October 10, Abstract

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "October 10, Abstract"

Transcription

1 R M F P : R C T Giorgio Motta Raffaele Rossi October 10, 2014 Abstract We study Ramsey monetary and fiscal policy in a New-Keynesian model with endogenous government spending, state-noncontingent public debt and distortive taxation. The fiscal authority has access to consumption taxation, in addition to labour income taxation. The contribution of this paper is twofold. First, we characterize analytically the steady-state optimal provision of public goods. We show that this depends on the agents risk aversion, the steady state level of public debt and on the tax instrument adopted. We proof that the optimal size of the public spending is, ceteris paribus, greater under consumption taxation than under labour income tax. Furthermore, if the agents risk aversion is suffi ciently high and the policy-maker can tax consumption, the optimal public spending to GDP ratio is increasing in the long run level of public debt. Second, in the stochastic equilibrium, movements in consumption taxation have non-trivial effects on the agents intertemporal allocation. In turn, the dynamic properties of consumption taxation enable the policy-maker to affect the stochastic discount factor via modifications of the marginal utility of consumption. This extra wedge impacts on the pricing decisions of firms, and hence on inflation stabilization, and greatly improves welfare. Keywords: Ramsey policy, Optimal public spending, Consumption tax, Distortionary taxation, Public debt. JEL: E30, E61, E62. We are grateful to Emanuele Bracco, Stefano Gnocchi, Sarolta Laczò, Dmitry Matveev, Monika Mertz, and Maurizio Zanardi for their comments on a early version of the paper. Furthermore, we benefit from discussions with Michela Cella, Andrea Colciago, Davide Debortoli and Nick Snowden, as well as seminar participants at the Bank of England, University of Milano-Bicocca, University of Durham, University of Vienna, University of Liverpool, University of Lancaster, the 2014 T2M conference in Lausanne, the 2013 CEF conference in Vancouver and the 2014 EEA meeting in Toulouse. All errors are our own. Department of Economics, Lancaster University Management School, LA1 4XY, United Kingdom. g.motta@lancaster.ac.uk Department of Economics, Lancaster University Management School, LA1 4XY, United Kingdom. r.rossi@lancaster.ac.uk 1

2 1 Introduction Most of the literature on Ramsey monetary and fiscal policy, e.g. Benigno and Woodford (2003), Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004, 2007), Adam (2011) and Leith and Wren-Lewis (2014), rules out consumption taxation, a policy instrument which is widely used in most industrialised economies. In 2013, for example, the value-added tax on standard items ranged from 15 to 27 percent in all European Union countries. Exceptions include Correia, Nicolini and Teles (2008), who find that in a New-Keynesian model with labour income and consumption taxes, the equilibrium allocations are independent of the degree of price stickiness. More recently, Correia, Farhi, Nicolini and Teles (2013) and Farhi, Gopinath and Itskhoki (2014), stress the role of consumption taxation as a tool to relax a constraint on monetary policy on the nominal interest rate, either as a result of the zero lower bound or when a country is locked in a monetary union. Our paper is closely related and contributes to this literature by highlighting two features of consumption taxation in the context of optimal monetary and fiscal policy. First, we study the role of consumption taxation alongside or as alternative to labor income taxation in shaping the optimal provision of public goods. Second, we analyze the interactions between monetary policy, inflation stabilization, public debt and consumption taxation. In our theoretical model we add a fiscal policy block to a standard closed-economy, stickyprice, cashless DSGE framework, similar to the workhorse model in e.g. Clarida, Galí and Gertler (1999) or Woodford (2003). Public consumption generates utility as in, inter alia, Galí and Monacelli (2008), Adam (2011) and Debortoli and Nunes (2011). All these contributions exclude consumption taxes. As in Correia, Nicolini and Teles (2008) and Correia, Farhi, Nicolini and Teles (2013), the fiscal authority has access to labour income taxes, consumption taxes and state-noncontingent public debt. However, unlike in our paper, they treat government spending as exogenous. More over, like most of the New-Keynesian literature, we abstract from capital accumulation. This modeling approach is particularly convenient as it allows us to better compare our results to previous analyzes and, perhaps more importantly, to obtain a set of original analytical results. The economic environment considered in this paper features three ineffi ciencies. First, firms have market power in the good markets so that they can charge a mark-up over marginal costs. This causes output to be ineffi ciently low. Second, sticky prices in the good market prevent prices from fully adjusting after a shock shocks. As a consequence, the aggregate supply is positively sloped (at least in the short run) and demand-side policies have real allocation effects. Third, fiscal policy uses distortionary taxation to finance public spending and interest payments on outstanding government debt. Hence fiscal policy has additional 2

3 negative consequences on the economic activity. In turn, as we will discuss in details later, this model generates several channels for which there exist interesting interactions between monetary and fiscal policy instruments. Our analysis is comprised of two parts. In the first one, we study optimal policy in the steady state. In the second one, we analyze optimal stabilization policies during an unexpected economic recession. Regarding the analysis of the optimal steady state, we can summarize our results as follows. First, we re-state the traditional result of optimal zero steady state inflation, e.g. Benigno and Woodford (2003). Then, we study analytically the optimal provision of public goods. More precisely, we analyze the optimal size of government consumption relative to total output. By setting a certain ratio of government spending to GDP, the Ramsey Planner can influence private sector behavior and therefore can reduce ineffi ciency and increase welfare. We show that the incentive for the Ramsey Planner to increase the government spending to GDP ratio increases with the households risk aversion. Furthermore we explore how the optimal size of government spending depends on whether consumption or labor income is taxed and on the level of outstanding public debt. We find that under consumption taxation the optimal share of government spending is, ceteris paribus, always larger then under labor income taxation. Then, we proof that when the agents risk aversion is suffi ciently high and the policy-maker can tax consumption, the optimal public spending to GDP ratio is increasing in the long run level of public debt. Furthermore, we find that taxing consumption allows the policy-maker to achieve higher levels of welfare. This is obtained despite the fact that in our model, due to the absence of capital accumulation, the equilibrium consumption tax base is in general smaller than labour income tax base. We also show that the superiority of consumption taxation is only marginally affected by different degrees of labour supply elasticity and it is robust to the introduction of full profit taxation. This results extend, in a New-Keynesian environment with endogenous government spending, the literature on the superiority of consumption taxation. For example, in a standard RBC model with capital accumulation, Colemann (2000) finds that replacing income taxes with consumption taxes would lead to large welfare gains compared to the existing tax system in the United States. Correia (2010) extends this result to a heterogeneous agents framework. Laczo and Rossi (2014) show that taxing consumption leads to large welfare gains even when the policy-maker is unable to commit to future policies. In the second part of the paper, we analyze the dynamic behavior of the economy under technology shocks. With a steady-state level of public debt (assets), interest rate movements will affect the return on government bonds and hence have budgetary consequences. In other words, unlike in the standard New-Keynesian model without fiscal policy, there are costs 3

4 associated with movements in the monetary policy instrument so that the Euler equation becomes a relevant constraint for the optimal policy. In turn, movements of consumption tax will affect, not only the leisure-consumption margin, but also the stochastic discount factor (via modification of the marginal utility of consumption in the Euler equation). This effect directly impacts on how agents discount future profits, and hence on firms price setting decisions. Hence the policy-maker can effectively stabilize inflation with an appropriate use of consumption taxation. We find that this extra wedge helps the stabilization of the economy and greatly increases welfare in the stochastic equilibrium when compared to the standard scenario where only labor income taxes are available. Ceteris paribus, the welfare gains of taxing consumption are larger, the stronger the interaction between monetary and fiscal policy, i.e. the higher the steady state level of public debt (assets). This second part of the paper contributes to the literature that stresses the role of consumption taxation as an unconventional instrument for monetary policy. With a transmission mechanism similar to our, Correia, Farhi, Nicolini and Teles (2013) show that when the nominal interest rate is zero, the policy-maker can use consumption taxation as demand managment tool, and hence unwind the negative effects of the zero lower bound. Similarly, Farhi, Gopinath and Itskhoki (2014) show that consumption taxation can be use as monetary policy instrument when a small open economy joins a monetary union. The goal of the paper is twofold. First, it wishes to contribute to the policy debate about the best (or rather the less distortive) way to finance, both in the long-run and along the business cycle, the increase in government spending and in the burden of public debt that the recent economic crisis brought about in most OECD countries. Second, it derives a set of analytical conditions to characterize the optimal provisions of public goods. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up the model. Section 3 presents the optimal policy exercises. Section 4 concludes. 2 The Model We add a fiscal policy block to the standard sticky-price cashless DSGE framework, similar to the workhorse model in e.g. Clarida et al. (1999) or Woodford (2003). Public consumption has intrinsic value for the agents as in Bohn (1992), Galí and Monacelli (2008), Leith, Moldovan and Rossi (2009) and Adam (2011). Government spending must be financed with linear labor income and/or consumption taxes. Lump-sum taxes or transfer are ruled out. We restrict public nominal debt to be of one-period maturity and to be state-noncontingent as in Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004) and Correia, Nicolini and Teles (2008). 4

5 Besides presenting the model ingredients, this section derives the implementability constraints characterizing optimal private sector behavior, i.e., it derives the optimality conditions determining households consumption and labor supply decisions, firms price setting decisions, as well as the government s budget constraint. 2.1 Private Sector Households We consider a continuum over [0, 1] of infinitely-lived households with preferences E 0 t=0 β t u (c t, h t, g t ), (1) where β is the discount factor, c t represents individual consumption, h t denotes hours worked and g t is government spending. E t identifies the rational expectations operator. We impose that utility is separable in its three arguments and u c > 0, u cc < 0, u g > 0, u gg < 0, u h < 0 and u hh 0, where u x defines the derivative of the utility function with respect to the generic variable x. Furthermore, we assume homothetic preferences over public and private consumption, so that gugg u g = cucc u c. There is a continuum of goods, indexed by i. Each i good enters with the same weight in the Dixit-Stiglitz aggregator. This can be written as [ 1 c t = 0 (c i,t ) η 1 η ] η η 1 di ; i [0, 1], (2) where η (1, ) is the price elasticity for differentiated goods, while the aggregate consumption price index is Hence, the demand for good i follows [ 1 P t = 0 ] 1 1 η P 1 η i,t di. (3) ( ) η Pi,t c i,t = c t. (4) P t In each period households maximize (1) subject to the following budget constraint P t c t (1 + τ c t) + R 1 t B t+1 + E t Λ t,t+1 Q t+1 = B t + Q t + P t d t + P t w t h t ( 1 τ h t ). (5) 5

6 In each time period t, households can purchase any desired state-contingent nominal payment Q t+1 in period t+1 at the dollar cost E t Λ t,t+1 Q t+1. The variable Λ t,t+1 denotes the stochastic discount factor between period t and t + 1. Here the only role of state-contingent securities is to define state-contingent prices. We assume that state-contingent claims are in zero net supply. Real dividends on firms profits are denoted by d t, while B t is the quantity of risk-less nominal bonds purchased in period t at price Rt 1 and paying one unit of the consumption numeraire at period t + 1. Taxes on consumption and labor income are, respectively, τ c t and τ h t, and w t is the real wage. The solution for the optimizing household problem is standard and can be written as: u c,t = λ t (1 + τ c t), (6) where λ t stands for the Lagrangian multiplier associated with this program. Labor supply is determined by while the Euler equation is u c,t 1 + τ c t u ( ) h,t 1 τ h = w t t u c,t (1 + τ c t), (7) = βe t [ u c,t+1 ( 1 + τ c t+1 ) R t π t+1 ], (8) where π t = Pt P t 1 is the gross inflation rate. The stochastic discount factor is defined as u E t Λ t,t+1 = βe c,t+1 t P t+1, and absence of arbitrage profits in the asset markets implies that E t Λ t,t+1 = R 1 t. P t (1+τ c t ) u c,t (1+τ c t+1) Firms A generic good i is produced in a monopolistically competitive market with technology y i,t = a t h i,t, (9) where a t is a common exogenous technology process. Firm i s real marginal costs are: mc t = w t a t. (10) 6

7 We assume that firms, when resetting their prices, incur in quadratic adjustment costs a lá Rotemberg (1983), i.e., where ϕ represents the degree of price stickiness. problem can be expressed as ( ) 2 ϕ 2 P Pi,t+s t 1, (11) P i,t+s 1 The profit maximizing generic firm i s + ( ) [ ( ) max E t β s uc,t+s (1 + τ c t) Pit+s y it+s y {P i,t } u s=0 c,t (1 + τ c it+s w t+s ϕ ( ) ] 2 Pi,t+s 1 t+s) P t+s a t+s 2 P i,t+s 1 ( ) η Pi,t+s s.t. y i,t+s = y t+s. P t+s We focus on the symmetric equilibrium in which P it = P t holds. Therefore, substituting for mc t, the condition for optimal pricing decision is {[ ] } u c,t+1 (1 + τ c [(1 η) a t + ηw t ] (h t ) ϕ (π t 1) (π t ) + ϕβe t) t ( ) (π u c,t 1 + τ c t+1 1) (π t+1 ) = 0. t+1 (12) 2.2 Government Sector Macroeconomic policies are implemented by two authorities. There is a Central Bank which sets the nominal interest rates on short-term nominal bonds. Furthermore, there is a government choosing the level of public expenditures, labor income tax, consumption tax and public debt. The government finances current expenditure by raising linear labor income and consumption taxes and by issuing new one-period state-noncontingent debt, i.e., b t π t + g t = b t+1 R t + w t h t τ h t + c t τ c t. (13) The fiscal authority credibly commits to repaying its debt. In what follows we assume that government debt and tax policies are such that the no-ponzi constraint lim s + E t [( t+s 1 i=0 ) ] 1 B t+s = 0, (14) R i 7

8 and the transversality condition are both satisfied. [ ( lim β t+s uc,t+s s τ c t+s ) Bt+s P t+s ] = 0, (15) 2.3 Aggregation In the symmetric equilibrium h it = h t. Hence, the economy-wide production function is y t = a t h t. (16) Furthermore, using the household s budget constraint, we can obtain the expression for aggregate profits as d t = a t h t w t h t ϕ 2 (π t 1) 2. (17) Combining the government budget constraint, the definition of profits and the households budget constraint, one can obtain the aggregate resource constraint as y t = a t h t = c t + g t + ϕ 2 (π t 1) 2. (18) With this set of structural equations at hand, we are now ready to define the model s rational expectations equilibrium. Definition 1 (Rational Expectations Equilibrium) A Rational Expectations Equilibrium (REE) is defined by a sequence of private sector decisions {c t, y, h t, w t, π t } t=0 and economic policies { } τ h t 1, τ c t 1, R t 1, g t, b t+1 that, given the initial level of public debt b 0 and the evolution of technology, solves equations (7), (8), (12), (13), (14), (15), t=0 (16), and (18). 3 Ramsey Policy Our policy exercise starts by defining the effi cient allocation within the model. Definition 2 (Social Planner s Program) The Social Planner s Program defines the first best allocation and consists in choosing {c t, h t, gt } t=0 taking as given the technology process {a t } t=0, in order to maximize the utility function of households as in (1) subject to the constraints imposed by the production technology. 8

9 Proposition 1 The Social Planner s allocation is (u c,t ) = (u h,t) = (u g,t ) (19) a t Proof. See Appendix. In the first best equilibrium the marginal utilities of private and public consumption must equate the marginal disutility of labor, where the latter is scaled by total productivity. This simple allocation rule is optimal because it is equally costly to produce public and private consumption goods. Definition 3 (Ramsey Problem): The Ramsey Problem is to maximize (1) over Rational Expectation Equilibria. A Ramsey outcome is a Rational Expectation Equilibrium that attains the maximum of (1). In this policy problem, the Lagrangian multipliers associated with forward looking variables, i.e. E t π t+1, E t u c,t+1, are additional state variables. Assuming these states initial values equal to zero generally implies transitory non-stationary components in the solution to the Ramsey problem, even in a non-stochastic environment. 1 In other words, the policy problem in the initial period is different than that of any future period. The reason why this occurs is that in the initial period the policy-maker may have the temptation to temporarily increase taxes or generate inflation so as to erode the real value of any outstanding government debt. 2 We do not study these non-stationary deterministic components and focus instead on the time-invariant deterministic long-run outcome. We define this allocation as the Ramsey Steady State (RSS henceforth). This means that we are implicitly imposing an initial commitment on the Ramsey planner not to generate surprise movements in taxes, prices, government spending, or nominal interest rates in period zero. This is standard practice in the optimal taxation literature, see e.g. Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004) Analytical Results As it is well known from Lucas and Stokey (1983), there exists a continuum of RSS, each of which associated with an outstanding level of public debt. In other words, without specifying the steady state level of public debt, the model displays an indeterminacy of degree one. 1 In section 3.6 we present a special case where the Ramsey policy is time consistent. This means that the Lagrangian multipliers associated with E tπ t+1, E tu c,t+1 are zero at all time. 2 However contrary to a flexible price economy, the Ramsey Planner does not find optimal to set P 0 =. 3 Furthermore, given the presence of sticky prices and state-noncontingent government bond, our primal form of the Ramsey problem can no longer be reduced to a unique intertemporal budget constraint in period 0 and a feasibility constraint holding in every period. However we could still write our policy problem in terms of a sequence of intertemporal implementability constraints. For a detailed discussion, see Aiyagari et. al. (2002) and Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004). 9

10 Proposition 2 (Optimal Inflation): Despite this indeterminacy, all the RSS are characterized by π = 1 (20) and R = 1 β (21) Proof. See Appendix. It is therefore suboptimal to use steady-state inflation to reduce the real value of any outstanding level of public debt or to erode the real value of profits and in turn RSS allocations are independent of the degree of price stickiness. This is a common result in the literature that considers this class of models, e.g. Benigno and Woodford (2003) and Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2007). In order to understand the indeterminacy problem, it suffi ces to recall the first order condition (FOC) of the Ramsey problem (see Appendix A) with respect to b t+1, i.e. γ 4,t R t βe t γ 4,t+1 π t+1 = 0, (22) where γ 4 is the Lagrangian multiplier on the government budget constraint. At steady-state, the Euler equation implies R = 1. Therefore, at steady-state, (22) is satisfied for any values β of γ 4. Hence, in order to pin down the RSS one has to fix the outstanding level of public debt such that (22) becomes redundant, i.e. public debt becomes exogenous at steady-state. This means that in order to find the RSS, it is possible to recast the policy problem as one featuring constant real public liabilities/assets, i.e. we can rewrite the (13) as x + g t = w t h t τ h t + c t τ c t, (23) where x = (1 β) b 0 represents the steady-state level of real government liabilities. As in Adam (2011), when optimal monetary policy is in place, this modified version of the Ramsey problem leads to the same real allocation as the general problem in Definition (3) and is used to obtain a number of analytical results. 4 Proposition 3 (First Best Decentralized Equilibrium): the Ramsey Steady State and the Social Planner s allocation at steady state coincide under the following necessary condi- 4 Detailed discussion of this can be found in Appendix B, Subsection

11 tions where x opt = b opt 0 (1 β). π = 1 (24) 1 τ h η = 1 + τ c η 1 with τ h (, 1) and τ c ( 1, ) (25) x opt = c h h (1 + τ c ) + η 1 τ h 1 with x opt < 0 η (26) Proof. See Appendix. Corollary 4 The Ramsey Planner cannot replicate the Social Planner Allocation for a generic level of outstanding public debt with τ h (, 1) and τ c ( 1, ). A few things are worth stressing. First, condition (25) indicates that the first best allocation requires at least one fiscal instrument between τ h and τ c to be a subsidy, i.e. to be negative. 5 Second, the first best allocation requires negative public debt. Put it differently, the Ramsey Planner cannot obtain the first best allocation with a generic level of debt, as this would imply either τ c < 1 or τ h > 1. 6 The reason for this result is the following. Consider, for sake of simplicity, a model with no public spending, no public debt ( x = 0) and perfect competition (η and w = 1). The monetary policy implements a zero inflation policy, i.e. π = 1. In this scenario, the market clearing condition is h = c and consumption taxes and labor income taxes have the same equilibrium tax base. Then, the decentralization of the first best implies τ c = τ h. This tax policy would raise zero revenues in equilibrium, i.e. τ c c = τ h h. However, in the presence of monopolistic competition, i.e. η <, the η first best policy implies τ h = 1 + τ c as the policy-maker needs to compensate households for the fact that the real wage fells short of ( equating the) marginal rate of substitution η 1 η 1 1 between consumption and leisure. Given that + τ c η h > τ c c, this policy implies η 1 η 1 negative revenues in equilibrium. Moreover, using numerical solutions which we describe in details below, we find that the policy-maker would always find a marginal welfare advantage in increasing consumption taxation and subsiding labor when the level of outstanding public debt is greater than x opt. This means that a potentially revenue-neutral combination of an increase in the consumption 5 In particular, if τ h > 0, then first best allocation requires τ c < 0. However it is possible to find negative values of τ h for which the first best requires τ c < 0. At the same time, if τ c > 0, the effi cient allocation requires τ h < 0. 6 One may wonder if this result relies on the absence of profit taxation. As it is well known, the optimal profit taxation in this class of models is generally equal to 100%, i.e. the Ramsey planner finds it optimal to confiscate all the profits in the economy, see for instance, Correia, Nicolini and Teles (2008) and Correia, Farhi, Nicolini and Teles (2013). We proof in the Appendix that even with the introduction of full profit taxation, i.e. τ d = 1, the effi cient level of public debt is negative. 11

12 tax and a decrease in the labor income tax, the latter restricted to being non negative, always increases effi ciency. However, while this policy will never replicate the first best allocation, it would create extreme tax and subsidy positions. 7 Hence, this policy would be extremely diffi cult to implement due, for example, to the high costs associated in verifying hours worked. Similarly, a very high consumption tax rate would perhaps lead to a significant amount of unreported barter. Therefore, we allow the policy-maker to use both tax instruments when x x opt, while under a generic level of steady-state debt(asset)-to-gdp, we study the cases where the Ramsey Planner is constrained in using only one tax instrument, i.e. either τ h = 0 or τ c = 0. 8 Proposition 5 Under labor income taxation, the Ramsey Planner sets u g u h (27) and ( η 1 u g u c g + x ). (28) η h }{{} (0,1) Proof. See Appendix. This proposition shows that it is optimal to set public consumption below the level suggested by the Social Planner. 9 This is because there exists a wedge between the marginal utility of leisure and the marginal utility of consumption, which is composed of two components. First, the monopolistic power that firms hold. Second, the distortive nature of fiscal policy used to finance public spending and public debt. By reducing government spending, the Ramsey Planner can lower the tax rate and hence shrinks the wedge between consumption and leisure. Moreover, while (28) does not give a precise analytical mapping between u g and u c, we can nevertheless provide some intuition about this relationship. Consider, for instance, any increase in ineffi ciency, due, for example, to more market power or higher outstanding debt. This would dampen economic activity. The Ramsey Planner by adjusting government size relative to GDP and therefore the level of taxation, can affect households labor supply and private consumption and potentially reduce ineffi ciency. For example, by imposing u g > u c, i.e. a government to consumption ratio lower than the first best, the policy-maker can sustain a given level of outstanding debt with lower taxation. Lower taxa- 7 For example Coleman (2000) finds that in a perfectly competitive economy with capital accumulation, the Ramsey planner would set τ c = 692% and τ h = 692%. Monopolistic distortion amplifies even further these fiscal positions, i.e. within standard parametrizations consumption taxation is higher than 1000%. 8 This is common practice in the literature when optimal policy implies extreme tax positions, e.g. Coleman (2000), Correia (2010) and Martin (2010). 9 This is true as long as private and public goods are not inferior goods, as it is assumed in this paper. 12

13 tion would increase labor supply. 10 The sign of c determines whether a higher labor supply h implies a higher or lower consumption level. In the Appendix we show that ( ) c = h sign c ( ) + cu cc c x 1h u c η The sign of (29) depends, inter alia, on the relative measure of risk aversion cucc u c, the degree of monopolistic competition η and the level of outstanding debt x. When (29) is positive, i.e. sign (29) when risk aversion is low, shrinking the government size (relative to GDP) below the first best, allows the Ramsey Planner to increase the labor supply and private consumption, thus reducing ineffi ciency. The opposite is true as (29) turns negative, i.e. when risk aversion is high. In this case the policy-maker has a strong incentive to set the government spending-to-gdp ratio greater than the first best allocation, i.e. u g < u c. With such a policy the Ramsey Planner can induce an increase in consumption and therefore reduce the wedge between the marginal utility of private consumption and the marginal utility of leisure. The desire for such a policy, i.e. u g < u c, is decreasing both in the degree of monopolistic competition and in the size of public debt. In the particular case of perfect competition and no public debt, i.e. η and x = 0, the RHS of (29) collapses to 1. In this case, if the utility is logarithmic in private and public consumption, the Ramsey Planner finds it optimal to set the share of government spending over total output as in the first best. 11 Next we analyze the scenario where the Ramsey Planner has access only to consumption taxation, i.e. τ h = 0. Proposition 6 Under consumption taxation the Ramsey Planner sets u g > u h. (30) Furthermore, if cu cc u c > 1 = u c > u g = 1 = u c = u g (31) < 1 = u c < u g u g is decreasing (increasing) in x if cucc u c = 1 for any outstanding level of public debt. and uc u c u g > (<) 1. In the special case where cucc u c = 1, 10 We are implicitly assuming that the substitution effect on labour supply always prevails, which is consistent with a Laffer curve in government revenues. 11 In the case of log utility and positive public debt and/or monopolistic competition, the Ramsey planner finds it c optimal to set the share of public spending-to-gdp lower than the first best, i.e. > 0. h 13

14 Proof. See Appendix. As under labor income taxation, the Ramsey Planner finds it optimal to set the level of government spending below the Social Planner level. This is due to the monopolistic features of the goods markets and the distortive nature of fiscal policy. Furthermore, (31) clarifies whether the optimal allocation requires the share of government over total output to be above or below the first best level. Interestingly, this is now only function of consumers risk aversion. If this is higher (lower) than 1, the optimal government spending-to-gdp ratio is set above (below) the Social Planner level. By allocating a high share of government spending, the Ramsey Planner is imposing, for a given level of outstanding debt, a higher tax rate. Assuming that consumption is a normal good, higher taxation implies lower consumption. In order to understand the implications of lower consumption on the labor supply schedule we need to study the sign of ( ) h = c sign ( ) [ uh ( cucc u c 1 u h+ x )] c c [ ( ) ] 1 h u hh c u h + 1 u h u c u hh u c x sign. (32) In the Appendix we show that the above expression is negative when cucc u c > 1 and positive otherwise. This means that when cucc u c > 1, the lower consumption generated by higher taxation implies an increase in labor supply, which in turn pushes the economy closer to the first best. On the contrary, when cucc u c < 1, the Ramsey Planner sets u c < u g. The resulting lower taxation pushes consumption, and therefore labor supply, upward, i.e. h > 0. c For the same reason, the optimal policy calls for an increase in the government spendingto-gdp ratio when public debt increases. Moreover, for the particular case in which risk aversion is 1, the Ramsey Planner, independently of the outstanding level of public debt, sets the marginal utility of private consumption equal to the marginal utility of public spending, as prescribed by the Social Planner. A simple comparative static exercise can show that for a given degree of risk aversion and a positive (or at least not too negative) outstanding debt, the optimal share of government spending-to-gdp is greater under consumption taxation than under labor income tax Computational Issues As discussed above, we assume that in period 0 the economy is in the RSS. When an analytical expression is missing, we rely on non-linear numerical solution algorithms. 13 Firstly, 12 Take for instance the case of logaritmic preferences, i.e. cucc u c = 1. Under labour income taxation u g > u c, while under consumption taxation u g = u c. 13 The different Ramsey problems are described in detail in the Appendix. 14

15 we compute the exact non-linear RSS by using the OLS projection approach proposed by Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004, 2007, 2012). This consists in exploiting the insight that the Ramsey equilibrium conditions are linear in the vector of Lagrange multipliers, γ i. Then, using the perturbation method proposed by Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004), we compute the accurate second-order approximation of the Ramsey s FOCs around the non-stochastic steady state of these conditions. We then use this solution to simulate the Ramsey equilibrium in the face of a technology shock. 14 The shock realizations and all the other structural parameters used for the simulations are kept constant through the different fiscal scenarios. This means that any difference between fiscal arrangements are attributable entirely to the properties of the economic policies. Moreover, we measure welfare in terms of percentage of consumption units, i.e. ϖ required by a generic policy X to reach the same level of utility as under policy Y, i.e. E 0 t=0 β t [ u ( c X t (1 + ϖ), h X t, g X t )] = E0 β [ t u ( c Y t, h Y t, gt Y t=0 )]. (33) 3.3 Parametrization We specify preferences to satisfy the conditions stated in Section 2, i.e. u (c t, h t, g t ) = c1 σ t 1 σ ω h h 1+φ t g 1 σ t 1 + φ + ω g 1 σ with σ, φ > 0. Each period represents a quarter with the discount factor, β, set to The elasticity of demand is chosen in order have a steady state gross markup of 1.2 (η = 6), which is in line with the macro literature. Given the importance of the CRRA parameter for our results, i.e. σ = cucc u c, we solve the model with a set of values of risk aversion that are generally found in the literature, i.e. σ (0.8, 2). However, we set σ = 1, i.e. log utility, as a benchmark value. The utility parameter ω h is chosen so that households supply between one fifth and one third of their time to work in the decentralized equilibrium when the steady-state level of public debt is zero, i.e. ω h = We further fix ω g in order to have in the decentralised allocation with labour income tax and no public debt, a ratio of government spending over total output of 20%, i.e. ω g = We set the inverse Frisch elasticity of labor supply φ to 1, a value generally used as a benchmark in the macroeconomic literature, e.g. Adam and Billi (2008). The price stickiness parameter is selected such that the log-linearized version 14 In the case of effi cient steady-state, i.e. when the government is allowed to accumulate a large asset position, the second order approximation approach gives the same welfare ranking of the correspondent linear-quadratic (LQ) representation of the problem, see Woodford (2003). For this reason, part of our results are readily comparable with the literature that adopts the LQ approach. 15

16 of the Phillips curve (12) is consistent with the estimates of Sbordone (2002), (ϕ = 17.4). The quarterly standard deviation of the technology shocks is 0.6% and it has a quarterly persistence equal to 0.7. Furthermore, we show the implications of varying the long run level of public debt. 15 Table 1 collects the parametrization adopted. 3.4 Steady State Results This section explores the quantitative implications of different fiscal scenarios for the RSS allocations (with particular focus on the Ramsey public spending) and welfare. In particular, here we show how the various fiscal arrangements interact with government spending and long-run level public debt in determining the Ramsey allocations. Figure (1) presents the RSS allocations when public debt is allowed to vary from -100% to 200% of GDP. Increasing the level of outstanding public debt implies an increase in the (distortive) tax rate and hence a loss of effi ciency. Higher taxes imply a lower after tax real wage. However, despite the consumption tax being higher than the labor income tax, it has a lower impact on the real wage. This is because consumption is generally more inelastic than leisure. Hence households respond less, ceteris paribus, to a variation in consumption tax than to a variation in labor income tax. As a consequence, under consumption taxation the increase in public debt implies a lower response of the gap variables. In order to better understand the reason why consumption taxation is, ceteris paribus, less distortive than labor income tax, let us consider a simplified version of the model, i.e. a one-period, perfectly competitive model where agents have preferences given by log (c) h and face a budget constrained given by (1 + τ c ) c = wh ( 1 τ h) + q. Wages are constant at 1 and q is a transfer equal to the tax revenues. In this simple case hours worked are equal to the tax wedge, i.e. h = ζ = 1 τ h 1+τ c and private consumption follows from c = wh. This means that consumption taxes and labor income taxes have the same tax base. Now, let us consider the case where one of the two tax rates is set to zero. Given our policy analysis, this exercise is particularly instructive. In this case, one achieves the same equilibrium labor supply with τ h = 1 ζ and τ c = 0 or with τ c = 1 ζ 1 and τ h = 0. In the first case, i.e. with labor income taxes, the tax revenues are given by ζ (1 ζ) and have a peak at ζ = h = 0.5. The tax revenues are equal to 1 ζ in the second case of consumption taxation, and are increasing to one as the tax wedge ζ, labor supply and therefore available resources approach to zero. Transfers q approach one, but they are treated as income before consumption taxes: when the household attempts to consume this transfer income, she has to pay taxes approaching 100%, so that she is indeed left only with the resources originally produced. In other words, for any level of tax revenues, under consumption taxation the system produces more resources then 15 As a benchmark value, we fix the debt-to-gdp ratio at 90%, a value consistent with Figure 1 for the year

17 under labor income tax and hence is less distortive. Figure (2) quantifies, in percentage of permanent steady state consumption units, the loss suffered by households as steady state public debt increases. Under both fiscal scenarios, higher values of steady state public debt imply an increase in ineffi ciency and hence a deterioration of welfare. However there is a surprisingly high gain from using consumption taxation over labor income taxation as a fiscal instrument. This gain is increasing in the debt-to-gdp ratio, passing from 24% when government debt to GDP is 100% (here we put 0) to 42% when public debt is 200% of total income. As public debt increases, the fiscal authority has to devote more and more resources to pay its burden. Therefore, the lower distortive effects of consumption taxation generate a relative gain as the ineffi ciency generated by the burden of public debt increases. Figure (3) shows the difference between the Ramsey government spending to GDP ratio and the Social Planner allocation when public debt is at its benchmark value, i.e. 90% of GDP and we allow σ to vary in the interval [0.8, 2] while all the other parameters are kept at their benchmark values. This figure may be seen as a graphical representation of Proposition 5 and 6. A negative (positive) number identifies a scenario where the Ramsey Planner sets the ratio between public spending and total output below (above) the first best, i.e. g y g < (>). Under both fiscal scenarios, this difference depends critically on the parameter y controlling the risk aversion in the CRRA utility function. In particular, as consumers become more risk adverse, optimal policy calls for reducing private consumption in favor of public spending. By directly affecting the size of government spending and therefore the level of distortive taxation, the policy-maker can influence labor supply and private consumption and potentially reduce ineffi ciency. As discussed above, for a give level of risk aversion, optimal policy under consumption taxation implies a higher share of government spending over GDP than under labor income taxation. 16 Figure (4) presents the optimal public spending rule as public debt increases for different degrees of risk aversion. Under labor income tax, the optimal share of public spending is decreasing in public debt. This is because the strong distortionary effects of higher tax rates prevail over the incentive of the Ramsey Planner to increase g/y as the degree of risk aversion increases. This is consistent with (29), i.e. for a given level of risk aversion a higher level of steady state public debt generates an incentive to reduce the share of public consumption. Differently, under consumption taxation, the optimal spending rule depends crucially on whether risk aversion is below or above unity, as presented in Proposition 6. Therefore when σ = 0.8, i.e. cucc u c < 1, the Ramsey Planner, by cutting the share of government as public debt increases, can boost both consumption and labor supply. On the contrary, when σ = 2, 16 In particular, under labour income tax g = g c for σ = = y y (c x 1 h), i.e. c = 0. h ε 17

18 i.e. cucc u c > 1, the optimal policy increases the government spending-to-gdp ratio in order to increase hours worked and therefore total output. Finally, as presented in Proposition 6, in the benchmark case of log utility in consumption, i.e. cucc u c = 1, the optimal share of government spending is always at the first best, independently of the level of steady state public debt. We perform a set of robustness checks both on some key structural parameters of the model as well as on the fiscal instruments available to the government. Results from this exercise are reported in Table 2. Decreasing the degree of market power, i.e. increasing η, it reduces ineffi ciency: the overall production increase, and so do private and public consumption. As a result, under both fiscal scenarios, as η becomes bigger, the welfare loss decreases. When consumption taxes are excluded, lower levels of monopolistic power are consistent with higher government spending-to-gpd ratios. This is consistent with Proposition (5) and (29). The reason is that as the ineffi ciency due to market power gets smaller, the Ramsey planner has an incentive to push g towards the effi cient level. Furthermore, in this fiscal scenario, as η y gets bigger, the optimal level of labour income tax decreases. This is due to the increase of the labour-income tax base that a greater degree of market competitiveness brings about. As a result, the fiscal authority can sustain a higher level of government spending, and ceteris paribus, a higher public spending-to total output ratio, with a lower labour income tax rate. Differently, when consumption taxes are available, reducing monopolistic power does not effect the optimal provision of public spending (as share of the GDP). This is a direct consequence of Proposition 6, where the Ramsey ratio of g depends solely on the degree of y risk aversion. Furthermore, in the optimal allocation, the increase in η reduces the ineffi ciency in the system, but it does not affect the consumption tax base. Therefore τ c stays constant at its benchmark value as the system moves towards perfect competition. 3.5 Ramsey Dynamics First Best Steady State We now turn our attention to the optimal policy in a stochastic setting. To this end we perturb the model with a technology shock as described in 3.4. Studying Ramsey policy in the face of this type of shock is standard practice in the literature (e.g. Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004), Correia et al. (2008), Adam (2011), Leith and Wren Lewis (2013) ) and allows us to better disentangle our contribution. We start our analysis by considering a situation where the policy-maker implements first best at steady-state. This implies that the government is allowed to accumulate large asset positions (i.e. negative debt) and that one (or both) taxes can be negative. Both these assumptions will be dropped later. We refer the 18

19 reader to Proposition 3 in Section 3.2 on how a Ramsey Planner can achieve the first best in this environment. In practise, we fix the steady state value of consumption taxation to 16%. This value corresponds to the average level of consumption taxation in the industrialized countries found by Gordon and Li (2009). Then, the labor income tax rate and the level of the government assets are pinned down by (25) and (26) respectively. Here we run three policy exercises. In the first one the policy-maker can respond to shocks by using both taxes. In the other two, we restrict the fiscal authority to use only one tax instrument in the face of shocks. The three scenarios share the same steady state allocation so that any difference can be attributed entirely to the dynamic properties of the tax instruments adopted. Results are reported in Figure (5). When the policy-maker has access to both taxes, first best is attainable in the stochastic economy under consideration. In other words, the Ramsey Planner can commit to a statecontingent policy such that in face of a technology shock the response in the decentralized economy coincides with the Social Planner s allocation. In this case, Ramsey policy is also time-consistent, i.e. if a policy-maker were given the opportunity to revise this policy in any future period, it would find it optimal not to do so. Absence economic policy, in a sticky-price environment a negative technology shock would imply an increase of inflation and a positive output gap, i.e. price would increase but not as much as required in a flexible price world, thus imply an ineffi ciently high level of output. As it is well know from Galí (2001), a welfare maximizing policy-maker would therefore tighten aggregate demand as to push output towards the effi cient level. This policy would also stabilize inflation. Here the Ramsey Planner looses monetary policy on impact and promises to keep it above the steady state level for some periods after the shock. At the same time, she increases the consumption tax and promises to cut it in the next period. As we discuss in more details later, this contingent tax policy represents one of the main advantages of using consumption taxation as a demand management tool. Indeed, the combined optimal use of monetary and fiscal instruments allows the policy-maker to fully control the stochastic discount factor and hence offset firms desire to changing prices, thus replicating the flexible price equilibrium. Furthermore, in order to mimic the Social Planner solution, the Ramsey Planner has to avoid distorting households consumption-leisure choice. In other words, the policy-maker moves the consumption and the labor income tax rate in the same measure and in opposite direction so that they do not create a wedges between the marginal utility of leisure and that of consumption. Finally the Ramsey equates the marginal utility of private and public consumption as required by the first best equilibrium by varying her assets positions. In other words, if the government is allowed to take large assets position and can use both consumption and labor income taxation, she can offset both the static and the dynamic 19

20 ineffi ciencies of the model. Table 3 reports the model s campionary moments of this exercise. 17 Given the shape of the utility function (σ = 1), dynamic effi ciency requires output, consumption, government spending and real wages to be perfectly correlated with each other and with the technology process, while hours worked and inflation should remain at their steady state values. These results are closely related to Correia et al. (2008). They show that with consumption and labor income taxation, full profit taxation and exogenous government spending, the Ramsey Planner can mimic the flexible price equilibrium, so that any real allocation is independent from the degree of nominal rigidities. Here we show that the first best allocation can be implemented without profit taxation and with endogenous government spending as long as the government is allowed to take large asset positions. Next, we analyze fiscal scenarios in which the government is constrained in using only one tax instrument. We start with the case where only consumption taxation is available. IRF s are presented in Figure (5). In this case, while the policy-maker can obtain long run effi ciency via asset accumulation, the absence of labor income taxation makes it impossible to reach dynamic effi ciency. In particular, the optimal tax policy required to balanced the government budget constraint distorts the leisure-consumption decision, thus creating an ineffi ciency wedge in the labor supply and therefore in the real wages. At the time of the shock, output, consumption and public spending all drop by roughly the same amount as the case where the Ramsey Planner has access to both taxations, thus resulting in very small movements of gap variables. 18 This policy, coupled with an initial cut in the nominal rate and an increase in consumption taxation, is aimed to generate an increase on impact of inflation. This helps to reduce the cut in the government assets necessary to balanced the government budget constraint. As for the case with two tax instruments, this policy is reverted in the period after the shock. Fiscal policy commits in reducing consumption taxation while monetary policy increases the nominal rate above its steady state value. These combined policies affect the real stochastic discount factor and imply a one-period deflation episode, which in turn pushes the price level near its steady state value. Table 3 reports the implied simulated moments of this policy experiment. Compared to the previous scenario, the ineffi ciency generated by the absence of labor income taxation generates an incentive for the policy-maker to reduce the volatility of output, consumption, 17 Given the quasi-random walk properties of public debt, unconditional moments are not available. Hence, like Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004), Arseneau and Chugh (2008) and Nieman and Pichler (2011), we calculate the campionary moments of the model. In particular we simulate the model 5000 times for 100 periods. For each simulation we calculate the statistics of interest. Then we report the median value. 18 As in Benigno and Woodford (2003) and Adam (2011), consumption, output, government spending, taxes and debt all follow a near ramdom walk pattern. However, given the optimal consumption tax policy, the long run values of these variables are very close to their steady state counterparts. 20

Optimal Fiscal Policy with Consumption Taxation

Optimal Fiscal Policy with Consumption Taxation Optimal Fiscal Policy with Consumption Taxation Giorgio Motta Raffaele Rossi August 2016 Abstract We characterise optimal fiscal policies in a tractable Dynamic General Equilibrium model with monopolistic

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy

GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy Barbara Annicchiarico* Fabio Di Dio** *Department of Economics and Finance University of Rome Tor Vergata **IT Economia - SOGEI S.P.A Workshop on Central Banking,

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing Guido Ascari and Lorenza Rossi University of Pavia Abstract Calvo and Rotemberg pricing entail a very di erent dynamics of adjustment

More information

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe August 2 211 This document contains supplementary material to Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (211). 1 A Two Sector

More information

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) Was The New Deal Contractionary? Gauti B. Eggertsson Web Appendix VIII. Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) ProofofProposition3:The social planner s problem at date is X min

More information

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10 Macro II John Hassler Spring 27 John Hassler () New Keynesian Model: 4/7 / New Keynesian Model The RBC model worked (perhaps surprisingly) well. But there are problems in generating enough variation in

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations Tommy Sveen Norges Bank January 28, 2009 TS (NB) ECON 4325 January 28, 2009 / 35 Introduction A simple model of a classical monetary economy. Perfect

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON QUALITY BIAS AND INFLATION TARGETS. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON QUALITY BIAS AND INFLATION TARGETS. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON QUALITY BIAS AND INFLATION TARGETS Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe Working Paper 1555 http://www.nber.org/papers/w1555 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 15 Massachusetts

More information

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) Monetary Policy, 16/3 2017 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) 1. Money in the short run: Incomplete

More information

Money in an RBC framework

Money in an RBC framework Money in an RBC framework Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 1 / 36 Money Two basic questions: 1 Modern economies use money. Why? 2 How/why do

More information

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 The Ramsey Model Lectures 11 to 14 Topics in Macroeconomics November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 Lecture 11, 12, 13 & 14 1/50 Topics in Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model: Introduction 2 Main Ingredients Neoclassical

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model. Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model. Olivier Blanchard May 25 14.452. Spring 25. Topic 7. 1 Why introduce nominal rigidities, and what do they imply? An informal walk-through. In the model we

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals. Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi March 2010; Revised January 2011 RWP 10-10

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals. Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi March 2010; Revised January 2011 RWP 10-10 Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi March 2010; Revised January 2011 RWP 10-10 Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals 1 Klaus Adam 2 and

More information

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from: Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ On the Implementation of Markov-Perfect Monetary Policy Michael Dotsey y and Andreas Hornstein

More information

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model Bianca De Paoli November 2008 1 Fiscal Policy in a New Keynesian Model 1.1 Positive analysis: the e ect of scal shocks How do scal shocks a ect in ation?

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

The science of monetary policy

The science of monetary policy Macroeconomic dynamics PhD School of Economics, Lectures 2018/19 The science of monetary policy Giovanni Di Bartolomeo giovanni.dibartolomeo@uniroma1.it Doctoral School of Economics Sapienza University

More information

MONETARY CONSERVATISM AND FISCAL POLICY. Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi First version: September 29, 2004 This version: February 2007 RWP 07-01

MONETARY CONSERVATISM AND FISCAL POLICY. Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi First version: September 29, 2004 This version: February 2007 RWP 07-01 MONETARY CONSERVATISM AND FISCAL POLICY Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi First version: September 29, 2004 This version: February 2007 RWP 07-01 Abstract: Does an inflation conservative central bank à la

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles 2. Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March Main idea: introduce nominal rigidities Why? in classical monetary models the price level ensures money

More information

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6 Contents 1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) 2 1.1 Question (a).................................................... 2 1.2 Question (b).................................................... 6 2 Countercyclical

More information

Optimal Capital Taxation Revisited. Staff Report 571 September 2018

Optimal Capital Taxation Revisited. Staff Report 571 September 2018 Optimal Capital Taxation Revisited V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Juan Pablo Nicolini Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and Universidad Di Tella Pedro Teles

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Cúrdia FRB New York Michael Woodford Columbia University Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial Frictions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

Money in a Neoclassical Framework Money in a Neoclassical Framework Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 1 / 21 Money Two basic questions: 1 Modern economies use money. Why? 2 How/why

More information

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux Online Appendix: Non-cooperative Loss Function Section 7 of the text reports the results for

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam MACROECONOMICS Prelim Exam Austin, June 1, 2012 Instructions This is a closed book exam. If you get stuck in one section move to the next one. Do not waste time on sections that you find hard to solve.

More information

Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Stabilization Policy

Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Stabilization Policy Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Stabilization Policy Behzad Diba Georgetown University May 2013 (Institute) Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Stabilization Policy May 2013 1 / 19 New Keynesian Models Over a

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Dynamic Macroeconomics Chapter 1 Introduction Dynamic Macroeconomics Prof. George Alogoskoufis Fletcher School, Tufts University and Athens University of Economics and Business 1.1 The Nature and Evolution of Macroeconomics

More information

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010 Booms and Busts in Asset Prices Klaus Adam Mannheim University & CEPR Albert Marcet London School of Economics & CEPR May 2010 Adam & Marcet ( Mannheim Booms University and Busts & CEPR London School of

More information

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities 14.452. Topic 7. Nominal rigidities Olivier Blanchard April 2007 Nr. 1 1. Motivation, and organization Why introduce nominal rigidities, and what do they imply? In monetary models, the price level (the

More information

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Introducing nominal rigidities. Introducing nominal rigidities. Olivier Blanchard May 22 14.452. Spring 22. Topic 7. 14.452. Spring, 22 2 In the model we just saw, the price level (the price of goods in terms of money) behaved like an

More information

Problem set Fall 2012.

Problem set Fall 2012. Problem set 1. 14.461 Fall 2012. Ivan Werning September 13, 2012 References: 1. Ljungqvist L., and Thomas J. Sargent (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, sections 17.2 for Problem 1,2. 2. Werning Ivan

More information

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model Guido Ascari University of Pavia Nicola Branzoli University of Pavia October 27, 2006 Abstract This note shows that full price indexation

More information

The new Kenesian model

The new Kenesian model The new Kenesian model Michaª Brzoza-Brzezina Warsaw School of Economics 1 / 4 Flexible vs. sticky prices Central assumption in the (neo)classical economics: Prices (of goods and factor services) are fully

More information

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound Timothy Hills Taisuke Nakata Sebastian Schmidt New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank 1 September 2016 1 The views expressed

More information

Oil Price Shock and Optimal Monetary Policy in a Model of Small Open Oil Exporting Economy - Case of Iran 1

Oil Price Shock and Optimal Monetary Policy in a Model of Small Open Oil Exporting Economy - Case of Iran 1 Journal of Money and Economy Vol. 8, No.3 Summer 2013 Oil Price Shock and Optimal Monetary Policy in a Model of Small Open Oil Exporting Economy - Case of Iran 1 Rabee Hamedani, Hasti 2 Pedram, Mehdi 3

More information

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function Eurilton Araújo Insper Working Paper WPE: 23/2008 Copyright Insper. Todos os direitos reservados. É proibida a reprodução

More information

Monetary and Fiscal Interactions without Commitment and the Value of Monetary Conservatism

Monetary and Fiscal Interactions without Commitment and the Value of Monetary Conservatism Monetary and Fiscal Interactions without Commitment and the Value of Monetary Conservatism Klaus Adam Roberto M. Billi First version: September 29,2004 Current version: April 28, 2005 Abstract We study

More information

Unemployment equilibria in a Monetary Economy

Unemployment equilibria in a Monetary Economy Unemployment equilibria in a Monetary Economy Nikolaos Kokonas September 30, 202 Abstract It is a well known fact that nominal wage and price rigidities breed involuntary unemployment and excess capacities.

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312/702 Basic New Keynesian Model of Transmission Can be derived from primitives:

More information

The New Keynesian Model

The New Keynesian Model The New Keynesian Model Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 1 / 37 Research strategy policy as systematic and predictable...the central bank s stabilization

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first introduce and discuss the intertemporal budget

More information

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55 Government debt Lecture 9, ECON 4310 Tord Krogh September 10, 2013 Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, 2013 1 / 55 Today s lecture Topics: Basic concepts Tax smoothing Debt crisis Sovereign risk Tord

More information

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Advanced Macroeconomics II Professor Lorenza Rossi/Jordi Gali T.A. Daniël van Schoot, daniel.vanschoot@upf.edu Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Schedule: 28th of May (seminar 4): Exercises 1, 2 and

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules WILLIAM A. BRANCH TROY DAVIG BRUCE MCGOUGH Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules This paper examines the implications of forward- and backward-looking monetary policy

More information

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far (Incomplete) summary of the course so far Lecture 9a, ECON 4310 Tord Krogh September 16, 2013 Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 16, 2013 1 / 31 Main topics This semester we will go through: Ramsey (check)

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing Florian Scheuer 5/1/2014 Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing 1 Finite Horizon 1.1 Setup 2 periods t = 0, 1 preferences U i c 0, c 1, l 0 sequential budget constraints in t = 0, 1 c i 0 + pbi 1 +

More information

Macroeconomics and finance

Macroeconomics and finance Macroeconomics and finance 1 1. Temporary equilibrium and the price level [Lectures 11 and 12] 2. Overlapping generations and learning [Lectures 13 and 14] 2.1 The overlapping generations model 2.2 Expectations

More information

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates at the effective lower bound for interest rates Bank of England 12 March 2010 Plan Introduction The model The policy problem Results Summary & conclusions Plan Introduction Motivation Aims and scope The

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) MACRO-LINKAGES, OIL PRICES AND DEFLATION WORKSHOP JANUARY 6 9, 2009 Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) Credit Frictions and

More information

Discussion: The Optimal Rate of Inflation by Stephanie Schmitt- Grohé and Martin Uribe

Discussion: The Optimal Rate of Inflation by Stephanie Schmitt- Grohé and Martin Uribe Discussion: The Optimal Rate of Inflation by Stephanie Schmitt- Grohé and Martin Uribe Can Ramsey optimal taxation account for the roughly 2% inflation target central banks seem to follow? This is not

More information

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Behzad Diba University of Bern April 2012 (Institute) Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background April 2012 1 / 19 Research Areas Research on fiscal policy typically

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Eric Sims University of otre Dame Spring 7 Introduction This set of notes studies fiscal policy in the RBC model. Fiscal policy refers to government

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Ozan Eksi TOBB University of Economics and Technology November 2 Abstract The standard new Keynesian

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 5 - Money Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 February A brief history of money in macro 1. 1. Hume: money has a wealth effect more money increase in aggregate demand Y 2. Friedman

More information

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 1 Imperfect Credibility of Policy: Trade Reform 1.1 Model Assumptions Output is exogenous constant endowment (y), not useful for consumption, but can be exported

More information

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility Comment Martín Uribe, Columbia University and NBER This paper represents the latest installment in a highly influential series of papers in which Paul Beaudry and Franck Portier shed light on the empirics

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

Optimal Capital Taxation Revisited. Working Paper 752 July 2018

Optimal Capital Taxation Revisited. Working Paper 752 July 2018 Optimal Capital Taxation Revisited V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Juan Pablo Nicolini Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Universidad Di Tella, and Universidad

More information

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2) MakØk3, Fall 2010 (blok 2) Business cycles and monetary stabilization policies Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

More information

Recently the study of optimal monetary policy has shifted from an

Recently the study of optimal monetary policy has shifted from an Implementation of Optimal Monetary Policy Michael Dotsey and Andreas Hornstein Recently the study of optimal monetary policy has shifted from an analysis of the welfare effects of simple parametric policy

More information

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES 1. REVIEW: SMALL TAXES SMALL DEADWEIGHT LOSS Static analysis suggests that deadweight loss from taxation at rate τ is 0(τ 2 ) that is, that for small tax rates the

More information

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples Jinill Kim, Korea University Sunghyun Kim, Sungkyunkwan University March 015 Abstract This paper provides two illustrative examples

More information

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1.

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1. Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective function max C,K,B t=0 β t C1 γ t 1 γ and faces the constraints at each period

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Economics 3307 - Intermediate Macroeconomics Aaron Hedlund Baylor University Fall 2013 Econ 3307 (Baylor University) The Real Business Cycle Model Fall 2013 1 / 23 Business

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

Lecture Notes in Macroeconomics. Christian Groth

Lecture Notes in Macroeconomics. Christian Groth Lecture Notes in Macroeconomics Christian Groth July 28, 2016 ii Contents Preface xvii I THE FIELD AND BASIC CATEGORIES 1 1 Introduction 3 1.1 Macroeconomics............................ 3 1.1.1 The field............................

More information

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound Robert G. King Boston University and NBER 1. Introduction What should the monetary authority do when prices are

More information

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture Barbara Annicchiarico BBLM del Dipartimento del Tesoro 2 Giugno 2. Annicchiarico (Università di Tor Vergata) (Institute) Microfoundations of DSGE Models 2 Giugno

More information

A Model with Costly-State Verification

A Model with Costly-State Verification A Model with Costly-State Verification Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania December 19, 2012 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 1 / 47 A Model with Costly-State

More information

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Pavel Herber 1 and Daniel Němec 2 1 Masaryk University, Faculty of Economics and Administrations Department of Economics Lipová 41a, 602 00 Brno,

More information

Problem set 1 - Solutions

Problem set 1 - Solutions Roberto Perotti November 20 Problem set - Solutions Exercise Suppose the process for income is y t = y + ε t + βε t () Using the permanent income model studied in class, find the expression for c t c t

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen June 15, 2012 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations June 15, 2012 1 / 59 Introduction We construct

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption Toulouse School of Economics Notes written by Ernesto Pasten (epasten@cict.fr) Slightly re-edited by Frank Portier (fportier@cict.fr) M-TSE. Macro I. 200-20. Chapter 3: Consumption Macroeconomics I Chapter

More information

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Econ 204A - Henning Bohn * Most of modern macroeconomics involves models of agents that optimize over time. he basic ideas and tools are the same as in microeconomics,

More information

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014 Macroeconomics Basic New Keynesian Model Nicola Viegi April 29, 2014 The Problem I Short run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks I I I persistent e ects on real variables slow adjustment of aggregate price

More information

Relative Price Distortion and Optimal Monetary Policy in Open Economies

Relative Price Distortion and Optimal Monetary Policy in Open Economies Relative Price Distortion and Optimal Monetary Policy in Open Economies Jinill Kim, Andrew T. Levin, and Tack Yun Federal Reserve Board Abstract This paper addresses three issues on the conduct of monetary

More information

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Michael Woodford Columbia University New Approaches to Fiscal Policy FRB Atlanta, January 8-9, 2010 Woodford (Columbia) Analytics of Multiplier

More information

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings Econ 20200 - Elements of Economics Analysis 3 (Honors Macroeconomics) Lecturer: Chanont (Big) Banternghansa TA: Jonathan J. Adams Spring 2013 Introduction Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

More information

Optimal Money and Debt Management: liquidity provision vs tax smoothing

Optimal Money and Debt Management: liquidity provision vs tax smoothing Optimal Money and Debt Management: liquidity provision vs tax smoothing Matthew Canzoneri Robert Cumby Behzad Diba First Draft: April 10, 2013 This Draft: 11/13/14 Abstract We extend a standard cash and

More information

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income 1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income Until now, we have assumed that government policy is exogenously given, so the government had a very passive role. Its only concern was balancing the intertemporal budget.

More information

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools Andrea Ferrero Richard Harrison Benjamin Nelson University of Oxford Bank of England Rokos Capital 20 th Central Bank Macroeconomic Modeling

More information

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Liquidity Trap and Excessive Leverage

Liquidity Trap and Excessive Leverage MACROECON & INT'L FINANCE WORKSHOP presented by Alp Simsek FRIDAY, April 8, 204 3:30 pm 5:00 pm, Room: HOH-706 Liquidity Trap and Excessive Leverage Anton Korinek Alp Simsek October 203 Abstract We investigate

More information

Liquidity Trap and Excessive Leverage

Liquidity Trap and Excessive Leverage Liquidity Trap and Excessive Leverage Anton Korinek Alp Simsek October 203 Abstract We investigate the role of debt market policies in mitigating liquidity traps driven by deleveraging. When constrained

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model

The Basic New Keynesian Model Jordi Gali Monetary Policy, inflation, and the business cycle Lian Allub 15/12/2009 In The Classical Monetary economy we have perfect competition and fully flexible prices in all markets. Here there is

More information

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve by George Alogoskoufis* March 2016 Abstract This paper puts forward an alternative new Keynesian

More information

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 26/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case

More information