Tender Offers versus Block Trades: Empirical Evidence

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Tender Offers versus Block Trades: Empirical Evidence"

Transcription

1 Tender Offers versus Block Trades: Empirical Evidence MARTIN HOLMÉN a and EUGENE NIVOROZHKIN b Forthcoming Managerial and Decision Economics Abstract In this paper, we test whether the determinants of block trade and non-partial tender offer probabilities differ and whether the relative magnitude of security and private benefits can explain the choice of transfer mode. We investigate the Swedish market for corporate control. The results emphasize the importance of investigating block trades and tender offers as two competing events. The proxies for private benefits of control, small controling voting blocks and separation of voting rights from cash flow rights are positively related to the likelihood of a block trade but negatively related to the likelihood of a non-partial tender offer. Our results suggest that separation of voting rights from cash flow rights might limit the efficiency of the market for corporate control. The prevalence of block trades in the presence of greater private benefits of control highlights the disadvantages of this control transfer mode in terms of incentive alignment between the buyer and the remaining dispersed shareholders. Keywords: Tender offers; Block trades; Ownership structure; Private benefits of control; Dual class shares; Stock pyramids JEL Classification: G34; G32 The authors would like to thank Tim Broadhurst, Cynthia Campbell, Ettore Croci, Thomas Lagoarde-Segot, Fredrik Lindqvist, and Richard Sweeney for valuable comments. Comments from participants at the EFMA symposium on Corporate Governance in Milan, the FMA meeting in Barcelona, the 2007 SNEE conference, the 2008 INFINITI Conference on International Finance at Trinity College Dublin, and a seminar at the Research Institute of Industrial Economics are also acknowledged. Financial Support from Jan Wallander s and Tom Hedelius Research Foundation and VINNOVA is gratefully acknowledged. a Corresponding author: Centre for Finance and Department of Economics, University of Gothenburg, Box 640, Gothenburg, Sweden, and Department of Finance and Statistics, Hanken School of Economics, Arkadiagatan 22, Helsinki, Finland. Martin.Holmen@cff.gu.se ; Phone: b SSEES, University College London, Gower Street, London WC1E 6BT, UK

2 Tender Offers versus Block Trades: Empirical Evidence Abstract In this paper, we test whether the determinants of block trade and non-partial tender offer probabilities differ and whether the relative magnitude of security and private benefits can explain the choice of transfer mode. We investigate the Swedish market for corporate control. The results emphasize the importance of investigating block trades and tender offers as two competing events. The proxies for private benefits of control, small controling voting blocks and separation of voting rights from cash flow rights, are positively related to the likelihood of a block trade but negatively related to the likelihood of a non-partial tender offer. Our results suggest that separation of voting rights from cash flow rights might limit the efficiency of the market for corporate control. The prevalence of block trades in the presence of greater private benefits of control highlights the disadvantages of this control transfer mode in terms of incentive alignment between the buyer and the remaining dispersed shareholders. Keywords: Tender offers; Block trades; Ownership structure; Private benefits of control; Dual class shares; Stock pyramids JEL Classification: G34; G32

3 1. Introduction This paper addresses two questions. First, do the determinants of block trade and non-partial tender offer probabilities differ? And second, does the controlling shareholder s relative magnitude of security benefits and pecuniary private benefits explain the choice of transfer mode? 1 Security and private benefits should be substitutes. We hypothesize that the relative magnitude of private benefits proportionately increases with a reduction in a controlling ownership stake and with an increase in a wedge between voting rights and cash flow rights. A wedge between voting rights and cash flow rights can be achieved by the use of dual class shares and stock pyramids. A greater proportion of private benefits would increase the incentives for preserving these benefits and would therefore increase the probability of a block trade transfer mode (Burkart, Gromb, and Panunzi, 2000). Given that private benefits tend to be internalised in a non-partial tender offer, we expect that the likelihood of a tender offer would tend to increase with a reduction in the factors used as proxies for private benefits of control. Researchers in corporate finance have given considerable attention to issues affecting transfer of control to the most efficient user of corporate resources. 2 The market for corporate control represents the institutional framework facilitating control changes. The typical modes of control transfers in publicly traded companies are block trades and nonpartial tender offers. 3 Until recently, the finance literature tended to treat the two transfer modes as equivalent as long as a block trade or tender offer resulted in the same party having control (Burkart et al., 2000). Burkart et al. (2000) argue theoretically that the incentive effect of the controling party s final holding has largely been overlooked in the control transfer literature (e.g. Grossman and Hart, 1988; Bebchuk, 1994; Zingales, 1995) and is likely to 1 With security benefits, we mean dividends and capital gains that accrue to all shareholders. 2 See e.g. Grossman and Hart (1980) and Shleifer and Vishny (1986). 3 Control changes through a block trade tend to be more common than tender offers. In 2000, only 27 percent of the changes in control of US firms were created by tender offers (Schmid, 2002). 1

4 have a significant effect on the choice of transfer mode. One suggested factor affecting this choice is interdependence of security benefits and private benefits attached to a controling ownership stake. Bethel, Liebeskind, and Opler (1998) document that the market for partial corporate control (block trades) plays an important role in limiting the agency costs in US corporations. However, little is known about the markets of corporate control outside the Anglo-Saxon countries. 4 Denis and McConnell (2003) point out that takeover activity does not appear to be an important governance mechanism throughout the world. Several papers have documented significant differences between the Anglo-Saxon countries and the rest of the world in terms of the typical corporate ownership structure (see e.g. La Porta et al., 1999). However, Franks and Mayer (2001) argue that the most important differences between Anglo-Saxon countries and continental Europe (Germany) are in terms of dynamic relations involving transfers of control. For example, the gains from German block trades are small and appear to solely accrue to large blockholders. In this paper, we investigate the Swedish market for corporate control. Exploring the effect of private benefits of control on the choice of a control transfer mode in the context of the Swedish equity market offers a couple of advantages. First, Sweden has an extreme separation of ownership and control. It ranks #1 in terms of the use of dual class shares and #2 in terms of the frequency of pyramid structures (after Belgium) (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer, 1999). 5 Thus, we have a simple measure of the incentives to extract private benefits from the corporation, i.e. the separation between ownership and control due to dual class shares and pyramids. This measure varies both between and within firms over time and it has also been used in earlier literature (see e.g. Claessens, Djankov, Fan and Lang, 2002; 4 The value of European mergers and acquisitions exceeded that in America for the first time in 2006 (Economist, Jan ). 5 Typically, Swedish firms issue A and B shares. The A-shares are one-share one-vote while the B shares are one-share 0.1 votes. 2

5 Faccio, Lang and Young, 2001; Giannetti and Simonov, 2006). Second, the high frequency of dual class shares and pyramids allows us to explore the relation between the market for corporate control and these instruments per se. In particular, we are able to disentangle the effect of dual class shares from the pyramid effect on the market for corporate control. Theoretically, dual class shares and pyramids are often considered to be perfect substitutes. Most of the existing financial economics literature on the likelihood of control changes relies on binary choice models. We adopt another approach and estimate the hazard rate of a non-partial tender offer and a block trade, respectively. 6 We use panel data where a majority of the firms are not subject to a non-partial tender offer or involved in a block trade during our sampling period. The hazard function approach allows us to investigate whether, given that a firm has not been subject to a non-partial tender offer (experienced a block trade) up to a certain point, changes in particular characteristics (e.g. ownership) of the firm will lead to a non-partial tender offer (block trade) event. In our main tests, we use an unbalanced panel of 195 large Swedish non-financial firms listed on the Stockholm Stock Exchange The sample contains 1461 firm years. On average, about 70 percent of the Swedish stock market capitalization are included in the sample each year. The sample includes 28 successful non-partial tender offers and 62 block trades. The evidence presented in this paper points out the importance of studying the control transfers through non-partial tender offers and block trades as two distinctive events, conditional on the regulatory environment. In accordance with our expectations, we find some important differences in factors determining the likelihood of the two events. Combining 6 Helwege, Pirinsky, and Stulz (2007) estimate hazard functions when estimating the likelihood of a firm becoming widely held. 7 The sample selection stops in 1998 since Sweden introduced a mandatory bid rule in A mandatory bid rule will trigger a non-partial tender offer if the traded block is sufficiently large. Thus, the analysis of the determinants of block trades and tender offers, respectively, becomes ambiguous with a mandatory bid rule in place. However, as a robustness test, we examine the likelihood of block trades in the period. 3

6 these events in a single model would lead to obscuring the information conveyed by a choice of transfer mode (Burkart et al., 2000). An increase in the largest shareholder s ownership stake tends to increase (decrease) the likelihood of a non-partial tender offer (block trade). Conversely, the use of dual class shares by the largest shareholder decreases (increases) the likelihood of a non-partial tender offer (block trade). Private benefits are proportionately increasing with a decrease in a controlling ownership stake and an increased separation between cash flow and control rights. When the relative magnitude of private benefits of control is large, the bidder and the incumbent in the target negotiate a control block transfer since the private benefits will be internalized in a tender offer. To our knowledge, this paper is the first empirical attempt at illustrating the critical importance of the interdependence between private and security benefits for the choice of transfer mode in an equity transaction involving change of control. Furthermore, while several papers have estimated the likelihood of non-partial takeovers, 8 Rapp et al. (2008) is the only other paper of which we are aware that empirically investigates the likelihood of block trades 9. As far as we know, empirical results on the effect of separation of voting rights from cash flow rights on the market for corporate control are also scarce. Our results suggest that the separation of voting rights from cash flow rights affects the market for corporate control by reducing the likelihood of a tender offer while increasing the likelihood of block trades. Even if block trades on average increase firm value, this does not prove that firm value is maximized at block trades or that it is the best feasible outcome (Burkart et al., 2000). It has been shown that separation of voting rights from cash flow rights is the norm outside the Anglo-Saxon countries (see e.g. La Porta et al., 1999). We argue that this partly explains why there are important differences between Anglo-Saxon countries and 8 See e.g. Hasbrouck (1985), Walkling (1985), Palepu (1986), Ambrose and Megginson (1992) and Powell (1997). 9 Unlike our paper, the paper by Rapp et al. (2008) does not consider tender offers and block trades as alternative control transfer modes. 4

7 the rest of the world in terms of dynamic relations involving control transfers (Franks and Mayer, 2001). While the market for corporate control in the Anglo-Saxon countries is an important governance mechanism, it is not clear that takeover activity plays an important role in limiting agency problems in other parts of the world (Bethel et al., 1998; Denis and McConnell, 2003). The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section outlines our hypotheses and describes the data. Section 3 discusses the survival analysis methodology. Section 4 presents the empirical results and the final section summarizes and concludes the paper. 2. Hypotheses and Data 2.1. Hypotheses non-partial tender offers and block trades The hypotheses are outlined for a situation without a mandatory bid rule. In the empirical section, we will discuss how the hypotheses might change with the introduction of a mandatory bid rule. Grossman and Hart (1980) show that due to the free-rider problem, an outsider will never take over a diffusely held firm in order to implement value-improving changes. Shleifer and Vishny (1986) consider a firm with a large minority blockholder and a fringe of small shareholders. When the large shareholder s return on his own shares suffices to cover monitoring and takeover costs, performance improving tender offers will be possible. Either the large shareholder makes a tender offer himself or he makes it easier for a well-informed outsider, who has no initial position in the firm, to make a tender offer. The outsider and the incumbent large shareholder would simply split the gains from the rise in the price of the incumbent s shares. The more shares the incumbent owns, the more likely it is that the return associated with improved performance will cover monitoring and takeover costs. Viewed in another way, the more shares the incumbent owns, the easier it is to convince small 5

8 shareholders that a low bid premium indicates a small performance improvement rather than an attempt to profit at their expense. If the incumbent accepts a bid by an outsider, it is convincing for small shareholders; since the incumbent s stake in firm increases, it is in his own interest to accept tender offers associated with some lower value improvements. This is the basis for our first hypothesis Hypothesis 1: The probability of a non-partial tender offer is increasing in the largest shareholder s ownership in the firm. Hypothesis 1 deals with friendly takeovers, i.e. the bidder has negotiated the terms of the tender offer with the management and large shareholders in the target before the tender offer is made public. Even if the frequency of hostile takeovers has increased in Sweden since the late 1990s, hostile takeovers were very rare in most of our sample period. It could be argued that if hostile takeovers dominated the Swedish market for corporate control, hypothesis 1 should be reversed. The risk of a hostile takeover is decreasing in the largest shareholder s ownership in the firm, since the probability of a control contest is inversely related to the ownership concentration of the firm (Nenova, 2003). In addition, Shleifer and Vishny (1986) do not consider the possibility that the large minority shareholder derives private benefits of control and how this would affect the probability of a successful tender offer. 10 Burkart et al. (2000) also consider control transfers in firms with a dominant incumbent minority shareholder and otherwise dispersed owners. The incumbent s influence over corporate decisions enables him to pursue own goals and extract private benefits. The incumbent can sell the minority block to an outside bidder in a negotiated block trade or as part of a non-partial tender offer. All private benefits are 10 We define a tender offer as successful if the target shareholders accept the offer and sell their shares to the bidder. 6

9 transferable to the bidder and the bidder is therefore willing to compensate the incumbent for the private benefits. The bidder will improve firm performance irrespective of transfer mode. However, as compared to a block trade, a tender offer leads to more concentrated ownership. The controlling shareholder s incentive to extract private benefits decreases with ownership concentration, since he internalizes more of the inefficiencies associated with the extraction of private benefits when the size of the block increases. Indeed, after a successful non-partial tender offer, there are no private benefits of control. Burkart et al. consider the incumbent and the bidder as a coalition which must acquire shares at the post tender offer value, since the dispersed shareholders free-ride in tender offers. Thus, since the coalition is not compensated for the reduction in private benefits associated with more concentrated ownership, only the block is traded. We relax this condition and base our second hypothesis on the argument that the contribution to the value of the controlling block of private benefits relative to security benefits increases when the size of the controlling block decreases. Hypothesis 2: The probability of a block trade is decreasing in the largest shareholder s ownership in the firm. When the large shareholder s control of voting rights is separated from cash flow rights by the use of dual class of shares and/or stock pyramids, the large shareholder s mitigation of the free-rider problem is reduced. Grossman and Hart (1988) also show how deviations from oneshare one-vote can reduce the likelihood of takeovers in the presence of private benefits of control. Hypothesis 3: The probability of a non-partial tender offer is decreasing in the large shareholder s separation of voting rights and cash flow rights. 7

10 Finally, all other things equal, a larger wedge between voting and cash flow rights is likely to increase the relative magnitude of the private benefits for the controlling owner, since it increases his ability/incentive to extract private benefits (Bebchuk, Kraakman, and Triantis, 1999; Claessens et al., 2002; Barak and Lauterbach, 2007). Therefore, a larger wedge between voting rights and cash flow rights should increase the likelihood of a block trade (Burkart et al., 2000). Hypothesis 4: The probability of a block trade is increasing in the large shareholder s separation of voting rights and cash flow rights. The private benefits of control are not easily determined or quantified and thus, it is very difficult to design an accurate proxy (Dyck and Zingales, 2004). Following the existing literature on corporate governance (e.g. Bebchuk et al., 1999; La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer, 2002), we use the wedge between voting rights and cash flow rights as a gauge on the ability/incentive to extract private benefits. Claessens et al. (2002) use the wedge between voting rights and cash flow rights as a gauge on entrenchment. There are a number of other methods that have been used to measure private benefits. One proxy is the premium paid for a controlling block of shares (Barclay and Holderness, 1989; Dyck and Zingales, 2004). Needless to say, this proxy can only be constructed for firms that experience a block trade and cannot be used to predict a block trade. A second proxy for private benefits is the premium paid for voting shares when a company has both voting and non-voting shares (Nenova, 2003; Zingales, 1994). Although many Swedish firms have dual class shares, only the low voting B-shares would be traded for a large number of these firms while the controlling owner would often keep all A-shares. 8

11 Hence, in many cases it is impossible to measure the voting premium. Relying on this measure would reduce our sample size by roughly 75 percent. Furthermore, Rydqvist (1996) shows that the voting premium dramatically increases in control contests. It is likely that the voting premium would increase prior to public tender offers and block trades. Thus, the interpretation of this variable in terms of predicting public tender offers and block trades would be somewhat ambiguous. Empirical studies that attempt to measure the private benefits of control generally find that the valuation proxies for private benefits of control in Sweden are similar to, but somewhat lower than, those in the US and the UK (see Nenova, 2003; Dyck and Zingales, 2004) Sample Selection Our main tests are performed on an unbalanced panel dataset containing accounting data for the largest non-financial Swedish firms listed on the Stockholm Stock Exchange The sample stops in 1998 since Sweden introduced a Mandatory Bid Rule (MBR) in The rule requires that the bidder in a block trade offers small shareholders the same price per share as he paid the incumbent in the block. The threshold at which the mandatory bid rule comes into play was first set to 40 percent of the voting rights. This threshold was changed to 30 percent of the voting rights in Thus, the MBR directly affects the ability of large shareholders to transfer private benefits and therefore, we do not expect to find any support for hypotheses 2 and 4 with an MBR. In fact, in the competing risk framework we adopt, our model specification is no longer valid in the post- MBR period, given the restrictions imposed on the control transfer mode. However, as a robustness test, we estimate the determinants of block trades on a sample containing data for The rule was introduced as an amendment of the Swedish self-regulation on takeovers. 9

12 The accounting data is collected from the Findata Trust database. The sample contains the vast majority of the largest non-financial public firms in this time period. Some large firms that were only listed for one or two years before delisting are not included in the sample. The accounting data is combined with ownership data from Sundqvist ( ) and Sundin and Sundqvist ( ). This source reports the 25 largest owners in all listed firms as of January each year. Sundin and Sundqvist provide detailed information on coalition structures in a wide sense. Thus, if two large shareholders are known to cooperate, their shareholdings are aggregated by Sundqvist et al. We have followed their definitions of ownership coalitions. After the collection of ownership data, the sample consists of 195 firms and 1461 firm years. To identify control block trades, we collect information on the identity of the largest voteholder coalition in each firm year. When there is a change in the identity of the largest voteholder, we collect information about the changes from the publications by Sundqvist ( ) and Sundin and Sundqvist ( ) and the Affärsdata database. Affärsdata contains Swedish business articles and news from 1981 until today. It now covers 90 sources. We identify 130 control changes (change in the identity of the largest voteholder) in our sample and classify them as due to block trades (62 obs), reconstructions upon financial distress (12 obs), accumulation of shares by an outsider through the acquisitions of minority blocks and/or open market trade (45 obs) and open market divestment by the controling owner (11 obs). Since we are interested in control changes where the incumbent and an outsider negotiate the control transfer, we focus on the 62 block trades. The other control changes do not involve a negotiated control transfer between the incumbent and the outsider gaining control. 10

13 We also identify 20 indirect control changes due to block trades (14 obs), non-partial takeover (2 obs), and accumulation of shares by an outsider (4 obs). We define a control change in firm B as indirect when there is a control change in firm A and firm A controls firm B. We do not define the indirect ownership change in firm B as a control change (non-partial takeover or block trade), since the ownership in firm B does not change. The takeover activity within Swedish pyramids has been analyzed by Holmen and Knopf (2004) and Doukas, Holmen, and Travlos (2002). A first rough estimate of successful non-partial tender offer activity is also collected from the publications by Sundqvist ( ) and Sundin and Sundqvist ( ) since they report all delistings. However, they do not distinguish among actual non-partial takeovers, minority buyouts, and going private transactions. We are only interested in transactions where there has been a change in control, i.e. not in minority buyouts and going private transactions. We use daily newspapers to separate going private transactions from non-partial takeovers after successful tender offers. 12 Moreover, we examine the ownership structure of the firm in the years preceding the delisting. In Sweden, almost all non-partial takeovers are preceded by a public tender offer (Bergström and Rydqvist, 1989). According to Swedish law, any shareholder or group of shareholders in the target that has 10% of the shares can block a legal merger. Therefore, the terms of the tender offer are often negotiated between the bidder and the large shareholders of the target before the public announcement. When the large blockholders have accepted the terms of the bid, a public tender offer is made for all target shares, including the blockholders shares (Rydqvist, 1993). Most bids are non-partial and contingent on 90% of the shareholders accepting the offer. The fact that we only look at successful non-partial tender offers suggests that all blockholders ultimately accepted the offer, sometimes after a revision of the offer. Some non- 12 Part of this data was provided by Clas Bergstrom and Kristian Rydqvist. 11

14 partial takeovers start with a hostile tender offer, i.e. an offer that has not been discussed with the blockholders in the target. The bidder then negotiates with the blockholders in the target and the offer might be revised. If a rival bidder offers a higher price, the blockholders in the target are not forced to sell to the initial bidder, even if they have agreed on the terms of the initial offer. However, since the terms of most tender offers are typically negotiated between the bidder and the blockholders in the target before they are made public, we do not observe many failed bids. On the other hand, failed negotiations are common, i.e. the bidder and the blockholders in the target start negotiations but do not reach an agreement and we do not observe a tender offer. Furthermore, blockholders in potential target firms may negotiate with several potential bidders before reaching an acceptable offer, or deciding not to sell. Our final takeover sample consists of 35 successful non-partial tender offers. Seven successful tender offers were preceded by a block trade, i.e. an outsider acquired the controling block from the incumbent and then made a tender offer for the remaining shares. We classify these seven observations as block trades since control was transferred at the block trade, not at the tender offer. Thus, our final non-partial tender offer sample includes 28 observations. Together with block trades, control changes due to financial distress, accumulation of shares by an outsider, and divestment in the open market, we have 158 control changes, 22 percent of which (28 of 158) are public tender offers. This is similar to the 27 percent reported by Schmid for the US in the year In our total sample, 24 firms were subjected to minority buyouts and four firms were delisted due to bankruptcy. Table 1 panel A summarizes our sample. On average, our sample roughly contains 100 firms each year and roughly comprises 70 percent of the Swedish stock market capitalization. On average, 2 firms are taken over by non-partial tender offers each year and 4.5 firms were subjected to control block transfers each year. 12

15 2.3. Descriptive Statistics In Table 2, we provide descriptive statistics for the 195 firms and 1461 firm years in our sample. The largest block of equity on average contains 33.5 percent of the firm s cash flow rights (Unadj Equity). When the controlling owners net investment in the firm is adjusted for pyramid structures, the average controlling owner holds 26.5 percent of the firm s cash flow rights. If firm B is controlled by firm A, Equity in firm B is adjusted for pyramid structures by multiplying the ultimate owner s fraction of cash flow rights in firm A with firm A s fraction of cash flow rights in firm B. This is in line with e.g. Claessens et al. (2002). However, we define equity ownership for the largest voteholder in each firm and do not use any cut off levels. Claessens et al. (2002) define firms where no shareholder holds 10 percent of the voting rights as having dispersed ownership. In only 22 observations in our sample (1.5% of the sample) is the largest voting block smaller than 10 percent. We control for holdings through multiple control chains according to Faccio and Lang (2002). The average ratio between Equity and Unadj Equity is The median is since less than 50 percent (32 percent) of the firms are part of a pyramid structure (see panel B). The average controlling owner holds 50.8 percent of the voting rights (Votes). 13 The difference in excess of pyramid structures [förstår inte riktigt detta] is due to the high frequency of dual class shares. More than 80 percent of the firms in our sample have dual class shares (see panel B). The median controlling shareholder has almost 50 percent more voting rights than cash flow rights (Votes/ Unadj Equity) and almost twice as many voting rights as pyramid adjusted equity (Votes/ 13 We define Votes as the ultimate owner s fraction of voting rights in the firm, independent of pyramid structures. Claessens et al. (2002) define Votes as the fraction of voting rights in the weakest link in terms of voting rights in the pyramid. We have run all our tests with the definition of Claessens et al. (2002). Votes become smaller for about half of the pyramidal firms. The block trade results reported below virtually remain unchanged. The tender offer results become somewhat less statistically significant, however. 13

16 Equity). 14 The median controlling owner has been the largest voteholder for 12 years (Tenure). We also define a cross-ownership dummy (unreported). For firm B, this dummy is equal to one if Firm A controls firm B and firm B owns shares in firm A, and zero otherwise. Only 80 observations in our sample (5.5%) were involved in cross-ownership. Including a cross-ownership dummy in the hazard models reported in the next section does not affect any of the other results and the dummy per se is insignificant in all models. The median firm has assets with a book value of 1482 million SEK (Size), is 48 years old (Age), generates a return of 3.4 percent on total assets (Profitability), has financed 23.1 percent of the total assets with long-term debt (Leverage), has 57 percent of its total assets in short-term assets (Liquidity) and has a Tobin s q of Tobin s q is defined as the sum of the market value of equity and the book value of total debt divided by the book value of total assets. The sample is split according to whether the firm was subject to a control change in Successful non-partial tender offers and block trades are defined as control changes. All years within the same ownership spell (N=396) prior to a successful non-partial tender offer or a block trade are classified as belonging to a firm experiencing a control change. An ownership spell is defined as all firm years with the same controlling owner. Thus, new ownership spells begin at control block transfers and other control changes. 15 At a non-partial tender offer, the firm is delisted and no new ownership spell begins. 14 Faccio and Lang (2002) and Giannetti and Simonov (2006) analyze the ratio of voting rights and cash flow rights. Claessens et al. (2002) analyze the difference between voting rights and cash flow rights. In our empirical work, we take the natural logarithm of the ratios in order to reduce the impact of extreme values. Using the differences generates similar but statistically somewhat weaker results. 15 We have 195 firms, 62 control block transfers, and 88 other ownership changes resulting in 345 ownership spells. The 62 block trades are related to 48 firms. Thus, some firms experienced more than one block trade during the sample period. Furthermore, 7 firms experienced a block trade before becoming a non-partial takeover target. Note, however, that if it is the shareholder gaining control by the block transfer that makes the non-partial tender offer for remaining shares, the tender offer is not classified as a takeover but as a going private transaction. 14

17 The mean and median difference tests suggest that the controling owners in firms experiencing a control change have less Votes. The median difference test also suggests that controling owners in firms experiencing a control change have less total excess votes (Votes/ Equity). There is no significant difference for the other ownership variables 16 and the descriptive statistics do not suggest any significant relation between control tenure and control changes. The firms experiencing control changes are smaller but of similar age as those not experiencing control changes. Firms experiencing control changes are less profitable (Profitability) according to the median difference test. The other difference tests are insignificant. In panel B, we report statistics for four binary variables. More than 80 percent of the firms have dual class shares. In 29.4 percent of the firms, the controlling shareholders hold all A-shares and only the B-shares are traded on the Stockholm Stock Exchange. The controlling shareholder holds all A-shares in roughly 40 percent of the dual class firms. Almost one third of the firms are controlled by a pyramid structure. The difference tests suggest that dual class shares increase the probability of a control change while there is no significant difference for pyramids. The relative magnitude of private benefits does not only depend on the size of the controlling block but also on the distribution of the remaining shares. To proxy for the distribution of outside shareholdings, we define a dummy variable (Outside Block) equal to one if the second largest shareholder holds more than 10 percent of the voting rights, and zero otherwise. In 43.7 percent of the firms does an outside shareholder hold 10 percent of the voting rights or more. The descriptive statistics suggest that an outside block holder increases the probability of the firm experiencing a control change. 16 Note that mean differences are tested on the natural logarithm of Unadj. Equity/ Equity, Votes/ Unadj. Equity, Votes/ Equity, Tenure, Firm Size, Firm Age and Tobin s q. 15

18 In panel C, the firms experiencing a control change are split by whether they are nonpartial tender offer targets or subject to control block transfers. All ownership spells prior to the non-partial tender offer and block trades are classified accordingly. The mean difference tests indicate that the ownership spells associated with non-partial tender offers have larger Unadj. Equity, Unadj. Equity/ Equity, Votes, Votes/ Equity and Tenure but less Votes/ Unadj Equity. The median difference test suggests that the controlling owners in tender offer targets have less Equity than owners of block trade targets. Compared to firms experiencing control block transfers, tender offer targets are also larger (Size), older (Age), more profitable (Profitability), and have higher Liquidity but lower Leverage. There are no significant differences in terms of Tobin s Q. Finally, the difference tests in panel D indicate that nonpartial tender offer targets are more likely to have Dual Class Shares and be Pyramid firms. It is also more likely that the controlling owners hold all A-shares in tender offer targets as compared to ownership spells associated with control block transfers (Controlling owner holds all A-shares) Statistics on the bidders in the control changes In table 3 panel A, we present some statistics on bidders in non-partial tender offers and block trades, respectively. Half of the bidders in non-partial tender offers are Swedish entities. The frequency of Swedish bidders in block trades is significantly higher, amounting to almost 76 percent. Among the Swedish bidders, there are no statistically significant differences between bidders in non-partial tender offers and block trade bidders in terms of being a listed firm. Among the listed bidders, it is more likely that the bidder will be a pyramidal firm in block trades, as compared to non-partial tender offers. The bidder is defined as being a pyramidal firm if it is controlled (largest voteholder) by another firm listed on the Swedish stock market. 16

19 Gaining control of a firm by a block trade requires less capital as compared to a non-partial tender offer. As a proxy for the bidder s size, we present the average and median market value of equity for the listed bidders in panel B. It is difficult to define and collect the size or wealth for bidders that are non-listed entities or individuals. The averages and medians do not suggest that bidders in block trades are statistically smaller than bidders in non-partial tender offers Announcement returns For illustrative purposes, we present statistics on the announcement returns at non-partial tender offers and block trades, respectively, in table 4. The announcement returns are estimated as the change in share price from five days before to five days after the first announcement of the control change. 17 The announcements are collected from the Affärsdata database. We are able to collect the necessary data for 25 non-partial tender offers and 56 negotiated block trades. The average and the median tender offer in our sample are associated with announcement returns above 25 percent. These numbers are similar to the abnormal price changes at tender offers in the US reported by e.g. Jensen and Ruback (1983). The average announcement return at a negotiated control block transfer is 5 percent. The median return at block trades is only 1.6 percent, but it is still statistically different from zero. Positive abnormal returns have also been reported for block trades in the US (Holderness, 2003). Even though minority shareholders are harmed in some block trades (large negative announcement returns), the average and the median share price increases suggest that improved management is at least part of the source of the gains in block trades (Berglöf and Burkart, 2003). 17 It would be interesting to also explore the control block premium. However, it is not possible to collect the prices at which the control block is traded since this is done outside the stock-market and the parties are obliged to make this information public. 17

20 3. Survival analysis methodology Survival analysis methodology is well-suited to analyses of factors explaining the likelihood of a change in firm control (e.g. Cameron and Trivedi, 1996). 18 In our context, the changes in control constitute an instance of competing risks. 19 We choose to look at two competing risks the change in the controlling owner of a firm due to a transfer of the controlling block of shares and the change due to a non-partial tender offer. The observation spell for a firm is the time until there is a change in the controlling owner or the end of the observation period has been reached. Therefore, the spells ending up with a control transfer due to other causes than block trade or a non-partial tender offer are treated as censored, resulting in the beginning of a new observation spell for the firm. As a result, at each point in time within a spell, firms can be considered to be in one of three mutually-exclusive states the status-quo state, the state of a non-partial tender offer, and the state of block trade. Over time, all firms are exposed to the chance of transiting from the status-quo state to one of the two alternative states block trade or non-partial tender offer. For the present analysis, we adopt an independent competing risks specification. In an independent competing risks model, the hazard associated with a non-partial tender offer is assumed to be independent from that of a block trade, conditional on the effects of the independent variables. 20 The estimation of an independent competing risks model is thus 18 Survival analysis deals with the modeling of time-to-event data, also known as transition data (or survival time data or duration data). Comprehensive treatments of these models can be found in Cox and Oakes (1984), Lancaster (1990), and Blossfeld and Rohwer (1995). 19 It should be noted that the absence of control change can be considered as a residual risk. 20 An important advantage of independent competing risks models is their computational tractability. Extensions to allow for correlated risks have been introduced in the literature, but have not yet been used to any considerable extent in applied work. In fact, the assumption of conditional independence is not very unrealistic given that if a particular covariate affects the hazard of more than one event, and it is in the model, then its effect is controled for. We use a large number of covariates, many of which vary with or are a function of time, which would be likely to mitigate the potential conditional dependence between the risks involved. In addition, if we assume the dependence to be due to a common unit effect, the inclusion of an unobserved heterogeneity term in our models would also ensure conditional independency of risks. 18

21 exactly equivalent to the estimation of separate models for each risk, while treating control transfers due to the other risk(s) and the situations of no control transfer as censored. 21 The advantage of the adopted methodology over more traditional Ordinary Least Squares or multinomial regressions is the ability of the survival analysis to directly account for the sequential nature of the data, and its ability to handle censoring and incorporate timevarying covariates (Jenkins, 2005). In our approach, the hazard rate captures the chances of a non-partial tender offer or a block trade within a year, conditional on survival (no such event) up to that point. The unconditional probability of not experiencing event k (where k is takeover or block trade) from the beginning of the observation period (t=0) until time t>0 for firm i in our sample is equal to λ ik (t)dt, where λ ik (t) is the hazard function defined by the equation Pr t dt Ti t lim 0 dt dt T t i ( t), i k and dt is an infinitesimal interval of time. Alternatively, λ ik (t)dt can be interpreted as an unconditional probability of a firm i experiencing an event in a tiny interval of time [t, t+dt]. The (instantaneous) hazard rate function for firm i at time t>0 is assumed to take the proportional hazards form ( t ) 0 ( t)exp( X ), i k k it where λ 0k (t) is the unknown baseline hazard at time t which may take a parametric or nonparametric form, and X it is a vector of covariates summarizing observed differences between firms at time t and β is a vector of parameters to be estimated. 21 For continuous time models, the log-likelihood for a model with multiple destinations has a separability property meaning that a multiple-destination survival model can be estimated by estimating a number of singledestination models separately, one for each destination (competing risk). With the discrete data, as in our case, an independent competing risk model can still be estimated by setting up the likelihood function as the likelihood for a standard multinomial logit model applied to re-organized data (Allison, 1982). For intervalcensored data with a relatively small interval hazard, it is common to assume that the continuous time hazard rate was constant within each interval. 19

22 Note that the probability density function in our context is a time to failure function that gives the instantaneous probability of the event. That is, in a survival experiment where the event is a non-partial tender offer, the value of the density function at time T is the probability of a firm subject to a tender offer precisely at time T. This differs from the hazard function which gives the probability conditional on a firm having survived to time T. 22 Although the survival of firms occurs in continuous time, our data calls for the discrete time specification of the model given that the spell length is observed only in oneyear intervals. In other words, the underlying continuous durations are only observed in disjoint time intervals [0 = a 0, a 1 ), [a 1, a 2 ), [a 2, a 3 ),, [a k-1, a k = ). Our covariates (e.g. firms characteristics) may vary between time intervals but are assumed to be constant within each of these. In the discrete case, hazard of exit to a particular destination k in the jth interval is given by j k a, a T a } h. ( X it ) Pr{ T j1 j j1 In our case, all intervals have the length of one year, so that the recorded duration for each firm i corresponds to the interval [t i-1, t i ). Firms are recorded as either experiencing a tender offer or a block trade during the interval, or as still remaining in status-quo. The former group, contributing completed spell data, is identified using censoring indicator c i =1. For the latter group, contributing right-censored spell data, c i =0. The number of intervals comprising a censored spell is here defined to include the last interval within which the firm is observed. The log-likelihood for each event k can be written in terms of the hazard function as: LogL k n c ti 1 ti log h ( X ) 1 hsk ( X is ) (1 ci )log1 hsk ( X is ), i ikt ikti i1 s1 s1 22 In this paper, we sometimes use the terms hazard rate of tender offer/block trade or tender offer/block trade risk instead of tender offer/block trade probability since what we model is the probability per time unit that a firm that has survived to the beginning of the respective interval will be taken over or that the controling shareholder will sell her block of shares in that interval. 20

23 where the discrete time hazard in the jth interval is h jk j ( X ij ) 1 exp exp( X ij jk ) with jk log 0k ( ) d. This specification allows for a fully non-parametric baseline hazard with a separate parameter for each duration interval. Alternatively, the γ jk may be described by some semiparametric or parametric function, e.g. θ k (j). If we define an indicator variable y ikt =1 if firm i experienced an event during the interval [t-1,t], and y ikt =0 otherwise, the log-likelihood can be rewritten in sequential binary response form: a a j 1 n ti yikj log h jk ( X ij ) (1 yikj )log1 h jk ( X ij ) log L. k i1 j1 This is one specification of log-likelihood which we estimate for each event. Our second specification incorporates a Gamma distributed random variable to describe unobserved (or omitted) heterogeneity between individuals. The instantaneous hazard rate is now specified as t) ( t) exp( X ) ( t)exp( X log( )), ik ( 0k i it k 0k it k i where ε i is a Gamma distributed random variable with unit mean and variance σ 2 v, and the discrete-time hazard function is now h jk ( X ij ) 1 exp exp( X ij log( )) k jk i. The likelihood functions of the second model are: LogL k where n i1 log 1 c i A i k c B i ik A ik t i 1 v exp X ij k k ( j) j1 (1/ v) and 21

24 B ik 1 v ti 1 j1 expx ij (1/ v) ( ) k k j Ai, if ti 1, or 1 Ai, if ti 1, where θ k (j) is a function describing duration dependence in the hazard rate. The loglikelihood function of the first model is the limiting case as v0. 4. Empirical Results In this section, we report the results of estimations of discrete time proportional hazards regression models with the hazard rate of control changes as the dependent variable. 23 First, we estimate competing risk models for non partial tender offers and block trades, respectively, for the period. A mandatory bid rule was introduced in 1999 with direct implications for the choice of control transfer mode and the ability of controlling shareholders to transfer private benefits of control. Despite the fact that our model specification is no longer valid in the post-mbr period, we do expect to find weaker relationships between ownership proxies and the probability of block trade. Therefore, we reestimate the block trade models for the period The probability of a non-partial tender offer In this section, we estimate the risk of a non-partial tender offer using the hazard regressions models. We include several independent variables. Our first hypothesis deals with the ownership fraction of the largest shareholder and, therefore, we include the natural logarithm of the largest shareholder s voting fraction (Ln(Votes)). To capture the effect of separation of voting rights from cash flow rights, we include two variables. The effect of dual class shares is captured by the natural logarithm of the ratio of the largest shareholder s vote fraction and 23 The models are estimated using the pgmhaz8 procedure of STATA 8.2. For each specification, two models are estimated by maximum likelihood methods: (1) the Prentice-Gloeckler (1978) model; and (2) the Prentice- Gloeckler (1978) model incorporating a gamma mixture distribution to summarize unobserved individual heterogeneity, as proposed by Meyer (1990). We estimate a fully non-parametric specification for the baseline hazard with four interval-specific baseline hazards. 22

Do anti-takeover devices affect the takeover likelihood or the. takeover premium?*

Do anti-takeover devices affect the takeover likelihood or the. takeover premium?* Do anti-takeover devices affect the takeover likelihood or the takeover premium?* MARTIN HOLMÉN a, EUGENE NIVOROZHKIN b and RAKESH RANA c Forthcoming European Journal of Finance Abstract In this paper

More information

Foreign Investors and Dual Class Shares

Foreign Investors and Dual Class Shares Foreign Investors and Dual Class Shares MARTIN HOLMÉN Centre for Finance, University of Gothenburg, Box 640, 405 30 Gothenburg, Sweden First Draft: February 7, 2011 Abstract In this paper we investigate

More information

Dual-Class Premium, Corporate Governance, and the Mandatory Bid Rule: Evidence from the Brazilian Stock Market

Dual-Class Premium, Corporate Governance, and the Mandatory Bid Rule: Evidence from the Brazilian Stock Market Dual-Class Premium, Corporate Governance, and the Mandatory Bid Rule: Evidence from the Brazilian Stock Market Andre Carvalhal da Silva * Coppead Graduate School of Business Avanidhar Subrahmanyam UCLA

More information

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Zhangkai Huang * and Xingzhong Xu Guanghua School of Management Peking University Abstract Unlike in other countries, negotiated block shares have

More information

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998) 219 239 Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Anup Agrawal*, Charles R. Knoeber College of Management, North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC

More information

Managerial Ownership, Controlling Shareholders and Firm Performance

Managerial Ownership, Controlling Shareholders and Firm Performance Managerial Ownership, Controlling Shareholders and Firm Performance Jon Enqvist May 29, 2005 Abstract On Swedish data I examine the relation between both managerial ownership as well as controlling shareholders

More information

Corporate Ownership Structure in Japan Recent Trends and Their Impact

Corporate Ownership Structure in Japan Recent Trends and Their Impact Corporate Ownership Structure in Japan Recent Trends and Their Impact by Keisuke Nitta Financial Research Group nitta@nli-research.co.jp The corporate ownership structure in Japan has changed significantly

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Trading-off Corporate Control and Personal Diversification through Capital Structure and Merger Activity

Trading-off Corporate Control and Personal Diversification through Capital Structure and Merger Activity Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 34(9) & (10), 1470 1495, November/December 2007, 0306-686X doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5957.2007.02057.x Trading-off Corporate Control and Personal Diversification through

More information

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXVI, NO. 1 MARCH 1991 Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers HENRI SERVAES* ABSTRACT This paper analyzes the relation between takeover gains and the q ratios of targets and

More information

Ownership Structure and Acquiring Firm Performance

Ownership Structure and Acquiring Firm Performance STOCKHOLM SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Master s Thesis in Finance Ownership Structure and Acquiring Firm Performance An Empirical Analysis of Minority Expropriation Caroline Johansson Emma Nyberg Abstract This

More information

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership Robert C. Hanson Department of Finance and CIS College of Business Eastern Michigan University Ypsilanti, MI 48197 Moon H.

More information

M&A Activity in Europe

M&A Activity in Europe M&A Activity in Europe Cash Reserves, Acquisitions and Shareholder Wealth in Europe Master Thesis in Business Administration at the Department of Banking and Finance Faculty Advisor: PROF. DR. PER ÖSTBERG

More information

Trading-off Corporate Control and Personal Diversification through Capital Structure and Merger Activity

Trading-off Corporate Control and Personal Diversification through Capital Structure and Merger Activity Trading-off Corporate Control and Personal Diversification through Capital Structure and Merger Activity Martin Holmen Department of Economics Uppsala University Sweden Martin.Holmen@nek.uu.se John D.

More information

A Law and Finance Analysis of Initial Public Offerings

A Law and Finance Analysis of Initial Public Offerings A Law and Finance Analysis of Initial Public Offerings Martin Holmén Department of Economics Uppsala University SE-751 40 Uppsala Peter Högfeldt ECGI and Department of Finance Stockholm School of Economics

More information

Large shareholders and firm value: an international analysis. Keywords: ownership concentration, blockholders, Tobin s Q, firm value

Large shareholders and firm value: an international analysis. Keywords: ownership concentration, blockholders, Tobin s Q, firm value Large shareholders and firm value: an international analysis Fariborz Moshirian *, Thi Thuy Nguyen **, Bohui Zhang *** ABSTRACT This study examines the relation between blockholdings and firm value and

More information

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? AEA Papers and Proceedings 2018, 108: 401 406 https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181116 In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? By Barbara A. Butrica and Nadia S. Karamcheva*

More information

A Law and Finance Analysis of Initial Public Offerings

A Law and Finance Analysis of Initial Public Offerings A Law and Finance Analysis of Initial Public Offerings Martin Holmén School of Business Stockholm University Peter Högfeldt Department of Finance Stockholm School of Economics Box 6501 SE-113 83 Stockholm

More information

Ownership structure and corporate performance: empirical evidence of China s listed property companies

Ownership structure and corporate performance: empirical evidence of China s listed property companies Ownership structure and corporate performance: empirical evidence of China s listed property companies Qiulin Ke Nottingham Trent University, School of Architecture, Design and the Built Environment, Burton

More information

Family Control and Leverage: Australian Evidence

Family Control and Leverage: Australian Evidence Family Control and Leverage: Australian Evidence Harijono Satya Wacana Christian University, Indonesia Abstract: This paper investigates whether leverage of family controlled firms differs from that of

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Family firms and industry characteristics?

Family firms and industry characteristics? Family firms and industry characteristics? En-Te Chen Queensland University of Technology John Nowland City University of Hong Kong 1 Family firms and industry characteristics? Abstract: We propose that

More information

The Effect of Corporate Governance on Quality of Information Disclosure:Evidence from Treasury Stock Announcement in Taiwan

The Effect of Corporate Governance on Quality of Information Disclosure:Evidence from Treasury Stock Announcement in Taiwan The Effect of Corporate Governance on Quality of Information Disclosure:Evidence from Treasury Stock Announcement in Taiwan Yue-Fang Wen, Associate professor of National Ilan University, Taiwan ABSTRACT

More information

DIVIDENDS AND EXPROPRIATION IN HONG KONG

DIVIDENDS AND EXPROPRIATION IN HONG KONG ASIAN ACADEMY of MANAGEMENT JOURNAL of ACCOUNTING and FINANCE AAMJAF, Vol. 4, No. 1, 71 85, 2008 DIVIDENDS AND EXPROPRIATION IN HONG KONG Janice C. Y. How, Peter Verhoeven* and Cici L. Wu School of Economics

More information

The Life Cycle of Family Ownership: A Comparative Study of France, Germany, Italy and the U.K.

The Life Cycle of Family Ownership: A Comparative Study of France, Germany, Italy and the U.K. The Life Cycle of Family Ownership: A Comparative Study of France, Germany, Italy and the U.K. Julian Franks, Colin Mayer, Paolo Volpin and Hannes F. Wagner 19 March 2009 Julian Franks is at the London

More information

EXAMINING THE EFFECTS OF LARGE AND SMALL SHAREHOLDER PROTECTION ON CANADIAN CORPORATE VALUATION

EXAMINING THE EFFECTS OF LARGE AND SMALL SHAREHOLDER PROTECTION ON CANADIAN CORPORATE VALUATION EXAMINING THE EFFECTS OF LARGE AND SMALL SHAREHOLDER PROTECTION ON CANADIAN CORPORATE VALUATION By Tongyang Zhou A Thesis Submitted to Saint Mary s University, Halifax, Nova Scotia in Partial Fulfillment

More information

The Effects of Ownership Concentration and Identity on Investment Performance: An. International Comparison *

The Effects of Ownership Concentration and Identity on Investment Performance: An. International Comparison * The Effects of Ownership Concentration and Identity on Investment Performance: An International Comparison * Klaus Gugler, Dennis C. Mueller and B. Burcin Yurtoglu University of Vienna, Department of Economics

More information

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW AND HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW AND HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT CHAPTER LITERATURE REVIEW AND HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT.1 Literature Review..1 Legal Protection and Ownership Concentration Many researches on corporate governance around the world has documented large differences

More information

CORPORATE OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE AND FIRM PERFORMANCE IN SAUDI ARABIA 1

CORPORATE OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE AND FIRM PERFORMANCE IN SAUDI ARABIA 1 Abstract CORPORATE OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE AND FIRM PERFORMANCE IN SAUDI ARABIA 1 Dr. Yakubu Alhaji Umar Dr. Ali Habib Al-Elg Department of Finance & Economics King Fahd University of Petroleum & Minerals

More information

Evolution of Family Capitalism: A Comparative Study of France, Germany, Italy and the UK

Evolution of Family Capitalism: A Comparative Study of France, Germany, Italy and the UK Evolution of Family Capitalism: A Comparative Study of France, Germany, Italy and the UK Julian Franks, Colin Mayer, Paolo Volpin and Hannes F. Wagner September 2008 Julian Franks is at the London Business

More information

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data by Peter A Groothuis Professor Appalachian State University Boone, NC and James Richard Hill Professor Central Michigan University

More information

This version: October 2006

This version: October 2006 Do Controlling Shareholders Expropriation Incentives Derive a Link between Corporate Governance and Firm Value? Evidence from the Aftermath of Korean Financial Crisis Kee-Hong Bae a, Jae-Seung Baek b,

More information

Cross-Country Determinants of Mergers and Acquisitions

Cross-Country Determinants of Mergers and Acquisitions Cross-Country Determinants of Mergers and Acquisitions Finance Working Paper N. 25/2003 September 2003 Stefano Rossi London Business School Paolo Volpin London Business School and ECGI Stefano Rossi and

More information

Multiple blockholders and rm valuation: Evidence from the Czech Republic

Multiple blockholders and rm valuation: Evidence from the Czech Republic Multiple blockholders and rm valuation: Evidence from the Czech Republic Ondrej Nezdara December 3, 2007 Abstract Using data for the Prague Stock Exchange in 996 to 2005, I investigate how presence and

More information

What drives the unification of multiple voting class shares?

What drives the unification of multiple voting class shares? What drives the unification of multiple voting class shares? Anete Pajuste* JOB MARKET PAPER Abstract Deviation from one share - one vote by issuing superior voting class shares is common in different

More information

Ownership Structure and Firm Performance in Sweden

Ownership Structure and Firm Performance in Sweden Ownership Structure and Firm Performance in Sweden University of Gothenburg School of Business, Economics and Law Bachelor thesis in Finance Autumn 2015 Authors: Linus Åhman and Oskar Brantås Supervisor:

More information

A Law and Finance Analysis of Initial Public Offerings

A Law and Finance Analysis of Initial Public Offerings A Law and Finance Analysis of Initial Public Offerings Martin Holmén a, * and Peter Högfeldt b a Department of Economics, Uppsala University, SE-751 40 Uppsala, Sweden b ECGI and Department of Finance,

More information

CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CASH HOLDINGS: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF CHINESE AND INDIAN FIRMS

CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CASH HOLDINGS: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF CHINESE AND INDIAN FIRMS CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CASH HOLDINGS: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF CHINESE AND INDIAN FIRMS Ohannes G. Paskelian, University of Houston Downtown Stephen Bell, Park University Chu V. Nguyen, University of

More information

Beyond the Biggest: Do Other Large Shareholders Influence Corporate Valuations?

Beyond the Biggest: Do Other Large Shareholders Influence Corporate Valuations? Beyond the Biggest: Do Other Large Shareholders Influence Corporate Valuations? Luc Laeven and Ross Levine* This Draft: March 13, 2005 Abstract: This paper examines the relationship between corporate valuations

More information

Minority Shareholder Protections and the Private Benefits of Control for Swedish Mergers

Minority Shareholder Protections and the Private Benefits of Control for Swedish Mergers Minority Shareholder Protections and the Private Benefits of Control for Swedish Mergers Martin Holmen Uppsala University SE-751 20 Uppsala Sweden Martin.Holmen@nek.uu.se +46 18 471 76 34 John D. Knopf

More information

The benefits and costs of group affiliation: Evidence from East Asia

The benefits and costs of group affiliation: Evidence from East Asia Emerging Markets Review 7 (2006) 1 26 www.elsevier.com/locate/emr The benefits and costs of group affiliation: Evidence from East Asia Stijn Claessens a, *, Joseph P.H. Fan b, Larry H.P. Lang b a World

More information

Complex Ownership Structures and Corporate Valuations

Complex Ownership Structures and Corporate Valuations Complex Ownership Structures and Corporate Valuations Luc Laeven and Ross Levine* May 9, 2007 Abstract: The bulk of corporate governance theory examines the agency problems that arise from two extreme

More information

Family ownership, multiple blockholders and acquiring firm performance

Family ownership, multiple blockholders and acquiring firm performance Family ownership, multiple blockholders and acquiring firm performance Investigating the influence of family ownership and multiple blockholders on acquiring firm performance Master Thesis Finance R.W.C.

More information

Managerial Entrenchment and Valuation Effects of. Toehold Acquisitions

Managerial Entrenchment and Valuation Effects of. Toehold Acquisitions Managerial Entrenchment and Valuation Effects of Toehold Acquisitions Ki Beom Binh, Jeongsun Yun Abstract This paper examines the market reactions to toehold acquisitions to determine whether and under

More information

Disentangling the Incentive and Entrenchment Effects of Large Shareholdings

Disentangling the Incentive and Entrenchment Effects of Large Shareholdings THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE * VOL. LVII, NO. 6 * DECEMBER 2002 Disentangling the Incentive and Entrenchment Effects of Large Shareholdings STIJN CLAESSENS, SIMEON DJANKOV, JOSEPH P. H. FAN, and LARRY H. P.

More information

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Anup Agrawal Culverhouse College of Business University of Alabama Tuscaloosa, AL 35487-0224 Jeffrey F. Jaffe Department

More information

Determinants of the corporate governance of Korean firms

Determinants of the corporate governance of Korean firms Determinants of the corporate governance of Korean firms Eunjung Lee*, Kyung Suh Park** Abstract This paper investigates the determinants of the corporate governance of the firms listed on the Korea Exchange.

More information

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance.

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Guillermo Acuña, Jean P. Sepulveda, and Marcos Vergara December 2014 Working Paper 03 Ownership Concentration

More information

Agency Costs of Controlling Shareholders Share Collateral with Taiwan Evidence

Agency Costs of Controlling Shareholders Share Collateral with Taiwan Evidence Agency Costs of Controlling Shareholders Share Collateral with Taiwan Evidence Anlin Chen* Department of Business Management National Sun Yat-Sen University Kaohsiung 804, TAIWAN Phone: +886-7-5252000

More information

The Payout Policy of Family Firms in Continental Western Europe. Alfonso Del Giudice 1 Catholic University of Sacred Hearth, Milano

The Payout Policy of Family Firms in Continental Western Europe. Alfonso Del Giudice 1 Catholic University of Sacred Hearth, Milano The Payout Policy of Family Firms in Continental Western Europe Alfonso Del Giudice 1 Catholic University of Sacred Hearth, Milano Abstract The idiosyncratic preferences of controlling shareholders play

More information

Privately Negotiated Repurchases and Monitoring by Block Shareholders

Privately Negotiated Repurchases and Monitoring by Block Shareholders Privately Negotiated Repurchases and Monitoring by Block Shareholders Murali Jagannathan College of Management Binghamton University Binghamton, NY 607.777.4639 Muralij@binghamton.edu Clifford Stephens

More information

Discussion Paper No. 2002/47 The Benefits and Costs of Group Affiliation. Stijn Claessens, 1 Joseph P.H. Fan 2 and Larry H.P.

Discussion Paper No. 2002/47 The Benefits and Costs of Group Affiliation. Stijn Claessens, 1 Joseph P.H. Fan 2 and Larry H.P. Discussion Paper No. 2002/47 The Benefits and Costs of Group Affiliation Evidence from East Asia Stijn Claessens, 1 Joseph P.H. Fan 2 and Larry H.P. Lang 3 May 2002 Abstract This paper investigates the

More information

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Anders Karlsson and Lars Nordén 1 Department of Corporate Finance, School of Business, Stockholm University, S-106 91 Stockholm, Sweden Abstract

More information

1. You are given the following information about a stationary AR(2) model:

1. You are given the following information about a stationary AR(2) model: Fall 2003 Society of Actuaries **BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** 1. You are given the following information about a stationary AR(2) model: (i) ρ 1 = 05. (ii) ρ 2 = 01. Determine φ 2. (A) 0.2 (B) 0.1 (C) 0.4

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

EUROPEAN ECONOMY EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL AFFAIRS

EUROPEAN ECONOMY EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL AFFAIRS EUROPEAN ECONOMY EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL AFFAIRS ECONOMIC PAPERS ISSN 1725-3187 http://europa.eu.int/comm/economy_finance N 212 September 2004 Determinants of

More information

Private placements and managerial entrenchment

Private placements and managerial entrenchment Journal of Corporate Finance 13 (2007) 461 484 www.elsevier.com/locate/jcorpfin Private placements and managerial entrenchment Michael J. Barclay a,, Clifford G. Holderness b, Dennis P. Sheehan c a University

More information

Managerial Stock Options and the Hedging Premium

Managerial Stock Options and the Hedging Premium European Financial Management, Vol. 13, No. 4, 2007, 721 741 doi: 10.1111/j.1468-036X.2007.00380.x Managerial Stock Options and the Hedging Premium Niclas Hagelin The Swedish National Debt Office, SE-103

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

Lecture 1: Introduction, Optimal financing contracts, Debt

Lecture 1: Introduction, Optimal financing contracts, Debt Corporate finance theory studies how firms are financed (public and private debt, equity, retained earnings); Jensen and Meckling (1976) introduced agency costs in corporate finance theory (not only the

More information

HOME BIAS. Magnus Dahlquist, Lee Pinkowitz, René M. Stulz, and Rohan Williamson* June 2002

HOME BIAS. Magnus Dahlquist, Lee Pinkowitz, René M. Stulz, and Rohan Williamson* June 2002 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE, INVESTOR PROTECTION, AND THE HOME BIAS by Magnus Dahlquist, Lee Pinkowitz, René M. Stulz, and Rohan Williamson* June 2002 * Respectively, Visiting Assistant Professor, Duke University,

More information

Multiple Controlling Shareholders and Firm Value **

Multiple Controlling Shareholders and Firm Value ** Multiple Controlling Shareholders and Firm Value ** C. Benjamin Maury a, Anete Pajuste b, * a Department of Finance and Statistics, Swedish School of Economics and Business Administration, P.O. Box 479,

More information

Pension Reform, Ownership Structure, and Corporate Governance:

Pension Reform, Ownership Structure, and Corporate Governance: Pension Reform, Ownership Structure, and Corporate Governance: Evidence from Sweden Mariassunta Giannetti Stockholm School of Economics, CEPR, and ECGI Department of Finance PO Box 6501 S 11 383 Stockholm

More information

Ownership structure and. economic performance of

Ownership structure and. economic performance of Centre for Economic and Business Research ÿkonomi- og Erhvervsministeriets enhed for erhvervs- konomisk forskning og analyse Report #3 2007 June 2007 Ownership structure and economic performance of European

More information

The choice of payment method in European mergers & acquisitions

The choice of payment method in European mergers & acquisitions The choice of payment method in European mergers & acquisitions Mara Faccio Owen Graduate School of Management Vanderbilt University 401 21 st Avenue South Nashville, TN 37203 and Ronald W. Masulis Owen

More information

The Relationship between Largest Shareholder s Ownership and Firm Performance: Evidence from Mainland China. Shiyi Ding. A Thesis

The Relationship between Largest Shareholder s Ownership and Firm Performance: Evidence from Mainland China. Shiyi Ding. A Thesis The Relationship between Largest Shareholder s Ownership and Firm Performance: Evidence from Mainland China Shiyi Ding A Thesis In The John Molson School of Business Presented in Partial Fulfillment of

More information

Cross-country determinants of mergers and acquisitions $

Cross-country determinants of mergers and acquisitions $ Journal of Financial Economics 74 (2004) 277 304 Cross-country determinants of mergers and acquisitions $ Stefano Rossi, Paolo F. Volpin* London Business School, Regent s Park, London NW1 4SA, UK Received

More information

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract In this paper we study the market reaction to capital expenditure announcements in the backdrop

More information

Ultimate controllers and the probability of filing for bankruptcy in Great Britain. Jannine Poletti Hughes

Ultimate controllers and the probability of filing for bankruptcy in Great Britain. Jannine Poletti Hughes Ultimate controllers and the probability of filing for bankruptcy in Great Britain Jannine Poletti Hughes University of Liverpool, Management School, Chatham Building, Liverpool, L69 7ZH, Tel. +44 (0)

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

Are Corporate Restructuring Events Driven by Common Factors? Implications for Takeover Prediction

Are Corporate Restructuring Events Driven by Common Factors? Implications for Takeover Prediction Are Corporate Restructuring Events Driven by Common Factors? Implications for Takeover Prediction RONAN POWELL,* ALFRED YAWSON School of Banking and Finance, the University of New South Wales, Sydney 2052,

More information

Keywords: Corporate governance, Investment opportunity JEL classification: G34

Keywords: Corporate governance, Investment opportunity JEL classification: G34 ACADEMIA ECONOMIC PAPERS 31 : 3 (September 2003), 301 331 When Will the Controlling Shareholder Expropriate Investors? Cash Flow Right and Investment Opportunity Perspectives Konan Chan Department of Finance

More information

ASSESSING THE DETERMINANTS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN FRENCH, ITALIAN AND SPANISH FIRMS 1

ASSESSING THE DETERMINANTS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN FRENCH, ITALIAN AND SPANISH FIRMS 1 C ASSESSING THE DETERMINANTS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN FRENCH, ITALIAN AND SPANISH FIRMS 1 Knowledge of the determinants of financial distress in the corporate sector can provide a useful foundation for

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS BASEMENT HD28.M414 no. Ibll- Dewey ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Corporate Investments In Common Stock by Wayne H. Mikkelson University of Oregon Richard S. Ruback Massachusetts

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

Equity Ownership and Firm Value in Emerging Markets

Equity Ownership and Firm Value in Emerging Markets Equity Ownership and Firm Value in Emerging Markets Forthcoming in The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis First draft: November 20, 1998 This draft: August 5, 2002 Karl V. Lins David Eccles

More information

Discussion Paper No. 593

Discussion Paper No. 593 Discussion Paper No. 593 MANAGEMENT OWNERSHIP AND FIRM S VALUE: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS USING PANEL DATA Sang-Mook Lee and Keunkwan Ryu September 2003 The Institute of Social and Economic Research Osaka

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LEGAL INVESTOR PROTECTION AND TAKEOVERS. Mike Burkart Denis Gromb Holger M. Mueller Fausto Panunzi

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LEGAL INVESTOR PROTECTION AND TAKEOVERS. Mike Burkart Denis Gromb Holger M. Mueller Fausto Panunzi NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LEGAL INVESTOR PROTECTION AND TAKEOVERS Mike Burkart Denis Gromb Holger M. Mueller Fausto Panunzi Working Paper 17010 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17010 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections

Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections Supporting information (For Online Publication Only) Ari Hyytinen University of Jyväskylä, School of Business and Economics (JSBE) Jaakko

More information

Pension Reform, Ownership Structure, and Corporate Governance: Evidence from a Natural Experiment

Pension Reform, Ownership Structure, and Corporate Governance: Evidence from a Natural Experiment Pension Reform, Ownership Structure, and Corporate Governance: Evidence from a Natural Experiment Mariassunta Giannetti Luc Laeven November 2007 Acknowledgments. We would like to thank Michael Weisbach

More information

Private Benefits of Control: An International Comparison

Private Benefits of Control: An International Comparison Forthcoming in the Journal of Finance Private Benefits of Control: An International Comparison Alexander Dyck* Harvard Business School and Luigi Zingales University of Chicago First Draft: November 2001

More information

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW 2.1 Background on capital structure Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set of assumptions, capital structure is irrelevant. This

More information

OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE AND THE QUALITY OF FINANCIAL REPORTING IN THAILAND: THE EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM ACCOUNTING RESTATEMENT PERSPECTIVE

OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE AND THE QUALITY OF FINANCIAL REPORTING IN THAILAND: THE EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM ACCOUNTING RESTATEMENT PERSPECTIVE I J A B E Ownership R, Vol. 14, Structure No. 10 (2016): and the 6799-6810 Quality of Financial Reporting in Thailand: The Empirical 6799 OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE AND THE QUALITY OF FINANCIAL REPORTING IN THAILAND:

More information

**BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** A random sample of five observations from a population is:

**BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** A random sample of five observations from a population is: **BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** 1. You are given: (i) A random sample of five observations from a population is: 0.2 0.7 0.9 1.1 1.3 (ii) You use the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test for testing the null hypothesis,

More information

Does takeover law matter? An empirical test of its wealth effects on mergers and acquisitions

Does takeover law matter? An empirical test of its wealth effects on mergers and acquisitions Does takeover law matter? An empirical test of its wealth effects on mergers and acquisitions Ying Wang * Henry Lahr January 2014 Abstract: Takeover regulation is fundamental to the efficient workings

More information

Antitakeover provisions and performance

Antitakeover provisions and performance Seppo Ikäheimo Vesa Puttonen Tuomas Ratilainen Antitakeover provisions and performance Evidence from the Nordic countries W-454 Seppo Ikäheimo* Vesa Puttonen* Tuomas Ratilainen** Antitakeover provisions

More information

Managerial Incentives and Corporate Leverage: Evidence from United Kingdom

Managerial Incentives and Corporate Leverage: Evidence from United Kingdom Managerial Incentives and Corporate Leverage: Evidence from United Kingdom Chrisostomos Florackis* and Aydin Ozkan ** *University of Liverpool, The Management School, Liverpool, L69 7ZH, Tel. +44 (0)1517953807,

More information

Fixed Effects Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a Flexibly Parametric Proportional Hazard Model with an Application to Job Exits

Fixed Effects Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a Flexibly Parametric Proportional Hazard Model with an Application to Job Exits Fixed Effects Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a Flexibly Parametric Proportional Hazard Model with an Application to Job Exits Published in Economic Letters 2012 Audrey Light* Department of Economics

More information

Corporate Governance Convergence: Evidence From Takeover Regulation Reforms in Europe

Corporate Governance Convergence: Evidence From Takeover Regulation Reforms in Europe Corporate Governance Convergence: Evidence From Takeover Regulation Reforms in Europe Marc Goergen Sheffield University Management School and European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI) Marina Martynova

More information

How do serial acquirers choose the method of payment? ANTONIO J. MACIAS Texas Christian University. P. RAGHAVENDRA RAU University of Cambridge

How do serial acquirers choose the method of payment? ANTONIO J. MACIAS Texas Christian University. P. RAGHAVENDRA RAU University of Cambridge How do serial acquirers choose the method of payment? ANTONIO J. MACIAS Texas Christian University P. RAGHAVENDRA RAU University of Cambridge ARIS STOURAITIS Hong Kong Baptist University August 2012 Abstract

More information

Managerial Performance, Bid Premiums, and the Characteristics of Takeover Targets *

Managerial Performance, Bid Premiums, and the Characteristics of Takeover Targets * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 3, 67 84 (2002) Managerial Performance, Bid Premiums, and the Characteristics of Takeover Targets * Chao Chen Center for China Finance and Business Research and Department

More information

State Ownership and Value of Firm: Evidence from China

State Ownership and Value of Firm: Evidence from China State Ownership and Value of Firm: Evidence from China Lifan Wu* Senior Visiting Research Fellow Shanghai Stock Exchange Department of Finance and Law California State University Los Angeles 5151 State

More information

Excess control, Corporate Governance, and Implied Cost of Equity: International Evidence*

Excess control, Corporate Governance, and Implied Cost of Equity: International Evidence* Excess control, Corporate Governance, and Implied Cost of Equity: International Evidence* Omrane Guedhami Faculty of Business Administration, Memorial University of Newfoundland, St. John s, NL, Canada

More information

What do we know about Capital Structure? Some Evidence from International Data

What do we know about Capital Structure? Some Evidence from International Data What do we know about Capital Structure? Some Evidence from International Data Raghuran G. Rajan Luigi Zingales Objective of the Study To establish whether capital structure in other countries is related

More information

Determinants of Capital Structure: A Case of Life Insurance Sector of Pakistan

Determinants of Capital Structure: A Case of Life Insurance Sector of Pakistan European Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Sciences ISSN 1450-2275 Issue 24 (2010) EuroJournals, Inc. 2010 http://www.eurojournals.com Determinants of Capital Structure: A Case of Life Insurance

More information

MERGER ANNOUNCEMENTS AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: DO MARKETS PREDICT SYNERGETIC GAINS FROM MERGERS PROPERLY?

MERGER ANNOUNCEMENTS AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: DO MARKETS PREDICT SYNERGETIC GAINS FROM MERGERS PROPERLY? MERGER ANNOUNCEMENTS AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: DO MARKETS PREDICT SYNERGETIC GAINS FROM MERGERS PROPERLY? ALOVSAT MUSLUMOV Department of Management, Dogus University. Acıbadem 81010, Istanbul / TURKEY Tel:

More information

Comment on Determinants of Intercorporate Shareholdings

Comment on Determinants of Intercorporate Shareholdings European Finance Review 1: 289 293, 1997. c 1997 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Comment on Determinants of Intercorporate Shareholdings B. ESPEN ECKBO Stockholm School of Economics

More information

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time,

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, 1. Introduction Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, many diversified firms have become more focused by divesting assets. 2 Some firms become more

More information

Panel Data with Binary Dependent Variables

Panel Data with Binary Dependent Variables Essex Summer School in Social Science Data Analysis Panel Data Analysis for Comparative Research Panel Data with Binary Dependent Variables Christopher Adolph Department of Political Science and Center

More information