AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society"

Transcription

1 Project no: AIM-AP Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies Specific Targeted Research or Innovation Project Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society Deliverable 1.4a Home production and fringe benefits in Greece Due date of deliverable: January 2008 Actual submission date: March 2008 Start date of project: 1 February 2006 Duration: 3 years Lead partner: CERES Revision [draft]

2 Distributional effects of consumption of own production and fringe benefits: Greece Christos Koutsambelas Athens University of Economics and Business and CERES and 2 Panos Tsakloglou Athens University of Economics and Business, IZA and CERES PRELIMINARY VERSION: PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE WITHOUT THE AUTHORS PERMISSION 1 Department of International and European Economics Studies, Athens University of Economics and Business, Pattision Str 76, Derigny Wing,, 5 th floor, Athens 10484, Greece. ckouts@aueb.gr 2 Corresponding author: Department of International and European Economics Studies, Athens University of Economics and Business, Pattision Str 76, Athens 10484, Greece. E- mail:tsaklog@aueb.gr 1

3 Table of Contents 1.Introduction Consumption of own production and fringe benefits in Greek economy Dataset and Methodology Empirical results: Reassessing inequality Distributional statistics Changes in the level of inequality Graphical Approach: Lorenz and Concentration Curves Inequality decomposition by subgroups Inequality decomposition by sources Changes in the level of poverty Poverty decomposition by subgroups Conclusion References Tables

4 1.Introduction As it is well regarded in economic science, individuals derive welfare from full income, which is nothing else from the sum of monetary and non-monetary income. Despite that monetary income is a conceptually simple notion, this is not the case for non-monetary income. That is why the classic Haig-Simons definition of income (Simons, 1938), which states that income is the sum of the market value of property rights exercised in consumption and the changes in the value of the store of such rights from the beginning until the end of the period the income is measured, is not trivial at all. Trying to fully satisfy this definition in empirical works is not easy and definitely depends upon the informational completeness of the used dataset. In other words the problems that are inherent in the measurement, valuation and imputation of non pecuniary incomes make their omission sometimes a necessity. Unfortunately it is not a harmless omission, since the distribution of in-kind goods may vary systematically across by country, by location or by population subgroup. Consequently estimates reported in empirical income studies may be seriously biased. Moreover, this practice has important implications for the design of policies aiming to fight poverty and social exclusion, since it may lead to imperfect targeting and misallocation of resources. This is the reason that in recent years many leading researchers and international organizations have called for the development of methods providing reliable estimates of non-cash income components and their incorporation in distributional studies [Hagenaars et al (1994), Atkinson et al (1995), van de Walle and Nead (1995), Canberra Group (2001), Atkinson et al (2002)]. In same spirit many income studies such as Smeeding et al (1993), Evandrou et al (1993), Harding et al (2006), Garfinkel et al (2006) and many other similar works, try to implement a more comprehensive definition of income by incorporating in their estimates as many sources of non-cash income as possible. There are also studies that choose to focus on the changes that are induced in income distribution by the inclusion of a specific non-monetary income such as education; Tsakloglou and 3

5 Antoninis (1999), imputed rents; Frick and Grabka (2003), health; LeGrand (1978) etc. This study belongs to the latter group of the literature, for its intention is to estimate the distributional impact of consumption of own farm and non-farm production and fringe benefits on the income distribution, also in the Appendix can be found estimates of the distributional impact of non-monetary transfers received from other households. What makes this study from distributional point of view interesting is the implicit evidence that their distribution effectively differs from the distribution of monetary income. Intuitively the inclusion of the imputed value of household production and fringe benefits should affect both tails of the distribution. Consumption of home production is more prevalent to low-income households (especially in the case of own farm production, see for example Bryant and Zick (1985)), in contrast with fringe benefits that are concentrated disproportionately to high wage employees (For example Pierce (2001) reports that fringe benefits are less equally distributed than wages). Therefore the inclusion of these non-money incomes in an empirical income study could not only but enrich the analysis, by shedding some more light in the measurement of poverty and inequality in Greece. To do so we take advantage of the rich informational basis of the 2004 Greek Budget Household Survey (hereafter BHS) in order to estimate the distributional effects of consumption of own production and fringe benefits in Greece. The structure of the paper goes as follows; Section 2 discusses the relevance of other non-cash incomes (hereafter under this generic term we will describe income advantages derived from own farm and non-farm production and fringe benefits) in Greek economy emphasizing issues such as the socioeconomic origin of their receivers and their composition with respect of each consumption category, section 3 briefly describes our dataset and methodological settings, section 4 reports estimations of poverty and inequality before and after the inclusion of other non-cash incomes and other distributional statistics as well as other distributional statistics and finally section 5 concludes. 4

6 2.Consumption of own production and fringe benefits in Greek economy. Graph 1 reports the position of the receivers of imputed incomes in the income distribution when the population is grouped in quintiles according to their equivalent disposable income. An immediate point is that the distribution of the receivers of imputed income derived from own farm production is clearly skewed towards the bottom of the distribution (about one quarter of the receivers belongs to the poorest quintile), exactly the opposite pattern is observed for fringe benefits. Fringe benefit receivers are clearly concentrated towards the upper part of the distribution. Finally a rather erratic pattern characterizes the distribution of the receivers of imputed income from own non-farm production. Finally graph 1 also describes the distribution of all receivers, irrespectively of the non-cash income enjoyed, and it more or less reflects the points made earlier; most receivers are concentrated in the poorest quintile (a result caused by own farm production), however many receivers can be found also in the richest quintile (mostly fringe benefits receivers). Of course these estimates try to capture only the location of receivers and naturally neglect the relative size of imputed income to their disposable income. Moreover the estimates may be driven from demographics. Therefore any distributional judgement at this stage would be premature. Nevertheless intuitively we can expect that fringe benefits are pro rich, own farm production pro poor and own non-farm production follows a middle path, mildly inclined towards progressivity. Table 1 disaggregates the population using the following socioeconomic criteria: household type, occupational status of the household head, educational status of the household head and geographical area. The first column reports the corresponding population shares of each subgroup, the next three contain estimates of the proportion of population of the specific subgroup that enjoy a positive imputed income from own farm production, own non-farm production and fringe benefits respectively. Consumption of own farm production is very common for people living in rural areas 5

7 (about 73% of the people that live in rural areas enjoy imputed income from own farm production), percentages are also high for people that belong to households headed by a low educated (44%), pensioner (39%), self employed (42%). In contrast consumption of own non-farm production percentages is less common, except of the case of the self-employed group, whereas a significant proportion of the group receives them. The latter also reflect an important aspect of the structure of Greek economy; a considerable portion of Greek labor force is not only employed in the sectors of agriculture, cattle breeding and fishing [11.4% of total labor force, BHS (2004)], but also most of them are either self-employed (71% ) or work in their family enterprise (22%). Consequently the widespread non-monetization of the production of the farm sector is not surprising. Finally fringe benefits, as it was expected, are more prevalent for the households headed by white (15.3%) and blue collar workers (14.9%), high educated (11.74% for the tertiary education group and 10.64% for the upper secondary education one) and for people located in urban areas (9.71%). Table 2, reports shares of households with non-purchased consumption above 10 euros per consumption category. Consumption of own farm production mainly consists of food and in some cases of housing goods (for example firewoods), consumption of own non-farm production (that is consumption of goods produced from household's own entreprise) naturally includes a greater variety of goods such as food, clothing, durables etc. Also fringe benefits comprise of several types of goods. But in most cases they take the form of the free provision of hotel/restaurant or communication services, even if there is a significant number of food provision. Finally table 3 that reports shares of non-purchased consumption in total consumption per category shows that consumption of non-purchased food represents almost 10% of the total food consumption, making non-purchased food - irrespectively of its source - as the most important case of non-purchased consumption. Less important, at least with regard their impact on household budget, are non-purchased communication services (a common fringe benefits as it was revealed by table 1) and alcohol/tobacco (2.8% and 2.0% of total consumption respectively). Finally the shares of the 6

8 remaining non-purchased consumption categories are too small to worth commenting them. 3.Dataset and Methodology The data used in the paper are the micro-data of the 2004/5 Greek Household Budget Survey, which was carried out by the National Statistical Service of Greece. The survey covers all the private (non-institutional) households of the country and its sampling fraction is 2/1000 (around 6,500 households or 18,000 individuals). It contains detailed information about consumption expenditures (actual and imputed), incomes and socioeconomic characteristics of the households and the household members. The baseline distribution is the distribution of disposable income. All monetary values were expressed in constant mid-2004 values in order to remove the impact of inflation. The distributions used are distributions of equivalent household disposable income per capita and they are derived using the modified OECD equivalence scales (Hagenaars et al, 1994) that assign weights of 1.00 to the household head, 0.50 to each of the remaining adults in the household and 0.30 to each child (person aged below 14) in the household. Since the estimates in the HBS are expressed in monthly figures, the cost estimates of Table 1 are adjusted accordingly. The estimation of the value of own production and fringe benefits depends ultimately upon the information provided by the dataset. Fortunately the Greek budget survey provides the necessary material for a rich analysis. Imputed own production and fringe benefits are included both in consumption and income information of the household. According to the classification of the survey, there are five ways to obtain a commodity: (1) Purchase (2) From own farm production 7

9 (3) From own non-farm production (services not included) (4) From other households (for example charities or gifts) (5) From employer Also the income list of the survey contains the follow five imputed items (excluding imputed rents) (1) Imputed income derived from the production of own agricultural or cattlebreeding production. (2) Imputed income derived from goods that are produced by an enterprise that belongs to the household. (3) Imputed value of goods that were given for free to the household. (4) Imputed income from fringe benefits except of cars. (5) Imputed value of car services provided by the employer. Imputed income (3) mainly refers to gifts and charities and was not included in the subsequent analysis. Incomes (4) and (5) were merged, for there were very few cases of imputed income (5) (45 observation). Consequently there are three categories of imputed income to consider, the first two refer to own production and the third to fringe benefits. Moreover the distributional impact of item (3) which was excluded from the main body of the analysis, will be incorporated in the tables provided but not commented. 4. Empirical results: Reassessing inequality 4.1 Distributional statistics In this subsection we report estimates of mean transfers per quintile, proportional increases in equivalent disposable income and changes in income shares induced by the inclusion of imputed incomes. In a sense these distributional statistics are precursors of inequality and poverty results that will follow in the next sections. Table 4 examines the mean imputed income per capita for each quintile. One can easily 8

10 notice that the mean income from own farm production not only is of considerable size, but also is higher in poor quintiles than in the rich one. Average imputed income stemming from own non-farm production follows a quite opposite pattern, first of all its size is modest and secondly is slightly higher for the top quintiles. Unsurprisingly average fringe benefits are high for the household members that belong to the rich quintiles and negligible for the poor ones. When all items taken together, the average aggregate imputed income is up to 13 euro. This number doesn't differ significantly across quintiles, indicating that somehow the different categories of imputed income complement each other, for example low-income households enjoy low fringe benefits but rather high consumption from own production and vice versa for the high-income households. As a result the level of average imputed income doesn't fluctuate much across quintiles. However from distributional point of view, what matters are the changes of the relative positions of individuals, something that is better captured from Table 5, which provides estimates of the proportional rise in the income of the quintiles caused by the inclusion of the imputed income. In both imputed income from own farm production and own non-farm production, the increase in the income of the quintiles diminishes as we move up the income distribution. Thus imputed income from own farm production causes an 12% increase in the equivalent disposable income of the poorest quintile, this increase declines steadily ass we move to the top quintiles, reaching 4.9% in the case of the top quintile. Imputed income from own non-farm production causes more significant increases in both tails of the distribution than in the middle, reflecting merely the fact that middle income classes in Greece are comprised mainly of blue and white collar workers (Note also from Table 1 that in these groups are income from own non-farm production is not very common). Naturally such patterns is not observed in the case of fringe benefit. Finally if we aggregate all imputed incomes, they account for 7% of the income of the bottom quintile, the corresponding share declining gradually as we proceed to higher quintiles, reaching 1.0% in the case of the top one. An immediate conclusion is that this declining pattern of proportional increases indicates that other non-cash income are progressively distributed across income distribution. 9

11 Table 6 reports the quintile income shares before and after the inclusion of imputed incomes in the concept of resources that are available to the household members. After their inclusion, the shares of the three lowest quintiles, and especially the bottom, increase (from 7.5% to 7.8%, 12.7% to 12.9% and 17.0% to 17.1% for each of the three bottom quintiles) while that of the top two decline (from 22.94% to 22.9% for the fourth quintile and from 39.8% to 39.4% for the top one). Again the main driving force behind these changes seems to be the imputed income derived from own farm production. 4.2 Changes in the level of inequality Table 7 examines the impact of other non-cash income on aggregate inequality; that is, it reports the proportional change in a number of inequality indices when we move from the distribution of disposable income to the distribution of augmented income. As inequality indices we chose the widely used Gini index and two members of the parametric family of Atkinson (1970) indices. The value of the inequality aversion parameter in the latter is set at (e=0.5 and e=1.5). Both indices satisfy the desirable properties for an inequality index (anonymity, mean independence, population independence, transfer sensitivity). Higher values of e make the Atkinson index relatively more sensitive to changes closer to the bottom of the distribution while, in practice, the Gini index is relatively more sensitive to changes around the median of the distribution [Cowell (2000), Lambert, (2001)]. When moving from the distribution of disposable income to the augmented distribution of resources, the Gini index declines by 2.0%, while the two Atkinson indices (e=0.5 and e=1.5) decline by around 4.1% and 4.9% respectively. Almost the entire effect is driven by the progressive redistributive impact of the consumption of own farm production ( for example the Gini index is reduced by about -1.8% and the two Atkinson -3.7% and -4.3% when we consider only for the partial effect of imputed income from own farm production). The other two sources of imputed income that is consumption of own non-farm production and fringe benefits have only marginally impacts on inequality. 10

12 4.3 Graphical Approach: Lorenz and Concentration Curves A well-known way of summarizing and comparing income distribution is the Lorenz curves. Lorenz curve plots cumulative proportions of income units (ordered according to their income) against cumulative proportions of income received by these income units. Algebraically it is defined as: L(p)= xf(x)/μ dx, p Ε [0,1] where x is the income variable, p is the proportion of population and f(x) the frequency density function. For the purpose of our analysis we define a function d(p), which is the difference between the Lorenz curve of the income distribution when each of the imputed income categories is included and the Lorenz curve of the baseline distribution (i.e. the Lorenz curve for the equivalent disposable income) that is: di( p) = Li ( p) Lbase( p). Thus, Graph 2 depicts: d 1(p), when L1(p) is the Lorenz curve for the distribution of disposable income plus the imputed income derived from of own farm production. d 2(p), When L2(p) is the Lorenz curve for the distribution of disposable income plus the imputed income derived from household's enterprise. d 3(p), When L3(p) is the Lorenz curve for the distribution of disposable income plus the fringe benefits. d all (p), When L 3 (p) is the Lorenz curve for the distribution of disposable income plus all imputed incomes. If the d-function is above zero for every possible value of p, then we have a case of Lorenz dominance that allows us to safely infer that inequality is reduced according to every possible index of relative inequality [Atkinson, (1970)] and vice versa. Graph 2 is very illuminating of the distributional implications of the inclusion of other non-cash incomes in the baseline distribution. An immediate conclusion is that the 11

13 augmented distribution Lorenz dominates the baseline distribution ( d all (p) is positive everywhere in its domain). This impact is almost entirely driven by the inclusion of imputed income from own farm production, something reflected on the similarity of d all (p) and d 1(p) curves. In fact dall(p) has almost exactly the same shape as d 1 (p), but is located a bit higher, for its redistributive impact is mildly enhanced by the equalizing effect of imputed income derived from own non-farm production. As far as d 2 (p) is concerned, it is everywhere positive (once again a case of Lorenz dominance). However d 3 (p) follows a different pattern; it crosses once the horizontal axis, being negative for p<0.79 and positive for p>0.79. This Lorenz crossing suggest that we cannot infer any unambiguous conclusion regarding the distributional impact of fringe benefit. Whatever conclusion will be conditional on distributional tastes. Given that we have more inequality at the bottom and at the middle and less at the top of the distribution after the inclusion of fringe benefits, an inequality index which gives more weight to transfers to the upper tail of distributions (a possible such index would be whatever belongs to the GE family if we set a high enough value of the parameter) could yield an inequality reduction (and vice versa). However it should be admitted that in order to measure a decrease in inequality, we have to set an unreasonably high value of the parameter (technically this happens because the crossing point is also high). The above results are also verified by the use of concentration curves analysis. The logic of concentration curves is similar to that of the Lorenz curves with the crucial difference that we now plot shares of one variable against quantiles of some other variable. In this sense, Lorenz curves are just a subset of the set of all possible concentration curves (for example, the Lorenz curve for disposable income is nothing else than the concentration curve for disposable income with respect to disposable income). The concentration curves are useful in that they allow us to isolate graphically and compare the pattern of distribution of each of the non-cash components in question. The corresponding concentration curves are reported in Chart 3. 12

14 C (p), when L 1 1(p) is the Lorenz curve for the distribution of disposable income plus the imputed income of own farm production. C (p), when L 2 2(p) is the Lorenz curve for the distribution of disposable income plus the imputed income of own non-farm production. C (p), when L 3 3(p) is the Lorenz curve for the distribution of disposable income plus the fringe benefits. C all (p), when L 3 (p) is the Lorenz curve for the distribution of disposable income plus all imputed incomes. Examining Graph 3, we notice that C 1 (p) lies well above the 45 o, this means that imputed income derived from own farm production is disproportionately distributed in favour of the people that belong to the low part of the distribution. C 2 (p) is located near the 45 o, that is imputed income derived own non-farm production is distributed evenly across distribution and finally C 3 (p) is bellow the Lorenz curve for the baseline distribution for p<0.69 and above it for p>0.69, thus for the bottom part of the income distribution fringe benefits are even more unequal than the distribution of disposable income but not so for the upper part. Finally C all (p), which is the combined effect of the above concentration curves, lies above the Lorenz curve for the baseline distribution. This is also one of the main points of this study; the distribution of other non-cash incomes is more equally distributed than the distribution of disposable income. 4.4 Inequality decomposition by subgroups The above results mainly refer to aggregate effects in inequality induced by other non-cash incomes. But what is also of potential interest is the source and structure of inequality and how they change by the inclusion of imputed incomes in the definition of income. An insight in these aspects of inequality can be obtained by exploiting the property of decomposability that indices of the Generalized Entropy family possess. Therefore, we performed decomposition by population subgroups on the mean log 13

15 deviation index. The choice of subgroups has been made with respect to their relevance in the analysis and what is available in our dataset, so we decomposed by household type (older single persons or couples, younger single persons or couples, couple with children up to 18, mono-parental household, other household type), by socioeconomic status of the household head (blue collar worker, white collar worker, self-employed, unemployed, pensioner, other), by education level of the household head (tertiary education, upper secondary education, lower secondary education, primary or less) and by age (bellow 25, 25-64, over 64). Table 8 reports the results. The first column of the table shows the different partitions of population we adopted and the various subgroups that came up. Column A reports the population share of each subgroup, so that we have an idea of its relevant importance; columns B and C contain the estimates of MLD for the baseline distribution (distribution of equivalent disposable income) and the one which includes imputed incomes, column D reports the percentage change of the inequality index. Columns E, F, G, H report the contributions to inequality and the relative positions of each subgroup before and after the inclusion of imputed incomes respectively and finally the last column refers to changes in relative position. The structure of inequality does not change substantially as we move from the distribution of disposable income to the augmented income distribution. Inequality declines within all population sub-groups and in all groupings both within and between inequality also declines. Finally with regard relative positions, we only observe marginal changes. Only members of households headed by a self-employed or a low educated person enjoy a proportional change of relative position higher than 1% (1.3% and 1.6% respectively), all the other changes are marginally. 4.5 Inequality decomposition by sources In this section we disaggregate the full income of individuals (that is the equivalent income of individuals after the inclusion of non-cash income) in the following factor 14

16 components; disposable income, imputed income from own farm production, imputed income from household's enterprise and fringe benefits in order to assess the contribution of these sources to total inequality. Following Pyatt et all (1980) Gini index can be written as: written as: K mk G = Σ Rk m G k = 1 k (1) m m where k R and are the mean of component k and total income respectively. k is the relative correlation coefficient of component k (that is the ratio of the covariance of component k with the total income rank and the covariance of component k with its G own rank) and finally k is the Gini index for the component k. (1) can be rearranged (divide both parts of the equation by G) so as to yield: K Σ w 1 kg = k (2) k= 1 w where k g is the share of component k in total income and k is the relative concentration coefficient of component k in aggregate inequality. The product wg k k can be interpreted as the proportional contribution of component k in aggregate g inequality. From the estimation of k we can detect whether an increase in the g income component k will increase or decrease aggregate inequality. In fact if k > 1 g then inequality will increase and if k <1 inequality will decrease. Furthermore from (1) we can calculate the elasticity of inequality with respect to a proportional change in component k. e dg m = k k wkg dmk G = k w k w g Estimates of k, k e, k are reported in Table 9 for each component and for all components taken together and for various values of the parameter of distributional g sensitivity ν (ν=1.5, ν=2, ν=4). The estimates of k show that all components mitigate aggregate inequality whatever the value of the distributional sensitivity parameter, 15 (3)

17 gs since all k g are less than one, except of the fringe benefits whose k is more than one whatever the value of the parameter v. These estimates taken together with the values are consistent with the estimations of elasticity of inequality with respect to components k. Indeed elasticity is always negative except of the case of fringe benefits. Elasticity of inequality of aggregate other non-cash incomes is negative (naturally fringe benefits are not so high so as to undo the equalizing effect of imputed income from own farm production and household's own entreprise. Thus increasing marginally the size of the imputed income, ceteris paribus, will decrease aggregate inequality, a decrease that is more significant the higher the value of the parameter v. wk 4.6 Changes in the level of poverty Poverty rates in Greece are considered high, especially in comparison with EU countries. In this section, we apply the parametric family of FGT(a) index in order to find out whether the inclusion of other non cash income does reduce poverty. The α parameter is defined as the social aversion to poverty; the higher the value of alpha the higher the aversion to poverty. When the value of the poverty aversion parameter is set at α=0, the index becomes the widely used poverty rate, that is the share of the population falling below the poverty line. When α=1, the index becomes the normalized income gap ratio, while when α=2 the index satisfies the axioms proposed by Sen (1976) (anonymity, focus, monotonicity and transfer sensitivity) and is sensitive not only to the population share of the poor and their average poverty gap, but also to the inequality in the distribution of resources among the poor. Following the practice of Eurostat, the poverty line is set at 60% of the median income. Table 10 reports the corresponding results. The results reported in Table 10 suggest that poverty is reduced according to all versions of FGT index after the inclusion of imputed income in the concept of resources. The poverty reducing effect of other non cash-income is enhanced for 16

18 higher values of the poverty sensitivity parameter alpha; when α=2 recorded poverty is reduced by almost 20%. Once again, the bulk of the poverty reduction can be attributed to the imputed income derived from own farm production, while the poverty reducing effect of imputed income from own non-farm production is mild and the partial effect of fringe benefits even causes a marginal increase in poverty for values of alpha higher than zero. 4.7 Poverty decomposition by subgroups This section reports the results of the poverty decomposition by subgroups, by which we try to identify population groups at high of poverty risk and how this risk and their contribution to aggregate poverty after the change in the concept of resources. The task is accomplished thanks to the property of additive decomposability that FGT index possess and the results are reported in Table 11. The differentiation of population was done by the same criteria as in the preceding inequality decomposition analysis. Column A reports population shares for each group, columns B and C contain estimates of FGT (a=0), D percentage changes in poverty, E and F the contributions of each subgroup to aggregate poverty, G, H, I, J, K report the same magnitudes but for FGT (a=1) and finally L, M, N, O, P for FGT (a=1). In general, after the inclusion of other non-cash income in the concept of resources the poverty risk declines in almost all population sub-groups; apart of the people that belong to households headed by unemployed or white collar workers. the tenants. The poverty reductions are especially high for the households headed by self-employed or pensioners and the low educated (lower secondary education and primary education or less groups). For example for the people that belong to households whose head is self employed, poverty falls -11.6%, % and % for the FGT a=0,1,2 respectively, for the primary education or less group the corresponding figures are - 7.8%, % and % and finally for the lower secondary education group %, -7.46%, %. The significant poverty reductions observed for these highly overlapping groups can be merely attributed to the fact that self employment is widespread among Greek farmers. 17

19 6.Conclusions The main aim of this paper was to assess the impact of other non-cash income, namely income derived from own farm production, own non-farm production and fringe benefits on income distribution. The empirical findings one more time in the literature of empirical income studies demonstrate the importance of including noncash incomes in applied welfare analysis. For the distribution of these resources may systematically differ from the distribution of monetary resources, thus making their omission a source of potential bias in the estimation of measures of relative well being This is the case with non-monetized production and non-pecuniary employers compensation in Greece. We found that the distribution of own production is more equally distributed than disposable income, in contrast with fringe benefits that appear to be concentrated more on the upper part of the distribution. This result is especially strong in the case of own farm production, something which can be attributed to the widespread self employment of Greek farmers. Consequently both aggregate inequality and poverty decrease after the inclusion of other non cash imputed incomes. Finally using decomposition analysis we concluded that inclusion of other non cash incomes is, at least in relative terms, more beneficial for some socioeconomic groups of the population that are found to be more sensitive to poverty (farmers, people living in rural areas, elderly, Tsakloglou (2000), we are inclined to support that at least in Greece non-monetization can be considered as a mean of self defence against poverty and inequality. 18

20 7. References Atkinson A.B. (1970). "On the measurement of inequality", Journal of Economic Theory 2, pp Atkinson, A.B., Cantillon, B., Marlier, E. and Nolan, B. (2002) Social indicators: The EU and social inclusion, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Atkinson, A.B., Rainwater, M. and Smeeding, T. (1995), Income distribution in OECD countries, OECD, Paris. Bryant, W. K. and Zick C. D., (1985), Income distribution implications of rural household production, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 67, No. 5, Proceedings issue., pp Canberra Group (2001), Final Report and Recommendations, The Canberra Group: Expert Group on Household Income Statistics, Ottawa. Cowell F.A. (2000). Measurement of inequality in A.B. Atkinson and F. Bourguignon Handbook of Income Inequality, Vol. I, North Holland, Amsterdam. Evandrou M., J. Falkingham, J. Hills and J. Le Grand (1993), Welfare benefits in kind and income distribution, Fiscal Studies, 14. Frick, R. and Grabka, M., (2003) Imputed Rent and Income Inequality: A Decomposition Analysis for Great Britain, West Germany and U.S., The Review of Income and Wealth, 49 (4), Garfinkel I., Rainwater L., and Smeeding T.M. (2006) A Reexamination of Welfare State and Inequality in Rich Nations: How In-Kind Transfers and Indirect Taxes Change the Story Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 25, pp Hagenaars, A.J.M., de Vos, K. and Zaidi, M.A. (1994). Poverty statistics in the late 1980s: Research based on micro-data. Luxembourg: Eurostat. Harding A., Lloyd R. and Warren N. (2006). "Moving beyond traditional cash measures of economic well-being: including indirect benefits and indirect taxes", National Centre For Social and Economic Modelling, Discussion Paper no. 61, University of Canberra. Lambert P.J. (2001). The distribution and redistribution of income: A mathematical analysis, 3rd edition, Manchester University Press, Manchester. LeGrand J. (1978) The distribution of public expenditure: The case of Health Care, Economica, New Series, Vol.45, No.178. (May 1978), pp National Statistic Service of Greece. Household Expenditure Survey 2004/2005. Athens: NSSG 19

21 Pierce B., (2001). Compensation Inequality, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol 116., pp Pyatt, G., Chen, C., and Fei, J. (1980). The distribution of income by factor components., Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol 95., pp Sen A.K. (1976). "Poverty: An ordinal approach to measurement", Econometrica 44, pp Simons, Herbert (1938). Personal Income Taxation, Chicago: University of Chicago Press Smeeding T.M., Saunders P., Coder J., Jenkins S.P., Fritzell J. Hagenaars A.J.M. Hauser R. and Wolfson M. (1993). "Poverty, inequality and living standard impacts across seven nations: the effects of non-cash subsidies for health, education and housing", Review of Income and Wealth 39, pp Tsakloglou P. and Antoninis M. (1999) On the distributional impact of public education: evidence from Greece, Economics of Education Review 18, pp Tsakloglou, Panos Poverty and Anti-Poverty Policies in Greece and a Comparison with Other Mediterranean EU Member States. In Contemporary Greece and Europe, edited by A. Mitsos, and E. Mossialos. Ashgate, Aldershot, pp Van de Walle, D. and Nead, K. (eds) (1995) Public spending and the poor: Theory and evidence, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore and London. 20

22 8. Charts and Tables Chart 1: Distribution of imputed income receivers per quintile 0,35 0,30 0,25 0,20 0,15 0,10 0,05 Imputed income from ow n farm production Imputed income from ow n non-farm production fringe benefits All imputed incomes 0, Quintiles 21

23 Table 1: Shares of people who receive positive other non-cash incomes per 3 socioeconomic category of whom positive imputed income from Characteristic of household or household head Household type Older single persons or couples (at least one 65+) Younger single persons or couples (none 65+) Couple with children up to 18 (no other HH members) Mono-parental household Population Share own farm production own non-farm production fringe benefits 7,86 39,01 1,44 0,06 18,02 26,02 2,29 4,74 33,81 23,13 6,58 10,10 1,52 11,15 2,33 5,93 Other household types 39,31 35,96 7,70 9,64 Socioeconomic group of HH head Blue collar worker 23,43 19,13 2,76 15,31 White collar worker 15,00 19,15 2,06 14,90 Self-employed 23,32 41,64 15,02 3,50 Unemployed 2,31 16,21 6,71 1,92 Pensioner 28,01 38,84 3,74 2,98 Other 8,44 18,50 1,80 7,56 Educational level of HH head Tertiary education 20,50 15,30 3,47 11,74 Upper secondary education 27,20 21,01 7,63 10,64 Lower secondary education 13,05 28,98 4,79 8,48 Primary education or less 39,76 43,38 6,04 4,40 Location urban 66,72 14,60 4,52 9,71 semi urban 12,81 4,08 8,20 7,43 rural 20,47 72,88 8,53 3,54 ALL ,88 5,81 8,16 3 Only positive imputed incomes over 10 euros are considered. 22

24 Table 2. Share of households with positive non-purchased consumption per category 4 from own farm from own non- farm from other households from employer Consumption group production production Food 26,75 2,26 16,60 1,39 40,64 Alcohol & Tobacco 3,29 0,50 1,20 0,09 5,00 Clothing & Footwear 0,00 0,39 0,46 0,27 1,12 Housing etc 3,43 0,56 2,65 0,10 6,71 Durables 0,00 0,59 0,63 0,07 1,29 Health & Personal Care 0,00 0,00 0,19 0,00 0,19 Transport 0,00 0,06 0,76 0,28 1,09 Communications 0,00 0,00 0,96 2,15 3,07 Recreation & Culture 0,00 0,09 0,59 0,07 0,73 Education 0,00 0,00 0,42 0,03 0,45 Hotels, Restaurants etc 0,00 1,37 8,54 2,43 12,10 Other Goods & Services 0,00 0,65 1,59 0,31 2,49 All Table 3. Share of non purchased households with positive non-purchased consumption in total consumption per category 5 Consumption category from own farm production from own non- farm production from other households from employer All other Food 5,5 0,7 2,9 0,1 9,3 Alcohol & Tobacco 1,6 0,5 0,6 0,1 2,8 Clothing & Footwear 0,0 0,5 0,2 0,3 1,0 Housing etc 0,3 0,0 0,6 0,0 0,9 Durables 0,0 0,2 0,7 0,0 1,0 Health & Personal Care 0,0 0,0 0,2 0,0 0,2 Transport 0,0 0,1 0,3 0,1 0,4 Communications 0,0 0,0 0,4 1,6 2,0 Recreation & Culture 0,0 0,0 0,3 0,1 0,4 Education 0,0 0,0 1,1 0,1 1,2 Hotels, Restaurants etc 0,0 1,5 5,1 1,7 0,6 Other Goods & Services 0,0 0,1 0,3 0,2 0,5 4 5 Only positive imputed incomes over 10 euros are considered. Only positive imputed incomes over 10 euros are considered. 23

25 Table 4: Equivalent mean imputed income per capita per quintile Quintiles from own farm from own non- farm from other households from employer All except of from other production production households 1 12,0 2,6 14,4 0,7 15,3 29,7 2 9,6 2,4 11,0 1,3 13,4 24,4 3 6,6 1,9 7,5 2,2 10,7 18,2 4 6,1 3,2 6,7 3,9 13,2 19,9 5 4,9 2,9 8,5 4,4 12,2 20,7 All 7,9 2,6 9,6 2,5 13,0 22,6 All Quintiles Table 5: Proportional increase in disposable income per quintile due to imputed incomes from own farm production from own non- farm production from other households from employer All except of from other households 1 5,2 1,3 5,5 0,3 6,8 12,3 2 2,5 0,7 2,5 0,4 3,6 6,1 3 1,3 0,4 1,4 0,4 2,1 3,5 4 0,9 0,5 0,9 0,6 2,0 2,9 5 0,4 0,2 0,7 0,4 1,0 1,7 All 1,3 0,5 1,4 0,4 2,2 3,6 All 24

26 Table 6. Quintile income shares before and after the inclusion of imputed incomes from own from own All except of from other from Quintiles Baseline farm non- farm from other All households employer production production households 1 7,5 7,73 7,53 7,67 7,48 7,8 7, ,69 12,84 12,73 12,81 12,68 12,9 12, ,07 17,12 17,03 17,11 17,06 17,1 17, ,94 22,84 22,95 22,88 22,97 22,9 22, ,81 39,48 39,76 39,53 39,82 39,4 39,14 Chart 2. Differences between Lorenz curves 25

27 Chart 3. Concentration curves 26

28 Table 7. Proportional changes in inequality indices due to imputed incomes Inequality Iindex Baseline from own farm production from own non- farm production from other households from employer All except of from other households Gini 0,3217-1,8-0,3-1,5 0,1-2,0-3,4 Atkinson0.5 0,0849-3,7-0,6-3,1 0,1-4,1-7,1 Atkinson1.5 0,2406-4,3-0,9-3,9 0,2-4,9-8,5 All 27

29 Table 8. Inequality Decomposition by Population Subgroups Characteristic of household or household head A Β C D E F G H I Household type Older single persons or couples (at least one 65+) 7,8 0,1461 0,1379-5,60 6,4 6,3 71,4 71,8 0,6 Younger single persons or couples (none 65+) 18 0,2241 0,2173-3,06 22,7 22,9 98,8 98,8 0,0 Couple with children up to 18 (no other HH members) 33,6 0,1778 0,1711-3,78 33,6 33,6 103,4 103,0-0,4 Mono-parental household 1,5 0,1980 0,1883-4,88 1,7 1,7 81,7 81,1-0,8 Other household types 39,1 0,1506 0,1441-4,26 33,1 33,0 104,1 104,4 0,3 Within groups inequality 0,1734 0,1667-3,89 1,0 1,0 Between groups inequality 0,0044 0,0043-2,25 0,0 0,0 Socioeconomic group of HH head Blue collar worker 23,3 0,0920 0,0916-0,42 12,1 12,5 88,3 87,9-0,5 White collar worker 14,9 0,1051 0,1041-1,01 8,8 9,1 137,1 135,7-1,0 Self-employed 23,3 0,2652 0,2463-7,12 34,8 33,6 108,2 109,6 1,3 Unemployed 2,3 0,1342 0,1310-2,37 1,7 1,8 71,0 70,5-0,7 Pensioner 27,9 0,1667 0,1593-4,41 26,2 26,0 89,5 89,7 0,2 Other 8,4 0,1638 0,1607-1,90 7,7 7,9 86,6 86,0-0,7 Within groups inequality 0,1628 0,1561-4,09 0,9 0,9 Between groups inequality 0,0150 0,0148-1,26 0,1 0,1 Educational level of HH head Tertiary education 20,4 0,1384 0,1373-0,81 15,9 0,1 147,1 145,2-1,3 Upper secondary education 27 0,1410 0,1372-2,72 21,4 0,1 101,0 100,8-0,2 Lower secondary education 13 0,1444 0,1393-3,50 10,6 0,1 89,2 89,0-0,2 Primary education or less 39,5 0,1627 0,1551-4,70 36,2 0,1 78,5 79,8 1,6 Within groups inequality 0,1474 0,1430-2,96 0,8 0,8 Between groups inequality 0,0304 0,0279-8,20 0,2 0,2 Age of population member Below ,1697 0,1630-3,99 25,8 25,7 95,7 95,6-0, ,5 0,1714 0,1651-3,67 50,6 50,7 109,2 109,1 0,0 Over 64 20,6 0,1766 0,1684-4,64 20,5 20,3 82,2 82,4 0,3 Within groups inequality 0,1719 0,1651-3,94 1,0 1,0 Between groups inequality 0,0059 0,0058-1,35 0,0 0,0 A: Population Share B: Mean Log Deviation (Disposable Income) C: Mean Log Deviation (Disposable Income + Imputed incomes) D: % Change in Inequality E: % Contribution to Aggregate Income Inequality (Disposable Income) F: % Contribution to Aggregate Income Inequality (Disposable Income + Imputed incomes) G: Relative Income Position (Disposable Income) H: Relative Income Position (Disposable Income + Imputed Income) I: % Change in Relative Position 28

30 Table 9. Inequality Decomposition by factor components ν=1,5 ν=2 v=4 wk gk ek wk gk ek wk gk ek Baseline 0,9649 1,03 0,0266 0,9649 1,03 0,0258 0,9649 1,01 0,0129 from own farm production 0,0125-0,27-0,0160 0,0125-0,29-0,0162 0,0125-0,27-0,0159 from own nonfarm production 0,0045 0,69-0,0014 0,0045 0,72-0,0013 0,0045 0,79-0,0009 from other households 0,0140 0,24-0,0106 0,0140 0,28-0,0101 0,0140 0,36-0,0089 from employer 0,0042 1,33 0,0014 0,0042 1,42 0,0017 0,0042 1,44 0,0018 All 0,0351 0,24-0,0266 0,0351 0,26-0,0258 0,0351 0,32-0,0239 Table 10. Proportional changes in poverty indices due to imputed incomes Poverty Index Baseline from own from own All except of from other from farm non- farm from other households employer production production households All FGT0 0,3217-6,1-1,1-3,4-0,5-7,1-10,2 FGT1 0,0849-8,2-1,9-5,9 0,3-9,3-14,2 FGT2 0, ,0-2,9-8,6 0,4-12,9-19,9 29

31 Table 10. FGT Decomposition by Population Subgroups Characteristic of household or household head A B C D E F G H I J K L M N O P Household type Older single persons or couples (at least one 65+) 7,8 0,379 0,359-5,31 14,94 15,24 0,092 0,085-8,47 13,50 13,62 0,033 0,030-9,86 11,11 11,49 Younger single persons or couples (none 65+) 18 0,238 0,224-5,97 21,68 21,95 0,075 0,070-7,23 25,34 25,92 0,036 0,033-9,28 28,12 29,27 Couple with children up to 18 (no other HH members) 33,6 0,186 0,173-6,67 31,54 31,69 0,050 0,045-9,99 31,39 31,16 0,022 0,019-14,30 31,78 31,26 Mono-parental household 1,5 0,288 0,280-2,83 2,18 2,28 0,088 0,085-4,18 2,48 2,62 0,049 0,043-13,01 3,21 3,20 Other household types 39,1 0,150 0,136-9,71 29,66 28,84 0,037 0,033-11,32 27,30 26,69 0,015 0,013-16,23 25,81 24,81 Socioeconomic group of HH head Blue collar worker 23,3 0,159 0,151-4,81 18,73 19,20 0,034 0,034 0,70 14,79 16,43 0,012 0,012 0,26 12,09 13,91 White collar worker 14,9 0,035 0,035 1,41 2,63 2,87 0,005 0,005-1,35 1,28 1,39 0,001 0,001 4,62 0,61 0,74 Self-employed 23,3 0,243 0,215-11,60 28,64 27,26 0,079 0,065-18,36 34,54 31,09 0,039 0,030-23,28 39,43 34,72 Unemployed 2,3 0,305 0,330 8,12 3,54 4,13 0,083 0,081-2,03 3,57 3,85 0,037 0,037-1,91 3,74 4,20 Pensioner 27,9 0,253 0,233-7,77 35,63 35,38 0,066 0,061-8,18 34,46 34,89 0,026 0,024-10,45 32,03 32,92 Other 8,4 0,259 0,247-4,42 10,98 11,30 0,073 0,072-1,67 11,55 12,52 0,034 0,033-2,91 12,29 13,70 Educational level of HH head Tertiary education 20,4 0,043 0,042-1,28 4,41 4,69 0,009 0, ,13 3,60 20,74 0,003 0,003 1,94 2,80 3,28 Upper secondary education 27 0,152 0,146-3,84 20,74 21,48 0,043 0,040-6,68 21,72 22,35 0,019 0,017-10,50 22,33 22,94 Lower secondary education 13 0,221 0,197-10,90 14,54 13,96 0,053 0,049-7,46 12,95 13,22 0,025 0,022-12,19 13,88 13,98 Primary education or less 39,5 0,302 0,278-7,79 60,18 59,76 0,083 0,074-11,13 61,60 60,36 0,035 0,030-14,55 60,86 59,68 Age of HH member Below ,205 0,192-6,02 27,94 28,28 0,057 0,052-9,30 28,74 28,74 0,025 0,022-13,57 29,53 29, ,5 0,152 0,139-8,62 40,38 39,73 0,041 0,037-10,19 40,47 40,08 0,018 0,016-13,80 42,00 41,55 Over 64 20,6 0,305 0,286-6,24 31,79 32,09 0,080 0,074-8,15 30,89 31,28 0,032 0,028-10,73 28,57 29,27 A: Population Share B and C: Poverty Index FGT0 (distributions of equivalent disposable income before and after the inclusion of imputed income) D: % change in poverty E and F: contributions to aggregate poverty FGT0 (distributions of equivalent disposable income before and after the inclusion of imputed income) G an H: % Poverty Index FGT1 (distributions of equivalent disposable income before and after the inclusion of imputed income) I: % change in poverty, J and K: % contributions to aggregate poverty FGT1(distributions of equivalent disposable income before and after the inclusion of imputed income) L and M: % Poverty Index FGT2 (distributions of equivalent disposable income before and after the inclusion of imputed income) N: % change in poverty, O and P: % contributions to aggregate poverty FGT2(distributions of equivalent disposable income before and after the inclusion of imputed income)

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society Project no: 028412 AIM-AP Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies Specific Targeted Research or Innovation Project Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society Deliverable

More information

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society Project no: 028412 AIM-AP Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies Specific Targeted Research or Innovation Project Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society Deliverable

More information

Distribution of poverty and inequality indices for various groups in Greece using the bootstrap technique

Distribution of poverty and inequality indices for various groups in Greece using the bootstrap technique International Journal of Economic Sciences and Applied Research 4 (2): 81-97 Distribution of poverty and inequality indices for various groups in Greece using the bootstrap technique Dimitra Aggelopoulou

More information

Redistributive effects in a dual income tax system

Redistributive effects in a dual income tax system Þjóðmálastofnun / Social Research Centre Háskóla Íslands / University of Iceland Redistributive effects in a dual income tax system by Arnaldur Sölvi Kristjánsson Rannsóknarritgerðir / Working papers;

More information

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary Social Situation Monitor - Glossary Active labour market policies Measures aimed at improving recipients prospects of finding gainful employment or increasing their earnings capacity or, in the case of

More information

In general, expenditure inequalities are lower than the income inequalities for all consumption categories as shown by the Lorenz curve for four

In general, expenditure inequalities are lower than the income inequalities for all consumption categories as shown by the Lorenz curve for four In general, expenditure inequalities are lower than the income inequalities for all consumption categories as shown by the Lorenz curve for four major categories of expenditure (Figures 9 and 10). According

More information

THE SENSITIVITY OF INCOME INEQUALITY TO CHOICE OF EQUIVALENCE SCALES

THE SENSITIVITY OF INCOME INEQUALITY TO CHOICE OF EQUIVALENCE SCALES Review of Income and Wealth Series 44, Number 4, December 1998 THE SENSITIVITY OF INCOME INEQUALITY TO CHOICE OF EQUIVALENCE SCALES Statistics Norway, To account for the fact that a household's needs depend

More information

METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES IN POVERTY RESEARCH

METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES IN POVERTY RESEARCH METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES IN POVERTY RESEARCH IMPACT OF CHOICE OF EQUIVALENCE SCALE ON INCOME INEQUALITY AND ON POVERTY MEASURES* Ödön ÉLTETÕ Éva HAVASI Review of Sociology Vol. 8 (2002) 2, 137 148 Central

More information

MONTENEGRO. Name the source when using the data

MONTENEGRO. Name the source when using the data MONTENEGRO STATISTICAL OFFICE RELEASE No: 50 Podgorica, 03. 07. 2009 Name the source when using the data THE POVERTY ANALYSIS IN MONTENEGRO IN 2007 Podgorica, july 2009 Table of Contents 1. Introduction...

More information

Income Inequality Measurement in Greece and Alternative Data Sources:

Income Inequality Measurement in Greece and Alternative Data Sources: Journal of Applied Economics and Business Income Inequality Measurement in Greece and Alternative Data Sources: 1957-2010 Kostas Chrissis *1, Alexandra Livada 2, 1 Department of Statistics, Athens University

More information

Estimating the Value and Distributional Effects of Free State Schooling

Estimating the Value and Distributional Effects of Free State Schooling Working Paper 04-2014 Estimating the Value and Distributional Effects of Free State Schooling Sofia Andreou, Christos Koutsampelas and Panos Pashardes Department of Economics, University of Cyprus, P.O.

More information

Topic 11: Measuring Inequality and Poverty

Topic 11: Measuring Inequality and Poverty Topic 11: Measuring Inequality and Poverty Economic well-being (utility) is distributed unequally across the population because income and wealth are distributed unequally. Inequality is measured by the

More information

An Analysis of Public and Private Sector Earnings in Ireland

An Analysis of Public and Private Sector Earnings in Ireland An Analysis of Public and Private Sector Earnings in Ireland 2008-2013 Prepared in collaboration with publicpolicy.ie by: Justin Doran, Nóirín McCarthy, Marie O Connor; School of Economics, University

More information

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society Project no: 028412 AIM-AP Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies Specific Targeted Research or Innovation Project Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society Deliverable

More information

What is So Bad About Inequality? What Can Be Done to Reduce It? Todaro and Smith, Chapter 5 (11th edition)

What is So Bad About Inequality? What Can Be Done to Reduce It? Todaro and Smith, Chapter 5 (11th edition) What is So Bad About Inequality? What Can Be Done to Reduce It? Todaro and Smith, Chapter 5 (11th edition) What is so bad about inequality? 1. Extreme inequality leads to economic inefficiency. - At a

More information

I INTRODUCTION. estimates of the redistributive effects of State taxes and benefits on the distribution of income among households. This publication 1

I INTRODUCTION. estimates of the redistributive effects of State taxes and benefits on the distribution of income among households. This publication 1 The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 13, No. 1, October, 1981, pp. 59-88. Redistribution of Household Income in Ireland by Taxes and Benefits BRIAN NOLAN* Central Bank of Ireland Precis: This study uses

More information

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society Project no: 028412 AIM-AP Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies Specific Targeted Research or Innovation Project Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society Deliverable

More information

PART 4 - ARMENIA: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY IN 2006

PART 4 - ARMENIA: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY IN 2006 PART 4 - ARMENIA: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY IN 2006 CHAPTER 11: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY AND LIVING CONDITIONS ASSESSMENT Poverty can be considered as both an objective and subjective assessment. Poverty estimates

More information

POVERTY ANALYSIS IN MONTENEGRO IN 2013

POVERTY ANALYSIS IN MONTENEGRO IN 2013 MONTENEGRO STATISTICAL OFFICE POVERTY ANALYSIS IN MONTENEGRO IN 2013 Podgorica, December 2014 CONTENT 1. Introduction... 4 2. Poverty in Montenegro in period 2011-2013.... 4 3. Poverty Profile in 2013...

More information

CHAPTER \11 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS, CONCLUSION AND SUGGESTION. decades. Income distribution, as reflected in the distribution of household

CHAPTER \11 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS, CONCLUSION AND SUGGESTION. decades. Income distribution, as reflected in the distribution of household CHAPTER \11 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS, CONCLUSION AND SUGGESTION Income distribution in India shows remarkable stability over four and a half decades. Income distribution, as reflected in the distribution of

More information

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INEQUALITY IN LUXEMBOURG AND THE NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES,

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INEQUALITY IN LUXEMBOURG AND THE NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES, INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INEQUALITY IN LUXEMBOURG AND THE NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES, 1995-2013 by Conchita d Ambrosio and Marta Barazzetta, University of Luxembourg * The opinions expressed and arguments employed

More information

Income Redistribution through Taxation in Canada and the United States: Implications for NAFTA

Income Redistribution through Taxation in Canada and the United States: Implications for NAFTA Law and Business Review of the Americas Volume 1 Number 4 Article 6 1995 Income Redistribution through Taxation in and the United States: Implications for NAFTA Sourushe Zandvakili Follow this and additional

More information

Income distribution and redistribution

Income distribution and redistribution Income distribution and redistribution HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation http://darp.lse.ac.uk/hmrc-hmt Frank Cowell, 7 December 2015 Overview... Income distribution and redistribution Income distribution

More information

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality Economics 448: Measures of Inequality 6 March 2014 1 2 The context Economic inequality: Preliminary observations 3 Inequality Economic growth affects the level of income, wealth, well being. Also want

More information

60% of household expenditures on housing, food and transport

60% of household expenditures on housing, food and transport Household Budget Survey 2015/2016 17 July 2017 60% of household expenditures on housing, food and transport The Inquérito às Despesas das Famílias 2015/2016 (Household Budget Survey/HBS series) definitive

More information

CIE Economics A-level

CIE Economics A-level CIE Economics A-level Topic 3: Government Microeconomic Intervention b) Equity and policies towards income and wealth redistribution Notes In the absence of government intervention, the market mechanism

More information

Income Distribution and Poverty

Income Distribution and Poverty C H A P T E R 15 Income Distribution and Poverty Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano Income Distribution and Poverty This chapter focuses on distribution. Why do some people get more than others?

More information

Income and Non-Income Inequality in Post- Apartheid South Africa: What are the Drivers and Possible Policy Interventions?

Income and Non-Income Inequality in Post- Apartheid South Africa: What are the Drivers and Possible Policy Interventions? Income and Non-Income Inequality in Post- Apartheid South Africa: What are the Drivers and Possible Policy Interventions? Haroon Bhorat Carlene van der Westhuizen Toughedah Jacobs Haroon.Bhorat@uct.ac.za

More information

Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth

Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Summer 22, Vol. 26, No. 3, pp. 2 35 Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of,, and Wealth Santiago Budría Rodríguez Teaching Associate Department

More information

The poverty and inequality nexus in Ghana: a decomposition analysis of household expenditure components

The poverty and inequality nexus in Ghana: a decomposition analysis of household expenditure components The poverty and inequality nexus in Ghana: a decomposition analysis of household expenditure components Jacob Novignon * Economics Department, University of Ibadan, Ibadan-Nigeria Email: nonjake@gmail.com

More information

INCOME INEQUALITY AND OTHER FORMS OF INEQUALITY. Sandip Sarkar & Balwant Singh Mehta. Institute for Human Development New Delhi

INCOME INEQUALITY AND OTHER FORMS OF INEQUALITY. Sandip Sarkar & Balwant Singh Mehta. Institute for Human Development New Delhi INCOME INEQUALITY AND OTHER FORMS OF INEQUALITY Sandip Sarkar & Balwant Singh Mehta Institute for Human Development New Delhi 1 WHAT IS INEQUALITY Inequality is multidimensional, if expressed between individuals,

More information

Impressionistic Realism: The Europeans Focus the U.S. on Measurement David S. Johnson10

Impressionistic Realism: The Europeans Focus the U.S. on Measurement David S. Johnson10 Impressionistic Realism: The Europeans Focus the U.S. on Measurement David S. Johnson10 In the art of communicating impressions lies the power of generalizing without losing that logical connection of

More information

Measuring Wealth Inequality in Europe: A Quest for the Missing Wealthy

Measuring Wealth Inequality in Europe: A Quest for the Missing Wealthy Measuring Wealth Inequality in Europe: A Quest for the Missing Wealthy 1 partly based on joint work with Robin Chakraborty 2 1 LISER - Luxembourg Institute of Socio-Economic Research 2 Deutsche Bundesbank

More information

Public economics: inequality and poverty

Public economics: inequality and poverty Agnes Norris Keiller agnes_nk@ifs.org.uk 1961 1964 1967 1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 Real median income (2007 08 = 100) Average income at an all-time

More information

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM August 2015 151 Slater Street, Suite 710 Ottawa, Ontario K1P 5H3 Tel: 613-233-8891 Fax: 613-233-8250 csls@csls.ca CENTRE FOR THE STUDY OF LIVING STANDARDS SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING

More information

Greek household indebtedness and financial stress: results from household survey data

Greek household indebtedness and financial stress: results from household survey data Greek household indebtedness and financial stress: results from household survey data George T Simigiannis and Panagiota Tzamourani 1 1. Introduction During the three-year period 2003-2005, bank loans

More information

THE DISAGGREGATION OF THE GIN1 COEFFICIENT BY FACTOR COMPONENTS AND ITS APPLICATIONS TO AUSTRALIA

THE DISAGGREGATION OF THE GIN1 COEFFICIENT BY FACTOR COMPONENTS AND ITS APPLICATIONS TO AUSTRALIA Review of Income and Wealth Series 39, Number 1, March 1993 THE DISAGGREGATION OF THE GIN1 COEFFICIENT BY FACTOR COMPONENTS AND ITS APPLICATIONS TO AUSTRALIA The University of New South Wales This paper

More information

Ireland's Income Distribution

Ireland's Income Distribution Ireland's Income Distribution Micheál L. Collins Introduction Judged in an international context, Ireland is a high income country. The 2014 United Nations Human Development Report ranks Ireland as having

More information

MEASURING THE EFFECTIVENESS OF TAXES AND TRANSFERS IN FIGHTING INEQUALITY AND POVERTY. Ali Enami

MEASURING THE EFFECTIVENESS OF TAXES AND TRANSFERS IN FIGHTING INEQUALITY AND POVERTY. Ali Enami MEASURING THE EFFECTIVENESS OF TAXES AND TRANSFERS IN FIGHTING INEQUALITY AND POVERTY Ali Enami Working Paper 64 July 2017 1 The CEQ Working Paper Series The CEQ Institute at Tulane University works to

More information

AN APPLICATION OF THE CEQ EFFECTIVENESS INDICATORS: THE CASE OF IRAN

AN APPLICATION OF THE CEQ EFFECTIVENESS INDICATORS: THE CASE OF IRAN AN APPLICATION OF THE CEQ EFFECTIVENESS INDICATORS: THE CASE OF IRAN Ali Enami Working Paper 58 November 2016 (Revised July 2017) 1 The CEQ Working Paper Series The CEQ Institute at Tulane University works

More information

Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States

Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States Kennesaw State University DigitalCommons@Kennesaw State University Faculty Publications 5-14-2012 Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States Timothy Mathews

More information

Poverty and income inequality

Poverty and income inequality Poverty and income inequality Jonathan Cribb Public Economics Lectures, Institute for Fiscal Studies 17 th December 2012 Overview The standard of living in the UK Income Inequality The UK income distribution

More information

Welfare Benefits In Kind and Income Distribution

Welfare Benefits In Kind and Income Distribution Fiscal Studies (1993) vol. 14, no. 1, pp. 57-76 Welfare Benefits In Kind and Income Distribution MARIA EVANDROU,* JANE FALKINGHAM, JOHN HILLS and JULIAN LE GRAND I. INTRODUCTION This article explores the

More information

TRENDS IN INCOME DISTRIBUTION

TRENDS IN INCOME DISTRIBUTION TRENDS IN INCOME DISTRIBUTION Authors * : Abstract: In modern society the income distribution is one of the major problems. Usually, it is considered that a severe polarisation in matter of income per

More information

Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE

Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORAMA Haroon

More information

Public Economics: Poverty and Inequality

Public Economics: Poverty and Inequality Public Economics: Poverty and Inequality Andrew Hood Overview Why do we use income? Income Inequality The UK income distribution Measures of income inequality Explaining changes in income inequality Income

More information

Inequality and Poverty in Greece: Changes in Times of Crisis

Inequality and Poverty in Greece: Changes in Times of Crisis Inequality and Poverty in Greece: Changes in Times of Crisis Eirini Andriopoulou, Alexandros Karakitsios, Panos Tsakloglou GreeSE Paper No.116 Hellenic Observatory Papers on Greece and Southeast Europe

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN Olympia Bover 1 Introduction and summary Dierences in wealth distribution across developed countries are large (eg share held by top 1%: 15 to 35%)

More information

Social exclusion, long term poverty and social transfers in the EU: Evidence from the ECHP

Social exclusion, long term poverty and social transfers in the EU: Evidence from the ECHP Panos Tsakloglou Athens University of Economics and Business, IZA & IMOP and Fotis Papadopoulos Athens University of Economics and Business Social exclusion, long term poverty and social transfers in the

More information

The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in

The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in Summary 1 The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in state funding assistance between municipalities in South NJ compared to similar municipalities in Central and North

More information

1 Income Inequality in the US

1 Income Inequality in the US 1 Income Inequality in the US We started this course with a study of growth; Y = AK N 1 more of A; K; and N give more Y: But who gets the increased Y? Main question: if the size of the national cake Y

More information

Poverty and Inequality in Ireland : A Comparison using measures of Income and Consumption 1

Poverty and Inequality in Ireland : A Comparison using measures of Income and Consumption 1 Poverty and Inequality in Ireland 1987-1994 : A Comparison using measures of Income and Consumption 1 Donal O'Neill and Olive Sweetman 2 NUI Maynooth, Co Kildare, Ireland March 1999 Abstract This paper

More information

Household Income and Asset Distribution in Korea

Household Income and Asset Distribution in Korea Household Income and Asset Distribution in Korea Sang-ho Nam Research Fellow, KIHASA Introduction This study bases its analysis of household and asset distribution on the Household Finances and Welfare

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

DECOMPOSING INEQUALITY BY POPULATION SUBGROUPS IN GREECE: RESULTS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. Christos Papatheodorou

DECOMPOSING INEQUALITY BY POPULATION SUBGROUPS IN GREECE: RESULTS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. Christos Papatheodorou DECOMPOSING INEQUALITY BY POPULATION SUBGROUPS IN GREECE: RESULTS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS By Christos Papatheodorou Discussion Paper No. DARP 49 November 2000 Distributional Analysis Research Programme

More information

Volume 30, Issue 1. Stochastic Dominance, Poverty and the Treatment Effect Curve. Paolo Verme University of Torino

Volume 30, Issue 1. Stochastic Dominance, Poverty and the Treatment Effect Curve. Paolo Verme University of Torino Volume 3, Issue 1 Stochastic Dominance, Poverty and the Treatment Effect Curve Paolo Verme University of Torino Abstract The paper proposes a simple framework for the evaluation of anti-poverty programs

More information

Globalization and the Feminization of Poverty within Tradable and Non-Tradable Economic Activities

Globalization and the Feminization of Poverty within Tradable and Non-Tradable Economic Activities Istanbul Technical University ESRC Research Papers Research Papers 2009/02 Globalization and the Feminization of Poverty within Tradable and Non-Tradable Economic Activities Raziye Selim and Öner Günçavdı

More information

WEEK 7 INCOME DISTRIBUTION & QUALITY OF LIFE

WEEK 7 INCOME DISTRIBUTION & QUALITY OF LIFE WEEK 7 INCOME DISTRIBUTION & QUALITY OF LIFE Di akhir topik ini, pelajar akan dapat menjelaskan Agihan pendapatan Konsep and pengukuran kemiskinan Insiden kemiskinan dalam dan luar negara Why is income

More information

Some Explanations for Changes in the Distribution of Household Income in Slovakia: 1988 and 1996

Some Explanations for Changes in the Distribution of Household Income in Slovakia: 1988 and 1996 Some Explanations for Changes in the Distribution of Household Income in Slovakia: 1988 and 1996 By: Thesia Garner and Katherine Terrell Working Paper No. 377 May 2001 SOME EXPLANATIONS FOR CHANGES IN

More information

1. The Armenian Integrated Living Conditions Survey

1. The Armenian Integrated Living Conditions Survey MEASURING POVERTY IN ARMENIA: METHODOLOGICAL EXPLANATIONS Since 1996, when the current methodology for surveying well being of households was introduced in Armenia, the National Statistical Service of

More information

vio SZY em Growing Unequal? INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY IN OECD COUNTRIES

vio SZY em Growing Unequal? INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY IN OECD COUNTRIES vio SZY em Growing Unequal? INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY IN OECD COUNTRIES Table of Contents Introduction 15 Parti MAIN FEATURES OF INEQUALITY Chapter 1. The Distribution of Household Income in OECD

More information

Revisiting the cost of children: theory and evidence from Ireland

Revisiting the cost of children: theory and evidence from Ireland : theory and evidence from Ireland Olivier Bargain (UCD) Olivier Bargain (UCD) () CPA - 3rd March 2009 1 / 28 Introduction Motivation Goal is to infer sharing of resources in households using economic

More information

Catalogue no XIE. Income in Canada

Catalogue no XIE. Income in Canada Catalogue no. 75-202-XIE Income in Canada 2005 How to obtain more information Specific inquiries about this product and related statistics or services should be directed to: Income in Canada, Statistics

More information

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016)

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) 68-131 An Investigation of the Structural Characteristics of the Indian IT Sector and the Capital Goods Sector An Application of the

More information

Growth in Pakistan: Inclusive or Not? Zunia Saif Tirmazee 1 and Maryiam Haroon 2

Growth in Pakistan: Inclusive or Not? Zunia Saif Tirmazee 1 and Maryiam Haroon 2 Growth in Pakistan: Inclusive or Not? Zunia Saif Tirmazee 1 and Maryiam Haroon 2 Introduction Cross country evidences reveal that Asian countries have experienced rapid growth over the last two decades.

More information

An inequality index of multidimensional inequality of opportunity

An inequality index of multidimensional inequality of opportunity An inequality index of multidimensional inequality of opportunity Gaston Yalonetzky Oxford Poverty and Human Development Initiative, University of Oxford November 2009 Table of contents Introduction The

More information

St. Gallen, Switzerland, August 22-28, 2010

St. Gallen, Switzerland, August 22-28, 2010 Session Number: Parallel Session 7A Time: Friday, August 27, AM Paper Prepared for the 31st General Conference of The International Association for Research in Income and Wealth St. Gallen, Switzerland,

More information

Distributional effects of non-cash incomes in seven European countries

Distributional effects of non-cash incomes in seven European countries Panos Tsakloglou, 1 Tim Callan, 2 Kieran Coleman, 2 Conchita D'Ambrosio, 3 Klaas de Vos, 4 Joachim R. Frick, 5 Chiara Gigliarano, 6 Tim Goedemé, 7 Markus M. Grabka, 5 Olaf Groh-Samberg, 5 Claire Keane,

More information

Who is Poorer? Poverty by Age in the Developing World

Who is Poorer? Poverty by Age in the Developing World Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized The note is a joint product of the Social Protection and Labor & Poverty and Equity Global

More information

Redistributive Effects of Pension Reform in China

Redistributive Effects of Pension Reform in China COMPONENT ONE Redistributive Effects of Pension Reform in China Li Shi and Zhu Mengbing China Institute for Income Distribution Beijing Normal University NOVEMBER 2017 CONTENTS 1. Introduction 4 2. The

More information

This study is concerned with income distribution and is intended as a. The Distribution and Redistribution of Income in the Republic of Ireland

This study is concerned with income distribution and is intended as a. The Distribution and Redistribution of Income in the Republic of Ireland The Economic and Social Review, Vol 13, No. 4, July 1982, pp. 251-278 The Distribution and Redistribution of Income in the Republic of Ireland PHILIP J. O'CONNELL* The Economic and Social Research Institute,

More information

GENDER AND INDIRECT TAX INCIDENCE IN GHANA

GENDER AND INDIRECT TAX INCIDENCE IN GHANA GENDER AND INDIRECT TAX INCIDENCE IN GHANA Isaac Osei-Akoto, Robert Darko Osei and Ernest Aryeetey ISSER, University of Ghana 2009 IAFFE ANNUAL CONFERENCE Simmons College Boston, MA, 26-28 June 2009 Data:-

More information

The Economic Situation and Income Inequality among the Older People in Japan: Measurement by Quasi Public Assistance Standard 1

The Economic Situation and Income Inequality among the Older People in Japan: Measurement by Quasi Public Assistance Standard 1 Review of Population and Social Policy, No. 10, 2001, 81 106 The Economic Situation and Income Inequality among the Older People in Japan: Measurement by Quasi Public Assistance Standard 1 Atsuhiro YAMADA*

More information

Creating Labor Market Diagnostics in LICs and MICs

Creating Labor Market Diagnostics in LICs and MICs Creating abor Market Diagnostics in ICs and MICs March 2009 otation ational level variables: P- Poverty measure population U number of unemployed in the economy number of economically active (employed

More information

Effectiveness of the Cutoff Audit Rule and Inequality of Income

Effectiveness of the Cutoff Audit Rule and Inequality of Income α Effectiveness of the Cutoff Audit Rule and Inequality of Income by PISSAS DIMITRIOS a and KOTSIOS STELIOS b Department of Economics, National and Kapodistrian University of Athens, Athens, Greece. email:

More information

To understand the drivers of poverty reduction,

To understand the drivers of poverty reduction, Understanding the Drivers of Poverty Reduction To understand the drivers of poverty reduction, we decompose the distributional changes in consumption and income over the 7 to 1 period, and examine the

More information

ECON 450 Development Economics

ECON 450 Development Economics and Poverty ECON 450 Development Economics Measuring Poverty and Inequality University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Summer 2017 and Poverty Introduction In this lecture we ll introduce appropriate measures

More information

Differentials in pension prospects for minority ethnic groups in the UK

Differentials in pension prospects for minority ethnic groups in the UK Differentials in pension prospects for minority ethnic groups in the UK Vlachantoni, A., Evandrou, M., Falkingham, J. and Feng, Z. Centre for Research on Ageing and ESRC Centre for Population Change Faculty

More information

Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper Series

Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper Series Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper Series Working Paper No. 150 Noncash Benefits and Income Distribution Elisabeth Steckmest December 1996 Luxembourg Income Study (LIS), asbl Noncash benefits and income

More information

JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL ACADEMIC RESEARCH FOR MULTIDISCIPLINARY Impact Factor 2.417, ISSN: , Volume 3, Issue 11, December 2015

JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL ACADEMIC RESEARCH FOR MULTIDISCIPLINARY Impact Factor 2.417, ISSN: , Volume 3, Issue 11, December 2015 INCOME AND RESOURCE INEQUALITY IN BIKANER DISTRICT OF NORTHERN RAJASTHAN, INDIA MADAMELKAMU* KUMAR DINESH** *PhD Scholar (Agricultural Economics), College of Agriculture, S.K Rajasthan, Agricultural University,

More information

A new multiplicative decomposition for the Foster-Greer-Thorbecke poverty indices.

A new multiplicative decomposition for the Foster-Greer-Thorbecke poverty indices. A new multiplicative decomposition for the Foster-Greer-Thorbecke poverty indices. Mª Casilda Lasso de la Vega University of the Basque Country Ana Marta Urrutia University of the Basque Country and Oihana

More information

Growth, Inequality, and Social Welfare: Cross-Country Evidence

Growth, Inequality, and Social Welfare: Cross-Country Evidence Growth, Inequality, and Social Welfare 1 Growth, Inequality, and Social Welfare: Cross-Country Evidence David Dollar, Tatjana Kleineberg, and Aart Kraay Brookings Institution; Yale University; The World

More information

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman Journal of Health Economics 20 (2001) 283 288 Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman Åke Blomqvist Department of Economics, University of

More information

Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries

Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries Poverty Reduction Group Poverty Reduction and Economic Management (PREM) World Bank ADePT: Labor Version 1.0 Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries User s Guide: Definitions

More information

THE REDISTRIBUTIVE EFFECT OF THE ROMANIAN TAX- BENEFIT SYSTEM: A MICROSIMULATION APPROACH 1

THE REDISTRIBUTIVE EFFECT OF THE ROMANIAN TAX- BENEFIT SYSTEM: A MICROSIMULATION APPROACH 1 THE REDISTRIBUTIVE EFFECT OF THE ROMANIAN TAX- BENEFIT SYSTEM: A MICROSIMULATION APPROACH 1 Eva MILITARU Postdoctoral fellow, Bucharest University of Economic Studies, Romania Researcher, National Research

More information

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM Revenue Summit 17 October 2018 The Australia Institute Patricia Apps The University of Sydney Law School, ANU, UTS and IZA ABSTRACT

More information

CONSUMPTION POVERTY IN THE REPUBLIC OF KOSOVO April 2017

CONSUMPTION POVERTY IN THE REPUBLIC OF KOSOVO April 2017 CONSUMPTION POVERTY IN THE REPUBLIC OF KOSOVO 2012-2015 April 2017 The World Bank Europe and Central Asia Region Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Unit www.worldbank.org Kosovo Agency of Statistics

More information

ECONOMETRIC SCALES OF EQUIVALENCE, THEIR IMPLEMENTATIONS IN ALBANIA

ECONOMETRIC SCALES OF EQUIVALENCE, THEIR IMPLEMENTATIONS IN ALBANIA ECONOMETRIC SCALES OF EQUIVALENCE, THEIR IMPLEMENTATIONS IN ALBANIA Msc. Evgjeni Xhafaj Department of Mathematics, Faculty of Nature Sciences, University of Tirana, Tirana, Albania PhD, Ines Nurja General

More information

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations Online Appendix of Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality By ANDREAS FAGERENG, LUIGI GUISO, DAVIDE MALACRINO AND LUIGI PISTAFERRI This appendix complements the evidence

More information

Interaction of household income, consumption and wealth - statistics on main results

Interaction of household income, consumption and wealth - statistics on main results Interaction of household income, consumption and wealth - statistics on main results Statistics Explained Data extracted in June 2017. Most recent data: Further Eurostat information, Main tables and Database.

More information

Economic Inequality in Portugal: A Picture in the Beginnings of the 21st century

Economic Inequality in Portugal: A Picture in the Beginnings of the 21st century MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Economic Inequality in Portugal: A Picture in the Beginnings of the 21st century Santiago Budria University of Madeira and CEEAplA 2007 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/1784/

More information

Income and Resource Inequality in Nagaur District of Northern Rajasthan Using Lorenz curve and Gini coefficient Approach

Income and Resource Inequality in Nagaur District of Northern Rajasthan Using Lorenz curve and Gini coefficient Approach American International Journal of Research in Humanities, Arts and Social Sciences Available online at http://www.iasir.net ISSN (Print): 2328-3734, ISSN (Online): 2328-3696, ISSN (CD-ROM): 2328-3688 AIJRHASS

More information

INSTITUTO NACIONAL DE ESTADÍSTICA. Descriptive study of poverty in Spain Results based on the Living Conditions Survey 2004

INSTITUTO NACIONAL DE ESTADÍSTICA. Descriptive study of poverty in Spain Results based on the Living Conditions Survey 2004 INSTITUTO NACIONAL DE ESTADÍSTICA Descriptive study of poverty in Spain Results based on the Living Conditions Survey 2004 Index Foreward... 1 Poverty in Spain... 2 1. Incidences of poverty... 3 1.1.

More information

Harmonized Household Budget Survey how to make it an effective supplementary tool for measuring living conditions

Harmonized Household Budget Survey how to make it an effective supplementary tool for measuring living conditions Harmonized Household Budget Survey how to make it an effective supplementary tool for measuring living conditions Andreas GEORGIOU, President of Hellenic Statistical Authority Giorgos NTOUROS, Household

More information

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018 Summary of Keister & Moller 2000 This review summarized wealth inequality in the form of net worth. Authors examined empirical evidence of wealth accumulation and distribution, presented estimates of trends

More information

Redistribution Through the Income Tax: The Vertical and Horizontal Effects of Noncompliance and Tax Evasion

Redistribution Through the Income Tax: The Vertical and Horizontal Effects of Noncompliance and Tax Evasion Redistribution Through the Income Tax: The Vertical and Horizontal Effects of Noncompliance and Tax Evasion John A. Bishop Department of Economics East Carolina University, USA John P. Formby Department

More information

Poverty Analysis Poverty and Dominance

Poverty Analysis Poverty and Dominance Module 035 Poverty Analysis ANALYTICAL TOOLS Poverty Analysis by Lorenzo Giovanni Bellù, Agricultural Policy Support Service, Policy Assistance Division, FAO, Rome, Italy Paolo Liberati, University of

More information

MEASUREMENT AND CHARACTERIZATION OF THE MIDDLE CLASS IN LATIN AMERICA 1

MEASUREMENT AND CHARACTERIZATION OF THE MIDDLE CLASS IN LATIN AMERICA 1 MEASUREMENT AND CHARACTERIZATION OF THE MIDDLE CLASS IN LATIN AMERICA 1 Maria F. Cortés Public Policy Consultant Econometría Consultores Nancy A. Daza Researcher at Directorate of Economic Studies National

More information

INCOME AND EXPENDITURE: PHILIPPINES. Euromonitor International March 2015

INCOME AND EXPENDITURE: PHILIPPINES. Euromonitor International March 2015 INCOME AND EXPENDITURE: PHILIPPINES Euromonitor International March 2015 I N C O M E A N D E X P E N D I T U R E : P H I L I P P I N E S P a s s p o r t I LIST OF CONTENTS AND TABLES Chart 1 SWOT Analysis:

More information