10 th Norwegian-German Seminar Public Sector Economics

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "10 th Norwegian-German Seminar Public Sector Economics"

Transcription

1 0 th Norwegian-German Seminar Public Sector Economics Munich, 7 8 November 07 Profit Shifting of Multinational orporations with Loss-Making Affiliates Marko Koethenbuerger and Mohammed Mardan

2 Profit shifting of multinational corporations with loss-making affiliates Marko Koethenbuerger ETH Zurich, ESifo and NoeT Mohammed Mardan ETH Zurich and NoeT Michael Stimmelmayr ETH Zurich, ESifo and NoeT 7 November 07 Abstract Despite the prominence of losses for affiliates of multinational enterprises, the implications of these losses for the investment behavior have not been considered in the literature. We set up a model which allows for the possibility of lossmaking affiliates and analyze the effects on affiliate investment and government policy. We show that an inverted-type of transfer pricing from the low-tax to the high-tax jurisdiction might also promote investment incentives in the low-tax as well as the high-tax jurisdiction. In equilibrium, affiliates might overinvest. The finding contrasts existing literature where transfer pricing incentives are insulated from investment incentives. Finally, we highlight the implications of our findings for the efficiency of government policy where the loss-related investment effects might generate too high taxes in equilibrium. Keywords: tax competition, profit shifting, corporate losses, investment. JEL lassification: H5, D, H87 We are grateful to seminar and conference participants at the 09th annual conference of the National Tax Association, the 73rd annual congress of the International Institute of Public Finance, and the 4th annual MaTax onference. In particular we are grateful for the valuable comments made by Eric Zwick, James Albertus and Aija Polakova. Department of Management, Technology and Economics, Leonhardstrasse, 809 Zurich, Switzerland; koethenbuerger@kof.ethz.ch; phone: Department of Management, Technology and Economics, Leonhardstrasse, 809 Zurich, Switzerland; mardan@kof.ethz.ch; phone: Department of Management, Technology and Economics, Leonhardstrasse, 809 Zurich, Switzerland; stimmelmayr@kof.ethz.ch; phone:

3 Introduction Affiliates of multinational enterprises (MNEs) frequently report losses. orporate tax losses and the associated loss carry-forwards have grown in importance and, expressed as a percentage of GDP, show large differences among countries, with some as high as 5 percent (OED, 0). The fiscal implications of tax losses are of concern to policy makers. The tax codes in most countries do not grant an immediate tax rebate in response to losses and also limit the extent to which losses can be deducted against future income or, in the context of MNEs, against profits of an affiliate in a foreign country. While these rules attempt to reduce tax fraud and excessive use of tax deductions, thereby protecting the domestic corporate tax base (Ashulter et al., 009), MNEs have the potential to bypass these waiting rules through the strategic use of transfer pricing, as documented in recent empirical research (Hopland et al., forthcoming; DeSimone et al., 05). In the same vein, empirical research has documented a tendency of MNE affiliates to bunch around zero reported profits, which is consistent with MNEs profit shifting behavior (Grubert et al., 993; Johannesen et al., 07; Habu, 07). 3 Bunching might occur from below zero, to use losses that allow shifted profits to be taxed at a zero rate, or from above zero, to shift profits out of profitable affiliates. In this paper, we analyze how transfer pricing strategies of MNEs respond to losses within the MNE network and how this intertwines with investment choices. We set up For the U.S., Altshuler et al. (009) relate this trend to different explanations, including an increase in the dispersion of the distribution of profits and a general decline in the rate of profit. For instance, in 00, U.S. corporations that lost money reported losses that amount to more than 60 percent of profits reported by profitable corporations (Edgerton, 00). In Germany, aggregate unused losses from the past were more than four times larger than taxable corporate profits in the economy. For 004, roughly 40 percent of incorporated firms suffer a loss (Dwenger, 009), with a similar magnitude for German MNEs only (Overesch, 009). The issue of tax-induced transfer pricing has recently gained momentum in the Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) initiative of the OED (OED, 03). Despite various attempts to regulate transfer pricing (OED, 00), limiting this type of tax avoidance behavior continues to be a taxing task for tax authorities. The notion of arm s-length pricing, which underlies most of the transfer pricing regulation, is difficult to implement with, e.g., intellectual property rights due to the highly idiosyncratic nature of this service and the associated difficulty in finding comparable transactions that are not influenced by tax-savings considerations. 3 Such a situation is consistent with highly-publicized cases of aggressive transfer pricing behavior of Apple, Google and Starbucks, which leaves almost zero taxable profits in high-tax jurisdictions (Levin and Mcain, 03).

4 a model of MNE behavior that, consistent with the empirical observation, generates a tendency of MNE affiliate profits to bunch around a zero profit level, both from below and above zero, and this bunching generates investment effects in the high-tax jurisdiction as well as low-tax jurisdiction. In showing these results, we depart from the usual assumption in the literature that, when determining the optimal amount of profit shifting, the MNE weighs the marginal benefit of higher tax savings vis-a-vis the marginal change in concealment cost associated with transfer pricing (see Haufler and Schjelderup (000) and Gresik (00), for instance). With such an interior solution to the transfer pricing problem, investment incentives are generically insulated from transfer pricing, meaning that changes in transfer prices have no effect on the MNE s investment decision. This approach by definition abstracts from the possibility of zerobunching of taxable profit. In our model, a MNE affiliate might incur a tax loss. We assume that the price levels of the final goods sold by each affiliate are uncertain. A very high price implies large profits whereas a very low price results in losses. Depending on the realizations of the price levels, the MNE determines its transfer pricing strategy. In contrast to the previous literature, the MNE may be constrained in its profit shifting strategy, which depends on the profitability of its affiliates. With a loss-making affiliate (in the high-tax jurisdiction), the amount of profits to be shifted falls below the interior solution when the profitability of the affiliate in the low-tax country is too low. Bunching occurs from above zero. In the same vein, the amount of profits to be shifted falls below the interior solution when the size of the losses in the affiliate in the high-tax country are too low. Bunching occurs from below zero. These constraints are the reason why the MNE s transfer pricing and investment decisions are intertwined in our model. In case of a binding profit shifting constraint an increase in investment relaxes the respective profit shifting constraint and allows the MNE to shift more profits. In this setting, transfer pricing might not only increase investments in high-tax jurisdictions, as likewise predicted by existing literature, but for different reasons. 4 It might also spur investments in low-tax jurisdictions, possibly leading to overinvestment 4 Mintz and Smart (004) show that internal debt shifting not only allows MNEs to save on taxes, but also promotes investments in high-tax affiliates. With internal debt shifting, investment effects follow from the reduced cost of capital due to the tax-deductibility of interest payments. This link is absent with other forms of transfer pricing that we consider.

5 in high-tax and low-tax jurisdictions. 5 The interrelatedness between profit shifting and investment decision has also implications for the efficiency of government policy. The typical positive externality that is caused by governments incentive to reduce their tax rate in order to attract profits is only present in the case of highly profitable MNE affiliates. In cases where the MNE is constrained in its profit shifting strategy, there also exists a investment externality which runs in the opposite direction. This might imply too high tax rates in equilibrium. The results of our analysis have important implications for the empirical literature. In empirical analyses on transfer pricing loss-making affiliates are frequently dropped from the analysis (Klassen et al., 993; Dharmapala, 04). While this presumably reflects the prior to avoid any bias from reversed incentives under net operating losses, Hopland et al. (forthcoming) have shown that this bias will only be eliminated under the assumption of ex-post shifting. Our analysis shows that, taking into account the possibility of zero-taxable profits and thereby departing from the usual assumption of an interior solution to transfer pricing, likely results in an underestimation of the tax sensitivity of reported profits, just because affiliates reporting zero-taxable profits will not react to a change in the tax rate. 6 Arguably, these affiliates belong to the most tax aggressive MNEs (Johannesen et al., 07). Moreover, our analysis shows that the disregard of loss-making affiliate will create a downward bias in the empirical estimates of investment responses to corporate taxes. The intuition is that a change in the corporate tax at the location where affiliates report zero-taxable profits will not change investment incentives because MNEs can escape the taxation of the marginal return on investment. 7 Our analysis contributes to the small, but evolving literature on the importance of 5 Tax rates might generate investment changes across affiliates, implying that investment levels in the two affiliates might co-move in response to a higher profit tax in one country. The implication is consistent with empirical findings in Becker and Riedel (0) who show that the tax rate of the foreign jurisdiction negatively affects domestic investment of MNEs. 6 This is consistent with Harbu (07) who finds that UK corporate tax rate cuts did not affect the ratio of taxable profits to total assets reported by foreign multinational subsidiaries and domestic stand-alone firms differently. 7 The implication is in line with empirical estimates of the user cost elasticity of investment in Dwenger and Walch (04), which increases in absolute value from 0.37 to 0.5 when accounting for tax losses. 3

6 losses for income shifting. 8 For instance, Overesch (009) shows that the statutory tax differential, the conventional measure of transfer pricing incentives, becomes less important in explaining transfer pricing in the presence of corporate tax losses. Using data on intercompany payments between affiliated firms in Norway, Hopland et al. (forthcoming) find evidence that, under losses, transfer pricing provides flexibility to adjust profit shifting ex post, i.e. after the financial performance of the affiliate has become known but before the tax return is filed. Similarly, De Simone et al. (07) show that affiliates of MNEs alter the distribution of reported profits to take advantage of losses. An increase of one percent in the tax incentives of a profitable affiliate are associated with a drop in reported profit by 8.8 percent whereas for an unprofitable affiliate the same tax incentive leads to an increase in reported profit by 6. percent. Theoretical contributions on corporate losses in an international context are scarce. Mardan and Stimmelmayr (07) analyze the implications of losses for the decision to switch from separate accounting to formula apportionment. Kalamov and Runkel (06) investigate the implications of an uncoordinated introduction of cross-border loss-offset provisions when countries compete for capital and profits of MNEs. Both studies rely on interior solutions to characterize transfer pricing incentives, which imply that investment behavior and transfer pricing incentives do not intertwine. To the best of our knowledge, existing literature has not yet established a link between transfer pricing and investment. The current paper tries to fill this gap. The paper is organized as follows. In Section we introduce the basic framework. In Section 3 we analyze transfer pricing behavior and investment choices of the MNE. We turn to government policy and characterize the efficiency of tax policy choices in Section 4 and discuss two assumption of the basic model in Section 5. Finally, we provide a summary of the results and offer some concluding remarks in Section 6. 8 Altshuler et al. (009) summarize the literature on investment effects of tax loss carry-forward provisions. This literature, however, abstracts from transfer pricing. 4

7 The basic framework onsider a set-up in which a multinational enterprise (MNE) has affiliates in two smallopen countries which levy source-based profit tax rates t i, i =,. Although tax rates are determined endogenously, we assume, without loss of generality, that country is the high-tax country. 9 Affiliates use capital, k i, to produce a final good, y i, using a standard production technology, y i = f(k i ), which satisfies f (k i ) > 0 > f (k i ). apital, k i, can be borrowed from the world market at an interest rate r. We assume that the price levels of the final goods are stochastic and drawn from a cumulative distribution function, H i (p i ), and density, h i (p i ), with support on [p i, p i ]. The uncertainty of the price level in country affects the profitability of affiliate, but we assume that ex post the affiliate is always profitable even when the realization of the price takes the lowest value of p. 0 Instead, the realization of the output price in country can lead to actual losses in affiliate ex post. We denote the average price in country i by ˆp i = i p i p i h i (p i )dp i. Additionally, each affiliate requires one unit of an essential intangible input good, g, for production. This input could, for instance, be a patent. The legal rights for using the intangible input good are located in the affiliate in country. The arm s-length price for g is normalized to zero. Any deviation from the arm s-length price is associated with convex concealment costs (g) = γ(g )/, γ > 0. Furthermore, we assume that the MNE has sufficient flexibility to determine the transfer price ex post, i.e. after the realization of the output price in country. 3 9 One reason for this could be that country hosts a larger number of purely national firms and therefore derives comparably more corporate tax revenues from this additional source. 0 This assumption reduces complexity without qualitatively affecting our results. In general, MNEs might close down a permanently loss-making affiliate. However, at least in the short run it might well be that the MNE continues the operation even though it temporarily incurs losses in expectation. Loss-making affiliates might be valuable in order to gain access to a new market or to show strategic presence in a relevant market. The reasoning is consistent with the persistence of losses, as reported in Auerbach (987) and Dwenger and Walch (04), for instance. We could also include size-related determinants of the concealment cost, such as affiliate assets. Such an extension allows corporate investments to influence transfer pricing and vice versa. To isolate the effects of losses for investment behavior, we condition the concealment cost only on the deviation from the arm s-length price. 3 See Hopland et al. (forthcoming) for evidence that the use of intangible assets gives MNEs the 5

8 The before-tax profit of each of the two affiliates is given by revenue from (expected) sales of the output good minus the user cost of capital adjusted by the payment/income from the intangible asset, π e = π e = p p p h (p )dp y rk g, p h (p )dp y rk g. () The timing of the decision is as follows. First, the two governments non-cooperatively set tax rates. Then, the MNE determines the optimal investment levels (before the realization of affiliates output prices) and thereafter (after the realization of affiliates output prices) it chooses the optimal transfer price. We solve by backward induction. 3 The firm 3. Ex-post period Taxable profits differ from pre-tax profits in that only a share δ < of the capital costs can be deducted in case of positive taxable profits. The restriction on the deductibility rate reflects the observation that real-world tax systems only offer delayed expensing of investment outlays and no deductibility of the cost of equity capital. 4 Non-negative taxable profits in country If the output price in country is sufficiently large, p y δrk > 0 and, depending on the choice of g, taxable profits of both affiliates are given by π t = p y δrk g, { π t p y δrk g if p y δrk g 0, = 0 otherwise. () opportunity to shift income ex post. 4 An immediate expensing of investment outlays (as with a R-based cash flow tax) or a full deductibility of the cost of capital (as with an Allowance for orporate Equity system) would imply δ =. Such corporate tax provisions however do not universally exist in national corporate tax codes. 6

9 We have already made used of the fact that g > 0, given that country levies the higher tax rate, t t > 0. We distinguish two scenarios: in the first case, the realization of the output price in country is sufficiently high and the MNE is not restricted in setting its transfer price. In the second case, the output price is still sufficiently high and the MNE generates positive taxable profits in affiliate in the absence of profit shifting. The MNE is now, however, able to shift all profits earned in affiliate into the low-tax jurisdiction, leading to a zero tax base in country, π t = 0. Assuming for the moment that the MNE is unrestricted in its profit shifting possibilities, total profits of the MNE amount to 5 Π UP = ( t )p y ( δt )rk ( t )p y ( δt )rk (t t )g γ g, and the optimal transfer price is determined by (3) g UP = t t, (4) γ where the superscript denotes that the MNE is unconstrained and taxable profits in country are positive. Optimal profit shifting behaviour implies that the marginal cost of shifting profits has to be set equal to the marginal benefit (i.e., the tax savings). Since t > t the MNE shifts profits from the high-tax country to the low-tax country, i.e. g UP > 0. However, the realization of the output price in country might not be sufficiently high to ensure that the MNE is unconstrained in its optimal profit shifting behaviour. Denoting p 0 as the price for which taxable profits of affiliate are zero in the absence of profit shifting and p UP as the price for which taxable profits evaluated at the transfer price (4) are zero, the MNE is constrained in its the choice of the transfer price if p 0 p < δrk y t t γy p UP. (5) Under this condition, the MNE is still profitable and shifts profits from the high-tax country to the low-tax country, but to a smaller extent. The reason is based on 5 For simplicity, we assign the concealment cost to the net-of-tax profit stream of the headquarter. Assigning the concealment cost to the affiliates and making the cost tax deductible (partly or fully) changes the endogenous probability of the different scenarios that we consider in our analysis arise, but does not change our findings qualitatively. 7

10 the lower output price and thus the lower profitability of affiliate. Since the MNE s profit shifting constraint stems from the insufficient profitability of affiliate, we refer to this scenario as the profit constraint in country. In this case, the MNE sets the transfer price in a way that reduces taxable profits in country to zero, i.e. g 0 = p y δrk, (6) where the superscript 0 denotes that taxable profits in country are zero. The MNE pursues this strategy as long as taxable profits are positive in the absence of profit shifting, i.e. as long as p δrk y p 0. Non-positive taxable profits in country If the realization of the final goods price is too low in country, that is p < p 0, the affiliate in country makes losses and the tax bases in the two countries are given by 6 { π t = 0 { otherwise. p y δrk g if p y δrk g 0, π t = 0 if p y δrk g 0, p y δrk g otherwise. (7) In setting up the conditions, we have already used the fact that g might be negative, as shown below. The tax base of affiliate is non-positive in the absence of profit shifting and, thus, the MNE has an incentive to shift profits from country to country, given that the effective tax rate in country is zero. We distinguish three scenarios depending on the levels of p and p. In the first case, none of the conditions in equation (7) is binding, i.e. taxable profits in country and losses in country are sufficiently large, such that the MNE is unrestricted in setting its transfer price. In the second case, the MNE is restricted by the size of taxable profits 6 We abstract from tax provisions to offset losses against positive profits across time or across affiliates, either because they do not eliminate incentives to engage in transfer pricing into loss-making affiliates or they are not commonly available in national tax codes (or both). Different to shifting into loss-making affiliates, loss carry forwards entail a cost of forgone interest and can only be used over a limited time span. Loss carry backs are by far less generous than loss carry-forwards. Only a small number of countries offer loss carry backs and the period in which this is possible is very short (at most three years). Many countries do not grant loss carry backs at all. Even more restricted is the possibility of cross-border loss offset. Only four countries (Austria, Denmark, France and Italy) currently allow for cross-border loss offsets (see OED, 0). 8

11 in country. This scenario implies that the MNE is forced to shift less profits from country to country, because profits of the affiliate in the low-tax country are insufficient to fully offset the loss incurred by the affiliate in country. We refer to this scenario as the profit constraint in country. In the third case, the MNE is restricted by the limited amount of losses in country. Given that the statutory tax rate in country is larger than in country, t > t, the MNE never chooses a transfer price which would result in positive taxable profits in country. Therefore, the optimal amount of profits shifted from the low-tax country to the high-tax country is confined by the size of affiliate s losses and we refer to this scenario as the MNE s loss constraint in country. Suppose scenario one holds and the MNE is unconstrained in determining its profit shifting behavior. Then total profits of the MNE are Π UN = ( t )p y ( δt )rk p y rk t g γ g. (8) and the optimal transfer price is determined by g UN = t γ. (9) The superscript indicates that the MNE is unconstrained and taxable profits in country are negative. In this unconstrained case, the MNE sets a transfer price which is negative to shift profits out of the low-tax country into the high-tax country where the effective tax rate is zero. The transfer price only depends on the level of country s tax rate. In contrast to the scenario where the affiliate in country is profitable, now, both price levels determine whether the MNE is unconstrained in setting the transfer price, or not. Denoting ( ) as the price for which taxable profits π t (π t ) evaluated at the transfer price (4) are zero, the MNE is unconstrained only if p δrk y t γy, p δrk y t γy. (0) That is, the price in country must be sufficiently high whereas the price in country needs to be sufficiently low. 9

12 One of the two conditions in (7) might, however, be binding. Namely, either the price in country could be too low (p < ) or the price in country might not be sufficiently low ( < p < p 0 ). The question arises whether the MNE then suffers from the profit constraint in country or the loss constraint in country. From (7) we infer the threshold under which both constraints are binding, i.e. the tax bases in both countries reduce to zero. This condition is given by implying a threshold for p of p y δrk p y δrk = 0, () p δr(k k ) y p y y p P, () For p below the threshold specified in (), the MNE is profit constrained in country. We note that this threshold depends on the realization of the output price p. The higher the output price in country the lower needs to be the output price in country to ensure that the MNE is still profit constrained in country. From equation (7) we infer that the optimal transfer price depends on the price induced restrictions set up by the constraints in the equation. If prices are such that the MNE is profit constrained, the optimal transfer price is given by g P = (p y δrk ) < 0. (3) Instead, if prices imply that the MNE s is loss constraint, the optimal transfer pricing strategy is g L = p y δrk < 0, (4) where the superscript of the two former transfer prices indicates whether the MNE is profit constrained or loss constrained. Figure summarizes our discussion of the MNE s profit shifting constraints. One should note that the p P threshold cuts the p -axis below the value of p 0. The explanation for this result originates from the assumption that the affiliate in country is always profitable. Therefore, the p P and p 0 lines intersect to the left of p and the hypothetical value on the p -axis would be a price of p 0 at which taxable profits in country are zero in the absence of profit shifting. 0

13 3. Ex-ante period Figure : Price dependent profit shifting In this section, we analyze the optimal investment decisions of the MNE conditional on the MNE s constraints. Taking all possible scenarios together, the MNE s expected profit is E(Π) = p p p UP p UN 0 p p P Π UP h (p )h (p )dp dp Π UN h (p )h (p )dp dp Π L h (p )h (p )dp dp p UP p p 0 UN P p p p 0 Π 0 h (p )h (p )dp dp Π P h (p )h (p )dp dp Π L h (p )h (p )dp dp. (5)

14 Differentiating (5) with respect to k, the optimal ex-ante investment level in country is given by 7 ( t )ˆp f (k ) = ( δt )r p UN P p p p UP p p 0 UN 0 p p P p 0 UN p t [p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp t [p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ(g UP g 0 )[p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ(g UP g 0 )[p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ(g UP g 0 )[p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p P f (k ) δr][p P y δrk t /γ]h (p P ) pp h (p )dp. (6) k In equation (6), the first effect on the right side describes the standard effect of taxation when affiliates are always successful and earn enough profits so that none of the constraints is binding. In this case profit shifting is insulated from the investment decision and capital investment is distorted by taxation in country because only a fraction δ of investment costs can be deducted from the tax base. The second and third terms show how investment is affected if the affiliate in country makes relatively large losses, i.e when the MNE is either unconstrained in its tax planning (second term) or when the MNE is profit-constrained in country (third term). These effects are negative and thus lead to an increase in the investment level in country. The reason is that the MNE knows that in this case it will pay no taxes in country and it thus has an incentive to increase its investment ex-ante. Terms four to six are also negative because g UP > g 0 and show that profit shifting has a positive effect on investment if the affiliate in country is either profit or loss constrained. In these two cases, an increase in the investment level in country relaxes either constraint and allows the MNE to shift additional profits. The last term captures how the likelihood of the MNE 7 The derivations of the first-order condition for k and k can be found in Appendix A..

15 being profit-constrained in country is affected by the capital investment in country. Hence, from (6) we can conclude that profit shifting affects investment incentives in the high-tax country by lowering the cost of capital and, thus, increasing investments. Differentiating (5) with respect to k, yields the first-order condition ( t )ˆp f (k ) = ( δt )r UN P p p UN p γ[p f (k ) δr](g P g UN )h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p f (k ) δr](g P g UN )h (p P ) pp h (p )dp = 0. (7) k The interpretation of the first effect on the right side of equation (7) is the same as for (6). It shows that investment in country will be insulated from profit shifting if affiliates earn enough profits. The second term on the right side of (7) is negative because g P > g UN and shows that profit shifting exerts a positive effect on the optimal investment level in country if the MNE is profit-constrained in country. This is because the MNE has an incentive to increase its investment in country in order to relax the profit constraint and in turn to shift more profits. Additional profits earned through the increase in investment in affiliate can be shifted to the loss making affiliate in country without triggering additional tax payments. Similarly to (6), the last term shows how the MNE s probability of being profit-constrained in country is affected by a change in capital investment in country. Thus, our result shows that profit shifting can have a positive effect on investment even in the low-tax country, possibly leading to overinvestment (p i f (k i ) < r) in the two countries. We can summarize: Proposition If MNEs are constrained in their profit shifting activity, the possibility of profit shifting exerts a positive effect on investment. The positive investment effect can also appear in the low-tax country. From the first-order conditions (6) and (7), we can derive how taxes affect optimal capital investments. Generally, these effects are ambiguous since taxes also affect the likelihoods of being in one or the other scenario. However, when prices are e.g. uniformly 3

16 distributed on a large support, the probability of being at a specific point in the price distribution is very small. Hence, under this condition, we can establish 8 k t < 0, k t < 0, k t < 0, k t = 0. (8) As in the standard model with only profitable affiliates, taxes in the host country reduce the incentives to invest. Possibly surprising, the tax rate in country also negatively affects investment in country. The reason is that a higher tax rate in country reduces the incentives to shift profits when the MNE is profit- or loss-constrained in country. 9 However, lower incentives to shift profits also mean a lower incentive to relax the respective constraint by increasing capital investment in country. The reason why country s tax rate has no effect on capital investment in country is that, when the MNE is profit-constrained in country, the statutory rate t is irrelevant for the MNE s profit shifting incentives because the effective tax rate in country is zero due to affiliate loss position. We summarize our results in: Proposition If MNEs are constrained in their profit shifting activity, the possibility of profit shifting allows profit taxes of the low-tax country to increase investment in the high-tax country. Further, although investment in the low-tax country is increased because the return to investment is shifted to the high-tax country, the latter s (statutory) tax rate generically does not influence the investment level in the low-tax country. Proposition and stand in contrast to the existing literature where MNEs profit shifting and investment decision are insulated from each other if MNEs use license payment to shift profits. This result emerges because previous studies assumed that the optimal profit shifting is characterized by an interior solution. Instead, if the MNE is constrained in its profit shifting strategy, our model show that even transfer price manipulation of an intangible asset can create investment effect. While previous studies related to the use of internal debt showed that investment effect can emerge through internal debt shifting, these investment effect could only arise in the high-tax country 8 See Appendix A. for more details. 9 The implication is consistent with empirical findings in Becker and Riedel (0) who show that the tax rate of the foreign jurisdiction negatively affects domestic investment of MNEs. 4

17 because through the reduction in capital costs via interest deduction of internal debt. Our results, however, suggest that when MNE affiliates can make losses, the investment effect can also occur in the low-tax country. Our model provides an underpinning to the empirically-observed bunching of MNE affiliates in two different ways. We highlight economic incentives to bunch around zero profits from above as well as from below. When division is profit constrained, its profits will be reduced to zero, providing a tendency to bunch from above. Differently, when division does not have enough absorbing capacity and, thereby, is loss constrained, its profit level will be increased to a zero level. Bunching occurs from below. Investment effects will reinforce the tendency to bunch. For instance, when division is profit constrained, the marginal return to investment in division is shifted to division. As shown above, this will promote division s investment incentives and, at the same time, reinforces bunching from above, since more investment costs will be deducted in division. 4 The government In this section, we analyze the implications of our results derived in the previous section on the efficiency of governments tax policies. We assume that each government sets its corporate income tax rate to maximize corporate tax revenues. The tax base in both countries consists of expected taxable profits generated by the local affiliate. On top of that, country collects additional tax revenues through the taxation of purely national firms. These revenues are labelled by t G(t ). 0 Expected tax revenues in each country 0 We assume that the tax base of national firms is sufficiently large to ensure t > t in equilibrium. 5

18 are given by T = t t t p p p UP p UP p p 0 p 0 t UN t p p P p 0 T = t G(t ) t p p ( p y δrk t ) t h (p )h (p )dp dp γ (p y δrk p y δrk ) h (p )h (p )dp dp ( p y δrk t γ ) h (p )h (p )dp dp (p y δrk p y δrk ) h (p )h (p )dp dp p UP (p y δrk p y δrk ) h (p )h (p )dp dp, (9) ( p y δrk t ) t h (p )h (p )dp dp. (0) γ We investigate the efficiency of the governments tax policies by deriving tax externalities, i.e. the influence of one country s corporate tax rate on the other country s tax revenues. Differentiating T i with respect to t j yields T t = t t t T t = t p p p UP p UP p p P p P p p UP γ h (p )h (p )dp dp [p f (k ) δr] k t h (p )h (p )dp dp [p f (k ) δr] k h (p )h (p )dp dp, t () ( γ [p f (k ) δr] k ) h (p )h (p )dp dp. t () If both affiliates earn enough profits the model replicates the standard insights that the tax externality generated by each country is given by the tax-induced adjustment in the MNE s profit shifting behavior which yields a positive tax externality /γ (first effect in () and ()). This is because a country s tax rate has no effect on the level of capital investments in the other country. This is different when the MNE is constrained in its profit shifting strategy. In this situation, a higher tax rate in one country affects investments in the other country and thus results in additional externalities. 6

19 Interestingly, the negative own-investment effect of a higher tax t generates a tax externality for country. This happens when affiliate is either profit or loss constrained. Under a profit constraint in country, the MNE shifts all profits out of affiliate into affiliate. Because a higher t lowers the capital stock k, also profits in affiliate are reduced and therefore the tax base in country. Under a loss constraint in country, a lower capital stock k lowers affiliate s capacity to absorb affiliate s profits, which results in a higher tax base in country. As such, the tax externality might be negative in sign, contrary to standard analysis, if the investment effect is strong enough. The externality on country s tax revenues is influenced by the cross-investment effect. However, the tax rate in country affects tax revenues in country only if affiliate is profitable, that is when p is sufficiently high, because in the other cases taxable profits of affiliate are zero. Similar to before, the cross-investment effect runs counter the standard profit shifting externality because a higher t reduces capital investment in country and thus the tax base in country. Again, depending on the relative sizes of these effects the tax externality on country might also be negative. We summarize in: Proposition 3 The sign of the tax externalities is ambiguous and depends on the relative sizes of the profit shifting and the investment externalities. If the investment externality is strong tax competition can lead to excessively high tax rates. Proposition 3 shows that in addition to the standard positive profit shifting externality our model delivers an additional negative externality of profit shifting which so far has been absent in the literature due to the assumption of unconstrained profit shifting by the MNE. In the presence of loss-making affiliates tax effects on investment will affect the tax externality in the high-tax as well as in the low-tax country. As such the negative externality will counteract the positive externality and might in cases overcompensate it. Becker and Riedel (0), have shown that investment effects can counteract the standard positive externality. Although their analysis abstracts from loss-making affiliates, and instead attributes the cross-border tax effect on investment to a common input like patents, our results are in line with their finding and comple- 7

20 ment their analysis. Because even in the standard model investment effects arise, our results suggest that focussing only on the direct effect of profit shifting is insufficient to derive implications for international tax issues. 5 Discussion Ex-ante transfer pricing In analyzing the role of losses for corporate investment incentives we have assume that transfer prices are set after the output price shock has been revealed. Ex-post transfer pricing implies that the MNE will excessively report profits around zero, an implication that is consistent with recent evidence on profit shifting with loss-making affiliates (Hopland et al., forthcoming; DeSimone et al., 07). The empirical finding suggests that MNEs have enough flexibility at their disposal to fine-tune transfer prices such that reported profits become slightly positive or negative. Still, an interesting question is whether the role of losses for investment behavior vanishes when the MNE has less flexibility in setting transfer prices. In doing so, we take the opposite view and derive the implications for the case when the MNE has to choose the transfer price before output prices are realized. In a situation where the transfer price has to be set before output prices are known, the MNE bases its optimal transfer pricing behavior on the expected price levels ˆp and ˆp. The major difference compared to the ex-post transfer pricing analysis becomes manifest in the fact that the MNE now knows (in expectation) in which of the five scenarios it will end up (cf. footnote ). Thus, the MNE maximizes a simplified version of equation (5) where profits of only one specific scenario will be maximized. For example, if the expected price in country is such that p 0 < ˆp < p UP the MNE will maximize Π 0. Our previous result that capital investments will be affected by profit shifting when the MNE is constrained in its tax-planning strategies, is basically unaffected with exante transfer pricing. However, there is one difference to the previous analysis. In cases The view that MNEs have sufficient flexibility in setting transfer prices is also in line with evidence reported in Johannesen et al. (07) where MNE affiliates in developing countries with presumably less tax enforcement capacity bunch around zero reported profit levels. 8

21 where the MNE is profit-constrained (either in country or ) the possibility of profit shifting will lead to over-investment in the country in which the constraint is binding. The intuition is that, when the MNE is profit-constrained in country, all profits of affiliate are shifted to country. As affiliate is loss-making, total profits of the MNE will be taxed at a zero rate. Moreover, since profit shifting exerts a positive effect on investment in country, it is easy to show that at the optimum p f (k ) < r holds. Instead, when the MNE is profit-constrained in country, the MNE shifts out all profit of affiliate into country. Thus, affiliate s profits will be taxed at country s rate t. However, investment in country is also affected by the MNE s profit shifting incentives. Again, it is easy to show that these incentives are strong enough such that at the optimum p f (k ) < r holds. To see whether tax externalities modify when the MNE has to commit to its profit shifting strategy ex ante, we start with the scenario in which affiliate is highly profitable. In this case, the MNE is unconstrained in its profit shifting strategy. Since capital investments in the two countries are not affected by the tax rate of the other country, the tax externalities comprise only the standard profit shifting effect and are thus given by T i t j = t i γ > 0. (3) Although a change in country s tax rate may still affect capital investment in country, this will not affect country s tax revenues in all other scenarios, just because the tax base of affiliate is zero even if capital investment in country changes. However, country s tax rate setting will have an effect on tax revenues in country. Intuitively, the externality exists not because the tax in country affects capital investment in country, but because it affects investment in country. Hence, similar to the case of ex-post profit shifting, the own-investment effect of a higher tax t generates a tax externality for country. The spillover exists when the MNE is profit constrained in country. In this case, the MNE can save on tax payments in country by shifting the marginal return on investment to country. 9

22 Asymmetric concealment cost The use of losses for tax savings leads to possibly unexpected directions in which transfer payments flow. They may flow to loss-making affiliates in otherwise high-tax jurisdictions, which are not susceptible of being the host country of transfer income and thereby inflated reported profits. Thus, fiscal authorities in low-tax jurisdictions, from where the profit flows originate, presumably do not place much monitoring effort on transfer payment of domestic affiliates to these otherwise high-tax jurisdictions. MNEs do not have to incur too much cost to prepare documents to justify the transfer payments and to restructure intra-firm transactions in order to masquerade the tax-savings strategy. All this might suggest that concealment costs are asymmetric w.r.t. deviations from the true price and that the asymmetry implies excessive deviations from the true price in the unexpected way with severe fiscal implications. Given the formal analysis above, the concern turns out to have less validity than possibly conjectured. Precisely, in the context of our model, the concealment cost function might take the form (g) = { γ(g )/ if g 0, γ(g )/ otherwise, (4) where γ > γ > 0. Overpricing of the internal service, g > 0, is more costly to the MNE as compared to tax-induced underpricing, g < 0. The parameter γ becomes relevant for MNE behavior when division is making losses, but is unconstrained in the choice of the transfer price. In this case, (9) governs the choice of the transfer price and a lower value of γ magnifies profit shifting from the low-tax jurisdiction to the high-tax jurisdiction. In all other cases, in which we observe an inverted transfer pricing, the asymmetry in concealment cost capitalizes in firm value, but does not influence MNE behavior. The capitalization effect occurs because the equilibrium is inherently asymmetric in nature and the equilibrium level of profit shifting will be non-zero. Of course, the described limited scope of asymmetric concealment cost to influence MNE behavior should be understood in a qualitative manner. When the price distribution is such that the scenario of an unconstrained transfer pricing choice in the presence of losses in division gets a sufficiently high probability mass, then the quantitative implications are important. 0

23 6 onclusion This paper examines multinational companies incentives to shift profits when their affiliates might end up in a loss position. Our theory suggests that investment and profit shifting incentives are insulated as assumed in previous studies only if multinationals are unconstrained in their profit shifting activities. However, when multinationals are constrained, the possibility of profit shifting will affect its investment decisions and gives rise to increase capital investments both in the high-tax and the low-tax country. Moreover, the existence of investment effects will also affect the efficiency of governments tax policies. In the standard model, the possibility of profit shifting only creates an incentive to lower tax rate to attract mobile profits. However, when investments also react to changes in the tax rate an additional negative externality of profit shifting arises. This is because affiliates profitability will determine the amount of profit shifting when the multinational is constrained. Our results thus suggest that focussing only on the direct effect of profit shifting is insufficient to derive implications for international tax issues.

24 A Appendix A. Deriving the first-order conditions for capital investment Differentiating (5) with respect to k yields E(Π) = k p UP p p 0 p UN P p p UN 0 p p P p 0 p p p p p UP {( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {( t )p f (k ) γ(p y δrk )[p f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {p f (k ) r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {p f (k ) r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {( t )p f (k ) γ(p y δrk )[p f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {( t )p f (k ) γ(p y δrk )[p f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {( t )p UP f (k ) ( δt )r}h (p UP ) pup k h (p )dp {( t )p UP f (k ) γ(p UP y δrk )[p UP f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p UP ) pup {( t )p 0 f (k ) γ(p 0 y δrk )[p 0 f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p 0 ) p0 h (p )dp k p { UN p UN p UN p f (k ) r}h (p )h ( {p P f (k ) r}h (p P ) pun k dp ) pp h (p )dp k {( t )p 0 f (k ) γ(p 0 y δrk )[p 0 f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p 0 ) p0 k h (p )dp {( t )p P f (k ) γ(p P y δrk )[p P f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p P {( t ) f (k ) γ( y δrk )[ f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h ( k h (p )dp ) pp h (p )dp k ) pun k h (p )dp {( t )p 0 f (k ) γ(p 0 y δrk )[p 0 f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p 0 ) p0 h (p )dp = 0. (A.) k

25 Rearranging the terms containing single integrals yields E(Π) = k p UP p p 0 p UN P p p UN 0 p p P p 0 UN p p p p p UP {( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {( t )p f (k ) γ(p y δrk )[p f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {p f (k ) r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {p f (k ) r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {( t )p f (k ) γ(p y δrk )[p f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p )h (p )dp dp {( t )p f (k ) γ(p y δrk )[p f (k ) δr] ( δt )r}h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p P f (k ) δr][p P y δrk t /γ]h (p P γ[p UP f (k ) δr][p UP y δrk (t t )/γ]h (p UP γ[ f (k ) δr][ y δrk t /γ]h ( ) pp h (p )dp k ) pup ) pun k h (p )dp k h (p )dp = 0. (A.) Because p UP = δrk y t t γy and = δrk y t γy, the last two terms vanish. Rearranging the second to the fifth terms as if taxes at a rate t have to be paid and capital costs 3

26 can be deducted at this rate, we get E(Π) = k UN p UN P p p p UP p p 0 UN 0 p p P p 0 UN p p [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )dp t [p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp t [p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p f (k ) δr][(t t )/γ (p y δrk )]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p f (k ) δr][(t t )/γ (p y δrk )]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p f (k ) δr][(t t )/γ (p y δrk )]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p P f (k ) δr][p P y δrk t /γ]h (p P ) pp h (p )dp = 0.(A.3) k Substituting g UP = (t t )/γ and g 0 = p y δrk solving the integral and rearranging the terms leads to first-order condition as given in (6) ( t )ˆp f (k ) = ( δt )r UN p UN P p p p UP p p 0 UN 0 p p P p 0 UN p t [p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp t [p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ(g UP g 0 )[p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ(g UP g 0 )[p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ(g UP g 0 )[p f (k ) δr]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p P f (k ) δr][p P y δrk t /γ]h (p P ) pp h (p )dp. (A.4) k 4

27 Differentiating (5) with respect to k yields E(Π) = k p UP p p 0 p UN P p p UN 0 p p P p 0 UN p P p UN p 0 p P UN p 0 p p p UP [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp {p f (k ) r γ(p y δrk )[p f (k ) δr]}h (p )h (p )dp dp [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp [( t ) f (k ) ( δt )r]h ( ) pun k h (p )dp { f (k ) r γ( y δrk )[ f (k ) δr]}h ( ) pun k h (p )dp {p f (k ) r γ(p y δrk )[p f (k ) δr]}h (p P ) pp h (p )dp k [( t ) f (k ) ( δt )r]h ( ) pun k h (p )dp [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p P ) pp h (p )dp k [( t ) f (k ) ( δt )r]h ( ) pun k h (p )dp = 0. (A.5) 5

28 Rearranging the terms containing single integrals, taking into account that y δrk t /γ = 0, yields E(Π) = k p UP p p 0 p UN P p p UN 0 p p P p 0 UN p p p p UP [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp {p f (k ) r γ(p y δrk )[p f (k ) δr]}h (p )h (p )dp dp [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p f (k ) δr][p y δrk t /γ]h (p P ) pp h (p )dp = 0. (A.6) k Rearranging the terms containing double integrals yields E(Π) = k UN P p p UN p p p p [( t )p f (k ) ( δt )r]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p f (k ) δr][t /γ (p y δrk )]h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p f (k ) δr][p y δrk t /γ]h (p P ) pp h (p )dp = 0. (A.7) k Replacing t /γ = g UN and (p y δrk ) = g P, solving the double integral and putting terms on the right side of the derivation delivers the first order conditions as in equation (7) ( t )ˆp f (k ) = ( δt )r UN P p p UN p γ[p f (k ) δr](g P g UN )h (p )h (p )dp dp γ[p f (k ) δr](g P g UN )h (p P ) pp h (p )dp = 0. (A.8) k 6

Tax Revenue Losses through Cross-Border Loss Offset: An Insurmountable Hurdle for Formula Apportionment?

Tax Revenue Losses through Cross-Border Loss Offset: An Insurmountable Hurdle for Formula Apportionment? Tax Revenue Losses through Cross-Border Loss Offset: An Insurmountable Hurdle for Formula Apportionment? Mohammed Mardan Michael Stimmelmayr CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 6368 CATEGORY 1: PUBLIC FINANCE FEBRUARY

More information

Cross-border loss offset can fuel tax competition WP 13/10. October Working paper series Mohammed Marden University of Munich

Cross-border loss offset can fuel tax competition WP 13/10. October Working paper series Mohammed Marden University of Munich Cross-border loss offset can fuel tax competition October 2013 WP 13/10 Andreas Haufler University of Munich and CESifo Mohammed Marden University of Munich Working paper series 2013 The paper is circulated

More information

Tax competition in developed, emerging and developing regions - same same but different?

Tax competition in developed, emerging and developing regions - same same but different? Tax competition in developed, emerging and developing regions - same same but different? Mohammed Mardan ETH Zurich, CESifo and NoCeT Michael Stimmelmayr ETH Zurich, CESifo and NoCeT 24 May 2018 Abstract

More information

Public Sector Economics Munich, April 2018 Tax Competition in Developed, Emerging and Developing Regions - Same Same but Different?

Public Sector Economics Munich, April 2018 Tax Competition in Developed, Emerging and Developing Regions - Same Same but Different? Public Sector Economics Munich, 12 14 April 2018 Tax Competition in Developed, Emerging and Developing Regions - Same Same but Different? Mohammed Mardan and Michael Stimmelmayr Tax competition in developed,

More information

Under the current tax system both the domestic and foreign

Under the current tax system both the domestic and foreign Forum on Moving Towards a Territorial Tax System Where Will They Go if We Go Territorial? Dividend Exemption and the Location Decisions of U.S. Multinational Corporations Abstract - We approach the question

More information

KPMG LLP 2001 M Street, NW Washington, D.C Comments on the Discussion Draft on Cost Contribution Arrangements

KPMG LLP 2001 M Street, NW Washington, D.C Comments on the Discussion Draft on Cost Contribution Arrangements KPMG LLP 2001 M Street, NW Washington, D.C. 20036-3310 Telephone 202 533 3800 Fax 202 533 8500 To Andrew Hickman Head of Transfer Pricing Unit Centre for Tax Policy and Administration OECD From KPMG cc

More information

Double tax discrimination to attract FDI and fight profit shifting: The role of CFC rules

Double tax discrimination to attract FDI and fight profit shifting: The role of CFC rules Double tax discrimination to attract FDI and fight profit shifting: The role of CFC rules January 2017 WP 17/02 Andreas Haufler University of Munich, CESifo and NoCeT Mohammed Mardan ETH Zurich and NoCeT

More information

Andreas Haufler; Mohammed Mardan; Dirk Schindler: Optimal Policies against Profit Shifting: The Role of Controlled-Foreign-Company Rules

Andreas Haufler; Mohammed Mardan; Dirk Schindler: Optimal Policies against Profit Shifting: The Role of Controlled-Foreign-Company Rules Andreas Haufler; Mohammed Mardan; Dirk Schindler: Optimal Policies against Profit Shifting: The Role of Controlled-Foreign-Company Rules Munich Discussion Paper No. 2016-6 Department of Economics University

More information

GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION GEABA DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT

GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION GEABA DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT Tax and Managerial Effects of Transfer Pricing on Capital and Physical Products Oliver Duerr, Thomas Rüffieux Discussion Paper No. 17-19 GERMAN ECONOMIC

More information

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry Lin, Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 7(2), December 2014, 17-31 17 Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically

More information

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries Munich Discussion Paper No. 2006-30 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität

More information

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley Michael P. Devereux Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation This version: September 3, 2014 Abstract

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information - preliminary and incomplete, please do not cite - Working Paper R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information Andreas Frick Heidrun C. Hoppe-Wewetzer Georgios Katsenos June 28, 2016 Abstract

More information

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation Afrasiab Mirza Department of Economics University of Birmingham a.mirza@bham.ac.uk Frank Strobel Department of Economics University of Birmingham f.strobel@bham.ac.uk

More information

Tax-Induced Transfer Pricing and Corporate Agency Costs

Tax-Induced Transfer Pricing and Corporate Agency Costs Tax-Induced Transfer Pricing and Corporate Agency Costs Marko Koethenbuerger and Michael Stimmelmayr Tax-Induced Transfer Pricing and Corporate Agency Costs Marko Koethenbuerger ETH Zurich and CESifo Michael

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Multinationals capital structures, thin capitalization rules, and corporate tax competition

Multinationals capital structures, thin capitalization rules, and corporate tax competition Multinationals capital structures, thin capitalization rules, and corporate tax competition Andreas Haufler University of Munich Marco Runkel University of Magdeburg Paper prepared for the meeting of the

More information

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment University of Konstanz Department of Economics Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment Florian Baumann and Tim Friehe Working Paper Series 2011-08 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/workingpaperseries

More information

Multinationals and pro t shifting:

Multinationals and pro t shifting: Multinationals and pro t shifting: 60 ways to cheat the tax man Guttorm Schjelderup* Norwegian School of Economics and Norwegian Center of Taxation* Uppsala May 14, 2014 Schjelderup. (NHH and NoCeT) Base

More information

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning Doug Hostland Department of Finance Working Paper * 2001-20 * The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not reflect those of the Department of Finance. A previous version of this

More information

A new model of mergers and innovation

A new model of mergers and innovation WP-2018-009 A new model of mergers and innovation Piuli Roy Chowdhury Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai March 2018 A new model of mergers and innovation Piuli Roy Chowdhury Email(corresponding

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

Profit Shifting and Corporate Profit Tax Evasion

Profit Shifting and Corporate Profit Tax Evasion Profit Shifting and Corporate Profit Tax Evasion Dirk Schindler and Guttorm Schjelderup Profit Shifting and Corporate Profit Tax Evasion Dirk Schindler and Guttorm Schjelderup Norwegian School of Economics,

More information

Public Sector Economics Munich, April 2018 Border Adjusted Taxes, Cash Flow Taxes, and Transfer Pricing

Public Sector Economics Munich, April 2018 Border Adjusted Taxes, Cash Flow Taxes, and Transfer Pricing Public Sector Economics Munich, 12 14 April 2018 Border Adjusted Taxes, Cash Flow Taxes, and Transfer Pricing Eric W. Bond and Thomas Gresik Border Adjusted Taxes, Cash Flow Taxes, and Transfer Pricing

More information

Firms financial choices and thin capitalization rules under corporate tax competition

Firms financial choices and thin capitalization rules under corporate tax competition Firms financial choices and thin capitalization rules under corporate tax competition Andreas Haufler University of Munich Marco Runkel University of Magdeburg This version: March 2011 Abstract Thin capitalization

More information

Transfer Pricing by Multinational Firms: New Evidence from Foreign Firm Ownership

Transfer Pricing by Multinational Firms: New Evidence from Foreign Firm Ownership Transfer Pricing by Multinational Firms: New Evidence from Foreign Firm Ownership Anca Cristea University of Oregon Daniel X. Nguyen University of Copenhagen Rocky Mountain Empirical Trade 16-18 May, 2014

More information

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions Journal of Economics and Management, 2018, Vol. 14, No. 1, 1-31 License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions Masahiko Hattori Faculty

More information

Notes Unless otherwise indicated, the years referred to in describing budget numbers are fiscal years, which run from October 1 to September 30 and ar

Notes Unless otherwise indicated, the years referred to in describing budget numbers are fiscal years, which run from October 1 to September 30 and ar Budgetary and Economic Outcomes Under Paths for Federal Revenues and Noninterest Spending Specified by Chairman Price, March 2016 March 2016 CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES Notes Unless otherwise indicated,

More information

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income 1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income Until now, we have assumed that government policy is exogenously given, so the government had a very passive role. Its only concern was balancing the intertemporal budget.

More information

Alex A. T. Rathke School of Economics, BA and Accounting, University of São Paulo, Brazil

Alex A. T. Rathke School of Economics, BA and Accounting, University of São Paulo, Brazil Note on tax enforcement and transfer pricing manipulation Alex A. T. Rathke School of Economics, BA and Accounting, University of São Paulo, Brazil E-mail: alex.rathke@usp.br Keywords: income shifting;

More information

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals Donald J. Wright January 2014 VERY PRELIMINARY DRAFT School of Economics, Faculty of Arts and Social Sciences, University of Sydney, NSW, 2006, Australia, Ph:

More information

Volume Title: International Taxation and Multinational Activity. Volume URL:

Volume Title: International Taxation and Multinational Activity. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: International Taxation and Multinational Activity Volume Author/Editor: James R. Hines, Jr.

More information

Bank Leverage and Social Welfare

Bank Leverage and Social Welfare Bank Leverage and Social Welfare By LAWRENCE CHRISTIANO AND DAISUKE IKEDA We describe a general equilibrium model in which there is a particular agency problem in banks. The agency problem arises because

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12: Introduction to International Taxation

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12: Introduction to International Taxation Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12: Introduction to International Taxation It is useful to begin a discussion of international taxation with a look at the evolution of corporate tax rates over the

More information

Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Prices and Output in an Open conomy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply chapter LARNING GOALS: After reading this chapter, you should be able to: Understand how short- and long-run equilibrium is reached

More information

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries BACKGROUND PAPER FOR THE WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2008 Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries Larry Karp The findings, interpretations, and conclusions

More information

Innovation and Adoption of Electronic Business Technologies

Innovation and Adoption of Electronic Business Technologies Innovation and Adoption of Electronic Business Technologies Kai Sülzle Ifo Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich & Dresden University of Technology March 2007 Abstract This paper

More information

Double tax discrimination to attract FDI and fight profit shifting: The role of CFC rules

Double tax discrimination to attract FDI and fight profit shifting: The role of CFC rules Double tax discrimination to attract FDI and fight profit shifting: The role of CFC rules Andreas Haufler University of Munich, CESifo and NoCeT Mohammed Mardan ETH Zurich and NoCeT Dirk Schindler Norwegian

More information

How does transfer-pricing enforcement affect reported profits?

How does transfer-pricing enforcement affect reported profits? How does transfer-pricing enforcement affect reported profits? Molly Saunders-Scott University of Michigan mojusaun@umich.edu October 28, 2013 Job Market Paper Abstract Many governments are concerned that

More information

Taxing Corporate Income

Taxing Corporate Income 9 Taxing Corporate Income Alan J. Auerbach, Michael P. Devereux, and Helen Simpson Alan Auerbach is Robert D. Burch Professor of Economics and Law and Director of the Burch Center for Tax Policy and Public

More information

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT Prepared by the Staff of the JOINT COMMITTEE ON TAXATION December 22, 2017 JCX-69-17 INTRODUCTION Pursuant to section

More information

Efficiency Enhancing Taxation in Two-sided Markets

Efficiency Enhancing Taxation in Two-sided Markets INSTITUTT FOR FORETAKSØKONOMI DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE AND MANAGEMENT SCIENCE FOR 008 ISSN: 500-4066 JANUARY 008 Discussion paper Efficiency Enhancing Taxation in Two-sided Markets BY HANS JARLE KIND, MARKO

More information

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency Problem Anthony M. Marino Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA 90089-1422 E-mail: amarino@usc.edu May 8,

More information

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno Fabrizio Perri Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR fperri@umn.edu December

More information

Dividends and Tax Policy in the Long Run: Discussion. Dhammika Dharmapala 1

Dividends and Tax Policy in the Long Run: Discussion. Dhammika Dharmapala 1 Dividends and Tax Policy in the Long Run: Discussion Dhammika Dharmapala 1 In Dividends and Tax Policy in the Long Run, 2 Professor Bank reviews the theoretical and empirical literature on dividend taxation,

More information

Fuel-Switching Capability

Fuel-Switching Capability Fuel-Switching Capability Alain Bousquet and Norbert Ladoux y University of Toulouse, IDEI and CEA June 3, 2003 Abstract Taking into account the link between energy demand and equipment choice, leads to

More information

CAPITAL MOBILITY AND TAX COMPETITION: A SURVEY

CAPITAL MOBILITY AND TAX COMPETITION: A SURVEY CAPITAL MOBILITY AND TAX COMPETITION: A SURVEY CLEMENS FUEST BERND HUBER JACK MINTZ CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 956 CATEGORY PUBLIC FINANCE MAY 2003 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded from

More information

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes James E. Anderson February 6, 2009 These notes derive the useful concepts of trade expenditure functions, the closely related trade indirect utility

More information

MEASURING TAXES ON INCOME FROM CAPITAL:

MEASURING TAXES ON INCOME FROM CAPITAL: MEASURING TAXES ON INCOME FROM CAPITAL: Michael P Devereux THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES WP03/04 MEASURING TAXES ON INCOME FROM CAPITAL Michael P. Devereux University of Warwick, IFS and CEPR First

More information

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH EXCHANGE RATE POLICY AND ENDOGENOUS PRICE FLEXIBILITY Michael B. Devereux HKIMR Working Paper No.20/2004 October 2004 Working Paper No.1/ 2000 Hong Kong Institute

More information

Firm-Specific Human Capital as a Shared Investment: Comment

Firm-Specific Human Capital as a Shared Investment: Comment Firm-Specific Human Capital as a Shared Investment: Comment By EDWIN LEUVEN AND HESSEL OOSTERBEEK* Employment relationships typically involve the division of surplus. Surplus can be the result of a good

More information

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings J Econ Finan (2010) 34:23 29 DOI 10.1007/s12197-008-9070-2 Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings Faruk Balli Rosmy J. Louis Mohammad Osman Published online: 24 December 2008 Springer Science + Business

More information

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Corporate Control Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Managerial Discipline and Takeovers Managers often don t maximize the value of the firm; either because they are not capable

More information

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL) EC 450 Advanced Macroeconomics Instructor: Sharif F. Khan Department of Economics Wilfrid Laurier University Winter 2008 Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL) Part B Problem Solving Questions

More information

Optimal Disclosure and Fight for Attention

Optimal Disclosure and Fight for Attention Optimal Disclosure and Fight for Attention January 28, 2018 Abstract In this paper, firm managers use their disclosure policy to direct speculators scarce attention towards their firm. More attention implies

More information

Internet Taxation. Francis Bloch. Toulouse, Postal Conference, April 16, Université Paris 1 and PSE

Internet Taxation. Francis Bloch. Toulouse, Postal Conference, April 16, Université Paris 1 and PSE Internet Taxation Francis Bloch Université Paris 1 and PSE Toulouse, Postal Conference, April 16, 2016 Bloch (PSE) Internet Taxation April 1, 2016 1 / 29 Introduction Taxation of Internet Platforms Internet

More information

The Elasticity of Corporate Taxable Income - Evidence from South Africa

The Elasticity of Corporate Taxable Income - Evidence from South Africa The Elasticity of Corporate Taxable Income - Evidence from South Africa Collen Lediga a, Nadine Riedel a,b,, Kristina Strohmaier c a University of Bochum b CESifo Munich c University of Tübingen Abstract

More information

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background 2 Theory 2.1 One Country 2.1.1 Background The theory that has guided the specification of the US model was first presented in Fair (1974) and then in Chapter 3 in Fair (1984). This work stresses three

More information

Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness

Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness James Dow Itay Goldstein Alexander Guembel London Business University of University of Oxford School Pennsylvania European Central Bank, 15-16 May, 2006

More information

Equilibrium Audit Strategies Against Tax Treaty Shopping

Equilibrium Audit Strategies Against Tax Treaty Shopping Equilibrium Audit Strategies Against Tax Treaty Shopping Sunghoon Hong April 2019 Abstract This paper examines game-theoretic models of tax treaty shopping. An investor can choose a direct or indirect

More information

research paper series

research paper series research paper series Research Paper 00/9 Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market by A. Mukherjee The Centre acknowledges financial support from The

More information

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser. University of Konstanz Department of Economics Optimal Contracting with Reciprocal Agents in a Competitive Search Model Maria Breitwieser Working Paper Series 2015-16 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/econdoc/working-paper-series/

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

BEPS, SPILLOVERS, ETC.: CURRENT ISSUES IN INTERNATIONAL CORPORATE TAXATION

BEPS, SPILLOVERS, ETC.: CURRENT ISSUES IN INTERNATIONAL CORPORATE TAXATION BEPS, SPILLOVERS, ETC.: CURRENT ISSUES IN INTERNATIONAL CORPORATE TAXATION Michael Keen JTA-IFA Tokyo, April 10 2015 See IMF (2014), Spillovers in international corporate taxation Views should not be attributed

More information

OWNERSHIP AND RESIDUAL RIGHTS OF CONTROL Ownership is usually considered the best way to incentivize economic agents:

OWNERSHIP AND RESIDUAL RIGHTS OF CONTROL Ownership is usually considered the best way to incentivize economic agents: OWNERSHIP AND RESIDUAL RIGHTS OF CONTROL Ownership is usually considered the best way to incentivize economic agents: To create To protect To increase The value of their own assets 1 How can ownership

More information

Do Tax Havens Divert Economic Activity?

Do Tax Havens Divert Economic Activity? Do Tax Havens Divert Economic Activity? Mihir A. Desai Harvard University and NBER C. Fritz Foley Harvard University and NBER and James R. Hines Jr. University of Michigan and NBER April, 005 The authors

More information

Rural Financial Intermediaries

Rural Financial Intermediaries Rural Financial Intermediaries 1. Limited Liability, Collateral and Its Substitutes 1 A striking empirical fact about the operation of rural financial markets is how markedly the conditions of access can

More information

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1 Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose,

More information

Centralized vs. De-centralized Multinationals and Taxes

Centralized vs. De-centralized Multinationals and Taxes Centralized vs. De-centralized Multinationals and Taxes Søren Bo Nielsen Copenhagen Business School, EPRU, CEPR, and CESifo Pascalis Raimondos-Møller Copenhagen Business School, EPRU, CEPR, and CESifo

More information

Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information

Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information Journal of Accounting Research Vol. 39 No. 3 December 2001 Printed in U.S.A. Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information MARK BAGNOLI, MARK PENNO, AND SUSAN G. WATTS Received 29 December

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Profit-sharing rules and taxation of multinational two-sided platforms

Profit-sharing rules and taxation of multinational two-sided platforms Profit-sharing rules and taxation of multinational two-sided platforms Francis Bloch Gabrielle Demange September 18, 2018 Abstract This paper analyzes taxation of a two-sided platform attracting users

More information

Income Taxation, Wealth Effects, and Uncertainty: Portfolio Adjustments with Isoelastic Utility and Discrete Probability

Income Taxation, Wealth Effects, and Uncertainty: Portfolio Adjustments with Isoelastic Utility and Discrete Probability Boston University School of Law Scholarly Commons at Boston University School of Law Faculty Scholarship 8-6-2014 Income Taxation, Wealth Effects, and Uncertainty: Portfolio Adjustments with Isoelastic

More information

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Henrik Horn (Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm) Giovanni Maggi (Princeton University) Robert W. Staiger (Stanford University and

More information

Economics 230a, Fall 2018 Lecture Note 14: Tax Competition

Economics 230a, Fall 2018 Lecture Note 14: Tax Competition Economics 30a, Fall 018 Lecture Note 14: Tax Competition We have discussed the incentives for individual countries in designing tax policy, but an important issue is how the tax policies in one country

More information

The impact of worldwide vs territorial taxation on the location of assets and the scale of investment: A survey of the empirical evidence

The impact of worldwide vs territorial taxation on the location of assets and the scale of investment: A survey of the empirical evidence The impact of worldwide vs territorial taxation on the location of assets and the scale of investment: A survey of the empirical evidence Martin Simmler University of Oxford Centre for Business Taxation

More information

Is regulatory capital pro-cyclical? A macroeconomic assessment of Basel II

Is regulatory capital pro-cyclical? A macroeconomic assessment of Basel II Is regulatory capital pro-cyclical? A macroeconomic assessment of Basel II (preliminary version) Frank Heid Deutsche Bundesbank 2003 1 Introduction Capital requirements play a prominent role in international

More information

Resale Price and Cost-Plus Methods: The Expected Arm s Length Space of Coefficients

Resale Price and Cost-Plus Methods: The Expected Arm s Length Space of Coefficients International Alessio Rombolotti and Pietro Schipani* Resale Price and Cost-Plus Methods: The Expected Arm s Length Space of Coefficients In this article, the resale price and cost-plus methods are considered

More information

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations Timothy J. Goodspeed Hunter College and CUNY Graduate Center timothy.goodspeed@hunter.cuny.edu November 9, 2014 Abstract: Taxation of the

More information

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure Corporate Financial Management Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure As we discussed in previous lectures, two extreme results, namely the irrelevance of capital structure and 100 percent

More information

Strategic Consolidation under Formula Apportionment

Strategic Consolidation under Formula Apportionment Strategic Consolidation under Formula Apportionment THIESS BUETTNER NADINE RIEDEL MARCO RUNKEL CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 2484 CATEGORY 1: PUBLIC FINANCE DECEMBER 2008 An electronic version of the paper

More information

SAVING-INVESTMENT CORRELATION. Introduction. Even though financial markets today show a high degree of integration, with large amounts

SAVING-INVESTMENT CORRELATION. Introduction. Even though financial markets today show a high degree of integration, with large amounts 138 CHAPTER 9: FOREIGN PORTFOLIO EQUITY INVESTMENT AND THE SAVING-INVESTMENT CORRELATION Introduction Even though financial markets today show a high degree of integration, with large amounts of capital

More information

The impact of interest rates and the housing market on the UK economy

The impact of interest rates and the housing market on the UK economy The impact of interest and the housing market on the UK economy....... The Chancellor has asked Professor David Miles to examine the UK market for longer-term fixed rate mortgages. This paper by Adrian

More information

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation May 1, 1997 On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation Yoshitsugu Kanemoto 1 Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo 7-3-1 Hongo, Bunkyo-ku, Tokyo 113 Japan Abstract The most important drawback

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Chapter 2 Fiscal Policies in Germany and France

Chapter 2 Fiscal Policies in Germany and France Chapter Fiscal Policies in Germany and France. The Model ) Introduction. For ease of exposition we make the following assumptions. The monetary union consists of two countries, say Germany and France.

More information

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies Lecture 14 Multinational Firms 1. Review of empirical evidence 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies 3. A model with endogenous multinationals 4. Pattern of trade in goods

More information

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy 1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy We start our analysis of fiscal policy by stating a neutrality result for fiscal policy which is due to David Ricardo (1817), and whose formal illustration is due

More information

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics June. - 2011 Trade, Development and Growth For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option Instructions

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 07/05 Firm heterogeneity, foreign direct investment and the hostcountry welfare: Trade costs vs. cheap labor By Arijit Mukherjee

More information

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules WILLIAM A. BRANCH TROY DAVIG BRUCE MCGOUGH Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules This paper examines the implications of forward- and backward-looking monetary policy

More information

Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply and the Short-Run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment Questions for Review 1. In this chapter we looked at two models of the short-run aggregate supply curve. Both models

More information

Taxation of firms with unknown mobility

Taxation of firms with unknown mobility Taxation of firms with unknown mobility Johannes Becker Andrea Schneider University of Münster University of Münster Institute for Public Economics Institute for Public Economics Wilmergasse 6-8 Wilmergasse

More information

Why Countries Differ in Thin Capitalization Rules: The Role of Financial Development

Why Countries Differ in Thin Capitalization Rules: The Role of Financial Development Why Countries Differ in Thin Capitalization Rules: The Role of Financial Development Mohammed Mardan CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 5295 CATEGORY 1: PUBLIC FINANCE APRIL 2015 An electronic version of the paper

More information

Sandra Ludwig; Philipp C. Wichardt und Hanke Wickhorst: Overconfidence Can Improve an Agent s Relative and Absolute Performance in Contests

Sandra Ludwig; Philipp C. Wichardt und Hanke Wickhorst: Overconfidence Can Improve an Agent s Relative and Absolute Performance in Contests Sandra Ludwig; Philipp C. Wichardt und Hanke Wickhorst: Overconfidence Can Improve an Agent s Relative and Absolute Performance in Contests Munich Discussion Paper No. 2010-35 Department of Economics University

More information

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Transport Costs and North-South Trade Transport Costs and North-South Trade Didier Laussel a and Raymond Riezman b a GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II b Department of Economics, University of Iowa Abstract We develop a simple two country

More information

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS 2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS JEL Classification: H21,H3,H41,H43 Keywords: Second best, excess burden, public input. Remarks 1. A version of this chapter has been accepted

More information