Spending Natural Resource Revenues in an Altruistic Growth Model

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Spending Natural Resource Revenues in an Altruistic Growth Model"

Transcription

1 Spending Natural Resource Revenues in an Altruistic Growth Model Elisabeth Hermann Frederiksen University of Copenhagen, FAME y and EPRU z Please, consider for the young economist session. Preliminary draft. Comments welcome. May 8, 2006 Abstract This paper examines how revenues from a natural resource interact with growth and welfare in an overlapping generations model with altruism. Spending policies determine the allocation of resource revenues between public services and direct transfers to members of society. It is well-known that the growth dynamics depend on whether the bequest motive is operative. We analyze the role of spending policies in how bequests and savings respond to higher resource revenues, and derive solutions which imply that growth can be harmed. Furthermore, we examine spending policies that may lead to multiplicity of equilibria, and illustrate that growth and welfare can be oppositely a ected by changes in the resource revenue. Finally, we provide the socially optimal spending policies. The analysis suggests that variation in spending policies, and in the strength of the bequest motive, may be part of the reason why resource revenues seem to a ect economic performance across nations di erently. Keywords: Natural Resources, Economic Growth, Welfare, Altruism JEL Classi cations: D64, O4, Q33, Q38 I wish to thank Carl-Johan Dalgaard, Massimo Franchi, Christian Groth, Christian Schultz, Ragnar Torvik, seminar participants at the University of Copenhagen, and at the 2005 annual DGPE workshop for their helpful discussions and suggestions. Correspondence: Elisabeth Hermann Frederiksen, Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Studiestræde 6, 455 Copenhagen - K, Denmark. ehfecon.ku.dk. y FAME (Fisheries & Aquaculture, Management & Economics) is a network and resource school within resource and sheries management and economics connecting universities, research institutions and researchers. z The activities of EPRU (Economic Policy Research Unit) are nanced through a grant from The Danish National Research Foundation.

2 Introduction An important hypothesis in the growth literature is the notion of a resource curse ; a notion that is not new but dates back in history. The decline of Spain s prosperity after it s colonization of the New World and discovery of large amounts of gold and other precious metals is a classical example. Also within the last decades has the resource curse hypothesis received support by a large body of empirical literature (see Auty 993, 200; Sachs and Warner 995, 999, 200 among others) 2. Nevertheless, recent empirical studies have begun to question an unconditional negative relationship between natural resources and growth. Stijns (2005) reexamines the e ect of natural resource abundance on growth rates in a cross-country study by decomposing natural resources into four groups, namely oil and gas, coal, minerals and land. He concludes that only land is negatively correlated with economic growth. Sala-i-Martin et al. (2004) investigate overall determinants of growth rates; also by means of cross-country regressions. Among the robust and signi cant variables contributing positively to economic growth is the fraction of GDP in mining. Moreover, the classical counterexample to the resource curse is oil-rich Norway. Larsen (2005) concludes that resources are a blessing for Norway s economy 3. Motivated by what could look like an empirical rejection of a pandemic resource curse, this paper takes a closer look at how the variation across nations in the relationship between growth performance and natural resources can be explained 4. We use the term resource curse to describe the situation where resource abundant nations grow slower than nations endowed with fewer resources. In the literature the term is sometimes used in a more general way to describe poor economic performance. However, in our model, it is important to distinguish between growth and welfare e ects. 2 For a recent survey of the literature, consult Stevens (2003). 3 He notes, however, a slow-down in growth after the mid-90s. 4 The theoretical literature has traditionally focused on how to link poor growth performance to natural resource abundance. Classical explanations include the Dutch disease theory (Corden and

3 We argue that one possibility is that countries may be in di erent economic stages of development, or what we refer to as di erent economic growth regimes, when more natural resources are discovered. In particular, if economic factors such as private savings di er in the way they are generated across economic development stages, it seems natural to hypothesize that economies respond di erently to resource in ows depending on the dynamics of the particular growth regime by which they are con ned, even when natural resource revenues are allocated in the same ways. Yet, resource revenues are typically managed by governments. Therefore, economic policies, institutions (Mehlum et al. 2006), and political economic factors are likely to in uence spending policies that, in turn, possibly matters for how resource revenues impact economic performance. Classical political economy explanations are based on an idea that easy revenues corrupt and bring about con icts (Ross 2004, 2006) and encourage economically ine cient - but politically important - projects (Robinson and Torvik 2005). As a solution to such problems, Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian (2003) suggest, at least for the case of Nigeria, to decentralize revenues by distributing them directly to the people, by which the government is forced to nance public services by taxes. Taxes may be costly to collect, but Neary 982; Torvik 200; van Wijnbergen 984), rent seeking problems (Tornell and Lane 999; Torvik 2002), and political economy explanations (Ross 2004, 2006; Robinson and Torvik 2005). Rodriguez and Sachs (999) suggest that natural resource rich countries are overshooting their consumption levels and consequently converge to their steady states from above, which results in slow rates of economic growth. Only a limited number of theoretical studies have tried to explain the diverging experiences in resource impact on economic performance. One exception, however, is Mehlum et al. (2006). The paper argues that growth performance varies with how resource rents are distributed between grabbing and production, which, in turn, depends on the type of institution. The paper empirically supports that the resource curse is weaker or completely missing in countries with producer friendly institutional quality. Another paper by Torvik (200) proposes a Dutch disease model that explains the variation in resource impact on economic outcomes by di erences in learning-by-doing e ects and spillovers across traded and non-traded sectors. 2

4 overall society gains in that collecting taxes is claimed to incorporate a disciplining mechanism that protects against wasteful projects 5. We argue that nations that follow this recommendation and allocate (a least a share of) the resource revenues directly to their inhabitants, may experience different economic outcomes due to di erent economic growth regimes. Moreover, is not at all clear whom within society the resources should be given to. Papyrakis and Gerlagh (2004) study a two-generation overlapping generations model where resource revenues are given exclusively to the retired old generation 6. They show that the higher the resource revenues, the less the young generation saves, and therefore the economy is resource cursed. In general, while there has been intense focus on analyzing natural resources in positive settings, an important aspect, namely how best to manage the resource revenues despite potentially harmful e ects on growth has been largely ignored 7. This paper combines the possibility of di erent growth regimes and the possibility of di erent spending policies in a uni ed framework in which the natural resource impact on economic growth and welfare is analyzed. We use a two-period overlapping generations model where individuals are altruistic in that parents care about the welfare of their children. Parents have the possibility to leave bequests, 5 A similar proposal is made by Sandbu (2004). He argues that tax revenues di er from resource revenues in that the rst is considered as out-of-pocket losses and the latter as forgone gains by members of society. In general, he argues, members of society are more likely to hold the government accountable for out-of-pocket losses than for forgone rents. 6 The authors consider in an appendix a situation where all individuals equally divide the resource revenue and nd that resource revenues are less harmful to savings than when only given to the old. 7 One exception is Matsen and Torvik (2005). They analyze an optimal intertemporal consumption path in a Dutch Disease model, and show that the growth maximizing policy di ers from the welfare maximizing policy. In their framework, this means some Dutch Disease is optimal. Within the literature of exhaustible natural resources, the literature of how optimally to manage resource revenues in order to achieve intergenerational equity is well established, see e.g. Hartwick (977), and Solow (974, 986). 3

5 which they will do when their altruism is su ciently high. In this case, the economy is dynastic and behaves like an in nitely-lived agent s model, whereas the economy behaves like an overlapping generations model when altruism is not intense enough and bequests are absent (cf. Barro 974). Natural resource revenues enter the model in every period as a xed fraction of man-made output. They are allocated by a given spending policy as direct transfers to members of society and as expenditures on a public service that works as input in production (in the sense of Barro 990). As rst pointed out by Weil (987), there is a threshold level of altruism that separates the two growth environments. Our paper shows that this threshold level of altruism is determined endogenously by the allocation of natural resource revenues and by the size of the resource ows. Nations with identical spending policies, but di erent resource in ows, and nations with identical resource in ows, but di erent spending policies, may therefore experience di erences in how the resource impacts economic development. We show by use of exogenous policies that the resource curse may occur when the bequests motive is not operative. In this case, under spending policies that allocate resources to the oldest generation, more resources may cause a drop in savings of the young and a subsequent decline in the economic growth rate. Yet, the e ect of a resource curse on welfare is ambiguous as spending policies exist for which the growth rate declines but welfare of the young generation is increased. An increase in consumption that follows from higher in ows of natural resource revenues may (more than) compensate for reduced growth rates. When the bequest motive is operative the resource curse is non-existing and 4

6 resource abundance increases both welfare and growth rates. Bequests interrupt the connection between in ows of natural resource revenues and savings by allowing for o setting intergenerational transfers from the oldest to the youngest. Therefore, consumption and saving are una ected by how resource revenues are allocated across generations. These results suggest an important caveat to the general recommendations by Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian (2003) and others. While trying to escape the resource curse created by political economy reasons by distributing revenues directly to members of society, a resource curse situation may be created due to economic factors instead. It seems reasonable to think of spending policies as typically endogenously determined by a speci c economic or political agenda. We study growth maximizing policies and policies chosen to give the highest feasible welfare of either the young or the old generation and examine if under such policies, potentially a resource curse situation may be triggered. In both cases, we nd possibility of multiplicity of equilibria. This means that ex ante identical nations may end up in ex post different growth regimes; expectations about whether bequests are positive or absent are self-ful lling. The resource curse is not triggered by growth maximizing policies. When bequests are absent, any direct transfers are given only to the young in order to increase savings and thus growth. Higher in ows of natural resources merely increase direct transfers and hence savings and growth. When bequests are positive, no revenues are allocated as direct transfers, since in a dynastic regime growth expands with more public services. Public services, in turn, expand with the resource 5

7 revenue in ow. Nevertheless, the resource curse may grow out of gerontocracies with in nitesimal levels of altruism. The old may allocate direct transfers to themselves to an extent that higher resource ows lead to decreased savings. In general, however, we cannot solve the welfare maximization problem. Nevertheless, if we restrict direct transfers to accrue only to the young, we show that resource curse may happen as the regime that yields highest welfare may not yield highest growth. It turns out that the competitive equilibria are sub-optimal. The sub-optimality partly stems from an externality that works through the production process, and partly from the budget restriction on public services. The rst reason is due to the fact that rms do not take into account the e ect of production on resource in ows and private decisions lead to underaccumulation of capital in this respect. The second reason is due to the fact that the budget available for the public service, which is con ned by the resource in ow, may be sub-optimally low. The social optimum can be decentralized by means of a production subsidy that allocates resource revenues entirely to the rm. In order to nance public services a lumpsum tax is levied on consumption. On a decentralized optimal balanced growth path, parents leave bequests, or are just indi erent between leaving bequests or not. Therefore, the resource curse does not exist. The results presented here are related to those of Papyrakis and Gerlagh (2004) but more general. In particular, we show that the resource curse is not robust to variation in allocation of natural resource revenue across generations in an economy with non-dynastic dynamics. The resource curse situation occurs as a special case. Moreover, we provide a political economy explanation for when it is likely to occur, 6

8 namely when an old generation which is not very altruistic decides the spending policy. Finally, our model is related to the literature that studies e ectiveness of economic policy in an altruistic setting. Caballe (998) analyzes how taxation of labor and capital in uences not only growth performance, but also the growth regime. In his model, the level of altruism that distinguishes the growth regimes is determined itself by the tax policy. Croix and Michel (2002) analyze the neutrality of economic policy when the bequest motive is operative. The paper proceeds as follows. We present the model in section two. In section three, we explain the market equilibrium and characterize the conditions for the altruism factor that distinguishes the growth regimes. In section four, we derive di erent spending policies and analyze the impact of natural resources on growth and welfare under those policies. In section ve, we study the optimal policy and the nal section provides concluding remarks. 2 The Model The economy is closed and described by a one sided altruistic overlapping generations framework. Parents care about the welfare of their o spring and have the possibility to make intergenerational transfers to their immediate descendants in the form of bequests. Individuals live for two periods, as young and as old. Only the young generation works, the old generation is retired. There are L individuals in each generation, which remains constant over time. 7

9 2. Natural Resource Revenues In every period t; an in ow from the sale of a natural resource enters the economy. The value of the revenues is exogenously given as a xed fraction of the real value of man-made output Y t where 0 < < : We may think of as a characteristic that is country speci c 8. Let E t denote the real value of the natural resource ow, then E t Y t : () In this way, our theoretical model also applies to in ows of foreign aid and other gifts and transfers from abroad. As the resource revenues are exogenously given and grow at the same rate as output, and therefore the revenue output ratio is constant over time, we focus purely on allocation questions of the resource revenue spending policy in relation to intergenerational transfers and economic growth 9. Similar ways of modelling of the natural resource (or foreign aid) ow are found in Chatterjee et al. (2003), Lensink and White (200), Papyrakis and Gerlagh (2004), and Torvik (200) Natural Resource Revenue Applications Based on a spending policy, a government spends all resource revenues in every period on potentially two purposes. First, it allocates a share where 0 < ; 8 The revenue output ratio varies considerably across countries. For instance, Iceland, Nigeria, Norway and Venezuela have a share of primary exports in GDP above 0.2, whereas Nepal, Sweden and the US have a share of primary exports below 0.. ( 9 For a reference on optimal resource extraction consult Dasgupta and Heal (979). 0 Torvik (200) discusses alternative ways of modelling the real value of the natural resource in- ow in footnote 4, p The important assumption is that the resource ow grows over time so that, as a share of income, it does not converge towards zero. 8

10 directly to members of society in a lump-sum fashion. Of this share is given to the young generation and ( ) to the old (0 ). Second, the government invests the rest of the resource revenues in a public service ow G t that works as input into production. We think of the public service as a broad range of services that could be infrastructure, administration, legal and environmental services, etc. There are no externalities associated with the use of public services. In every period, the government runs a balanced budget. It cannot issue debts nor run surpluses by accumulating assets. Hence, G t ( )E t ( )Y t : (2) Summing up, the resource constraint satis es 2.3 Firms E t + ( )E t + ( )E t E t Y t : (3) A representative rm produces output Y t and uses three factors in production: labor, the average public service ow per worker g t G t L, and capital K t : Output per worker y t is produced according to the following production technology, y t Akt gt : (4) where 0 < < is the share of labor and public services in production, A is a positive constant productivity term, and k t is capital per worker. Labor productivity increases, as the public service ow per worker g t increases 2. A real example of direct transfers of resource rents is found in Alaska. One purpose of the socalled Alaska Permanent Fund is to distribute the returns of the fund, which come from minerals and oil, to all inhabitants of the state in the form of a check (Hannesson 200). 2 The public service ow per worker is non-rival but subject to congestion from L: 9

11 The representative rm maximizes pro ts taking g t ; as well as the price of output, which is the numeraire, and of inputs as given. Capital fully depreciates in each period and each factor is paid its private marginal product 2.4 Altruistic Individuals Y t gt L ( )A + r t ; (5) K t K t Y t gt L A k t w t : (6) L t K t Individuals are identical within, as well as across, generations. A parent is altruistic with respect to the welfare of her o spring in the Barro (974) sense and weights her o spring s utility in her utility function V t : Let U t denote utility derived from lifecycle consumption, so that total utility of an individual at time t can be presented as V t U t + V t+ ; (7) where 0 < < is the intergenerational discount factor, which we refer to as the altruism factor. When generations are altruistic, parents care about the welfare of their children, who in turn care about the welfare of their children and so forth. In this way, welfare of all future generations is linked. Utility from own consumption is the sum of utility from consumption as young c t ; and the discounted utility of consumption as old c 2t+. Speci cally, U t u(c t ) + u(c 2t+ ) ln(c t ) + ln(c 2t+ ); (8) where 0 < < is the intertemporal discount factor. By recursively eliminating 0

12 V t+i ; i 0; :::; in (7) we have 3 P V t i [ln(c t+i ) + ln(c 2t++i )]; (9) i0 saying that the utility of a young individual born at time t equals own life-cycle utility plus the discounted sum of life-cycle utilities of her descendants. In any period t; the young individual inelastically supplies one unit of labor for which she receives the market wage w t. When > 0 she also receives a direct transfer as a share of the natural resource revenue, and nally she may inherit bequests b t from her parents. She consumes c t and saves s t for her retirement, hence c t + s t b t + w t + e t ; (0) where e t E t L denotes the lump-sum resource revenue income of a young at time t: When old, she receives the proceeds of her saving ( + r t+ )s t ; where r t+ is the real rate of interest. In addition, if < she receives income from the natural resource, which she consumes, and possibly bequeaths to her o spring. Accordingly, her period two budget constraint can be written as c 2t+ + b t+ ( + r t+ )s t + ( )e t+ ; () where ( )e t+ is the resource revenue given lump-sum to an old person at time t +. Bequests cannot be negative, i.e. b t+ 0: This restriction prevents parents from leaving debts to their children. The dynamics of bequests are found by eliminating s t in (0) and (): b t+ ( + r t+ )(b t + w t + e t c t ) + ( )e t+ c 2t+ : (2) 3 Eq. (7) can be rewritten by induction as V t P T i0 i [u(c t+i ) + u(c 2t++i )] + T + V t++t : Taking the limit for T! and assuming that total utility satisfy the limit condition lim T! T + V t++t 0 we get V t P T i0 i (U t+i ): Using U t ln(c t ) + ln(c 2t+ ) we have (9).

13 An individual of generation t maximizes life time utility given in (9) subject to the two budget constraints (0) and (), and the non-negativity constraint on bequests, by optimally choosing consumption, savings and bequests taking b t ; w t ; r t+ ; e t and e t+ as given. The Lagrangian of period t is equal to life-cycle utility U t with the change, p t+ b t+ p t b t ; in the shadow price p t of b t over a period (Croix and Michel 2002, 244) L t ln(c t ) + ln(c 2t+ ) + p t+ b t+ p t b t : (3) Note that b t+ 0 implies ( + r t+ )(b t + w t + e t ) + ( )e t+ ( + r t+ )c t + c 2t+ : Incorporating this restriction in the maximization problem, the optimality conditions, which are both necessary and su cient, are given by c t ( + r t+) c 2t+ ; (4) and b t+ c t+ 0 ( 0 if b t+ > 0): (5) c 2t+ The transversality condition is lim t! t p t b t 0: (6) Equation (4) describes the trade-o between consumption as young and old. In optimum, the individual is indi erent between consuming as young and saving for old consumption. Equation (5) says that if bequests are positive, marginal utility of own consumption as old has to equal marginal utility of consumption of the o spring as young. If a parent s marginal utility from her o spring s consumption is less than the marginal utility of her own consumption, then bequests are zero and the solution is given by a corner solution. 2

14 3 Competitive Equilibrium For simplicity, we normalize the number of working people L to unity, and we can write E t e t ; Y t y t ; K t k t and G t g t : We obtain the following condition by rewriting (4) using (2): y t Ak t ( )yt k t, y t [A( ) ] kt f(; ; )k t (7) where f(;;) < 0: The larger the share of the natural resource revenues that is spent on direct transfers, the smaller the public service ow. This implies a smaller public service ow capital ratio, gt k t. Due to the AK structure of the model, it also leads to a drop in the output capital ratio. Therefore, all things equal, f(;;) > 0; higher resource in ows increase public services. Using (4), factor market clearing implies and using (7) in (8) and (9), we get r t ( )A( g t k t ) ; (8) w t A( g t k t ) k t : (9) r t ( )f(; ; ) r(; ; ); (20) w t f(; ; )k t w(; ; )k t ; (2) where w(; ; ) denotes the wage capital ratio. Since both the real rate of return and the real wage are positively associated with the public service ow capital ratio g t k t ; more resources allocated to direct transfers decrease both the real rate of return and the real wage; r(;) < 0 and w(;) < 0. The capital market equilibrium requires savings to equal capital installed in the 3

15 productive sector s t k t+ : (22) Finally, the goods market equilibrium is given by the aggregate resource constraint. Using the budget constraints (0), () and the equilibrium conditions (2), (20), (2), and (22) the aggregate resource constraint can be expressed as ( + )y t c t + c 2t + k t+ + g t : (23) The total income period t is the sum of man-made output plus the natural resource revenue given as direct transfers. 3. Dynamics In the following, we distinguish two growth regimes of the economy based on the presence of intergenerational transfers. When parents marginal utility of own consumption is larger than marginal utility of the o spring s consumption, the nonnegativity constraint on bequests is binding and there are no bequests. 3.. Zero Bequests Assume that (5) holds with inequality so that bequests are absent. Letting b t b t+ 0 in (0) and (), we can, by also using (4), derive the an expression for the savings s t : s t + [w(; ; )k t + e t ] ( )e t+ ( + )[ + r(; ; )] : (24) Savings are increasing in wages and resource revenues received as young and decreasing in resource revenues received as old. This is intuitive; the smaller the income as old compared to income as young, consumption smoothing requires higher savings. 4

16 Using (22), we get k t+ + [w(; ; )k t + e t ] ( )e t+ ( + )[ + r(; ; )] ; which is the law of motion of capital. Dividing both sides by k t ; we get 0 t+ + [w(; ; ) + e t k t ] ( ) et k t ( 0 t+ + ) ( + )[ + r(; ; )] ; where 0 t+ (k t+ k t ) is the growth rate in the economic growth regime without bequests of capital and also capital per worker due to a constant labor force. Rearrange to get 0 t+ et [ + r(; ; )][w(; ; ) + k t ] 0 (; ; ; ; ): (25) ( + )[ + r(; ; )] + ( ) et k t We de ne a balanced growth path as a path along which c t ; c 2t ; k t ; y t ; g t and e t grow at constant relative rates in all periods t > 0. From (7) it follows that capital grows at the same rate as output. Since resource revenues are given as a xed fraction of output (in ()) it follows immediately that also the ow of natural resource revenues grows at the same rate as output. Moreover, as public services are given as a xed fraction of total resource revenues (in (2)), public services grow at the same rate as output. From the goods market equilibrium in (23), it follows that aggregate consumption (c t and c 2t ) grows at the same rate of output. By (4), (20) and r t r(; ; ); it then follows that period one and period two consumption grow at the rate output. Hence, the bequest constrained economy has no transitional economics; c t ; c 2t ; k t ; y t ; g t and e t grow at the same rate along a balanced growth path at all periods t. We denote values taken by the variables on the balanced growth path without bequests with the superscript 0 : Using (20), (2), noting that e t y t f(; ; )k t ; 5

17 and taking k 0 > 0 as given, equilibrium is given by c 0 + ( ) t f(; ; )( + ) ( + )( ) + ( ) k0 t ; (26) c 0 2t f(; ; )[ + ( )]k 0 t ; (27) k 0 t+ ( )f(; ; )( + ) ( + )( ) + ( ) k0 t : (28) On this growth path, parents behave as if they are sel sh as they do not leave intergenerational transfers. Essentially, the economy behaves like a overlapping generations model. Growth is positive when income received in period one is su ciently large to ensure that savings exceeds the capital depreciation. Accordingly, ( )f(; ; )(+ ) > ( + )( ) + ( ) implies that 0 (; ; ; ) > 0: 3..2 Positive Bequests When bequests are positive, (5) holds with equality. The growth rate of period one consumption is found by dividing the rst order solutions given in (4) and (5) I t+ [ + r(; )] I (; ; ; ): (29) Again, we de ne a balanced growth path as a path along which c t ; c 2t ; k t ; y t ; g t ; b t and e t grow at a constant relative rates in all periods t > 0. From (7) it follows that capital grows at the same rate as output. Since resource revenues are given as a xed fraction of output (in ()) it follows immediately that the ow of natural resource revenues grows at the same rate as output. Moreover, as public services are given as a xed fraction of total resource revenues (in (2)), also public services grow at the same rate as output. By the goods market equilibrium in (23) and r t r(; ; ) it must be that if capital and output grow as the same rate, then this rate equals that of consumption. 6

18 From (4) we know that consumption as old and young is a constant ratio, so old consumption grows at the same rate as young consumption. From either of the budget constraints (0) or () it follows that also bequests grow at the same rate as consumption. Thus, the bequest constrained economy has no transitional economics; c t ; c 2t ; k t ; y t ; g t ; b t and e t grow at the same rate along a balanced growth path at all periods t. From the rst order conditions to (3) it can be shown that p t equals c t when bequests are positive 4. Hence, p t decreases at the rate I (; ; ): We can thus conclude that when b t > 0; p t b t is a constant, and the transversality condition in (6) simpli es to <. When (5) holds with equality, parents leave bequests and the economy behaves like a dynasty of in nitely-lived generations. We denote values taken by the variables on the balanced growth path with positive bequests with the superscript I : Equilibrium is given by + [ + ( + )]( ) b I t f(; ; ) + + ( ) c I t f(; ; ) + + ( ) c I 2t f(; ; ) + kt I ; (30) kt I ; (3) kt I ; (32) k I t+ f(; ; )( )k I t ; (33) with k 0 > 0. Along this growth path the growth rate is positive when +r(;;) : This condition says that for a young individual to have positive savings and bequests, the marginal utility of returns to savings discounted at the intergenerational discount factor, the altruism factor, obtained by the o spring must exceed the marginal 4 L By (3), t c t 0 implies that c t p t+ [ + r(; ; )]; and Lt b t 0 implies that p t p t+ [ + r(; ; )], so it follows that c t p t : 7

19 utility of her own consumption. Clearly, in general the growth rates described by (25) and (29) will di er as will the way they respond to changes in the resource ow and spending policies. 3.2 The Resource Curse We can think of two possibilities of why an economy may wind up being resource cursed, namely when spending policies are such that increased resource ows (i) lead to savings decline, and (ii) lead to a the regime shift to a regime with a lower growth rate. In the following we examine both possibilities Savings Decline Indeed, we nd that savings may be negatively in uenced by increased resource in ows. In particular, Proposition. There exist policies that imply a resource curse only when bequests are absent. Proof. First, when bequests are absent along 0 (; ): 0 (;) n f(;;) ( )( + ) + f(; ; )[( ) ( )(+)( ) (+)( )+( ) ] o R 0: In particular, a policy where 0 and ( 2) > (+)( )+( ) ( ) ( + ) implies 0 (;;;) < 0: Second, in the dynastic growth regime, I (;) ( ) f(;;) > < proves the non-existence of a resource curse when bequests are positive. An operative bequest motive eliminates the resource curse as the growth rate in this regime is increasing in the real rate of return to capital, which, in turn, is increasing in in ows of natural resources, r(;;) > 0. Savings are una ected by the allocation of direct transfers, si t 0; as any change in revenues given to a young 8

20 individual is o set by an identical opposite change in bequests 5. Hence, the rate of growth in this environment I (; ; ) is independent of : When bequests are absent, accumulation of capital responds to the distribution of resource revenues across generations. For example, a policy that distributes all direct transfers solely to the old generation may lead to a resource curse outcome, in which, more generous resource ows result in less savings. The resource curse prevails when the positive e ect that resource ows have on wages is not large enough to increase the marginal utility of young consumption as much as the marginal utility of discounted old consumption. The lower the labor share in production, i.e. the lower ; the worse the curse if present 6. What generates the resource curse is a disproportional large direct transfer to the old generation in the situation where bequests are absent. Therefore, Proposition 2. When direct transfers are absent, or when they, if present, are allocated only to the young generation, the resource curse does not exist. Proof. By proposition we only have to analyze an economy without bequests. h i When 0; 0 (;;;) f(;;) > < and when ; (+) h i 0 (;;;) f(;;) ( )( + ) + f(; ; )( ) > (+)( ) < : A higher in ow of natural resources in the economy allows, ceteris paribus, for more resources to be spent on public service ows. This enhances the public service ow capital ratio and thus the real wage and the real rate of return. When 5 To see this notice that along a balanced growth path (2) can be rewritten as b I t (+r())(w()k I t +ei t c I t )+( )(+I ())e I t w()k I t + e I t ) (+I ())c I t where bi (+ I t ()) (+r()) ei t : Now, write s I t + (bi t + ( )(+ I )e I t (+ I ())b I t (+)(+r()) : Calculating si t (+) (+) +(+)( (+) )+ + 6 It can be shown that if 9 using bi t ei t gives si t 0: then 0 (;;;) 0:

21 direct transfers are positive, also the direct transfers given to the young generation increase, young income goes further up relative to old income, and savings grow. We make an interesting observation about the resource curse: Proposition 3. Higher in ows of natural resource revenues may improve welfare for a young generation, despite causing a resource curse. Proof. See appendix. Next, we turn to examine if the resource curse exist when an economy switch regime as a consequence of higher resource in ows Growth Regime Shifts Though the altruism factor is exogenously given, whether bequests are positive or zero is determined endogenously by the rst order condition given in (5). From (5) we know that when parents marginal utility of own consumption is greater than their marginal utility from the o spring s consumption, the economy is without bequests. A decline in the consumption of the o spring relative to consumption of the parent triggers intergenerational transfers, if the decline is large enough. We de ne the threshold value of the altruism factor such that under a given spending policy (; ) when then 0 (; ; ; ) I (; ; ). In this special case, the non-negativity constraint on bequests is just binding. Inverting (29) and substituting in (25), using (20) and (2) yields ( + ) ( + )( ) + ( ) (; ; ; ; ): (34) Using the de nition of given in (34) we obtain the standard result (Caballe 998; Cardia and Michel 2004; Weil 987) that when the altruism factor is less than the 20

22 threshold value, < (; ; ; ); the economy is without bequest and the growth path is described by (25). On the other hand, when the altruism factor is higher than the threshold value, > (; ; ; ), bequests are positive and growth evolves according to (29). We can now compare growth rates in the two regimes: Proposition 4. Under exogenous policies (; ), everything else equal, an economy with an altruism level that ensures positive bequests grows faster than an economy with an altruism level that leads to absence of bequests. Proof. We note that by (34) equation (25) can be rewritten as 0 (; ; ; ) (; ; ; )( a)f(; ; ) : Since the economy follows this growth path as long as < (; ) but changes to I (; ; ) ( a)f(; ; ) with positive bequests when > (; ) it must be that 0 (; ; ; ) < I (; ; ): We observe in particular that (; ; ; ) is a function of the spending policy as well as the size of the natural resource ow. The more direct transfers given to the young ; the more altruistic the parents must be to leave bequests, and the more direct transfers given to the old ( ); less altruistic parents also leave bequests. In general, changes in amplify di erences in direct transfers across generations, and, we give the following direct transfer allocation rules: When [( + )( in ; i.e. (;;;) (;;;) > (<)0: ) + ] is there no e ect on (; ; ; ) from changes 0; and when < (>)[( + )( ) + ] we have that Therefore, changes in may push economies from one growth regime to another. The question, what happens to the growth rate, when increases in cause the regime to shift is answered in the following: 2

23 Proposition 5. For a given spending policy (; ), when the economy moves from one growth regime to another growth regime due to increased in ows of natural resources, the growth rate goes up. Proof. See appendix. Summing up, this section illustrates that spending policies matter and they matter di erently depending on the presence of bequests. The resource curse prevail as a consequence of savings decline, i.e. s t < 0; whereas regime shifts caused by endogenous changes in the threshold altruism factor lead to higher growth rates. Finally, we noted that the resource curse and welfare gains may be opposite sides of the same coin. 4 Political Equilibrium In this section we ask a slightly di erent question, namely if there are economies in which the resource curse exist under endogenous policies. We examine speci c policy objectives with an eye for this. 4. Growth Maximizing Policies Let b 0 and b 0 be the growth maximizing policy when the economy is without bequests, i.e. (b 0 ; b 0 ) arg max ; 0 (; ; ; ): Lemma. Then b 0 and ( 0 if b if 2 > 0 : Proof. See Appendix. The intuition for this result is as follows. When direct transfers are positive 22

24 and given to the young, in uences 0 (; ; ; ) through two channels between which there is a trade-o. The higher the higher direct transfers (to the young generation) which, ceteris paribus, leads to higher savings for retirement. However, the higher ; the less public service input into private production. Lower public service input into production leads to lower marginal factor productivity. Lower wages means less savings for retirement. Moreover, less public service input into production means less man-made output. Since resource revenues are de ned as a xed fraction of total output, this e ect feeds back into lowering the total amount of resource revenues to be distributed in the rst place. When b 0 and b 0 (; ) savings are maximized, and generate the highest feasible growth rate in a no bequest environment. We notice that when the value of b 0 is given by a corner solution, the rate of economic growth would increase further if the government is able to collect lump-sum taxes to expand the public service. In such a situation the size of the public service ow is sub-optimal. Notice also that b 0 (;) > 0 when 2 > 0: This means that the higher the in ow of natural resources, a larger share should be given as direct transfers in order to maximize growth. The reason is that the larger ; the higher the value of one unit of direct transfer. Higher costs, in terms of lower factor payments, can therefore be tolerated. Let b I be the growth maximizing policy when bequests are positive, i.e. b I arg max I (; ; ): Lemma 2. Then b I 0: Proof. Because I (;;) r(;;) < 0 we have that b I 0: 23

25 In the in nitely-lived generations environment, the growth maximizing policy is independent of the magnitude of the in ows of the natural resource revenues: letting resource revenues work as input into production leads to higher growth rates since the real rate of return is maximized when direct transfers are zero. Combining lemma and 2, it can be shown that when 2, the growth max- imizing policy is identical for the two growth regimes, namely zero direct transfers. The lower the value of the resource in ow for given, the lower the value of direct transfers relative to wages, and hence savings are increased when all revenues are used as investment in public services. Proposition 6. A resource curse does not exist under growth maximizing policies; increased in ows of natural resources enhance growth. Proof. See Appendix. The growth maximizing spending policy depends on the strength of altruism in the economy. For high values of the altruism factor, in order to enhance growth, all resource revenues should be invested in public services. However, for low values of the altruism factor, the growth maximizing policy is to allocate a share of the natural resource revenues as direct transfers to the young. Under growth maximizing policies, by proposition, 2, and lemma it follows immediately that when the economy after a change in remains in its initial growth environment, it will not su er from the resource curse in neither growth environment. Yet, by (34) we know that also the threshold altruism factor depends on and in order to completely exclude the resource curse as a possibility under growth maximizing policies, we must also analyze the relationship between the rate of eco- 24

26 nomic growth and when the economy may shifts growth regime in response to changed resource ows. We observe multiplicity of equilibria for a range of resource in ows. However, the government by de nition frame policies as to achieve the highest growth rate. They will therefore not choose policies that send the economy in a regime with a lower growth rate. Yet, growth maximizing policies may su er from another potential problem, namely dynamic ine ciency. When bequests are absent, the only way for the young to provide for themselves when old is to save, which they may do even when the interest is very low. In this case, transferring resources from the young generation to the old generation is Pareto e cient. Dynamic ine ciency in endogenous growth models occurs when the competitive real rate of interest falls short of the growth rate (King and Ferguson 993). This condition corresponds to 0 (; ; ) > r(; ; ), (; )( a)f(; ; ) > ( a)f(; ; ) () (; ) >. Under growth maximizing policies, only the young receives direct transfers if any, i.e. (b 0 ; b 0 ; ; ) (+) ; therefore growth + maximizing policies trigger dynamic ine ciency when > + absent. when bequests are Just like in the exogenous policy case, this section points out a trade-o between growth gains and welfare costs when bequests are absent. We therefore proceed to study the resource impact under welfare maximizing policies. 25

27 4.2 Young and Old Policies In this section, we assume that either the young or the old decide a policy that is implemented by the government. The policy remains unaltered in perpetuity 7. The policy decision is made at the beginning of the period. After determining the policy, the young earn a wage, decide their savings, and possibly receive a direct transfer and/or bequests. The old receive a return on their savings and possibly leave bequests. At time t; the utility of a young person is given as in (9): V Y oung t P i0 i [ln(c t+i ) + ln(c 2t++i )]; (35) + ln(c t ) + ln(c 2t ) + ln[ + (; )] : (36) The young derive utility of own consumption both as young and as old. The old, on the other hand, only derive utility of own consumption as old: V Old t ln(c 2t ) + P i0 ln(c 2t ) + +i [ln(c t+i ) + ln(c 2t++i )]; (37) + ln(c t ) + ln(c 2t ) + ln[ + (; )] : (38) When altruistic, both young and old derive utility of consumption of the o spring. However, Proposition 7. The resource curse exists when spending policies are decided by an old generation with in nitesimal levels of altruism. Proof. See Appendix. When the economy is borderline non-altruistic, a policy decided by the old can trigger a resource curse. This may not be surprising in that the old generation 7 A similar assumption is made in Alesina and Rodrik (994). 26

28 care overridingly about their own consumption. Yet, since the old receive a higher return to savings the higher the real rate of return, the old do not claim all resource revenues. A part, if not all, of the resource ow is still allocated to public services. Therefore, a non altruistic economy ruled by the old is not cursed per de nition. Unfortunately, solving generally the welfare maximizing policy of either generation cannot be done analytically in this model. Yet, by imposing an additional assumption to the problem, we are able to obtain analytical results. Assumption. Only the young receives direct transfers from natural resource revenues. We refer to policies under assumption as semi-endogenous policies, as the assumption exogenously determines the intergenerational allocation of direct transfers. Assumption is not binding when bequests are positive, since any change in the distribution of direct transfers of natural resource revenues across generations is o set by an opposite change in bequests. Assumption does, however, a ect the threshold altruism factor positively, which push economies towards being in the overlapping generations regime. When bequests are absent, by proposition 2, assumption ensures that the resource curse does not prevail due to savings decline. We therefore focus on examining if a resource curse exists due to regime shifts enforced by changed resource ow. Under assumption, let Y oung and Old denote the policy that maximizes V Y oung t and Vt Old. As the public budget is restricted by 0 < ; utility maximizing policies may not be feasible. Therefore, let and denote the spending policy that yields the highest level of utility for the young and the old generation 27

29 respectively. Then, 0 if Y oung 0 Y oung if Y oung > 0 and 0 if Old 0 Old if Old > 0 : (39) The utility maximizing resource revenue transfers are negative when a person is willing to make positive lump-sum payments to the government to increase the size of the public service. In this case, expanded public services increase the real wage and the real return to capital leading to an overall increase in utility, thereby making the person better o. We analyze this possibility in the next section, but for now, the size of the public service may be restricted by in ows of natural resource revenues as they were under growth maximizing policies. Let 0 be the spending policy that maximizes young welfare when the economy is without bequests, and let I be the spending policy that maximizes young welfare when bequests are positive. Moreover, de ne 0 ) 0 : Then, under assumption, + and I ( ( )++ Lemma 3. Young policy: ( ( 0 if 0 0 if I 0 0 if (+ 0 ) 0 > and ( ) I I [ ( )] if I > ( ) : (+ I ) Proof. See Appendix. Likewise, let 0 be the spending policy that maximizes welfare of the old generation when bequests are absent, and let I be the spending policy that maximizes old welfare when bequests are present. Moreover, de ne 0 and I ( )( + ) ( ) 2 +( )++ : Then, under assumption, + ( ) 2 +( )++ Lemma 4. Old policy: ( ( 0 if 0 0 if I 0 0 if (+ 0 ) 0 > and ( ) I I [ ( )] if I > ( ) : (+ I ) 28

30 Proof. See Appendix. We notice that the young and old spending policies, and ; are both functions of the intertemporal and intergenerational discount factors as well as the resource in ow; (; ; ; ) and (; ; ; ): For both growth regimes is the marginal loss of increasing direct transfers the decline in public service input into productions and thus factor payments. The marginal bene t stems from increased direct transfers. The trade-o faced by the individual depends on the weights given in her welfare function, which, in turn, depends on whether she is old or young, and the growth dynamics. For example, we notice that when bequests are absent, all things equal, the young are more likely to implement a spending policy that involves direct transfers; 0 > 0 and 0 () 0 > 0 and 0 () 0 > 0: The young generation values the utility of own consumption in their utility function undiscounted, whereas the old discounts the o springs utility of young consumption using the intergenerational discount factor. The marginal utility the young obtain from direct transfers is therefore larger and o sets higher marginal utility costs that the direct transfers impose. It is straightforward to show that under assumption, increased in ow of natural resource revenues increase both growth and welfare of the young and the old under both a young and an old policy when the growth regime remains unaltered. Under both policies, c0 t we have that V Old t > 0; ci t > 0 and V Y oung t > 0; c0 2t > 0; ci 2t > 0; 0 I > 0 and > 0, and > 0 8 and 0 < within regimes. Moreover, lemma 3 and 4 imply that policies, and therefore also growth rates, may vary across generations. However, there is no systematic variation, so either a young economy or an old economy may grow faster in either regime. However, 29

31 when direct transfers are zero, within regimes, no matter if policies are decided by the young or the old the growth rate remains the same Growth Regime Shifts Having laid out the semi-endogenous policies of an economy ruled by the young or the old in lemma 3 and 4, this section focuses on analyzing what happens to the growth rates when increased in ows of natural resources enable growth regime shifts. It su ces to analyze either young or old policy to understand the economics of the regime shifts. We choose an economy ruled by the young and apply a numerical example given by A ; 0:4, 0:4 and 0:8 so that 0 5:4 4:56 and I 3:24 4:56 : Threshold altruism; altruism; growth Xi Figure. Young policy In gure, the thin horizontal line illustrates the altruism factor. The threshold altruism factor is illustrated by the bifurcate line. The horizontal part of the 30

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth Florian Misch a, Norman Gemmell a;b and Richard Kneller a a University of Nottingham; b The Treasury, New Zealand March

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice 1. MWG - Decisive Subgroups Recall proposition 21.C.1: (Arrow s Impossibility Theorem) Suppose that the number of alternatives is at least

More information

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation Edgar A. Ghossoub The University of Texas at San Antonio Abstract Most studies that use an overlapping generations setting assume complete depreciation

More information

Exercises on chapter 4

Exercises on chapter 4 Exercises on chapter 4 Exercise : OLG model with a CES production function This exercise studies the dynamics of the standard OLG model with a utility function given by: and a CES production function:

More information

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Sta Report November 2009 Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies Geo rey Heal and Bengt Kristrom May 24, 2004 Abstract In a nite-horizon general equilibrium model national

More information

The Dutch Disease and Intergenerational Welfare

The Dutch Disease and Intergenerational Welfare The Dutch Disease and Intergenerational Welfare Jørgen Juel Andersen y June 2011 Abstract Governments in resource abundant economies face a tradeo between transferring wealth to present generations and

More information

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set 3 Solutions

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set 3 Solutions 4.454 - Macroeconomics IV Problem Set 3 Solutions Juan Pablo Xandri 05/09/0 Question - Jacklin s Critique to Diamond- Dygvig Take the Diamond-Dygvig model in the recitation notes, and consider Jacklin

More information

1 Two Period Production Economy

1 Two Period Production Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 3 1 Two Period Production Economy We shall now extend our two-period exchange economy model

More information

The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role. of Fiscal Policy Revisited

The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role. of Fiscal Policy Revisited The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role of Fiscal Policy Revisited Santanu Chatterjee y Department of Economics University of Georgia Sugata Ghosh z Department of Economics and Finance

More information

The Role of Physical Capital

The Role of Physical Capital San Francisco State University ECO 560 The Role of Physical Capital Michael Bar As we mentioned in the introduction, the most important macroeconomic observation in the world is the huge di erences in

More information

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469 Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469 1 Introduction and Motivation International illiquidity Country s consolidated nancial system has potential short-term

More information

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium? Money in OLG Models 1 Econ602, Spring 2005 Prof. Lutz Hendricks, January 26, 2005 What this Chapter Is About We study the value of money in OLG models. We develop an important model of money (with applications

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 1 Imperfect Credibility of Policy: Trade Reform 1.1 Model Assumptions Output is exogenous constant endowment (y), not useful for consumption, but can be exported

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Policy, 8/2 206 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal behavior and steady-state

More information

Companion Appendix for "Dynamic Adjustment of Fiscal Policy under a Debt Crisis"

Companion Appendix for Dynamic Adjustment of Fiscal Policy under a Debt Crisis Companion Appendix for "Dynamic Adjustment of Fiscal Policy under a Debt Crisis" (not for publication) September 7, 7 Abstract In this Companion Appendix we provide numerical examples to our theoretical

More information

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the form Economic Growth and Development : Exam Consider the model by Barro (990). The production function takes the Y t = AK t ( t L t ) where 0 < < where K t is the aggregate stock of capital, L t the labour

More information

Optimal Progressivity

Optimal Progressivity Optimal Progressivity To this point, we have assumed that all individuals are the same. To consider the distributional impact of the tax system, we will have to alter that assumption. We have seen that

More information

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #4 (version 1.3)

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #4 (version 1.3) Economics 202A Lecture Outline #4 (version.3) Maurice Obstfeld Government Debt and Taxes As a result of the events of September 2008, government actions to underwrite the U.S. nancial system, coupled with

More information

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS 5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS We studied how individual consumers and rms behave in Part I of the book. In Part II of the book, we studied how individual economic agents make decisions when there are strategic

More information

Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA

Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics I (IKT 233) Ozan Eksi Practice Questions (for Midterm) Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA 1-)... variables are determined within the model (exogenous

More information

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking (preliminary draft) Ying Syuan Li National Taiwan University Yiting Li National Taiwan University April 2009 Abstract We consider an economy where people have the needs

More information

Simple e ciency-wage model

Simple e ciency-wage model 18 Unemployment Why do we have involuntary unemployment? Why are wages higher than in the competitive market clearing level? Why is it so hard do adjust (nominal) wages down? Three answers: E ciency wages:

More information

The New Growth Theories - Week 6

The New Growth Theories - Week 6 The New Growth Theories - Week 6 ECON1910 - Poverty and distribution in developing countries Readings: Ray chapter 4 8. February 2011 (Readings: Ray chapter 4) The New Growth Theories - Week 6 8. February

More information

Lecture Notes 1

Lecture Notes 1 4.45 Lecture Notes Guido Lorenzoni Fall 2009 A portfolio problem To set the stage, consider a simple nite horizon problem. A risk averse agent can invest in two assets: riskless asset (bond) pays gross

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Henrik Horn (Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm) Giovanni Maggi (Princeton University) Robert W. Staiger (Stanford University and

More information

II. Competitive Trade Using Money

II. Competitive Trade Using Money II. Competitive Trade Using Money Neil Wallace June 9, 2008 1 Introduction Here we introduce our rst serious model of money. We now assume that there is no record keeping. As discussed earler, the role

More information

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth Alberto Bisin October 29, 2009 Question Consider a two period economy. Agents are all identical, that is, there is

More information

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result Arantza Gorostiaga Rubio-Ramírez Juan F. Universidad del País Vasco Duke University and Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Abstract

More information

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Stephen R. Bond Institute for Fiscal Studies and Nu eld College, Oxford Måns Söderbom Centre for the Study of African Economies,

More information

1 Unemployment Insurance

1 Unemployment Insurance 1 Unemployment Insurance 1.1 Introduction Unemployment Insurance (UI) is a federal program that is adminstered by the states in which taxes are used to pay for bene ts to workers laid o by rms. UI started

More information

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1 Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose,

More information

Income Distribution and Growth under A Synthesis Model of Endogenous and Neoclassical Growth

Income Distribution and Growth under A Synthesis Model of Endogenous and Neoclassical Growth KIM Se-Jik This paper develops a growth model which can explain the change in the balanced growth path from a sustained growth to a zero growth path as a regime shift from endogenous growth to Neoclassical

More information

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies Harris Schlesinger Department of Finance, University of Alabama, USA Center of Finance & Econometrics, University of Konstanz, Germany E-mail: hschlesi@cba.ua.edu

More information

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality . 1 Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality Lutz Hendricks Iowa State University, CESifo, CFS March 28, 2004. 1 Introduction 2 Wealth is highly concentrated in U.S. data: The richest 1% of households

More information

On the Political Complementarity between Globalization. and Technology Adoption

On the Political Complementarity between Globalization. and Technology Adoption On the Political Complementarity between Globalization and Technology Adoption Matteo Cervellati Alireza Naghavi y Farid Toubal z August 30, 2008 Abstract This paper studies technology adoption (education

More information

Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements

Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements Mostafa Beshkar (University of New Hampshire) Eric Bond (Vanderbilt University) July 17, 2010 Prepared for the SITE Conference, July

More information

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate University of British Columbia Department of Economics, International Finance (Econ 556) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout #3 1 1 on-traded goods and the real exchange rate So far we have looked at environments

More information

The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups

The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups November 9, 23 Abstract This paper compares the e ciency implications of aggregate output equivalent

More information

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation Pai-Ling Yin First Draft: October 2002 This Draft: June 2005 Abstract This paper proposes tests to empirically examine whether auction prices aggregate information

More information

Optimal Dutch Disease

Optimal Dutch Disease Optimal Dutch Disease Egil Matsen y Ragnar Torvik z Abstract Growth models of the Dutch disease explain why resource abundance may reduce growth. The literature, however, also raises a new question: if

More information

Problem Set # Public Economics

Problem Set # Public Economics Problem Set #5 14.41 Public Economics DUE: Dec 3, 2010 1 Tax Distortions This question establishes some basic mathematical ways for thinking about taxation and its relationship to the marginal rate of

More information

Partial Centralization as a Remedy for Public-Sector Spillovers: Making Interjurisdictional Transportation a National Responsibility

Partial Centralization as a Remedy for Public-Sector Spillovers: Making Interjurisdictional Transportation a National Responsibility Partial Centralization as a Remedy for Public-Sector Spillovers: Making Interjurisdictional Transportation a National Responsibility Christophe Feder Università degli Studi di Torino, Italy April 27, 2015

More information

Exploding Bubbles In a Macroeconomic Model. Narayana Kocherlakota

Exploding Bubbles In a Macroeconomic Model. Narayana Kocherlakota Bubbles Exploding Bubbles In a Macroeconomic Model Narayana Kocherlakota presented by Kaiji Chen Macro Reading Group, Jan 16, 2009 1 Bubbles Question How do bubbles emerge in an economy when collateral

More information

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing /49 Introduction We present models of asset pricing where investors preferences are subject to psychological biases or where investors

More information

Cross-Border Tax Externalities: Are Budget De cits. Too Small? 1

Cross-Border Tax Externalities: Are Budget De cits. Too Small? 1 Cross-Border Tax Externalities: Are Budget De cits Too Small? 1 Willem H. Buiter 2 Anne C. Sibert 3 Revised 4 April 2005 1 cwillem H. Buiter and Anne C. Sibert 2005. The views and opinions expressed are

More information

Pareto-Improving Bequest Taxation. Volker Grossmann* and Panu Poutvaara**

Pareto-Improving Bequest Taxation. Volker Grossmann* and Panu Poutvaara** Pareto-Improving Bequest Taxation by Volker Grossmann* and Panu Poutvaara** * University of Fribourg; CESifo, Munich; and Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn. Postal address: Department of Economics,

More information

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 26/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case

More information

Inequality and the Process of Development. Lecture II: A Uni ed Theory of Inequality and Development

Inequality and the Process of Development. Lecture II: A Uni ed Theory of Inequality and Development The Classical Approach The Modern Approach CICSE Lectures, Naples Lecture II: of Inequality and Development June 9, 2009 Objectives The Classical Approach The Modern Approach A uni ed theory of inequality

More information

Compositional and dynamic La er e ects in models with constant returns to scale

Compositional and dynamic La er e ects in models with constant returns to scale Compositional and dynamic La er e ects in models with constant returns to scale Anders Fredriksson a,y a Institute for International Economic Studies (IIES), Stockholm University, SE-106 91 Stockholm,

More information

D S E Dipartimento Scienze Economiche

D S E Dipartimento Scienze Economiche D S E Dipartimento Scienze Economiche Working Paper Department of Economics Ca Foscari University of Venice Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi Illiquidity and Under-Valutation of Firms ISSN: 1827/336X No. 36/WP/2008

More information

Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers

Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers Vasileios Zikos University of Surrey Dusanee Kesavayuth y University of Chicago-UTCC Research Center

More information

Self-Financing Education, Government Policies, and Economic Growth

Self-Financing Education, Government Policies, and Economic Growth Self-Financing Education, Government Policies, and Economic Growth Hoang D. Duong Departament d Economia Aplicada Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Fernando Sánchez-Losada Departament de Teoria Econòmica

More information

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4 Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4 Introduction Multiple goods Role of relative prices 2 Price of non-traded goods with mobile capital 2. Model Traded goods prices obey

More information

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model T.Huw Edwards Dept of Economics, Loughborough University and CSGR Warwick UK Tel (44)01509-222718 Fax 01509-223910 T.H.Edwards@lboro.ac.uk

More information

SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 5

SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 5 Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 5 The Solow AK model with transitional dynamics Consider the following Solow economy production is determined by Y = F (K; L) = AK

More information

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model Zhiwei Xu (xuzhiwei@sjtu.edu.cn) Solow model (Solow, 1959) is the starting point of the most dynamic macroeconomic theories. It introduces dynamics and transitions into

More information

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics ISSN 974-40 (on line edition) ISSN 594-7645 (print edition) WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY

More information

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function Eurilton Araújo Insper Working Paper WPE: 23/2008 Copyright Insper. Todos os direitos reservados. É proibida a reprodução

More information

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from: Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ On the Implementation of Markov-Perfect Monetary Policy Michael Dotsey y and Andreas Hornstein

More information

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University WORKING PAPER NO. 11-4 OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University Daniel R. Sanches Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia December 2010 Optimal

More information

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters Khaled Bennour 2006 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7233/ MPRA Paper No. 7233, posted. September

More information

Keynesian Multipliers with Home Production

Keynesian Multipliers with Home Production Keynesian Multipliers with Home Production By Masatoshi Yoshida Professor, Graduate School of Systems and Information Engineering University of Tsukuba Takeshi Kenmochi Graduate School of Systems and Information

More information

Energy & Environmental Economics

Energy & Environmental Economics Energy & Environmental Economics Public Goods, Externalities and welfare Università degli Studi di Bergamo a.y. 2015-16 (Institute) Energy & Environmental Economics a.y. 2015-16 1 / 29 Public Goods What

More information

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 805 Extra Problems on Production and Uncertainty: Questions and Answers Winter 003 Prof. Peck () In the following economy, there are two consumers,

More information

Optimal Trade Policy and Production Location

Optimal Trade Policy and Production Location ERIA-DP-016-5 ERIA Discussion Paper Series Optimal Trade Policy and Production Location Ayako OBASHI * Toyo University September 016 Abstract: This paper studies the role of trade policies in a theoretical

More information

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D by Eytan Sheshinski* (Contribution to the Baumol Conference Book) March 2005 * Department of Economics, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, ISRAEL.

More information

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics Roberto Perotti November 20, 2013 Version 02 Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics 1 The intertemporal government budget constraint Consider the usual

More information

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics Instructor Min Zhang Answer 3 1. Answer: When the government imposes a proportional tax on wage income,

More information

The Economics of State Capacity. Weak States and Strong States. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th 2008.

The Economics of State Capacity. Weak States and Strong States. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th 2008. The Economics of State Capacity Weak States and Strong States Ely Lectures Johns Hopkins University April 14th-18th 2008 Tim Besley LSE Lecture 2: Yesterday, I laid out a framework for thinking about the

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first introduce and discuss the intertemporal budget

More information

The Economics of State Capacity. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th Tim Besley LSE

The Economics of State Capacity. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th Tim Besley LSE The Economics of State Capacity Ely Lectures Johns Hopkins University April 14th-18th 2008 Tim Besley LSE The Big Questions Economists who study public policy and markets begin by assuming that governments

More information

Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version

Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version Andreea Cosnita and Jean-Philippe Tropeano y Abstract We develop a theoretical model to compare the current ex post

More information

Using Surveys of Business Perceptions as a Guide to Growth-Enhancing Fiscal Reforms

Using Surveys of Business Perceptions as a Guide to Growth-Enhancing Fiscal Reforms Using Surveys of Business Perceptions as a Guide to Growth-Enhancing Fiscal Reforms Florian Misch, Norman Gemmell and Richard Kneller WORKING PAPER 04/2014 January 2014 Working Papers in Public Finance

More information

Stochastic No-Ponzi-Game condition and government debt dynamics

Stochastic No-Ponzi-Game condition and government debt dynamics Stochastic No-Ponzi-Game condition and government debt dynamics Chen He Supervisor Prof.dr.Lex Meijdam Tilburg University Number of words: 6536 May 30, 2012 Abstract This paper concerns the optimal government

More information

The ratio of consumption to income, called the average propensity to consume, falls as income rises

The ratio of consumption to income, called the average propensity to consume, falls as income rises Part 6 - THE MICROECONOMICS BEHIND MACROECONOMICS Ch16 - Consumption In previous chapters we explained consumption with a function that relates consumption to disposable income: C = C(Y - T). This was

More information

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin 4.454 - Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin Juan Pablo Xandri Antuna 4/22/20 Setup Continuum of consumers, mass of individuals each endowed with one unit of currency. t = 0; ; 2

More information

Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA

Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics I (IKT 233) 2017/18 Fall-Ozan Eksi Practice Questions with Answers (for Midterm) Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA 1-)... variables are determined

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Indirect Taxation and the Welfare Effects of Altruism on the Optimal Fiscal Policy Carlos Garriga and Fernando Sánchez-Losada Working

More information

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017 For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market June 017 This appendix contains the proofs and additional analyses that we mention in paper but that

More information

The Representative Household Model

The Representative Household Model Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model The representative household class of models is a family of dynamic general equilibrium models, based on the assumption that the dynamic path of aggregate consumption

More information

Borrowing Constraints, Parental Altruism and Welfare

Borrowing Constraints, Parental Altruism and Welfare Borrowing Constraints, Parental Altruism and Welfare Jorge Soares y Department of Economics University of Delaware February 2008 Abstract This paper investigates the impact of borrowing constraints on

More information

Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers

Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers Elif Incekara y Department of Economics, Pennsylvania State University June 006 Abstract In this paper, we show that the consumer might be unresponsive

More information

Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments

Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments 1 Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments David C. Mills, Jr. 1 Federal Reserve Board Washington, DC E-mail: david.c.mills@frb.gov Version: May 004 I explore

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

Problem Set # Public Economics

Problem Set # Public Economics Problem Set #3 14.41 Public Economics DUE: October 29, 2010 1 Social Security DIscuss the validity of the following claims about Social Security. Determine whether each claim is True or False and present

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus Summer 2009 examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2008/2009 syllabus Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours. This paper contains nine questions in three sections. Answer question one

More information

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Introducing nominal rigidities. Introducing nominal rigidities. Olivier Blanchard May 22 14.452. Spring 22. Topic 7. 14.452. Spring, 22 2 In the model we just saw, the price level (the price of goods in terms of money) behaved like an

More information

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing Guido Ascari and Lorenza Rossi University of Pavia Abstract Calvo and Rotemberg pricing entail a very di erent dynamics of adjustment

More information

Fuel-Switching Capability

Fuel-Switching Capability Fuel-Switching Capability Alain Bousquet and Norbert Ladoux y University of Toulouse, IDEI and CEA June 3, 2003 Abstract Taking into account the link between energy demand and equipment choice, leads to

More information

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II ECON 532) Practice Problems III Q: Consumption Theory CARA utility) Consider an individual living for two periods, with preferences Uc 1 ; c 2 ) = uc 1

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

CER-ETH - Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich

CER-ETH - Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich CER-ETH - Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich Economics Working Paper Series Eidgenössische Technische Hochschule Zürich Swiss Federal Institute of Technology Zurich Human Capital, Resource Constraints

More information

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Microeconomics, IB and IBP Microeconomics, IB and IBP ORDINARY EXAM, December 007 Open book, 4 hours Question 1 Suppose the supply of low-skilled labour is given by w = LS 10 where L S is the quantity of low-skilled labour (in million

More information

Optimal monetary policy and economic growth

Optimal monetary policy and economic growth Economics Working Papers (2002 206) Economics 4-25-2006 Optimal monetary policy and economic growth Joydeep Bhattacharya Iowa State University, joydeep@iastate.edu Joseph Haslag University of Missouri

More information

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints The University of Hong Kong From the SelectedWorks of Yulei Luo 00 Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints Yulei Luo, The University of Hong Kong Eric Young, University of Virginia Available

More information

DO GATT RULES HELP GOVERNMENTS MAKE DOMESTIC COMMITMENTS?

DO GATT RULES HELP GOVERNMENTS MAKE DOMESTIC COMMITMENTS? ECONOMICS AND POLITICS 0954-1985 Volume 11 July 1999 No. 2 DO GATT RULES HELP GOVERNMENTS MAKE DOMESTIC COMMITMENTS? ROBERT W. STAIGER* AND GUIDO TABELLINI We investigate empirically whether GATT rules

More information

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

1 Multiple Choice (30 points) 1 Multiple Choice (30 points) Answer the following questions. You DO NOT need to justify your answer. 1. (6 Points) Consider an economy with two goods and two periods. Data are Good 1 p 1 t = 1 p 1 t+1

More information