Macroeconomic Performance Before and After Disinflation in Israel

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Macroeconomic Performance Before and After Disinflation in Israel"

Transcription

1 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized FPollcy, Planning, and Research WORKING PAPERS Macroeconomic Adjustment and Growth Country Economics Department The World Bank November 1989 WPS 311 Macroeconomic Performance Before and After Disinflation in Israel Leonardo Leiderman and Nissan Liviatan Israel's successful 1985 stabilization program brought sharp, immediate disinflation, a private consumption boom, increased economic activity, relatively high real wages and interest rates, and a low (appreciated) exchange rate. Only in the fourth year did th.- boom stop and unemployment rise. What lessens from that experience can be applied elsewhere? The Policy, Planning, and Reseatch Complex distributes PPR Working Papers to dissanunate the findings of work in progrcss and Lo encourage the exchange of ideas among Bank staff and all others intercsted in development issues. These papers carry the names of the authors, reflect only their vic%s, and should he used and cited accordingly 'Mc findings, unterpretauons, and conclusions are the authors own. They should not be attsnbuted to the World l3ank, its Board of Directos, its management, or any of its mcmbercountries.

2 Plc,Plannlng, and Research Mcocnomic Adjustment and Growth The Israeli stabilization program of 198S is but will allow an increase in long-term growth generally considered one of the most successful after adjustment is completed. such programs in years. Under it, the inflation rate plummeted from about 400 percent a year to What implications does the Israeli program about percent a year. - a laboratory experiment in heterodox policy - have for the debate about gradualism versus Leiderman and Liviatan examined how shock treatment in the process of stabilization? stabilization affected other key economic variables after They were particularly In reducing inflation, the program seems to struck by the immediate, abrupt reduction in the have had the same effectiveness as other shock rate of inflation and the timing and impact of treatment programs: there was a sharp and disinflation on other real variables. immediate disinflation. This was probably because multiple nominal targets (such as a For more than two years after the program, a fixed exchange rate and price-wage controls) private consumption boom was accompanied by were used in conjunction with adjustments in increased economic activity, relatively high real fundamentals, right from the start. This mix wages and real interest rates, and a low (appreci- makes the pro-ram heterodox. ated) real exchange rate. In terms of the real costs of disinflation, the Only in the beginning of the fourth year program may seem more gradualist. The real after t1.e program did the consumption boom costs, in terms of increased unemployment, were stop, economic activity become stagnant, and postponed for several years and in the transition the rate of unemployment rise. there was actually a boom in economic activity. The consumption boom seems closely related to the possibility that the program and the fixed exchange rate policy partially lacked credibility. Apparently the pubiic perceived the changes as mainly temporary. The recent rise in unemployment seems largely to reflect the beginning of a process of structural adjustment whereby resources are reallocated across the economy to conform to the new low inflation equilibrium. This process may involve less growth in the transitional stage Which of these results are peculiar to Israel and which are common to heterodox policies generally is a question worth addressing. Method: Using simple times series techniques applied to monthly data for , Leiderman and Liviatan investigated changes in the time series properties of key macroeconomic variables in 1985 and after. They focused especially on changes in the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. This paper is a product of the Macroeconomic Adjustment and Growth Division, Country Economics Department. Copies are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC Please contact Raquel Luz, room N , extension (56 pages with figures and tables). The PPR Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work under way in the Bank's Policy, Planning, and Research C'- nplex. An objective of the series is to get these findings out quickly, even if presentations are less than fully polished. Tnte findings, interpretations, and conclusions in thesc papers do not necessarily represent offici.l policy of the Bank. Produced at the PPR Dissemination Center

3 A OP OFCOMM I. Introduction 1 II. The Change in Regimes Facts and Models 3 A. Some Facts 4 B. Models 6 III. Times Seiies Evidence and Comparisons 10 A. Summary Statistics 10 B. Responses to Shocks 16 C. Cross-Sectional Variabilities 20 D. Persistence of Fluctuations 21 E. Relating the Findings to the Models 23 IV. The Changing of the Nature Inflation/Unemployment Tradeoff 25 A. The High Inflation Period 26 B. The Post Stabilization Period 29 C. The Tradeoff in the Transition 29 V. Conclusions 34 VI. References 36 The authors would like to thank Plhanan Uelpman, Miguel Kiguel, and. participants at a World Bank seminar for their comments and suggestions. This paper is part of World Bank RPO

4 1 I. INTRODUCTION The Israeli stabilization program of 1985 is generally considered as one of the most successful programs of recent years, in that it rapidly disinflated the economy from inflation rates of about 400 percent per year to rates between percent per year. While much attention has been devoted to the heterodox components of the program and their analytical foundations, 1 relatively little work has been done quantitatively comparing the structure and performance of the macroeconomy before and after the program. Yet, such a comparison can be regarded as a key ingredient in an overall evaluation of the pros and cons of programs such as that of Israel. Accordingly, the main objective of this paper is to examine how macroeconomic performance has changed after the implementation of the stabilization program and to determine whether these changes conform with the predictions of standard macroeconomic models. We investigate, using simple time series techniques applied to monthly data for , the changes that have taken place in the time series properties of key macroeconomic variables after the stab4iization program of Special attention is given to changes in the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment which are apparent after the program. The notion that a change in the policy regime should cause changes in the relationships among macroeconomic variables is quite familiar since Lucas' (1976) critique. We focus here on some of the empirical implications of this critique. Comparing policy regimes before and after 1985 suggests that the post-program regime is characterized by a tight fiscal policy, and by a 1 See, (.g., Blejer and Liviatan (1987), Bruno (1986), Bruno and Piterman (1988), Fischer (1987), Helpman and Leiderman (1988), Kiguel and L'viatan (1988), and Liviatan (1989).

5 sharp decrease in the degree of exchange rate accomodation as reflected in the fixing of the exchange rate, which was viewed as the main anchor for the 2 nominal system. For other nominal variables it is less clear whether and how their rules of behavior have changed after the program. Prices of controlled goods and services were periodically adjusted to changes in the rate of inflation. Monetary policy was mainly conducted so as to provide indirect support for the exchange rate anchor and it did not target directly monetary aggregates such as Ml or M2. Wage policy resulted in slow transition of COLA and of other institutional features of the wage setting process toward a low inflation position. The upshot of this discussion for the analysis that follows is that it seems plausible to hypothesize that the program brought a decrease in the degree of accommodation of nominal policy variables, effected mainly through a decrease in exchange rate accommodation. Policy regime changes such as the above can be expected to have affected relations between key macro variables. First, less accommodative exchange rate and nominal policies can cause changes in the form of the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. Second, these less accommodative policies are likely to result in changes in the persistence (or inertia) of inflation and other nominal variables. Third, to the extent that after the program there is a more dominant role of real shocks relative to nominal shocks, as it is likely to be the case given the less active role of nominal policy variables after the program, it is likely that there would be changes in the relations between variabilities of relative prices, relative wages, and relative outputs across sectors in the economy. Moreover, this enhanced importance of real vs. nominal shocks can, by itself, result in changes in the form of the inflation/unemploymentradeoff. Fourth, lack of credibility of

6 3 the new policies can result in high real wages, high real interest rates, and a consumption boom at the start of the stabilization program and thus importantly affect the transition of the economy to its new equilibrium. Identifying these types of changes in macroeconomic performance is the focal point of this research. The paper is organized as follows. Section II briefly describes the main changes in the behavior of nominal policy variables brought about by the stabilization program. It also discusses the predictions of standard macro models tor the likely impact of these changes on the economy. Sectijn III provides evidence on macroeconomic performance in the Israeli economy before and after the disinflation program. We investigate and interpret the time serias behavior of key macro variables and characterize their changes in terms of means, standard deviations, correlations, responses to shocks, and degree of persistence. We also examine changes in the co-movements of cross sectional variabilities of relative prices, wages, and outputs. Changes in the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment (Phillips curve) are discussed and analyzed in section IV. Section V concludes the paper. II. THE CHANGE IN REGIME: FACTS AND MODELS We begin this section by describing briefly the main nominal policy rule changes brought about by the 1985 program. Later on, we turn to a discussion of standard macroeconomic models in order to get analytical guidance as to what to expec. when comparing the Israeli economy before and after the program.

7 4 A. Some Facts Since the Israeli program has been described in detail elsewhere (see Fn.l on page 1), we focus here briefly on its main aspects that are relevant for analysis of the effects of changes in the rules governing the evolution of nominal policy variables. Comparing the policy regimes before and after the program suggests that there were at least five main changes brought about by the disinflation program. First, there was a fiscal contraction as the public sector sharply reduced its fiscal deficit by about 9 2 of GNP. About half of this reduction was effected by a decrease in public sector consumption and the remaining half by increasing taxes. Second, the government adopted a fixed exchange rate regime. 2 Fixing the exchange rate was conceived as a key element in anchoring the nominal system at a low inflation equilibrium. The Israeli Shekel was initially pegged to the U.S. dollar, but later on (August 1986) the pegging was done relative to a basket of foreign currencies. 3 Thus, the authorities abandoned the previous policy of using devaluations in a one-sided manner to affect real wages and external balance, and adopted the view that further changes in exchange rate policy would have to reflect cooperative agre-ments between government, labor, and employers. It is in this spirit that the devaluations of January 1987 and of December/January 1988/89 have to be interpreted. Since the fixed exchange rate policy, coupled with other internal aad external developments, resulted in marked real appreciation trends of real exchange rates, it was changed early in 1989 toward more flexibility. That is, the 2 The shekel was devalued by 102 in January 1987 and by 132 in January Since the latter date the exchange rate is targeted within a band of +3X. 3 This was facilitated by a 1.5 billion US$ grant from the U.S. government

8 exchange rate is being targeted now within a relatively fixed band rather than at a specific fixed race. Third, there have been changes in wvrge policy toward disinflation. It appeare that after the program there was an increase in the importance and length of nominal contracts and an increase in the fraction of wage changes that are due to agreements at the company or plant level as opposed to centralized collective agreements. 4 Of special interest in this context is the evolution of the cost of living agreement (COLA). COLA's structure has been gradually changed so that the trigger level of inflation (for actual payment of indexation) has been raised and the frequency of COLA payments has been reduced. The agreement reached in February 1989 stipulates wage indexation payments once every six months (and not every three months as before), at a rate of 85 percent of the excess of the inflation rate beyond 3 percent during these six months. Though these changes represent important adjustments in the transition to a low inflation economy, one can certainly question why progress in this direction has been relatively slow in the face of the fast disinflation that took place and whether the present agreement is indeed appropriate under the current rates of inflation of less than 20Z per year. The slow adjustment of COLA's structure may well reflect partial lack of credibility of the stabilization program. Fourth, there was a shift to a tight monetary policy. Immediately after the program the monetary authority targeted commercial bank credit to the pri-vate sector, which was considered as an additional nominal anchor. Later on, there was a shift toward targeting real M3 with a view toward the economy's international reserves' position. In addition, real interest rates 4 For a detailed discussion, see Artstein and Sussman (1988).

9 were kept high to affect the current account and the state of aggregate 6 demand. Obviously, some of the observed increases in MI and other shekeldenominated assets capture the effects of disinflation on the composition of private portfolios. Fifth, in Israel government directly determines prices of goods and services whose weight in the consumer price index is of about percent; e.g., prices of public transportation, gasoline, and basic foodstuff. Given the sizable weight of these controlled prices, and their importance in government (subsidies) budget, the stabilization program stipulated a government policy of changing them at a rate compatible with the attempted low inflation. Overall, the policy regime after the program features a decrease in the degree of exchange rate accommodation. This decrease was supported by a tight fiscal policy. Whethez and how the degree of accommodation of other nominal policy variables changed after the program remains Rs an open queption. B. Models What are the possible implications of these facts for macroeconomic performance? Here we attempt to answer this question in the light of two classes of standard macro modelss contracting models and imperfect information models. 5 i. Contracting Models Models of the Fischer (1977)-Taylor(1979) variety emphasize the role of contractual rigidities in generating real costs of disinflation. In S We do not examine here the more recent real business cycle approach because its implications for short run impacts of stabilization policies remain yet to be analyzed.

10 7 particular, the models posit a nonstate contingent structure of overlapping multi-period wage contracts. As a result, ending inflation is generally costly (in terms of unemployment) because firms and workers are locked into long term nominal contracts that were negotiated on the basis of price and wage expectations formed in the past. 6 A tradeoff between the variance of inflation and the variance of output arises from these frameworks. In these models, the degree of accommodation of nominal policy variables plays a key role in determining the shape of this tradeoff between output and inflation variabilities. For example, high monetary accommodation to nominal wage shocks generally results in higher output stability but at the cost of generating higher price instability. To sharpen the discussion, consider the impacts of a decrease in the degree of nominal exchange rate accommodation in the context of Dornbusch's (1982) open economy analysis of contracting models. The exchange rate is postulated to affect both demand and supply sides of the macroeconomy, and some of the results are ambiguous depending on the relative strength of these two effects. The analysis indicates that a decrease in exchange rate accommodation lowers the variability of prices and has ambiguous effects on the variability of output. The latter is decreased when the cost channel of exchange rates dominates, but it is increased if the aggregate demand role of the real exchange rate dominates. To the extent that the move toward lower exchange rate accommodation is accompanied by decreased monetary accommodation, there is a fu:rther decrease in price variability and a 6 This class of models implies that there can be a costless di.inflation only if there is a gradual tightening of fiscal and monetary policies with a timing that pays attention to the persistence in nominal wages that was built in by old wage contracts.

11 a dampening or even offset of the effects on output variability that arise from the supply side effects of the exchange rate. Numerical examples provided by Dornbusch (1982) indicate that starting with high degrees of exchange rate and monetary accommodation, a decrease in the former accompanied by no major change in the latter leads to a marked reduction in price variability with only a minor change in output variability. The model has also implications for per3istence 7 and for the impact of unanticipated disturbances on output. Specifically, when the aggregate demand effect dominates, a decrease in monetary or exchange rate accommodation lowers the persistence of wages and prices through time and raisos the impact of unanticipated disturbalces on output. This discussion of persistence has to be qualified, however, in that it assumes no change in the frequency of wage and exchange rate adjustments. To the extent that a disinflation program results in less frequent exchange rate and wage adjustments, it can contribute toward higher and not lower persistence of nominal disturbances. Thus, a mole complete analysis would indicate ambiguous effects of exchange rate accommodation on persistence. Taking into account changes in the frequency of exchange rate and wage adjustments following disinflation would strengthen the above described rise in the impact of unanticipated disturbances on output in response to a decrease in exchange rate accommodation. ii. Imperfect Information Models. These models posit that agents' imper'-?t information about current and future real and nominal shocks is the main factor explaining observed Phillips curves. Movements in output and other real variables can result from 7 In this model persistence is defin,d as the first order dutoregressive coefficient of a given dynamic variable.

12 9 rhanges in nominal variables only to the extent that the latter are not fully known with certainty. In Lucas' (197S) setup, producers cannot fully determine the eztent of relative price change from current information about their own nominal price. Under these conditions, the slope of the aggregate supply schedule (inverse Phillips curve) depends on the relative importance of real (relative) vs. nominal (aggregate) shocks. The higher the importance of real (relative) shocks, the flatter becomes the aggregate supply schedule in the (price, output) plane, and the stronger is probably the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. To the extent that following a disinflation program there is a diminished role of nominal shocks, and other things equal, it can result in a more pronounced observed tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. While there are some methods for measuring the relative importance of real vs. nominal shocks, additional information on this issue can be obtained by examining the comovements between the variabilities of prices and outputs across sectors in the economy. As shown by Cukierman (1983), imperfect information models imply (under some restrictive assumptions regarding parameter values) that when nominal aggregate shocks dominate, these variabilities can be expected to move in opposite directions. That is, an increase in the variance of nominal aggregative shocks reduces demand and supply relative price elasticities in each market and thus results in higher relative price dispersion but lower output variability across sectors. However, cross sectional output and price variabilities would move in the same direction in the presence of dominant real shocks. Thus, under the maintained hypothesis of these models it may be expected that while before a major disinflation program these output and price variabilities moved in opposite

13 d..rections, they moved in unison after disinflation. 10 III. TIME SERIES EVIDENCE AND COMPARISONS In this section, we present time series evidence on changes in the relations between key macro variables that occurred after the program. We assemble and interpret the evidence in the light of the models discussed in the previous section. We start by looking at summary statistics such as means and standard deviations -- the latter taken here as a measure of the degree of variability of different variables -- as well as by examining changes in contemporaneous cross correlations. Then, we investigate how the dynamics of selected variables changed after the program by studying their responses to shocks. We first consider responses to own shocks and later on responses to shocks in other variables. Then, we turn to evidence on the cross sectional variabilities of output growth, real wage growth, and relative prices which provide indication as to whether there has been a change in the type of shocks that are dominant. Last, we investigate whet1-er the persistence of economic fluctuations changed after the program. We conclude the section by summarizing the key findings and by discussing the extent to which they conform with the models. A. Summary Statistics Figures 1 to 4. Our discussion in this subsection is mainly based on Table 1 and i. Means The first two columns of panel la in Table 1 report monthly means for a set of macroeconomic variables before (i.e., 1980:2-1985:6) and after (i.e., 1986:1-1988:12) the disinflation program of It can be seen that before

14 11 the program prices, money, wages, and nominal exchange rates were increasing at a rate of about 9 percent per month. The stabilization program resulted in a remarkable reduction in the rate of inflation to a rate of about 1.3 percent per month. Growth rates for other nominal variables changed in different patterns. Some variables feature a lower rate of growth than the rate of inflation in the post stabilization period, but others increased at much higher rates than inflation. Specifically, while exchange rates for the dollar and the basket of foreign currencies depreciated at a lower rate than inflation, there were relatively high rates of growth of nominal wages, Ml. and credit in the later period. Overall, and as transparent from Figures 1 and 2, there have been two patterns. Some nominal variables have shown movements that have been aligned well in the later period with those in the rate of inflation; see Figure 1 for evidence on the growth rates of the nominal ex,change rate, controlled prices, and M3 money. However, there has been some nonsynchronization after the program between the growth rates in wages, Ml money, and credit and the rate of inflation; see Figure 2. Turning to real variables, there has been a slowdown in the rate of growth of industrial production 8 and of employment after the disinflation, from monthly growth rates of.73 and.20 percent respectively before the program to rates of.51 and.16 after the program. These, however, have not been major changes; see Figure 3. Quantitatively more important changes show up for the rate of unemployment, which increased from 5.13 percent to 6.58 percent, and in private consumption purchases, which have increased at a more rapid rate in the later period; see Figure 4. Though the rate of unemployment 8 Domestic gross investment increased significantly in 1986 but its rate of growth fell.

15 12 increased immediately after the implementation of the program, this increase partly represents a continuation of existing trends from before the program. In addition, from the first quarter of 1986 on there was a downward trend in unemployment -- a trend that was reversed in 1988 and early 1989 and has resulted in a rate of unemployment of about 8 percent. It is straightforward to translate the evidence in the first panel of Table 1 into evidence regarding relative price type variables. Some of these calculations are reported in the third panel of the table. Two key features of the data are the almost tripling in the rate of growth of the real wage in the later period and the real appreciation of the Israeli shekel, as inflation exceeded the rate of devaluation during that period. Despite the sharp increase in the real interest rate at the start of the program, the real interest rate for the period is only slightly higher (on average) than in the previous period. However, since it is likely that there has been a fall in the risk premium component of the interest rate, associated with a decrease in inflation uncertainty, the Onet* real interest rate may well be much higher after the program than before it. The evidence on the monthly trade deficit indicates that, despite some reduction immediately after the program, in dollar terms the deficit has remained quite unchanged after the program at a level of about $240 million; see Figure 3. However, the deficit was somewhat reduced in real terms and relative to GDP. ii. Standard Deviations Tne middle two columns of Table 1, panel la, can be used to analyze changes in the variability of these variables, measured by their 3tandard deviations. For most nominal variables, there has been a decrease in their

16 13 standard deviations, along with the above discussed decrease in mean rates of growth. In particular, the standard deviations of inflation and most other nominal variables after the program are at levels of about percent their previous levels; a similar pattern holds generally for coefficients of variation also reported in Table 1.9 In contrast to this general pattern, there has been a relatively minor change in the variability of the rates of growth of nominal wages and of Hl after the program. Thus, for these variables the observed decreases in their mean rates of growth were not accompanied by a decline in their standard deviations -- a somewhat puzzling finding. We have checked changes in the standard deviations of these two variables for each one of the three years from 1986 to It appears that the standard deviations of the rate of growth of nominal wages and of Ml have remained high for each one of these years. Specifically, the standard deviation of movements in wage growth were 8.05, 5.99, and 5.63 in 1986, 1987, and 1988 respectively, and those for Ml growth were 7.52, 8.15, and 8.56 respectively. This evidence indicates that the relatively high variabilities of these variables during are not the result of particularly high variability in a given year. Not only that changes in the mean growth rates of wages and Ml have not been synchronized with the rate of inflation, but nonsynchronization has also been present when comparing changes in the standard deviations of inflation and of these two variables; see again Figure 2 for general evidence on such nonsynchronization. Among the possible reasons for these phenomena we can mention the following: (i) the adjustment of Hl may well be the net result of gradual 9 Notice that coefficients of variation would not be well defined measures of variability for variables whose means are close to zero.

17 and time varying shifts in agents' portfolios toward shekel denominated assets; (ii) the adjustment of wages may reflect increased staggering and 14 sectorial variability as well as interference of economy-wide wage norms with sectorial adjustments toward equilibrium; see Artstein and Sussman (1988). The volatilities of real variables have changed less markedly, if at all, after the program than those of the nominal variables. The standard deviations of the rate of growth of industrial production and of the rate of unemployment increased in the later period. On the other hand, the standard deviations of the rates of growth of employment and of consumption decreased in the later period. The variability of the trade deficit has not changed much after the program. For relative-price type variables there is generally some decrease in their variability after the program. These findings suggest that generally there has been a decrease in the relative variability of nominal vs. real quantity variables in the post stabilization period. This conclusion would not be incompatible with characterizing the later period as one in which there has been an increase in the quantitative importance of real shocks as compared to that of nominal shocks. In addition, the notion that when inflation is sharply reduced this induces less variability, both over time and across sectors, in relativeprice variables is supported by the data. iii. Cross Correlations Cross correlations between monthly movements in inflation and in other key nominal variables are reported in panel lb of Table 1 for the periods before and after the disinflation program. Before the 1985 stabilization program, there were relatively large correlations between inflation, rates of growth of monetary aggregates (HI, M3, and credit), the

18 nominal interest rate and the rate of change of the exchange rate. These 15 monthly cross correlations generally reached values in the (.65,.80] range. The period after 1985 features a marked reduction in these correlations. In fact, some of them became negative, such as the correlations between inflation and monetary aggregates. This may well capture a shift toward a less indexed nominal side cf the economy and toward smaller accommodation after the program. The evidence supports the notion that before the plan there was a strong and close association between monthly movements in key nominal variables. This has changed after the implementation of the plan, in that there are now much weaker links within the nominal side of the system. Cross correlations between monthly movements in inflation and selected real variables are reported in panel lc of Table 1. Not surprisingly, the correlations between monthly movements in inflation and in real variables are much smaller than those reported in part lb of the Table. Upon comparing correlations before and after the program, notice that while before mid-1985 there was a positive link between inflation and the rate of unemployment, the relation between these variables becomes negative in the later period. Thus, the statistical (monthly) Phillips curve appears to have changed as a result of the program. Considering jointly the evidence in panels lb and lc of Table 1 reveals that the signs and sizes of cross correlations between monthly movements in inflation and in other macroeconomic variables have generally changed after the disinflation plan. These changes are more pronounced for the nominal variables than for the real variables -- a pattern that held also generally for comparisons involving means and standard deviations.

19 16 B. Responses to Shocks Having discussed the evidence on some summary statistics, we turn now to an examination of whether and how the dynamics of key macroeconomic time series have changed after the implementation of the disinflation program. To achieve this goal, bivariate autoregressions are estimated and transformed into moving average form (or impulse response functions) in which the impact of shocks can be measured. The estimated equations are of the form '4 (1) xt - Aixt_i i-i + et where xt - (It,yt)', with X denoting the rate of inflation and y denoting any other variable entering the autoregression (e.g., y may denote the rate of growth of money). The moving average for this system is given by U (2) xt 3 E Biet-i where the Bi matrices can be obtained from the Ai matrices; see Sims (1980). For our purposes, it is convenient to orthogonalize the covariance matrix of the e's thus yielding the representation (3) x~t - E Cei imo

20 17 where e* denotes the orthogonalize disturbances. Bivariate autoregression such as in equation (1) were estimated for the rate of inflation and another variable selected those appearing in Table 1. Each such run was implemented on monthly data twice: for the 80:6-85:6 period, i.e. before the disinflation program, and for the 85:12-88:12 period. Before we discuss changes in the impacts of shocks, it is well to turn to Table 2 which reports evidence on the size of the shocks in both time periods. The shocks in the system are measured by the estimated disturbances in the econometric equations; thus, wage shocks are the disturbances to the bivariate regression of the rate of change of wages on four own lagged values, four lagged values of the rate of inflation, and a constant. For inflation shocks, we used the disturbances from the autoregression including lagged inflation and wage growth as explanatory variables. The size of the shocks is measured by the standard error of the estimated disturbances. The evidence reported in Table 2 is quite consistent with that reported in Table 1. That is, the size of most nominal shocks has generally decreased by a large extent. Standard deviations of nominal shocks in the post 1985 period are at about percent of their levels before the program. The exceptions are shocks to nominal wage growth and to Ml growth, which had in the later period standard deviations of the same order of magnitude as in the first period. For real variables, the picture is somewhat different in that for most shock-type quantity variables there have been only relatively minor changes in standard deviations. Thus, this evidence tends to support the notion that real shocks have become more important relative to nominal shocks in the period after the 1985 stabilization program.

21 18 To examine the nature of the changes in the dynamic responses to shocks we use Figures 5 to 8 and begin by looking at the responses of each variable of interest to its own shocks. The first chart in Figure 5 depicts the response of inflation through time to a unit shock (i.e., one standard deviation) in the rate of inflation in period 1 as calculated for the periods before and after the disinflation program. The Figure also reports responses of wage growth and of.11 growth to respective own unit shocks. Two main features are salient in Figure 5. First, there is generally less own-persistence in the impact of the shocks in the first 2-3 periods. For example, against the same unit shock to the inflation rate there is a smaller rate of inflation by period 4 after the program than before. Second, there has been an increase in the variability of the responses through time after the program. There is now more pronounced cyclicality in the process of convergence following the shocks. Figure 6 presents evidence on responses to own shocks for variables that have been subject to greater control by policymakers than those in the previous figure. These are tae rate of change of the exchange rate (basket), the rate of change of controlled prices, and the rate of change of credit. It is seen that for each one of these variables responses to own shocks show less persistence after the program, especially in the first few periods immediately after the shocks and there is a somewhat faster convergence back to the steady state or control values of zero. This seems to be consistent with stronger attempts by policy makers to bring these nominal variables back to their preshock levels more rapidly than in the period before the program. Responses of real variables to unit shocks in their values are presented in Figure 7. Shocks to the rate of growth of employmeat and to the

22 rate of unemployment seem to have slightly larger persistence in the first 19 periods Rfter the shocks. Altogethr., however, there are no major changes in the responses of real variables to their own shocks after the 1985 program. Some evidence regarding changes in cross effects before and after the program is provided in Figure 8. In all cases we consider the effects of inflation shocks on other variables. The first two charts depict the responses of wage growth and MI money growth to unit shocks in inflation. It can be seen that these shocks generate a less accommodating short term response of nominal wages and Ml in the post-program period. These responses show a greater degree of volatility, or cyclicality, in the later period. Considering the effects of infl. ion shocks on the rate of change of the exchange rate, in the third chart of the figure, indicates that the shocks have a much smaller impact and result in somewhat less variability of the rate of change of the exchange rate than before the program. This probably reflects the decrease in exchange rate accommodation implied in the use of the exchange rate as a policy variable in the process of disinflation. The last chart in the figure gives the responses of employment growth to inflation shocks. After the program, there is a stronger short run impact of inflation shocks on the rate of change of employment and the latter's responses show higher volatility than before -- this last finding is similar to that reported above for wage and Ml growth. Another type of cross effects arises from considering the response of inflation to shocks in the other variables. The evidence, not reported here in charts for brevity, is straightforward: shocks in other variables have a much smaller impact on the rate of inflation after the program. Thus, the

23 20 disinflation program appears to have weakened the link going from shocks to key macro variables to the process of inflation. C. Cross-Sectional Variabilities The conclusion, based on Tables 1 and 2, that it appears that there is a less important role of nominal vs. real shocks after the program is now further verified by turning to cross sectional variabilities. We discussed in the previous section the predictions of imperfect information models regarding the direction of comovement between price and output cross sectional variabilities. Figure 8a plots three measures of variability: of relative prices (across 10 broad categories in the CPI), relative growth rates of output (across 6 main sectors such as industry, agriculture, construction, etc.), and relative rates of growth of real wages (across 9 main sectors). We consider the latter two measures at applying to real variables. In each case, variability is measured by weighted cross sectional variances. 1 0 There are two salient features of Figure 8a. First, there has been a decrease in cross sectional variabilities after the 1985 program. In particular, the index of dispersion of relative prices after the disinflation has become about one-third of its value before the program. This finding is in line with the observed positive co:relation between inflation and relative price dispersion that has been documented for several countries. Similarly, there has been a decrease of about 20 percent in the variability of real wage growth rates after There has been a somewhat slower downward adjustment 10 The data source for our calculations is Bank of Israel's Annual Report (various issues).

24 21 of relative real wage growth variability than that of relative price Second, notice the form of corovement between these three measures of dispersion before and after the program. Up to 1984 there was generally a common movement of the variabilities of output growth and real wage growth, in opposite direction to that of the variability of relative prices. Thus, periods with high price variability were typically also periods of low variability of output growth and wage growth across different sectors. This pattern chansed after 1985, in that the three variabilities appear to be positively correlated since then. Using these patterns to classify time periods according to the relative importance of real vs. nominal shocks, as suggested in the previous section, provides further support to the hypothesis that real shocks have become more dominant after the program. Notice also that while 1987 was a year with remarkably low values of our three measures of dispersion, they all show increases in 1988 and especially so the variability of output growth rates. D. Persistence of Fluctuations Has there been a change in the degree of persisv.ice of macroeconomic fluctuations after the disinflation program? We interpre. persistence in a time series sense and measure it by the variance ratio, used recently by Cochrane (1988). Consider time series for a given variable, say the rate of inflation ft. The variance ratio consists of dividing (1/k) times the variance of k-differences in r by the variance of its first differences: 11 This may partly reflect the interference of %conomy wide range wage norms imposed by the program with different stages ot. adjustment to long term equilibrium of different sectors. See Artstein and.ussman (1988).

25 22 (4) V(k) - (l/k)cvar(ft- ft-k)ivar(ft -t)] One extreme case of persistence is when ft follows a random walk. In this case, the variance of k-dlfferences in X grows linearly with k and the variance ratio is equal to one. Under these condltions fluctuations in i are permanent and the underlying process is nonstationary. At the other extreme is the case in which it follows a stationary (mean reverting) process. The variance of k-dlfferences in 1 t approaches then a constant equal to twice the variance of the series and the variance ratio approaches zero for large k; in thls case, fluctuations in X are transitory. Between these two extremes there are cases in which fluctuations in u are partly permanent and partly temporary, as when the series are a combination of a random walk and a stationary component. In these more general cases the variance ratio provides a measure of the relative importance of the permanent component, in that for large k it settles down to the ratio of the innovation variance of the random walk component to the variance of first differences. Variance ratios adjusted for small sample bias are reported in Table 3 and Figure 9 provides plots of the ratios for four variables: the rate of inflation, the rate of unemployment, the rate of change of the real exchange rate, and the real interest rate. For each variable the ratios are reported for periods before and after the disinflation program. In each case we used monthly data and k Caution is suggested in regarding the findings as definitive because small samples are being used and standard errors are not provided. Comparing persistence before and after the program yields two main patterns. On the one hand, no major change in variance ratios shows up for

26 23 the nominal variables such as the rate of inflation, and the rates of growth of MI, wages, controlled prices, the nominal exchange rate, etc. See in this context the first chart in Figure 9 which gives the variance ratio for the rate of inflation. It is seen that before and after the program fluctuations in inflation were primarily transitory, as indicated by the variance ratios of.16 and.12 respectively (for k - 13).12 Variance ratios for real variables, on the other hand, yield a somewhat different pattern. The ratios reported in Table 3 indicate that there has been an increase in the degree of persistence of fluctuations in some real variables after the program, especially so for the rate of unemployment, the rate of change of the real exchange rate, and the real interest rate (see their variance ratios plotted in Figure 9). This increased persistence of unemployment after the program may well reflect a process of structural adjustment and reallocation of resources across sectors; see Section IV below. E. Relating the Findings to the Models In sumarizing and interpreting the evidence presented above we would like to highlight siz main results. First, it seems safe to characterize the post 1985 regime as one with a lower degree of exchange rate, and perhaps overall nominal accommodation. That is, there is weaker transmission of changes in the rate of inflation into changes in other nominal variables after the program. This finding is especially relevant for contracting models, where changes in the degree of accommodation of nominal policy variables play 12 Notice, however, that there are subperiods before the program in which inflation persistence may have well increased, as in the inflation outburst that occurred from late 1983 to mid 1985; see again Figure 1.

27 24 an important role in changing macroeconomic performance. We discussed earlier (in Section II) the predictions of these models regarding the effects of lowering the degree of nominal accommodation and will explain shortly how these predictions fit the data. Second, changes in the size of the shocks and in the direction of comovements of cross-sectional variabilities generally indicate a larger role of real vs. nominal shocks after dicinflation. To the extent that this enhanced importance of real shocks can be associated with a greater role of relative disturbances, then imperfect information models would predict that this will induce an increase in economic agents' responsiveness to perceived rel&'tive prices -- an effect that may result in a flatter Phillips curve. Third, there appears to be a more pronounced tradeoff between inflation and unemployment in the later period. This is consistent with the analysis of contracting models, which predict that lowering the degree of nominal policy accommodation should result in a larger impact of unanticipated disturbances on output and on other real variables. This finding is also in line with imperfect information models, as discussed above. In the next section we will discuss the statistical links between inflation and unemployment in the transition from high to low inflation. Fourth, the tradeoff between output variability and inflation variability, if existent, has shifted downward such that inflation variability has diminished and output variability shows very little change. Interestingly, this pattern conforms quite well with the outcomes from numerical examples applied to open economy contracting models by Dornbusch (1982); see our discussion in Section II above. Fifth, the evidence on changes in persistence is not clearcut. Perhaps this is not surprising given the theoretical ambiguities that arise when analyzing the impact of lower nominal accommodation on persistence in

28 25 contracting models. Sixth, after the program there has been a decrease in the dispersion of relative prices across different sectors. Thus, the idea that reducing inflation leads to a decrease in the high-inflation induced 'noise' component of relative prices seems to be supported by che evidence. Also, real relative price type variables such as real exchange rates and real interest rates exhibit lower variability through time after the program. While we obviously recognize that our findings are not based on definitive tests of a model or set of models, we regard the evidence presented thus far as harmonious with the predictions of standard macroeconomic models. IV. THE CHANGING OF THE NATURE INFLATION/UNEMPLOYMENT TRADEOFF This section provides further evidence on the inflation/unemployment tradeoff before and after the program. We begin by examining statistical and econometric Phillips curves before and after the program and move on to investigate the relations between the rate of unemployment and three important variables: the real exchange rate, the real interest rate, and the real wage. We focus on the timing of changes in unemployment and on the difficulties in attempting to account for the observed timing with standard macro models. Four years after the implementation of the stabilization program it has become clear that the remarkable disinflation that took place, from inflation rates of about 9.3 percent per month to rates of about 1.3 percent per month, has been accompanied by an increase in the rate of unemplcyment from about 5 percent per month before the program to about 8 percent in early 1989; see Figure 10 for half-yearly data. The observed empirical relation between inflation and unemployment exhibits a positive association between these variables in the high inflation

29 26 period and practically no systematic relation after stabilization. By contrast, inflation and unemployment appear to be strongly negatively related when comparing the means of these variables before and atter stabilization. Thus, with the benefit of hindsight, the empirical Phillips curve for the high inflation period had no predictive value with regard to what was to be anticipated for after the program. These facts raise the question of why the empirical relation between these two variables is so different within regimes as compared with the transition between regimes, and especially what are.he causes for the negative relation in the latter case. The case of the transition is of course the more important aspect of this discussion since it is only in this case that a tradeoff is indeed observed. In what follows, we suggest some answers to these questions. A. The High Inflation Period In this period the behavior of inflation and unemployment seems to reflect the economy's reaction to policy makers' actions intended to influence another policy target: the economy's external balance. When the balance of payments gets into a crisis and international reserves are being depleted -- as in and this consideration probably takes precedence over the targets of having low inflation and unemployment. In fact, both inflation and unemployment may become instruments in dealing with such a criris. Under these circumstances, and assuming an indexed economy, a positive association may emerge between inflation and unemployment. Yet this association has nothing to do with the tradeoff between these variables that is relevant in the context of a disinflation program. When the stress on the balance of

30 payments is relieved, there is probably room for policy makers to shift attention toward stabilizing inflation. However, this shift did not 27 materialize in the period before Although an attempt was made to combat inflation back in , it was not supported by an adjustmaent in fiscal and monetary fundamentals. Therefore, it seems plausible that such attempt did not confront a tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. The reasoning behind a positive association between inflation and unemployment in periods of balance of payments crises is as follows. Handling these crises normal'y requires improving competitiveness by effecting a real devaluation and a drop in real wages. In principle, the latter could be accomplished by a reduction in nominal wage growth which possibly will also induce a decrease in inflation. However, in a highly indexed economy in which workers are not willing to make wage concessions the adjustment is somewhat different. Put a bit more formally, we can express the average real wage over a given period (say a year). wr, in such an economy as (5) wr * g(wp,, n).(+) ( -) (+) where wp denotes the peak real wage (i.e.. at the time of the COLA payment) and n denotes the frequency of COLA's per year. When improving competitiveness requires at least some drop in real wages, and unless workers are willing to change the wage agreement as reflected in wp and in n, the only viable alternative is to raise F. This can be accomplished by raising the rate of devaluation (as in the 1984 crisis) and by raising public sector prices (as in 1980). In fact, the evidence provided in Figure 12 indicates that there were aevere cuts in real wages in the context of the upward

31 28 adjustments in the rate of inflation that followed the 1979 and 1984 balance of payments crises. So far for the increase in inflation in coping with a deterioration in external balance. What about unemployment? Since the solution of a balance of payments crisis typically involves also contractionary fiscal and monetary policies, in order to reduce spending and imports, there may be a tendency for the rate of unemployment to rise. This is intensified by government's direct attempts to restrict growth of employment in the public sector. These combined policies may contribute toward increased unemployment; see Figure 12 for evidence in this regard for the 1979 and 1984 episodes. The overall outcome of these policies is compatible with observing a positive link between inflation and unemployment. This link is somewhat confirmed by the regression equations (1) and (2) in Table 4. These are univariate and multivariate Phillips curve type equations. In both cases, the coefficient on the rate of unemployment is positive, and in equation (1) it is significantly different from zero. In between these two balance of payments crises, the exchange rate was used, especially for about one year after September 1982, as a means to reduce inflation by adopting a policy of devaluing at a rate of 5 percent per month which was about 2 percent below the ongoing rate of inflation. The fact that now inflation was used as a target was not sufficient to create a tradeoff in the course of the policy. Thus, the point 83/1 in Figure 10 is one with relatively low inflation and low unemployment. What appears to be a main explanation for this outcome is the combination of the direct effect of slowing down devaluations on the rate of inflation, and the lack of credibility of the policy which stimulated consumption spending and hence

32 economic activity. These effects of perceived temporariness and of lack of credibility of government policies are further explored in what follows. 29 B. The Post Stabilization Period For the period after the stabilization program, Figure 10 indicates no clear pattern of relation between inflation and unemployment. There were two peaks for the rate of unemployment; one in the second half of 1985, immediately after the program, and the other one in the second half of In early 1989, the rate of unemployment reached an overall peak level of about 8 percent. It is evident that disinflation was achiceed quite rapidly, yet unemployment increased only gradually through time. In fact, the points for 1986 through 1988 in Figure 10 suggest movements in the rate of unemployment that were not accompanied by changes in the rate of inflation. Consequently, the statistical Phillips curve for this period is approximated by a horizontal line. C. The Tradeoff in the Transition Despite these mixed patterns within subperiods, it is evident that comparing the economy's position before and after the program (see the broad averages plotted in points B and A of Figure 10) yields a statistical tradeoff between the rates of inflation and unemployment. This is somewhat confirmed by the econometric evidence provided in Table 4, equations (3) and (4). Both the latter suggest that when one considers the entire period for estimation purposes, the coefficient describing the inflation/unemployment tradeoff becomes negative and marginally significant. Thus, while a positively sloped statistical Phillips curve may have prevailed in the period

33 30 up to mid-1985, and no clearcut relation emerged for the post 1985 period, the statistical tradeoff emerges when comparing the pre and post program periods. It is precisely when a strong disinflation is attempted and achieved that we see an inverse relation between inflation and unemployment arising from the data. Modern macroeconomic theory treats the Phillips curve as a reducedform relation. Behind it there is a set of fundamental factors that determine its shape. Changes in these factors can lead to changes in the reduced form. Key among these fundamental factors are the existing macroeconomic policies, their credibility, private sector's expectations, the type of shocks affecting the economy, the existing rigidities in the system, etc. To further examine how some of these factors are captured in the inflation/unemployment tradeoff in the transition from high to low inflation, we present in Figure 11 the relations in the data between the rate of unemployment and three important relative-price type variables: the real exchange rate, the real interest rate, and the real wage. Comparing the half-year averages in Figure 11 before and after the stabilization program suggests a clearcut patterns the increase in the rate of unemployment after the program was accompanied by a real exchange rate appreciation, by an increase in the real interest rate, and by an increase in the real wage. And, as in the case of Figure 4.1, these links are more pronounced when comparing performance across the pre and post periods than when looking at the relations within each subperiod. Examining the figures and the data suggests that the behavior of the rate of unemployment after the program followed a cycle consisting of three phases. In the initial stage of six to nine nonths inflation was simply reduced by a combination of orthodox and heterodox policies. This was

34 accompanied by an increase in unemployment for about a year and a drop in 31 industrial production for about two to three quarters. However, the size of these recessionary tendencies was relatively smalls a spectacular disinflation was then effected without major losses in output. The second phase is characterized by a boom in private consumption spending in which stimulated economic activity. The main features and explanations for this boom have been analyzed in more detail in an earlier paper by Liviatan (1989). The data indicate that while private consumption spending amounted to 53 percent of GDP in , this ratio increased to 59 percent during Though partially offset by decreases in private investment and public consumption, these changes in consumption dictated the direction of change in total domestic uses which increased by 9 percent in 1986 and by 6.1 percent in GDP growth for these years was 3.6 and 5.2 percent respectively. Overall, then, the period was one of booming private consumption and economic activity, high real wages 13 and real interest rates, and a low real exchange rate.1 4 Liviatan (1989) discussed several explanations for the consumption boom after stabilization and reached the conclusion that the boom is most probably due to an initial perception that stabilization is only temporary an argument which is in line with recent theoretical work by Calvo (1987) and by Helpman and Razin (1987). 13 The fact that output growth accelerated in spite of the growth of real wages suggest that the economy was driven by demand factors. 14 Helpman (1988) has argued that some of these comovements cannot be accounted for by models of pure competition. Instead, they can be explained by using a framework of oligopolistic competition. 15 Similar booms have been documented for several Latin American countries after the implementation of stabilization programs; see e. g. Liviatan (1989).

35 32 Phase three started in 1988, when there was a slowdown in private consumption growth and in the growth of GDP, which was about 1.6 percent for that year. Industrial production started to fall and unemployment reached unprecedented levels in While these recent developments have not yet been fully analyzed, it appears that an important part of the recent increase in unemployment can be explained by a combination of factors that resulted in a profit squeeze for the business sector in recent years. First, the cycle discussed above was such that it resulted in persistently high real interest rates, high and increasing real wages, and continuous real appreciation of the Israeli shekel. Second, there were decreases in subsidies to the corporate sector, and an increase in tax rates on corporate profits. Third, there was a decrease in public sector's demands for goods and services from the private sector -- a decrease that was probably perceived by the business sector as permanent. Fourth, the uprising in the occupied territories contributed to a downturn in economic activity. In addition to these factors, it appears that the recent increase in unemployment reflects a slow adjustment of the economy's structure to the new economic environment with low inflation. This adjustment entails major reallocations of resources among sectors. Thus, factors of production had to be reshuffled between financial and nonfinancial activities to accommodate the decrease in the intensity of the former. Similarly, in the high inflation regime many large combines (such as government and labor union enterprises and transportation cooperatives) relied on government support in periods of financial and liquidity crises. Such support was gradually eliminated after the program and therefore these combines had to contract their activities.

36 33 Interestingly, these allocative effects of disinflation have great similarity with those in the aftermath of the German hyperinflation; see Garber (1982). During the hyperinflation in Germany, there was a policy of subsidizing the capital goods industry through the inflation tax revenue. When this source of revenue was terminated and a 'Rationalization Period' was started, a major reallocation of resources was required, with capital and labor moving out of the capital goods industry. It is this reallocation that, in Garber's (1982) view, generated the transitional costs of disinflation which showed up in a decrease of industrial production by about 20 percent in less than one year and an increase in the rate of unemployment to 22 percent of union members. Similarly to the case of Israel, these developments did not occur immediately after disinflation but instead emerged with a lag (that is, one and a half years after the November 1923 reform). Finally, we relate these developments to standard macroeconomic models such as those discussed in Section II. In these models,imperfect information and contractual rigidities determine the transition path of the economy from high to low inflation. Once these imperfections and rigidities are removed, disinflation is not predicted to have an impact on real output, unemployment, and other real variables. The fact that the rate of unemployment has markedly increased to about 8 percent only three years after the program does not appear to be explained by the existence of these imperfections and rigidities. Thus, even if agents correctly perceive and predict the new policy regime and even under an heterodox policy package there may be real costs associated with disinflation to the extent that the latter entails a process of structural adjustment consisting of major reallocations of resources across sectors.

37 34 V. CONCLUSIONS Much of the evidence obtained from comparing macroeconomic performance in Israel before and after the stabilization program of 1985 conforms well with standard macro models. The decreases in exchange rate and nominal accommodation and the enhanced importance of real, as opposed to nominal, shocks that characterize the post-program regime appear to have strengthened the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. They have also been associated with a decrease in inflation variability and no major change in the stability of output or other real variables. Cross-sectional variabilities, of relative prices, outputs, and real wages, have changed in a direction compatible with the notion that indeed real shocks have become more dominant in the low inflation economy. 'What are less standard from the standpoint of conventional theories are the immediate and abrupt reduction in the rate of inflation, and the timing and form of the impact of disinflation on real variables. For more than two years after the program there was a private consumption boom that was accompanied by increases in economic activity and by relatively high real wages and real interest rates and a low (appreciated) real exchange rate. It is only in the beginning of the fourth year after the program that the consumption boom stopped, economic activity was stagnant, and there was a rise in the rate of unemployment. It seems difficult to explain these developments solely on the basis of models stressing the role of imperfect information and contractual rigidities. The consumption boom appears to be closely related to partial lack of credibility of the program and of the exchange rate policy. Apparently the public perceived the changes as mainly temporary. In addition,

38 35 the recent rise in unemployment seems to reflect, to an important extent, the beglnnlng of a process of structural adiustment whereby resources are reallocated across the economy to conform with the new low inflation equilibrium. This process may involve a reduction of growth in the transitional stage, but wvll enable an increase in long term growth after the completion of the adjustment. Considering the Israeli program as a laboratory experiment in heterodox policy, we can address its implications so far for the well-known debate between gradualism vs. shock treatment in the process of stabilization. From the point of view of reducing lnflation, the program seems to have had the same advantage as of shock treatment policiest There was a sharp and immediate disinflation after mid This was probably due to the use of multiple nominal targets (such as a fixed exchange rate and price-wage controls) in conjunctior. with adjustments in fundamentals right at the start of the prog%am -- a mix that makes the program heterodox. From the perspective of the real costs of disinflation, the program resembles more a gradualist policy. The real costs, in the form of increased unemployment, were postponed for several years and in the transition there was actually a boom in economic activity. Which of these features of the results of the program are specific to Israel and which ones are common to heterodox policies applicable to other countries is an important question that needs to be addressed in the future.

39 36 VI. REFERENCES Artutein, Y. and Z. Sussman (1988), 'Wage Policy During Disinflation: the Israeli Stabilization Program of 1985.' Discussion Paper 88.07, Research Department, Bank of Israel. Blejer, M. and N. Liviatan (1987), 'Fighting Hyperinflation - Stabilization Strategies in Argentina and Israel ,' IMP Staff Papers, Vol. 34, no. 3, pp Bruno, M. (1986), 'Sharp Disinflation Strategyt Israel 1985,' Economic Policy 2, pp and Sylvia Piterman (1988),"Israel's Stabilization: a Two Year Review' in Inflation Stabilization ed. Bruno et.al., pp Calvo, G. A. (1986),'Temporary Stabilization: Predetermined Exchange Rates," Journal of Political Economy, 94, pp Cochrane, J. (1988), 'How Big Is the Random Walk in GNP?' Journal of Political Economy 96, pp Cukierman, A. (1983),'Relative Price Variability and Inflation: a Survey and Further Results," Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy 19, pp Dornbusch, R. (1982), 'PPP Exchange Rate Rules and Macroeconomic Stability,' Journal of Political Economy 90, pp Fischer, S. (1977), 'Long Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule,' Journal of Political Economy 85, (1987), 'The Israeli Stabilization Program ,' American Economic Review 77, pp Garber, P. (1982), 'Transition From Inflation to Price Stability,' CMrnegie- Rochester Series on Public Policy 16, pp Helpman, E. (1988), 'Macroeconomic Effects of Price Controls: the Role of Market Structure," Economic Journal 98, pp and L. Leiderman (1988),'Stabilization in High-Inflation Countries: Analytical Foundations and Recent Experience,' Carnegie- Rochester Series on Public Policy 28, pp and A. Razin (1987), 'Exchange Rate Managements Intertemporal Tradeoffs,' American Economic Review 77, pp

40 37 Kiguel, H. and N. Liviatan (1989), 'The Old and the New Heterodox Stabilization Program.s a Study of the Sixties with Perspective of the Eighties," unpublished manuscript, The World Bank. Liviatan, N. (1989), 'Israel's Stabilization Cycle with Some Reference to Latin American Experience,' preliminary manuscript, The World Bank. Lucas, R. E. Jr. (1973), 'Some International Evidence on Output Inflation Tradeoffs,' American Economic Review 63, pp (1976),'Econometric Policy Evaluation: a Critique,' Carnegie- Rochester Series on Public Policy 1, pp Sims, C. A. (1980),'Macroeconomics and Reality,* Econometrica 48, pp Taylor, J. B. (1979), 'Staggered Wage Setting in a Macro Model," American Economic Review 69,

41 38 Table 1 - S_macy Statistics - Israel: (Monthly Data) la. Means, Standard Deviations, and Coefficients of Variationa Variable Meanb Standard Coefficient Deviationb of Variationb (2 rate of change) J.L (A) (B) (A) (B) (A) CPI Price of Controlled Goods Price of Free Goods Nominal Wage Exchange Rate (Basket) Exchange Rate (Dollar) Ml Money M3 Money Credit Interest Ratec Industrial Production los Employment Rate of Unemploymentc Consumption Real Wage Real Exchange Rate (Basket) Real Exchanga Rate (Dollar) Real Relative Price of Controlled Goods Real Interest Ratec Trade Deficitd Trade Deficit/GDPe Notes: a) Data definitions and sources are provided in Appendix 1. b) Columns (B) refer to the period 1980:2-1985:6; i.e., before the implementation of the 1985 stabilization program. Columns (A) apply to the 1986:1-1988:12 post stabilization period. c) Level (and not rate of change). d) Level, in millions of dollars. e) Trade deficit in domestic currency units divided by a monthly measure of GDP.

42 39 (Table 1 - cont.) lb. Correlations Matrix for Inflation and Selected Nominal Variablesa DP 1.00 DP DW DM1 DM3 DC DPC DER INT DV (.08) DM (-.27) (.33) DM (-.33) (.12) (.60) DC (-.10) (.34) (.32) (.32) DPC (.62) (.04) (-.19) (-.39) (.04) DER (-.00) (-.19) (-.09) (.15) (.33) (.10) INT (-.27) (.04) (.31) (.46) (.24) (-.17) (.23) Notes: a) The variables DP, DW, DM1, DM3, DC, DPC, and DER denote the rates of change of the CPI, nominal wage, M1, M3, credit, controlled prices, and nominal (basket) exchange rate. INT denotes the nominal interest rate. Each entry gives a correlation coefficient for the period 1980:2-1985:6. Figures in parentheses are correlation coefficients for the period 1986:1-1988:12.

43 40 (Table 1 - cont.) lc. Correlations Matrix for Inflation and Selected Real Variablesa DP 1.00 DP UNE DIP DEMP DCON DRER RIR DRW UNE (-.21) DIP (-.10) (.19) DEMP (-.25) (-.00) (.54) DCON (.02) (.09) (.19) (.04) DRER (-.50) (.07) (-.03) (.14) (.05) RIR (-.87) (.07) (.00) (.16) (-.00) (.54) DRW (-.05) (-.01) (.39) (.35) (.06) (-.14) (.08) Notes: a) The variables DP, DIP, DEMP, DCON, DRER, and DRW denote the rates of change of the CPI, industrial production, employment, consumption, real exchange rate, and real wage. UNE and RIR denote, respectively, the rate of unemployment and real interest rate. Each entry gives a correlation coefficient for the period 1980:2-1985:6. Figures in parentheses are correlation coefficients for the period 1986:1-1988:12.

44 41 Table 2 - The Size of the Shocks: Standard Deviations of Estimated Disturbances* 1980:6-1985:6 1985: :12 Inflation Wage Growth Ml Growth M3 Growth Credit Growth Devaluation (Basket) Devaluation (Dollar) Controlled Prices' Inflation Nominal Interest Rate Unemployment Industrial Production Growth Employment Growth Consumption Growth Trade Deficit/GDP * Note: Each entry is the standard deviation of the estimated disturbance from bivariate autoregressions that used four lagged values of inflation and of the other relevant variable and a constant. The figures for inflation are based on autoregressions that had lagged inflation and wage growth as explanatory variables.

45 Table 3 - Variance Ratios [V(k); Equation (4) in Text] Inflation Wage Growth Devaluation Controlied Pri'%es Ml Growth k B A B A A A A u,.'~e38?/ (' o 9~b62 l s ,148 *414)(3 34 * ~ i 4 37 F o u3~0. * ~r' I /3/137 lotxs` O. d :342 ~ , ) *24~33f S8122 I I ti8172 4t4A4&' ' 0. l247 Co S Z (P it '.129 2Q109 1'1 C r!.1 050( * e18 9o I3.2~ o14 74 I' a U4, (l (' :.258' i~0201 O ? to 4) ) ' I 'l (3111 t) (j Q ' Li '9. j 3 II-.' O.Z (43 I Cl.fl Co.2 O r5( ?7 I C' I.'. 163/9 -~.i'aa ) , Ol.05B37 I1.169:? h ''.t ) Real Interest Rate Real Exchange Rate M3 Growth Trade neficit k B A B -A B Ea A,loyen Grov B A Cot Unempoymen 5roucio Inutra * oo. 001' 1. :n.::o Growth I*001:34: I..0004:0 Crdt4 1.0:0:01:34 r I ':004. c::ori. 0013'1(34 2 '1? ,58" 903? : j ( l. 7C'74A % 0.l0 ) t o. 4: ') (I24) Q l.9464 Cs ~ ( ) 317r7 (3 48 : ~.7 6 i' :34T' (' e( el. 104(33~ 0) :.2"1079 e) 2174j 4: , 0l i 65~ 18.1 ':.1889')( : (3623: - 0: : T J I.C Qj: :3(30. C511fl 0:.4:7961 Co '5.1A73 0, 4: ( Employment G-rowth Unemployment Rate Industrial Production Growth Credit Growth k A B A B A B A *(3: :43:3:1:.4313:4:4l 43:(3I4: ').(30:430 (3.7744:34 ~I. 4: ±. :':'3C431 :3:4I0. 1:.2:3 : Coe 4:.64:812 ( ( L (: : Q : (3 4 0.b.204(36 0: : : ( ( i:i ( i :.676:4 (3.0: C (3332 (3) ( ( ( *3 Q.20964: ( i. 44: (3.( Q * ( ' (1' J4.43 ( ( i C:o Co (3825 ( (3. 1( *14135 L (( ( '~(8396 1'.( ( :' :.0: :92-3 0(30*3:575 (:3*:31:33C: 43.Q4631 Co * ':371:59 1. Co' ':' (3 * C. 3214:31 Q.3 00:1:840 0:. 10: I 9190):34:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PROPOGATION OF SHOCKS IN A HIGH-INFLATION ECONOMY: ISRAEL, Leonardo Leiderman. Assaf Razin. Working Paper No.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PROPOGATION OF SHOCKS IN A HIGH-INFLATION ECONOMY: ISRAEL, Leonardo Leiderman. Assaf Razin. Working Paper No. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PROPOGATION OF SHOCKS IN A HIGH-INFLATION ECONOMY: ISRAEL, 1980-85 Leonardo Leiderman Assaf Razin Working Paper No. 2003 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s As part of its monetary policy strategy, the ECB regularly monitors the development of a wide range of indicators and assesses their implications

More information

Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy

Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy Luděk Niedermayer 1 This paper discusses several empirical aspects of the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy. The introduction

More information

The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting

The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting Christopher Ragan* An essential part of the Bank of Canada s inflation-control strategy is a flexible exchange rate that is free to adjust to various

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning Doug Hostland Department of Finance Working Paper * 2001-20 * The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not reflect those of the Department of Finance. A previous version of this

More information

Inflation Targeting Under a Crawling Band Exchange Rate Regime: Lessons from Israel

Inflation Targeting Under a Crawling Band Exchange Rate Regime: Lessons from Israel 9 Inflation Targeting Under a Crawling Band Exchange Rate Regime: Lessons from Israel Leonardo Leiderman and Gil Bufman 1 Consider a small, open economy that, after a long period of chronically high inflation,

More information

Karnit Flug: Macroeconomic policy and the performance of the Israeli economy

Karnit Flug: Macroeconomic policy and the performance of the Israeli economy Karnit Flug: Macroeconomic policy and the performance of the Israeli economy Remarks by Dr Karnit Flug, Governor of the Bank of Israel, to the conference of the Israel Economic Association, Tel Aviv, 18

More information

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU?

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU? JEL classification: C3, C33, E31, F15, F2 Keywords: common and country-specific shocks, output and inflation dispersions, convergence What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU? Emil STAVREV

More information

Lecture notes 10. Monetary policy: nominal anchor for the system

Lecture notes 10. Monetary policy: nominal anchor for the system Kevin Clinton Winter 2005 Lecture notes 10 Monetary policy: nominal anchor for the system 1. Monetary stability objective Monetary policy was a 20 th century invention Wicksell, Fisher, Keynes advocated

More information

Stabilization, Accommodation, and Monetary Rules

Stabilization, Accommodation, and Monetary Rules Stabilization, Accommodation, and Monetary Rules A central feature of the monetarist approach to the problem of inflation is a preannounced gradual reduction in monetary growth. This reduction is to be

More information

Recent Changes in Macro Policy and its Effects: Some Time-Series Evidence

Recent Changes in Macro Policy and its Effects: Some Time-Series Evidence HAS THE RESPONSE OF INFLATION TO MACRO POLICY CHANGED? Recent Changes in Macro Policy and its Effects: Some Time-Series Evidence Has the macroeconomic policy "regime" changed in the United States in the

More information

Challenges to Central Banking from Globalized Financial Systems

Challenges to Central Banking from Globalized Financial Systems Challenges to Central Banking from Globalized Financial Systems Conference at the IMF in Washington, D.C., September 16 17, 2002 Mr. Jerzy Pruski, Member of the Monetary Policy Council, National Bank of

More information

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV John E. Floyd University of Toronto May 10, 2013 Our major task here is to look at the evidence regarding the effects of unanticipated money shocks on real

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking Michael Dotsey Executive Vice President and Director of Research Keith Sill Senior Vice President and Director, Real-Time Data Research Center Federal

More information

Bruno Eeckels, Alpine Center, Athens, Greece George Filis, University of Winchester, UK

Bruno Eeckels, Alpine Center, Athens, Greece George Filis, University of Winchester, UK CYCLICAL MOVEMENTS OF TOURISM INCOME AND GDP AND THEIR TRANSMISSION MECHANISM: EVIDENCE FROM GREECE Bruno Eeckels, Alpine Center, Athens, Greece beeckels@alpine.edu.gr George Filis, University of Winchester,

More information

Erdem Başçi: Recent economic and financial developments in Turkey

Erdem Başçi: Recent economic and financial developments in Turkey Erdem Başçi: Recent economic and financial developments in Turkey Speech by Mr Erdem Başçi, Governor of the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, at the press conference for the presentation of the April

More information

Box 1.3. How Does Uncertainty Affect Economic Performance?

Box 1.3. How Does Uncertainty Affect Economic Performance? Box 1.3. How Does Affect Economic Performance? Bouts of elevated uncertainty have been one of the defining features of the sluggish recovery from the global financial crisis. In recent quarters, high uncertainty

More information

Automatic Fiscal Stabilizers

Automatic Fiscal Stabilizers 118 Finance Challenges of the Future Automatic Fiscal Stabilizers Narcis Eduard Mitu 1 1 Faculty of Economy and Business Administration, University of Craiova mitunarcis@yahoo.com Abstract: Policies or

More information

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom Gaétan Stephan 1 University of Rennes 1, CREM April 2012 (Preliminary draft) Abstract We model the relation between output

More information

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models By Mohamed Safouane Ben Aïssa CEDERS & GREQAM, Université de la Méditerranée & Université Paris X-anterre

More information

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Policy Research Working Paper 6525 Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in

More information

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation ECONOMIC BULLETIN 3/218 ANALYTICAL ARTICLES Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation Ángel Estrada and Francesca Viani 6 September 218 Following

More information

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom WP//8 Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom Dennis Botman and Keiko Honjo International Monetary Fund WP//8 IMF Working Paper European Department and Fiscal Affairs Department Options

More information

Potential Output in Denmark

Potential Output in Denmark 43 Potential Output in Denmark Asger Lau Andersen and Morten Hedegaard Rasmussen, Economics 1 INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY The concepts of potential output and output gap are among the most widely used concepts

More information

Implications of Low Inflation Rates for Monetary Policy

Implications of Low Inflation Rates for Monetary Policy Implications of Low Inflation Rates for Monetary Policy Eric S. Rosengren President & Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Washington and Lee University s H. Parker Willis Lecture in

More information

Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy

Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy Eric S. Rosengren President & Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Boston The Global Interdependence Center Central Banking Conference

More information

Macroeconomics I International Group Course

Macroeconomics I International Group Course Learning objectives Macroeconomics I International Group Course 2004-2005 Topic 4: INTRODUCTION TO MACROECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS We have already studied how the economy adjusts in the long run: prices are

More information

September 21, 2016 Bank of Japan

September 21, 2016 Bank of Japan September 21, 2016 Bank of Japan Comprehensive Assessment: Developments in Economic Activity and Prices as well as Policy Effects since the Introduction of Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing

More information

3. Measuring the Effect of Monetary Policy

3. Measuring the Effect of Monetary Policy 3. Measuring the Effect of Monetary Policy Here we analyse the effect of monetary policy in Japan using the structural VARs estimated in Section 2. We take the block-recursive model with domestic WPI for

More information

Estimating Key Economic Variables: The Policy Implications

Estimating Key Economic Variables: The Policy Implications EMBARGOED UNTIL 11:45 A.M. Eastern Time on Saturday, October 7, 2017 OR UPON DELIVERY Estimating Key Economic Variables: The Policy Implications Eric S. Rosengren President & Chief Executive Officer Federal

More information

Israel's Inflation Target Policies - Historical Perspective and Future Outlook Introduction

Israel's Inflation Target Policies - Historical Perspective and Future Outlook Introduction Israel's Inflation Target Policies - Historical Perspective and Future Outlook Introduction Israel's Consumer Price Index (CPI) rose by 6.5% in 2002, sharply overshooting the government's inflation target

More information

Some Considerations for U.S. Monetary Policy Normalization

Some Considerations for U.S. Monetary Policy Normalization Some Considerations for U.S. Monetary Policy Normalization James Bullard President and CEO, FRB-St. Louis 24 th Annual Hyman P. Minsky Conference on the State of the US and World Economies 15 April 2015

More information

Inflation Targeting: A New Monetary Policy Framework in Korea. October Junggun Oh The Bank of Korea

Inflation Targeting: A New Monetary Policy Framework in Korea. October Junggun Oh The Bank of Korea Inflation Targeting: A New Monetary Policy Framework in Korea October 2000 Junggun Oh The Bank of Korea Inflation Targeting Framework Korean Experiences in Inflation Targeting Inflation Targeting Framework

More information

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence Loyola University Chicago Loyola ecommons Topics in Middle Eastern and orth African Economies Quinlan School of Business 1999 Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MEA Countries: Theory

More information

Donald L Kohn: Asset-pricing puzzles, credit risk, and credit derivatives

Donald L Kohn: Asset-pricing puzzles, credit risk, and credit derivatives Donald L Kohn: Asset-pricing puzzles, credit risk, and credit derivatives Remarks by Mr Donald L Kohn, Vice Chairman of the Board of Governors of the US Federal Reserve System, at the Conference on Credit

More information

Lecture: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Lecture: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Lecture: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Macroeconomics II Winter 2018/2019 SGH Jacek Suda Overview Goods Market Money Market IS Curve LM/TR Curve IS-LM/TR Model Aggregate Demand (AD) Curve AD-AS

More information

Meeting with Analysts

Meeting with Analysts CNB s New Forecast (Inflation Report III/2018) Meeting with Analysts Karel Musil Prague, 3 August 2018 Outline 1. Assumptions of the forecast 2. The new macroeconomic forecast 3. Comparison with the previous

More information

Managing Sudden Stops. Barry Eichengreen and Poonam Gupta

Managing Sudden Stops. Barry Eichengreen and Poonam Gupta Managing Sudden Stops Barry Eichengreen and Poonam Gupta 1 The recent reversal of capital flows to emerging markets* has pointed up the continuing relevance of the sudden-stop problem. This paper seeks

More information

Mr. Bäckström explains why price stability ought to be a central bank s principle monetary policy objective

Mr. Bäckström explains why price stability ought to be a central bank s principle monetary policy objective Mr. Bäckström explains why price stability ought to be a central bank s principle monetary policy objective Address by the Governor of the Bank of Sweden, Mr. Urban Bäckström, at Handelsbanken seminar

More information

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael Discussion Benoît Carmichael The two studies presented in the first session of the conference take quite different approaches to the question of price indexes. On the one hand, Coulombe s study develops

More information

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 ) II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 ) There have been significant fluctuations in the euro exchange rate since the start of the monetary union. This section assesses

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment Chapter 6 Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment In Romer s IS/MP/IA model, we assume prices/inflation adjust imperfectly when output changes. Empirically, there is a negative relationship

More information

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 17. Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 17. Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy Chapter 17 Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy Introduction For more than 50 years, many economists have used an inverse relationship involving the unemployment rate and real GDP as a guide to

More information

Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks

Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks Robert M. Feinberg Professor of Economics American University With the assistance of: Ataur Rahman Ph.D. Student in Economics American University

More information

The impact of interest rates and the housing market on the UK economy

The impact of interest rates and the housing market on the UK economy The impact of interest and the housing market on the UK economy....... The Chancellor has asked Professor David Miles to examine the UK market for longer-term fixed rate mortgages. This paper by Adrian

More information

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012 Comment on: Structural and Cyclical Forces in the Labor Market During the Great Recession: Cross-Country Evidence by Luca Sala, Ulf Söderström and Antonella Trigari Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis

More information

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) Monetary Policy, 16/3 2017 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) 1. Money in the short run: Incomplete

More information

Øystein Olsen: The economic outlook

Øystein Olsen: The economic outlook Øystein Olsen: The economic outlook Address by Mr Øystein Olsen, Governor of Norges Bank (Central Bank of Norway), to invited foreign embassy representatives, Oslo, 29 March 2011. The address is based

More information

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Properties of the estimated five-factor model Informationin(andnotin)thetermstructure Appendix. Additional results Greg Duffee Johns Hopkins This draft: October 8, Properties of the estimated five-factor model No stationary term structure model is

More information

THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1986

THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1986 of women in the labor force. Over the past decade, women have accounted for 62 percent of total labor force growth. Increasing labor force participation of women has not led to large increases in unemployment

More information

Foreign exchange rate and the Hong Kong economic growth

Foreign exchange rate and the Hong Kong economic growth From the SelectedWorks of John Woods Winter October 3, 2017 Foreign exchange rate and the Hong Kong economic growth John Woods Brian Hausler Kevin Carter Available at: https://works.bepress.com/john-woods/1/

More information

Characteristics of Prolonged Users

Characteristics of Prolonged Users 48 PART I, CHAPTER IV CHAPTER IV Characteristics of Prolonged Users 1. This chapter describes some of the main characteristics of the prolonged users in terms of performance and key economic indicators

More information

What Operating Procedures Should Be Adopted to Maintain Price Stability? Practical Issues

What Operating Procedures Should Be Adopted to Maintain Price Stability? Practical Issues What Operating Procedures Should Be Adopted to Maintain Price Stability? Practical Issues Charles Freedman In this paper I provide a broad-brush examination from a practitioner s point of view, of some

More information

Deepak Mohanty: Perspectives on inflation in India

Deepak Mohanty: Perspectives on inflation in India Deepak Mohanty: Perspectives on inflation in India Speech by Mr Deepak Mohanty, Executive Director of the Reserve Bank of India, at the Bankers Club, Chennai, 28 September 2010. * * * The assistance provided

More information

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Petra Gerlach-Kristen Hong Kong Institute of Economics and Business Strategy May, Abstract This paper uses unobserved components analysis to estimate

More information

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996 Economics 200 Macroeconomic Theory Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996 You have 1 hour to complete this exam. Answer any four questions you wish. 1. Suppose that an increase in consumer confidence

More information

Quarterly Currency Outlook

Quarterly Currency Outlook Mature Economies Quarterly Currency Outlook MarketQuant Research Writing completed on July 12, 2017 Content 1. Key elements of background for mature market currencies... 4 2. Detailed Currency Outlook...

More information

Models of the Neoclassical synthesis

Models of the Neoclassical synthesis Models of the Neoclassical synthesis This lecture presents the standard macroeconomic approach starting with IS-LM model to model of the Phillips curve. from IS-LM to AD-AS models without and with dynamics

More information

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender * COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY Adi Brender * 1 Key analytical issues for policy choice and design A basic question facing policy makers at the outset of a crisis

More information

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan The US recession that began in late 2007 had significant spillover effects to the rest

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory. Fall 2010

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory. Fall 2010 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory Fall 2010 ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

More information

Developments in inflation and its determinants

Developments in inflation and its determinants INFLATION REPORT February 2018 Summary Developments in inflation and its determinants The annual CPI inflation rate strengthened its upward trend in the course of 2017 Q4, standing at 3.32 percent in December,

More information

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking Michael Dotsey Senior Vice President and Director of Research Charles I. Plosser President and CEO Keith Sill Vice President and Director, Real-Time

More information

ANALYSES OF MODEL DERIVED IS LM,

ANALYSES OF MODEL DERIVED IS LM, ANALYSES OF MODEL DERIVED ISLM, AGGREGATE DEMANDAGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND BP CURVES* The group of the EPA World Model Economic Research Institute Economic Planning Agency * This paper was presented at the

More information

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking Michael Dotsey Executive Vice President and Director of Research Keith Sill Senior Vice President and Director, Real-Time Data Research Center Federal

More information

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1.1 WHAT IS VOLATILITY? It is useful to start with an explanation of what volatility is, at least for the purpose of clarifying the scope of this book. Volatility

More information

Business Cycles. (c) Copyright 1998 by Douglas H. Joines 1

Business Cycles. (c) Copyright 1998 by Douglas H. Joines 1 Business Cycles (c) Copyright 1998 by Douglas H. Joines 1 Module Objectives Know the causes of business cycles Know how interest rates are determined Know how various economic indicators behave over the

More information

Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis.

Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis. Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis. This paper takes the mini USAGE model developed by Dixon and Rimmer (2005) and modifies it in order to better mimic the

More information

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities - The models we studied earlier include only real variables and relative prices. We now extend these models to have

More information

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking Michael Dotsey Executive Vice President and Director of Research Keith Sill Senior Vice President and Director, Real-Time Data Research Center Federal

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

Near-Rationality and Inflation in Two Monetary Regimes

Near-Rationality and Inflation in Two Monetary Regimes Near-Rationality and Inflation in Two Monetary Regimes by Laurence Ball San Francisco Fed/Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Conference Structural Change and Monetary Policy March 3 4, 2000

More information

THE CHOICE BETWEEN ACCOMMODATIVE AND

THE CHOICE BETWEEN ACCOMMODATIVE AND Copyright License Agreement Presentation of the articles in the Topics in Middle Eastern and North African Economies was made possible by a limited license granted to Loyola University Chicago and Middle

More information

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India Michael Hutchison and Rajeswari Sengupta and Nirvikar Singh University of California Santa Cruz 3. March 2010 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/21106/

More information

Chapter 13 Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy

Chapter 13 Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy Chapter 13 Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy 1 Goals of Chapter 13 Two primary aspects of interdependence between economies of different nations International

More information

THE REACTION OF THE WIG STOCK MARKET INDEX TO CHANGES IN THE INTEREST RATES ON BANK DEPOSITS

THE REACTION OF THE WIG STOCK MARKET INDEX TO CHANGES IN THE INTEREST RATES ON BANK DEPOSITS OPERATIONS RESEARCH AND DECISIONS No. 1 1 Grzegorz PRZEKOTA*, Anna SZCZEPAŃSKA-PRZEKOTA** THE REACTION OF THE WIG STOCK MARKET INDEX TO CHANGES IN THE INTEREST RATES ON BANK DEPOSITS Determination of the

More information

14.02 Quiz 3. Time Allowed: 90 minutes. Fall 2012

14.02 Quiz 3. Time Allowed: 90 minutes. Fall 2012 14.02 Quiz 3 Time Allowed: 90 minutes Fall 2012 NAME: MIT ID: FRIDAY RECITATION: FRIDAY RECITATION TA: This quiz has a total of 3 parts/questions. The first part has 13 multiple choice questions where

More information

Growth and Productivity in Belgium

Growth and Productivity in Belgium Federal Planning Bureau Kunstlaan/Avenue des Arts 47-49, 1000 Brussels http://www.plan.be WORKING PAPER 5-07 Growth and Productivity in Belgium March 2007 Bernadette Biatour, bbi@plan.b Jeroen Fiers, jef@plan.

More information

M.I.T. LIBRARIES - DEWEY

M.I.T. LIBRARIES - DEWEY M.I.T. LIBRARIES - DEWEY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/consumptionrecesooblan working paper department

More information

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure Comment on Dewachter and Lyrio s "Learning, Macroeconomic Dynamics, and the Term Structure of Interest Rates" 1 by Jordi Galí (CREI, MIT, and NBER) August 2006 The present paper by Dewachter and Lyrio

More information

Article published in the Quarterly Review 2014:2, pp

Article published in the Quarterly Review 2014:2, pp Estimating the Cyclically Adjusted Budget Balance Article published in the Quarterly Review 2014:2, pp. 59-66 BOX 6: ESTIMATING THE CYCLICALLY ADJUSTED BUDGET BALANCE 1 In the wake of the financial crisis,

More information

What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates?

What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates? 1 What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates? This chapter does not provide a definitive or comprehensive definition of FEERs. Many discussions of the concept already exist (e.g., Williamson 1983, 1985,

More information

Explaining trends in UK business investment

Explaining trends in UK business investment By Hasan Bakhshi and Jamie Thompson of the Bank s Structural Economic Analysis Division. The ratio of business investment to GDP at constant prices has been trending upwards over the past two decades,

More information

Thai monetary policy transmission in an inflation targeting era

Thai monetary policy transmission in an inflation targeting era Journal of Asian Economics 18 (2007) 144 157 Thai monetary policy transmission in an inflation targeting era June Charoenseang, Pornkamol Manakit * Faculty of Economics, Chulalongkorn University, Bangkok

More information

Review of the literature on the comparison

Review of the literature on the comparison Review of the literature on the comparison of price level targeting and inflation targeting Florin V Citu, Economics Department Introduction This paper assesses some of the literature that compares price

More information

* + p t. i t. = r t. + a(p t

* + p t. i t. = r t. + a(p t REAL INTEREST RATE AND MONETARY POLICY There are various approaches to the question of what is a desirable long-term level for monetary policy s instrumental rate. The matter is discussed here with reference

More information

Lebanon: a macro-economic framework

Lebanon: a macro-economic framework Lebanon: a macro-economic framework This paper is intended to present a synthetic overview of the Lebanese economic situation and to assess the main options of macro-economic policies. Basic economic trends

More information

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Liuren Wu Baruch College, City University of New York Joint work with Jian Hua 6th Annual Conference of the Society for Financial Econometrics June 12-14,

More information

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD European Economic Review 42 (1998) 887 895 The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD Philip R. Lane *, Roberto Perotti Economics Department, Trinity College Dublin, Dublin 2, Ireland Columbia University,

More information

Topic 4: AS-AD Model Dealing with longer run; more variance; look at the role of wages and prices

Topic 4: AS-AD Model Dealing with longer run; more variance; look at the role of wages and prices Topic 4: AS-AD Model Dealing with longer run; more variance; look at the role of wages and prices Aggregate Supply-Aggregate Demand (AS-AD) Model: Diagram General price level measured by some price index

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Dynamic Macroeconomics Chapter 1 Introduction Dynamic Macroeconomics Prof. George Alogoskoufis Fletcher School, Tufts University and Athens University of Economics and Business 1.1 The Nature and Evolution of Macroeconomics

More information

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock Binh Le Thanh International University of Japan 15. August 2015 Online

More information

19.2 Exchange Rates in the Long Run Introduction 1/24/2013. Exchange Rates and International Finance. The Nominal Exchange Rate

19.2 Exchange Rates in the Long Run Introduction 1/24/2013. Exchange Rates and International Finance. The Nominal Exchange Rate Chapter 19 Exchange Rates and International Finance By Charles I. Jones International trade of goods and services exceeds 20 percent of GDP in most countries. Media Slides Created By Dave Brown Penn State

More information

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION by John B. Taylor Stanford University October 1997 This draft was prepared for the Robert A. Mundell Festschrift Conference, organized by Guillermo

More information

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve Capacity Utilization As a Real-Time Predictor of Manufacturing Output Evan F. Koenig Research Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve indices

More information

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve Econometrics II Fall 2017 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve The Case: Inflation tends to be pro-cycical with high inflation during times of

More information

Macroeconomics, Cdn. 4e (Williamson) Chapter 1 Introduction

Macroeconomics, Cdn. 4e (Williamson) Chapter 1 Introduction Macroeconomics, Cdn. 4e (Williamson) Chapter 1 Introduction 1) Which of the following topics is a primary concern of macro economists? A) standards of living of individuals B) choices of individual consumers

More information