q p ) increases, however, in spite of the lower capital requirement, which discourages investments in this sector. The reason for the increase in this shadowprice is that the higher production level in the public consumption sector leads to higher government expenditures, which increases the tax rate and thereby the social marginal costs of extra public revenues ( ) These higher social marginal costs lead to higher shadowprices of capital in the public sectors [q p and q s ; cf. eqs. (4.26) and (4.35)]. The extra public revenues that are required increase the tax rate. It turns out that, in this case, the increased political influence of workers has a positive influence on the utility of workers, and a negative influence on the utilities of capital owners (cf. Figure 5.8). The effect of the change in political influence on the value of the political interest function (P) is even larger than the effect on the utility of workers. This is due to the change in the influence weights with which the utilities of the different social groups are weighted in the political decisionmaking process (see also Section 5.2). As holds for the government, producers must in the first periods mainly rely on adaptations in labor input to adjust the production level to the altered demand. In

30 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 215 addition, investment increases to adjust the capital stock, which takes time. In the first few periods, the effects of the political influence change are largely related to a redistribution of income, which changes the demand for goods, and to changes in labor input. After these periods, income redistribution and the demand for goods hardly change. Consequently, changes in utilities become negligible as well. The economic effects of the change in the political influence structure are then mainly related to the developments that take place on the production side, and the adjustments in the capital stocks. Capital stocks reach their new steady state value after approximately 100 periods (cf. Figure 5.1). In the first periods after the political influence change investment in the public consumption sector grows rapidly. Even overinvestment occurs in the sense that the capital stock increases to a level that is higher than the new steady state level. This is followed by a decline in investments which leads, with a time-lag, to a decrease in the capital stock (see also Figure 5.5). The (static) expectation rule that the government maintains with respect to the shadowprice of capital underlies the overinvestments in this sector, as explained in Section 4.7. In contrast with the public consumption sector, the change in the political influence structure has a negative effect on the capital stocks in the private sectors and the public production sector, which leads to lower investments in these sectors. In fact the decrease in investments is so strong that, after a while, underinvestment occurs, leading to a level of the capital stock that is lower than the new steady state value (see Figures 5.1 and 5.5). This effect is most prominent in private sector 1. This sector shows also the smallest initial adaptation in investment and, as a consequence, the largest change in investment and production during the remainder of the transition path. This is not so surprising, because the goods of this sector are not only used for consumption but also for investment, and the adjustment in the demand for investment goods (or capital) proceeds more slowly than the adjustment in the demand for consumption goods. The shadowprices of capital in the two private sectors recover after the first periods, as excess capital wears out and is not replaced by new capital (cf. Figure 5.4). This increases the marginal benefits of capital and, consequently, the price capital owners are willing to pay for extra capital. An opposite effect occurs in the public consumption sector. There, the change in the political influence structure leads to a higher demand for the public consumption good, for the production of which the government needs extra capital. The marginal benefit of capital increases, therefore, and the government is willing

31 216 Chapter 5 to pay a higher price for extra capital. Through higher investments the capital deficiency disappears, which reduces again the marginal benefit of capital and thus the price that the government is willing to pay for extra capital. In the public production sector the development of the shadowprice of capital is dominated by the social marginal cost of extra public revenues, which tends to increase over the whole period (cf. Figure 5.4) Change in workers' preference for the public consumption good In case of a stronger preference of workers for the public consumption good the government is induced to increase the production of the public consumption good. 12 On the other hand, the simultaneous decrease in the preference for private goods causes the demand for private goods to decrease. The transition paths for this preference change are presented in Figures For convenience, the effects of this preference change are decomposed into effects concerning the production levels and the total demand for goods and factor inputs, on the one hand, and effects concerning redistribution and utilities on the other hand. It turns out that the transitional effects of the preference change on the production levels have the same direction as the effects discussed above for a change in the political influence structure in favor of workers (compare Figures 5.3 and 5.11). These results will not be repeated here. With respect to the redistribution of income and the utility levels, the effects differ substantially from the effects that followed a political influence change (compare Figures 5.8 and 5.16). The main reason for this dissimilarity is the different impact that the two shocks have on the redistribution of income through transfers (special provisions). Larger political influence of workers led to an increase in their special provisions at the cost of the special provisions for capital owners. As a consequence, capital owners not only had to contribute to the extra production of the public consumption good, through a higher income tax, but were also confronted with higher taxes in form of special provisions that restricted their disposable income substantially. The resulting strong decrease in their private consumption and leisure overshadowed the extra utility received from the higher The preference change of workers that is analyzed here consists of an increase in stribution parameter a Gw 1 parameter <x c from 0.50 to 0.40.

32 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 217 level of the public consumption good, which led to a lower utility level for capital owners. A change in the preference of workers again leads to a higher income tax for the finance of the extra public production. However, workers must now pay a price for the contribution of capital owners to the extra costs of public production. This contribution is realized by transferring income from workers to capital owners through the redistribution system. This enables capital owners to consume more of all private goods and to reduce their labor input. Together with the higher level of the public consumption good, this leads to higher utility levels for capital owners. Although workers are confronted with a reduction in the consumption of private goods, their utility levels also increase, because their leisure increases as well as the level of the public consumption good which is now more preferred by workers. The fact that all groups receive a higher utility, and the political influence weights do not change, implies that the value of the political interest function increases. The new situation is Pareto superior to the situation that existed before the preference shock. The redistribution effects mainly occur in the first periods after the preference change, as was also the case for the change in political influence Simultaneous increase in the political influence of workers and their preference for the public consumption good A simultaneous change in the preference for the public consumption good and the political influence of workers is of interest, for the following reason. An increase in the preference for the public consumption good induces an increase in the number of public sector workers, at the cost of the number of private sector workers. Because there are good reasons to expect that the political influence of public sector workers is more strongly related to numerical strength than the influence of private sector workers, 13 the increase in the number of public sector workers may also lead to an increase in the political influence of workers. Therefore, an increase in the workers' preference for public consumption may be accompanied by an increase in the political influence of workers. The transition paths for this simultaneous change are presented in Figures Since the 13 Reasons for this difference are that public sector workers are better organized and that they can also influence the political decisionmaking process from within the governmental organization.

33 218 Chapter 5 Figure 5.9 Transition effects on capital stocks if preference of workers for public good increases 1.3 Index Sector 1 Sector s Sector 2 - Sector p Period 100 Figure 5.10 Transition effects on labor demand if preference of workers for public good increases 1.2 Index Sector 1 Sector s Sector 2 - Sector p "1 ' 1 80 Period 100

34 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 219 Figure 5.11 Transition effects onproiuction if preference of workers for public good increases 1.2 i Index "i ' r Sector 1 Sector s Sector 2 - Sector p T Period 100 Figure 5.12 Transition effects on shadowprice of capital if preference of workers for public good increases 3.5 -, 3.0 Index Sector 1 - Sector s Sector 2 - Sector p T Period 1(

35 220 Chapter 5 Figure 5.13 Transition effects on investment-capital ratio if preference of workers for public increases 013 _, Value Sector 1 Sector s Sector 2 - Sector p ' 1 Period 100 Figure 5.14 Transition effects on labor-capital ratio if preference of workers for public good increases 1.2 Index ~r Sector 1 Sector s Sector 2 - Sector p T Period 100

36 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 221 Figure 5,15 Transition effects on labor productivity if preference of workers for public good increases , Index Sector 1 Sector s Sector 2 Sector p I Period i( Figure 5.16 Transition effects on utility levels and value of political interest function (P) if preference of workers for public good increases 2.2 Index r Cap. owners 1 - Cap. owners 2 - i 1 r Workers Value P Period 1(

37 222 Chapter 5 Figure 5.17 Transition effects on capital stocks if political influence of workers and preference of workers for public good increase 1.4 Sector 1 Sector s Sector 2 - Sector p T ~~' 1 Period 10( Figure 5.18 Transition effects on labor demand if political influence of workers and preference of workers for public good increase Index 1.2 -i Sector 1 Sector 2 Sector s Sector p Period 1(

38 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption Figure 5.19 Transition effects on production if political influence of workers and preference of workers for public good increase 1.2 -i 1.1 Index t i Sector 1 Sector 2 Sector s Sector p Period i( Figure 5.20 Transition effects on shadowprice of capital if political influence of workers and preference of workers for public good increase 5.0 Index Sectorl Sector 2 - Sectors - Sector p Period 100

39 224 Chapter 5 Figure 5.21 Transition effects on investment-capital ratio if political influence of workers and preference of workers for public good increase Value '"' \ : O.OS I / Sector 1 Sector s Sector 2 - Sector p -' 1 Period 1Q0 Figure 5.22 Transition effects on labor-capital ratio if political influence of workers and preference of workers for public good increase Period 100

40 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 225 Figure 5.23 Transition effects on labor productivity if political influence of workers and preference of workers for public good increase Index Sector 1 Sector 2 Sector s Sector p Period \( Figure 5.24 Transition effects on utility levels and value of political interest function (P) if political influence of workers and preference of workers for public good increase 2.5 Index Cap. owners Cap. owners 2 - Workers - Value P ~r 20 r Period 100

41 226 Chapter 5 effects of the simultaneous change in preferences and political influence can be easily understood with the above discussion of the separate changes, the interpretation of the results is left to the reader. 5.5 Concluding remarks In this chapter, we first studied the robustness of some conclusions that were arrived at in Chapter 2. In that chapter, we concluded that the political influence structure does not affect the levels of production if individuals have identical preferences and the government can use lump-sum transfers to redistribute income. We conjectured that the Cobb-Douglas specification of the utility functions was responsible for this result. Therefore, the effect of the political influence structure on production levels were analyzed in Section 5.2 with a nested CES utility function. It turned out that, in that case, a change in the political influence structure did lead to a change in the production levels. However, the changes in production were very small. The change in the political influence structure leads to a redistribution of income and welfare, but does hardly affect production. This result is still valid if the utility functions are of a more flexible, quasi-homothetic form. The effect of the political influence structure on production levels was also studied for the situation that preferences differ between the individuals of different social groups. It was, in particular, assumed that workers have a stronger preference for leisure and the public consumption good than capital owners. In that case, an increase in the political influence of capital owners leads to an increase in private as well as public production. However, the level of the public consumption good is hardly affected by the political influence structure, unless the increase in the political influence weights of capital owners is very strong. If the change in political influence is not very large, the special provisions are the most effective instruments of the government to redistribute welfare. A strong increase in the political influence of capital owners requires, however, also a change in the level of the public consumption good. The importance of the presence of special provisions to redistribute income will be studied in greater detail in Chapter 7. The impact of the political influence structure on the value of the political interest function was the second issue analyzed in Section 5.2. It appeared that, if individuals have identical preferences, the political interest function had the lowest

42 Consumer behavior, redistribution and public consumption 227 value in a situation where political influence is equally distributed over the social groups (that is, the political influence is determined by the numerical strength of the social groups). It was illustrated in Section 5.2 that the demand for the public consumption good is at its peak in a situation with an equal distribution of political influence. The finance of the production costs of this good with a distortionary tax explains the lowest value of the political interest function in that situation. This result changes somewhat if individuals have different preferences. In that case, we assumed again that workers are more interested in leisure and the public consumption good than capital owners. Under this assumption the value of the political interest function increases if political influence shifts from an equal distribution to a distribution where the influence of capital owners is stronger. Although the level of the public consumption good is hardly affected if the political influence of capital owners increases (because the government uses the special provisions to redistribute welfare), the contribution of this good to the value of the political interest function decreases, because the utility that capital owners derive from this good is lower than the utility attained by workers. This negative effect is not outweighed by the positive effect on the political interest function of the higher consumption of private commodities. However, if the political influence of capital owners increases strongly, the effect of the higher consumption of private commodities dominates and the value of the political interest function increases. The analysis of preferences in Section 5.3 led to the somewhat surprising conclusion that a decrease in the preference for private commodities and an increase in the preference of either leisure or the public consumption good, leads to an increase in the utility of all social groups and the value of the political interest function, whereas production and investment in the private sector and total employment decrease. If the decrease in the preference for private commodities goes with an increase in the preference for the public consumption good, the income tax rate as well as the tax revenue increases. Hence, although the usual economic indicators suggest that the change in preferences leads to a poorer economic performance, the utility levels and the value of the political interest function increase. We analyzed also in Section 5.3 the effect of a change in the substitution elasticities. It appeared that these effects are dominated by the mechanism that an increase in the Subsumtion elasticity increases the demand for the commodity with the lowest price. Because the public consumption good has the lowest (shadow-)price in our model, the demand for this good increases if the Subsumtion

43 228 ^ Chapter 5 elasticity between private commodities, leisure and the public consumption good increases, while the demand for private commodities and leisure decrease. The transition effects of changes in political influence and preferences were studied in Section 5.4. This was done for the case that workers are more interested in leisure and public consumption than capital owners. First, the transition effects of an increase in the political influence of workers was analyzed. The effects in the short run are dominated by changes in labor demand in the different sectors and special provisions. In the model, these variables can be changed 'overnight', whereas changes in capital stocks take time. The increase in the political influence of workers leads, in the short run to an increase in labor demand by the public consumption sector, whereas the labor demand by the other sectors decreases. The change in special provisions implies a stronger redistribution of income from capital owners to workers. These changes lead to an increase in the level of the public consumption and the utility of workers and to a decrease in the production of other goods and the utility of capital owners. The production and particularly the utility levels that are reached within a few periods after the change in political influence, are hardly affected by the further adjustment of the capital stocks. Only the production in sector 1 decreases substantially, which is due to the decrease in the demand for investment goods. The transition paths of a change in the preferences of workers, that were also analyzed in Section 5.4, led to similar conclusions: an increase in the workers' preference for the public consumption good leads in the short run to an increase in labor demand by the public consumption sector and a decrease in labor demand by the other sectors, whereas the adjustment of the capital stocks hardly affects production and utility levels in the longer run.

44 Appendix 5.A Alternative parameter sets Most of the studies in this chapter use the base case parameter set that was discussed in Section 4.5. However, for some exercises, the discussion starts from another parameter set. These alternative parameter sets are presented in this Appendix. The first occasion where an alternative parameter set is used concerns the analysis of the political influence structure. The impact of political influence is not only analyzed for the base case situation with identical, homothetic preferences, but also for the cases that preferences are not identical (Section 5.2.3) or quasi homothetic (Section 5.2.2). The parameter sets used for these additional exercises are presented in Section 5.A.I. The second occasion where an alternative parameter set is used concerns the discussion of transition effects that occur after a change in the political influence structure and/or preferences (Section 5.4). For these dynamic analyses the same initial parameter set is employed. This parameter set can be found in Section 5.A.2. This section also offers the results for the steady state that corresponds to this initial parameter set, and for the new steady states that occur for the parameter changes in the different dynamic exercises. This parameter set will also be used in Chapters 6 and 7 to study transition effects for technical changes and a change in the government's time preference. In order to avoid repetition, the new steady states for the parameter changes that are discussed in the Chapters 6 and 7 are produced in this Appendix. 5.A.1 Alternative consumption parameters The alternative parameter sets that are used at the end of Section and in Section differ only from the base case parameter set with respect to the consumer parameters. For the analysis where consumers of different social groups have different preferences, the differences are concentrated in the share parameters. Workers have higher share parameters for leisure and the public consumption good than capital owners. The share parameters are summarized in Table 5.A.I. All other parameters are equal to the base case values. In order to establish quasi homothetic preferences, subsistence quantities are introduced for all goods. These subsistence quantities are presented in Table 5.A.2. The values of other parameters for the analyses with quasi homothetic preferences resemble the base case values.

45 230 Chapter 5 Table 5.A.1 Consumer parameters if jreferences differ Entrepr. cl Entrepr. c2 Workers w Private goods share a ci Leisure share a,, Public good share <x a Share composite good 1 a n Share composite good 2 a 2i Share domestic good 1 a dn Share foreign good 1 ce fn Share domestic good 2 <x d2i Share foreign good 2 a pi Table 5.A.2 Subsistence levels if preferences are quasi homothetic Entrepr. cl Entrepr. c2 Workers w Domestic private commodity Foreign private commodity Domestic private commodity Foreign private commodity Leisure Public consumption good A.2 Parameter set for dynamic analyses and steady state results Transition effects of a parameter shocks are discussed at several places in this chapter and in the Chapters 6 and 7. In order to get articulated results for all these analyses with the same initial parameter set, the base case parameter set has to be modified. From the analyses where the steady state effects of parameter changes are discussed it follows that identical preferences give negligible effects on production if a change in the political influence structure was investigated. To obtain more pronounced results, it is assumed that preferences of workers differ from preferences of capital owners in sector 1 and in sector 2. The differences only show up in the share parameters in the first nesting. A second difference with the parameter set presented in Section 4.5 concerns the production in sector 1, that is now more dependent on private capital and infrastructure. All other parameters are

46 Redistribution and public consumption 231 Table 5.A.3 Production parameters for dynamic analyses Sector 1 Sector 2 Sector p Sector s Scale parameter fy Labor share ô LJ Capital share ô KJ Public good share ô aj Depreciation rate depj Scale parameter <p tj Adjustment cost parameter <p 2J Scale parameter rj ö Export elasticity r) 2J Table 5.A.4 Consumer parameters for dynamic analyses Entrepr. cl Entrepr. c2 Workers w Substitution parameter y, Private goods share a ci Leisure share a,, Public good share a Gi Substitution parameter y ci Share composite good 1 a n Share composite good 2 a 2l Substitution parameter y cli Share domestic good 1 a dn Share foreign good 1 a fn Substitution parameter y c2i Share domestic good 2 a d2l Share foreign good 2 a. pi Numerical strength A', Political influence weight /^,

47 232 Chapter 5 Table 5.A.5 Typology of dynamic analyses description abbrev. sect. change Initial situation Political influence Preferences of workers Preferences of workers and political influence Production technique sector 1 Production technique sector 1 and political influence Foresight government Foresight government and political influence initial influence preference pref. + infl. technique tech. + infl. foresight fore. + infl ^1=0.02,^=0.02,^= a c%v = 0.40,a ]w = 0.25,«Gw = a cw = 0.40,a lw = 0.25,a Gw = 0.35 /i cl =0.025,jt c2 =0.025,/x w = <5 L1 =0.30,Ô K1 =0.30,Ô GI = ô L1 =0.30,ô K1 =0.30,<5 G1 =0.40 /x cl =0.16,^=0.04,^= p= /o = 1.00 l* cl =0.025,fi c2 =0.025,^=0.95 Table 5.A.6 Effects on capital and shadowprice of capital K, K 2 K s Kp q. = <h q P = q s initial influence preferences pref. + infl technique tech.+ infl foresight fore.+ infl equal to the parameter values that were presented in Section 4.5. The producer and consumer parameters used as a base case for all dynamic analyses are presented in Table 5.A.3 and Table 5.A.4, respectively. Table 5.A.5 summarizes the different dynamic analyses. It shows in which section the different investigations are discussed, and it gives the exact parameter changes that are used to generate the different shocks. For a convenient presentation of the transition paths, these paths are for most variables presented in relative deviations from the initial values. In this Appendix the steady state values are presented for both the initial steady state and for the end steady state of all parameter changes that are analyzed. These steady state results can be found in Tables 5.A.6-5.A.10.

48 Redistribution and public consumption 233 Table 5.A.7 Effects on labor demand and leisure L, U L s Lp 'el z* L initial influence preferences pref. + infl technique tech. + infl foresight fore.+ infl Table 5.A.8 Effects on production and commodity prices x, X 2 G s Gp Pi P 2 initial influence preferences pref. + infl technique tech.+ infl foresight fore.+ infl Table 5.A.9 Effects on special provisions and utility»cl "a ffw u cl u c2 u w initial influence preferences pref. + infl technique tech.+ infl foresight fore.+ infl

49 234 Chapter 5 Table 5.A. 10 Effects on dividends, wage rate, taxes and value of political interest function d, d 2 PL Th T P initial influence preferences pref. + infl technique tech.+ infl foresight fore. + infl

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Technical Analysis in Financial Markets Griffioen, G.A.W. Link to publication

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Technical Analysis in Financial Markets Griffioen, G.A.W. Link to publication UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Technical Analysis in Financial Markets Griffioen, G.A.W. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Griffioen, G. A. W. (2003). Technical Analysis

More information

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Essays in pension economics and intergenerational risk sharing Vos, S.J. Link to publication

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Essays in pension economics and intergenerational risk sharing Vos, S.J. Link to publication UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Essays in pension economics and intergenerational risk sharing Vos, S.J. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Vos, S. J. (2012). Essays in pension

More information

Understanding the complex dynamics of financial markets through microsimulation Qiu, G.

Understanding the complex dynamics of financial markets through microsimulation Qiu, G. UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Understanding the complex dynamics of financial markets through microsimulation Qiu, G. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Qiu, G. (211). Understanding

More information

The impact of institutional investors on equity markets and their liquidity Dezelan, S.

The impact of institutional investors on equity markets and their liquidity Dezelan, S. UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) The impact of institutional investors on equity markets and their liquidity Dezelan, S. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Dezelan, S. (2001).

More information

Citation for published version (APA): du Toit, C. P. (1999). Beneficial Ownership of Royalties in Bilateral Tax Treaties Amsterdam: IBFD

Citation for published version (APA): du Toit, C. P. (1999). Beneficial Ownership of Royalties in Bilateral Tax Treaties Amsterdam: IBFD UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Beneficial Ownership of Royalties in Bilateral Tax Treaties du Toit, C.P. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): du Toit, C. P. (1999). Beneficial

More information

Consequences of success in pediatrics: young adults with disability benefits as a result of chronic conditions since childhood Verhoof, Eefje

Consequences of success in pediatrics: young adults with disability benefits as a result of chronic conditions since childhood Verhoof, Eefje UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Consequences of success in pediatrics: young adults with disability benefits as a result of chronic conditions since childhood Verhoof, Eefje Link to publication

More information

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository)

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Response from IBFD Research Staff to: Clarification of the Meaning of 'Beneficial Owner' in the OECD Model Tax Convention van Boeijen-Ostaszewska, A.; de Goede, J.;

More information

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Het sociaal plan van der Hulst, J. Link to publication

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Het sociaal plan van der Hulst, J. Link to publication UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Het sociaal plan van der Hulst, J. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): van der Hulst, J. (1999). Het sociaal plan Deventer: Kluwer General rights

More information

Citation for published version (APA): van Dijk, D. W. (2019). Commercial and residential real estate market liquidity.

Citation for published version (APA): van Dijk, D. W. (2019). Commercial and residential real estate market liquidity. UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Commercial and residential real estate market liquidity van Dijk, D.W. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): van Dijk, D. W. (2019). Commercial

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

Citation for published version (APA): du Toit, C. P. (1999). Beneficial Ownership of Royalties in Bilateral Tax Treaties Amsterdam: IBFD

Citation for published version (APA): du Toit, C. P. (1999). Beneficial Ownership of Royalties in Bilateral Tax Treaties Amsterdam: IBFD UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Beneficial Ownership of Royalties in Bilateral Tax Treaties du Toit, C.P. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): du Toit, C. P. (1999). Beneficial

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 4

Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 4 Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 4 Due May 6th (Friday), in-class 1. Two countries, Richland and Poorland, are described by the Solow growth model. They have the same Cobb Douglas production function,,

More information

Optimal Progressivity

Optimal Progressivity Optimal Progressivity To this point, we have assumed that all individuals are the same. To consider the distributional impact of the tax system, we will have to alter that assumption. We have seen that

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first introduce and discuss the intertemporal budget

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

News media and the stock market: Assessing mutual relationships Strauß, N.

News media and the stock market: Assessing mutual relationships Strauß, N. UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) News media and the stock market: Assessing mutual relationships Strauß, N. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Strauß, N. (2018). News media

More information

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS University of Victoria Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS Martin Farnham Problem Set #5 Note: Answer each question as clearly and concisely as possible. Use of diagrams, where appropriate, is strongly

More information

Appendix: Numerical Model

Appendix: Numerical Model Appendix to: Costs of Alternative Environmental Policy Instruments in the Presence of Industry Compensation Requirements A. Lans Bovenberg Lawrence H. Goulder Mark R. Jacobsen Appendix: Numerical Model

More information

Essays on markets over random networks and learning in Continuous Double Auctions van de Leur, M.C.W.

Essays on markets over random networks and learning in Continuous Double Auctions van de Leur, M.C.W. UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Essays on markets over random networks and learning in Continuous Double Auctions van de Leur, M.C.W. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): van

More information

1 Excess burden of taxation

1 Excess burden of taxation 1 Excess burden of taxation 1. In a competitive economy without externalities (and with convex preferences and production technologies) we know from the 1. Welfare Theorem that there exists a decentralized

More information

The sources of EU law and their relationships: Lessons for the field of taxation Szudoczky, R.

The sources of EU law and their relationships: Lessons for the field of taxation Szudoczky, R. UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) The sources of EU law and their relationships: Lessons for the field of taxation Szudoczky, R. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Szudoczky,

More information

Problems. the net marginal product of capital, MP'

Problems. the net marginal product of capital, MP' Problems 1. There are two effects of an increase in the depreciation rate. First, there is the direct effect, which implies that, given the marginal product of capital in period two, MP, the net marginal

More information

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations 19.1: Introduction This chapter is interesting and important. It also helps to answer a question you may well have been asking ever since we studied quasi-linear

More information

Alan A. Powell Keith R. McLaren Ken R. Pearson Maureen T. Rimmer

Alan A. Powell Keith R. McLaren Ken R. Pearson Maureen T. Rimmer Cobb-Douglas Douglas-Eventually! Alan A. Powell Keith R. McLaren Ken R. Pearson Maureen T. Rimmer Monash University TOPICS COVERED IN PAPER historical review of directly additive preferences (LES) Engel

More information

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Robert J. Barro 1990 Represented by m.sefidgaran & m.m.banasaz Graduate School of Management and Economics Sharif university of Technology 11/17/2013

More information

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box Paolo Crosetto paolo.crosetto@unimi.it DEAS - University of Milan Exercises solved in class on March 15th, 2010 Recap: pure exchange The simplest model of a general equilibrium

More information

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade. Product Di erentiation Introduction We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade. Now we see how product di erentiation can provide a basis for trade due to consumers valuing

More information

Citation for published version (APA): Jonker, N. (2001). Job performance and career prospects of auditors Amsterdam: Tinbergen Instituut

Citation for published version (APA): Jonker, N. (2001). Job performance and career prospects of auditors Amsterdam: Tinbergen Instituut UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Job performance and career prospects of auditors Jonker, N. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Jonker, N. (2001). Job performance and career

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

1. Introduction. 1 MIMIC stands for MIcro Macro model to analyze the Institutional Context.

1. Introduction. 1 MIMIC stands for MIcro Macro model to analyze the Institutional Context. 1. Introduction Many European countries suffer from high structural unemployment, especially among the unskilled. Various reforms of labor-market institutions and the tax and social insurance systems have

More information

A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax

A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax Michael Smart Department of Economics University of Toronto June 30, 1998 Abstract This note reviews the problems inherent in using the sum of compensating

More information

Comments on Michael Woodford, Globalization and Monetary Control

Comments on Michael Woodford, Globalization and Monetary Control David Romer University of California, Berkeley June 2007 Revised, August 2007 Comments on Michael Woodford, Globalization and Monetary Control General Comments This is an excellent paper. The issue it

More information

Main Features. Aid, Public Investment, and pro-poor Growth Policies. Session 4 An Operational Macroeconomic Framework for Ethiopia

Main Features. Aid, Public Investment, and pro-poor Growth Policies. Session 4 An Operational Macroeconomic Framework for Ethiopia Aid, Public Investment, and pro-poor Growth Policies Addis Ababa, August 16-19, 2004 Session 4 An Operational Macroeconomic Framework for Ethiopia Pierre-Richard Agénor Main features. Public capital and

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Article published in the Quarterly Review 2014:2, pp

Article published in the Quarterly Review 2014:2, pp Estimating the Cyclically Adjusted Budget Balance Article published in the Quarterly Review 2014:2, pp. 59-66 BOX 6: ESTIMATING THE CYCLICALLY ADJUSTED BUDGET BALANCE 1 In the wake of the financial crisis,

More information

Aggregate Supply and Demand

Aggregate Supply and Demand Aggregate demand is the relationship between GDP and the price level. When only the price level changes, GDP changes and we move along the Aggregate Demand curve. The total amount of goods and services,

More information

Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation

Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation Optimal income taxation is quite a different problem than optimal commodity taxation. In optimal commodity taxation the issue was which commodities to tax,

More information

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy, Tufts University 2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross E212 Macroeconomics Prof. George Alogoskoufis Consumer Spending

More information

Preferences and Utility

Preferences and Utility Preferences and Utility PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University 1 Axioms of Rational Choice Completeness If A and B are any two situations, an individual can always

More information

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

1. Money in the utility function (continued) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (continued) a. Welfare costs of in ation b. Potential non-superneutrality

More information

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 26/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case

More information

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far.

More information

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 1 Imperfect Credibility of Policy: Trade Reform 1.1 Model Assumptions Output is exogenous constant endowment (y), not useful for consumption, but can be exported

More information

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

We will make several assumptions about these preferences: Lecture 5 Consumer Behavior PREFERENCES The Digital Economist In taking a closer at market behavior, we need to examine the underlying motivations and constraints affecting the consumer (or households).

More information

A term structure model of interest rates and forward premia: an alternative monetary approach Daal, W.H.

A term structure model of interest rates and forward premia: an alternative monetary approach Daal, W.H. UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) A term structure model of interest rates and forward premia: an alternative monetary approach Daal, W.H. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA):

More information

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Class Notes on Chaney (2008) Class Notes on Chaney (2008) (With Krugman and Melitz along the Way) Econ 840-T.Holmes Model of Chaney AER (2008) As a first step, let s write down the elements of the Chaney model. asymmetric countries

More information

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth The analysis of why some countries have achieved a high and rising standard of living, while others have

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality Lecture 5 Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H Summary of Lectures, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality 2 Summary of Lecture 4: Consumption theory 2. Preference orders 2.2 The utility function

More information

A Graphical Exposition of the GTAP Model

A Graphical Exposition of the GTAP Model A Graphical Exposition of the GTAP Model by Martina BROCKMEIER GTAP Technical Paper No. 8 October 1996 Minor Edits, January 2000 Revised, March 2001 BROCKMEIER is with the Institute of Agricultural Economics,

More information

Chapter 3. National Income: Where it Comes from and Where it Goes

Chapter 3. National Income: Where it Comes from and Where it Goes ECONOMY IN THE LONG RUN Chapter 3 National Income: Where it Comes from and Where it Goes 1 QUESTIONS ABOUT THE SOURCES AND USES OF GDP Here we develop a static classical model of the macroeconomy: prices

More information

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository)

UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Rechtskarakter en financiering van de cooperatie : een onderzoek naar de civielrechtelijke kenmerken van de cooperatie in het licht van de vraag of daaruit beperkingen

More information

Paying the medical specialist: the eternal puzzle : experiments in the Netherlands Mot, E.S.

Paying the medical specialist: the eternal puzzle : experiments in the Netherlands Mot, E.S. UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Paying the medical specialist: the eternal puzzle : experiments in the Netherlands Mot, E.S. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Mot, E. S.

More information

Citation for published version (APA): Oosterhof, C. M. (2006). Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging s.n.

Citation for published version (APA): Oosterhof, C. M. (2006). Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging s.n. University of Groningen Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging Oosterhof, Casper Martijn IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish

More information

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics Spring - 2005 Trade and Development Instructions (For students electing Macro (8701) & New Trade Theory (8702) option) Identify yourself

More information

Chapter Four. Utility Functions. Utility Functions. Utility Functions. Utility

Chapter Four. Utility Functions. Utility Functions. Utility Functions. Utility Functions Chapter Four A preference relation that is complete, reflexive, transitive and continuous can be represented by a continuous utility function. Continuity means that small changes to a consumption

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

Lecture 7. The consumer s problem(s) Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2018 Last updated: April 28, 2018

Lecture 7. The consumer s problem(s) Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2018 Last updated: April 28, 2018 Lecture 7 The consumer s problem(s) Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2018 Last updated: April 28, 2018 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents 1. Introducing

More information

Chapter 11: Cost Minimisation and the Demand for Factors

Chapter 11: Cost Minimisation and the Demand for Factors Chapter 11: Cost Minimisation and the Demand for Factors 11.1: Introduction We assume a very simple objective for firms namely, that they want to maximise profits 1. We will explore the implications of

More information

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics June. - 2011 Trade, Development and Growth For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option Instructions

More information

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices : Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices (2008, AER) December 5 th, 2008 Empirical motivation US PPI-based RER is highly volatile Under PPP, this should induce a high volatility

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies Prepared on behalf of the Organization for International Investment June 2015 (Page intentionally left

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 3 & 4

Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 3 & 4 Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 3 & 4 Due May 4th (Friday), in-class 1. In this chapter we saw that the steady-state rate of unemployment is U/L = s/(s + f ). Suppose that the unemployment rate

More information

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income 1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income Until now, we have assumed that government policy is exogenously given, so the government had a very passive role. Its only concern was balancing the intertemporal budget.

More information

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1 Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak Lecture 1 Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Demand Utility Maximization Problem Expenditure Minimization Problem Mathematical Theory of Production Profit Maximization

More information

CHAPTER 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

CHAPTER 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes CHAPTER 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes A PowerPoint Tutorial To Accompany MACROECONOMICS, 7th. Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Tutorial written by: Mannig J. Simidian B.A. in Economics

More information

3. Consumer Behavior

3. Consumer Behavior 3. Consumer Behavior References: Pindyck und Rubinfeld, Chapter 3 Varian, Chapter 2, 3, 4 25.04.2017 Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation Microeconomics Chapter 3

More information

The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role. of Fiscal Policy Revisited

The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role. of Fiscal Policy Revisited The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role of Fiscal Policy Revisited Santanu Chatterjee y Department of Economics University of Georgia Sugata Ghosh z Department of Economics and Finance

More information

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD European Economic Review 42 (1998) 887 895 The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD Philip R. Lane *, Roberto Perotti Economics Department, Trinity College Dublin, Dublin 2, Ireland Columbia University,

More information

Earnings quality and earnings management : the role of accounting accruals Bissessur, S.W.

Earnings quality and earnings management : the role of accounting accruals Bissessur, S.W. UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Earnings quality and earnings management : the role of accounting accruals Bissessur, S.W. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Bissessur, S.

More information

Utility Maximization and Choice

Utility Maximization and Choice Utility Maximization and Choice PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University 1 Utility Maximization and Choice Complaints about the Economic Approach Do individuals make

More information

Brita Bye, Birger Strøm and Turid Åvitsland

Brita Bye, Birger Strøm and Turid Åvitsland Discussion Papers No. 343, March 2003 Statistics Norway, Research Department Brita Bye, Birger Strøm and Turid Åvitsland Welfare effects of VAT reforms: A general equilibrium analysis Abstract: Indirect

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Policy, 8/2 206 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal behavior and steady-state

More information

Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation: Pigou, Taxation, and Pollution

Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation: Pigou, Taxation, and Pollution Tufts University From the SelectedWorks of Gilbert E. Metcalf 2002 Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation: Pigou, Taxation, and Pollution Gilbert E. Metcalf, Tufts University Available at: https://works.bepress.com/gilbert_metcalf/8/

More information

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom WP//8 Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom Dennis Botman and Keiko Honjo International Monetary Fund WP//8 IMF Working Paper European Department and Fiscal Affairs Department Options

More information

Exercise 3 Short Run Determination of Output, the Interest Rate, the Exchange Rate and the Current Account in a Mundell Fleming Model

Exercise 3 Short Run Determination of Output, the Interest Rate, the Exchange Rate and the Current Account in a Mundell Fleming Model Fletcher School, Tufts University Exercise 3 Short Run Determination of Output, the Interest Rate, the Exchange Rate and the Current Account in a Mundell Fleming Model E212 Macroeconomics Prof. George

More information

Subject Index. Bankruptcy costs, See also Leverage-related

Subject Index. Bankruptcy costs, See also Leverage-related Subject Index Accelerated depreciation, 262-63 Adjusted gross income (AGI), 24-26, 141 Adjustment cost function, 285-86 After-tax wage, nonconstancy of, 48 Age-asset profile, 469 Aid for Dependent Children

More information

Chapter URL:

Chapter URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Effect of Education on Efficiency in Consumption Volume Author/Editor: Robert T. Michael

More information

The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Tax Revenue Elasticity

The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Tax Revenue Elasticity Department of Economics Working Paper Series The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Tax Revenue Elasticity John Creedy & Norman Gemmell October 2010 Research Paper Number 1110 ISSN: 0819 2642 ISBN: 978

More information

New Trade Theory I. Part A: Simple monopolistic competition model. Robert Stehrer. The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw

New Trade Theory I. Part A: Simple monopolistic competition model. Robert Stehrer. The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw Part A: Simple monopolistic competition model The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw May 15, 217 Introduction 1 Classical models 1 Explanations based on technology and/or factor

More information

THE KEYNESIAN MODEL IN THE SHORT AND LONG RUN

THE KEYNESIAN MODEL IN THE SHORT AND LONG RUN Lecture: THE KENESIAN MODEL IN THE SHORT AND LONG RUN In the short run actual GDP,, may be lower or higher or equal to full-employment GDP,. The aim of the Keynesian model in the short run is to explain

More information

PRACTICE QUESTIONS CHAPTER 5

PRACTICE QUESTIONS CHAPTER 5 CECN 104 PRACTICE QUESTIONS CHAPTER 5 1. Marginal utility is the: A. sensitivity of consumer purchases of a good to changes in the price of that good. B. change in total utility realized by consuming one

More information

Trade and Development

Trade and Development Trade and Development Table of Contents 2.2 Growth theory revisited a) Post Keynesian Growth Theory the Harrod Domar Growth Model b) Structural Change Models the Lewis Model c) Neoclassical Growth Theory

More information

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization Copyright 2002 Pearson Education, Inc. and Dr Yunus Aksoy Slide 1 Discussion So far: How to measure variables of macroeconomic

More information

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Journal of Economic Integration 20(4), December 2005; 631-643 Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Noritsugu Nakanishi Kobe University Toru Kikuchi Kobe University

More information

Financial Structure and Monetary Transmission in Europe: A Cross-Country Study de Bondt, G.J.

Financial Structure and Monetary Transmission in Europe: A Cross-Country Study de Bondt, G.J. UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Financial Structure and Monetary Transmission in Europe: A Cross-Country Study de Bondt, G.J. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): de Bondt,

More information

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Matthias Doepke UCLA Martin Schneider NYU and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Abstract This paper shows that a zero-sum redistribution

More information

Do Not Write Below Question Maximum Possible Points Score Total Points = 100

Do Not Write Below Question Maximum Possible Points Score Total Points = 100 University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2012 Ajaz Hussain TEST 2 SOLUTIONS TIME: 1 HOUR AND 50 MINUTES YOU CANNOT LEAVE THE EXAM ROOM DURING THE LAST 10 MINUTES OF THE TEST. PLEASE

More information

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand Economics 101 Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand 1 Intro First, a note on wealth and endowment. Varian generally uses wealth (m) instead of endowment. Ultimately, these two are equivalent. Given prices p, if

More information

Methods Examination (Macro Part) Spring Please answer all the four questions below. The exam has 100 points.

Methods Examination (Macro Part) Spring Please answer all the four questions below. The exam has 100 points. Methods Examination (Macro Part) Spring 2006 Please answer all the four questions below. The exam has 100 points. 1) Infinite Horizon Economy with Durables, Money, and Taxes (Total 40 points) Consider

More information

Environmental Policy in the Presence of an. Informal Sector

Environmental Policy in the Presence of an. Informal Sector Environmental Policy in the Presence of an Informal Sector Antonio Bento, Mark Jacobsen, and Antung A. Liu DRAFT November 2011 Abstract This paper demonstrates how the presence of an untaxed informal sector

More information

The Welfare Cost of Inflation. in the Presence of Inside Money

The Welfare Cost of Inflation. in the Presence of Inside Money 1 The Welfare Cost of Inflation in the Presence of Inside Money Scott Freeman, Espen R. Henriksen, and Finn E. Kydland In this paper, we ask what role an endogenous money multiplier plays in the estimated

More information

Optimal tax and transfer policy

Optimal tax and transfer policy Optimal tax and transfer policy (non-linear income taxes and redistribution) March 2, 2016 Non-linear taxation I So far we have considered linear taxes on consumption, labour income and capital income

More information

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS OF FLORIDA AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS TO CUBA

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS OF FLORIDA AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS TO CUBA GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS OF FLORIDA AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS TO CUBA Michael O Connell The Trade Sanctions Reform and Export Enhancement Act of 2000 liberalized the export policy of the United States with

More information

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2009/10/2 (Lecture 4, Micro Theory I) 1 The Consumer Problem We have some powerful tools: Constrained Maximization (Shadow Prices) Envelope

More information

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1 University of California, Merced EC 121-Money and Banking Chapter 5 Lecture otes Professor Jason Lee I. Introduction Figure 1 shows the interest rates for 3 month treasury bills. As evidenced by the figure,

More information

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley Theoretical Tools of Public Finance 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley 1 THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL TOOLS Theoretical tools: The set of tools designed to understand the mechanics

More information

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction Philippe Aghion Antonin Bergeaud Timo Boppart Peter J Klenow Huiyu Li January 17, 2017 A1 Heterogeneous elasticities and varying markups In

More information

Principle of targeting in environmental taxation

Principle of targeting in environmental taxation Principle of targeting in environmental taxation Firouz Gahvari Department of Economics University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Urbana, IL 61801, USA November 2010 I thank Luca Micheletto for his careful

More information