Is contracting-out intensified placement services more effective than in-house production? Evidence from a randomized field experiment

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Is contracting-out intensified placement services more effective than in-house production? Evidence from a randomized field experiment"

Transcription

1 Is contracting-out intensified placement services more effective than in-house production? Evidence from a randomized field experiment Gerhard Krug Institute for Employment Research (IAB) and University of Erlangen-Nuremberg, Germany Gesine Stephan Institute for Employment Research (IAB) and University of Erlangen-Nuremberg, Germany January 2011 PRELIMINARY VERSION, PLEASE DO NOT CITE JEL Codes: J68, J64, J65 Keywords: Randomized field experiment, contracting-out, intensified placement services Summary: There is a longstanding debate on the advantages of quasi-markets for placement services for the unemployed compared to a public deliverance of such services. In Germany, the insurance-funded branch of the Public Employment Service (PES) usually assigns hard-to-place unemployed persons to private providers of intensified placement services after some months of unemployment. During 2009, a randomized field experiment has been implemented to investigate if such services might more effectively be provided in-house by the PES. We present first results from this experiment and show that half a year after random assignment, in-house provision resulted in a significantly lower share in unemployment and significantly fewer cumulated days in unemployment. The positive effect arises from exits into employment as well as from withdrawals from the labor market. However, in particular non-benefit recipients of in-house services withdraw more often from unemployment without finding a job. Acknowledgements: We are grateful to the SWA2 unit of the German Public Employment Service in particular Michael Irskens for provision of data from the TrEffeR data base and to the ITM unit of the Institute for Employment Research in particular Ali Athmani for supporting the implementation and maintenance of the EMu data base. 1

2 1 Introduction According to the OECD, public employment services (PES) are concerned with three main functions (OECD 2001). The first function is to provide income support to job seekers during the time of unemployment, the second one is concerned with the provision and improvement of skills or employability through labor market or job training programs and the third function is to provide job brokerage or placement services. In most European welfare states, placement services have typically been provided by public institutions. The state provision of such services has, however, been increasingly criticized for its lack of efficiency. State agencies delivering placement services are not subject to pressure from a competitive market and therefore are presumed to lack incentives to control costs, to provide quality of service and to respond to the consumers` needs (cf. Grout/Stevens 2003). Contracting-out has been proposed as a solution to this problem. In contrast to the in-house production of placement services contracting-out to private providers involves the creation of quasi-markets where several potential providers are competing. The competitive incentive structure of such quasi-markets is expected to lead to better placement services. In this paper we conduct an empirical comparison between two different programs that provide intensified placement services for hard-to-place unemployed persons. One program is based on the idea of contracting-out while the other one is based on the idea of in-house production of the PES. In both programs, intensified placement services consisted of measures to improve the employability of the unemployed, diminish and overcome their placement deficits, to place them into regular jobs, and to stabilize the newly established employment relationships. Our analysis draws on data from two German local labor market agencies, where a randomized field experiment has been conducted since March Our (preliminary) results provide some evidence that an in-house provision of such services has been more efficient within these agencies. The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 compares in-house provision and contracting-out of placement services, whereas Section 2.1 presents some theoretical considerations in favor of contracting-out and in-house production of placement services respectively. Section 2.2 complements these theoretical arguments with empirical findings. Section 3 presents a randomized field experiment implemented by the German Federal Employment Agency as the basis of our analysis. Section 3.1 describes the labor market political background of the experiment and Section 3.2 the design and implementation of the experiment. Section 3.3 sketches data, sample and outcome variables, while Section 3.4 discusses the parameter of interest. The results are presented in Section 4, followed by a discussion of potentially relevant factors that drive these results in Section 5. Section 6 presents some conclusions. 2

3 2 In-house provision or contracting-out of placement services Among OECD countries, Germany established the option of contracting-out placement services relatively late. Only since 1998, the Federal Employment Agency (FEA, Bundesagentur für Arbeit ) has been allowed to contract out parts of its placement services - like profiling and case management - to private providers. During 2002, the scope of contracting-out was widened and encompassed the complete placement service. Even though the details of this institutional framework were subject to several changes, it is basically still in place today. 2.1 Theoretical Considerations Economic theory points out several advantages in contracting-out to private firms providing placement services (cf. Bruttel 2005b). The first advantage is that private providers are often assessed to be more flexible than bureaucratic organizations, both in terms of the services they provide and in terms of personnel policy. Whereas private employment agencies are to a large degree restricted by formal rules and legal requirements this is not so much the case for their private counterparts. For example, the latter can acquire additional services such application training or psychosocial counseling on the market without the extensive tendering processes government agencies are subjected to. Also, private firms are often seen as more innovative than bureaucracies. When it comes to personnel policy, private providers are more flexible in using incentive contracts, for example containing performance payment. Such advantages should result in private providers to be more effective than public employment services. The second and potentially more important advantage is seen in the competitive environment that contracting-out takes place in and that should not only lead to more effective placement services but also to more efficient ones. However, even if it is private firms delivering placement services, one has to distinguish contracting-out from privatization. While the latter includes the transfer of physical assets from public to private ownership, contracting-out means that a set of economic activities previously not open to competition is now opened for it. Competition through contracting-out usually implies ex-ante competition and thus rather competition for a market in contrast to competition in a market. This market is denoted as a quasi-market (Bartlett/Le Grand 1993), because it differs from a conventional market: Whereas on the supply side several (for profit or non-profit) service providers are competing with each other, on the demand side consumer purchasing power is centralized within a single state purchasing agency (a variant we do not discuss further is consumer purchase power in the form of vouchers). In quasi-markets, competition is achieved through contract specifications and a bidding process similar to an auction. The lowest-price tenderer wins the right to supply for a specified period of time (Struyven/Steurs 2004). A state agency specifies the tasks to be performed by the private 3

4 providers within contracts. Therefore the state keeps a certain amount of control over the activities of private providers, which would not be the case if placement services were privatized (Domberger/Jensen 1997). Contracting-out will achieve its goal of enhancing efficiency of service provision as compared to monopolistic state providers only insofar as such a competitive quasi-market has successfully been established (Bartlett/Le Grand 1993). A prerequisite for this is that there should be no barriers to market entry and new providers have the opportunity to enter the market. Likewise providers should run the risk of making losses and consequently must face the danger to exit the market. Also prices in quasi-markets should reflect the interaction of supply and demand, which is usually achieved through negotiations between the state purchasing agency and potential service providers. However, as implementing a quasi-market is not trivial, contracting-out schemes have not always been able to deliver on promises. One major reason for this is made explicit by transaction-cost theoretic arguments (cf. Boardman/Hewitt 2004; Williamson 1985). From this perspective, quasi-markets or contracting-out need not always be the most efficient way to provide placement services. Assume bounded rationality, high uncertainty about the future state of the labor market, and high asset specificity. First, as employment services were exclusively provided by public services for a long time, the problem of a low level of ex ante competitiveness may arise: The number of potential providers can be rather small. Second, there might be certain investments that are specific to the transaction at hand (asset specificity). For instance, specialized software might be needed for delivering placement services, caseworkers have to have specific skills to provide the respective placement service, or relationships to potential employers have to be build and fostered. Such transaction specific investments make it costly for providers to change purchasers and vice versa. Also, writing and monitoring the contracts specifying the tasks and remuneration of private providers takes specific skills that have to be acquired or bought by the respective government agency. Given uncertainty of the development of the labor market, contracts that pay the provider on the basis of results might require a risk premium. Because of such transaction costs in some cases it might be more efficient to turn to inhouse production than to contract out placement services. There is also a second reason why efficiency gain from contracting-out might be lower than proponents of quasi-markets suggest. As an alternative to privatization or contracting-out recent reforms of the public employment services in Germany have replaced bureaucratic input-based administrative structures with output oriented performance management (Sol/Westerveld 2005). The PES has introduced management by objectives, where targets are negotiated between the public employment agency headquarters, regional headquarters and operating units. Objectives are instrumented through a number of performance indicators that are provided on a monthly 4

5 basis. At the executive level, wage premiums are awarded dependent on the degree of fulfillment of these objectives (Kaltenborn et al. 2010). Thus incentives for effective and efficient services are provided even in the absence of market competition. Furthermore, a critical aspect is the choice of an adequate incentive design for private providers (Bruttel 2005a). As contracting-out relies on incentive-induced behavior, there are serious consequences if incentives are not designed well. From a theoretical point of view, private providers have an incentive for creaming, accepting only individuals that have comparatively good labor market prospects. In contrast, parking of hard-to-place individuals at private providers might arise, if their integration proves too costly, thus they are not helped at all. While the reward of providers should mirror their net impact of their treatment, this information is generally not available, and gross integration rates are taken as a proxy for net impact. Finn (2007) distinguishes between three pure types of contracts: Pure pay-for-performance contracts, costimbursement contracts, and fixed-price contracts. In practice, often hybrid contracts are sought to balance incentives, viability and the delivery of particular services. A further important point is how performance of private providers is monitored and benchmarked (Bruttel 2005a). 2.2 Empirical evidence On the one hand, the comparative advantage of quasi-markets depends on the quality of its implementation within a given institutional framework. On the other hand, a crucial factor is how in-house production of placement services is organized and how contracts are designed. This makes the issue of effectiveness and efficiency an empirical question. However, empirical analysis comparing contracting-out and in-house production of placement services is scarce. One of the main difficulties is that most countries that implement a system of contracting-out, do so for the entire population of the unemployed (e.g. Australia), for all unemployed with certain characteristics (e.g. the hard-to-place in the Netherlands) or for all unemployed in a certain region (e.g. the 13 regional employment zones in Great Britain). This makes it hard to control for temporal or regional differences in labor market conditions that are also influencing the effectiveness of re-employment services. In the following we report empirical research on effectiveness, because to the best of our knowledge there are no empirical papers on efficiency in the context of placement services. For unemployment insurance recipients in Germany, the few existing econometric evaluation studies on private placement services for the unemployed use propensity score matching to find a comparison group of similar individuals that received placement services by the Federal Employment Agency. They indicate that private providers might at best be as effective as in-house production of placement services. Winterhager (2006a, 2006b, 2008) uses propensity score 5

6 matching and analyses assignments taking place during He finds significant small and negative short-term effects of private placement services on employment prospects of individuals assigned to a private placement agency. He attributes these results to deficits in contract management, where low prices were coupled with low quality. Similarly, WZB/infas (2006) find no effect on employment four month after assignment for unemployed assigned to private providers in Germany during 2003 and For recipients of means-tested benefits (unemployment benefit II) who were assigned to a private provider during 2005, the results of Bernhard/Wolff (2008) suggest that such an assignment is generally ineffective and in some subgroups even counterproductive regarding the goal of avoiding unemployment and benefit receipt. Nonetheless, for selected groups of job-seekers who are rather hard to place, they find the assignment to be effective. In a randomized experiment, Bennmarker et al. (2009) focus on younger unemployed under 25, immigrants and disabled in Sweden. They argue that the Swedish case has many features that are deemed and necessary for effective contracting-out. The authors apply instrumental variable methods, instrumenting private job placement through random assignment, while compliance with assignment was voluntary and amounted to 28 percent. However, they find no effects on employment probability for all three groups combined, even if there is evidence for positive effects on migrants and negative effects on young unemployed. These effects disappear over time, indicating that no long term effects were present. Hägglund (2009) presents experimental evidence on the effects of intensified placement efforts compared to standard services on subsequent employment and earnings of participants for Sweden. Due to small caseloads, he finds mainly insignificant effects. Nevertheless, intensified services seem to reduce unemployment among the treated compared to standard services (no comparison to contracting-out took place in this experiment). 3 The randomized field experiment 3.1 Background Since 2005, the German PES is organized in two branches, an insurance-funded branch for unemployment benefit recipients as well as job seekers not receiving unemployment benefits or social assistance, and a tax-funded branch for needy job seekers receiving social assistance. Our analysis is concerned with the insurance-funded branch only. As a standard procedure when individuals register as unemployed, caseworkers conduct a soft profiling of clients to identify their need of services. Individuals profiled as hard-to-place are expected to have difficulties regarding their abilities as well as their motivation in returning 6

7 to the labor market and are therefore supposed to benefit from intensified placement services. 1 Since 2008, the default treatment for this group of unemployed persons encompasses contracted -out services: Caseworkers are advised to assign hard-to-place unemployed to a private provider after four months of unemployment, where they receive intensified placement services. Whether an unemployed is in fact assigned is, however, at the discretion of the individual caseworker. The acronym for this program is Ganzil 2. To avoid creaming, private providers cannot refuse to enroll an unemployed person. Furthermore, assigned unemployed persons participation could reject enrollment at a private provider only for good reason, which would be very difficult to verify, thus non-compliance could result in a cut-off period from benefits. To ensure intensified placement services contracts contain a clause obligating the private providers to guarantee a minimum contact frequency. During the time period under investigation, assigned unemployed persons had a contact frequency of at least every two weeks (according to more recent contracts they had to be present at the provider for at least two days per week). Other than that, private providers are, however, free to choose what kind of placement services they want to provide and how. Usually, contracts between local labor market agencies and private providers encompass a period of two years. Payment for private providers consists of a fixed commencement component per unemployed (700 to 990 Euros) and a performance pay component (300 to 3000 Euros). One part of the performance payment is due after an unemployed has been in a regular job for three month, the other part after six month. The amount of the performance payment as well as a minimum rate of successful re-employment is negotiated between the responsible state agency and the respective provider. Usually the latter lies between 20 to 30 percent. If providers do not reach negotiated employment rates, a fine is imposed. It equals at least 1000 Euros per person, up to 50 percent of the case-wise performance pay component. During 2008, the German FEA started a pilot project to gain knowledge how the quality of services for hard-to-place unemployed individuals might be improved and how durable reemployment in the labor market might be fostered. More specific, a program was set up to test the effectiveness of an in-house provision of intensified placement services, compared to standard placement procedures including contracting-out. The program acronym is Pinguin 3. Under this program, unemployed hard-to-place individuals receiving unemployment benefits or registering for search without benefits are assigned to special teams of the local employment In German, these unemployed persons are denoted as Betreuungskunden or Kunden mit komplexen Profillagen. Ganzil is short for Ganzheitliche Integrationsleistungen für Arbeitslose mit Aktivierungs- und Unterstützungsbedarf sowie multiplen Vermittlungshemmnissen und geringen Integrationschancen. Pinguin is short for Projekt Interne ganzheitliche Unterstützung zur Integration im SGB III. 7

8 agency. To ensure intensified placement services, these Pinguin teams are characterized by a comparatively low caseload (1:40), more freedom in their allocation of working time and less restrictions in their placement activities. Furthermore, caseworkers have discretion in utilizing a fixed budget of around 600 Euro per participating person for active labor market programs (as short training programs or longer-term further training). This should set incentives for an efficient use of resources. As part of this pilot, during 2009 a field experiment was implemented within three local labor agencies. Individuals that were profiled as hard-to-place were randomly assigned to internal teams of these agencies that provided intensified placement services. The control group consists of individuals that received standard services of the public employment service, stipulating an assignment to a private placement agency providing intensified services ( Ganzil ). At each point of time, each agency had a contract with only one private provider of such services. We denote this group as the control group for reasons convenience only, as it is receiving a treatment, too. In our paper, we consider only those two agencies where caseworkers were instructed to assign all control group members to a private provider Design and implementation of the experiment A key feature of the experiment is random assignment of hard-to-place individuals in a control and a treatment group. Random assignment is based on a computer program EMu 5 that has been developed by the FEA for evaluation purposes and has been modified by the authors for the present field experiment. Caseworkers are instructed to call the program after unemployed person has been profiled as a hard-to-place person. 6 The electronic device has been available since April 17, As a first part of the pilot project, since 2008 in-house intensified placement services for hard-toplace unemployed persons were provided by three local agencies. In these agencies, however, no target group members were contracted out to private providers. Thus in an internal review, the FEA compared aggregate labor market results of participating regional agencies with synthetic agencies with similar labor market characteristics. It was noted, however, that this comparison lacked internal validity, as even similar labor markets will still inhibit different unobserved features. Within the third agency in the second part of the pilot, control group members received standard services, but assignment to a private provider was not mandatory. In consequence, only 50 percent of control group members actually received contracted-out services. EMu is short for Elektronischer Muenzwurf. As this part of the pilot project started in March 2009 already, between March and April 17 assignment was based on the year of birth: Individuals born in even years were assigned to the treatment group, while individuals born in odd years were assigned to the control group. As year of birth might, however, have an impact on the profiling result, a manipulation resistant mechanism was required (and found in the computer program). In our analysis, we will take into account only individuals that have been assigned by the computer tool. 8

9 Originally, participation in the project was restricted to individuals registering as unemployed (with unemployment benefit receipt or searching without benefit receipt), who were not registered at the public employment service during the previous six months. Unemployment benefit recipients should have a benefit entitlement length of at least three months. As the inflow in the project was, however, smaller than the FEA had expected, several individuals from the stock of unemployed had to be randomly assigned, too, to meet planned caseloads of caseworkers (1:40). In our analysis, we exclude all persons who entered unemployment before January 1, 2009 from the treatment and control group, as well as stock unemployed persons. The design of the experiment in both agencies differs only with regard to the timing of the intensified placement service. In Agency 1 (located in East Germany), random assignment took place immediately after registering as unemployed, in Agency 2 (located in West Germany), random assignment took place only four months after registering as unemployed. After randomization, caseworkers were instructed to immediately assign unemployed persons to a private placement agency or to internal teams of the agency. Both kinds of intensified placement services were delivered for a period of around eight months. Afterwards, individuals who were still registered as unemployed returned to the local employment agency to receive standard public employment services (i.e. not the intensified one as before). While the transition into in-house services occurred without frictions, there was usually a time gap between randomization and the first appointment with the private provider of intensified placement services. Several assigned control group members obviously de-registered from unemployment during this period. Furthermore, for several individuals in the control group we do not find information in administrative data that the program started, although they were unemployed for quite some time. For these individuals, we are still acquiring information if they rejected participation in the program or if the program was not offered to them. 3.3 Data, sample and outcome variables The results from the randomization computer program (EMu) were stored in a central database. We use the EMu data base to identify members of the control and of the treatment group. We match administrative information from the so called TrEffeR-data base (Stephan et al. 2006), which has been constructed for monitoring purposes of the FEA. The current version merges data flows from computer based operative systems of the Public Employment Service on periods of registered job search, registered unemployment, participation in labor market programs and employment that is subject to social security contributions. The version we use relies on information available in administrative systems on August 18, We utilize data until the end of June 2010, thus some of the information used in this paper is still preliminary. 9

10 The sample analyzed in this paper covers entries into the project since April 17, 2009, when the randomization computer program was implemented, until the end of December In Agency 3, entries into the projects started not until June As has already been mentioned, the analysis restricts itself on new entries into unemployment. Currently, we observe these individuals for a period of six months. Our sample covers around 720 observations in Agency 1, around 650 observations in Agency 2, and around 460 observations in Agency 3. The success of placement services can be measured in various ways. Until further information is available (e.g. on wages) we distinguish three outcome variables, capturing different aspects of successful placement. The first outcome variable is registered unemployment. This outcome variable is particularly important for the public employment agencies as every registered unemployed incurs costs at least through placement services. Reduction of unemployment therefore is an indicator for the cost reduction. The second outcome variable is regular employment (covered by social security; thus excluding marginal employment). The third outcome variable is not being registered as unemployed or employed, which in most cases results from labor market withdrawal. In fact, if caseworkers are pessimistic to find a suitable job for the respective unemployed, they have an incentive to convince him or her to deregister from unemployment, as this will improve monitoring results of his or her agency. This goes especially for unemployed without unemployment benefit receipt. We consider for each outcome variable the shares of persons in a given labor market status, as well as cumulated days in each of these labor market statuses at the end of our observation period. Suppose that we are interested in program effects on days in employment at the end of an observation period of several months. Then cumulated program effects are affected by lock-in effects of programs (the more, the longer the program and the shorter the observation period is). In contrast, program effects on shares at the end of the observation period indicate how cumulative effects may evolve further. Shares do not necessarily sum up to one, as individuals might at the same time be part-time employed and unemployed. We measure outcome variables since the day the random assignment took place. If the unemployment spell started after random assignment, outcome variables are computed since the day of unemployment entry. 3.4 Parameter of interest For a formal representation of the experiment, assume that Z i = 0 indicates that individual i is randomly assigned to standard services, mostly including assignment to a private provider, while Z i = 1 indicates an immediate assignment to the internal Pinguin teams. Accordingly, Y 0 and Y 1 are labor market results of individuals receiving standard treatment or the new services. Because of random assignment, E[Y i (0) Z=1] - E[Y i (0) Z=0] should equal zero, the differ- 10

11 ence E[Y i Z=1] - E[Y i Z=0] measures the causal effect of Z on Y (see for instance Duflo et al. 2008). This effect does, however, not mirror the effect of in-house production versus contracting-out, as Z i = 0 does not equal factual receipt of services of a private placement provider. As we will see, compliance reached 100 percent for in-house services, while nearly 80 percent of those assigned to a private provider actually started the program. But Z at least has a strong influence on the kind of services received, thus the difference displays the effect of an in-house treatment versus a likely assignment to a private provider. 7 We start with a simple representation of this effect, the difference in means in outcome variables between groups. To test for the similarity between those receiving standard services or intensified in-house services, the mean standardized bias (MSB) (Rosenbaum/Rubin 1983) is computed across a number of individual characteristics, variables describing the employment history and the calendar month of assignment. The standardized bias of a covariate is defined as the difference of means in the treated and matched comparison sample, divided by the square root of the average sample variance. For comparison using statistical matching techniques, Caliendo/Hujer (2006) summarize that most studies assess a MSB of 3 or 5 percent as acceptable. Even in randomized experiments some covariate imbalance can remain, especially at the start of a project, where the number of participants is still rather low. Thus we conduct an additional statistical matching analysis. In detail, we perform a radius matching (Dehejia/Wahba 2002) with a caliper of 0.05, which matches participants with synthetic comparison persons, composed of a weighted equivalent of all persons falling within the radius of their propensity score. Radius matching reduces the variance of estimated treatment effects by using information from several potential comparison persons to construct the counterfactual for each participant, while setting a caliper a maximum distance of propensity scores between treated and comparison persons avoids the risk of bad matches (Caliendo/Kopeinig 2008). For matching, we consider only individuals that are in common support. For these individuals the data indicate a positive probability of participating in standard services as well as in intensified in-house services. 4 Results Table 1 displays the distribution of characteristics for both groups under consideration. First, it should be noted that we find rather few significant differences across both randomly assigned groups. The main exception is the share of individuals without benefit receipt in Agency 1, 7 Note that we cannot apply instrumental variable methods as Bennmarker et al. (2010) did, as we have in fact not two, but three treatments. Those individuals not receiving private services do not take part in intensified in-house services (where compliance is 100 percent) instead, but receive standard services of the PES. 11

12 which is 12 percentage points higher in the group receiving in-house services. The mean standardized bias between both groups takes values of 7.1 and 10.0, respectively. Figure 1 shows the distribution of propensity scores, estimated probabilities to be assigned to treatment, which in consequence differs mostly in Agency 1. Thus we will additionally present results from a statistical matching analysis. [Figure 1 about here] [Table 1 about here] Regarding individual characteristics, both agencies obviously differ. In the East-German Agency 1, the share of hard-to-place individuals without unemployment benefit receipt amounts to 30 to 40 percent, while it is only around 10 percent in the West-German Agency 2. Furthermore, in particular in the East German agency, women constitute more than 60 percent of hard-to-place unemployment entries. The share of individuals looking for part-time work, the share of foreign nationality as well as the share without secondary schooling degree or vocational training is much lower in the East German agency than in the West German agency. In both agencies, individuals of age constitute around 40 percent of project participants. Table 2 informs about the share of individuals participating in active labor market programs. Most interestingly is the share of individuals in the control group in fact receiving placement services by a private provider ( Ganzil ). The share amounts to nearly 80 percent of the control group. Thus not all control group members actually received private placement services, even if they were considered to do so. We will return to this point in Section 5. [Table 2 about here] Table 3 contains the main results of our analysis, which are presented as the results from an ordinary least squares estimate (OLS). As the only explaining variable is assignment to intensified in-house services, this representation is identical to a descriptive analysis. The constant indicates mean values for unemployed persons that were assigned to contracted-out services, while the estimated coefficient for intensified in-house services shows the differential effect of internal services. Additionally, Figure 2 and 3 show how shares and cumulated days as well as the average treatment effects evolve over time. [Table 3 about here] [Figure 2 about here] [Figure 3 about here] For both agencies, we find that shares of individuals unemployed as well as cumulated days in unemployment are significantly lower across those receiving in-house produced services. The same holds for shares in employment and in another status (withdrawal from the labor market). 12

13 As Figures 1 and 2 shows, however, confidence bands are rather wide. Regarding the shares in a particular status after 180 days, we find only minor differences between the two agencies. Estimated effects are 17 and 18 percentage points less in unemployment for those assigned to the internal Pinguin teams, and correspondingly 7 percentage points more in regular employment and 10 to 12 percentage points more withdrawals from the labor market. However, as can be seen from Figure 2, in Agency 1 effects become significant much earlier after assignment took place. Regarding cumulated days in a respective status, effects are larger for every outcome variable in Agency 1 compared to Agency 2, too. Half a year after random assignment, all effects are significant in Agency 1. Unemployed persons receiving in-house services spent 23 days less in unemployment, 7 days more in regular employment and were 16 days more in another status. For Agency 2, while smaller, there is a significant negative effect on cumulated days in unemployment, and a significant positive effect on labor market withdrawal, too. the effect on cumulated days in employment is, however, positive, but not significant. As the distribution of characteristics differs partly between our control and treatment group, we additionally conduct a statistical matching analysis (see Section 3). As can be seen from the lowermost row in Table 1, balancing considerably improves through matching. After matching, we do not find any significant differences between the means of individual characteristics across both groups. The main results after matching are displayed in Table 4. Again, we conduct OLS estimates, but now weights are provided by the previously conducted matching analysis. For all three agencies, estimated effects are slightly smaller in size, but otherwise very similar to those obtained before balancing the covariates. 5 Discussion As our randomized experiment has shown, both public employment offices are more successful in delivering placement services than their private counterparts. Even given the theoretical considerations above, these results are a surprisingly strong argument for the in-house production of intensified placement services. In this section, drawing partly on extensive research conducted by SOFI (2010) 8, we want to present several considerations that will shed some light on why this notable effect arises. The study provides some important insights on important differences concerning the constraints framework contracted-out and in-house produced placement services 8 SOFI is short for Soziologisches Forschungsinstitut Göttingen. 13

14 operate under. These different constraints might in part drive the positive performance of public placement services as compared to their private counterparts. [Table 5 about here] A first point worth noting is that incentives to especially push non-benefit recipients to deregister from unemployment differ between public and private employment agencies. For private providers of placement services, it makes no difference whether an unemployed is receiving benefits or not. In each case, they receive a success premium if they find a (stable) employment opportunity for the individual assigned to them. In contrast, caseworkers within public employment agencies have a strong incentive to encourage non-benefit recipients to de-register from unemployment, because their performance indicators are mostly based on (registered) unemployment duration or status. To empirically test this argument, Table 5 interacts a dummy variable for no benefit receipt with the treatment dummy intensified in-house services. For Agency 1 at least, we find the expected tendency that effects on unemployment and on another status are much stronger for non-benefit recipients. This gives some weight to the assumption that part of the favorable results of this agency, which is the one with the stronger treatment effects, seems to stem from successfully pushing of non-benefit recipients out of registered unemployment rather than re-employing them. A second point explaining the success of in-hours produced placement services is that public providers face several transaction costs that are absent in the case of in-house provision. For example, the in-house version of intensified placement services follows immediately after randomization, because unemployed only have to be transferred from the regular caseworkers to the new intensified-placement teams in the same public employment agency. In contrast, there is often a considerable time gap for those who are randomized into the control status, during which the depreciation of the unemployed person`s human capital continues, making it harder to provide them with suitable job offers. Such a time gap could of course be shortened if the transition is better organized, but transaction costs are difficult to avoid altogether. Another form of transaction costs private providers have to deal with is the necessary investment of time and money into collecting information about the unemployed person`s qualifications and employment history. The respective information has already been gathered by the public employment agency, but private providers do not have access to this data, but have to invest time and financial resources to develop a data base of their own. In addition, as is usual in the German system of unemployment insurance, placement teams in public employment agencies are specialized at the supply side of the labor market. However, they can contact the local employer service for support, which is a department of the public agency responsible for the demand side, e.g. for the acquisition of vacancies. In contrast public providers are not served by the employer service, so 14

15 that individual caseworkers in private agencies have to concern themselves with the supply as well as the demand side. A third point is concerned with the use of active labor market programs such as wage subsidies and training programs. As can be seen in Table 2, 10 to 20 percent of the unemployed assigned to the Pinguin teams (the treatment group) participated in a short activation measure, for instance application trainings or short measures providing skills. In contrast only 3 to 6 percent of the unemployed in the control groups took part in such a measure. A major reason is that during the time period under investigation, private providers obtained the performance pay component for individuals that were re-integrated into employment without the help of subsidies or other labor market programs. This might have been a clear disadvantage of private providers compared to the public employment service. However, also the internal Pinguin-teams had to finance participation in such programs from the fixed budget that was available per unemployed person, which clearly made the use of such programs less attractive. A fourth point is the issue of effectiveness. A major argument supporting the implementation of quasi-markets, however, is that they improve cost-efficiency of placement services. To analyze this question we are currently trying to collect the necessary data. Only if the higher reemployment chances induced by in-house placement services are cost-effective is there a strong case for intensified in-house placement services. If in contrast in-house placement services raise re-employment chances but come with higher costs (e.g. because of additional caseworkers to guarantee the caseload of 1:40), the case is not as clear. Therefore, efficiency is a matter worth investigating further. Finally, up to now our analysis consider all individuals assigned to the treatment or the control group. We do not investigate the fact that around 20 percent of individuals assigned to standard services did in fact not receive services of a private provider, as they dropped out of registered unemployment before the planned program date or were not enrolled in such services at all. In our analysis, these persons are treated as successful re-employment by private providers. However, taking these persons into account would not change the general conclusions of this paper, e.g. that re-employment rates are higher for in-house produced placement services. consider three possible interpretations of why these persons did not receive services from a private provider: First, dropout may be a result of selection, where those individuals with the best labor market prospects drop out of unemployment in the aforementioned time gap between randomization and the first appointment with the private provider Second, participating in a program provided by a private provider might have a threat effect on individuals assigned to such a program, inducing them to de-register from unemployment. In both cases the conclusion remains that in-house production is more effective. Third, caseworkers may despite instructions provided refuse to enroll particular hard-to-place unemployed persons into the Ganzil pro- 15

16 gram. This might have lead to a lower performance of private providers, if those not enrolled were unemployed with particularly good employment prospects. As our current data does contain only data on program participation, but not on planned program participation, we are currently gathering additional information on planned program starts (regardless from the fact that the program took place in fact). In a next step we are going to conduct some survival time analysis to gain some deeper understanding of these processes. 6 Conclusions In this paper, we investigated whether in-house production is more effective than contracting of intensified placement services. We started out with some theoretical considerations about conditions for contracting-out to be an effective and efficient strategy. What is considered most important is the creation of quasi-markets, where several potential providers of placement services are competing with each through contract specifications in a bidding process. In-house production, however, can also have some advantages, especially when high transaction costs are involved. Analyzing data from a randomized field experiment in two German cities we estimated treatment effects indicating higher re-employment chances and shorter unemployment durations for unemployed subjected to in-house placement services. This relative success of public employment offices is due to several important differences that are only in part inherent aspects of inhouse production and contracting-out. Such differences include different incentive structures, for example the treatment of non-benefit recipients or the usage of active labor market programs to activate and/or train the unemployed. They also entail frictions in the transfer of unemployed from the public employment agencies, where they have to register as unemployed, to the private counterparts. Finally, they comprise transaction specific investments for private providers regarding the collection of information on the unemployment and on vacancies in the local labor market. Taken together, the results of our analysis and the observed differences regarding the implementation of in-house and contracted-out placement services let us conclude that intensified public placement services can be more effective than private ones. However, their comparative advantage depends in part on several factors restricting the effectiveness of private providers. If those factors were to be eliminated, the relative performance of private placement services might improve. Finally, our experimental design ensures internal validity of the results, in other words, our estimates are not biased by unobserved characteristics of the unemployed or their casework- 16

17 ers. However, we cannot claim external validity of our results, as we investigate only two agencies and two associated private providers of placement services. 17

18 References Bartlett, W., Le Grand, J. (1993), The theory of quasi-markets, in: Le Grand, J., Bartlett, W., (eds.) Quasi-markets and social policy. Macmillan Press, Basingstoke, UK, Bennmarker, H., Grönqvist, E., Öckert, B. (2009), Effects of outsourcing employment services: evidence from a randomized experiment, IFAU Working Paper 2009/23. Bernhard, S., Wolff, J. (2008), Contracting out placement services in Germany: Is assignment to private providers effective for needy job-seekers?, IAB Discussion Paper 5/2008. Boardman, A. E., Hewitt, E. S. (2004), Problems with contracting out government services: Lessons from orderly services at SCGH, Industrial and Corporate Change 13, Bruttel, O. (2005a), Contracting-out and Governance Mechanisms in the Public Employment Services, WZB Discussion Paper SP I Bruttel, O. (2005b), Privatisierung der Bundesagentur für Arbeit Perspektive für Deutschland? Zeitschrift für Sozialreform 51, Caliendo, M., Hujer, R. (2006), The microeconometric estimation of treatment effects An overview, Allgemeines Statistisches Archiv 90, Caliendo, M., Kopeinig, S. (2008), Some practical guidance for the implementation of propensity score matching, Journal of Economic Surveys 22, Dehejia, R. H., Wahba, S. (2002), Propensity score matching methods for nonexperimental causal studies, The Review of Economics and Statistics 84, Domberger S., Jensen P. (1997), Contracting out by the public sector: theory, evidence, prospects, Oxford Review of Economic Policy 13, Duflo, E., Glennerster, R., Kremer, M., (2008), Using Randomization in Development Economics Research: A Toolkit, Handbook of Development Economics 4, Finn, D. (2007), Contracting Out Welfare to Work in the USA: Delivery Lessons, University of Portsmouth, Department for Work and Pensions Research Report 466. Grout P. A., Stevens M. (2003), The Assessment: Financing and Managing Public Services, Oxford Review of Economic Policy 19, Hägglund, P. (2009), Experimental Evidence from Intensified Placement Efforts among Unemploymed in Sweden, IFAU Working Paper 2009/16. Kaltenborn, B., Wielange, N., Bothmer, A. Henkel, I. A. (2010), Zielsteuerung in der Arbeitsverwaltung ein europäischer Vergleich, Le Grand, J., Bartlett, W. (eds.) (1993), Quasi-markets and social policy. Macmillan Press, Basingstoke, UK. OECD (2001), Labour Market Policies and the Public Employment Service, Prague Conference, July Rosenbaum, P. R., Rubin, D. B. (1983), The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects, Biometrika 70, SOFI (2010), Evaluation/Implementationsanalyse zum Projekt Interne ganzheitliche Unterstützung zur Integration im SGB III (PINGUIN), 1. Zwischenbericht, mimeo. Sol, E., Westerveld, M. (eds.) (2005), Contractualism in Employment Services. A New Form of Welfare State Governance, Den Hague: Kluwer Law International. 18

Is contracting-out intensified placement services more effective than in-house production? Evidence from a randomized field experiment

Is contracting-out intensified placement services more effective than in-house production? Evidence from a randomized field experiment Is contracting-out intensified placement services more effective than in-house production? Evidence from a randomized field experiment Gerhard Krug Institute for Employment Research (IAB) and University

More information

econstor zbw

econstor zbw econstor www.econstor.eu Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft The Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Krug, Gerhard;

More information

2. Temporary work as an active labour market policy: Evaluating an innovative activation programme for disadvantaged youths

2. Temporary work as an active labour market policy: Evaluating an innovative activation programme for disadvantaged youths 2. Temporary work as an active labour market policy: Evaluating an innovative activation programme for disadvantaged youths Joint work with Jochen Kluve (Humboldt-University Berlin, RWI and IZA) and Sandra

More information

The Relative Effectiveness of Selected Active Labour Market Programmes and the Common Support Problem

The Relative Effectiveness of Selected Active Labour Market Programmes and the Common Support Problem DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3767 The Relative Effectiveness of Selected Active Labour Market Programmes and the Common Support Problem Gesine Stephan André Pahnke October 2008 Forschungsinstitut

More information

IAB Discussion Paper 12/2008

IAB Discussion Paper 12/2008 IAB Discussion Paper 12/2008 Beiträge zum wissenschaftlichen Dialog aus dem Institut für Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung The effects of active labor market s in Germany An investigation using different

More information

The impact of monitoring and sanctioning on unemployment exit and job-finding rates

The impact of monitoring and sanctioning on unemployment exit and job-finding rates Duncan McVicar Queen s University Belfast, UK The impact of monitoring and sanctioning on unemployment exit and Job search monitoring and benefit sanctions generally reduce unemployment duration and boost

More information

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF RISING THE RETIREMENT AGE: LESSONS FROM THE SEPTEMBER 1993 LAW*

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF RISING THE RETIREMENT AGE: LESSONS FROM THE SEPTEMBER 1993 LAW* THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF RISING THE RETIREMENT AGE: LESSONS FROM THE SEPTEMBER 1993 LAW* Pedro Martins** Álvaro Novo*** Pedro Portugal*** 1. INTRODUCTION In most developed countries, pension systems have

More information

BEAUTIFUL SERBIA. Holger Bonin (IZA Bonn) and Ulf Rinne* (IZA Bonn) Draft Version February 17, 2006 ABSTRACT

BEAUTIFUL SERBIA. Holger Bonin (IZA Bonn) and Ulf Rinne* (IZA Bonn) Draft Version February 17, 2006 ABSTRACT BEAUTIFUL SERBIA Holger Bonin (IZA Bonn) and Ulf Rinne* (IZA Bonn) Draft Version February 17, 2006 ABSTRACT This paper evaluates Beautiful Serbia, an active labor market program operating in Serbia and

More information

Evaluating Monitoring Unemployed Workers Using Experiment. Controlled Social Experiment. Gerard J. van den Berg

Evaluating Monitoring Unemployed Workers Using Experiment. Controlled Social Experiment. Gerard J. van den Berg Evaluating the Monitoring of Unemployed Workers Using a Controlled Social Experiment (Alexander von Humboldt Professor, Mannheim) AIM: study effects of C&M on individual outcomes: exit rate to work, outcomes

More information

Introduction to De Economist Special Issue Retirement and Employment Opportunities for Older Workers

Introduction to De Economist Special Issue Retirement and Employment Opportunities for Older Workers De Economist (2013) 161:219 223 DOI 10.1007/s10645-013-9214-4 Introduction to De Economist Special Issue Retirement and Employment Opportunities for Older Workers Pierre Koning Received: 10 July 2013 /

More information

Long-term unemployment: Council Recommendation frequently asked questions

Long-term unemployment: Council Recommendation frequently asked questions EUROPEAN COMMISSION MEMO Brussels, 15 February 2016 Long-term unemployment: Council Recommendation frequently asked questions Why a focus on long-term unemployment? The number of long-term unemployed persons

More information

The Effectiveness of Targeted Wage Subsidies for Hard-to-Place Workers

The Effectiveness of Targeted Wage Subsidies for Hard-to-Place Workers The Effectiveness of Targeted Wage Subsidies for Hard-to-Place Workers Ursula Jaenichen, Gesine Stephan Institute for Employment Research, Nuremberg May 2007 Keywords: Targeted wage subsidies, evaluation

More information

Dynamic Evaluation of Job Search Training

Dynamic Evaluation of Job Search Training Dynamic Evaluation of Job Search Training Stephen Kastoryano Bas van der Klaauw September 20, 2010 Abstract This paper evaluates job search training for unemployment insurance recipients. We use a unique

More information

Data and Methods in FMLA Research Evidence

Data and Methods in FMLA Research Evidence Data and Methods in FMLA Research Evidence The Family and Medical Leave Act (FMLA) was passed in 1993 to provide job-protected unpaid leave to eligible workers who needed time off from work to care for

More information

Evaluating Search Periods for Welfare Applicants: Evidence from a Social Experiment

Evaluating Search Periods for Welfare Applicants: Evidence from a Social Experiment Evaluating Search Periods for Welfare Applicants: Evidence from a Social Experiment Jonneke Bolhaar, Nadine Ketel, Bas van der Klaauw ===== FIRST DRAFT, PRELIMINARY ===== Abstract We investigate the implications

More information

How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment

How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 4691 How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment Jan C. van Ours Sander Tuit January 2010 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit

More information

Results from the South Carolina ERA Site

Results from the South Carolina ERA Site November 2005 The Employment Retention and Advancement Project Results from the South Carolina ERA Site Susan Scrivener, Gilda Azurdia, Jocelyn Page This report presents evidence on the implementation

More information

How do women with a partner respond to activation policies? Household roles and employment effects of training and workfare in Germany

How do women with a partner respond to activation policies? Household roles and employment effects of training and workfare in Germany How do women with a partner respond to activation policies? Household roles and employment effects of training and workfare in Germany Eva Kopf and Cordula Zabel Preliminary version -Please do not cite

More information

IAB Discussion Paper 20/2008

IAB Discussion Paper 20/2008 IAB Discussion Paper 20/2008 Beiträge zum wissenschaftlichen Dialog aus dem Institut für Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung Start me up The effectiveness of a self-employment programme for needy unemployed

More information

Session 5:Training opportunities for quality transitions

Session 5:Training opportunities for quality transitions Session 5:Training opportunities for quality transitions Chair: Anneleen FORRIER, K.U. Leuven/Lessius Antwerpen, Belgium Joost BOLLENS - K.U. Leuven, Belgium Lars SKIPPER - Aarhus University, Denmark Michael

More information

Mutual Learning Programme

Mutual Learning Programme Mutual Learning Programme DG Employment, Social Affairs and Inclusion Peer Country Comments Paper- Denmark Prevention and integration The Danish approach to long-term unemployment Peer Review on Approaches

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

Explaining the Employability Gap of Short-term and Long-term Unemployed Persons

Explaining the Employability Gap of Short-term and Long-term Unemployed Persons Explaining the Employability Gap of Short-term and Long-term Unemployed Persons Stephan L. Thomsen, Otto-von-Guericke-University, Magdeburg & ZEW, Mannheim June 4, 2008 Abstract This paper analyzes the

More information

CHAPTER 13. Duration of Spell (in months) Exit Rate

CHAPTER 13. Duration of Spell (in months) Exit Rate CHAPTER 13 13-1. Suppose there are 25,000 unemployed persons in the economy. You are given the following data about the length of unemployment spells: Duration of Spell (in months) Exit Rate 1 0.60 2 0.20

More information

Lessons from research on unemployment policies

Lessons from research on unemployment policies Econ 4715 Lecture 5 Lessons from research on unemployment policies Simen Markussen Insurance vs. incentives Policy makers face difficult trade-offs when designing unemployment insurance Insurance vs. incentives

More information

Déjà Vu? Short Term Training in Germany and

Déjà Vu? Short Term Training in Germany and DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3540 Déjà Vu? Short Term Training in Germany 1980 1992 and 00 03 Bernd Fitzenberger Olga Orlyanskaya Aderonke Osikominu Marie Waller June 08 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft

More information

Evaluation of the effects of the active labour measures on reducing unemployment in Romania

Evaluation of the effects of the active labour measures on reducing unemployment in Romania National Scientific Research Institute for Labor and Social Protection Evaluation of the effects of the active labour measures on reducing unemployment in Romania Speranta PIRCIOG, PhD Senior Researcher

More information

Annex 1 EUROFRAME-EFN Autumn 2007 Report. Introduction of minimum wages in Germany: Coverage and consequences

Annex 1 EUROFRAME-EFN Autumn 2007 Report. Introduction of minimum wages in Germany: Coverage and consequences Annex 1 EUROFRAME-EFN Autumn 2007 Report Introduction of minimum wages in Germany: Coverage and consequences Microeconomic evidence based on the SOEP Karl Brenke, Christian Dreger, DIW Berlin Key words:

More information

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance Benefits Nynke de Groot Bas van der Klaauw July 14, 2014 Abstract This paper exploits a substantial reform of the Dutch UI law to

More information

Unemployment, tax evasion and the slippery slope framework

Unemployment, tax evasion and the slippery slope framework MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Unemployment, tax evasion and the slippery slope framework Gaetano Lisi CreaM Economic Centre (University of Cassino) 18. March 2012 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/37433/

More information

German Self-Employment Programmes for the Unemployed. by Kurt Vogler-Ludwig

German Self-Employment Programmes for the Unemployed. by Kurt Vogler-Ludwig Discussion Paper German Self-Employment Programmes for the Unemployed Contribution to the European Employment Observatory Spring Review 2005 by Kurt Vogler-Ludwig Introduction... 1 Features of the self-employment

More information

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion Luis Diaz-Serrano and Donal O Neill National University of Ireland Maynooth, Department of Economics Abstract In this paper

More information

The role of regional, national and EU budgets in the Economic and Monetary Union

The role of regional, national and EU budgets in the Economic and Monetary Union SPEECH/06/620 Embargo: 16h00 Joaquín Almunia European Commissioner for Economic and Monetary Policy The role of regional, national and EU budgets in the Economic and Monetary Union 5 th Thematic Dialogue

More information

Identifying Effect Heterogeneity to Improve the Efficiency of Job Creation Schemes in Germany

Identifying Effect Heterogeneity to Improve the Efficiency of Job Creation Schemes in Germany Identifying Effect Heterogeneity to Improve the Efficiency of Job Creation Schemes in Germany Marco Caliendo, Reinhard Hujer and Stephan L. Thomsen DIW, Berlin and IZA, Bonn J.W.Goethe-University, Frankfurt/Main,

More information

Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans

Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans Attributes Influencing Likelihood and Implications for Consumer- Driven Approaches Wendy Lynch, PhD Harold H. Gardner, MD Nathan Kleinman, PhD 415 W. 17th St.,

More information

Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans: Attributes Influencing Likelihood and Implications for Consumer-Driven Approaches

Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans: Attributes Influencing Likelihood and Implications for Consumer-Driven Approaches Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans: Attributes Influencing Likelihood and Implications for Consumer-Driven Approaches Wendy D. Lynch, Ph.D. Harold H. Gardner, M.D. Nathan L. Kleinman, Ph.D. Health

More information

Linking Microsimulation and CGE models

Linking Microsimulation and CGE models International Journal of Microsimulation (2016) 9(1) 167-174 International Microsimulation Association Andreas 1 ZEW, University of Mannheim, L7, 1, Mannheim, Germany peichl@zew.de ABSTRACT: In this note,

More information

Valuation of Businesses

Valuation of Businesses Convenience translation from German into English Professional Guidelines of the Expert Committee on Business Administration of the Institute for Business Economics, Tax Law and Organization of the Austrian

More information

Dynamic Evaluation of Job Search Assistance

Dynamic Evaluation of Job Search Assistance DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 5424 Dynamic Evaluation of Job Search Assistance Stephen Kastoryano Bas van der Klaauw January 2011 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study

More information

Contracts, Reference Points, and Competition

Contracts, Reference Points, and Competition Contracts, Reference Points, and Competition Behavioral Effects of the Fundamental Transformation 1 Ernst Fehr University of Zurich Oliver Hart Harvard University Christian Zehnder University of Lausanne

More information

An ex-post analysis of Italian fiscal policy on renovation

An ex-post analysis of Italian fiscal policy on renovation An ex-post analysis of Italian fiscal policy on renovation Marco Manzo, Daniela Tellone VERY FIRST DRAFT, PLEASE DO NOT CITE June 9 th 2017 Abstract In June 2012, the share of dwellings renovation costs

More information

Ontario Works Program

Ontario Works Program MINISTRY OF COMMUNITY AND SOCIAL SERVICES Ontario Works Program 3.02 Short-term financial assistance to allow for a basic standard of living has historically been provided under the General Welfare Assistance

More information

Balancing Activation and Protection Learning from Active Social Policies in the European Union and the United States

Balancing Activation and Protection Learning from Active Social Policies in the European Union and the United States uman evelopment conomics, urope and Central Asia Region Balancing Activation and Protection Learning from Active Social Policies in the uropean Union and the United States Arup Banerji Sofia, Bulgaria

More information

Key issues in reshaping the public debt management framework of the new EU members. Lars Boman Swedish National Debt Office Rome, 27 November 2003

Key issues in reshaping the public debt management framework of the new EU members. Lars Boman Swedish National Debt Office Rome, 27 November 2003 Key issues in reshaping the public debt management framework of the new EU members Lars Boman Swedish National Debt Office Rome, 27 November 2003 Key issues Foreign currency, domestic currency and the

More information

Does Work for the Dole work?*

Does Work for the Dole work?* Does Work for the Dole work?* Jeff Borland (University of Melbourne) and Yi-Ping Tseng (University of Melbourne) July 2004 Abstract This study examines the effect of a community-based work experience program

More information

How can we assess the policy effectiveness of randomized control trials when people don t comply?

How can we assess the policy effectiveness of randomized control trials when people don t comply? Zahra Siddique University of Reading, UK, and IZA, Germany Randomized control trials in an imperfect world How can we assess the policy effectiveness of randomized control trials when people don t comply?

More information

Role of Foreign Direct Investment in Knowledge Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence from Korean Firms Patent and Patent Citations

Role of Foreign Direct Investment in Knowledge Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence from Korean Firms Patent and Patent Citations THE JOURNAL OF THE KOREAN ECONOMY, Vol. 5, No. 1 (Spring 2004), 47-67 Role of Foreign Direct Investment in Knowledge Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence from Korean Firms Patent and Patent Citations Jaehwa

More information

Assessment of Active Labour Market Policies in Bulgaria: Evidence from Survey Data

Assessment of Active Labour Market Policies in Bulgaria: Evidence from Survey Data Assessment of Active Labour Market Policies in Bulgaria: Evidence from Survey Data Atanas Atanassov * Summary: The paper presents the main results of a research that focuses on the subsequent assessment

More information

Long-Term Effects of Job-Search Assistance: Experimental Evidence Using Administrative Tax Data *

Long-Term Effects of Job-Search Assistance: Experimental Evidence Using Administrative Tax Data * Long-Term Effects of Job-Search Assistance: Experimental Evidence Using Administrative Tax Data * Day Manoli Marios Michaelides Ankur Patel UT-Austin and NBER University of Cyprus and US Treasury IMPAQ

More information

1 Active Labour Market Policy

1 Active Labour Market Policy Active Labour Market Policy Lecture notes Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003 1 Active Labour Market Policy Question: What do we mean ALMP? ² Measures to improve the functioning of the labour

More information

International Accounting Standard 36. Impairment of Assets

International Accounting Standard 36. Impairment of Assets International Accounting Standard 36 Impairment of Assets CONTENTS paragraphs BASIS FOR CONCLUSIONS ON IAS 36 IMPAIRMENT OF ASSETS INTRODUCTION SCOPE MEASURING RECOVERABLE AMOUNT Recoverable amount based

More information

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance Benefits Nynke de Groot Bas van der Klaauw February 6, 2019 Abstract This paper uses a difference-in-differences approach exploiting

More information

Active Unemployment Insurance Evidence from Scandinavia Knut Røed

Active Unemployment Insurance Evidence from Scandinavia Knut Røed Active Unemployment Insurance Evidence from Scandinavia Knut Røed Stiftelsen Frischsenteret for samfunnsøkonomisk forskning Ragnar for Economic Research www.frisch.uio.no A welfare state dilemma? Generous

More information

The Interaction of Workforce Development Programs and Unemployment Compensation by Individuals with Disabilities in Washington State

The Interaction of Workforce Development Programs and Unemployment Compensation by Individuals with Disabilities in Washington State External Papers and Reports Upjohn Research home page 2011 The Interaction of Workforce Development Programs and Unemployment Compensation by Individuals with Disabilities in Washington State Kevin Hollenbeck

More information

In this issue: Fair value measurement of financial assets and financial liabilities. Welcome to the series

In this issue: Fair value measurement of financial assets and financial liabilities. Welcome to the series IFRS FOR INVESTMENT FUNDS September 2012, Issue 5 Welcome to the series Our series of IFRS for Investment Funds publications addresses practical application issues that investment funds may encounter when

More information

Investing in Youth. Norway. Oslo, 5 April, 2018

Investing in Youth. Norway. Oslo, 5 April, 2018 Investing in Youth Norway Oslo, 5 April, 2018 @OECD_Social Stefano Scarpetta, Director Stéphane Carcillo, Head of the Jobs and Income Division Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs Part

More information

econstor Make Your Publications Visible.

econstor Make Your Publications Visible. econstor Make Your Publications Visible. A Service of Wirtschaft Centre zbwleibniz-informationszentrum Economics Cribb, Jonathan; Emmerson, Carl; Tetlow, Gemma Working Paper Labour supply effects of increasing

More information

Reemployment Bonuses, Unemployment Duration, and Job Match Quality

Reemployment Bonuses, Unemployment Duration, and Job Match Quality Reemployment Bonuses, Unemployment Duration, and Job Match Quality Taehyun Ahn School of Economics, Sogang University Seoul 121-742, Korea ahn83@sogang.ac.kr, tahn.83@gmail.com July 2016 ABSTRACT This

More information

Analyzing the Anticipation of Treatments using Data on Notification Dates

Analyzing the Anticipation of Treatments using Data on Notification Dates Analyzing the Anticipation of Treatments using Data on Notification Dates Bruno Crépon Marc Ferracci Grégory Jolivet Gerard van den Berg CREST-INSEE University of Marne-la-Vallée University of Bristol

More information

Transition Between Labour Market Statuses a Comparison Between the LFS and the Labour Market Account (LMA) in Denmark

Transition Between Labour Market Statuses a Comparison Between the LFS and the Labour Market Account (LMA) in Denmark Transition Between Labour Market Statuses a Comparison Between the LFS and the Labour Market Account (LMA) in Denmark Purpose and Background Which labour market statuses are difficult to capture in the?

More information

Growth Accounting: A European Comparison

Growth Accounting: A European Comparison Cyprus Economic Policy Review, Vol. 6, No. 2, p.p. 67-79 (212) 145-4561 67 Growth Accounting: A European Comparison Theofanis Mamuneas and Elena Ketteni Department of Economics and Economic Research Centre

More information

RANDOMIZED TRIALS Technical Track Session II Sergio Urzua University of Maryland

RANDOMIZED TRIALS Technical Track Session II Sergio Urzua University of Maryland RANDOMIZED TRIALS Technical Track Session II Sergio Urzua University of Maryland Randomized trials o Evidence about counterfactuals often generated by randomized trials or experiments o Medical trials

More information

ETLA Working Papers. The Effects of an Education-Leave Program on Educational Attainment and Labor-Market Outcomes. No. 56.

ETLA Working Papers. The Effects of an Education-Leave Program on Educational Attainment and Labor-Market Outcomes. No. 56. ETLA Working Papers No. 56 14 February 2018 Antti Kauhanen The Effects of an Education-Leave Program on Educational Attainment and Labor-Market Outcomes Suggested citation: Kauhanen, Antti (14.2.2018).

More information

The Role of APIs in the Economy

The Role of APIs in the Economy The Role of APIs in the Economy Seth G. Benzell, Guillermo Lagarda, Marshall Van Allstyne June 2, 2016 Abstract Using proprietary information from a large percentage of the API-tool provision and API-Management

More information

Basic Income - With or Without Bismarckian Social Insurance?

Basic Income - With or Without Bismarckian Social Insurance? Basic Income - With or Without Bismarckian Social Insurance? Andreas Bergh September 16, 2004 Abstract We model a welfare state with only basic income, a welfare state with basic income and Bismarckian

More information

Alex Morgano Ladji Bamba Lucas Van Cleef Computer Skills for Economic Analysis E226 11/6/2015 Dr. Myers. Abstract

Alex Morgano Ladji Bamba Lucas Van Cleef Computer Skills for Economic Analysis E226 11/6/2015 Dr. Myers. Abstract 1 Alex Morgano Ladji Bamba Lucas Van Cleef Computer Skills for Economic Analysis E226 11/6/2015 Dr. Myers Abstract This essay focuses on the causality between specific questions that deal with people s

More information

Idiosyncratic Volatility and Earnout-Financing

Idiosyncratic Volatility and Earnout-Financing Idiosyncratic Volatility and Earnout-Financing Leonidas Barbopoulos a,x Dimitris Alexakis b Extended Abstract Reflecting the importance of information asymmetry in Mergers and Acquisitions (M&As), there

More information

Mutual Learning Programme

Mutual Learning Programme Mutual Learning Programme DG Employment, Social Affairs and Inclusion Peer Country Comments Paper Lithuania Time to change traditional approaches to the more innovative ones? Peer Review on Approaches

More information

CHAPTER 17 INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT. by Alistair Byrne, PhD, CFA

CHAPTER 17 INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT. by Alistair Byrne, PhD, CFA CHAPTER 17 INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT by Alistair Byrne, PhD, CFA LEARNING OUTCOMES After completing this chapter, you should be able to do the following: a Describe systematic risk and specific risk; b Describe

More information

Credit Risk in Banking

Credit Risk in Banking Credit Risk in Banking TYPES OF INDEPENDENT VARIABLES Sebastiano Vitali, 2017/2018 Goal of variables To evaluate the credit risk at the time a client requests a trade burdened by credit risk. To perform

More information

The Labor Market Effects of U.S. Reemployment Policy: Lessons from an Analysis of Four Programs during the Great Recession

The Labor Market Effects of U.S. Reemployment Policy: Lessons from an Analysis of Four Programs during the Great Recession The Labor Market Effects of U.S. Reemployment Policy: Lessons from an Analysis of Four Programs during the Great Recession Marios Michaelides University of Cyprus mariosm@ucy.ac.cy Peter Mueser (corresponding

More information

Topic 2.3a - Social Programs. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370. Alternative Income Maintenance Schemes

Topic 2.3a - Social Programs. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370. Alternative Income Maintenance Schemes opic 2.3a - Social Programs Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370 Alternative Income Maintenance Schemes Governments in Canada spend over 10 percent of GDP on income maintenance schemes he effectiveness

More information

European Foundations: report on Top 50 ranking and database

European Foundations: report on Top 50 ranking and database W W W. W A T S O N W Y A T T. C O M European Foundations: report on Top 50 ranking and database A joint research project by Watson Wyatt and Prof. Elroy Dimson of London Business School February 2007 Content

More information

Get Training or Wait? Long Run Employment Effects of Training Programs for the Unemployed in West Germany

Get Training or Wait? Long Run Employment Effects of Training Programs for the Unemployed in West Germany Get Training or Wait? Long Run Employment Effects of Training Programs for the Unemployed in West Germany BERND FITZENBERGER, Goethe University Frankfurt, ZEW, IZA, IFS Ronke Osikominu, Robert Völter,

More information

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang Pre-print version: Tang, Tuck Cheong. (00). "Does exchange rate volatility matter for the balancing item of balance of payments accounts in Japan? an empirical note". Rivista internazionale di scienze

More information

Data Warehouse Monitoring in the Public Employment Service: Austria Statements and Comments

Data Warehouse Monitoring in the Public Employment Service: Austria Statements and Comments Data Warehouse Monitoring in the Public Employment Service: Austria Statements and Comments Stephen Lissenburgh Employment Research Policy Studies Institute This paper comments on Data Warehouse monitoring

More information

LABOUR MARKET. People in the labour market employment People in the labour market unemployment Labour market policy and public expenditure

LABOUR MARKET. People in the labour market employment People in the labour market unemployment Labour market policy and public expenditure . LABOUR MARKET People in the labour market employment People in the labour market unemployment Labour market policy and public expenditure Labour market People in the labour market employment People

More information

The JOBS Evaluation: Monthly Participation Rates in Three Sites and Factors Affecting Participation Levels in Welfare-to-Work Programs

The JOBS Evaluation: Monthly Participation Rates in Three Sites and Factors Affecting Participation Levels in Welfare-to-Work Programs The JOBS Evaluation: Monthly Participation Rates in Three Sites and Factors Affecting Participation Levels in Welfare-to-Work Programs July 1995 Gayle Hamilton In 1988, the Family Support Act (FSA) sought

More information

Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany

Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany Contents Appendix I: Data... 2 I.1 Earnings concept... 2 I.2 Imputation of top-coded earnings... 5 I.3 Correction of

More information

Annex 1. Reporting table for the assessment of CSRs and key macro-structural reforms Information of the planned and already enacted measures - DENMARK

Annex 1. Reporting table for the assessment of CSRs and key macro-structural reforms Information of the planned and already enacted measures - DENMARK Annex 1. Reporting table for the assessment of CSRs and key macro-structural reforms Information of the planned and already enacted s - DENMARK Description of main s of direct relevance address the CSRs

More information

Evaluation of the Active Labour. Severance to Job. Aleksandra Nojković, Sunčica VUJIĆ & Mihail Arandarenko Brussels, December 14-15, 2010

Evaluation of the Active Labour. Severance to Job. Aleksandra Nojković, Sunčica VUJIĆ & Mihail Arandarenko Brussels, December 14-15, 2010 Evaluation of the Active Labour Market Policy in Serbia: Severance to Job Aleksandra Nojković, Sunčica VUJIĆ & Mihail Arandarenko Brussels, December 14-15, 2010 1 Summary The paper evaluates the treatment

More information

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV John E. Floyd University of Toronto May 10, 2013 Our major task here is to look at the evidence regarding the effects of unanticipated money shocks on real

More information

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE I. Introduction Income disparities between males and females have been identified as one major issue in the process

More information

At the European Council in Copenhagen in December

At the European Council in Copenhagen in December At the European Council in Copenhagen in December 02 the accession negotiations with eight central and east European countries were concluded. The,,,,,, the and are scheduled to accede to the EU in May

More information

Evaluation of Subsidized Employment Programs for Long-Term Unemployment in Bulgaria A Matching Approach

Evaluation of Subsidized Employment Programs for Long-Term Unemployment in Bulgaria A Matching Approach Emil Mihaylov Evaluation of Subsidized Employment Programs for Long-Term Unemployment in Bulgaria A Matching Approach MSc Thesis 2009 Evaluation of Subsidized Employment Programs for Long- Term Unemployed

More information

The Targeted Negative Income Tax (TNIT) in Germany: Evidence from a quasi-experiment

The Targeted Negative Income Tax (TNIT) in Germany: Evidence from a quasi-experiment The Targeted Negative Income Tax (TNIT) in Germany: Evidence from a quasi-experiment WS 2014/15 Alexander Spermann 1. Introduction 2004: Most important labour-market reform since the war in Germany (Economist)

More information

A Comparative Analysis of Elderly Care Quasi-markets in Japan and Korea

A Comparative Analysis of Elderly Care Quasi-markets in Japan and Korea A Comparative Analysis of Elderly Care Quasi-markets in Japan and Korea LEE, Sun-Young (Ph.D. Student, Doshisha University, Kyoto, Japan) Chung-Ang University June 25, 2011 1 Ⅰ. Introduction Recently,

More information

Do active labour market policies for welfare recipients in Germany raise their regional outflow into work?

Do active labour market policies for welfare recipients in Germany raise their regional outflow into work? Do active labour market policies for welfare recipients in Germany raise their regional outflow into work? A matching function approach Rüdiger Wapler (Institute for Employment Research) Katja Wolf (Institute

More information

$1,000 1 ( ) $2,500 2,500 $2,000 (1 ) (1 + r) 2,000

$1,000 1 ( ) $2,500 2,500 $2,000 (1 ) (1 + r) 2,000 Answers To Chapter 9 Review Questions 1. Answer d. Other benefits include a more stable employment situation, more interesting and challenging work, and access to occupations with more prestige and more

More information

Unemployment Benefits, Unemployment Duration, and Post-Unemployment Jobs: A Regression Discontinuity Approach

Unemployment Benefits, Unemployment Duration, and Post-Unemployment Jobs: A Regression Discontinuity Approach Unemployment Benefits, Unemployment Duration, and Post-Unemployment Jobs: A Regression Discontinuity Approach By Rafael Lalive* Structural unemployment appears to be strongly correlated with the potential

More information

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY Institute of Business and Economic Research Fisher Center for Real Estate and Urban Economics PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY WORKING PAPER SERIES WORKING PAPER NO. W06-001B HOUSING POLICY IN THE UNITED

More information

Online Appendices Practical Procedures to Deal with Common Support Problems in Matching Estimation

Online Appendices Practical Procedures to Deal with Common Support Problems in Matching Estimation Online Appendices Practical Procedures to Deal with Common Support Problems in Matching Estimation Michael Lechner Anthony Strittmatter April 30, 2014 Abstract This paper assesses the performance of common

More information

The Youth Guarantee in Europe:

The Youth Guarantee in Europe: The Youth Guarantee in Europe: Estimating costs and number of beneficiaries 1. OVERVIEW In July 2012, the International Labour Office (ILO) estimated the costs of introducing a youth guarantee in the Eurozone

More information

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Anders Karlsson and Lars Nordén 1 Department of Corporate Finance, School of Business, Stockholm University, S-106 91 Stockholm, Sweden Abstract

More information

Quantitative Measure. February Axioma Research Team

Quantitative Measure. February Axioma Research Team February 2018 How When It Comes to Momentum, Evaluate Don t Cramp My Style a Risk Model Quantitative Measure Risk model providers often commonly report the average value of the asset returns model. Some

More information

Marginal Employment : Stepping Stone or Dead End?

Marginal Employment : Stepping Stone or Dead End? Marginal Employment : Stepping Stone or Dead End? Evaluating the German Experience Ronny Freier Stockholm School of Economics, DIW Berlin Email: Ronny.Freier@hhs.se Viktor Steiner Free University Berlin,

More information

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser. University of Konstanz Department of Economics Optimal Contracting with Reciprocal Agents in a Competitive Search Model Maria Breitwieser Working Paper Series 2015-16 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/econdoc/working-paper-series/

More information

[11] Pension Security

[11] Pension Security [11] Pension Security Outline of Pension System Overview Japanese Pension system In Japan, every people of working-age population shall be an insured person of National Pension and receive a Basic in their

More information

Is There a Relationship between EBITDA and Investment Intensity? An Empirical Study of European Companies

Is There a Relationship between EBITDA and Investment Intensity? An Empirical Study of European Companies 2012 International Conference on Economics, Business Innovation IPEDR vol.38 (2012) (2012) IACSIT Press, Singapore Is There a Relationship between EBITDA and Investment Intensity? An Empirical Study of

More information

Check against delivery.

Check against delivery. Bullet Points for intervention delivered at the OECD-IMF Conference on structural reforms by Jürgen Stark Member of the Executive Board and the Governing Council of the European Central Bank 17 March 2008

More information