An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty"

Transcription

1 Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Volume 29, Number 1, 2013, pp An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty Robert Joyce* and Luke Sibieta** Abstract We document the evolution of average incomes, poverty and inequality over the period of Labour government from 1997 to 2010, comparing these trends with those seen over other periods in recent history. We also relate these changes to Labour s stated distributional objectives, which we argue were clear in relation to the bottom of the income distribution (and absolutely explicit in relation to child poverty), but much less clear in relation to inequality more generally. It is thus perhaps no surprise that we observe substantial falls in child and pensioner poverty alongside increases in overall income inequality, with the latter largely driven by growth in top incomes. We also use micro-simulation techniques to demonstrate the crucial importance of direct tax and benefit reforms in driving the changes observed over this period. Key words: inequality, poverty JEL classification: D31, I30, I32 I. Introduction When Labour came to power in 1997, income inequality stood at historically high levels, and relative income poverty had risen substantially since the party was last in office in the late 1970s. In this article, we analyse the record of the Labour governments from 1997 to 2010 in addressing income inequality and poverty. We assess how the income distribution changed over the period and how these changes related to Labour s policies. This draws on new results from a tax and benefit micro-simulation exercise. It is important to try to discern what Labour s distributional objectives were, and the extent to which policy as opposed to other economic and societal factors contributed to trends in poverty and inequality. It quickly became apparent that Labour was focused on reducing poverty among families with children and pensioners. In 1999, Tony * Institute for Fiscal Studies, robert_j@ifs.org.uk ** Institute for Fiscal Studies, luke_s@ifs.org.uk The authors gratefully acknowledge funding from the ESRC Centre for the Microeconomic Analysis of Public Policy at the Institute for Fiscal Studies. The paper also draws partly on work supported by the Joseph Rowntree Foundation. The authors would like to thank Anthony Atkinson, Mike Brewer, Paul Johnson, John Micklewright, and participants at the Oxford Review s seminar on Labour s economic record for their comments on previous versions of this paper. The Family Resources Survey is crown copyright material and is reproduced with the permission of the Controller of HMSO and the Queen s Printer for Scotland. It was obtained from the Economic and Social Data Service at the UK Data Archive. doi: /oxrep/grt008 The Authors Published by Oxford University Press. For permissions please journals.permissions@oup.com

2 An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty 179 Blair made a famous commitment to end child poverty within a generation; and Gordon Brown promised to end pensioner poverty in our country at the 2002 Labour party conference. As discussed in this paper, these commitments clearly motivated policy and, in particular, the substantial increases in welfare spending on low-income pensioners and families with children. All else being equal, reductions in poverty will tend to reduce inequality as well. However, it is much less clear that Labour took a strong view on the appropriate level of inequality within the top half of the income distribution. Its 1997 manifesto deplored the fact that There is a wider gap between rich and poor than for generations, but was thin on commitments to address income inequality. Indeed, statements made by senior government figures suggested a keenness to emphasize a lack of such intentions: Peter Mandelson, a key architect of New Labour, famously stated that he was intensely relaxed about people getting filthy rich as long as they pay their taxes. Labour also made firm commitments not to increase the basic or top rates of income taxation, which limited its ability to use the tax system to influence income inequality. If this is an accurate summary of Labour s objectives, then we show that outcomes closely reflected those objectives, although the scale of the changes achieved did not always match the considerable ambition. Poverty among families with children and pensioners both fell particularly strongly, although the extremely ambitious relative child poverty target was still missed in 2010/11. However, the incomes of low-income working-age adults without dependent children, a group not favoured by tax and benefit reforms, rose very little over the period, and hence their relative poverty rate actually increased. As a result, Labour s period in office saw a convergence in the risks of poverty across the major demographic groups. Incomes at the very top of the distribution saw the strongest growth of all during Labour s period in office. Largely as a result of that, most measures of income inequality nudged up. The main focus of this paper is on household incomes, and poverty and inequality statistics based upon the distribution of household incomes. This is consistent with most of the academic literature on the income distribution, and with the standard measures of poverty and inequality tracked by governments (for example, see Department for Work and Pensions (DWP, 2012)). But we recognize that there are other important and relevant dimensions of distribution, such as intra-household allocation and gender inequalities. Although a comprehensive treatment of all such dimensions is beyond the scope of this paper, we note these issues where we believe they are relevant and refer the reader to relevant research. Elsewhere in this issue, Lindley and Machin (2013) analyse trends in wage inequality under the Labour governments. The paper proceeds as follows. Section II provides important context to the discussion of poverty and inequality by briefly summarizing trends in average living standards under Labour. Section III analyses what happened to income inequality and what drove these trends. Section IV examines trends in poverty and the extent to which they reflect the policy priorities and reforms. Section V concludes. II. Average incomes Before discussing how income inequality and poverty changed over Labour s period in office, it is important to describe how average living standards changed. Table 1 compares five measures

3 180 Robert Joyce and Luke Sibieta Table 1: Measures of income growth compared (%) GDP per head Household a final consumption expenditure per capita Real household disposable income per head Mean HBAI income (BHC b ) Median HBAI income (BHC) Conservatives 1979 to 1996/7 Labour 1996/7 to 2009/10 of which: Fast growth (1996/7 to 2001/2) Weak growth (2001/2 to 2007/8) Recent recession (2007/8 to 2009/10) Post-recession: 2009/10 to 2010/ Notes: a And non-profit institutions serving households. b BHC: before housing costs have been deducted. Incomes have been measured before housing costs have been deducted. National accounts measures are for the UK as a whole, while HBAI measures relate to Great Britain only. Source: Authors calculations using ONS series IHXW, IHXX, and IHXZ, and HBAI data. of growth in average living standards. Three are derived from the National Accounts: gross domestic product (GDP) per capita, real household disposable income (RHDI) per capita, and household final consumption expenditure (HFCE) per capita. The remaining two are mean and median household income. These are based on the Family Resources Survey (FRS) and take the same definition of income as used by the government in Households Below Average Income (HBAI), i.e. net, equivalized household income from all sources. The different series measure living standards in different ways. Of the National Accounts measures, real GDP per head is a widely used measure of economic wellbeing, showing the estimated market value of all final goods and services produced in the UK economy, divided by the total number of people in the UK. One important advantage of using GDP per head to measure living standards is that it also captures expenditure on public services and thus will not fall one-for-one with any tax increases used to pay for more public services. In contrast, household income measures will fall with such tax increases, with no account taken of the extra spending on public services or its impact on living standards. Real household disposable income, as the name implies, focuses on the household sector, 1 and so excludes the incomes of companies and the government. Household final consumption expenditure (including 1 Though the household sector used for this measure also includes charities and universities.

4 An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty 181 the expenditure of non-profit institutions serving households) is a measure of spending, rather than income, and is also derived from the National Accounts. It captures expenditure incurred by households on consumption of goods and services. The HBAI measures focus on current household disposable income, adjusted for family size and composition. These measures allow us to look at the whole distribution of income (unlike the National Accounts measures). Despite these definitional differences, growth over Labour s period in office was broadly similar across all five measures, at around 2 per cent per year on average. The only exception is median income growth, which grew less quickly than the other four measures (all of which are means). This reflects continued increases in inequality within the top half the income distribution, as discussed in the next section. Growth in mean living standards was generally higher under the period of Conservative government between 1979 and 1997 than under Labour, particularly for household disposable income and consumption. As suggested by previous work, there were three quite distinct phases in growth in average living standards under Labour (Cribb et al., 2012). During the first phase (1996/7 to 2001/2), average income growth was relatively fast, with most measures growing by around 3 per cent per year (and household consumption growing even faster at more than 4 per cent per year). This was followed by a period of sluggish growth in average incomes between 2001/2 and 2007/8, with only about 1 per cent average annual growth. Growth in household consumption and GDP per capita also slowed, but not to the same extent. Interestingly, this meant that average household consumption grew by a total of 39 per cent over Labour s first 10 years of office, while measure of disposable income grew by 27 per cent or less. This suggests that part of the growth in household consumption was driven by household borrowing. The gap between GDP per capita growth and disposable incomes over the 2000s may partly reflect the increase in the tax burden over this period (Chote et al., 2010a). However, it is difficult to place a monetary value on the value to households of the increased spending on public services such as health and education over the same period (Chote et al., 2010b). The last years of the Labour government were dominated by the financial crisis and recession. GDP per capita fell substantially, by more than 7 per cent between 2007/8 and 2009/10. Nevertheless, average disposable incomes actually continued growing slowly over that period. Previous work (Cribb et al., 2012) suggests that this largely reflects a combination of very low and falling inflation, increased welfare payments, and a fiscal stimulus which included a temporary cut in VAT from 17.5 to 15 per cent. This delayed impact of the late-2000s recession on household incomes was an experience shared by other countries (for a detailed cross-national comparison, see Jenkins et al. (2012)). But the respite was temporary and a large fall in average disposable incomes followed in 2010/11. Interestingly, falls in household consumption clearly preceded falls in household income, and occurred more contemporaneously with falls in GDP, perhaps reflecting the earlier adjustment of consumption patterns in light of the effects of the recession on expectations about future income. For detailed analysis of household spending during and after the recent recession, see Crossley et al. (2011). To summarize, average income growth under Labour was slightly lower than under the Conservative governments between 1979 and 1997, but this masks considerable variation over time. Income growth was largely concentrated in the first 5 years of Labour s period in office, and the subsequent slowdown far predated the late 2000s

5 182 Robert Joyce and Luke Sibieta recession. From 2002 onwards, average income growth was sluggish, and it finally went into reverse after the recession and financial crisis. III. Income inequality Labour had no specific targets relating to overall income inequality. It was very clear that it wanted to see a reduction in relative income poverty (at least among pensioners and children), which implies a narrower gap between the bottom and the middle of the income distribution. But, as indicated by the earlier quotation from Peter Mandelson, there were no clear goals with regard to the level of income inequality in the top half of the income distribution and thus the overall level of income inequality. Things started to change at least implicitly after the onset of the global financial crisis in To raise revenue to close a widening budget deficit, those on high incomes were expected to bear the biggest burden. Alistair Darling, the then Chancellor, announced plans to introduce a new 50 per cent marginal rate of tax on incomes above 150,000 from April 2010, as well as other measures aimed at increasing the tax take from individuals with very high incomes: withdrawing their personal income tax allowance and restricting the generosity of tax relief on their pension contributions. Darling said: I considered a number of options to raise revenue in future years. And I have chosen those which are fairest and affect those who have done best out of the growth of the last decade (Hansard, 2008). There is no explicit reference to inequality, but the intended distributional consequences of the changes were clear. The rest of this section discusses trends in income inequality between 1997 and We then discuss potential explanations for these trends, including policy reforms and wider socio-economic changes. (i) Trends in income inequality under Labour Figure 1 shows the evolution of the Gini coefficient in Great Britain since Inequality as measured by the Gini rose dramatically over the 1980s, from around 0.25 in 1979 to around 0.34 in the early 1990s. The scale of this rise in inequality has been shown to be unparalleled in recent British history and was larger than the growth in income inequality occurring at the same time in most other developed countries (the United States being a key exception). 3 Between the early 1990s and 2009/10, the changes in income inequality were less dramatic. After falling slightly over the early to mid-1990s, the Gini rose again during Labour s first term, reaching a new peak of 0.35 in 2000/1. During Labour s second term, however, the Gini fell. It then crept up again during the first 3 years of Labour s third term, but held steady during the financial crisis at just under 0.36 a historic high 2 Data for the UK as a whole are only available from 2002/3 onwards. We therefore focus on inequality within Great Britain only. Between 2002/3 and 2010/11 the trends for the UK as a whole were very similar to those for Great Britain only. 3 See Atkinson (1999), Goodman et al. (1997), and Gottschalk and Smeeding (1997).

6 An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty 183 Figure 1: The Gini coefficient (Great Britain) Note: The Gini coefficient has been calculated using incomes before housing costs have been deducted. Source: Authors calculations using Family Expenditure Survey and Family Resources Survey, various years. since our consistent data series began in Overall then, the Gini coefficient rose from 0.33 in 1996/7 to 0.36 in 2009/10. Other summary inequality measures exhibit a similar pattern (see Cribb et al., 2012). Although Labour was in power for only 1 month of the 2010/11 financial year, it would be very unusual for an incoming government to significantly change the tax and benefit system midway through a financial year, and it is unlikely that any other mechanism by which the government could have affected the income distribution would have had substantial immediate effects. It therefore makes sense to include 2010/11 when considering Labour s record. The Gini coefficient in Great Britain fell from 0.36 to 0.34 in 2010/11, returning inequality to just below its 1997/8 level. This 1-year decline in the Gini was statistically significant 4 and the largest 1-year fall for at least 50 years. Of course income changes in that year cannot all be directly attributed to the policies of either the incoming or outgoing governments, as they were obviously strongly related to the global financial crisis. But Labour s policy did have some role to play when it comes to changes in top incomes, and hence summary measures of income inequality. The introduction of the new 50 per cent marginal rate of income tax in April 2010 will clearly have reduced the after-tax incomes of high-income individuals before accounting for any changes in behaviour. After behavioural response, the effect on net incomes at the top of the distribution is likely to have been even larger as a result of financial incentives for these individuals to reduce their hours (assuming the substitution effect dominates the income effect), engage in tax avoidance or evasion, and/or emigrate. However, it will also have provided strong incentives for high-income individuals to bring forward their income into 2009/10 in order to reduce their overall tax burden, artificially inflating measured top incomes in 2009/10 and reducing them in 2010/11. Hence, some of the reduction in the Gini coefficient in 2010/11 is almost certainly due 4 Standard errors were calculated by bootstrapping. See Cribb et al. (2012) for further details.

7 184 Robert Joyce and Luke Sibieta to the unwinding of the temporary forestalling behaviour of very rich individuals in the previous year. It is therefore difficult to ascertain the extent to which the reduction in income inequality in 2010/11 will prove to be a permanent or temporary phenomenon (especially with more planned changes to top rates of tax in the pipeline: see Cribb et al. (2012) for more details). It is important to note, however, that these issues affect only the very richest individuals (approximately the top 1 per cent), whereas inequality in 2010/11 declined right across the distribution. This wider reduction in inequality was largely because real earnings fell by more than real state benefit levels (see Cribb et al., 2012). A large part of the trends in summary measures of income inequality such as the Gini coefficient under Labour can be explained by the top of the distribution. To illustrate this, Figure 2 shows the level of the Gini coefficient over time if we were to exclude the richest 1, 5, and 10 per cent of individuals in any given year. This provides some guidance as to how sensitive the levels and changes in the Gini coefficient have been to the top of the distribution. As one would expect, the Gini coefficient goes down in any given year if one excludes the top of the distribution. The changes under Labour between 1997 and 2010 also become much less pronounced, suggesting that trends in the Gini over this period were largely being driven by the top of the distribution. Finally, it is noteworthy that all measures of the Gini coefficient show a fall in 2010/11, reflecting the fact that income inequality fell unambiguously in that year across the entire income distribution (and, in particular, that the fall in inequality was not driven only by temporary or permanent effects of the new 50 per cent marginal income tax rate). To further understand the changes in income inequality under Labour, Figure 3 moves away from summary measures of inequality and shows how incomes changed right across the distribution between 1996/7 and 2010/11. Growth was quite evenly spread, with the highest growth in the second and third poorest decile groups and the Figure 2: The Gini coefficient (Great Britain), excluding various top income groups Note: The Gini coefficient has been calculated using incomes before housing costs have been deducted. Source: Authors calculations using Family Expenditure Survey and Family Resources Survey, various years.

8 An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty 185 Figure 3: Real income growth by percentile point, 1996/7 to 2010/11 (Great Britain) Notes: The changes in income at the 1st and 99th percentiles are not shown on this graph. Incomes have been measured before housing costs have been deducted. The differently-shaded bars refer to decile groups. Source: Authors calculations using Family Expenditure Survey and Family Resources Survey, various years. lowest growth towards the top of the distribution (the seventh, eighth, and ninth decile groups). By itself, this would suggest falling inequality. However, the trends in the tails of the distribution explain the overall increase in summary measures of inequality. The poorest 10 per cent experienced lower-than-average growth, and the richest 10 per cent saw strong income growth. Indeed, inequality was increasing quickly even within the top decile group, with the top 1 per cent seeing the fastest growth of all. This pattern reinforces the point that increases in overall income inequality over this period were largely driven by trends right at the top of the distribution. The figure makes two further important points. First, the grey line shows average annual income growth across the distribution from 1996/7 to 2009/10 (the last full financial year of Labour s period in office). The difference between this and the bars shows the impact of including data from 2010/11 on the average annual rate of growth in incomes at each percentile since 1996/7. The difference is striking: for instance, the fall in income in 2010/11 reduced average annual median income growth over the entire period from 1.6 to 1.2 per cent. The largest difference between growth to 2009/10 and to 2010/11 is at the very top of the income distribution, where the falls in income in the most recent year of data were largest (as might be expected, given the changes to top rates of tax and the resultant incentives). Second, the black line shows the average annual income growth from 1979 to 1996/7, when the Conservatives were in office. It shows that increases in incomes in the bottom part of the distribution were greater under Labour and increases in the top part of the distribution were greater under the Conservatives. This also explains, in part, why income growth at the mean was higher under the Conservatives. Figure 4 breaks income trends under Labour into four separate periods: fast growth in average incomes (1996/7 to 2001/2); weak growth (2001/2 to 2007/8); the recession (2007/8 to 2009/10); and 2010/11. Apart from at the very bottom of the distribution, 1996/7 to

9 186 Robert Joyce and Luke Sibieta Figure 4: Real income growth by percentile point in four periods since (Great Britain) Notes: The changes in income at the 1st, 2nd, and 99th percentiles are not shown on this graph. Incomes have been measured before housing costs have been deducted. Source: Authors calculations using Family Resources Survey, various years. 2001/2 saw the strongest income growth of all. Growth over this period was also inequality-reducing across most of the distribution, with the highest growth at around the 30th percentile. However, the tails of the distribution were a different matter, with fast growth for the top 5 per cent and much slower growth for the bottom 10 per cent. The period between 2001/2 and 2007/8 saw much slower income growth across the board. For most of the distribution, income growth was relatively flat at around 1 per cent per year. However, strong growth at the top and real falls in income at the bottom acted to increase income inequality. Income growth between 2007/8 and 2009/10 was similar to that for the preceding 6 years for the top two-thirds of the income distribution. But growth was noticeably higher in the bottom third during the recession than over the previous 6 years; and the difference was most pronounced for the poorest 20 per cent. This is likely to reflect a number of factors that led to real-terms increases in benefits and tax credits: falling inflation and the uprating rules for state benefits and tax credits (by which their rates are generally increased annually in line with a lagged measure of inflation); and discretionary changes to benefits and tax credits. This meant reduced inequality across most of the income distribution during the recession. In 2010/11, there were falls in real income right across the income distribution, much of which reflects the unwinding of some of the factors supporting real disposable incomes during the recession, such as the temporary cut to VAT. The pattern of income falls was unambiguously inequality-reducing, with real falls as large as 5.1 per cent at the 90th percentile. This clearly shows that the fall in income inequality in 2010/11 was driven not just by changes at the very top of the distribution: there was a pattern of inequality-reducing growth right across the board. In Figure 5, we show the consequences of these patterns of income growth on the 90/10, 50/10, and 99/50 ratio measures of inequality. During the 1980s, each of these

10 An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty 187 Figure 5: Income ratios: 90/10, 50/10, and 99/50 ratios (Great Britain) Note: The Gini coefficient has been calculated using incomes before housing costs have been deducted. Source: Authors calculations using Family Expenditure Survey and Family Resources Survey, various years. ratio measures increased, as one would expect given the unambiguously inequalityincreasing pattern of income growth documented in Figure 3. The 99/50 ratio saw the fastest increase of all: income at the 99th percentile was three times the median in 1979, but more than five times the median by the early 1990s. Trends under Labour were much less dramatic. The 90/10 and the 50/10 ratio both hovered at around 4.0 and 2.0, respectively. This suggests little change in the gap between top and bottom incomes, or between middle and bottom incomes. Note, however, that the pattern of income growth by percentile shows a slight narrowing of the gap between the 20th (close to the relative poverty line) and 50th percentiles: this will be important for considering how relative poverty changed under Labour. The rise in the 99/50 ratio continued under Labour (particularly in the late 1990s and the late 2000s). By 2009/10, the gap between the very top and the middle had reached its highest level for at least 50 years. There was then a slight dip in 2010/11. As discussed, the extent to which this just reflects the temporary effects of income forestalling in response to tax changes is highly uncertain. In summary, we saw a small increase in overall measures of income inequality during Labour s period in office. Following on from much larger increases that occurred during the 1980s, income inequality thus remained at historically high levels. This seems to have been driven largely by income trends at the very top: inequality actually declined a little within the middle chunk of the distribution. Labour left office towards the beginning of 2010/11, during which there were large real reductions in household incomes, reflecting the delayed effects of the recession. Those income reductions were also inequality-reducing, with larger falls in income higher up the distribution.

11 188 Robert Joyce and Luke Sibieta (ii) Drivers of income inequality under Labour Given that Labour s tax and benefit reforms tended to benefit poorer households by proportionately far more than richer ones (Browne and Phillips, 2010), it might seem surprising that overall income inequality did not fall over Labour s tenure. But, as in the period of Conservative government between 1979 and 1997, there were other changes acting to increase the level of inequality in private incomes. Labour s redistributive tax and benefit reforms were mitigating such changes, but were not able to offset them fully. What was driving increases in inequality? Brewer et al. (2009b) decompose changes in income inequality in Great Britain over recent decades and show that much of the overall rise in income inequality during the 1980s was driven by increased earnings inequality between workers, with increased wage gaps between education groups and occupations featuring particularly prominently. A variety of explanations for these kinds of trends have been proposed, both for the UK and elsewhere: skill-biased technological change (Katz and Murphy, 1992; Nickell and Bell, 1995; Katz and Autor, 1999); institutional factors such as the removal of wage/price controls and reduced trade union powers (Goodman and Shephard, 2002); and, at the household level, increased polarization between those that are work-rich and those that are workpoor (Gregg and Wadsworth, 2008). But the extent to which these factors also explain rising pre-transfer inequality under Labour is less clear. Machin (2002) argues that shifts in the relative demand for skilled workers were moderated from the 1990s onwards. There was no further major weakening of the power of trade unions or the scope of collective wage-bargaining. And there was some progress made under Labour in reducing the number of workless households, at least some of which can probably be attributed to welfare reform (see section IV). Crucially, we have already seen that the rise in income inequality under Labour was driven largely by trends in incomes right at the top of the distribution. An explanation of rising pre-tax income inequality under Labour should thus focus mostly on what happened among that relatively small group of people. It is useful to place trends in UK top incomes in an international context. Figure 6 illustrates the changes in the share of income of total income received by the top 1 per cent over time across G-7 countries (excluding Germany). This illustrates the fact that the share of income received by the top 1 per cent in the UK followed a similar pattern to that seen for Canada and the US, generally increasing over time. However, there have been much smaller increases over time in Italy and France. Atkinson et al. (2011) further analyse trends in top incomes over a very long time frame and across a wider range of countries. One of their key findings is that there is a set of countries in which top income shares have broadly followed a U-shaped pattern, with top income shares declining in the immediate post-war period before showing continuous increases from about 1979 onwards. This group includes the UK and a number of other Anglo-Saxon economies such as the USA, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand, as well as Sweden and Norway. They further show that a large part of these increases in top income shares can be accounted for by rising wage income. Other countries, largely those from continental Europe, have seen an L-shaped pattern, with little or no increase in top income shares in recent history. Atkinson et al. (2011) also discuss potential explanations for these trends, focusing on the roles of political economy, macroeconomics, global economic forces, and progressive taxation.

12 An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty 189 Figure 6: Top income shares across G7 countries, Note: Data for Germany are not shown as data are only available for a small number of years. Source: Data downloaded from World Top Incomes Database on 20 December 2012 ( Kaplan and Rauh (2010) attempt to distinguish which groups make up the top income groups in the USA over time and the likely explanations for these trends. They conclude that a large and increasing proportion of those with top incomes work in financial corporations. This stands in contrast to Dew-Becker and Gordon (2005), who suggest that the top income group is mostly made up of CEOs, celebrities, and athletes. Kaplan and Rauh (2010) also conclude that the most plausible driving forces behind the growth in top income shares are skill-biased technological change (Katz and Murphy, 1992), greater scale (Gabaix and Landier, 2008), and superstar effects (Rosen, 1981). The latter two explanations are strongly connected, with globalized markets and increased information flows allowing those at the top of their markets or fields to capture even greater returns. Such explanations have also been advanced by Feenberg and Poterba (1993) and Atkinson (2003). These explanations for rising top incomes seem plausible for the UK as well, and would be a very good candidate for further research. Brewer et al. (2008) show that a large proportion of those with the highest incomes in the UK work in the financial sector. Furthermore, they note a strong correlation between the performance of the stock market and the growth in top incomes. This is consummate with analysis by Stewart (2010) of trends in earnings inequality between 1970 and 2010, which finds that a large part of the increase in earnings inequality since the mid-1990s can be attributed to growing inequality within the financial sector and within London. Finally, it is important to note that we have focused on measures of inequality using snapshots of household incomes. To understand fully the implications of these changes for the scale of differences in household living standards, it is also helpful to consider

13 190 Robert Joyce and Luke Sibieta other measures of inequality, including those based on consumption or long-run measures of income. Blundell and Preston (1998) show that both consumption and income inequality increased during the 1980s, first reflecting mostly increases in permanent income inequality in the early 1980s and then increases in short-term income risks in the late 1980s. Blundell and Etheridge (2010) corroborate this view and show that the increase in income inequality during Labour s first term reflected an increase in permanent income inequality as well as a mild increase in short-term income volatility. Brewer and O Dea (2012) compare the evolution of consumption inequality, income inequality, and inequality in broad income (encompassing imputed income from housing and motor vehicles). Between 1997 and 2009, they show no change in either measure of income inequality, but a statistically significant decline in consumption inequality. Jenkins and Van Kerm (2011) use longitudinal data to follow the same individuals over time, rather than comparing quantiles of repeated cross-sections (the approach taken in this paper). They show that the poorest individuals at the start of Labour s period in office experienced the fastest growth of all over the period. This pattern which was particularly stark between 1998 and 2002, when poverty fell by the most. IV. Income poverty We now analyse trends in low incomes under Labour. In contrast to income inequality across the distribution as a whole, this is an area in which Labour had very clear distributional objectives, or at least a much stronger desire to change the distribution that it inherited. This is evident both from its tax and benefit policies (as we show here) and, in the case of child poverty, its explicitly defined targets: Labour aimed to halve incomebased child poverty measures between 1998/9 and 2010/11. The adoption of numerical child poverty targets was unusual in a European context only Ireland was earlier in adopting numerical poverty targets. The European Union has since adopted a target to reduce the number of people living below national poverty lines by 25 per cent by 2020, with individual targets for member states (EC, 2010). In the rest of this article, we document the trends in income poverty under Labour, before discussing the reasons for the changes observed. (i) What happened to poverty under Labour? We first document the key trends in measures of absolute and relative income poverty under Labour, and present the series back to 1979 for historical context. These measures indicate how the incomes of the poor developed in absolute terms and relative to median income. We focus on the standard measure of relative poverty used in the European Union (and, indeed, by the previous Labour governments), with a poverty line equal to 60 per cent of contemporary median income. To track trends in absolute poverty we fix the poverty line at 60 per cent of the 1998/9 median in real terms. Conceptually, the precise choice of absolute poverty line is arbitrary. We choose this one for its policy relevance, as it was the line used by the government to define its absolute child poverty target for 2010/11.

14 An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty 191 Figures 7 and 8 show that poverty among the whole population fell substantially under Labour. Relative poverty fell from about 20 per cent in 1997/8 to about 16 per cent in 2010/11. This ran contrary to the recent historical trend of for the most part rising relative poverty, although it had fallen for 3 consecutive years in the early 1990s. The rapidity of the decline in absolute poverty also compares favourably to recent history, with approximately a halving of the absolute poverty rate since 1997/8 (although it is striking how little of this reduction occurred in Labour s latter years, as discussed below). Both of these facts fit naturally with the analysis presented in the previous section: this showed that income growth under Labour tended to be higher towards the bottom of the income distribution (excluding the extreme tails), contrary to the pattern observed between 1979 and 1997/8; and that real income growth towards the bottom of the distribution was generally higher in absolute terms than it was over that prior period (while lower in the top half). The figures highlight two further points. First, the reductions in income poverty under Labour were not spread evenly throughout its period in office: a large majority of this reduction had already occurred by 2004/5, with relative and absolute poverty each falling by no more than 1 percentage point over the subsequent 6 years. The 3 years between 2004/5 and 2007/8, in particular, stand out from the rest of Labour s tenure as a period when poverty actually rose. As we shall see, in the case of child poverty these 3 years now look critical in accounting for the government s failure to meet its own 2010/11 targets. Figure 7: Relative poverty rates since 1979 Note: Years refer to calendar years up to 1993 and financial years thereafter. Poverty rates are measured as the percentage of the group with income below 60 per cent of the population-wide median. Incomes have been measured before housing costs have been deducted. Source: Authors calculations based on Family Expenditure Survey and Family Resources Survey, various years.

15 192 Robert Joyce and Luke Sibieta Figure 8: Absolute poverty rates since 1979 Note: Years refer to calendar years up to 1993 and financial years thereafter. Poverty rates are measured as the percentage of the group with income below 60 per cent of the 1997/8 population-wide median. Incomes have been measured before housing costs have been deducted. Source: Authors calculations based on Family Expenditure Survey and Family Resources Survey, various years. Second, there was much variation in low-income trends by demographic group. In particular, the headline trends in poverty both the overall reductions and the slowdown or stalling of those reductions in the mid-2000s were driven by pensioners and families with children. The rates of relative and absolute poverty among children fell by about one-quarter and one-half, respectively, between 1997/8 and 2004/5. In the case of absolute child poverty, this meant that the government had achieved its 2010/11 target level 6 years early. In the case of relative child poverty, it meant that it could have met its 2010/11 target by maintaining approximately the same rate of progress in the period after 2004/5. Rates of pensioner poverty also fell sharply. Absolute pensioner poverty halved between 1997/8 and 2010/11 (again, mostly because of progress up to and including 2004/5). It had also been falling over the preceding 18 years: new retirees typically have higher private incomes than the cohorts that preceded them they have both higher employment rates and higher private pension incomes so there is a tendency for the composition of the pensioner population to shift towards higher-income households over time (Brewer et al., 2007). But relative pensioner poverty also fell substantially, from 25 per cent in 1997/8 to 17 per cent in 2010/11; and the relatively sustained nature of these reductions in relative pensioner poverty, which occurred during times of both boom (the late 1990s/2000s) and bust (the late 2000s), differs markedly from recent history. Previously, low-income pensioners had consistently fallen further behind median income during economic booms and had caught up only when recessions hit. In stark contrast, low-income working-age adults without children fell further behind median income under Labour and their incomes did not change much even in absolute

16 An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty 193 terms, continuing the recent historical trend. Absolute poverty among the group fell by just 1.6 percentage points over the 13 years between 1997/8 and 2010/11; and their relative poverty rate rose from about 12 per cent to about 15 per cent over the same period. (ii) Reasons for changes in poverty under Labour What was driving the poverty trends discussed above? Figures 9 and 10 show the results of a counterfactual simulation exercise using TAXBEN, the Institute for Fiscal Studies s tax and benefit micro-simulation model. We hold the 2010/11 population constant but replace the 2010/11 personal tax and benefit system which determined net household incomes in 2010/11, given economic behaviour and demographic characteristics with unreformed systems from each year between 1997/8 and 2009/10. An unreformed system from a particular year is defined as the system as it would have been if nominal tax thresholds and benefit rates from April of that year had simply been uprated until April 2010, using the default indexation rules that Labour inherited (mostly price indexation). This allows us to uncover the direct impacts of direct tax and benefit reforms on income poverty for each year since 1997/8. (The first of Labour s reforms to direct taxes and benefits were in April 1998.) Note that this particular exercise holds behaviour constant (as it was in 2010/11), and so does not account for indirect effects of reforms via behavioural responses (e.g. labour supply changes, or rates of take-up of Figure 9: Effects of direct tax and benefit reforms under Labour on relative poverty rates Notes: Years refer to financial years. Poverty rates are measured as the percentage of the group with income below 60 per cent of the population-wide median. Incomes have been measured before housing costs have been deducted. Source: Authors calculations based on 2010/11 Family Resources Survey and assumptions specified in the text.

17 194 Robert Joyce and Luke Sibieta Figure 10: Effects of direct tax and benefit reforms under Labour on absolute poverty rates Notes: Years refer to financial years. Poverty rates are measured as the percentage of the group with income below 60 per cent of the 1997/8 population-wide median. Incomes have been measured before housing costs have been deducted. Source: Authors calculations based on 2010/11 Family Resources Survey and assumptions specified in the text. means-tested support 5 ). Evidence on the effects on poverty of labour supply responses to these reforms is discussed separately below. But it is clear from the figures that the direct effects of the reforms alone are extremely powerful in explaining movements in income poverty over the period. The figures highlight that children and pensioners, the major demographic groups which experienced large reductions in poverty risk under Labour, were also the groups clearly favoured by Labour s reforms to the direct tax and benefit system. In fact, without those reforms the simulations suggest that absolute child poverty would have stayed approximately at its 1997/8 level, and that relative child poverty would have continued to increase as low-income households with children would have fallen further behind the median (this is evident by comparing actual poverty levels in 1997/8 with their simulated 2010/11 levels under an unreformed 1997/8 tax and benefit system). Low-income pensioners would have improved their position in absolute terms even without these reforms most likely due to the continuing cohort effects described above but by far 5 The simulations do allow for non-take-up. Those simulated as entitled to a benefit or tax credit in 2010/11 but who did not report receiving it are assumed not to take up that benefit under any other tax and benefit system either. For Family Credit and Working Families Tax Credit, which existed in previous years but not in 2010/11, we have to make assumptions about which eligible people would take up entitlements to them if they still existed in 2010/11. To do this, we randomize non-take-up using official estimates of the takeup rates of these payments, disaggregated by family type, for the last full financial year in which they existed (DWP, 2000; Inland Revenue, 2005).

18 An assessment of Labour s record on income inequality and poverty 195 less than their position actually did improve; and relative pensioner poverty would have stayed approximately flat. Which specific reforms are important in driving the patterns visible in Figures 9 and 10? Low-income households with children benefitted, in particular, from increases in Income Support and the inception and subsequent expansion of the tax credit system, with the introduction of Working Families Tax Credit (WFTC) in autumn 1999 to replace its smaller-scale forebear Family Credit, and then WFTC s own replacement with the current system of Child Tax Credit and Working Tax Credit in April By 2010/11, 25 billion per year was spent on tax credits, most of which went to low-income households with children. Low-income pensioners gained, in particular, from the introduction of the Minimum Income Guarantee in 1999 and its subsequent replacement, Pension Credit, in October 2003 (both of which were increased in real terms year-on-year in line with average earnings), and Winter Fuel Payments in Overall, reforms between 1997 and 2010 amounted to an 18 billion annual increase in spending on benefits for families with children and an 11 billion annual increase in spending on benefits for pensioners (Browne and Phillips, 2010). On an entitlements and liabilities basis, the poorest half of children were about 4,390 (28 per cent) better off in terms of annual net household income in 2010/11 than they would have been under an unreformed 1997/8 direct tax and benefit system; and the corresponding annual gain for the poorest half of pensioners was about 1,970 (19 per cent). (Note that not everyone actually claims what they are entitled to, and this non-take-up is accounted for in the modelling underlying Figures 9 and 10.) The increase in the generosity of state support for low-income families with children and pensioners stands in stark contrast to the lack of priority in this area attached to the childless working-age population. Indeed, direct tax and benefit reforms under Labour had almost no net impact on poverty rates among that group. This is arguably unsurprising given budgetary and political constraints, increases in welfare of the scale of those that benefitted mainly pensioners and families with children could perhaps not realistically have been implemented for everyone. It is striking that the low-income demographic group whose real entitlements to state benefits were not substantially increased under Labour also experienced such little real income growth over the period. And the period in which tax and benefit reforms did little or nothing to reduce income poverty more generally between 2004/5 and 2007/8 was the period in which poverty stopped falling, and, indeed, rose slightly. Both of these facts are evidence that poverty reduction under Labour was heavily dependent on the direct impacts of reforms to taxes and benefits. Tax and benefit reforms were not the only thing contributing to poverty reduction: changing work patterns also played a role. To show this, Table 2 presents a simple but revealing analysis looking in more detail at the fall in child poverty. The table decomposes the overall reduction in relative child poverty into the effects of changes in poverty risk for different groups of children ( incidence effects ), and changes in the relative sizes of those groups ( compositional effects ). Groups are defined according to family type and parental work status. The compositional effects show that changes in work patterns were a poverty-reducing factor. Reductions in the proportion of children living in workless families (a performance indicator that the government was tracking) both in lone parent and couple families acted to reduce relative child poverty by about 2 percentage points. There is good evidence that this was at least partly a result of government policy. In particular, the introduction of WFTC in October 1999 strengthened

Poverty and income inequality

Poverty and income inequality Poverty and income inequality Jonathan Cribb Public Economics Lectures, Institute for Fiscal Studies 17 th December 2012 Overview The standard of living in the UK Income Inequality The UK income distribution

More information

Public Economics: Poverty and Inequality

Public Economics: Poverty and Inequality Public Economics: Poverty and Inequality Andrew Hood Overview Why do we use income? Income Inequality The UK income distribution Measures of income inequality Explaining changes in income inequality Income

More information

Living standards during the recession

Living standards during the recession Living standards during the recession IFS Briefing Note 117 James Browne 1. Introduction Living standards during the recession James Browne Institute for Fiscal Studies 1 We are used to our incomes rising

More information

IFS. Poverty and Inequality in Britain: The Institute for Fiscal Studies. Mike Brewer Alissa Goodman Jonathan Shaw Andrew Shephard

IFS. Poverty and Inequality in Britain: The Institute for Fiscal Studies. Mike Brewer Alissa Goodman Jonathan Shaw Andrew Shephard IFS Poverty and Inequality in Britain: 2005 Mike Brewer Alissa Goodman Jonathan Shaw Andrew Shephard The Institute for Fiscal Studies Commentary No. 99 Poverty and Inequality in Britain: 2005 Mike Brewer

More information

Living standards, poverty and inequality in the UK: Jonathan Cribb Agnes Norris Keiller Tom Waters

Living standards, poverty and inequality in the UK: Jonathan Cribb Agnes Norris Keiller Tom Waters Living standards, poverty and inequality in the UK: 2018 Jonathan Cribb Agnes Norris Keiller Tom Waters Living standards, poverty and inequality in the UK: 2018 Jonathan Cribb Agnes Norris Keiller Tom

More information

Public economics: Inequality and Poverty

Public economics: Inequality and Poverty Public economics: Inequality and Poverty Chris Belfield Overview Measuring living standards Why do we use income? Accounting for inflation and family composition Income Inequality The UK income distribution

More information

Poverty and Inequality in the UK: 2010

Poverty and Inequality in the UK: 2010 Poverty and Inequality in the UK: 2010 Robert Joyce Alastair Muriel David Phillips Luke Sibieta Institute for Fiscal Studies Copy-edited by Judith Payne The Institute for Fiscal Studies 7 Ridgmount Street

More information

Living Standards: Recent Trends and Future Challenges

Living Standards: Recent Trends and Future Challenges Living Standards: Recent Trends and Future Challenges IFS Briefing Note BN165 IFS election analysis: funded by the Nuffield Foundation Jonathan Cribb Andrew Hood Robert Joyce Election 2015: Briefing Note

More information

Recessions, income inequality and the role of the tax and benefit system. Jonathan Cribb Andrew Hood Robert Joyce

Recessions, income inequality and the role of the tax and benefit system. Jonathan Cribb Andrew Hood Robert Joyce Recessions, income inequality and the role of the tax and benefit system Jonathan Cribb Andrew Hood Robert Joyce Recessions, income inequality and the role of the tax and benefit system Jonathan Cribb

More information

The Short- and Medium-Term Impacts of the Recession on the UK Income Distribution*

The Short- and Medium-Term Impacts of the Recession on the UK Income Distribution* FISCAL STUDIES, vol. 34, no. 2, pp. 179 201 (2013) 0143-5671 The Short- and Medium-Term Impacts of the Recession on the UK Income Distribution* MIKE BREWER, JAMES BROWNE, ANDREW HOOD, ROBERT JOYCE and

More information

Public economics: inequality and poverty

Public economics: inequality and poverty Agnes Norris Keiller agnes_nk@ifs.org.uk 1961 1964 1967 1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 Real median income (2007 08 = 100) Average income at an all-time

More information

Child and working-age poverty in Northern Ireland over the next decade: an update

Child and working-age poverty in Northern Ireland over the next decade: an update Child and working-age poverty in Northern Ireland over the next decade: an update IFS Briefing Note BN144 James Browne Andrew Hood Robert Joyce Child and working-age poverty in Northern Ireland over the

More information

Public economics: Income Inequality

Public economics: Income Inequality Public economics: Income Inequality Chris Belfield Overview Measuring living standards Why do we use income? Accounting for inflation and family composition Income Inequality The UK income distribution

More information

The 30 years between 1977 and 2007

The 30 years between 1977 and 2007 Economic & Labour Market Review Vol 2 No 12 December 28 FEATURE Francis Jones, Daniel Annan and Saef Shah The distribution of household income 1977 to 26/7 SUMMARY This article describes how the distribution

More information

INEQUALITY UNDER THE LABOUR GOVERNMENT

INEQUALITY UNDER THE LABOUR GOVERNMENT INEQUALITY UNDER THE LABOUR GOVERNMENT Andrew Shephard THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES Briefing Note No. 33 Income Inequality under the Labour Government Andrew Shephard a.shephard@ifs.org.uk Institute

More information

Poverty and Income Inequality in Scotland: 2013/14 A National Statistics publication for Scotland

Poverty and Income Inequality in Scotland: 2013/14 A National Statistics publication for Scotland Poverty and Income Inequality in Scotland: 2013/14 A National Statistics publication for Scotland EQUALITY, POVERTY AND SOCIAL SECURITY This publication presents annual estimates of the percentage and

More information

Incomes and inequality: the last decade and the next parliament

Incomes and inequality: the last decade and the next parliament Incomes and inequality: the last decade and the next parliament IFS Briefing Note BN202 Andrew Hood and Tom Waters Incomes and inequality: the last decade and the next parliament Andrew Hood and Tom Waters

More information

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis IFS Briefing Note 118 James Browne The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis 1. Introduction 1 James Browne Institute

More information

MONITORING POVERTY AND SOCIAL EXCLUSION 2013

MONITORING POVERTY AND SOCIAL EXCLUSION 2013 MONITORING POVERTY AND SOCIAL EXCLUSION 213 The latest annual report from the New Policy Institute brings together the most recent data to present a comprehensive picture of poverty in the UK. Key points

More information

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations IFS Briefing Note BN192 Andrew Hood Robert Joyce Andrew Hood Robert Joyce Copy-edited by Judith Payne Published by The Institute for Fiscal Studies

More information

STATE PENSIONS AND THE WELL-BEING OF

STATE PENSIONS AND THE WELL-BEING OF STATE PENSIONS AND THE WELL-BEING OF THE ELDERLY IN THE UK James Banks Richard Blundell Carl Emmerson Zoë Oldfield THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES WP06/14 State Pensions and the Well-Being of the Elderly

More information

EC3311. Seminar 2. ² Explain how employment rates have changed over time for married/cohabiting mothers and for lone mothers respectively.

EC3311. Seminar 2. ² Explain how employment rates have changed over time for married/cohabiting mothers and for lone mothers respectively. EC3311 Seminar 2 Part A: Review questions 1. What do we mean when we say that both consumption and leisure are normal goods. 2. Explain why the slope of the individual s budget constraint is equal to w.

More information

Living standards, poverty and inequality in the UK: to Andrew Hood Tom Waters

Living standards, poverty and inequality in the UK: to Andrew Hood Tom Waters Living standards, poverty and inequality in the UK: 2017 18 to 2021 22 Andrew Hood Tom Waters Living standards, poverty and inequality in the UK: 2017 18 to 2021 22 Andrew Hood Tom Waters Copy-edited by

More information

Living Standards, Poverty and Inequality in the UK: to

Living Standards, Poverty and Inequality in the UK: to Living Standards, Poverty and Inequality in the UK: 2016 17 to 2021 22 Neil Andrew Amin Hood Smith, David Phillips, Tom Polly Waters Simpson Institute for Fiscal Studies David Eiser Fraser of Allander

More information

Basic income as a policy option: Technical Background Note Illustrating costs and distributional implications for selected countries

Basic income as a policy option: Technical Background Note Illustrating costs and distributional implications for selected countries May 2017 Basic income as a policy option: Technical Background Note Illustrating costs and distributional implications for selected countries May 2017 The concept of a Basic Income (BI), an unconditional

More information

THE IMPACT OF TAX AND BENEFIT CHANGES BETWEEN APRIL 2000 AND APRIL 2003 ON PARENTS LABOUR SUPPLY

THE IMPACT OF TAX AND BENEFIT CHANGES BETWEEN APRIL 2000 AND APRIL 2003 ON PARENTS LABOUR SUPPLY THE IMPACT OF TAX AND BENEFIT CHANGES BETWEEN APRIL 2000 AND APRIL 2003 ON PARENTS LABOUR SUPPLY Richard Blundell Mike Brewer Andrew Shepherd THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES Briefing Note No. 52 The Impact

More information

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY IN THE OECD AREA: TRENDS AND DRIVING FORCES

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY IN THE OECD AREA: TRENDS AND DRIVING FORCES OECD Economic Studies No. 34, 22/I INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY IN THE OECD AREA: TRENDS AND DRIVING FORCES Michael Förster and Mark Pearson TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction... 8 Main trends in the distribution

More information

Micro-simulating child poverty in 2010 and Mike Brewer, James Browne and Holly Sutherland

Micro-simulating child poverty in 2010 and Mike Brewer, James Browne and Holly Sutherland Micro-simulating child poverty in 2010 and 2020 Mike Brewer, James Browne and Holly Sutherland The Joseph Rowntree Foundation has supported this project as part of its programme of research and innovative

More information

Income Poverty. Chris Belfield 16 th July Institute for Fiscal Studies

Income Poverty. Chris Belfield 16 th July Institute for Fiscal Studies Income Poverty Chris Belfield 16 th July 2015 Outline Recent trends in income poverty how has poverty changed since the recession and why? how have different groups been affected? Relationship between

More information

The Links between Income Distribution and Poverty Reduction in Britain

The Links between Income Distribution and Poverty Reduction in Britain Human Development Report Office OCCASIONAL PAPER The Links between Income Distribution and Poverty Reduction in Britain Goodman, Alissa and Andrew Shephard. 2005. 2005/14 Child poverty and redistribution

More information

The impact in of the change to indexation policy

The impact in of the change to indexation policy The impact in 2012-13 of the change to indexation policy IFS Briefing Note 120 Robert Joyce Peter Levell The impact in 2012 13 of the change to indexation policy 1. Introduction 1 Robert Joyce and Peter

More information

Impact on households: distributional analysis to accompany Budget 2018

Impact on households: distributional analysis to accompany Budget 2018 Impact on households: distributional analysis to accompany Budget 2018 October 2018 Impact on households: distributional analysis to accompany Budget 2018 October 2018 Crown copyright 2018 This publication

More information

Maurizio Franzini and Mario Planta

Maurizio Franzini and Mario Planta Maurizio Franzini and Mario Planta 2 premises: 1. Inequality is a burning issue for economic, ethical and political reasons (Sen, Stiglitz, Piketty and many others ) 2. Inequality is today a more complex

More information

Poverty figures for London: 2010/11 Intelligence Update

Poverty figures for London: 2010/11 Intelligence Update Poverty figures for London: 2010/11 Intelligence Update 11-2012 Key points The number of Londoners living in poverty has seen little change. Children, particularly those in workless households, remain

More information

Effects of taxes and benefits on UK household income: financial year ending 2017

Effects of taxes and benefits on UK household income: financial year ending 2017 Statistical bulletin Effects of taxes and benefits on UK household income: financial year ending 2017 Analysis of how household incomes in the UK are affected by direct and indirect taxes and benefits

More information

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract CHAPTER 5 Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract The opportunities open to today s young people through their lifetimes will depend to a large extent on their prospects in employment and

More information

The Coalition s Record on Housing: Policy, Spending and Outcomes

The Coalition s Record on Housing: Policy, Spending and Outcomes Summary Working Paper 18 January 2015 The Coalition s Record on Housing: Policy, Spending and Outcomes 2010-2015 Rebecca Tunstall Coalition Ministers were highly critical of the state of UK housing when

More information

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates) Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates) Emmanuel Saez March 2, 2012 What s new for recent years? Great Recession 2007-2009 During the

More information

Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives Ontario August Losing Ground. Income Inequality in Ontario, Sheila Block

Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives Ontario August Losing Ground. Income Inequality in Ontario, Sheila Block Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives Ontario August 2017 Losing Ground Income Inequality in Ontario, 2000 15 Sheila Block www.policyalternatives.ca RESEARCH ANALYSIS SOLUTIONS About the authors Sheila

More information

Spring Statement 2018: The lost decade

Spring Statement 2018: The lost decade Thomas Pope Wednesday 14 th March 2018 2015-16 2016-17 2017-18 2018-19 2019-20 2020-21 2021-22 2022-23 2007 08 =100 Very small improvement in the growth forecast yesterday 120 118 116 114 112 110 108 106

More information

Structural Changes in the Maltese Economy

Structural Changes in the Maltese Economy Structural Changes in the Maltese Economy Dr. Aaron George Grech Modelling and Research Department, Central Bank of Malta, Castille Place, Valletta, Malta Email: grechga@centralbankmalta.org Doi:10.5901/mjss.2015.v6n5p423

More information

John Hills, Francesca Bastagli, Frank Cowell, Howard Glennerster, Eleni Karagiannaki and Abigail McKnight

John Hills, Francesca Bastagli, Frank Cowell, Howard Glennerster, Eleni Karagiannaki and Abigail McKnight CASEbrief 33 May 2013 Wealth distribution, accumulation, and policy John Hills, Francesca Bastagli, Frank Cowell, Howard Glennerster, Eleni Karagiannaki and Abigail McKnight Household wealth in Great Britain

More information

Trends in Retirement and in Working at Older Ages

Trends in Retirement and in Working at Older Ages Pensions at a Glance 211 Retirement-income Systems in OECD and G2 Countries OECD 211 I PART I Chapter 2 Trends in Retirement and in Working at Older Ages This chapter examines labour-market behaviour of

More information

Consumption Inequality in Canada, Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur

Consumption Inequality in Canada, Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur Consumption Inequality in Canada, 1997-2009 Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur Inequality has rightly been hailed as one of the major public policy challenges of the twenty-first century. In all member countries

More information

Labour Supply Estimation Project - Briefing Note

Labour Supply Estimation Project - Briefing Note Labour Supply Estimation Project - Briefing Note MODEL APPLICATION EMPLOYMENT EFFECTS OF REFORMS BETWEEN 1997-2002 Michal Myck and Howard Reed Crown Copyright 2005. This report has been co-financed by

More information

Household disposable income and inequality in the UK: financial year ending 2017

Household disposable income and inequality in the UK: financial year ending 2017 Statistical bulletin Household disposable income and inequality in the UK: financial year ending 2017 Initial insight into main estimates of household incomes and inequality in the UK, along with analysis

More information

Poverty. David Phillips, p, IFS May 21 st, Institute for Fiscal Studies

Poverty. David Phillips, p, IFS May 21 st, Institute for Fiscal Studies Poverty David Phillips, p, IFS May 21 st, 2010 Poverty: the story under Labour After poverty rose between 2004/5 and 2007/8 200,000000 for each of pensioners and children 200,000 for working age adults

More information

Britain s War on Poverty

Britain s War on Poverty Britain s War on Poverty Jane Waldfogel Presentation to OECD, The Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs July 8, 2010 In 1964 US President Lyndon Johnson declared war on poverty This administration,

More information

Economic Standard of Living

Economic Standard of Living DESIRED OUTCOMES New Zealand is a prosperous society, reflecting the value of both paid and unpaid work. Everybody has access to an adequate income and decent, affordable housing that meets their needs.

More information

Pensioners Incomes Series: An analysis of trends in Pensioner Incomes: 1994/ /16

Pensioners Incomes Series: An analysis of trends in Pensioner Incomes: 1994/ /16 Pensioners Incomes Series: An analysis of trends in Pensioner Incomes: 1994/95-215/16 Annual Financial year 215/16 Published: 16 March 217 United Kingdom This report examines how much money pensioners

More information

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM Revenue Summit 17 October 2018 The Australia Institute Patricia Apps The University of Sydney Law School, ANU, UTS and IZA ABSTRACT

More information

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take?

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take? Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take? September 2018 Prepared by the

More information

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments Address by Mr Ric Battellino, Deputy Governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia, at the Annual Stockbrokers Conference, Sydney, 26 May 2011. * * * Introduction

More information

Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals

Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals IFS Briefing Note BN209 Stuart Adam Andrew Hood Robert Joyce David Phillips Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals

More information

Redistribution via VAT and cash transfers: an assessment in four low and middle income countries

Redistribution via VAT and cash transfers: an assessment in four low and middle income countries Redistribution via VAT and cash transfers: an assessment in four low and middle income countries IFS Briefing note BN230 David Phillips Ross Warwick Funded by In partnership with Redistribution via VAT

More information

IFS. Options for a UK 'flat tax' Some simple simulations. The Institute for Fiscal Studies. Stuart Adam James Browne. IFS Briefing Note No.

IFS. Options for a UK 'flat tax' Some simple simulations. The Institute for Fiscal Studies. Stuart Adam James Browne. IFS Briefing Note No. IFS Options for a UK 'flat tax' Some simple simulations Stuart Adam James Browne The Institute for Fiscal Studies IFS Briefing Note No. 72 Options for a UK flat tax : some simple simulations Stuart Adam

More information

Monitoring poverty and social exclusion 2009

Monitoring poverty and social exclusion 2009 Monitoring poverty and social exclusion 29 December 29 Findings Informing change The New Policy Institute has produced its twelfth annual report of indicators of poverty and social exclusion in the United

More information

The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence from the UK

The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence from the UK Fiscal Studies (1996) vol. 17, no. 2, pp. 1-36 The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence from the UK SUSAN HARKNESS 1 I. INTRODUCTION Rising female labour-force participation has been one of the most striking

More information

The Impact of Austerity Measures on Households with Children

The Impact of Austerity Measures on Households with Children Families in an Age of Austerity: January 2012 The Impact of Austerity Measures on Households with Children Analysis by James Browne, Institute for Fiscal Studies Contents Foreword 3 Executive Summary 5

More information

The cost of a child in Donald Hirsch

The cost of a child in Donald Hirsch The cost of a child in 2013 Donald Hirsch August 2013 The cost of a child in 2013 Donald Hirsch August 2013 CPAG promotes action for the prevention and relief of poverty among children and families with

More information

Poverty. Chris Belfield, IFS 15 th July Institute for Fiscal Studies

Poverty. Chris Belfield, IFS 15 th July Institute for Fiscal Studies Poverty Chris Belfield, IFS 15 th July 2014 Outline Income based measures how has poverty changed since the recession and why? which groups have been affected by recent changes? Non-income based measures

More information

Economic Perspectives

Economic Perspectives Economic Perspectives What might slower economic growth in Scotland mean for Scotland s income tax revenues? David Eiser Fraser of Allander Institute Abstract Income tax revenues now account for over 40%

More information

Socio-economic Series Changes in Household Net Worth in Canada:

Socio-economic Series Changes in Household Net Worth in Canada: research highlight October 2010 Socio-economic Series 10-018 Changes in Household Net Worth in Canada: 1990-2009 introduction For many households, buying a home is the largest single purchase they will

More information

Inequality, poverty and the crisis in Greece

Inequality, poverty and the crisis in Greece Inequality, poverty and the crisis in Greece Manos Matsaganis & Chrysa Leventi Department of International and European Economics Athens University of Economics and Business ETUI Monthly Forum Brussels

More information

Distributive Impact of Low-Income Support Measures in Japan

Distributive Impact of Low-Income Support Measures in Japan Open Journal of Social Sciences, 2016, 4, 13-26 http://www.scirp.org/journal/jss ISSN Online: 2327-5960 ISSN Print: 2327-5952 Distributive Impact of Low-Income Support Measures in Japan Tetsuo Fukawa 1,2,3

More information

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM August 2015 151 Slater Street, Suite 710 Ottawa, Ontario K1P 5H3 Tel: 613-233-8891 Fax: 613-233-8250 csls@csls.ca CENTRE FOR THE STUDY OF LIVING STANDARDS SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING

More information

The distributional impact of the crisis in Greece

The distributional impact of the crisis in Greece The distributional impact of the crisis in Greece Manos Matsaganis & Chrysa Leventi Department of International and European Economics Athens University of Economics and Business EUROMOD Research workshop

More information

EMPLOYMENT EARNINGS INEQUALITY IN IRELAND 2006 TO 2010

EMPLOYMENT EARNINGS INEQUALITY IN IRELAND 2006 TO 2010 EMPLOYMENT EARNINGS INEQUALITY IN IRELAND 2006 TO 2010 Prepared in collaboration with publicpolicy.ie by: Nóirín McCarthy, Marie O Connor, Meadhbh Sherman and Declan Jordan School of Economics, University

More information

READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO

READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO 2050 Dreaming with BRICs: The Path to 2050, by Dominic Wilson and Roopa Purushothaman, reprinted from Global Economics Paper Number 99. Copyright 2003. Reprinted

More information

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2017 preliminary estimates)

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2017 preliminary estimates) Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2017 preliminary estimates) Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley October 13, 2018 What s new for recent years? 2016-2017: Robust

More information

Economic Standard of Living

Economic Standard of Living DESIRED OUTCOMES New Zealand is a prosperous society, reflecting the value of both paid and unpaid work. All people have access to adequate incomes and decent, affordable housing that meets their needs.

More information

Public Sector Statistics

Public Sector Statistics 3 Public Sector Statistics 3.1 Introduction In 1913 the Sixteenth Amendment to the US Constitution gave Congress the legal authority to tax income. In so doing, it made income taxation a permanent feature

More information

Prospects for the Social Safety Net for Future Low Income Seniors

Prospects for the Social Safety Net for Future Low Income Seniors Prospects for the Social Safety Net for Future Low Income Seniors Marilyn Moon American Institutes for Research Presented at Forgotten Americans: The Future of Support for Older Low-Income Adults National

More information

Gabriel Zucman. Inequality: Are we really 'all in this together'? #ElectionEconomics PAPER EA030

Gabriel Zucman. Inequality: Are we really 'all in this together'? #ElectionEconomics PAPER EA030 PAPER EA030 A series of background briefings on the policy issues in the May 2015 UK General Election Inequality: Are we really 'all in this together'? Gabriel Zucman #ElectionEconomics CEP ELECTION ANALYSIS

More information

Credit crunched: Single parents, universal credit and the struggle to make work pay

Credit crunched: Single parents, universal credit and the struggle to make work pay 1. Introduction Credit crunched: Single parents, universal credit and the struggle to make work pay Professor Mike Brewer, Dr Paola DeAgostini Institute of Social and Economic Research, Essex University

More information

Poverty, inequality and policy since 1997

Poverty, inequality and policy since 1997 Poverty, inequality and policy since 1997 February 2009 Findings Informing change This study examines what has happened to different aspects of inequality in Britain, and how this relates to policies adopted

More information

Potential Output in Denmark

Potential Output in Denmark 43 Potential Output in Denmark Asger Lau Andersen and Morten Hedegaard Rasmussen, Economics 1 INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY The concepts of potential output and output gap are among the most widely used concepts

More information

Department of Quantitative Social Science. The impact of the Great Recession on the incomes of households. John Micklewright

Department of Quantitative Social Science. The impact of the Great Recession on the incomes of households. John Micklewright Department of Quantitative Social Science The impact of the Great Recession on the incomes of households John Micklewright DoQSS Working Paper No. 12-07 October 2012 Disclaimer Any opinions expressed here

More information

Using the British Household Panel Survey to explore changes in housing tenure in England

Using the British Household Panel Survey to explore changes in housing tenure in England Using the British Household Panel Survey to explore changes in housing tenure in England Tom Sefton Contents Data...1 Results...2 Tables...6 CASE/117 February 2007 Centre for Analysis of Exclusion London

More information

POLICY BRIEFING. ! Institute for Fiscal Studies 2015 Green Budget

POLICY BRIEFING. ! Institute for Fiscal Studies 2015 Green Budget Institute for Fiscal Studies 2015 Green Budget 1 March 2015 Mark Upton, LGIU Associate Summary This briefing is a summary of the key relevant themes in the Institute of Fiscal Studies 2015 Green Budget

More information

Redistribution from a Lifetime Perspective

Redistribution from a Lifetime Perspective Redistribution from a Lifetime Perspective IFS Working Paper W15/27 Peter Levell Barra Roantree Jonathan Shaw Redistribution from a Lifetime Perspective Peter Levell, Institute for Fiscal Studies and University

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 2013-38 December 23, 2013 Labor Markets in the Global Financial Crisis BY MARY C. DALY, JOHN FERNALD, ÒSCAR JORDÀ, AND FERNANDA NECHIO The impact of the global financial crisis on

More information

2.5. Income inequality in France

2.5. Income inequality in France 2.5 Income inequality in France Information in this chapter is based on Income Inequality in France, 1900 2014: Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA), by Bertrand Garbinti, Jonathan Goupille-Lebret

More information

Women Leading UK Employment Boom

Women Leading UK Employment Boom Briefing Paper Feb 2018 Women Leading UK Employment Boom Published by The Institute for New Economic Thinking, University of Oxford Women Leading UK Employment Boom Summary Matteo Richiardi a, Brian Nolan

More information

Economic Standard of Living

Economic Standard of Living DESIRED OUTCOMES New Zealand is a prosperous society, reflecting the value of both paid and unpaid work. All people have access to adequate incomes and decent, affordable housing that meets their needs.

More information

Household Income Distribution and Working Time Patterns. An International Comparison

Household Income Distribution and Working Time Patterns. An International Comparison Household Income Distribution and Working Time Patterns. An International Comparison September 1998 D. Anxo & L. Flood Centre for European Labour Market Studies Department of Economics Göteborg University.

More information

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study 47 Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study Jacob Isaksen, Paul Lassenius Kramp, Louise Funch Sørensen and Søren Vester Sørensen, Economics INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY What are the

More information

The Political Economy of Tax Reform

The Political Economy of Tax Reform ECFIN Annual Tax Workshop, 19 October 2015 The University College London and Institute for Fiscal Studies @IanPPreston @EconUCL @TheIFS (drawing on joint work with James Alt and Luke Sibieta) 1 The Need

More information

Structural changes in the Maltese economy

Structural changes in the Maltese economy Structural changes in the Maltese economy Article published in the Annual Report 2014, pp. 72-76 BOX 4: STRUCTURAL CHANGES IN THE MALTESE ECONOMY 1 Since the global recession that took hold around the

More information

Neoliberalism, Investment and Growth in Latin America

Neoliberalism, Investment and Growth in Latin America Neoliberalism, Investment and Growth in Latin America Jayati Ghosh and C.P. Chandrasekhar Despite the relatively poor growth record of the era of corporate globalisation, there are many who continue to

More information

According to the life cycle theory, households take. Do wealth inequalities have an impact on consumption? 1

According to the life cycle theory, households take. Do wealth inequalities have an impact on consumption? 1 Do wealth inequalities have an impact on consumption? Frédérique SAVIGNAC Microeconomic and Structural Analysis Directorate The ideas presented in this article reflect the personal opinions of their authors

More information

Ireland's Income Distribution

Ireland's Income Distribution Ireland's Income Distribution Micheál L. Collins Introduction Judged in an international context, Ireland is a high income country. The 2014 United Nations Human Development Report ranks Ireland as having

More information

Institute for Fiscal Studies Analysis of the Autumn Statement 2011 and the OBR Economic and Fiscal Outlook. Opening remarks.

Institute for Fiscal Studies Analysis of the Autumn Statement 2011 and the OBR Economic and Fiscal Outlook. Opening remarks. Opening remarks Paul Johnson Downward revisions in the outlook for tax revenues, fiscal rules expected to be met by the merest whisker, investment spending plans being cumulated over several years, a complex

More information

Trends in Income Inequality in Ireland

Trends in Income Inequality in Ireland Trends in Income Inequality in Ireland Brian Nolan CPA, March 06 What Happened to Income Inequality? Key issue: what happened to the income distribution in the economic boom Widely thought that inequality

More information

INEQUALITY AND LIVING STANDARDS IN GREAT BRITAIN: SOME FACTS

INEQUALITY AND LIVING STANDARDS IN GREAT BRITAIN: SOME FACTS INEQUALITY AND LIVING STANDARDS IN GREAT BRITAIN: SOME FACTS Alissa Goodman Andrew Shephard THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES Briefing Note No. 19 INEQUALITY AND LIVING STANDARDS IN GREAT BRITAIN: SOME

More information

Health Insurance Coverage in 2013: Gains in Public Coverage Continue to Offset Loss of Private Insurance

Health Insurance Coverage in 2013: Gains in Public Coverage Continue to Offset Loss of Private Insurance Health Insurance Coverage in 2013: Gains in Public Coverage Continue to Offset Loss of Private Insurance Laura Skopec, John Holahan, and Megan McGrath Since the Great Recession peaked in 2010, the economic

More information

Economic Standard of Living

Economic Standard of Living DESIRED OUTCOMES New Zealand is a prosperous society where all people have access to adequate incomes and enjoy standards of living that mean they can fully participate in society and have choice about

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

Australian welfare spending trends: past changes and future drivers Brotherhood of St Laurence lunchtime seminar

Australian welfare spending trends: past changes and future drivers Brotherhood of St Laurence lunchtime seminar Australian welfare spending trends: past changes and future drivers Brotherhood of St Laurence lunchtime seminar John Daley CEO, Grattan Institute 8 August 213 Overview Stable overall spending conceals

More information

Distributional Implications of the Welfare State

Distributional Implications of the Welfare State Agenda, Volume 10, Number 2, 2003, pages 99-112 Distributional Implications of the Welfare State James Cox This paper is concerned with the effect of the welfare state in redistributing income away from

More information