Inferring Trader Behavior from Transaction Data: A Simple Model

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Inferring Trader Behavior from Transaction Data: A Simple Model"

Transcription

1 Inferring Trader Behavior from Transaction Data: A Simple Model by David Jackson* First draft: May 08, 2003 This draft: May 08, 2003 * Sprott School of Business Telephone: (613) Ext Carleton University djackson@sprott.carleton.ca 710 Dunton Tower 1125 Colonel By Drive Ottawa, Ontario K1S 5B6

2

3 Inferring Trader Behavior from Transaction Data: A Simple Model Abstract A model is presented that uses trade counts to characterize the arrival of news and the propensity of informed and uninformed traders to transact. Our model has extremely low data requirements, is very fast to estimate and is adaptable for different research applications. The model is used to investigate changes in the bid / ask spread in conjunction with trades. We develop and estimate an innovative extension of the model that relaxes the assumption that news is independent from day to day.

4

5 Introduction In 1987, Easley and O Hara (EO) introduced a discrete-time, sequential trade microstructure model 1 that shines a light on the flow of information about an asset and reveals some characteristics of subsequent informed and uninformed trading. A strength of the EO model is its limited data requirements. Transaction counts of buying and selling, along with counts of non-trading periods are enough to estimate the probability that informed traders are active in a given asset market. Because most data sets do not provide the buy / sell direction of trades, EO use the Lee and Ready algorithm 2 to classify trade direction. The idea underlying the Lee and Ready method is to use both transaction and quote data to infer trade direction. A transaction price above the mid-quote is classified as buy-initiated; a transaction price below the mid-quote is classified as sell-initiated. As implemented in EO s published papers, no allowance is made for the uncertainty introduced by estimating trade direction. In effect, a researcher using the Lee and Ready algorithm in this way assumes more precise information than is available. Trade classification schemes have been shown to classify trades imperfectly, 3 however, raising questions about test outcomes that are dependent upon estimates from the EO model. In this paper, we derive a sequential trade model that uses trade counts only. There is no use of the unobserved trade direction, removing any concerns about misclassification of trades and understated standard errors. Our model, thus, has very low data preparation Easley and O Hara, Journal of Financial Economics, Lee and Ready, Journal of Finance, Theissen, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money, 2000.

6 requirements, is extremely fast to estimate and is adaptable to different research applications. Ours is an example of models in which a subset of traders have private information about the value of the asset. These traders act to profit from their information at the expense of uninformed liquidity traders and the market maker. The directed trading behavior of the informed enables the market maker and other uninformed market observers to make inferences about the true value of the asset. Glosten and Milgrom provide an early sequential trade, asymmetric information model. 4 Sequential trade models allow only one trader at a time, and place some limit on the size of an individual trade. Because informed traders must wait their turn and because trade size is limited, informed trading is not instantly revealing. Thus, sequential trade models have the potential to show time series patterns in learning about the asset s value. Indeed, the process of learning by the market maker is a primary focus of the Easley and O Hara BSN model upon which our TNT model is based. The richness of information provided by buy and sell counts enables the BSN model to infer a bid / ask spread time series that reflects the parameters of the news process and the balance of informed and uninformed trading activity. By using trade counts only, the TNT model gives up the ability to infer the spread. Our contribution is to provide a model is very easy to work with and that does not suffer from possible misclassification of trade direction. We will demonstrate our trade / no-trade (TNT) model and briefly compare our parameter estimates with those provided by the EO buy / sell / no-trade (BSN) model. Both the TNT and BSN models assume day-to-day independence of information. We will 2

7 test this assumption and extend our model to allow for information that is not revealed to the public for two days. Finally, we present a generalisation of the TNT model that we use to investigate whether or not market makers change their quoted spreads in response to trading activity. This paper is organised as follows. Section 1 presents the EO buy / sell / no-trade (BSN) model and our trade / no-trade (TNT) model. The TNT model makes no assumptions about trade direction. In Section 2 the data is described. In Section 3 the model is estimated, and some robustness and goodness of fit tests are performed. Section 4 generalizes the model to estimate the propensity of market makers to change spreads around informed and uninformed trades. In Section 5 we summarise what we have demonstrated. 1. Two Discrete-Time Sequential Trade Models In a world with a single, risky asset, we model sequential trade between investors and a market maker. A key feature of the models considered here is that news about the value of the asset is generated intermittently. On any given day, there is uncertainty about whether or not the value of the asset has changed since the previous day. Before the start of trading, news about the end-of-day value of the asset is generated with a probability,. Any such news is bad with probability and good with probability 1 of each trading day, the news becomes publicly available.. At the end The market maker is risk neutral and faces competition, so quotes are set at the expected value of the asset, conditional on the trade direction of the next transaction. There are 4 Glosten and Milgrom, Journal of Financial Economics,

8 assumed to be a fixed number of trading periods during the day, with one trade possible during any one period. All trades are for one unit of the asset, with all buys occurring at the ask and all sells at the bid. In each trading period, one potential trader arrives at the market. This trader observes any news with probability. If news is observed, this (informed) trader always trades, buying on good news and selling on bad. If news is not observed, this (uninformed) trader makes a liquidity trade with probability or chooses not to trade with probability 1. Similarly, on days, with no news, each trader must be uninformed and trades with probability or chooses not to trade with probability 1. Uninformed trades are equally likely to be buys or sells. The market maker can learn from periods of non-trading because they are more likely on days with no information than on days with good or bad news. 1.1 The EO BSN Model The EO trading structure is depicted in Figure 1. Note that a draw from the news generating process (no news, good news, bad news) occurs once during the day, whereas only the first of many trading periods is represented in Figure 1. For a given day, the probability of observing B buys, S sells, and NT no-trade periods, given the model parameters is Pr BSNT,,,,, BS B S NT B S NT NT 4

9 Day-to-day news events are assumed to be independent, so the likelihood function for many days is the product of the daily probabilities. The log-likelihood function for D trading days is D LBSN log Pr Bd, Sd, NTd,,, d 1 B S NT 2 2 B S NT log NT log 1 BS 1.2 The TNT Model The BSN model relies upon counts of buys and sells. Since trade direction is not provided in most transaction databases, it is useful to consider a model that depends only upon counts of trades. This simplified trade model is depicted in Figure 2. Because trade direction is not observed, the TNT model does not distinguish between days with good or bad news. Similarly, the propensity of uninformed traders to buy rather than sell becomes irrelevant. What this model captures is the intuition that trade will tend to be more intense on news days than on no-news days. A news day should have a higher count of trades and fewer no-trade periods than a day with no news. For a given day with T trades and NT no-trade periods, the likelihood function is T T NT NT Pr T, NT,, The log-likelihood function for D trading days is 5

10 L TNT D log Pr T, NT,, d 1 T NT T NT log Data Transaction and quote data is obtained from the TORQ database. The TORQ database provides quotes, orders and associated transaction prices for 144 NYSE securities from November 01, 1990 through to January 31, The securities in TORQ were chosen randomly so as to be distributed evenly among NYSE size quintiles. In order to remove securities that may have different trading practices and timing of information effects than common shares, we eliminate all REIT s, units, and closed-end funds. Because the model requires a certain level of trading activity to estimate meaningful parameters, we eliminate all common stocks that have many days with no market order transactions, including at least one stretch of more than five trading days with no transactions. This study uses 20 of the remaining 98 common stocks. For each stock, trade price and trade size for all market order transactions after the open are saved. Bid-ask spread and midquote price are calculated from the ask and bid quote time series. To allow for imperfect synchronisation between the quote and transaction time clocks, a quote must be in effect 5 seconds before a trade execution. Buy and sell direction of each transaction is inferred following the Lee and Ready (1991) algorithm. Following EO (1997), a 5 minute window without a trade is counted as a non-trading period. EO (1997) use data for 60 trading days to estimate the parameters of their model. For this study, we use the 60 trading days from November 06, 1990 through to January 31,

11 Table 1 lists summary statistics of counts of trades, no-trade periods and inferred buys and sells for the 20 stocks. The overall stock market increased sharply over the three months covered by the TORQ data. This is the probable explanation for the excess of buys over sells in Table 1. The mean daily trade count varies by a factor of nine from GLX to EMC, but the mean daily no-trade count varies only by a factor of two. This suggests that trades tend to cluster, rather than be uniformly distributed through the trading day. 3. Model Estimation Estimating the TNT Model Table 3 presents maximum likelihood estimates for 20 NYSE firms from the TORQ database. Daily trade counts for 60 trading days are used along with a five minute notrade interval. The log likelihood function is well behaved. Estimation is very fast and 60 days of data is sufficient to get significant estimates of all three parameters of the model:, the probability of a news day,, the probability that on a news day a given trader is informed, and, the probability that an uninformed trader chooses to trade. The model parameters,,,, can be used to calculate the probability of an informed trade, PI 1. Table 3 reveals a fair degree of cross-sectional variation in all four parameters. For example, over this period, the probability of an informed trade, PI, varies from 6.5% for FFB to 52.7% for HAN. Comparing the BSN and TNT Models Is the TNT model simply a restricted version of the BSN model? For example, are similar parameter estimates obtained if one uses the BSN model, but does not assume that 7

12 buy/sell direction is observable? Let us compare the TNT model to a version of the BSN model in which one half of the total number of trades are assigned to be buys and the other half are assigned to be sells. Further, set the probability of bad news,, equal to one half. Pr BS T 2, NT,,, 1 2 T T 1 T NT NT Compare this to the TNT equation. T T NT NT Pr T, NT,, The restricted BSN model does not reduce to a multiple of the TNT model. Since the two equations differ in their first term, the two equations will give different estimates for the parameters,,. None the less, does the BSN model give parameter estimates close to those of the TNT model? Table 3 presents estimates for Ashland Oil, 5 the firm used by Easley, Kiefer and O Hara (1997) to demonstrate the BSN model. The 95 percent confidence intervals for,, overlap. Since one model is driven by buy and sell counts and the other model is driven by their sum, we would hope to find consistent parameter estimates. Notice that is estimated with much less precision than and. Since there are many trading opportunities during a day, but 5 Thirty trading days of buy / sell / no-trade counts for Ashland Oil come from Table 1 in Easley, Kiefer and O Hara, Review of Financial Studies,

13 only one draw from the news process, we effectively have more observations for estimating, than. Are parameter estimates always so consistent for the two models? Table 4 presents 30 and 60 day parameter estimates for four NYSE firms that were selected to represent a range of trading activity. Given the relatively large standard errors, estimates for the probability of a news day,, mostly fall within the 95% confidence intervals. Such is not the case for other parameters, however. The estimates provided by the two models, for the probability that uninformed traders choose to transact,, and for the probability that a trader is informed on a news day,, differ significantly in many instances. Estimates of the probability of informed trading, PI, can be quite different too. This suggests some caution when using either model for research. Tests that rely upon absolute levels of the parameters may be sensitive to which model is chosen. Model Specification Sensitivity to Choice of No-Trade Interval A number of specification tests will now be presented. Looking first at parameter stability, Table 5 shows 60-day parameter estimates as the time specified for a no-trade period varies from one minute to 10 minutes. All estimates increase with the length of a no-trade period, especially for the 10 minute interval. Estimates of the probability of news,, are fairly consistent for different no-trade periods. This is expected, since reflects relative levels of trading from day to day, not relative levels of trading to nontrading. The probabilities that a trader is informed on a news day,, and that an uninformed trader chooses to transact,, both increase with the length of a no-trade 9

14 period. This is expected, since and reflect levels of trading relative to trading opportunities within each day. Two important composite measures of trade are, the fraction of informed trades on a new days and PI, the fraction of informed trades. We would like the model s estimates of and PI to reflect the flow of private information during a given period, without being sensitive to the choice of a no-trade interval. Table 5 shows that the increase in the estimates of and PI are proportional to the length of the no-trade period. The rate of increase is small, however, averaging 1.5% per minute for and 1.6% per minute for PI. Do Intermittent News and Private Information Help Explain Trade? The TNT model explains daily trade counts in terms of intermittent news events, captured by, and traders with different trading propensities on days with news than days without. One test of the model specification is to compare this model to one in which news is not intermittent, making trading propensity fixed from day to day. Which model is more likely given the data? The model restriction constrains the probability of news,, to be 1. With one parameter constrained, the likelihood ratio statistic is approximately distributed chi-squared, with one degree of freedom. We reject the restricted model for large values of the statistic. The five percent rejection value is Likelihood ratio statistics were calculated from 60-day estimates for the 20 NYSE firms. The smallest statistic from the 20 firms was 269, soundly rejecting the restricted model. The TNT model, with news on some days and no news on others better explains the data than a model in which each day is a news day. 10

15 Are News Events Independent from Day to Day? The two sequential trade models considered so far specify that any news about firm value is revealed at the end of each trading day. This specification results in a model with a very simple structure, but may be a poor representation of the information process driving trades. Easley, Kiefer and O Hara (EKO 1997), test and cannot reject the hypothesis that day-to-day news is independent for their one firm, Ashland Oil. One wonders whether or not this daily independence of news holds more generally. Although it is the quality of the predictions from a model that matters, not the realism of the assumptions, we will test for independence of day-to-day news events. Testing for independence is difficult because news events are not observed. Following EKO, we use the estimated probability of a news day,, to infer news events. Consider the firm, FPL, which has an of We assume that approximately of the trading days have news events. When FPL s daily trade counts are sorted, the twentysecond highest trade count is found to be 166. All days with trade count greater than 166 are categorized as news days; all days with a count less than 166 are categorized as nonnews days. Days with exactly 166 trades are ignored. For FPL there are n = 21 news days and m = 38 non-news days. Runs of news and non-news days are counted. Under the null of news independence, the number of runs is approximately normally distributed, with: mean 2nm n m 1 and 2 var iance 2nm 2nm n m n m n m

16 Table 6 presents the results of the runs tests on the 20 NYSE firms. The null hypothesis of independence is rejected in 11 of the 20 firms. We also look at trade autocorrelations. If news is independent from day to day, there should be no AR structure to daily trade counts. Table 7 gives the first four autocorrelations of daily trades for the 20 firms. The first order autocorrelation is significant for 13 of the firms. Higher order autocorrelations are significant for five of the 13. Together, the runs and autocorrelation tests suggest that news is independent from day to day for some firms, but not for others. The TNT model can be adapted to model news that lasts more than one day. Figure 3 depicts a generalisation of the TNT model that allows for news that is revealed to the public at the end of two days. A new parameter in the two-day model is, the probability that yesterday s news is observed today, given that there was news yesterday. becomes the probability that today s news is observed today, given that there is new today. It seems plausible that the probability of observing news that has been around for a while may differ from the probability of observing news that has recently been generated. Yesterday s informed trading may have lead to a search for yesterday s news, increasing the likelihood of it being observed. Alternatively, after yesterday s informed trading, much of the value of the news may already be incorporated into prices, reducing the incentive to search for the old news. Extending news beyond one day makes the two-day model considerably more complex than the one-day news model. In particular, the two-day model is dependent upon the order of days with and without news. Although it would be possible to write out the 12

17 likelihood function for the two-day TNT model, the path dependence means that the likelihood function is no longer a product of identical daily terms. We have implemented estimation of the model in a recursive routine. Estimation is fairly fast, but a linearisation of the log likelihood function is used to prevent overflow and underflow during the likelihood maximisation. Table 8 presents parameter estimates for the two-day TNT model. For firms in which news is independent from day to day, we would expect to see a low value of, because the probability of seeing yesterday s news today is zero if the news was revealed after one day. should also be smaller than the estimate for the oneday model, because we are weighting the case in which a trader sees yesterday s news yesterday. For firms in which news is not independent from day to day, we expect a nonzero, and because yesterday s news is explaining some of today s trading, we again expect to smaller than the estimate for the one-day model. 4. Extensions: Do Bid / Ask Spreads Respond to Trading? In their 1997 paper, Easley, Kiefer and O Hara (EKO) demonstrate an extension of the BSN model to test whether or not informed trades concentrate in larger trade sizes. EKO find no evidence that larger trades are more likely to be informed trades. In another paper, we intend to use the TNT model to give this intriguing result a thorough examination. In this article, we will demonstrate how the TNT model can be extended to study how market makers behave in changing the bid / ask spread. Do market makers increase the spread if they believe that informed traders are active? If so, are the spreads increased before or after the informed trading? Can market makers even distinguish informed from uninformed trades on average? To investigate these 13

18 questions, we will use quote data in addition to transaction data to count when there is a spread increase in conjunction with a trade and when there is no spread increase in conjunction with a trade. Figure 4 depicts the diagram of the trading process for this extended model. Two new parameters are added to the model. is the probability that the spread increases when there is an informed trade. is the probability that the spread increases when there is an uninformed trade. Table 9 presents 60-day estimates of the model for the 20 NYSE firms. The model parameters have been estimated twice for each firm for counts of spread increases before trade,,, and for counts of spread increases after trade,,. 6 Table 9 also shows SI, the probability of a spread increase when there is any trade. Look first at the question whether the spread tends to increase more often before or after trade. There is no evidence that differs from or that differs from. Spreads are not more likely to increase before a trade than after, whether that trade is informed or not. Look next at the question whether or not the spread tends to increase more in conjunction with informed than uninformed trading. The estimates of the probability of an increase with informed trades are generally smaller than the estimates for informed trades, but the difference is significant at the 5 percent level only for CPC, CMY, AL, FBO and FPC. These results are similar whether we consider spread changes before or after trades. It 6 The quote time series corresponds to bid and ask quotes in effect at the time of market order transactions. The spread is the ask minus the bid. A spread change is calculated as the spread in effect for the market order transaction at time t minus the spread in effect for the market order transaction at time t-1. Note that the spread may change more than once or not at all between market order transactions, it is the cumulative change that is calculated here. 14

19 would seem that spreads are less likely to increase in conjunction with informed than uninformed trading. This result is an interpretation of the data in the context of the model. News days are not observable. Days with relatively many trades are interpreted as days with news, and some of the trades on these days are interpreted as informed. Given this, we conclude that market makers prefer to increase spreads around uninformed trades. One might argue that this result makes little sense, in that it suggests that market makers have some ability to distinguish informed from uninformed trades, and that they prefer to increase the spread around the uninformed trades. A more likely interpretation is that the spread increases for uninformed trades are related to the lighter trading during days without news. At any time, proportional spreads tend to be higher for lower volume stocks. For many of the same reasons, one might expect to see time series variation in spread, reflecting differences in volume from day to day. 5. Conclusions We have demonstrated the viability and usefulness of the trade / no-trade (TNT) model that depends only upon transaction counts to infer features of market maker and trader behavior. The model s assumption of intermittent news performs well compared to one in which news arrives every day. The model s assumption of day-to-day independence of the news is not well supported for many firms. We have shown that the model can be extended to allow for news that lasts for one day. Using an extension of the basic one-day news model, we find that market makers are no more likely to increase the bid / ask spread before a trade than after. We do find that the 15

20 spread is more likely to increase around an uninformed trade than around an informed trade. This may simply reflect higher per share costs of market making under the lower trade volume of days with no news. 16

21 References Easley, D., S. Hvidkjaer, and M. O Hara, 2002, Is information risk a determinant of asset returns?, Working paper. Easley, D., N. Kiefer, and M. O Hara, 1996, Cream-skimming or profit-sharing? The curious role of purchased order flow, Journal of Finance, 51, Easley, D., N. Kiefer, M. O Hara, and J. Paperman, 1996, Liquidity, information and infrequently traded stocks, Journal of Finance, 51, Easley, D., and M. O Hara, 1987, Price, trade size, and information in securities markets, Journal of Financial Economics, 19, Easley, D., and M. O Hara, 1997, One day in the life of a very common stock, Review of Financial Studies, 10, Glosten, L., and P. Milgrom, 1985, Bid, ask, and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed traders Journal of Financial Economics, 13, Lee, C., and M. Ready, 1991, Inferring trade direction from intraday data, Journal of Finance, 46, Theissen, E., 2000, A test of the accuracy of the Lee/Ready trade classification algorithm, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money, 11,

22 Appendix Informed Trader Sells Uninformed Seller Sells Bad News Uninformed Seller No-Trade Uninformed Buyer Buys Day With News 1-1- Good News 12 Informed Trader Buys Uninformed Buyer No-Trade Uninformed Seller Sells Uninformed Seller No-Trade Uninformed Buyer Buys Day With No News Uninformed Buyer No-Trade Uninformed Seller Sells Uninformed Seller No-Trade Uninformed Buyer Buys Before Start of Trading Day During Trading Day Uninformed Buyer No-Trade Figure 1 EO s Discrete-Time (BSN) Model: Trade Direction Observable Once each day, before trading starts, nature chooses either good news, bad news, or no news. is the probability of a day with news; is the probability that any news is bad. Every trading period during the day, the trader in line to trade may observe the news. If so, there is an informed trade. If not, the trader may or may not choose to make an uninformed trade. is the probability that the trade is from an informed trader, given a news day; is the probability that an uninformed trader chooses to trade. 18

23 Informed Trade 1- Uninformed Trade 1- Day With News No Trade 1- Day With No News Uninformed Trade Before Start Of Trading Day During Trading Day 1- No Trade Figure 2 Simplified Discrete-Time (TNT) Model: Trade Direction Not Observable Once each day, before trading starts, nature chooses whether or not to generate news. is the probability of a day with news. Every trading period during the day, the trader in line to trade may observe the news. If so, there is an informed trade. If not, the trader may or may not choose to make an uninformed trade. is the probability that the trade is from an informed trader, given a news day; is the probability that an uninformed trader chooses to trade. 19

24 Assume No News on Day 0 1- Informed Trade Uninformed Trade Uninformed No-Trade Uninformed Trade Uninformed No-Trade 2 Before Start of Trading Day During Trading Day 1 Days 2+ Represent by Informed Trade Uninformed Trade Uninformed No-Trade Informed Trade Uninformed Trade Represent by Informed Trade Uninformed Trade Uninformed No-Trade Uninformed Trade 1 1- Uninformed No-Trade 1- Uninformed No-Trade Figure 3 TNT Model For News That Becomes Public After Two Days Once each day, before trading starts, nature chooses whether or not to generate news. is the probability of a day with news. Every trading period during the day, the trader in line to trade may observe the news for today or the news for yesterday. If so, there is an informed trade. If not, the trader may or may not choose to make an uninformed trade. Given news today; is the probability that the trade is from an informed trader on today s news. is the probability that the trade is from an informed trader on yesterday s news. is the probability that an uninformed trader chooses to trade, given the opportunity. 2 To save space on the diagram, we define: 11 1 and If there is news today, then tomorrow s tree diagram has the form 1. If there is no news today, then tomorrow s tree diagram has the form 2. We assume that the first day of observations had no news on the (unobserved) previous day. 20

25 Informed Trade & Spread Increase 1- Informed Trade & Spread Non-increase Uninformed Trade & Spread Increase Day With News Uninformed Trade & Spread Non-increase No Trade 1- Uninformed Trade & Spread Increase Day With No News 1-1- Uninformed Trade & Spread Non-increase Before Start Of Trading Day During Trading Day No Trade Figure 4 TNT Model Extended to Track Increases in Bid / Ask Spread Once each day, before trading starts, nature chooses whether or not to generate news. is the probability of a day with news. Every trading period during the day, the trader in line to trade may observe the news. If so, there is an informed trade. If not, the trader may or may not choose to make an uninformed trade. Given a news day; is the probability that the trade is from an informed trader. is the probability that an uninformed trader chooses to trade, given the opportunity. Either immediately before or immediately after each trade, the market maker decides to increase the spread or not to increase it. Around informed trades, the market maker increases the spread with probability and around uninformed trades, the market maker increases the spread with probability. 21

26 Table 1 Summary Statistics of Trade Counts for 20 TORQ Firms 60-Day Stats Daily Number of Trade Size Daily # of Trade Price Buys Sells Trades (Shares) No-Trades ($) GLX Mean $32.90 Std $1.34 FPL Mean $28.49 Std $0.62 FNM Mean $33.96 Std $2.77 DI Mean $20.41 Std $1.42 AMD Mean $5.22 Std $0.99 CPC Mean $78.44 Std $2.54 CL Mean $70.47 Std $2.24 FDX Mean $34.08 Std $2.73 CMY Mean $27.43 Std $1.40 HAN Mean $18.44 Std $0.66 CUE Mean $12.84 Std $1.18 AL Mean $18.81 Std $1.15 CYR Mean $30.99 Std $3.69 FBO Mean $17.97 Std $1.82 CYM Mean $17.13 Std $1.68 FFB Mean $16.84 Std $1.55 DCN Mean $26.27 Std $2.49 AR Mean $26.13 Std $1.53 FPC Mean $38.15 Std $0.43 EMC Mean $8.85 Std $0.99 This table presents summary statistics for 20 firms NYSE used to estimate the BSN and TNT sequential trade models. Statistics are based upon 60 days of trade data for November 6, 1990 January 31, 1991 from the TORQ database. Buys and sells are inferred from transaction and quote data using the Lee and Ready (1991) algorithm. A five minute window without any transactions is counted as a non-trading period. The number of buys and sells are summed to give the number of trades for each day. Firms are sorted by daily number of trades. 22

27 Table 2 Parameter Estimates: 60 Trading Days; 5 Minute No-Trade Interval Pr[News] Pr[Informed Pr[Uninformed Pr[Informed news] trade] Trade] PI GLX (0.067) (0.016) (0.007) (0.000) FPL (0.070) (0.020) (0.011) (0.000) FNM (0.092) (0.025) (0.012) (0.000) DI (0.053) (0.026) (0.007) (0.000) AMD (0.060) (0.020) (0.008) (0.000) CPC (0.078) (0.019) (0.012) (0.000) CL (0.043) (0.031) (0.007) (0.000) FDX (0.064) (0.023) (0.009) (0.000) CMY (0.059) (0.022) (0.008) (0.000) HAN (0.056) (0.027) (0.031) (0.000) CUE (0.060) (0.023) (0.009) (0.000) AL (0.074) (0.016) (0.011) (0.000) CYR (0.080) (0.015) (0.014) (0.000) FBO (0.081) (0.023) (0.012) (0.000) CYM (0.052) (0.023) (0.007) (0.000) FFB (0.039) (0.033) (0.007) (0.000) DCN (0.039) (0.023) (0.006) (0.000) AR (0.052) (0.022) (0.007) (0.000) FPC (0.102) (0.029) (0.010) (0.000) EMC (0.058) (0.019) (0.008) (0.000) This table presents maximum likelihood estimates for the TNT sequential trade model. Estimates are based upon 60 days of trade data for November 6, 1990 January 31, 1991 for 20 NYSE firms. Firms are sorted by daily number of trades. GLX averages 155 trades per day; DI averages 94 trades; FDX averages 66 trades; and EMC averages 19 trades per day. A five minute window without any transactions is counted as a non-trading period. Standard errors are given in parentheses. 23

28 Table 3 Comparing Parameter Estimates, with and without Trade Direction: Ashland Oil 30 Trading Days Ashland Oil BSN (Buy, Sell, No-Trade) TNT (Trade, No-Trade) Pr[News], (0.1033) (0.1956) Pr[News is bad News], (0.1121) Not in model Pr[Informed News], (0.0138) (0.0216) Pr[Uninformed Trade Chance], (0.0119) (0.0331) Pr[Informed Trade], PI () () Log-Likelihood This table presents maximum likelihood parameter estimates for the BSN and TNT sequential trade models. Asymptotic standard errors are given in parentheses. Estimation uses 30 days of trade data for Ashland Oil (October 1, 1990 November 9, 1990) as supplied in Table 1 of EO (1987). Buys and sells are inferred from transaction and quote data using the Lee and Ready (1991) algorithm. A five minute window without any transactions is counted as a non-trading period. The number of buys and sells are summed to give the number of trades for each day. 24

29 Table 4 Comparing Parameter Estimates, With and Without Trade Direction: Selected TORQ Firms GLX TNT GLX BSN DI TNT DI BSN FDX TNT FDX BSN EMC TNT EMC BSN Pr[News] Pr[Bad News News] Pr[Informed News] Pr[Uninformed Trade Chance] Pr[Informed Trade] Days PI (0.091) n/a (0.026) (0.009) (0.000) (0.093) n/a (0.023) (0.010) (0.000) (0.067) n/a (0.016) (0.007) (0.000) (0.091) (0.277) (0.014) (0.008) (0.000) (0.091) (0.075) (0.015) (0.006) (0.000) (0.067) (0.033) (0.013) (0.005) (0.000) (0.132) n/a (0.046) (0.015) (0.000) (0.085) n/a (0.022) (0.011) (0.000) (0.053) n/a (0.026) (0.007) (0.000) (0.086) (0.079) (0.014) (0.010) (0.000) (0.086) (0.145) (0.023) (0.009) (0.000) (0.076) (0.076) (0.014) (0.007) (0.000) (0.067) n/a (0.039) (0.010) (0.000) (0.090) n/a (0.023) (0.011) (0.000) (0.064) n/a (0.023) (0.009) (0.000) (0.164) (0.343) (0.043) (0.014) (0.000) (0.081) (0.356) (0.018) (0.009) (0.000) (0.073) (0.385) (0.029) (0.009) (0.000) (0.074) n/a (0.025) (0.009) (0.000) (0.086) n/a (0.024) (0.011) (0.000) (0.058) n/a (0.019) (0.008) (0.000) (0.086) (0.127) (0.016) (0.009) (0.000) (0.105) (0.095) (0.016) (0.011) (0.000) (0.066) (0.076) (0.012) (0.007) (0.000) This table presents maximum likelihood parameter estimates for the BSN and TNT sequential trade models for four NYSE firms chosen to represent a range of trading activity. GLX averages 155 trades per day; DI averages 94 trades; FDX averages 66 trades; and EMC averages 19 trades per day. Estimation uses 60 days of trade data from the TORQ database (November 6, 1990 January 31, 1991).Estimates are shown for the full 60 days and for the two 30-day sub-periods. Buys and sells are inferred from transaction and quote data using the Lee and Ready (1991) algorithm. A five minute window without any transactions is counted as a non-trading period. The number of buys and sells are summed to give the number of trades for each day. Standard errors are given in parentheses. The parameters of the models are,, and. is the probability of a news day. Conditional on news, is the probability that the news is bad and is the probability that an informed trader comes forward to trade. is the probability that an uninformed investor chooses to trade, given the opportunity. 25

30 Table 5 Comparing Parameter Estimates for Different No-Trade Intervals GLX DI FDX EMC No-Trade Pr[News] Pr[Informed Pr[Uninformed Pr[Informed Pr[Informed Interval news] trade] Trade news] Trade] (Minutes) PI Maximum likelihood parameter estimates for the BSN and TNT trade models using different no-trade intervals. Respectively, a one, two, five or ten minute window without transactions is counted as a non-trading period. Results are shown for four NYSE firms chosen to represent a range of trading activity. GLX averages 155 trades per day; DI averages 94 trades; FDX averages 66 trades; and EMC averages 19 trades per day. Estimation uses 60 days of trade data from the TORQ database (November 6, 1990 January 31, 1991). Standard errors are given in parentheses. The model parameters are: is the probability of a news day, the probability that the current trader is informed and the probability that an uninformed investor chooses to trade. Derived parameter of the model are, 1 the fraction of informed trades on a news day and PI the fraction of informed trades. 26

31 Table 6 Runs Tests for Independence of News from Day to Day TNT Model Mean Number of Runs Under Null of Independence Actual Number of Runs GLX 30.5 (3.7) 12 * FPL 29.8 (3.6) 16 * FNM 28.3 (3.4) 24 DI 17.7 (2.1) 12 * AMD 23.5 (2.8) 16 * CPC 28.3 (3.4) 26 CL 11.8 (1.3) 10 FDX 21.4 (2.5) 16 * CMY 21.4 (2.5) 16 * HAN 16.3 (1.9) 13 CUE 20.2 (2.4) 20 AL 29.8 (3.6) 25 CYR 30.5 (3.7) 20 * FBO 24.5 (2.9) 22 CYM 17.7 (2.1) 18 FFB 08.5 (0.9) 6 * DCN 10.2 (1.1) 8 * AR 16.3 (1.9) 14 FPC 21.4 (2.5) 12 * EMC 22.5 (2.7) 8 * This table present runs tests for the hypothesis that news events are independent from day to day. Because the presence of news cannot be observed, estimates of the probability of news,, from Table 6 are used to categorize trading days as days with or without news. For each firm, daily trade counts are sorted. The 60 th highest trade count is taken as the demarcation point. Days with more than this number of trades are classified as news days (denoted by 1 s) and days with fewer trades are taken as no-news days (denoted by 0 s). Days with exactly this number of trades are ignored. Runs of 1 s and 0 s are totaled for the 60 trading days. Under the null hypothesis of day-to-day independence of the news, the number of runs has a normal distribution with: 2nm 2nm2nmnm Mean 1 and Variance 1, 2 n m nm nm1 where n is the number of news days and m is the number of no-news days. Estimates are based upon 60 days of trade data for November 6, 1990 January 31, 1991 for 20 NYSE firms. Firms are sorted by daily number of trades. GLX averages 155 trades per day; DI averages 94 trades; FDX averages 66 trades; and EMC averages 19 trades per day. Standard errors are given in parentheses. An asterisk indicates rejection of the null at the 5 percent level. 27

32 Table 7 Autocorrelation of Trade Counts for the 20 TORQ Firms Order of Autocorrelation * GLX (0.0000) (0.0025) (0.0002) (0.0019) * FPL (0.0009) (0.2152) (0.3411) (0.8227) * FNM (0.0067) (0.5732) (0.0729) (0.6035) * DI (0.0000) (0.0408) (0.0053) (0.0071) * AMD (0.0000) (0.0097) (0.0335) (0.0142) CPC (0.1171) (0.5811) (0.5145) (0.3782) * CL (0.0398) (0.7908) (0.7686) (0.9149) * FDX (0.0169) (0.6190) (0.7954) (0.1958) * CMY (0.0015) (0.2281) (0.6227) (0.8529) HAN (0.1717) (0.5427) (0.6339) (0.2545) CUE (0.1471) (0.0360) (0.6117) (0.8977) AL (0.0591) (0.7590) (0.6487) (0.9293) * CYR (0.0006) (0.2596) (0.7321) (0.5624) * FBO (0.0258) (0.6750) (0.5677) (0.7686) CYM (0.2795) (0.9655) (0.7824) (0.5030) * FFB (0.0144) (0.6676) (0.8755) (0.7449) DCN (0.1177) (0.7995) (0.7118) (0.7454) AR (0.0686) (0.6748) (0.8887) (0.3280) * FPC (0.0010) (0.0318) (0.0059) (0.2818) * EMC (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0029) (0.0701) This table presents autocorrelations of daily trade counts for 20 NYSE firms used to estimate the BSN and TNT sequential trade models. Autocorrelation estimates are based upon 60 days of trade data for November 6, 1990 January 31, Firms are sorted by daily number of trades. p-values are shown in parentheses. An asterisk indicates a first order autocorrelation that is different from zero at the 5 percent level. 28

33 Table 8 Parameter Estimates When News Becomes Public After Two Days Pr[News] Pr[Informed Pr[Informed Pr[Uninformed Pr[Informed News Today] News Yesterday] Trade] Trade] PI GLX () () () () FPL () () () () FNM () () () () DI () () () () AMD () () () () CPC () () () () CL () () () () FDX () () () () CMY () () () () HAN () () () () CUE () () () () AL () () () () CYR () () () () FBO () () () () CYM () () () () FFB () () () () DCN () () () () AR () () () () FPC () () () () EMC () () () () This table presents maximum likelihood estimates of the probability of a news day for the TNT sequential trade model. Estimates are based upon 60 days of trade data for November 6, 1990 January 31, 1991 for 20 NYSE firms. Firms are sorted by daily number of trades. GLX averages 155 trades per day; DI averages 94 trades; FDX averages 66 trades; and EMC averages 19 trades per day. A five minute window without any transactions is counted as a non-trading period. Standard errors are given in parentheses. 29

34 Table 9 Do Market Makers Increase Bid / Ask Spreads in Reaction to Informed Trading? Pr[Spread Increase] Before Pr[Spread Increase] After Informed Uninformed Any Trade Informed Uninformed Any Trade Trade Trade Trade Trade SI SI GLX (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) FPL (0.008) (0.007) (0.008) (0.007) FNM (0.012) (0.006) (0.012) (0.006) DI (0.012) (0.006) (0.012) (0.006) AMD (0.011) (0.006) (0.011) (0.006) CPC (0.019) (0.009) (0.019) (0.008) CL (0.023) (0.007) (0.023) (0.007) FDX 0.181(0.021) (0.008) (0.019) (0.008) CMY (0.015) (0.012) (0.015) (0.012) HAN (0.019) (0.025) (0.019) (0.026) CUE (0.023) (0.009) (0.023) (0.009) AL (0.018) (0.011) (0.017) (0.011) CYR (0.019) (0.011) (0.019) (0.011) FBO (0.020) (0.007) (0.020) (0.007) CYM (0.018) (0.009) (0.018) (0.008) FFB (0.021) (0.008) (0.021) (0.008) DCN (0.018) (0.015) (0.018) (0.015) AR (0.018) (0.008) (0.018) (0.008) FPC (0.052) (0.019) (0.051) (0.017) EMC (0.016) (0.015) (0.016) (0.014) This table presents maximum likelihood estimates for the TNT sequential trade model as extended to estimate the probabilities of spread change before or after trade. is the probability of a spread change before an informed trade, is the probability of a spread change before an uninformed trade and PI 1 PI is the probability of a spread change before any trade., and are the respective probabilities for spread change after. Estimates are based upon 60 days of trade data for November 6, 1990 January 31, 1991 for 20 NYSE firms. Firms are sorted by daily number of trades. GLX averages 155 trades per day; DI averages 94 trades; FDX averages 66 trades; and EMC averages 19 trades per day. A five minute window without any transactions is counted as a non-trading period. Standard errors are given in parentheses. 30

Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market

Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market Esen Onur 1 and Ufuk Devrim Demirel 2 September 2009 VERY PRELIMINARY & INCOMPLETE PLEASE DO NOT CITE WITHOUT AUTHORS PERMISSION

More information

Research Proposal. Order Imbalance around Corporate Information Events. Shiang Liu Michael Impson University of North Texas.

Research Proposal. Order Imbalance around Corporate Information Events. Shiang Liu Michael Impson University of North Texas. Research Proposal Order Imbalance around Corporate Information Events Shiang Liu Michael Impson University of North Texas October 3, 2016 Order Imbalance around Corporate Information Events Abstract Models

More information

Large price movements and short-lived changes in spreads, volume, and selling pressure

Large price movements and short-lived changes in spreads, volume, and selling pressure The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 39 (1999) 303 316 Large price movements and short-lived changes in spreads, volume, and selling pressure Raymond M. Brooks a, JinWoo Park b, Tie Su c, * a

More information

Internet Appendix: High Frequency Trading and Extreme Price Movements

Internet Appendix: High Frequency Trading and Extreme Price Movements Internet Appendix: High Frequency Trading and Extreme Price Movements This appendix includes two parts. First, it reports the results from the sample of EPMs defined as the 99.9 th percentile of raw returns.

More information

Lectures on Market Microstructure Illiquidity and Asset Pricing

Lectures on Market Microstructure Illiquidity and Asset Pricing Lectures on Market Microstructure Illiquidity and Asset Pricing Ingrid M. Werner Martin and Andrew Murrer Professor of Finance Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University 1 Liquidity and Asset

More information

The Reporting of Island Trades on the Cincinnati Stock Exchange

The Reporting of Island Trades on the Cincinnati Stock Exchange The Reporting of Island Trades on the Cincinnati Stock Exchange Van T. Nguyen, Bonnie F. Van Ness, and Robert A. Van Ness Island is the largest electronic communications network in the US. On March 18

More information

The Effect of Trading Volume on PIN's Anomaly around Information Disclosure

The Effect of Trading Volume on PIN's Anomaly around Information Disclosure 2011 3rd International Conference on Information and Financial Engineering IPEDR vol.12 (2011) (2011) IACSIT Press, Singapore The Effect of Trading Volume on PIN's Anomaly around Information Disclosure

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Are Retail Orders Different? Charles M. Jones Graduate School of Business Columbia University. and

Are Retail Orders Different? Charles M. Jones Graduate School of Business Columbia University. and Are Retail Orders Different? Charles M. Jones Graduate School of Business Columbia University and Marc L. Lipson Department of Banking and Finance Terry College of Business University of Georgia First

More information

COMPARATIVE MARKET SYSTEM ANALYSIS: LIMIT ORDER MARKET AND DEALER MARKET. Hisashi Hashimoto. Received December 11, 2009; revised December 25, 2009

COMPARATIVE MARKET SYSTEM ANALYSIS: LIMIT ORDER MARKET AND DEALER MARKET. Hisashi Hashimoto. Received December 11, 2009; revised December 25, 2009 cientiae Mathematicae Japonicae Online, e-2010, 69 84 69 COMPARATIVE MARKET YTEM ANALYI: LIMIT ORDER MARKET AND DEALER MARKET Hisashi Hashimoto Received December 11, 2009; revised December 25, 2009 Abstract.

More information

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology FE570 Financial Markets and Trading Lecture 6. Volatility Models and (Ref. Joel Hasbrouck - Empirical Market Microstructure ) Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 10/02/2012 Outline 1 Volatility

More information

Price Formation in a Market with a Short-Sale Prohibition: an Empirical Investigation

Price Formation in a Market with a Short-Sale Prohibition: an Empirical Investigation Price Formation in a Market with a Short-Sale Prohibition: an Empirical Investigation by Pongsak Hoontrakul, Peter Ryan, Anya Khanthavit* and Stylianos Perrakis This study examines the behaviour of stock

More information

Is Information Risk Priced for NASDAQ-listed Stocks?

Is Information Risk Priced for NASDAQ-listed Stocks? Is Information Risk Priced for NASDAQ-listed Stocks? Kathleen P. Fuller School of Business Administration University of Mississippi kfuller@bus.olemiss.edu Bonnie F. Van Ness School of Business Administration

More information

THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS

THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS PART I THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS Introduction and Overview We begin by considering the direct effects of trading costs on the values of financial assets. Investors

More information

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 6 Jan 2004

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 6 Jan 2004 Large price changes on small scales arxiv:cond-mat/0401055v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 6 Jan 2004 A. G. Zawadowski 1,2, J. Kertész 2,3, and G. Andor 1 1 Department of Industrial Management and Business Economics,

More information

Maximum Likelihood Estimation Richard Williams, University of Notre Dame, https://www3.nd.edu/~rwilliam/ Last revised January 13, 2018

Maximum Likelihood Estimation Richard Williams, University of Notre Dame, https://www3.nd.edu/~rwilliam/ Last revised January 13, 2018 Maximum Likelihood Estimation Richard Williams, University of otre Dame, https://www3.nd.edu/~rwilliam/ Last revised January 3, 208 [This handout draws very heavily from Regression Models for Categorical

More information

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms 19 Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms Vol I Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms Annika Westphäling * Four eyes see more than two that information gets more precise being aggregated

More information

Prediction Market Prices as Martingales: Theory and Analysis. David Klein Statistics 157

Prediction Market Prices as Martingales: Theory and Analysis. David Klein Statistics 157 Prediction Market Prices as Martingales: Theory and Analysis David Klein Statistics 157 Introduction With prediction markets growing in number and in prominence in various domains, the construction of

More information

Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing

Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing Wen Chen 1 Yajun Wang 2 1 The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shenzhen 2 Baruch College Institute of Financial Studies Southwestern University of Finance and Economics

More information

Why is PIN priced? Jefferson Duarte and Lance Young. August 31, 2007

Why is PIN priced? Jefferson Duarte and Lance Young. August 31, 2007 Why is PIN priced? Jefferson Duarte and Lance Young August 31, 2007 Abstract Recent empirical work suggests that a proxy for the probability of informed trading (PIN) is an important determinant of the

More information

Johnson School Research Paper Series # The Exchange of Flow Toxicity

Johnson School Research Paper Series # The Exchange of Flow Toxicity Johnson School Research Paper Series #10-2011 The Exchange of Flow Toxicity David Easley Cornell University Marcos Mailoc Lopez de Prado Tudor Investment Corp.; RCC at Harvard Maureen O Hara Cornell University

More information

Change in systematic trading behavior and the cross-section of stock returns during the global financial crisis: Fear or Greed?

Change in systematic trading behavior and the cross-section of stock returns during the global financial crisis: Fear or Greed? Change in systematic trading behavior and the cross-section of stock returns during the global financial crisis: Fear or Greed? P. Joakim Westerholm 1, Annica Rose and Henry Leung University of Sydney

More information

Cascades in Experimental Asset Marktes

Cascades in Experimental Asset Marktes Cascades in Experimental Asset Marktes Christoph Brunner September 6, 2010 Abstract It has been suggested that information cascades might affect prices in financial markets. To test this conjecture, we

More information

Czech Experience with Market-Maker Trading System. Jan Hanousek and Richard Podpiera* December 2003

Czech Experience with Market-Maker Trading System. Jan Hanousek and Richard Podpiera* December 2003 Czech Experience with Market-Maker Trading System Jan Hanousek and Richard Podpiera* December 2003 Abstract: We study the evolution of trading in a market-maker trading system (SPAD) introduced to the

More information

Market Variables and Financial Distress. Giovanni Fernandez Stetson University

Market Variables and Financial Distress. Giovanni Fernandez Stetson University Market Variables and Financial Distress Giovanni Fernandez Stetson University In this paper, I investigate the predictive ability of market variables in correctly predicting and distinguishing going concern

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports. Estimating a Structural Model of Herd Behavior in Financial Markets. Marco Cipriani Antonio Guarino

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports. Estimating a Structural Model of Herd Behavior in Financial Markets. Marco Cipriani Antonio Guarino Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Estimating a Structural Model of Herd Behavior in Financial Markets Marco Cipriani Antonio Guarino Staff Report No. 561 May 2012 FRBNY Staff REPORTS This

More information

The Aspect of Market Microstructure on Indonesian Stock Exchange (IDX)

The Aspect of Market Microstructure on Indonesian Stock Exchange (IDX) The Aspect of Market Microstructure on Indonesian Stock Exchange (IDX) December 16, 2010 This study investigates the effect of the types of information, especially economic news and firm specific information

More information

Speed of Execution of Market Order Trades and Specialists' Inventory Risk-Management at the NYSE

Speed of Execution of Market Order Trades and Specialists' Inventory Risk-Management at the NYSE Speed of Execution of Market Order Trades and Specialists' Inventory Risk-Management at the NYSE December 23 rd, 2007 by Sasson Bar-Yosef School of Business Administration The Hebrew University of Jerusalem

More information

Measuring and explaining liquidity on an electronic limit order book: evidence from Reuters D

Measuring and explaining liquidity on an electronic limit order book: evidence from Reuters D Measuring and explaining liquidity on an electronic limit order book: evidence from Reuters D2000-2 1 Jón Daníelsson and Richard Payne, London School of Economics Abstract The conference presentation focused

More information

Maximum Likelihood Estimation Richard Williams, University of Notre Dame, https://www3.nd.edu/~rwilliam/ Last revised January 10, 2017

Maximum Likelihood Estimation Richard Williams, University of Notre Dame, https://www3.nd.edu/~rwilliam/ Last revised January 10, 2017 Maximum Likelihood Estimation Richard Williams, University of otre Dame, https://www3.nd.edu/~rwilliam/ Last revised January 0, 207 [This handout draws very heavily from Regression Models for Categorical

More information

Trading costs - Spread measures

Trading costs - Spread measures Trading costs - Spread measures Bernt Arne Ødegaard 20 September 2018 Introduction In this lecture we discuss various definitions of spreads, all of which are used to estimate the transaction costs of

More information

An Analysis of the ESOP Protection Trust

An Analysis of the ESOP Protection Trust An Analysis of the ESOP Protection Trust Report prepared by: Francesco Bova 1 March 21 st, 2016 Abstract Using data from publicly-traded firms that have an ESOP, I assess the likelihood that: (1) a firm

More information

The Effects of High Frequency Trading in a Multi-Asset Model

The Effects of High Frequency Trading in a Multi-Asset Model The Effects of High Frequency Trading in a Multi-Asset Model Austin Gerig 1 and David Michayluk 2 1 University of Oxford 2 University of Technology, Sydney Overview -High frequency traders have largely

More information

What does the PIN model identify as private information?

What does the PIN model identify as private information? What does the PIN model identify as private information? Jefferson Duarte, Edwin Hu, and Lance Young May 1 st, 2015 Abstract Some recent papers suggest that the Easley and O Hara (1987) probability of

More information

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics Eric Zivot April 29, 2013 Lecture Outline The Leverage Effect Asymmetric GARCH Models Forecasts from Asymmetric GARCH Models GARCH Models with

More information

Heterogeneous Hidden Markov Models

Heterogeneous Hidden Markov Models Heterogeneous Hidden Markov Models José G. Dias 1, Jeroen K. Vermunt 2 and Sofia Ramos 3 1 Department of Quantitative methods, ISCTE Higher Institute of Social Sciences and Business Studies, Edifício ISCTE,

More information

3: Balance Equations

3: Balance Equations 3.1 Balance Equations Accounts with Constant Interest Rates 15 3: Balance Equations Investments typically consist of giving up something today in the hope of greater benefits in the future, resulting in

More information

Classification of trade direction for an equity market with price limit and order match: evidence from the Taiwan stock market

Classification of trade direction for an equity market with price limit and order match: evidence from the Taiwan stock market of trade direction for an equity market with price limit and order match: evidence from the Taiwan stock market AUTHORS ARTICLE INFO JOURNAL FOUNDER Yang-Cheng Lu Yu-Chen-Wei Yang-Cheng Lu and Yu-Chen-Wei

More information

Appendix CA-15. Central Bank of Bahrain Rulebook. Volume 1: Conventional Banks

Appendix CA-15. Central Bank of Bahrain Rulebook. Volume 1: Conventional Banks Appendix CA-15 Supervisory Framework for the Use of Backtesting in Conjunction with the Internal Models Approach to Market Risk Capital Requirements I. Introduction 1. This Appendix presents the framework

More information

Measurement Effects and the Variance of Returns After Stock Splits and Stock Dividends

Measurement Effects and the Variance of Returns After Stock Splits and Stock Dividends Measurement Effects and the Variance of Returns After Stock Splits and Stock Dividends Jennifer Lynch Koski University of Washington This article examines the relation between two factors affecting stock

More information

Lecture 1: The Econometrics of Financial Returns

Lecture 1: The Econometrics of Financial Returns Lecture 1: The Econometrics of Financial Returns Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Winter/Spring 2016 Overview General goals of the course and definition of risk(s) Predicting asset returns:

More information

A Liquidity Motivated Algorithm for Discerning Trade Direction

A Liquidity Motivated Algorithm for Discerning Trade Direction 1 A Liquidity Motivated Algorithm for Discerning Trade Direction David Michayluk University of Technology, Australia Laurie Prather Bond University, Australia Most exchanges do not report trade direction

More information

Seasonal Analysis of Abnormal Returns after Quarterly Earnings Announcements

Seasonal Analysis of Abnormal Returns after Quarterly Earnings Announcements Seasonal Analysis of Abnormal Returns after Quarterly Earnings Announcements Dr. Iqbal Associate Professor and Dean, College of Business Administration The Kingdom University P.O. Box 40434, Manama, Bahrain

More information

Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions Volume 11 Number 2 Fall 1998 THE INFORMATION CONTENT OF THE ADOPTION OF CLASSIFIED BOARD PROVISIONS

Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions Volume 11 Number 2 Fall 1998 THE INFORMATION CONTENT OF THE ADOPTION OF CLASSIFIED BOARD PROVISIONS Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions Volume 11 Number 2 Fall 1998 THE INFORMATION CONTENT OF THE ADOPTION OF CLASSIFIED BOARD PROVISIONS Philip H. Siegel * and Khondkar E. Karim * Abstract The

More information

TraderEx Self-Paced Tutorial and Case

TraderEx Self-Paced Tutorial and Case Background to: TraderEx Self-Paced Tutorial and Case Securities Trading TraderEx LLC, July 2011 Trading in financial markets involves the conversion of an investment decision into a desired portfolio position.

More information

ESTIMATING THE PROBABILITY OF INFORMED TRADING. Abstract

ESTIMATING THE PROBABILITY OF INFORMED TRADING. Abstract The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXV, No. 4 Pages 485 505 Winter 2002 ESTIMATING THE PROBABILITY OF INFORMED TRADING Ken Nyholm European Central Bank Abstract Using a new empirical model, I estimate

More information

Liquidity and Risk Management

Liquidity and Risk Management Liquidity and Risk Management By Nicolae Gârleanu and Lasse Heje Pedersen Risk management plays a central role in institutional investors allocation of capital to trading. For instance, a risk manager

More information

Quantifying fluctuations in market liquidity: Analysis of the bid-ask spread

Quantifying fluctuations in market liquidity: Analysis of the bid-ask spread Quantifying fluctuations in market liquidity: Analysis of the bid-ask spread Vasiliki Plerou,* Parameswaran Gopikrishnan, and H. Eugene Stanley Center for Polymer Studies and Department of Physics, Boston

More information

No DO LOCAL OR FOREIGN TRADERS KNOW MORE IN AN EMERGING MARKET? A POSSIBLE SOLUTION OF THE PUZZLE. Diego A. Agudelo

No DO LOCAL OR FOREIGN TRADERS KNOW MORE IN AN EMERGING MARKET? A POSSIBLE SOLUTION OF THE PUZZLE. Diego A. Agudelo No. 07-06 2007 DO LOCAL OR FOREIGN TRADERS KNOW MORE IN AN EMERGING MARKET? A POSSIBLE SOLUTION OF THE PUZZLE Diego A. Agudelo Do Local or Foreign traders know more in an emerging market? A possible solution

More information

Making Derivative Warrants Market in Hong Kong

Making Derivative Warrants Market in Hong Kong Making Derivative Warrants Market in Hong Kong Chow, Y.F. 1, J.W. Li 1 and M. Liu 1 1 Department of Finance, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong Email: yfchow@baf.msmail.cuhk.edu.hk Keywords:

More information

Updating traditional trade direction algorithms with liquidity motivation

Updating traditional trade direction algorithms with liquidity motivation Bond University epublications@bond Bond Business School Publications Bond Business School 8-10-2004 Updating traditional trade direction algorithms with liquidity motivation William J. Bertin Bond University,

More information

Participation Strategy of the NYSE Specialists to the Trades

Participation Strategy of the NYSE Specialists to the Trades MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Participation Strategy of the NYSE Specialists to the Trades Köksal Bülent Fatih University - Department of Economics 2008 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/30512/

More information

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion Luis Diaz-Serrano and Donal O Neill National University of Ireland Maynooth, Department of Economics Abstract In this paper

More information

Day-of-the-Week Trading Patterns of Individual and Institutional Investors

Day-of-the-Week Trading Patterns of Individual and Institutional Investors Day-of-the-Week Trading Patterns of Individual and Instutional Investors Hoang H. Nguyen, Universy of Baltimore Joel N. Morse, Universy of Baltimore 1 Keywords: Day-of-the-week effect; Trading volume-instutional

More information

Likelihood Approaches to Low Default Portfolios. Alan Forrest Dunfermline Building Society. Version /6/05 Version /9/05. 1.

Likelihood Approaches to Low Default Portfolios. Alan Forrest Dunfermline Building Society. Version /6/05 Version /9/05. 1. Likelihood Approaches to Low Default Portfolios Alan Forrest Dunfermline Building Society Version 1.1 22/6/05 Version 1.2 14/9/05 1. Abstract This paper proposes a framework for computing conservative

More information

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS BASEMENT HD28.M414 no. Ibll- Dewey ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Corporate Investments In Common Stock by Wayne H. Mikkelson University of Oregon Richard S. Ruback Massachusetts

More information

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Putnam Institute JUne 2011 Optimal Asset Allocation in : A Downside Perspective W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Once an individual has retired, asset allocation becomes a critical

More information

Portfolio Rebalancing:

Portfolio Rebalancing: Portfolio Rebalancing: A Guide For Institutional Investors May 2012 PREPARED BY Nat Kellogg, CFA Associate Director of Research Eric Przybylinski, CAIA Senior Research Analyst Abstract Failure to rebalance

More information

Information asymmetry, information dissemination and the effect of regulation FD on the cost of capital $

Information asymmetry, information dissemination and the effect of regulation FD on the cost of capital $ Journal of Financial Economics 87 (2008) 24 44 www.elsevier.com/locate/jfec Information asymmetry, information dissemination and the effect of regulation FD on the cost of capital $ Jefferson Duarte a,

More information

MAGNT Research Report (ISSN ) Vol.6(1). PP , 2019

MAGNT Research Report (ISSN ) Vol.6(1). PP , 2019 Does the Overconfidence Bias Explain the Return Volatility in the Saudi Arabia Stock Market? Majid Ibrahim AlSaggaf Department of Finance and Insurance, College of Business, University of Jeddah, Saudi

More information

CHAPTER 7 AN AGENT BASED MODEL OF A MARKET MAKER FOR THE BSE

CHAPTER 7 AN AGENT BASED MODEL OF A MARKET MAKER FOR THE BSE CHAPTER 7 AN AGENT BASED MODEL OF A MARKET MAKER FOR THE BSE 7.1 Introduction Emerging stock markets across the globe are seen to be volatile and also face liquidity problems, vis-à-vis the more matured

More information

Dynamic games with incomplete information

Dynamic games with incomplete information Dynamic games with incomplete information Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium (PBE) We have now covered static and dynamic games of complete information and static games of incomplete information. The next step

More information

Short Sales and Put Options: Where is the Bad News First Traded?

Short Sales and Put Options: Where is the Bad News First Traded? Short Sales and Put Options: Where is the Bad News First Traded? Xiaoting Hao *, Natalia Piqueira ABSTRACT Although the literature provides strong evidence supporting the presence of informed trading in

More information

Simulation Wrap-up, Statistics COS 323

Simulation Wrap-up, Statistics COS 323 Simulation Wrap-up, Statistics COS 323 Today Simulation Re-cap Statistics Variance and confidence intervals for simulations Simulation wrap-up FYI: No class or office hours Thursday Simulation wrap-up

More information

The Liquidity Effects of Revisions to the CAC40 Stock Index.

The Liquidity Effects of Revisions to the CAC40 Stock Index. The Liquidity Effects of Revisions to the CAC40 Stock Index. Andros Gregoriou * Norwich Business School, University of East Anglia Norwich, NR4 7TJ, UK January 2009 Abstract: This paper explores liquidity

More information

Chapter-3. Sectoral Composition of Economic Growth and its Major Trends in India

Chapter-3. Sectoral Composition of Economic Growth and its Major Trends in India Chapter-3 Sectoral Composition of Economic Growth and its Major Trends in India This chapter deals with the first objective of the study, that is to evaluate the sectoral composition of economic growth

More information

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ Christopher Ting : christopherting@smu.edu.sg :

More information

Efficiency and Herd Behavior in a Signalling Market. Jeffrey Gao

Efficiency and Herd Behavior in a Signalling Market. Jeffrey Gao Efficiency and Herd Behavior in a Signalling Market Jeffrey Gao ABSTRACT This paper extends a model of herd behavior developed by Bikhchandani and Sharma (000) to establish conditions for varying levels

More information

Short Selling, Informed Trading, and Stock Returns

Short Selling, Informed Trading, and Stock Returns Short Selling, Informed Trading, and Stock Returns Tyler R. Henry University of Georgia This Draft: May 2006 Abstract This paper considers the effect of private information on the returns to stocks with

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

Analysis Determinants of Order Flow Toxicity, HFTs Order Flow Toxicity and HFTs Impact on Stock Price Variance

Analysis Determinants of Order Flow Toxicity, HFTs Order Flow Toxicity and HFTs Impact on Stock Price Variance Analysis Determinants of Order Flow Toxicity, HFTs Order Flow Toxicity and HFTs Impact on Stock Price Variance Serhat Yildiz University of Mississippi syildiz@bus.olemiss.edu Bonnie F. Van Ness University

More information

Internet Appendix to. Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity

Internet Appendix to. Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity Internet Appendix to Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity Joel PERESS & Daniel SCHMIDT 6 October 2018 1 Table of Contents Internet Appendix A: The Implications of Distraction

More information

The (implicit) cost of equity trading at the Oslo Stock Exchange. What does the data tell us?

The (implicit) cost of equity trading at the Oslo Stock Exchange. What does the data tell us? The (implicit) cost of equity trading at the Oslo Stock Exchange. What does the data tell us? Bernt Arne Ødegaard Abstract We empirically investigate the costs of trading equity at the Oslo Stock Exchange

More information

The information value of block trades in a limit order book market. C. D Hondt 1 & G. Baker

The information value of block trades in a limit order book market. C. D Hondt 1 & G. Baker The information value of block trades in a limit order book market C. D Hondt 1 & G. Baker 2 June 2005 Introduction Some US traders have commented on the how the rise of algorithmic execution has reduced

More information

Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility. David A. Hsieh. Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC (919)

Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility. David A. Hsieh. Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC (919) Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility by David A. Hsieh Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC 27706 (919)-660-7779 October 1993 Prepared for the Conference on Financial Innovations: 20 Years

More information

ISSN BWPEF Probability of Informed Trading and Volatility for an ETF. Dimitrios Karyampas Birkbeck, University of London

ISSN BWPEF Probability of Informed Trading and Volatility for an ETF. Dimitrios Karyampas Birkbeck, University of London ISSN 1745-8587 Birkbeck Working Papers in Economics & Finance School of Economics, Mathematics and Statistics BWPEF 1101 Probability of Informed Trading and Volatility for an ETF Dimitrios Karyampas Birkbeck,

More information

Universal Properties of Financial Markets as a Consequence of Traders Behavior: an Analytical Solution

Universal Properties of Financial Markets as a Consequence of Traders Behavior: an Analytical Solution Universal Properties of Financial Markets as a Consequence of Traders Behavior: an Analytical Solution Simone Alfarano, Friedrich Wagner, and Thomas Lux Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre der Christian

More information

Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz

Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz Abstract: This paper is an analysis of the mortality rates of beneficiaries of charitable gift annuities. Observed

More information

SUPERVISORY FRAMEWORK FOR THE USE OF BACKTESTING IN CONJUNCTION WITH THE INTERNAL MODELS APPROACH TO MARKET RISK CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS

SUPERVISORY FRAMEWORK FOR THE USE OF BACKTESTING IN CONJUNCTION WITH THE INTERNAL MODELS APPROACH TO MARKET RISK CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS SUPERVISORY FRAMEWORK FOR THE USE OF BACKTESTING IN CONJUNCTION WITH THE INTERNAL MODELS APPROACH TO MARKET RISK CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS (January 1996) I. Introduction This document presents the framework

More information

Ultra High Frequency Volatility Estimation with Market Microstructure Noise. Yacine Aït-Sahalia. Per A. Mykland. Lan Zhang

Ultra High Frequency Volatility Estimation with Market Microstructure Noise. Yacine Aït-Sahalia. Per A. Mykland. Lan Zhang Ultra High Frequency Volatility Estimation with Market Microstructure Noise Yacine Aït-Sahalia Princeton University Per A. Mykland The University of Chicago Lan Zhang Carnegie-Mellon University 1. Introduction

More information

On the Performance of the Tick Test

On the Performance of the Tick Test On the Performance of the Tick Test Marcelo Perlin (msperlin@ea.ufrgs.br) Chris Brooks (c.brooks@icmacentre.ac.uk) Alfonso Dufour (a.dufour@icmacentre.ac.uk) First Version: July 19, 2011 This version:

More information

Three essays on corporate acquisitions, bidders' liquidity, and monitoring

Three essays on corporate acquisitions, bidders' liquidity, and monitoring Louisiana State University LSU Digital Commons LSU Doctoral Dissertations Graduate School 2006 Three essays on corporate acquisitions, bidders' liquidity, and monitoring Huihua Li Louisiana State University

More information

Lecture 4. Market Microstructure

Lecture 4. Market Microstructure Lecture 4 Market Microstructure Market Microstructure Hasbrouck: Market microstructure is the study of trading mechanisms used for financial securities. New transactions databases facilitated the study

More information

The Effects of Information-Based Trading on the Daily Returns and Risks of. Individual Stocks

The Effects of Information-Based Trading on the Daily Returns and Risks of. Individual Stocks The Effects of Information-Based Trading on the Daily Returns and Risks of Individual Stocks Xiangkang Yin and Jing Zhao La Trobe University First Version: 27 March 2013 This Version: 2 April 2014 Corresponding

More information

Predicting Economic Recession using Data Mining Techniques

Predicting Economic Recession using Data Mining Techniques Predicting Economic Recession using Data Mining Techniques Authors Naveed Ahmed Kartheek Atluri Tapan Patwardhan Meghana Viswanath Predicting Economic Recession using Data Mining Techniques Page 1 Abstract

More information

CHAPTER V ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION

CHAPTER V ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION CHAPTER V ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION 1 CHAPTER-V: ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION OF DATA 5.1. DESCRIPTIVE ANALYSIS OF DATA: Research consists of a systematic observation and description of the properties

More information

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed Snehal Banerjee (Northwestern) Brett Green (UC-Berkeley) AFA 2014 Meetings July 2013 Learning about other traders Trade motives

More information

Systematic patterns before and after large price changes: Evidence from high frequency data from the Paris Bourse

Systematic patterns before and after large price changes: Evidence from high frequency data from the Paris Bourse Systematic patterns before and after large price changes: Evidence from high frequency data from the Paris Bourse FOORT HAMELIK ABSTRACT This paper examines the intra-day behavior of asset prices shortly

More information

The following content is provided under a Creative Commons license. Your support

The following content is provided under a Creative Commons license. Your support MITOCW Recitation 6 The following content is provided under a Creative Commons license. Your support will help MIT OpenCourseWare continue to offer high quality educational resources for free. To make

More information

IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA?

IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA? IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA? C. Barry Pfitzner, Department of Economics/Business, Randolph-Macon College, Ashland, VA, bpfitzne@rmc.edu ABSTRACT This paper investigates the

More information

Université de Montréal. Rapport de recherche. Empirical Analysis of Jumps Contribution to Volatility Forecasting Using High Frequency Data

Université de Montréal. Rapport de recherche. Empirical Analysis of Jumps Contribution to Volatility Forecasting Using High Frequency Data Université de Montréal Rapport de recherche Empirical Analysis of Jumps Contribution to Volatility Forecasting Using High Frequency Data Rédigé par : Imhof, Adolfo Dirigé par : Kalnina, Ilze Département

More information

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO Graduate School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2003, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO Graduate School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2003, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO Graduate School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2003, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay Homework Assignment #2 Solution April 25, 2003 Each HW problem is 10 points throughout this quarter.

More information

FIN11. Trading and Market Microstructure. Autumn 2017

FIN11. Trading and Market Microstructure. Autumn 2017 FIN11 Trading and Market Microstructure Autumn 2017 Lecturer: Klaus R. Schenk-Hoppé Session 7 Dealers Themes Dealers What & Why Market making Profits & Risks Wake-up video: Wall Street in 1920s http://www.youtube.com/watch?

More information

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power? International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 9, No. 9; 2014 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really

More information

The economic and statistical significance of spread forecasts: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange

The economic and statistical significance of spread forecasts: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange Journal of Banking & Finance 26 (2002) 795 818 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase The economic and statistical significance of spread forecasts: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange Nicholas Taylor Department

More information

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They?

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? Massimiliano Marzo and Paolo Zagaglia This version: January 6, 29 Preliminary: comments

More information

Is Information Risk a Determinant of Asset Returns?

Is Information Risk a Determinant of Asset Returns? Is Information Risk a Determinant of Asset Returns? By David Easley Department of Economics Cornell University Soeren Hvidkjaer Johnson Graduate School of Management Cornell University Maureen O Hara Johnson

More information

Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections

Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections Supporting information (For Online Publication Only) Ari Hyytinen University of Jyväskylä, School of Business and Economics (JSBE) Jaakko

More information

The Accuracy of Trade Classification Rules: Evidence from Nasdaq

The Accuracy of Trade Classification Rules: Evidence from Nasdaq The Accuracy of Trade Classification Rules: Evidence from Nasdaq Katrina Ellis Australian Graduate School of Management Roni Michaely Cornell University and Tel-Aviv University And Maureen O Hara Cornell

More information

An Introduction to Market Microstructure Invariance

An Introduction to Market Microstructure Invariance An Introduction to Market Microstructure Invariance Albert S. Kyle University of Maryland Anna A. Obizhaeva New Economic School HSE, Moscow November 8, 2014 Pete Kyle and Anna Obizhaeva Market Microstructure

More information