Conflicts of Interests Among Shareholders: The Case of Corporate Acquisitions *

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Conflicts of Interests Among Shareholders: The Case of Corporate Acquisitions *"

Transcription

1 Conflicts of Interests Among Shareholders: The Case of Corporate Acquisitions * Jarrad Harford University of Washington Dirk Jenter Massachusetts Institute of Technology and NBER Kai Li University of British Columbia First Draft: June 2006 This Version: June 2007 Abstract: We identify important conflicts of interests among shareholders and examine their effects on corporate decisions. When a firm is considering an action that affects other firms in its shareholders portfolios, shareholders with heterogeneous portfolios will disagree about whether to proceed. This effect is measurable and potentially large in the case of corporate acquisitions, where bidder shareholders with holdings in the target want management to maximize a weighted average of both firms equity values. Empirically, we show that such cross-holdings are large for a significant group of institutional shareholders in the average acquisition and for a majority of institutional shareholders in a significant number of deals. We find that managers consider cross-holdings when identifying potential targets and in structuring deals. Further, targets selected on cross-holdings will have lower synergies on average, which offsets the tendency for cross-holdings to lead to more aggressive bidding. Overall, we conclude that conflicts of interests among shareholders are sizeable and, at least in the case of acquisitions, affect managerial decisions. Keywords: cross-holdings, shareholder heterogeneity, target selection, mergers and acquisitions, toehold, synergies, agency JEL classification: G30, G34 * We thank Nittai Bergman, Murray Carlson, Adlai Fisher, Ron Giammarino, Jon Karpoff, Alan Kraus, Kalina Manova, Wayne Mikkelson, Pablo Moran, Hernan Ortiz-Molina, Jon Reuter, Frederik Schlingemann, Jeremy Stein, and Ralph Walkling for useful comments and discussions, and seminar participants at Bentley College, Boston College, Concordia, MIT finance lunch, Rutgers University, Simon Fraser University, University of British Columbia, University of Texas at Austin, University of Toronto, and York University, as well as participants of the Pacific Northwest Finance Conference (Seattle), and the 13 th Mitsui Life Symposium on Value Creation at the University of Michigan (Ann Arbor). We acknowledge the financial support from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. All remaining errors are our own. University of Washington Business School, Box , Seattle, WA , , jarrad@u.washington.edu. Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, E52-446, Cambridge, MA 02142, , djenter@mit.edu. Sauder School of Business, University of British Columbia, 2053 Main Mall, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z2, , kai.li@sauder.ubc.ca.

2 Conflicts of Interests Among Shareholders: The Case of Corporate Acquisitions Abstract We identify important conflicts of interests among shareholders and examine their effects on corporate decisions. When a firm is considering an action that affects other firms in its shareholders portfolios, shareholders with heterogeneous portfolios will disagree about whether to proceed. This effect is measurable and potentially large in the case of corporate acquisitions, where bidder shareholders with holdings in the target want management to maximize a weighted average of both firms equity values. Empirically, we show that such cross-holdings are large for a significant group of institutional shareholders in the average acquisition and for a majority of institutional shareholders in a significant number of deals. We find that managers consider cross-holdings when identifying potential targets and in structuring deals. Further, targets selected on cross-holdings will have lower synergies on average, which offsets the tendency for cross-holdings to lead to more aggressive bidding. Overall, we conclude that conflicts of interests among shareholders are sizeable and, at least in the case of acquisitions, affect managerial decisions. Keywords: cross-holdings, shareholder heterogeneity, target selection, mergers and acquisitions, toehold, synergies, agency JEL classification: G30, G34

3 Much of the corporate finance literature takes for granted the assumption that (homogenous) shareholders want to maximize the value of their firm s equity. In reality, most shareholders are diversified and care about the effects of managerial actions on their portfolio values, not just on the value of the specific firm taking the action. When shareholders have different portfolios, they may disagree about which actions managers should take. In acquisitions, diversified shareholders who hold equity stakes in both a bidder and its target (cross-holdings) want bidder management to maximize a weighted average of the bidder s and the target s equity values. Concentrated shareholders with stakes in only the bidder want management to focus on the bidder s equity value, setting-up a conflict between shareholder groups. Managers must choose how to act in the presence of heterogeneous shareholders with different portfolios. They could ignore this heterogeneity and simply align themselves with the concentrated shareholders. Alternatively, they could take it into account in an attempt to maximize the wealth of most stockholders, and/or opportunistically use it to lower shareholder resistance to empire-building acquisitions. In this study, we first measure the extent of shareholder cross-holdings and then test for their impact on target choice and deal characteristics to determine whether managers incorporate cross-holdings into their acquisition decisions. The insight that cross-holdings by shareholders alter their preferences over takeover decisions is a special case of the general result that diversified shareholders prefer corporate policies which maximize their portfolio values to policies which narrowly maximize the values of individual firms (Hansen and Lott (1996), and Rubin (2006)). In general, however, externalities on other firms imposed by managers decisions are likely to be small or hard to estimate, so in a bounded-rationality framework, it makes sense for managers to focus on own firm value. In corporate acquisitions, one of the externalities is large and easily computed, and so the opportunity to correctly maximize the wealth of the majority (but not simultaneously all) of the shareholders is present. Thus, we use merger bids as our experimental setting and specifically 1

4 test the hypothesis that cross-holdings by bidder shareholders affect target selection and deal structure. We formally show that the preference of a bidder shareholder with cross-holdings in the target is captured by the ratio of her percentage stake in the target to her percentage stake in the bidder, and that this preference is equivalent to the preference of a value-maximizing bidder with a toehold in the target. In all models of takeover bidding with toeholds considered in the prior literature, toeholds make bidders more willing to pursue an acquisition and more willing to bid aggressively. Bidding firms that consider their shareholders cross-holdings are therefore expected to follow a more aggressive acquisition strategy because their shareholders will capture some of the premium paid. The net effect of cross-holdings on bidding strategies and bid outcomes is more ambiguous. Under the null hypothesis that cross-holdings have an effect on mergers, managers will choose targets that have high cross-holdings, high synergies, or both. Thus, among targets with high cross-holdings, some will also have high synergies, but many will not. Although the direct effect of cross-holdings would be to increase premiums and completion likelihoods, the fact that they may signal low synergies produces an indirect opposing effect. As a result, while cross-holdings should have an observable effect on target selection and bidder announcement returns, they have an ambiguous effect on premiums and deal completion. Bidder managers who want to take their shareholders cross-holdings into consideration face the challenge that different shareholders have different portfolios and hence different crossholdings in the target, with many bidder shareholders holding no shares in the target at all. The heterogeneity in investors cross-holdings leads to disagreements about the objective function for the bidding firm, and it is far from obvious which decision rule managers should adopt to determine their optimal acquisition strategy. We therefore use several measures of the distribution of shareholder preferences in the empirical analysis. An intuitively appealing solution to the aggregation problem is for managers to maximize a weighted average of their 2

5 shareholders preferences. This implies that a bidder shifts to a more aggressive acquisition strategy even if only 10 or 20 percent of its shareholders own shares in the target. Alternatively, management may follow a majority rule and simply adopt the preferences of its median shareholder. The median shareholder in our context is defined such that 50 percent of the bidder s shares are held by shareholders with smaller cross-holdings and 50 percent by shareholders with larger cross-holdings. We document the magnitude of investor cross-holdings in takeovers and the resulting conflicts of interests using information on the portfolios of large institutional investors and takeover data from 1984 to We show that the average bidder s median institutional shareholder 1 has a cross-holding of 5.3 percent in the target, with a median of 0.0 percent. The distribution of cross-holdings is strongly right-skewed both across bidders and across shareholders in a given bidder; in five percent of the bidders, the median institution has crossholdings of 40 percent or more in the target. In the average bidder, 20 percent of the institutional holdings are by investors with cross-holdings of more than 34 percent, and 10 percent of the institutional holdings are by investors with cross-holdings above 75 percent. Hence many institutional investors want bidder management to act as if the bidder had a large toehold in the target, which in turn implies substantial disagreements between shareholders with cross-holdings and those without. We compute the effect of these cross-holdings on the total abnormal returns experienced by institutional investors around the bids, including the effect of the bid on the target s stock price. We find that the median institution averages a positive 0.2 percent return improvement, or about 17 percent of the average bidder announcement return of 1.2 percent. We find that the presence of cross-holdings by bidder shareholders is important in determining the target. Target firms have significantly higher cross-holdings by bidder shareholders than do non-target control firms. Further, consistent with the conjecture that any 1 The median institutional shareholder is defined such that 50% of the institutional ownership in the bidder is by institutions with larger cross-holdings and 50% by institutions with smaller cross-holdings. This definition is similar to the definition of the median shareholder discussed before, with all percentiles re-defined relative to the total institutional ownership in the firm. 3

6 positive direct effect of cross-holdings on the aggressiveness of bidding strategies is mitigated by an indirect selection effect associating cross-holdings with low synergies, we find no effect of cross-holdings on bid premiums or deal completion probabilities. Cross-holdings are associated with lower post-acquisition operating performance, further supporting our conjecture that bidders trade off cross-holdings with synergies when selecting acquisition targets. Finally, we do not find evidence that managers are using cross-holdings to facilitate empire-building acquisitions. We conclude that the conflicts of interests between diversified and concentrated shareholders in mergers are pervasive enough to matter, and that managers pay attention to the cross-holdings of their diversified shareholders. In related work, Matvos and Ostrovsky (2006) argue that investor cross-holdings may explain the low and often negative returns to acquiring firms in takeovers. They argue that bidder shareholders with large cross-holdings do not mind overpaying for the target, and hence that cross-holdings help explain why shareholders fail to block apparently bad takeover deals. Different from our work, they do not analyze individual cross-holdings and instead add up bidder shareholders stakes in the target. This approach aggregates away the conflicts between shareholders with heterogeneous cross-holdings. Our analysis clarifies that shareholders preferences are determined by their relative holdings in the bidder and the target, and that only shareholders who own a larger percentage of the target than of the acquirer favor overpayment. Empirically, shareholders with cross-holdings above 100 percent are rare and hold on average only 4.1 percent of the bidders equity in the mergers in our data. Hence the influence of investors who favor overpayment is likely to be limited, and cross-holdings are unlikely to explain why bidders overpay. 2 2 Matvos and Ostrovsky (2006) also show that mutual funds that hold shares in both a bidder and its target are more likely to vote for mergers with negative announcement returns. This finding suggests that institutional investors do pay attention to the interactions between the firms in their portfolios. There has also been other work on shareholder conflicts. Eckbo and Verma (1994) identify shareholder conflicts over dividend policy due to heterogeneous tax rates, information asymmetries, and agency costs. Rice (2006) demonstrates that the importance of a shareholder group to price formation depends on the group s price elasticity of demand for shares, leading to a divergence between the effects of corporate decisions on market values and the effects of those decisions on shareholder 4

7 The plan of the paper is as follows. The next section draws on prior theoretical work on toeholds to formally analyze the effects of cross-holdings on firms objectives, and to develop our null hypothesis and some testable implications. Section II describes our data and the variable definitions used in the empirical analysis. Section III presents summary statistics on the size and prevalence of cross-holdings in actual takeovers and examines their effects on target selection, announcement returns, takeover premiums, and the probability of takeover success. The last section summarizes and concludes. I. Theoretical Background and Hypothesis Development This section examines how cross-holdings affect shareholders preferences over mergers and acquisitions, and how bidder management may react to the heterogeneous preferences of its shareholders. We first analyze shareholder preferences in the two canonical classes of takeover models analyzed in the prior literature, models of tender offers in the spirit of Grossman and Hart (1980) and models of competitive takeover bidding in the spirit of Fishman (1988). We then present our null hypothesis and its testable implications. I.A. Cross-holdings in a model of tender offers with free-riding This section describes shareholder preferences in a Grossman and Hart (1980)-type setting with dispersed target shareholders. To illustrate the idea, consider a model with two firms, a bidder and a target. The value of the target under incumbent management is V I. The bidder is able to create synergies worth S > 0 that are realized only if the bidder acquires control. To obtain control, the bidder needs to acquire 50 percent of the target shares in a conditional tender offer, which entails a transaction cost of k > 0. Assume that S > k so that the acquisition is socially efficient. All target shares are held by dispersed shareholders. welfare. Kraus and Rubin (2007) show that the conflict between diversified shareholders who want to maximize their portfolio values and managers who use capital budgeting rules to choose firm-value maximizing projects has important implications for executive compensation design. 5

8 Now consider the preferences of a shareholder who owns α B percent of the bidder and α T percent of the target. This shareholder wants the bidder to pursue an acquisition whenever her share of the associated takeover gains exceeds her share of the takeover costs: α T α T S > α B k k + S > 0 (1) α B The shareholder wants bidder management to put a weight of (α T / α B ) on target value and to effectively internalize (α T / α B ) percent of the takeover gains accruing to target shareholders. But the decision rule in (1) is simply the optimal rule for a value-maximizing bidding firm that owns a toehold of (α T / α B ) percent in the target (see for example, Shleifer and Vishny (1986), Hirshleifer and Titman (1990), and Chowdhry and Jegadeesh (1994)). Hence a bidder shareholder with relative cross-holdings of (α T / α B ) wants bidder management to act as if the bidder itself had a toehold of (α T / α B ). In the extreme, a shareholder who owns a higher percentage of the target than of the bidder wants management to act as if the bidder had a toehold larger than 100 percent in the target, which is to say that this shareholder would actually benefit from overpayment for the target. 3 I.B. Cross-holdings in a model of competitive takeover bidding This section examines shareholder preferences in models (for example, Fishman (1988), and Burkhart (1995)), in which two or more bidders compete for a target, and in which the Grossman-Hart free-rider problem plays no role. For simplicity, we assume that there are only two bidders, labeled 1 and 2, that both bidders are risk neutral, and that there are no bidding costs. Let V i denote the private value of the target to bidder i, and assume that both V 1 and V 2 exceed the value of the target firm under incumbent management. This ensures that the target will be taken over by one of the bidders in equilibrium, and that all target shares are acquired by 3 It may seem surprising that the shareholder s preference is independent of the values of her positions in the two firms, or equivalently, of the size of the bidder relative to the target. However, this result obtains because the impact of a larger relative bidder value on the shareholder s wealth (α B V B ) is exactly offset by the smaller effect on the bidder value due to overpaying for a relatively smaller target. 6

9 the winning bidder. Bidder 1 s and bidder 2 s strategies consist of choosing price ceilings C 1 and C 2, respectively, at which to withdraw from the auction, given that the rival is still actively bidding. Now consider the preferences of a shareholder who owns α B percent of bidder 1 and α T percent of the target. This shareholder receives α B percent of any takeover gains accruing to bidder 1 in case bidder 1 wins the auction, and the shareholder sells her α T percent target stake at the winning price to whichever bidder wins the auction. Hence her expected payoffs are given by: Pr(bidder 1 wins) Pr(bidder 1wins) V 1 E [ α ( V E( C bidder 1wins) ) + α E( C bidder 1wins) ] + Pr(bidder 2 wins) [ α C ] B 1 α T αt ( C bidder 1wins) + E( C bidder 1wins) + Pr(bidder 2 wins) C 2 2 α B T 2 2 T α B The payoff function puts a relative weight of one on the takeover gains to bidder 1 in case that bidder wins, and a relative weight of (α T / α B ) on the takeover price paid, independently of which bidder wins. But this is exactly the objective function of a bidding firm that owns a toehold of (α T / α B ) percent in the target and sells that toehold to the rival bidder in case the rival wins the auction (Burkhart (1995) and Singh (1998)). It follows that a bidder shareholder with relative cross-holdings of (α T / α B ) would see her expected wealth maximized if the bidder set its bidding strategy as if the bidder itself had a toehold of (α T / α B ) in the target. To summarize, we have shown that both in free-rider models based on Grossman and Hart (1980) and in models of competitive bidding based on Fishman (1988) and Burkhart (1995), a shareholder with stakes of α B percent in the bidder and α T percent in the target wants bidder management to act as if the bidder itself had a toehold of size (α T / α B ). This motivates our focus on the distribution of these (relative) cross-holdings among bidder shareholders in Section III. 1 (2) 1 7

10 I.C. Aggregation of shareholder preferences by bidder management The relative cross-holdings are by construction shareholder-specific and range from zero to values above 100 percent in most bidder-target combinations. Bidder management thus faces the question of how to aggregate the preferences of its shareholders into a decision rule for the overall firm. Even if we assume that bidder managers wish to maximize the overall welfare of their shareholders, it is far from obvious what acquisition strategy managers should adopt. With different cross-holdings by different shareholders, any policy has to favor the preferences of one subset of bidder shareholders over others. Theory provides little guidance as to how bidder management should aggregate its shareholders preferences, and what weight to attach to the target value in its objective function. Two intuitively appealing solutions to the aggregation problem are for managers to adopt the preferences of its median shareholder, or for managers to maximize a weighted average of shareholder preferences. Under the median-shareholder criterion, bidder management pursues all takeover deals which are supported by the owners of a majority of its shares. The median shareholder is defined such that 50 percent of bidder shares are held by investors with larger cross-holdings and 50 percent by investors with smaller cross-holdings. Since larger cross-holdings make a shareholder prefer a more aggressive acquisition strategy, the median shareholder defines the most aggressive strategy managers can implement while retaining the support of a majority of shareholders votes. The median-shareholder criterion by design ignores the preferences of most shareholders. Alternatively, bidder managers may try to maximize a weighted average of all their shareholders subjective preferences. While it is not obvious what weights management should use to aggregate shareholder preferences, most reasonable weighting schemes would imply that bidders shift to a more aggressive acquisition strategy even if only 10 or 20 percent of their shareholders 8

11 have equity stakes in a target. 4 In Section III, we document both the preferences of the median shareholder and of the subsets of bidder shareholders with the highest cross-holdings, and examine whether their preferences are reflected in acquisitions. The above aggregation schemes for shareholder preferences can only be relevant to realworld acquisitions if bidder management does in fact consider the portfolios held by its shareholders, or if diversified shareholders have the means to impose portfolio-value maximization on management. A priori, there are several reasons to expect that managers may ignore the cross-holdings their shareholders have in other firms. Large concentrated shareholders such as founding families or venture capitalists are unlikely to own any cross-holdings in target firms, but are likely to be active in corporate governance and to exert influence over managers. Further, the compensation of top executives is heavily biased towards stock options and restricted stock and thus ultimately depends on own-firm performance (Murphy (1999)). 5 Hence managers are given strong incentives to maximize the performance of their own firm, but few obvious incentives to care about any externalities they impose on other firms in their shareholders portfolios. The degree to which cross-holdings will matter thus depends on the ability of crossholding investors to influence bidder management. Shareholders with cross-holdings may be able to influence acquisition decisions through their representatives on boards of directors, voting at shareholders meetings, or private or public communication with the management team (Smith (1996), and Carleton, Nelson, and Weisbach (1998)). This kind of influence is most likely for 4 Drèze (1974) proposes to use shareholders ownership stakes as weights when aggregating heterogeneous shareholder preferences. Interestingly, applying this weighting scheme to relative cross-holdings amounts to simply adding up the bidder shareholders percentage stakes in the target, and hence gives the same aggregate preferences as if there were a perfect coalition among bidder shareholders. This degree of coordination between shareholders is not realistic and we opt not to use this aggregation scheme in the empirical analysis. We do, however, consider the possibility that the largest institutional shareholders may align their preferences through negotiated side-payments. 5 This raises the question of why managerial contracts are written this way to begin with. While beyond the scope of this paper, we offer the following considerations. First, incentives are endogenous and negotiated between managers and the board. If concentrated shareholders dominate corporate governance and boards, then incentive contracts will reflect their preferences. Second, moving away from firm-value maximization as the objective function in designing executive compensation schemes may have costs, e.g., create more opportunities for managers to maximize their own welfare at the expense of shareholders. 9

12 institutional investors and for blockholders, and for this reason our empirical analysis focuses on the cross-holdings of institutional investors with large stakes in the bidder. Whether bidder management takes its shareholders portfolios into account when making acquisition decisions is ultimately an empirical question which we attempt to answer in Section III. I.D. Hypothesis development and testable implications Our null hypothesis is that bidder managers take their shareholders cross-holdings into account in target selection and structuring deals, while our alternative hypothesis is that crossholdings have no effect on mergers. Assuming that the null hypothesis prevails, how would the bidder s acquisition strategy change? In Grossman and Hart (1980), a toehold bidder receives some of the takeover gains accruing to target shareholders, making it more likely that the bidder is able to cover the acquisition cost and hence more likely that the bid goes ahead. Crossholdings by bidder shareholders in a target should thus make an acquisition bid more likely. Thus, we expect: Testable Implication 1: There is a positive association between cross-holdings by a bidder s shareholders and, ceteris paribus, the likelihood that a firm will be targeted by that bidder. In models of competitive takeover bidding, a toehold makes it optimal for a bidder to bid more aggressively and to even raise its bid above its own valuation for the target. The more aggressive bidding strategy increases the bidder s expected capital gain on the toehold should a rival win and purchase the toehold. Hirshleifer and Titman (1990), and Chowdhry and Jegadeesh (1994) conclude that the probability of takeover success increases in the size of the bidder s toehold. Cross-holdings by bidder shareholders in a target should therefore motivate bidder management to bid more aggressively. Empirically, however, we only observe the net effect of cross-holdings on target selection and on bid aggressiveness. If firms select targets by trading off cross-holdings with synergies, then a substantial fraction of targets with high cross-holdings will have lower than average 10

13 synergies. Shleifer and Vishny (1986), and Hirshleifer and Titman (1990) show that toeholds are associated with lower bid premiums as toeholds allow acquisitions with lower value-added to proceed. To the extent that we are unable to perfectly measure synergies, this confounds our analysis. For example, a bid where a high premium is paid for a target with low synergies and high bidder shareholder cross-holdings may be indistinguishable from a bid where a normal premium is paid for a target with high synergies and low shareholder cross-holdings. Moreover, the benefits of more aggressive bidding accrue only to bidder shareholders with cross-holdings and not to the bidding firm itself. We predict: Testable Implication 2: The net effects of cross-holdings on premiums and completion rates are ambiguous, while their effect on bidder announcement returns is negative. Testable Implication 3: Ceteris paribus, there is a negative association between crossholdings and synergies. Under the null hypothesis, bidder managers may choose to take their shareholders crossholdings into account for the opportunistic purpose of reducing their resistance to empirebuilding acquisitions. If the motivation is management driven, then we would still expect to see an effect of cross-holdings in target selection, but not necessarily in bid characteristics. More importantly, we would expect to see this type of managerial behavior concentrated in poorly governed firms. Empirically, if agency problems drive the effect of cross-holdings on target selection, we expect: Testable Implication 4: There is a positive association between cross-holdings and poor governance in the bidding firm. II. Sample Formation and Variable Construction II.A. Sample selection We begin with all announced (both completed and cancelled) US mergers with announcement dates between January 1, 1984 and December 31, 2002 as identified from the 11

14 Mergers and Acquisitions database of the Securities Data Company (SDC). We identify all deals where both the bidder and target are public firms and the form of deal was coded as a merger, an acquisition of majority interest, or an acquisition of assets. After applying the above filters, we get 8,075 deals. The sample period is chosen because the information in SDC is less reliable before 1984 and we require data on post-merger performance. Next, we match our bidders and targets with Compustat and CRSP data, and we only retain an acquisition if the bidder owns less than 50 percent of the target prior to the bid and is seeking to own greater than 50 percent of the target. For completed deals, we require that the bidder owns more than 90 percent of the target after the deal completion. These filters yield 2,885 deals. Finally, we merge our acquisition data with the CDA/Spectrum 13F data on institutional shareholdings in the bidder and the target. 6 Ideally, we would also like to measure cross-holdings at the individual investor level. Using data on institutional investors adds a layer of intermediation between individual investors and firms, and makes it difficult to assess the extent to which the ultimate owners of the assets are diversified across firms. However, given the greater size of their stakes, the cross-holdings of institutional investors are more likely to be reflected in company policies than the cross-holdings of the individuals behind these institutions. When interpreting our results it is nevertheless useful to keep in mind that we do not observe the portfolios of non-institutional investors and therefore miss potentially significant cross-holdings by individual shareholders. In a similar vain, an institutional portfolio reported to the SEC may be an aggregate of multiple distinct portfolios managed by the institution, adding noise to our measure of cross-holdings. Our final sample has 2,815 merger deals where both the bidder and the target have data on institutional shareholdings in the quarter-end prior to the bid announcement. 6 A 1978 amendment to the Securities and Exchange Act of 1934 requires all institutions with greater than $100 million of equity securities under discretionary management to report every quarter using the SEC s form 13F all common-stock positions greater than 10,000 shares or $200,000. These reports are available in electronic form back to 1980 from CDA/Spectrum, a firm hired by the SEC to process the Form 13F filings. 12

15 II.B. Variable construction In Section I we show that bidder shareholders preferences are determined by their crossholdings, defined as their percentage ownership of the target divided by their percentage ownership of the bidder. Since different shareholders have different cross-holdings, the resulting shareholder preferences over acquisitions are heterogeneous. We therefore adopt three complementary approaches to describing the (cumulative) distribution of cross-holdings across shareholders. Given that we do not observe the portfolios of non-institutional investors, we focus most of our discussion on the cross-holdings of institutional investors and restrict our sample to bidders that have at least 20 percent of their equity owned by institutions. This restriction excludes firms in which institutional investors are unlikely to have any influence on management. The first approach to measuring shareholder preferences captures what percentage of the institutional holdings in the bidder is by investors with large cross-holdings, and what percentage by investors with small or no cross-holdings. Figure 1 illustrates the approach. Specifically, we order all institutional investors in the bidder by their cross-holdings, and then calculate the (marginal) cross-holding for the top 1, 5, 10, 20, and 50 percent of institutional shareholdings (labeled as the top-1%, top-5%, top-10%, top-20%, and median cross-holdings, respectively). For example, a top-10% cross-holding of 75 percent means that 10 percent of the institutional ownership in the bidder is controlled by investors with cross-holdings of at least 75 percent. Probably the most relevant measure of investor incentives in this set is the cross-holding of the median institutional shareholder in the bidder. The cross-holding of this investor, called the median cross-holding for short, determines the set of acquisition policies the bidder can pursue while maintaining the support of the majority of its institutional shareholders votes. To complement the analysis for institutional shareholders, we also calculate and report crossholdings for all shareholders of the bidder by making the conservative assumption that all noninstitutional investors have zero cross-holdings. 13

16 The above approach to measuring cross-holdings ignores the fact that bidder shareholders differ greatly in their ability to impose their preferences on bidder management. We expect bidder management to be most responsive to the preferences of its largest shareholders; hence our next two approaches look explicitly at the cross-holdings of blockholders, defined as institutional investors who own at least five percent of the bidder s shares. Specifically, we order the blockholders by their cross-holdings, and then report the (marginal) cross-holding for the top 5, 10, 20, 50, 75, and 100 percent of all shares owned by blockholders, in parallel to the calculations for all institutional investors described above. Finally, we consider the possibility that blockholders might coordinate their actions and negotiate side-payments with each other. With costless bargaining, the Coase Theorem (Coase (1960)) predicts that the blockholders should act in unison and support any acquisition that is profitable for all blockholders combined. The aggregate preferences of this coordinated group of investors are determined by their combined cross-holdings, given by the sum of their equity stakes in the target divided by the sum of their stakes in the bidder. In reality, coordination between blockholders may not be costless and side-payments are likely to be restricted by law. 7 Hence the blockholders combined cross-holdings should be interpreted as an upper bound on the cross-holding the blockholders may bring to bear on the bidding firm s decision process. III. Empirical Results In this section, we first present an overview of our sample with a focus on the magnitude of shareholder cross-holdings. Then, we formally test the null hypothesis that shareholder crossholdings do matter in target selection, bid characteristics, and outcomes in a multivariate regression framework. Finally, we present evidence on the indirect effect of cross-holdings on 7 The Securities and Exchange Commission passed new rules in 1992 allowing shareholders to directly communicate with each other (SEC (1992)). Thus, the costs of creating shareholder coalitions were substantially reduced. 14

17 bid characteristics and outcomes due to endogenous target selection and explore alternative explanations to our findings. III.A. Sample overview Table 1 presents descriptive statistics on the announced merger deals, the bidders, and the targets. In Panel A, we show that 75 percent of the announced deals are eventually completed. A quarter of the deals use only cash as the method of payment, and over 40 percent of the deals are pure stock swaps. Approximately 13 percent of the targets receive competing bids within one year. The sample is split evenly between diversifying and within industry deals. The mean relative deal size, defined as the ratio of the transaction value to the market value of the bidder, is 30 percent. Consistent with the prior literature, there are few direct toeholds, and more than 95 percent of the bidders in our sample have no toehold at all in their targets. On average, the bidder is offering a premium of 45 percent above the market price of the target as of four weeks before the bid. In Panel B, we show that the average three-day abnormal announcement period return (CAR3) for the bidder is 1.2 percent, while the average CAR3 for the target is close to 20 percent. Following Bradley, Desai, and Kim (1988), we also compute the dollar amount of the synergistic gains (= bidder CAR3 bidder market capitalization + target CAR3 (1 toehold) target market capitalization) as well as the percentage synergy gains (= synergy in dollars /(bidder market capitalization + (1 toehold) target market capitalization). Panel B shows that the average synergies amount to about $47 million in 2002 dollars, corresponding to an average percentage gain of about 2 percent. This implies that, once we account for the large positive announcement return to the target, mergers in our sample are on average welfare-improving. Panels C and D present summary statistics on the bidders and targets in our sample, respectively. Consistent with the relative size variable, the bidders are much larger than their targets in terms of both book and market values. The bidders and targets have similar levels of 15

18 leverage, while the bidders appear to enjoy faster sales growth, better operating performance, and higher stock returns in the year prior to the bid. Table 2 presents summary statistics of institutional shareholdings in the bidders and targets. On average, institutional investors own 46 percent of the equity of bidding firms and 32 percent of the equity of targets. Bidder institutions that also own shares in the target control 14 percent of all bidder shares, or 31 percent of the bidder shares owned by institutions. While target institutions that also own shares in the bidder control a similar 18 percent of all target shares, they own over half of the generally smaller institutional holdings in the target. III.B. The size and pervasiveness of cross-holdings Table 3 summarizes the empirical distribution of cross-holdings in the bidders and targets. In Part I of Panel A, we calculate cross-holdings for the top 1, 5, 10, 20, and 50 percent of the bidders institutional shareholders and limit our sample to bidders with total institutional ownership no less than 20 percent. This reduces our sample by only 16 percent to 2,356 observations. We find that the average cross-holding by the median institutional shareholder is 5.3 percent, with a median of 0.0 percent. The distribution of cross-holdings across bidders is strongly right-skewed; in five percent of the bidders, the median institution has cross-holdings of 40 percent or more, while in one percent of the bidders, the median cross-holding is at least 87 percent. Focusing on the largest cross-holdings, we find that the average top-10% cross-holding is above 75 percent, and that the average top-5% cross-holding is 140 percent. In Part II of Panel A, we calculate cross-holdings for the top 1, 5, 10, 20, and 50 percent of all bidder shareholders, assuming that the cross-holdings of non-institutional investors are zero. With this assumption, we find that the average median cross-holding is only 0.3 percent. This low number is a direct result of the assumed zero cross-holdings for non-institutional investors and of the fact that the median shareholder is an institution in less than half of the bidders in our sample. However, even under these assumptions, the average top-10% cross- 16

19 holding is 30 percent. We also compute the fraction of bidder shares whose holders own a higher percentage stake of the target than of the bidder. We find that bidder shareholders with crossholdings greater than one are rare and control on average only 4.1 percent of the bidder s equity and only 10.1 percent of the total institutional holdings in the bidder. This means that the influence of bidder shareholders who favor overpayment for the target is likely to be small. We conclude that there is a substantial number of institutional investors with large crossholdings in the average bidder, and that there is a significant set of mergers in which even the median institution owns a large stake in the target. At the same time, many institutional shareholders of the bidder have no cross-holdings in the target at all, implying significant conflicts of interests over the objective function of the bidder. The above analysis ignores the differences in the power of different shareholders to impose their preferences on bidder management. We therefore focus next on large shareholders. Table 4 presents summary statistics of cross-holdings held by blockholders, defined as institutions that own at least five percent of the shares of a firm. Part I of Panel A shows that the average cross-holdings by the median blockholder is 11 percent (median 0.0 percent), and that in five percent of the bidders, the median blockholder has a cross-holding of 82 percent or more in the target. Turning to blockholders with large cross-holdings, the average top-20% cross-holding exceeds 18 percent, and the average top-10% cross-holding is almost 20 percent. These numbers suggest that there is a significant number of institutional blockholders, the subset of institutional investors most likely to influence bidder management, with large cross-holdings in the target. In Part II of Panel A we examine what would happen if blockholders were to negotiate side-payments with one another and act as a group. The average combined cross-holding by all blockholders in the bidder is 12 percent. The distribution is again skewed, with the median of the combined cross-holding equal to zero. In ten percent of all deals, however, blockholders want management to act as if the bidder had a 46 percent toehold in the target, and in five percent of all deals as if the bidder had a 69 percent toehold in the target. For comparison, Betton, Eckbo, 17

20 and Thorburn (2005) analyze toeholds held directly by the acquirer in a comprehensive sample of twelve thousand bidders and find that only 11 percent of the bidders own any toehold in the target. In their sample, the average toehold size among bidders with a positive toehold is 21 percent, with a median of 17 percent. 8 Of course, target shareholders can have cross-holdings in the bidder as well, so Tables 3 and 4 present analogous information for target shareholders cross-holdings in the bidder. We find similar, but generally higher cross-holdings held by target shareholders in the bidder. This is likely a mechanical outcome driven by the relatively greater institutional interest in bidders observed in Table 2. III.C. Wealth effects of bid announcements Next we examine to what extent the wealth effects of takeovers on bidder shareholders change when we take their cross-holdings in the target into account. To address that question, we introduce the concept of a return improvement. First define the total abnormal announcement return for an institutional investor in a bidder as Total Abnormal Announcement Return = αbi VB + αti VT (3) where α is the percentage shareholding by institution i in either the bidder (subscript B) or in the target (subscript T) and V is the abnormal change in firm value, computed as the product of the bidder s or target s market value and the corresponding abnormal announcement period return. The return improvement is the difference between the total abnormal announcement return and the bidder abnormal announcement period return. This measure thus captures the improvement in return experienced by a given bidder shareholder due to her ownership stake in the target. Table 5 presents the return improvement for institutional investors in the bidder, identified by the size of their cross-holdings. Part I limits the sample to bidders with total 8 Similar, if somewhat higher, numbers have been documented before by, among others, Bradley, Desai, and Kim (1988), Jarrell and Poulsen (1989), Jennings and Mazzeo (1993), and Betton and Eckbo (2000). 18

21 institutional ownership no less than 20 percent. We find that the average return improvement for the median institutional shareholder is 0.2 percent, with a median of 0.0 percent. The distribution of return improvement is somewhat skewed; in five percent of the bidders, the median institution has a return improvement of 1.7 percent or better, while in one percent of the bidders, the median institution has a return improvement of 6.2 percent or better. Focusing on bidder institutions with large cross-holdings, we find that the average return improvement for the institution with the top- 10% cross-holdings is 2.5 percent; for the institution with the top-5% cross-holdings, it is 3.7 percent. As a reference point, the average bidder announcement return in our sample is 1.2 percent (see Table 1, Panel B). Thus, we conclude that, in general, the return improvement provided by cross-holdings is moderate, but that in some cases, it is large relative to the average announcement effect. Part II of Table 5 presents the return improvement for all shareholders, assuming individual shareholders have zero cross-holdings. There remain moderate improvements across bidder shareholders with non-trivial cross-holdings, although as expected the improvements are not as big as those in Panel A. III. D. The effect of cross-holdings on target selection In the next three sub-sections, we formally examine the null hypothesis that managers account for their shareholders cross-holdings when making decisions about acquisitions. The literature on toeholds has shown that the presence of a toehold increases the bidding likelihood, so we start our investigation by examining the role of cross-holdings in target selection. To examine the first testable implication of our null hypothesis, we compare the cross-holdings of bidder shareholders in the actually chosen targets to their cross-holdings in a sample of potential alternative targets that were not chosen. Our control sample of potential target firms is obtained by first identifying the set of all CRSP/Compustat firms that were neither targets nor bidders in our merger sample and that have 19

22 institutional shareholding data available from the CDA. This forms the base set of potential control firms. For each actual target in our sample, we select a control firm from its Fama-French (1997) industry that is closest in market capitalization (requiring that the difference does not exceed 25 percent of the sample firm market capitalization) at the fiscal year-end prior to the bid announcement. 9 Matching is done with replacement and only one control firm is matched to each sample firm. We are able to match 2,427 control firms to target firms in our sample. We refer to the matching firms as potential targets. In Table 6, Panel A, we present summary statistics for the potential targets, which can be compared to the corresponding statistics for the actual targets presented in Table 1, Panel D. There is no statistical difference between the actual and potential target samples across most firm characteristics, including the extent of institutional shareholding. This suggests that we have found valid control firms for the targets. The only significant difference between the potential and actual target firms is that the potential target firms tend to have higher market-to-book ratios. Table 6, Panel B presents the empirical distribution of cross-holdings by bidder shareholders in the potential targets. Comparing these figures to those in Panel A of Table 3, it is clear that the cross-holdings by bidder shareholders in the actual targets are larger than that in the potential targets (except where the cross-holdings for the median shareholder remain zero in both samples). Tests of differences in means and medians show that the cross-holdings by bidder shareholders in the chosen targets are significantly different from those in the control sample. An alternative explanation for the difference in cross-holdings are unobservables, that is, institutions may invest in firms that are similar along some dimension that we do not observe, and that same similarity may make those firms more likely to merge. While this explanation is plausible for within-industry acquisitions, it is unlikely to apply to diversifying acquisitions. It would have to be the case that institutions invest in firms across different industries based on some unobservable dimension that also makes these firms more likely to merge with each other. 9 Our main inferences remain unchanged if we impose different size matching criteria. 20

Shareholder Cross-holdings and Their Effect on Acquisition Decisions *

Shareholder Cross-holdings and Their Effect on Acquisition Decisions * Shareholder Cross-holdings and Their Effect on Acquisition Decisions * Jarrad Harford University of Washington Dirk Jenter Stanford University and NBER Kai Li University of British Columbia First Draft:

More information

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Corporate Control Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Managerial Discipline and Takeovers Managers often don t maximize the value of the firm; either because they are not capable

More information

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXVI, NO. 1 MARCH 1991 Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers HENRI SERVAES* ABSTRACT This paper analyzes the relation between takeover gains and the q ratios of targets and

More information

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership Robert C. Hanson Department of Finance and CIS College of Business Eastern Michigan University Ypsilanti, MI 48197 Moon H.

More information

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Mehmet E. Akbulut 1 Department of Finance College of Business and Economics California State University Fullerton Abstract This paper examines whether managers

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. Stulz Working Paper 9523 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9523 NATIONAL

More information

Acquiring Intangible Assets

Acquiring Intangible Assets Acquiring Intangible Assets Intangible assets are important for corporations and their owners. The book value of intangible assets as a percentage of total assets for all COMPUSTAT firms grew from 6% in

More information

Weak Governance by Informed Large. Shareholders

Weak Governance by Informed Large. Shareholders Weak Governance by Informed Large Shareholders Eitan Goldman and Wenyu Wang June 15, 2016 Abstract A commonly held belief is that better informed large shareholders with greater influence improve corporate

More information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Critical Finance Review, 2016, 5: 165 175 Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Kent Daniel Sheridan Titman 1 Columbia Business School, Columbia University, New York,

More information

The Gains from Contracting with Equity. Myron B. Slovin Department of Finance Louisiana State University Baton Rouge, LA 70803

The Gains from Contracting with Equity. Myron B. Slovin Department of Finance Louisiana State University Baton Rouge, LA 70803 The Gains from Contracting with Equity by Myron B. Slovin Department of Finance Louisiana State University Baton Rouge, LA 70803 Marie E. Sushka Department of Finance Arizona State University Tempe, AZ

More information

Motivated Monitors: The Importance of Institutional Investors Portfolio Weights

Motivated Monitors: The Importance of Institutional Investors Portfolio Weights Motivated Monitors: The Importance of Institutional Investors Portfolio Weights March 12, 2013 Eliezer M. Fich LeBow College of Business Drexel University Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA +1-215-895-2304 efich@drexel.edu

More information

The Characteristics of Bidding Firms and the Likelihood of Cross-border Acquisitions

The Characteristics of Bidding Firms and the Likelihood of Cross-border Acquisitions The Characteristics of Bidding Firms and the Likelihood of Cross-border Acquisitions Han Donker, Ph.D., University of orthern British Columbia, Canada Saif Zahir, Ph.D., University of orthern British Columbia,

More information

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM ) MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM Ersin Güner 559370 Master Finance Supervisor: dr. P.C. (Peter) de Goeij December 2013 Abstract Evidence from the US shows

More information

The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1

The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1 Preservation The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1 Kenneth R. Spong Senior Policy Economist, Banking Studies and Structure, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Richard J. Sullivan Senior

More information

Idiosyncratic Volatility and Earnout-Financing

Idiosyncratic Volatility and Earnout-Financing Idiosyncratic Volatility and Earnout-Financing Leonidas Barbopoulos a,x Dimitris Alexakis b Extended Abstract Reflecting the importance of information asymmetry in Mergers and Acquisitions (M&As), there

More information

Why do acquirers switch financial advisors in mergers and acquisitions?

Why do acquirers switch financial advisors in mergers and acquisitions? Why do acquirers switch financial advisors in mergers and acquisitions? Xiaoxiao Yu 1 and Yeqin Zeng 2 1 University of Texas at Arlington 2 University of Reading September 14, 2017 Abstract Using a sample

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

M&A Activity in Europe

M&A Activity in Europe M&A Activity in Europe Cash Reserves, Acquisitions and Shareholder Wealth in Europe Master Thesis in Business Administration at the Department of Banking and Finance Faculty Advisor: PROF. DR. PER ÖSTBERG

More information

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome.

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome. AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED Alex Gershkov and Flavio Toxvaerd November 2004. Preliminary, comments welcome. Abstract. This paper revisits recent empirical research on buyer credulity

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Shareholder Wealth Effects of M&A Withdrawals

Shareholder Wealth Effects of M&A Withdrawals Shareholder Wealth Effects of M&A Withdrawals Yue Liu * University of Edinburgh Business School, 29 Buccleuch Place, Edinburgh, EH3 8EQ, UK Keywords: Mergers and Acquisitions Withdrawal Abnormal Return

More information

Corporate Innovations and Mergers and Acquisitions *

Corporate Innovations and Mergers and Acquisitions * Corporate Innovations and Mergers and Acquisitions * Jan Bena University of British Columbia Kai Li University of British Columbia First Version: October, 2010 This Version: December, 2010 Abstract Using

More information

Markup pricing revisited

Markup pricing revisited Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth Tuck School of Business Working Paper No. 2008-45 Markup pricing revisited Sandra Betton John Molson School of Business, Concordia University B. Espen Eckbo Tuck School

More information

Management Ownership and Dividend Policy: The Role of Managerial Overconfidence

Management Ownership and Dividend Policy: The Role of Managerial Overconfidence 1 Management Ownership and Dividend Policy: The Role of Managerial Overconfidence Cheng-Shou Lu * Associate Professor, Department of Wealth and Taxation Management National Kaohsiung University of Applied

More information

Does Debt Help Managers? Using Cash Holdings to Explain Acquisition Returns

Does Debt Help Managers? Using Cash Holdings to Explain Acquisition Returns University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2017 Does Debt Help Managers? Using Cash Holdings to Explain Acquisition Returns Michael Evans Michael.Evans-1@Colorado.EDU

More information

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision Modern Applied Science; Vol. 9, No. 4; 2015 ISSN 1913-1844 E-ISSN 1913-1852 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision Seok Weon Lee 1 1 Division

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS BASEMENT HD28.M414 no. Ibll- Dewey ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Corporate Investments In Common Stock by Wayne H. Mikkelson University of Oregon Richard S. Ruback Massachusetts

More information

NCER Working Paper Series

NCER Working Paper Series NCER Working Paper Series Momentum in Australian Stock Returns: An Update A. S. Hurn and V. Pavlov Working Paper #23 February 2008 Momentum in Australian Stock Returns: An Update A. S. Hurn and V. Pavlov

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets:

Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets: Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets: The Débutant Effect of IPOs * Luyao Pan a Xianming Zhou b February 18, 2015 Abstract Both theory and economic intuition suggest that newly listed firms differ

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

Discussion Paper No. 593

Discussion Paper No. 593 Discussion Paper No. 593 MANAGEMENT OWNERSHIP AND FIRM S VALUE: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS USING PANEL DATA Sang-Mook Lee and Keunkwan Ryu September 2003 The Institute of Social and Economic Research Osaka

More information

Wealth Destruction on a Massive Scale? A Study of Acquiring-Firm Returns in the Recent Merger Wave

Wealth Destruction on a Massive Scale? A Study of Acquiring-Firm Returns in the Recent Merger Wave THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LX, NO. 2 APRIL 2005 Wealth Destruction on a Massive Scale? A Study of Acquiring-Firm Returns in the Recent Merger Wave SARA B. MOELLER, FREDERIK P. SCHLINGEMANN, and RENÉ M.STULZ

More information

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017 ECON 459 Game Theory Lecture Notes Auctions Luca Anderlini Spring 2017 These notes have been used and commented on before. If you can still spot any errors or have any suggestions for improvement, please

More information

Can Bonus Bids Capture Economic Rent? Should Governments Opt for Increased Reliance on Bonus Bids Over Royalties?

Can Bonus Bids Capture Economic Rent? Should Governments Opt for Increased Reliance on Bonus Bids Over Royalties? Can Bonus Bids Capture Economic Rent? Should Governments Opt for Increased Reliance on Bonus Bids Over Royalties? The Toronto based C.D. Howe Institute (Institute) has recommended that governments should

More information

Do Wealth Creating Mergers and Acquisitions Really Hurt Acquirer Shareholders? * School of Banking and Finance, Australian School of Business, UNSW

Do Wealth Creating Mergers and Acquisitions Really Hurt Acquirer Shareholders? * School of Banking and Finance, Australian School of Business, UNSW Do Wealth Creating Mergers and Acquisitions Really Hurt Acquirer Shareholders? * Ron Masulis, Peter L. Swan and Brett Tobiansky, School of Banking and Finance, Australian School of Business, UNSW Draft:

More information

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? *

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Thomas Moeller Neeley School of Business Texas Christian University Abstract In a large sample of public-public acquisitions, target

More information

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Zhangkai Huang * and Xingzhong Xu Guanghua School of Management Peking University Abstract Unlike in other countries, negotiated block shares have

More information

The Role of Management Incentives in the Choice of Stock Repurchase Methods. Ata Torabi. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business

The Role of Management Incentives in the Choice of Stock Repurchase Methods. Ata Torabi. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business The Role of Management Incentives in the Choice of Stock Repurchase Methods Ata Torabi A Thesis In The John Molson School of Business Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree

More information

Do Management Buyouts of US Companies Demand Higher Premiums than UK Companies? Why?

Do Management Buyouts of US Companies Demand Higher Premiums than UK Companies? Why? Do Management Buyouts of US Companies Demand Higher Premiums than UK Companies? Why? Harsh Nanda The Leonard N. Stern School of Business Glucksman Institute for Research in Securities Markets Faculty Advisor:

More information

Blockholder Heterogeneity, Monitoring and Firm Performance

Blockholder Heterogeneity, Monitoring and Firm Performance Blockholder Heterogeneity, Monitoring and Firm Performance Christopher Clifford University of Kentucky Laura Lindsey Arizona State University December 2008 Blockholders as Monitors Separation of Ownership

More information

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power? International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 9, No. 9; 2014 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really

More information

The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk, Reduction and Impact

The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk, Reduction and Impact The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk Reduction and Impact Jonathan Harris ET Index Research Quarter 1 017 This report focuses on three key questions for responsible investors:

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6. Separation of Ownership and Control

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6. Separation of Ownership and Control Leonardo Felli 16 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6 Separation of Ownership and Control The definition of ownership considered is limited to an environment in which the whole ownership

More information

Activism Mergers. Nicole M. Boyson, Nickolay Gantchev, and Anil Shivdasani* October 2015 ABSTRACT

Activism Mergers. Nicole M. Boyson, Nickolay Gantchev, and Anil Shivdasani* October 2015 ABSTRACT Activism Mergers Nicole M. Boyson, Nickolay Gantchev, and Anil Shivdasani* October 2015 ABSTRACT Activist hedge funds play a central role in the market for corporate control. An activist campaign makes

More information

Some Puzzles. Stock Splits

Some Puzzles. Stock Splits Some Puzzles Stock Splits When stock splits are announced, stock prices go up by 2-3 percent. Some of this is explained by the fact that stock splits are often accompanied by an increase in dividends.

More information

The Benefits of Market Timing: Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions

The Benefits of Market Timing: Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions The Benefits of Timing: Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions Evangelos Vagenas-Nanos University of Glasgow, University Avenue, Glasgow, G12 8QQ, UK Email: evangelos.vagenas-nanos@glasgow.ac.uk Abstract

More information

Privately Negotiated Repurchases and Monitoring by Block Shareholders

Privately Negotiated Repurchases and Monitoring by Block Shareholders Privately Negotiated Repurchases and Monitoring by Block Shareholders Murali Jagannathan College of Management Binghamton University Binghamton, NY 607.777.4639 Muralij@binghamton.edu Clifford Stephens

More information

Two essays on Corporate Restructuring

Two essays on Corporate Restructuring University of South Florida Scholar Commons Graduate Theses and Dissertations Graduate School January 2012 Two essays on Corporate Restructuring Dung Anh Pham University of South Florida, dapham@usf.edu

More information

DO CEOS IN MERGERS TRADE POWER FOR PREMIUM? EVIDENCE FROM MERGERS OF EQUALS

DO CEOS IN MERGERS TRADE POWER FOR PREMIUM? EVIDENCE FROM MERGERS OF EQUALS University of Pennsylvania Law School ILE INSTITUTE FOR LAW AND ECONOMICS A Joint Research Center of the Law School, the Wharton School, and the Department of Economics in the School of Arts and Sciences

More information

MERGER ANNOUNCEMENTS AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: DO MARKETS PREDICT SYNERGETIC GAINS FROM MERGERS PROPERLY?

MERGER ANNOUNCEMENTS AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: DO MARKETS PREDICT SYNERGETIC GAINS FROM MERGERS PROPERLY? MERGER ANNOUNCEMENTS AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: DO MARKETS PREDICT SYNERGETIC GAINS FROM MERGERS PROPERLY? ALOVSAT MUSLUMOV Department of Management, Dogus University. Acıbadem 81010, Istanbul / TURKEY Tel:

More information

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity *

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity * Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity * Index Section 1: High bargaining power of the small firm Page 1 Section 2: Analysis of Multiple Small Firms and 1 Large

More information

The Accrual Anomaly in the Game-Theoretic Setting

The Accrual Anomaly in the Game-Theoretic Setting The Accrual Anomaly in the Game-Theoretic Setting Khrystyna Bochkay Academic adviser: Glenn Shafer Rutgers Business School Summer 2010 Abstract This paper proposes an alternative analysis of the accrual

More information

A theory of initiation of takeover contests

A theory of initiation of takeover contests A theory of initiation of takeover contests Alexander S. Gorbenko London Business School Andrey Malenko MIT Sloan School of Management February 2013 Abstract We study strategic initiation of takeover contests

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Private placements and managerial entrenchment

Private placements and managerial entrenchment Journal of Corporate Finance 13 (2007) 461 484 www.elsevier.com/locate/jcorpfin Private placements and managerial entrenchment Michael J. Barclay a,, Clifford G. Holderness b, Dennis P. Sheehan c a University

More information

Comment on Determinants of Intercorporate Shareholdings

Comment on Determinants of Intercorporate Shareholdings European Finance Review 1: 289 293, 1997. c 1997 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Comment on Determinants of Intercorporate Shareholdings B. ESPEN ECKBO Stockholm School of Economics

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Information Signaling or Agency Conflicts: What Explains Canadian Open Market Share Repurchases?

Information Signaling or Agency Conflicts: What Explains Canadian Open Market Share Repurchases? Information Signaling or Agency Conflicts: What Explains Canadian Open Market Share Repurchases? Kai Li * Faculty of Commerce University of British Columbia 2053 Main Mall, Vancouver, B.C. Canada V6T 1Z2

More information

Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application

Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application Vivek H. Dehejia Carleton University and CESifo Email: vdehejia@ccs.carleton.ca January 14, 2008 JEL classification code:

More information

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Manohar Singh The Pennsylvania State University- Abington Reporting a positive relationship between institutional ownership on one hand and capital expenditures

More information

January 26,

January 26, January 26, 2015 Exercise 9 7.c.1, 7.d.1, 7.d.2, 8.b.1, 8.b.2, 8.b.3, 8.b.4,8.b.5, 8.d.1, 8.d.2 Example 10 There are two divisions of a firm (1 and 2) that would benefit from a research project conducted

More information

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Trading Company and Indirect Exports Trading Company and Indirect Exports Kiyoshi Matsubara June 015 Abstract This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation. In the model, manufacturing firm(s) wanting to export their products

More information

Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets:

Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets: Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets: The Débutante Effect * Luyao Pan a Xianming Zhou b Abstract Both theory and economic intuition suggest that newly listed firms differ from seasoned ones as potential

More information

Payment Method in Mergers and Acquisitions

Payment Method in Mergers and Acquisitions Payment Method in Mergers and Acquisitions A Study on Swedish firm s Domestic and Cross-Border Acquisitions Bachelor Thesis in Financial Economics and Industrial and Financial Management School of Business,

More information

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Anup Agrawal Culverhouse College of Business University of Alabama Tuscaloosa, AL 35487-0224 Jeffrey F. Jaffe Department

More information

Toehold Strategies, Takeover Laws and Rival Bidders

Toehold Strategies, Takeover Laws and Rival Bidders Toehold Strategies, Takeover Laws and Rival Bidders by S. Abraham Ravid* and Matthew Spiegel** Revised: December 5, 1998 * Rutgers University, Faculty of Management and New York University, Stern School

More information

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure Corporate Financial Management Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure As we discussed in previous lectures, two extreme results, namely the irrelevance of capital structure and 100 percent

More information

Do firms have leverage targets? Evidence from acquisitions

Do firms have leverage targets? Evidence from acquisitions Do firms have leverage targets? Evidence from acquisitions Jarrad Harford School of Business Administration University of Washington Seattle, WA 98195 206.543.4796 206.221.6856 (Fax) jarrad@u.washington.edu

More information

Industry Volatility and Workers Demand for Collective Bargaining

Industry Volatility and Workers Demand for Collective Bargaining Industry Volatility and Workers Demand for Collective Bargaining Grant Clayton Working Paper Version as of December 31, 2017 Abstract This paper examines how industry volatility affects a worker s decision

More information

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract In this paper we study the market reaction to capital expenditure announcements in the backdrop

More information

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment University of Konstanz Department of Economics Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment Florian Baumann and Tim Friehe Working Paper Series 2011-08 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/workingpaperseries

More information

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance.

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Guillermo Acuña, Jean P. Sepulveda, and Marcos Vergara December 2014 Working Paper 03 Ownership Concentration

More information

Capital Gains Taxation and the Cost of Capital: Evidence from Unanticipated Cross-Border Transfers of Tax Bases

Capital Gains Taxation and the Cost of Capital: Evidence from Unanticipated Cross-Border Transfers of Tax Bases Capital Gains Taxation and the Cost of Capital: Evidence from Unanticipated Cross-Border Transfers of Tax Bases Harry Huizinga (Tilburg University and CEPR) Johannes Voget (University of Mannheim, Oxford

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

Perhaps the most striking aspect of the current

Perhaps the most striking aspect of the current COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, CROSS-BORDER MERGERS AND MERGER WAVES:INTER- NATIONAL ECONOMICS MEETS INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION STEVEN BRAKMAN* HARRY GARRETSEN** AND CHARLES VAN MARREWIJK*** Perhaps the most striking

More information

Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments

Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments Carl T. Bergstrom University of Washington, Seattle, WA Theodore C. Bergstrom University of California, Santa Barbara Rodney

More information

Motivated Monitors: The Importance of Institutional Investors Portfolio Weights

Motivated Monitors: The Importance of Institutional Investors Portfolio Weights Motivated Monitors: The Importance of Institutional Investors Portfolio Weights February 24, 2014 Eliezer M. Fich LeBow College of Business Drexel University Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA +1-215-895-2304

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO ACQUIRERS WITH MORE UNCERTAIN GROWTH PROSPECTS GAIN LESS FROM ACQUISITIONS?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO ACQUIRERS WITH MORE UNCERTAIN GROWTH PROSPECTS GAIN LESS FROM ACQUISITIONS? NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO ACQUIRERS WITH MORE UNCERTAIN GROWTH PROSPECTS GAIN LESS FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. Stulz Working Paper 10773 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10773

More information

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS 1 NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS Options are contracts used to insure against or speculate/take a view on uncertainty about the future prices of a wide range

More information

We examine the impact of risk aversion on bidding behavior in first-price auctions.

We examine the impact of risk aversion on bidding behavior in first-price auctions. Risk Aversion We examine the impact of risk aversion on bidding behavior in first-price auctions. Assume there is no entry fee or reserve. Note: Risk aversion does not affect bidding in SPA because there,

More information

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options Joshua D. Anderson jdanders@mit.edu (617) 253-7974 John E. Core* jcore@mit.edu (617) 715-4819 Abstract We measure

More information

The Impact of Mergers and Acquisitions on Corporate Bond Ratings. Qi Chang. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business

The Impact of Mergers and Acquisitions on Corporate Bond Ratings. Qi Chang. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business The Impact of Mergers and Acquisitions on Corporate Bond Ratings Qi Chang A Thesis In The John Molson School of Business Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of

More information

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009 Long Chen Washington University in St. Louis Fresh Momentum Engin Kose Washington University in St. Louis First version: October 2009 Ohad Kadan Washington University in St. Louis Abstract We demonstrate

More information

Top-up Options and Tender Offers

Top-up Options and Tender Offers Top-up Options and Tender Offers ERIK DEVOS, WILLIAM B. ELLIOTT, and HILMI SONGUR 1 ABSTRACT We investigate the role of top-up options granted by target managers to bidders in tender offers. A top-up option

More information

Large Shareholders and Dividends: Game Theoretic Analysis of Shareholder Power

Large Shareholders and Dividends: Game Theoretic Analysis of Shareholder Power Large Shareholders and Dividends: Game Theoretic Analysis of Shareholder Power Xiaoying Chen a, 1, Amit K. Sinha b a Department of Finance, College of Business Administration, California State University,

More information

Real Estate Crashes and Bank Lending. March 2004

Real Estate Crashes and Bank Lending. March 2004 Real Estate Crashes and Bank Lending March 2004 Andrey Pavlov Simon Fraser University 8888 University Dr. Burnaby, BC V5A 1S6, Canada E-mail: apavlov@sfu.ca, Tel: 604 291 5835 Fax: 604 291 4920 and Susan

More information

BOARD CONNECTIONS AND M&A TRANSACTIONS. Ye Cai. Chapel Hill 2010

BOARD CONNECTIONS AND M&A TRANSACTIONS. Ye Cai. Chapel Hill 2010 BOARD CONNECTIONS AND M&A TRANSACTIONS Ye Cai A dissertation submitted to the faculty of the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor

More information

Merger negotiations with stock market feedback

Merger negotiations with stock market feedback INSTITUTT FOR FORETAKSØKONOMI DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE AND MANAGEMENT SCIENCE FOR 8 2011 ISSN: 1500-4066 MAY 2011 Discussion paper Merger negotiations with stock market feedback BY SANDRA BETTON, B. ESPEN

More information

ESSAYS IN CORPORATE FINANCE. Cong Wang. Dissertation. Submitted to the Faculty of the. Graduate School of Vanderbilt University

ESSAYS IN CORPORATE FINANCE. Cong Wang. Dissertation. Submitted to the Faculty of the. Graduate School of Vanderbilt University ESSAYS IN CORPORATE FINANCE By Cong Wang Dissertation Submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Vanderbilt University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

More information

Investor Behavior and the Timing of Secondary Equity Offerings

Investor Behavior and the Timing of Secondary Equity Offerings Investor Behavior and the Timing of Secondary Equity Offerings Dalia Marciukaityte College of Administration and Business Louisiana Tech University P.O. Box 10318 Ruston, LA 71272 E-mail: DMarciuk@cab.latech.edu

More information

Do Long-Term Investors Improve Corporate Decision Making?

Do Long-Term Investors Improve Corporate Decision Making? Do Long-Term Investors Improve Corporate Decision Making? Jarrad Harford (University of Washington) Ambrus Kecskés (York University) Sattar Mansi (Virginia Tech) Are long-term investors desirable for firms?

More information

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Abstract Several previous studies show that consensus analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts are excessively influenced by past firm

More information

Master in Finance. The effect of ownership structure on firm performance: Are mutual funds actually monitoring?

Master in Finance. The effect of ownership structure on firm performance: Are mutual funds actually monitoring? Master Thesis Finance The effect of ownership structure on firm performance: Are mutual funds actually monitoring? Abstract: In this thesis, the effect of mutual fund ownership on firm performance, as

More information

Corporate Governance and Diversification*

Corporate Governance and Diversification* Corporate Governance and Diversification* Kimberly C. Gleason Dept of Finance Florida Atlantic University kgleason@fau.edu Inho Kim Dept of Finance University of Cincinnati Inho73@gmail.com Yong H. Kim

More information

Activism Mergers * Nicole M. Boyson, Nickolay Gantchev, and Anil Shivdasani. November 2015 ABSTRACT

Activism Mergers * Nicole M. Boyson, Nickolay Gantchev, and Anil Shivdasani. November 2015 ABSTRACT Activism Mergers * Nicole M. Boyson, Nickolay Gantchev, and Anil Shivdasani November 2015 ABSTRACT Activist hedge funds play a critical role in the market for corporate control. Activists foster acquisition

More information

Monitoring, Contractual Incentive Pay, and the Structure of CEO Equity-Based Compensation. Fan Yu. A dissertation

Monitoring, Contractual Incentive Pay, and the Structure of CEO Equity-Based Compensation. Fan Yu. A dissertation Monitoring, Contractual Incentive Pay, and the Structure of CEO Equity-Based Compensation Fan Yu A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

More information

How do serial acquirers choose the method of payment? ANTONIO J. MACIAS Texas Christian University. P. RAGHAVENDRA RAU University of Cambridge

How do serial acquirers choose the method of payment? ANTONIO J. MACIAS Texas Christian University. P. RAGHAVENDRA RAU University of Cambridge How do serial acquirers choose the method of payment? ANTONIO J. MACIAS Texas Christian University P. RAGHAVENDRA RAU University of Cambridge ARIS STOURAITIS Hong Kong Baptist University August 2012 Abstract

More information