Price Level Determination when Requiring Tax Payments in Paper Money

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Price Level Determination when Requiring Tax Payments in Paper Money"

Transcription

1 Price Level Determination when Requiring Tax Payments in Paper Money Hannes Malmberg and Erik Öberg Work in progress, September 25, 2013 Abstract We explore the consequences of requiring consumers to pay taxes in paper money in a general equilibrium model without frictions. We show that a government policy that determines 1) the price by which the government exchanges money for goods, 2) the nominal tax level and 3) the interest rate at which the government trade money intertemporally together form a sufficient condition for having a unique positive price sequence for money. We also show this set of nominal policy tools uniquely determines the level of real government consumption. 1 Introduction In this paper we develop general equilibrium model which pins down the price level as a function of fiscal policy. We show that Hahn s problem, We have benefited greatly from insightful comments and help by Phillipe Aghion, David Domeij, Tore Ellingsen, John Hassler, Per Krusell, Lars Ljungqvist, Dirk Niepelt, Lars EO Svensson and seminar participants at the SUDSWEC conference in Stockholm. All mistakes are our own. hannes.malmberg@iies.su.se; erik.oberg@iies.su.se 1

2 that of excluding equilibria were money has zero value, can be solved by requiring tax payments in government printed paper money. Given that we can exclude non-monetary equilibria, we also show that by emitting money via purchases of real goods, the government can uniquely pin down the price level with fiscal policy. The intuition of the model can be explained in a simple story. Suppose we live in a one-period world, where the state pays $10,000 to anyone working in the military and requires every citizen to pay $1,000 in a lump sum tax. Assume that taxes can be paid in dollars only. Given sufficiently hard punishment for not paying taxes, it is clear that a 1/10 th of the population will work in the military in order to achieve the necessary money for tax payments. Also, if there is an option is to produce y of a private good, labor market equilibrium requires that yp = 10, 000 p = 10, 000/y, where p is the money price of the private good. Government ensures a unique value for government consumption and price level given nominal government wages and taxes. Thus, the model ensures that paper money has positive value in equilibrium. In this paper, we will formalize and extend this story in a general equilibrium setting. We will show how the theory sheds light on the fiscal determination of monetary variables, including the price level, and the interconnection of bond issues, government consumption, government wage levels, tax levels and nominal interest rates. Our theory manages to determine the price level without resorting to the tools used by other fiscal explanations of monetary phenomena such as the fiscal theory of the price level (FTPL) and seigniorage explanations 2

3 of the price level. In the FTPL, the price level is determined by equating the real value of outstanding nominal debt with the real value of all future primary surpluses (?). Our model can explain the price level even when the government runs a balanced budget and there is no outstanding government debt. In seigniorage theories of the price level, a money demand function is posited and the monetary effects of fiscal policy is analyzed by finding the price level equilibrating money demand with supply given the government s seigniorage generating strategy, for example see (?). Our model, on the other hand, also works in a cashless economy where there is no transaction demand for money. It will turn out that our model has important implications for the interpretation of monetary phenomena. To illustrate its workings, we introduce progressively more complex models, allowing us to sequentially illustrate the different mechanisms in operation. We begin in section 2 with a one-period endowment model where we show the basic workings of price level determination in our theory. In section 3, we add a transaction induced demand for money and show that the proposed mechanism of price level determination still hold and also that the model provide a novel interpretation of the quantity equation of money. In section 4, we use a multi-period model to illustrate how bond policy, interest rates, government consumption, taxes, and the price level are jointly determined in our economy. In section 5, we perform a number of monetary experiments and discuss policy implications. We conclude the paper by discussing to model s ability to meet with requirements needed for any monetary theory. Before closing the introduction we review the history of legal restriction theories of money. The idea is old, notably put forth by? and?. The first attempt to formalize it is due to?. In a static Walrasian economy with 3

4 exchanges constrained to goods for money -barters (exchanging a real good for another good thus requires at least two exchanges) and where money were given as endowments to agents, he showed that requiring taxes to be paid in money can indeed ensure a positive value of money in equilibrium. However, as Starr also showed, this is not true for all parametrizations of the tax system. If the tax system is designed such that after taxes has been collected, the money endowment is not exhausted, money is no longer a scarce resource and therefore cannot maintain a positive value in equilibrium. This non-robustness was raised by? as a critique against the legal restrictions theory of money. However, as will be clear after having introduced our model this non-robustness arose in Starr s economy solely because money was introduced as an endowment and not treated endogenously.? also raised the issue that even if requiring taxes to be paid in money can support a positive price of money, it might be exceeded by the price implied by the transaction induced demand for money. If money is more highly valued as a medium of exchange than as a specie for tax payments, we cannot interpret the legal restriction equilibrium as the true monetary equilibrium. This question on price level determination is the principal motivation for the model we present in section 3. As we will show there, this critique does not take into account the equilibrium effects when the stock of money is endogenous - the price level will still be determined through the same channel as in the economy without any transactions motive for holding money. We therefore argue that legal restrictions can indeed provide a foundation of monetary analysis. There has also been an attempt to integrate legal restrictions in a search model of money (?). Agents are randomly matched with other agents, government purchasers and government tax collectors. Taxes are required to 4

5 be paid in government printed money. If not having enough money when meeting a collector, a large punishment is dealt. Tax collectors are only encountered directly after trade with other agents. Agents are thus willing to give up goods to the government purchasers in order to avoid the punishment after trading with other agents, which provides government money a positive value. Government money is made unique medium of exchange if the punishment is large enough. The model thus have the virtue of explicitly accounting for how government policy can promote the use of government money as medium of exchange in competition with other currencies, but the result hinges on the assumption that tax collectors are met either directly or never after a trade has been made. We treat the legal restrictions in the same manner as Starr (1972), by requiring taxes to paid at the end of every period with certainty instead. 2 One-period model A representative consumer seeks to maximise his utility U which is increasing in consumption C. His problem is given below. The consumer has an endowment of W real goods. There exist two markets in which trades can be done. A private market where the consumer can exchange goods for privately held money. The relative price of private money M p in terms of real goods is denoted p m. The inverse of p m will be interpreted as the price level. In the other market, the consumer can sell real goods to the government in exchange for government money M g. The government sets the price of government money in terms of real goods, which will be denoted p g. Ex ante we need to separate between government and private money because the government will be able to control the price p g but not the 5

6 market price of money p m. We capture this scheme in the first constraint of the consumer problem. At the end of the period, the consumer is required to pay a lump sum tax T in money. This is captured in the second constraint. The government will be a monopolist in the production of money and is thus indifferent whether the consumer pay his taxes in money received from a private source, M p, or via direct trade with the government M g. M p is government money that has been bought by the consumer second hand in the private market. The government only trades one way, and will not relinquish goods in return for money, so even if the consumer had a wish to go short in trade with the government, this is not possible. There is, however, no constraint on trading in privately held money. Finally, we also impose non-negativity on consumption. max U(C) (1) C,M p,m g s.t. C + p m M p + M g p g W (2) T M p + M g (3) M g 0 (4) C 0 (5) In this model, the quantity M g p g represents the real goods in government hands at the end of the period, and thus, government consumption is determined by the consumer s choice of M g p g. Thus, we will write G = M g p g, while recognizing that G is an endogenous variable. The government chooses the tax level T and how many goods it is willing to buy for one unit of money p g. We will assume that only the government 6

7 can print money and thus there is no net supply of money in the private market, i.e. M p = 0. To exclude a situation where people cannot possibly pay their taxes, we forbid the government to choose parameters such that money does not suffice to pay taxes even though people sell all their endowment to the government. That is, we require T p g W. Otherwise, the government is free to let its nominal parameters take any value. However, as soon as the government seeks to achieve a consumption target, it is constrained by having to set its parameters to make its consumption target a market outcome. Thus, if the government aims at consumption level Ḡ, it has the constraint Ḡ = M g (T, p g )p g (6) The reader may already see the direction of this exercise. As mentioned above, we must have M p = 0 in equilibrium. Hence, when the government sets T > 0 the second constraint gives us M G = T > 0. Arbitrage conditions then give us that p m = p g ; if p m > p g, the consumer would gain unbounded utility by selling goods to government and exchanging money for goods in the private market. If p m < p g the consumer would choose M p > 0, thereby violating the condition of zero net supply of money in the private market. As long as the government set p g > 0, government policy has, using nominal instruments only, ensured government consumption, given money value, and pinned down the price level. We provide a formal argument following a standard equilibrium definition: Definition 1 A competitive equilibrium as an allocation {C, G, M P, M g }, a 7

8 government policy {T, p g } and a price system {p m } s.t. Given prices and government policy, the allocation solves the consumer s problem The real resource constraint is satisfied: C + G W The money resource constraint is satisfied: M p + M g M Only the government can print money: M p 0 The equilibrium calculations are then simple: Proposition 1 Given that the government policy satisfies T p g < W and p g > 0, there exist a unique equilibrium where p m > 0. Moreover, in equilibrium government consumption G is determined by government policy {T, p g } Proof. Money market constraints require M p = 0. The consumer s problem gives p g p m with equality if M g > 0 As T > 0 and M p = 0, we have M g = τ > 0. Thus, we get and allocations are then p m = p g G = T p g C = W T p g We see from the resource constraint that this equilibrium exist if and only if T p g W. 8

9 Given that all money the is sent into circulation via government expenditure is taken out of circulation via tax payments, the price level is uniquely determined by the nominal price offered by the government is exchange for real goods. Note that the fact that quantity of money M = M g is endogenous make the equilibrium robust. Starr s analysis was on the presumption of money being a fixed endowment. Hence, taxation could support a positive price of money if and only if the tax system is designed such that for all money prices p m < b, the sum of taxes collected will exceed the money endowment. This non-robustness has been used as critique against the legal tender theory of money (Calvo, 2012). However, in the light of our model, this critique seems invalid. If the equilibrium quantity of money is endogenous, the consumers will never acquire more money than what is required to pay their taxes. As such, the only requirement on government tax policy is that the consumer knows what her nominal tax level when she engages in the market. Moreover, proposition 1 shows that any level of government consumption G [0, W ] can be implemented and is uniquely determined by the policy decision {T, p g }. It may thus be reasonable to understand the existence of money as a solution to a fiscal problem. In an unpublished manuscript under construction, we raise the question if requiring taxes to be paid in government printed money is an distortion-minimizing solution for implementing a government tax system given any government consumption target Ḡ when there is imperfect information on equilibrium prices. The general problem is that a real goods tax system will distort production if the relative taxation value of real goods differs from market relative prices. If requiring taxes to be paid in government printed money, no information on market prices is needed to implement a non-distorting tax system.. 9

10 3 One period model with a money-in-the-utility function The model presented in section II cannot in a strict sense be said to be a monetary model, since money did not carry any transaction-facilitating function. We will now incorporate such a function and study the implications of a legal restriction constraint. This can be done in many ways, we will proceed with the ordinary money-in-the-utility function for no other reason than its mathematical simplicity. The exercise is important for three questions. First, as Calvo (2012) conjectured, although a legal restriction might exclude equilibria were money is not valued, the transaction-facilitating function of money may raise its price above the price implied by a legal restriction. As such, we cannot treat the legal tender equilibrium as the true monetary equilibrium. However, we will show that the price level determination mechanism will not change when adding transaction purposes to our model. Rather, the equilibrating mechanism is adjusting the money stock to equate supply and demand at any given price level. Secondly, we will see that our model flips the interpretation of the quantity equation. In standard environments where money carries a transactionfacilitating function, the money supply is exogenous. Here it is endogenous, and as such, the interpretation of the quantity equation will go from prices to the money stock rather than the other way around. We proceed with setting up the model. We will consider two environments, differing in the timing of tax payments. If taxes are collected after trade in the private market has been conducted, the money holdings entering utility is M p + M g. If taxes are collected pre-trade, the argument is 10

11 M p + M g T. This timing difference will have implications for the money stock in equilibrium, and as such, also the amount of government consumption in equilibrium. Hence, we will study both environments. 3.1 Post-trade tax payments The model will be exactly the same as in section II, apart from the incorporation of real money balances in the utility function. We will assume that utility U is additively separable in consumption and real money holdings, U = u(c) + v((m p + M g )p m ), that both u and v are increasing and concave and that u satisfies the Inada conditions. It is common to assume that also v satisfies Inada conditions, since this excludes any equilibrium where money is not held and valued. However, this assumption seems empirically implausible since it is observable that trade can be conducted without money. We do not need it since non-monetary equilibria can be excluded with the legal tender constraint. The consumer problem is max u(c) +v((m p + M g )p m ) (7) C,M p,m g s.t. C + p m M p + M g p g W (8) T M p + M g (9) M g 0 (10) C 0 (11) The equilibrium definition is identical to the model in section II. As in section II, uniqueness follows: Proposition 2 Given that the government policy satisfies T p g < W and p g > 0, there exist a unique equilibrium where p m = p g. Moreover, in 11

12 equilibrium government consumption G is determined by government policy {T, p g } The proof is established in much the same fashion as in section II. It is left in the appendix. Notice that even though we have added a utility increasing function of money, the price level in equilibrium does not change. No arbitrage stills implies that given a government policy for p g we have that p m = p g. Only the quantity of money in equilibrium can be affected. The latter effect can be better understood by looking at the first order conditions: u (C) λ 1 + λ 3 = 0 (12) v ((M p + M g )p m )p m λ 1 p m + λ 2 = 0 (13) v ((M p + M g )p m )p m λ 1 p g + λ 2 + λ 4 = 0 (14) where λ 1,..., λ 4 are the Lagrange multipliers. Now, λ 3 = λ 4 = 0 holds in optimum. p m = p g, M p = 0 and C = W M g p m holds in equilibrium. We thus get the equilibrium condition u (W M g p m )p m + λ 2 = v (M g p m )p m (15) By the proof of 2:, we know that there exist a T such that for all T T, λ 2 = 0 and for for all T > T, λ 2 > 0 in any solution to the consumer s problem. Moreover, we also know that λ 2 is strictly increasing in the parameter value T whenever T > T. With this characterization at hand, equation 15 is easy to interpret. We know that u is increasing and v decreasing in real money holdings M g p m. Assuming that taxes are such that the tax constraint is not binding, the quantity of money is determined by the intratemporal tradeoff shown in graph 1. This means that the consumer will buy more 12

13 money from the government than the amount she is required to pay back in taxes. The equilibrium quantity of money is then equal to a model with only consumption in the utility function. Now consider the case where the tax level is increased such that the tax constraint becomes binding, say from T to T. This means that the required real tax payments T p m are higher than the amount of real money holdings that would be optimal without any legal restriction constraint. Then λ 2 > 0 which will bump up the left hand side of 15 such that it intersects the right hand side where the M g = T. This is illustrated in graph 2. 13

14 3.2 Pre-trade tax payments With pre-trade tax payments, the real money balances entering utility is (M p + M g T )p m. Everything else will be the same as in the model above. The equilibrium tradeoff between real money balances and consumption becomes u (W M g p m )p m + λ 2 = v ((M g T )p m )p m (16) The only thing that has changed is that the argument on the left hand side has been reduced by a constant. As such, 1 and 2 still applies. However, the tax constraint will start binding at a higher level. If taxes are high enough, the Inada conditions on u will shift all spending towards consump- 14

15 tion. 3.3 Comments We have thus seen that adding money in the utility function can increase the equilibrium quantity of money compared to the model with only consumption in utility. The requirement is that taxes are low enough. If we were to make the marginal utility of holding real money balances high enough, it is clear that the consumer will demand a greater money balances than the required tax payments for any given price level. A peculiar feature of the model is that it produces a reversed interpretation of the quantity equation. We cannot perform the classical monetarist experiment of doubling the money supply since the stock of money is endogenous. We can, however, pursue the experiment of doubling the price level, that is decreasing p g by 50 per cent. To hold government real consumption constant, this must be done in conjunction with doubling T. Equilibrium condition 16 then requires that M g is doubled. Our model thus implies a causal relationship from the price level to the stock of money rather than the other way around. We urge the reader to take this as a preliminary result. As we will see, we need to be more careful when analysing the stock of money in a multiperiod framework, as will be discussed in section 5. An well-known implication is that transaction induced demand for money creates the opportunity for seinorage taxing. When the quantity of money increases, so must government consumption G for any given price policy p g. Consumers will for the purpose of getting enough real money balances sell more real goods to the government than what is required to pay back in taxes and as such G = M g p g > T p g. 15

16 We stress that the equilibrating mechanism is by adjusting the quantity of money M g since the price level 1 p m is indirectly determined by the government via equilibrium condition p m = p g. Giving money an extra utility increasing function (such as facilitating trade) does not change the fact that government purchasing policy determines the price level. Hence, The critique put forth by Calvo (2012) that a legal tender constraint will not affect the price level when money carries such a function does seem invalid. 4 Infinite horizon model We extend our theory to an infinite horizon setting. To this aim, we make only one non-trivial modification to the one period-model, namely the introduction of a one-period risk-free money bond. We view money borrowing as running a deficit on one s tax account, or equivalently as getting a resource which is perfectly substitutable with M pt and M gt from the one-period model as means of paying taxes. This market structure allows us to understand the intertemporal constraints on government s behavior in our model, as well as laying foundations for more sophisticated models with realistic policy experiments. Also, as there is no uncertainty, government bonds will provide complete markets provided has a positive value in every period. Thus, the restriction of the set of intertemporal assets to government bonds is non-essential for the economic interpretation of the model. Our aim in this section is to establish the criteria for government money being valued, and express the value of money as a function of the government s choice variables. Furthermore, we want to show that for every feasible sequence of {g t } t=0, there exists a sequene of nominal government 16

17 prices {p gt } t=0, nominal taxes {T t} t=0 and nominal interest rates {i t+1} t=0 implementing {g t } as a unique equilibrium outcome. There is one important technical aspect of the model: the form of the no Ponzi-condition. As always with per-period trading, we have to rule out Ponzi schemes to ensure that households optimization problems are wellbehaved. Usually, this is done by noting that the market would not advance any loans to an agent planningan unsustainable sequence of debt holdings, as they will not be paid back. However, the government is not profit-making, so we cannot rely directly on this argument to conclude that a Ponzi game in money is unsustainable. Furthermore, the constraint when money has zero value in every period is not easy to interpret. In this case, people can run up debts growing as fast as the rate of interest, while the value of the debt in terms of individual goods endowments would always be 0. We need to exclude this case, as our price level determination mechanism relies on non-arbitrage conditions between government and private prices, and this mechanism requires an interior solution. If people can run Ponzi schemes, they can pay taxes by taking money loans, and pay interest rates and refinancing by lifting new loans. If the value of money is zero, the real value of debt is also zero. Thus, no one needs to work for the government, and in this case, we cannot exclude the non-valued money equilibrium. Thus, it is clear that we need a nominal no Ponzi-constraint. Analyzing the problem further, we note that if someone is allowed to run a Ponzi scheme, the government will advance loans, the repayments of which are inconsistent with the price sequence {p gt } that the government seeks to implement. Assuming that the government has a belief in its ability to implement a particular price sequence, we will constrain the agents to be consistent with 17

18 repayment of their loans if the state is successful in implementing its desired price sequence. This is also a canonical borrowing constraint in that it agrees with the natural borrowing limit whenever money is valued. 1 Below are the equations governing our model. Noe the similarity to the first period model. Equation (19) formalizes the tax account interpretation of money loans, but can equivalently be seen as a consolidation of a tax constraint with a flow account balance at the central bank. Equations (22)- (23) implements the nominal borrowing constraint discussed above. max {C t,m pt,m gt} t=0 U(C t ) (17) s.t. C t + p mt M pt + p gt M gt W t (18) where I t+1,s = s j=t+1 sup t 0 T t M p + M g (B t+1 (1 + i t )B t ) (19) C t 0 (20) M gt 0 (21) B t+1 W t+s p g,t+s = A t I t+1,t+s (22) (1 + i j ) s=1 A t < (23) Notice that the bonds B t+1 do not show up in the real budget constraint (18). However, B t+1 can be traded for money M pt as shown in the tax constraint (19). Assuming p mt = p gt 0 (as we will show below), (18) and (19) can then be consolidated: 1 The fact that this agrees with the natural borrowing limit means that this borrowing constraint on money loans leads to markets being incomplete once money is valued, a private market will yet again be redundant 18

19 C t + T t p mt + B t+1 p mt W t + (1 + i t )B t p mt (24) which the reader will recognize as a standard consumer per-period budget constraint. 4.1 Equilibrium in the multi-period model As in the single-period model, we are interested in how the government can use the tools at its disposal to implement a preferred sequence of government consumption. There are different choices for what the government takes as exogenous or endogenous: the government can for example choose to target bond issues or interest rates. However, throughout this section, we will assume that the government chooses sequences {p gt, T t, i t+1 } t=0. We will show that subject to very mild restrictions, every policy choice by the government implies a unique equilibrium. Secondly, we will show that any feasible sequence of government consumption can be implemented by an appropriate tax/pricing policy. Definition 2 A competitive equilibrium is a set of government policies {p gt, T t, i t+1 } t=0, a set of allocations {c t, g t, M gt, M pt, B t+1 } t=0 prices {p mt } t=0 such that: and a set of private money Consumers maximize (17) given prices, government policy, and constraints (18)-(22). Resource constraints for goods C t + p g,t M t W t, and private money M pt = 0, hold in every period. 19

20 Proposition 3 Suppose the government chooses a policy {p gt, T t, i t+1 } t=0 satisfying T t > 0 and i t > 0 in every period, the sequence {p gt } t=0 is bounded, taxes satisfy lim s s t=0 T t and t=0 T t I t < t=0 p gt W t I t, where I 0 = 1 and I t = t s=1 (1 + i s). Then, there exists Ī0,t s.t. for all I 0,t > Ī0,t there exist a unique competitive equilibrium, and it will have p mt = p gt. The proof is included in the technical appendix. The idea behind it is this. We first establish that p m,t 0 in every period. This is true as consumers otherwise will try to settle all their tax liabilities for all time by trading private goods for money at an infinite exchange rate in the period where the price of money is zero. Some technical issues arise because binding borrowing constraints on the optimal path may hinder the consumers to settle all tax liabilities in this manner. However, we show that such a tax repayment schedule is possible, and this establishes that M g,t = 0 for all time periods i.e. no one will ever work for the government. The second step of the proof is to show that an equilibrium where no one works for the government is not possible if taxes are positive. In particular, we show that not working for the government leads to an exponentially increasing nominal debt burden which will eventually break the borrwing constraint (22). Proposition 3 shows that any feasible government policy uniquely pins the down the price level of the economy and the level of government consumption. The imposed requirements are technical. The government bonds 20

21 serve the purpose of tax smoothing and hence consumption smoothing. Also equivalent to the one-period model, we can show that the government can use the set of policy tools to implement any feasible government consumption target {G t } t=0 : Proposition 4 Assume all conditions in Proposition 3. Given a government policy target Ḡ = {Ḡt} t=0 that satisfies G T < W t for all t, there exist a policy sequence {p gt, T t, i t+1 } t=0 s.t. in equilibrium. {M gtp gt } t=0 = {Ḡt} t=0 Proof. By the proof of proposition 1, we know that there exist a interest rate paths I 0,t such that p mt = p gt for all t. Assume the government set I 0,t such that this holds. In equilibrium, the Euler equation then become u (W t M gt p gt ) = β(1 + i t+1 ) p gt+1 p gt u (W t+1 M gt+1 p gt+1 ) (25) Together with the consolidated budget constraint, this equation uniquely pins down the the path of {M gt } t=0 = {Ḡt} t=0 for any choice of {p gt} t=0 = {Ḡt} t=0. 5 Policy implications in the infinite-horizon model 6 Conclusion This paper presents a skeleton for a novel monetary theory. There are four important features that we believe a good monetary theory should possess, which are the requirements we want to measure our theory against. 1. The theory should explain why money is valued, and exclude a zerovalue equilibrium. 21

22 2. The theory should uniquely pin down the price level as a function of the behaviour of the monetary authority. 3. The theory should be possible to integrate into a wide range of economic environments. 4. The theory should allow us to analyze monetary policy within the setting of the theory. In this paper, we have showed that our theory satisfies the first three requirements. We have demonstrated that non-zero taxes and the pricing policy of the government uniquely determines the sequence of prices in the economy. Furthermore, this has been done both in a single-period and a multi-period model, both with and without a transactions motive for holding money. All analysis has also been done in a standard neo-classical framework, which makes extensions to a wide range of canonical models straightforward. What we have not yet achieved within the model is to analyze monetary policy. For an interesting model of monetary policy, we neede a multi-period model with a transactions motive for money, and this is beyond the scope of this paper, but is the topic of a sister paper to this one (Malmberg & Öberg, 2013). It is also important to point out that this is not a model of fiat money as characterized by?. Wallace stressed that fiat money should be inconvertible and intrinsically useless. In our main model, money is intrinsically useless, but they are not in a strict sense inconvertible. They can be interpreted as being convertible into get out of jail free -cards, in the sense that the transfer of money to the government relieves you of the punishment of not paying taxes (as the requirement is strict, we can view this as an infinite punishment for paying to little taxes). Indeed, one purpose of our model is 22

23 to show that even after formal convertibility to specie has been abolished, government issued paper money in modern economies is not fiat money in the sense suggested by Wallace. Technical appendix Proof of Proposition 2. Optimality conditions of the consumer s problem are u (C) λ 1 + λ 3 = 0 (26) v ((M p + M g )p m )p m λ 1 p m + λ 2 = 0 (27) v ((M p + M g )p m )p m λ 1 p g + λ 2 + λ 4 = 0 (28) where λ 1,..., λ 4 are the Lagrange multipliers. Now, λ 3 = 0 by Inada and λ 4 = 0 holds in equilibrium since M p = 0. If p m > p g the consumer would sell all his endowment W to the government in return for W/p g money units. Since W/p g > T, the consumer can then buy (W/p g T )p m > 0 in the private market which violates the resource constraint. If p m < p g the consumer would buy all money needed for tax payments in the private market which would violate equilibrium condition M p > 0. We must thus have p g = p m in equilibrium. Optimality conditions then reduces to u (W M g p m )p m + λ 2 = v (M g p m )p m (29) We provide to intermediate results: Lemma 1 There exist a T such that for all T T, λ 2 = 0 and for all T > T, λ 2 > 0 in any solution to the consumer s problem. 23

24 Proof: We know that the solution is unique and interior. If M g = T we have that u (W T p m )p m + λ 2 = v (T p m )p m (30) Now, this can be true if and only if v (T p m )p m u (W T p m ) > 0. Since both u and v are concave there exist a T such that v (T p m )p m + u (W T p m ) 0 for all T T and v (T p m )p m + u (W T p m ) > 0 for all T > T. Lemma 2 There exist a T such that for all T > T, λ 2 is strictly increasing in the parameter value T in any solution to the consumer s problem. Proof: By 1, we know that there exist a T such that for all T > T, λ 2 > 0. Whenever λ 2 > 0, we have that λ 2 = v (M g p m )p m u (W M g p m )p m (31) by 29, which by strict concavity of u and v is strictly increasing in T. With these results we know that M g is strictly increasing in T in equilibrium. Uniqueness follows. Proof of Proposition 3. We first establish p mt > 0 for all t. Let us proceed by contradiction, and assume that t is the first period for which p mt = 0. We seek to show that the condition M ps 0 will be violated for some time period s, that is, we will have an excess demand for money in the private market at some point if p mt = 0 for any time period. To do so, we will first show that we have M gs = 0 in all periods. 24

25 If p mt = 0, M gs = 0 for all s t. That is, after the time period where money is free, no one will ever again sell goods to the government. Indeed, any plan involving M gs > 0 can be improved upon by reducing M gs to 0, increasing consumption by p gs M gs, and replacing the money shortfall by increasing M pt by M gs /( s j=t+1 (1 + i j)) and invest it in bonds. As p mt = 0, this can be done without forfeiting any time-t consumption. Furthermore, if the borrowing constraint is not binding at any time s < t, we also have M gs = 0. Indeed, if M gs > 0, we could increase consumption at time s by reducing M gs by ɛ and borrow money to make up the shortfall. We repay ɛ(1 + r s+1 ) (1 + r t ) in time-t at zero cost in consumption terms. Thus, if there does not exist any binding borrowing constraint at any time s < t, we have M gs = 0 for all s. Let us now assume that s is the last time period for which the borrowing constraint is binding, that is B s+1 = A s. However, as the borrowing constraint is not binding at any time between s+1 and t, we get that M g,s+1 = 0, and equilibrium gives us that M p,s+1 0. Therefore, using T t > 0, the tax constraint gives us B s+2 M p, s+1 + M g, s+1 (1 + i s+1 )B s+1 T t < (1 + i s+1 )B s+1 = (1 + i s+1 )A s = (1 + i s+1 )W s+1 p g, s+1 A s+1 < A s+1. Thus, we violate the borrowing constraint, which is not allowed. Hence, we 25

26 conclude that the borrowing constraint does not hold in any time period, and therefore, M g,s = 0 for all s. Now, we show that an allocation with M g,s an equilibrium. M p,s = 0, we get = 0 for all s cannot be Using the tax constraint and the equilibrium constraint B t+1 t I s,t T s (1 + i) t T 0. s=0 As sup t A t <, we eventually will break the borrowing constraint. Hence, we have shown that p m,t > 0 in all time periods, and thus fiat money is valued in our model. We seek to show that given a price sequence {p gt, i t+1, T t }, there exists a unique competitive equilibrium. First, we use sup t A t < + to consolidate the consumer s tax constraint (using that it will always hold with equality, as p mt > 0 for all t), to get t=0 M gt + M pt I 0,t = t=0 T t I 0,t. Thus, we reduce the consumer s choice set to private and government money holdings in every period. After substituting in constraint (18) into the consumer s objective function, and using M gt 0, the consumer s Lagrangian becomes ( β t u (W t M gt p gt M pt p mt )+µ t M gt +λ max M gt,m pt t=0 The f.o.c.:s become t=0 M gt + M pt I 0,t T t I t=0 0,t β t p gt u (W t M gt p gt M pt p mt ) = λ I 0,t + µ t (32) β t p mt u (W t M gt p gt M pt p mt ) = λ (33) I 0,t t=0 M gt + M pt I 0,t = 26 t=0 T t I 0,t. (34) ).

27 An equilibrium is a solution to the conditions above with M pt = 0 in every period, reflecting the zero net supply of private money. We note first that p gt = p mt for all t where M gt > 0. Furthermore, we have that M gt = 0 if and only if ( ) β t p gt u λ (W t ) λ/i 0,t W t φ β t I 0,t p g,t (35) where φ( ) = u 1 ( ). Using this result, and re-arranging (32), we get 0 if (35) holds M gt = ( 1 p gt (W t φ )) λ β t p mti 0,t otherwise Substituting this result into (34) with M pt = 0, we get ( )) 1 λ p gt (W t φ ( ( )) β t p mti 0,t λ I W t > φ I 0,t β t = I 0,t p g,t t=0 t=0 T t I 0,t. where I is the indicator function. As φ is strictly decreasing, the left hand ( ) λ side is increasing in λ. Furthermore, as λ 0, we have that φ β t I 0,t p g,t by Inada conditions. Thus, the indicator function will go uniformly towards 0 (as W t is bounded), which means that LHS goes to 0. Thus LHS ( ) λ starts below RHS. Furthermore, as λ we get that φ β t I 0,t p g,t 0 by the Inada condition. Thus, we get LHS t=0 W t p gt I 0,t > T t I t=0 0,t by the assumption in theorem. Thus, there exists a unique λ = λ compatible with equilibrium. We now go from the unique λ to fully characterize the equilibrium. For ( λ all t with W t φ β t I 0,t p g,t ), we know that W t = c t, and use (33) to get p mt = λ β t u (W t ) p gt. 27

28 And since by no-arbitrage p mt For t such that ( λ ) W t > φ β t I 0,t p g,t, we have M gt > 0 and hence µ t = 0. We can then use (32) to get ( ) λ c t = φ β t < W t. p gt I 0,t The quantities c t in periods with M g,t = 0 are already trivially determined, and so are prices p m,t when M g,t > 0. Thus, we have fully characterized the equilibrium. 28

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam MACROECONOMICS Prelim Exam Austin, June 1, 2012 Instructions This is a closed book exam. If you get stuck in one section move to the next one. Do not waste time on sections that you find hard to solve.

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption Notes for Econ22A: Consumption Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas UC Berkeley Fall 215 c Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 215, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. Disclaimer: These notes are riddled with inconsistencies, typos and

More information

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Assets with possibly negative dividends Assets with possibly negative dividends (Preliminary and incomplete. Comments welcome.) Ngoc-Sang PHAM Montpellier Business School March 12, 2017 Abstract The paper introduces assets whose dividends can

More information

Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective

Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Monetary and Fiscal Policy Issues in General Equilibrium

More information

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 The Ramsey Model Lectures 11 to 14 Topics in Macroeconomics November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 Lecture 11, 12, 13 & 14 1/50 Topics in Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model: Introduction 2 Main Ingredients Neoclassical

More information

A Central Bank Theory of Price Level Determination

A Central Bank Theory of Price Level Determination A Central Bank Theory of Price Level Determination Pierpaolo Benigno (LUISS and EIEF) Monetary Policy in the 21st Century CIGS Conference on Macroeconomic Theory and Policy 2017 May 30, 2017 Pierpaolo

More information

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints 1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints In this section we study conditions under which savings react to changes in income uncertainty. Recall that in the PIH, when you abstract from

More information

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Econ 204A - Henning Bohn * Most of modern macroeconomics involves models of agents that optimize over time. he basic ideas and tools are the same as in microeconomics,

More information

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8 Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8 1 Cagan Model of Money Demand 1.1 Money Demand Demand for real money balances ( M P ) depends negatively on expected inflation In logs m d t p t =

More information

Slides III - Complete Markets

Slides III - Complete Markets Slides III - Complete Markets Julio Garín University of Georgia Macroeconomic Theory II (Ph.D.) Spring 2017 Macroeconomic Theory II Slides III - Complete Markets Spring 2017 1 / 33 Outline 1. Risk, Uncertainty,

More information

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

Problem set 1 ECON 4330 Problem set ECON 4330 We are looking at an open economy that exists for two periods. Output in each period Y and Y 2 respectively, is given exogenously. A representative consumer maximizes life-time utility

More information

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Two Period Exchange Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 2 1 Two Period Exchange Economy We shall start our exploration of dynamic economies with

More information

Macroeconomics and finance

Macroeconomics and finance Macroeconomics and finance 1 1. Temporary equilibrium and the price level [Lectures 11 and 12] 2. Overlapping generations and learning [Lectures 13 and 14] 2.1 The overlapping generations model 2.2 Expectations

More information

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income 1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income Until now, we have assumed that government policy is exogenously given, so the government had a very passive role. Its only concern was balancing the intertemporal budget.

More information

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing Florian Scheuer 5/1/2014 Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing 1 Finite Horizon 1.1 Setup 2 periods t = 0, 1 preferences U i c 0, c 1, l 0 sequential budget constraints in t = 0, 1 c i 0 + pbi 1 +

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 207 Introduction This note works through some simple two-period consumption-saving problems. In

More information

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Transport Costs and North-South Trade Transport Costs and North-South Trade Didier Laussel a and Raymond Riezman b a GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II b Department of Economics, University of Iowa Abstract We develop a simple two country

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Real Business Cycles (Solution)

Real Business Cycles (Solution) Real Business Cycles (Solution) Exercise: A two-period real business cycle model Consider a representative household of a closed economy. The household has a planning horizon of two periods and is endowed

More information

1 Two Period Production Economy

1 Two Period Production Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 3 1 Two Period Production Economy We shall now extend our two-period exchange economy model

More information

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University Lecture Notes Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University November 28, 2010 1 Fiscal Policy To study questions of taxation in

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005 14.05: SECION HANDOU #4 CONSUMPION (AND SAVINGS) A: JOSE ESSADA Fall 2005 1. Motivation In our study of economic growth we assumed that consumers saved a fixed (and exogenous) fraction of their income.

More information

Money in an RBC framework

Money in an RBC framework Money in an RBC framework Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 1 / 36 Money Two basic questions: 1 Modern economies use money. Why? 2 How/why do

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Adverse Selection, Segmented Markets, and the Role of Monetary Policy

Adverse Selection, Segmented Markets, and the Role of Monetary Policy Adverse Selection, Segmented Markets, and the Role of Monetary Policy Daniel Sanches Washington University in St. Louis Stephen Williamson Washington University in St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing

Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing Economics 714, Spring 2018 1 Asset Pricing 1.1 Lucas (1978) Asset Pricing Model We assume that there are a large number of identical agents, modeled as a representative

More information

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies Introduction In macroeconomics, we study the behavior of economy-wide aggregates e.g. GDP, savings, investment, employment and so on - and

More information

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55 Government debt Lecture 9, ECON 4310 Tord Krogh September 10, 2013 Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, 2013 1 / 55 Today s lecture Topics: Basic concepts Tax smoothing Debt crisis Sovereign risk Tord

More information

Scarce Collateral, the Term Premium, and Quantitative Easing

Scarce Collateral, the Term Premium, and Quantitative Easing Scarce Collateral, the Term Premium, and Quantitative Easing Stephen D. Williamson Washington University in St. Louis Federal Reserve Banks of Richmond and St. Louis April7,2013 Abstract A model of money,

More information

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Oil Monopoly and the Climate Oil Monopoly the Climate By John Hassler, Per rusell, Conny Olovsson I Introduction This paper takes as given that (i) the burning of fossil fuel increases the carbon dioxide content in the atmosphere,

More information

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

Money in a Neoclassical Framework Money in a Neoclassical Framework Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 1 / 21 Money Two basic questions: 1 Modern economies use money. Why? 2 How/why

More information

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Behzad Diba University of Bern April 2012 (Institute) Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background April 2012 1 / 19 Research Areas Research on fiscal policy typically

More information

Optimal tax and transfer policy

Optimal tax and transfer policy Optimal tax and transfer policy (non-linear income taxes and redistribution) March 2, 2016 Non-linear taxation I So far we have considered linear taxes on consumption, labour income and capital income

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

Game Theory Fall 2003

Game Theory Fall 2003 Game Theory Fall 2003 Problem Set 5 [1] Consider an infinitely repeated game with a finite number of actions for each player and a common discount factor δ. Prove that if δ is close enough to zero then

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH). ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). Prepared by Dmytro Hryshko. In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH). Let us consider the following two-period

More information

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics Roberto Perotti November 20, 2013 Version 02 Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics 1 The intertemporal government budget constraint Consider the usual

More information

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption Problem Set 3 Thomas Philippon April 19, 2002 1 Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption The goal of the question is to derive the formulas on p13 of Topic 2. This is a partial equilibrium analysis

More information

Public budget accounting and seigniorage. 1. Public budget accounting, inflation and debt. 2. Equilibrium seigniorage

Public budget accounting and seigniorage. 1. Public budget accounting, inflation and debt. 2. Equilibrium seigniorage Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 2/2 2015 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Public budget accounting and seigniorage 1. Public budget accounting, inflation and debt 2. Equilibrium

More information

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6 Contents 1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) 2 1.1 Question (a).................................................... 2 1.2 Question (b).................................................... 6 2 Countercyclical

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Introduction Intermediate Macroeconomics Consumption/Saving, Ricardian

More information

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics Laurent Simula ENS Lyon 1 / 54 Roadmap Introduction Pareto Optimality General Equilibrium The Two Fundamental Theorems of Welfare

More information

Reply to the Second Referee Thank you very much for your constructive and thorough evaluation of my note, and for your time and attention.

Reply to the Second Referee Thank you very much for your constructive and thorough evaluation of my note, and for your time and attention. Reply to the Second Referee Thank you very much for your constructive and thorough evaluation of my note, and for your time and attention. I appreciate that you checked the algebra and, apart from the

More information

Unemployment equilibria in a Monetary Economy

Unemployment equilibria in a Monetary Economy Unemployment equilibria in a Monetary Economy Nikolaos Kokonas September 30, 202 Abstract It is a well known fact that nominal wage and price rigidities breed involuntary unemployment and excess capacities.

More information

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model 2012-2013 Master 2 Macro I Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model Franck Portier (based on Gilles Saint-Paul lecture notes) franck.portier@tse-fr.eu Toulouse School of Economics Version 1.1 07/10/2012 Changes

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings Econ 20200 - Elements of Economics Analysis 3 (Honors Macroeconomics) Lecturer: Chanont (Big) Banternghansa TA: Jonathan J. Adams Spring 2013 Introduction Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

More information

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Sudden Stops and Output Drops Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 353 January 2005 Sudden Stops and Output Drops V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Patrick J.

More information

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469 Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469 1 Introduction and Motivation International illiquidity Country s consolidated nancial system has potential short-term

More information

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result Arantza Gorostiaga Rubio-Ramírez Juan F. Universidad del País Vasco Duke University and Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Abstract

More information

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box Paolo Crosetto paolo.crosetto@unimi.it DEAS - University of Milan Exercises solved in class on March 15th, 2010 Recap: pure exchange The simplest model of a general equilibrium

More information

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1. FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal Consumption-Saving and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer 21 ECON 422:Fisher 1 Reading PCBR, Chapter 1 (general overview of financial decision making)

More information

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2018 1 / 21 Readings GLS Chapter 11 2 / 21 Production and

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 9 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3 Consider now a different cause for the failure of the Coase Theorem: the presence of transaction costs. Of course for this to be an interesting

More information

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations Tommy Sveen Norges Bank January 28, 2009 TS (NB) ECON 4325 January 28, 2009 / 35 Introduction A simple model of a classical monetary economy. Perfect

More information

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy 1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy For a long time, when economists thought about the effect of government debt on aggregate output, they focused on the so called crowding-out effect. To simplify

More information

Dynamic Contracts. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. December 5, Econ720

Dynamic Contracts. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. December 5, Econ720 Dynamic Contracts Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 December 5, 2016 1 / 43 Issues Many markets work through intertemporal contracts Labor markets, credit markets, intermediate input supplies,... Contracts

More information

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013 Comprehensive Exam August 19, 2013 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question. Good luck! 1 1 Menu

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3) FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS These notes are missing interpretation of the results, and especially toward the end, skip some steps in the mathematics. But they should be useful

More information

Problem set Fall 2012.

Problem set Fall 2012. Problem set 1. 14.461 Fall 2012. Ivan Werning September 13, 2012 References: 1. Ljungqvist L., and Thomas J. Sargent (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, sections 17.2 for Problem 1,2. 2. Werning Ivan

More information

1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models

1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models 1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models Consider the problem of a household who faces idiosyncratic productivity shocks, supplies labor inelastically and can save/borrow only through a risk-free

More information

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev Department of Economics, Trinity College, Dublin Policy Institute, Trinity College, Dublin Open Republic

More information

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25 Department of Applied Economics Johns Hopkins University Economics 60 Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Midterm Exam Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 00 NAME: The Exam has a total of four

More information

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES 1. REVIEW: SMALL TAXES SMALL DEADWEIGHT LOSS Static analysis suggests that deadweight loss from taxation at rate τ is 0(τ 2 ) that is, that for small tax rates the

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

Consumption and Saving

Consumption and Saving Chapter 4 Consumption and Saving 4.1 Introduction Thus far, we have focussed primarily on what one might term intratemporal decisions and how such decisions determine the level of GDP and employment at

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

Optimal Taxation and Debt Management without Commitment

Optimal Taxation and Debt Management without Commitment Optimal Taxation and Debt Management without Commitment Davide Debortoli Ricardo Nunes Pierre Yared March 14, 2018 Abstract This paper considers optimal fiscal policy in a deterministic Lucas and Stokey

More information

Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34

Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34 Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34 13. Sovereign debt (public debt) governments borrow from international lenders or from supranational organizations (IMF, ESFS,...) problem of contract

More information

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy 1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy We start our analysis of fiscal policy by stating a neutrality result for fiscal policy which is due to David Ricardo (1817), and whose formal illustration is due

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence A The infinite horizon model This section defines the equilibrium of the infinity horizon model described in Section III of the paper and characterizes

More information

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

Uncertainty in Equilibrium Uncertainty in Equilibrium Larry Blume May 1, 2007 1 Introduction The state-preference approach to uncertainty of Kenneth J. Arrow (1953) and Gérard Debreu (1959) lends itself rather easily to Walrasian

More information

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far (Incomplete) summary of the course so far Lecture 9a, ECON 4310 Tord Krogh September 16, 2013 Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 16, 2013 1 / 31 Main topics This semester we will go through: Ramsey (check)

More information

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing Florian Scheuer 2/25/2016 Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing 1 Finite Horizon 1.1 Setup 2 periods t = 0, 1 preferences U i c 0, c 1, l 0 sequential budget constraints in t = 0, 1 c i 0 + pbi 1 +

More information

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Davide Porcellacchia 8 February 2017 Abstract The canonical New Keynesian model features a zero lower bound on the interest rate. In the simple setting

More information

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2017 Intermediate Macroeconomics Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations Fall 2017 1 / 33 Business Cycles We can

More information

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption Toulouse School of Economics Notes written by Ernesto Pasten (epasten@cict.fr) Slightly re-edited by Frank Portier (fportier@cict.fr) M-TSE. Macro I. 200-20. Chapter 3: Consumption Macroeconomics I Chapter

More information

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017] Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017] 1. A tax is to be levied on a commodity bought and sold in a competitive market. Two possible forms of tax may be used: In one case, a per unit tax

More information

Intermediate microeconomics. Lecture 1: Introduction and Consumer Theory Varian, chapters 1-5

Intermediate microeconomics. Lecture 1: Introduction and Consumer Theory Varian, chapters 1-5 Intermediate microeconomics Lecture 1: Introduction and Consumer Theory Varian, chapters 1-5 Who am I? Adam Jacobsson Director of studies undergraduate and masters Research interests Applied game theory

More information

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 1 Imperfect Credibility of Policy: Trade Reform 1.1 Model Assumptions Output is exogenous constant endowment (y), not useful for consumption, but can be exported

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2 Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2 Universität Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 1 / 26 1 Two period model - Problem 1 2 Two period model with borrowing constraint - Problem 2 Dynamic Macroeconomics 2 /

More information

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Class Notes on Chaney (2008) Class Notes on Chaney (2008) (With Krugman and Melitz along the Way) Econ 840-T.Holmes Model of Chaney AER (2008) As a first step, let s write down the elements of the Chaney model. asymmetric countries

More information

Online Appendix for Debt Contracts with Partial Commitment by Natalia Kovrijnykh

Online Appendix for Debt Contracts with Partial Commitment by Natalia Kovrijnykh Online Appendix for Debt Contracts with Partial Commitment by Natalia Kovrijnykh Omitted Proofs LEMMA 5: Function ˆV is concave with slope between 1 and 0. PROOF: The fact that ˆV (w) is decreasing in

More information

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications Econ PhD, UC3M Lecture 9: Data and facts Hernán D. Seoane UC3M Spring, 2016 Today s lecture A look at the data Study what data says about open

More information

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl) University of California, Davis Date: September 1, 2011 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Macroeconomics Reading Time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Directions: Answer all

More information

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Christopher Phelan Working Paper 676 December 2009 Phelan: University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1 Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose,

More information