Firm Default and Aggregate Fluctuations

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Firm Default and Aggregate Fluctuations"

Transcription

1 Firm Default and Aggregate Fluctuations Tor Jacobson Jesper Lindé Kasper Roszbach August 22, 2011 Abstract This paper studies the relationship between macroeconomic fluctuations and corporate defaults while conditioning on industry affiliation and an extensive set of firm-specific factors. By using a panel data set for virtually all incorporated Swedish businesses over , a period which includes a full-scale banking crisis, we find strong evidence for a substantial and stable impact from aggregate fluctuations on business defaults. A standard logit model with financial ratios augmented with macroeconomic factors can account surprisingly well for the outburst in business defaults during the banking crisis, as well as the subsequent fluctuations in default frequencies. Moreover, the effects of macroeconomic variables differ across industries in an economically intuitive way. Out-of-sample evaluations show that our approach is superior to models that exclude macro information and standard well-fitting time-series models. Our analysis shows that firm-specific factors are useful in ranking firms relative riskiness,but that macroeconomic factors are necessary to understand fluctuations in the absolute risk level. Keywords: Default, default-risk model, business cycles, aggregate fluctuations, microdata, logit, firm-specific variables, macroeconomic variables JEL: C35, C52, E44, G33. Jacobson and Roszbach: Research Division, Sveriges Riksbank, firstname.lastname@riksbank.se. Lindé: Federal Reserve Board and CEPR, jesper.l.linde@frb.gov. We would like to thank Rikard Kindell, who co-authored the working paper version of this paper on a shorter data sample for outstanding contributions to this project. Discussions with and suggestions from Franklin Allen, Ed Altman, Mitch Berlin, Mark Carey, Ines Drumond, Xavier Freixas, Bob Hunt, Wenli Li, Leonard Nakamura, Dragon Tang, Cees Ullersma, and Kostas Tsatsaronis have been very helpful in improving upon earlier drafts. We are also grateful for comments from seminar participants at the Bank of Austria, the Bank of Hungary, the Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance, the Bank of England, the Bank of Finland, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Uppsala University, EARIE, the C.R.E.D.I.T conference, the EEA-ESEM meetings in Budapest (2008) and Barcelona (2009), the 2009 BIS Research task force workshop, the 2008 ASSA meetings, the DNB conference on Financial Stability and Financial Crises, and the BIS. Erica Reisman, Erik von Schedvin and Ingvar Strid provided outstanding research assistance. The views expressed in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Executive Board of Sveriges Riksbank, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System.

2 1 Introduction The failure of a business is an event of fundamental importance in economic life. Our understanding of the determinants of business defaults, despite long-studying, is far from complete, particularly with respect to the influences of broader economic conditions. Recent economic events, namely a global financial crisis shifting into a recession of exceptional depth, highlight the importance of understanding and predicting this crucial aspect of the economy, not least for timely and appropriate policy measures. The aim of this paper is to shed light on the dynamics of business defaults. In particular, we seek to understand the interactions between macroeconomic fluctuations and firms individual likelihoods to default, as well as the relationship between macro variables and the aggregate rate of default. To this end we have compiled a new panel data set with detailed firm-level information on all incorporated Swedish businesses over the period The panel comprises more than 16 million firm-date observations, with an average of more than firms per point in time. The length and width of this panel allow for several extensions of previous research; we are able to, among other things, carefully evaluate industry-specific effects of macroeconomic fluctuations. Since our data set includes virtually all incorporated Swedish firms, our findings provide insight into the significance of aggregate fluctuations for both listed and privately held firms; the latter group is typically responsible for over half of GDP in developed economies. This feature is important because Merton-like models of default, being based on equity-price information, are in practice limited to listed firms. Econometric studies of business defaults started in the 1960s with work by Altman and coauthors ( ). These influential papers focus on explaining bankruptcies of publicly quoted businesses in a cross-sectional context using a small set of firm-specific variables. Later work by Shumway (2001) attempts to account for the dynamic nature of defaults for publicly listed firms. Bharath and Shumway (2008) evaluate the out-of-sample accuracy of the 1

3 Merton (1974) modelandfind that the distance-to-default measure is not a sufficient statistic for the probability of default. Over time the average default frequency and individual default probabilities display comovement with macroeconomic and financial variables in a way that suggests that aggregate shocks might be an important driver of default. The seminal work of Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1999) provides a theoretical framework whereby both firm-specific factors and macro shocks affect the default outcome of individual firms. In the BGG framework, firm default is affected by firm-specific productivity shocks and aggregate shocks (e.g., an aggregate productivity shock). Hence, it follows that an empirical model of default should feature variables that proxy for the underlying firm-specific productivity, as well as variables that proxy for unobserved aggregate shocks. The recent paper by Hackbarth, Miao and Morellec (2006) provides an additional mechanism through which macroeconomic conditions affect default risk. They argue that, when cash flows depend on economic conditions, firms optimal default thresholds will be affected by aggregate shocks. Hence, aggregate shocks can trigger simultaneous defaults. These theoretical insights have recently been explored in the empirical literature on default modelling, and there is a small but growing number of papers investigating the importance of macroeconomic fluctuations on business defaults. Recent work by Duffie, Saita and Wang (2007), Pesaran, Schuerman, Treutler, and Weiner (2006), Bonfim (2009), Lando and Nielsen (2010), and Tang and Yan (2010) provides empirical evidence that firm-specific factors alone appear unable to fully explain the variation in corporate default rates and credit spreads. Using aggregate times series and data on publicly listed industrial firms, these authors find that macrofinancial covariates have significant explanatory power for credit losses, spreads and corporate default rates using structural and reduced-form approaches. In this paper, we adopt a standard econometric specification and estimate multi-period logistic regressions on firm-level default data. Shumway (2001) shows that, under some mild 2

4 restrictions, this model is equivalent to a discrete-time hazard model, and hence not prone to the bias and inconsistency of the static model hitherto used in bankruptcy modelling. In addition to an extensive set of financial statement variables and payment remarks reflecting a firm s financial track record, we include four standard macroeconomic variables. The default risk models are estimated both at an economy-wide level and for 10 industries on a sub-sample covering Our large panel data set enables us to make several contributions to the above-mentioned literature. First, we show that a simple logit model with constant parameters is able to account for the outburst in default rates during the Swedish banking crisis, as well as the historically low rates occurring in subsequent recovery periods. The included macroeconomic variables are of key importance for explaining the time-varying likelihood of default. Firm-specific variables prove insufficient for explaining variation in the level of default risk over time, but are very useful for ranking firms according to their relative riskiness. Second, having access to a very rich set of firm-specific controls we can credibly reject the possibility that the empirical significance of macroeconomic variables is merely (or partially) an artifact of a shortage of firm-specific controls. Third, the length of our panel enables us to do extensive out-of-sample performance testing The results suggest that the default risk models with both macroeconomic and firm-specific variables included perform very well out-of-sample. This holds both in the cross-sectional and the time-series dimension. Fourth, the width of our panel permits us to investigate the relationship between aggregate fluctuations and business defaults across industries. By isolating and comparing industry-specific effects from macroeconomic variables we get an additional measure of the robustness of their impact on business defaults. Our results arequiteintuitiveandsuggestthattheeffects are stronger in sectors like construction and real estate, which on a priori grounds can be deemed to be more cyclical since they involve production of more durable goods. Fifth, the combined width and length of our panel allow us to look 3

5 into the stability over time of cross-sectionally estimated parameters. We show that models estimated on cross-sectional data are likely to suffer from substantial parameter instability over time, and therefore will be unable to account for variations in the average default frequency over time. Finally, our analysis also suggests that considering only macroeconomic variables while ignoring relevant firm-specific information leads to a substantial loss of out-of-sample prediction accuracy. According to our analysis, the two key macroeconomic factors affecting business defaults are the nominal interest rate and the output gap. In the current situation, where economic activity and the output gap in many countries have dropped at the fastest pace since the Great Depression, our results suggest that central banks can reduce the likelihood of an outburst in defaults rates and the associated spike in credit losses for banks by aggressively cutting nominal interest rates. Interestingly, this is exactly what many central banks have done during the recent crisis. The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. The next section presents the micro and macro data sets. The regression results are presented in Section 3 along with an assessment of the in-sample fit. In Section 4, we undertake a thorough out-of-sample investigation of the estimated models along several dimensions. Finally, Section 5 concludes. 2 Data The firm data set is a panel consisting of quarterly observations on the population of Swedish aktiebolag, or firms, between January 1, 1990, and June 30, Aktiebolagareby approximation the Swedish equivalent of US corporations and UK limited liability businesses. Swedish law requires every aktiebolag to have at least SEK (approximately US$ ) of equity to be eligible for registration at Bolagsverket, the Swedish Companies Registration Office (SCRO). Swedish corporations are also required to submit an annual report to the SCRO. 4

6 The firm data have been obtained from Upplysningscentralen AB (UC), the leading credit bureau in Sweden, independently operated but jointly owned by the Swedish commercial banks. The UC data come from two general sources. Annual balance sheet and income statement data come from firms compulsory annual reports submitted to the SCRO. These data cover the period January 1, 1989, through June 30, 2009, and the format follows European Union standards. We convert the annual report data into quarterly observations by linear interpolation, i.e., we assume that the variables remain constant over the quarters in a given reporting period. The second information source is atypical in the existing default literature and is somewhat unique for Sweden. The credit bureau systematically collects information about events related to firms payment behavior from all relevant sources, e.g., the Swedish retail banks, the Swedish tax authorities, and the institutions that deal with the legal formalities in firms bankruptcy processes. The credit bureau thus has a register of more than 60 different payment remarks concerning primarily credit and tax-related events, but also records of various steps in the legal procedures leading up to formal bankruptcy. The information in the register includes a flag for the occurrence of an event in the form of a date and the amount of due payment (if applicable). Some examples of registered events are delays in tax payments, the repossession of delivered goods, the seizure of property, the restructuring of loans, and actual bankruptcy. Payment remarks turn out to be powerful predictors of default and are essentially available in real-time. Admittedly, to allow for comparability with other studies, one might prefer excluding payment remarks, as these are not generally available outside Sweden. However, we prefer to include the payment remarks in our analysis in order to have a comprehensive set of firm-specific control variables. This way, we seek to eliminate the possibility of macroeconomic variables spuriously proxying for omitted firm-specific controls. In the online Appendix B, however, it is shown that the role of neither the accounting variables nor the macroeconomic factors is much affected by the inclusion of the remark variables that we consider. 5

7 The population of existing firms in quarter is defined as including those firms that have issued a financial statement covering that quarter and are classified as active, i.e., the firm has reported total sales and total assets in excess of SEK (roughly US$ 130). However, since there are firms that neglect to fulfill their reporting obligation, a behavior typically associated with distress, we would miss an important segment of firms by only considering those that submit annual reports regularly. For this reason, we will add firms that, according to the data set with payment remarks, are classified as defaulted firms in quarter. Manyfirms that default choose not to submit their compulsory annual reports in that year or even for a number of years prior to default. Hence, often the only records of their existence that we have come from the payment remark registers. We adopt the following definition of a default: a firm has default status if any of the following events has occurred: the firm is declared legally bankrupt, has suspended payments, has negotiated a debt composition settlement, is undergoing a re-construction, or is distraint without assets. More details on the construction of the default variable are provided in the online Appendix A. For the selection of which financial ratios to use in the default models, we evaluated a large number of frequently used ratios in the literature on bankruptcy risk and on the balance sheet channel. 1 Many papers employ measures of liquidity, profitability and efficiency, and solvency or leverage, while some also make use of a size variable. In this paper the six selected financial ratios are: earnings before interest, depreciation, taxes and amortization (EBITDA) over total assets (TA) (earnings ratio); interest payments (IP) over the sum of interest payments and earnings before interest, depreciation, taxes and amortization (interest coverage ratio); total liabilities (TL) over total assets (leverage ratio); the log of total liabilities over total sales (TS) (debt ratio); liquid assets (LA) in relation to total liabilities (quick ratio); and inventories (I) 1 Table A.1 in Appendix A.3 provides an account of the variables considered in Altman (1968), Altman, Frydman, and Kao (1985), Shumway (2001), Pesaran et al (2006), Duffie et al (2007), Bonfim (2009), and Bharath and Shumway (2008). 6

8 over total sales (inventory turnover ratio). Details on the selection of financial ratios along with a graphical exposition of the data are provided in Appendix A.2. It is important to note that the non-linear feature of some financial ratios does not imply that these variables are uninformative for default risk when entered linearly in the logit model. The reason for this is that the covariation between the financial ratios in the cross-section is substantial, which makes each of these variables contribute substantially to predicting default events in the joint linear empirical model. Moreover, the accounting data provides information on whether a firm has paid out dividends to shareholders or not, which we enter as a dummy variable (PAYDIV) in the models. As mentioned previously, some firms classified as active, or defaulted, fail to submit a financial report in every period, leading to a missing-observation problem. For the purpose of using an aggregate default series that closely corresponds to the official default frequency series as computed in the official statistics for Sweden and to ensure unbiased macro coefficients in the econometric model, we decided to retain firmswithmissingvariablesinthesample, byreplacing missing values by imputation rather than excluding such firms from the sample. 2 In order to capture the relationship between not submitting a financial statement and subsequent default, we include a dummy variable, denoted TTLFS. In line with actual reporting lags, this dummy equals unity at time if a firm has not issued a financial statement in the one and a half years prior to the current quarter, and equals zero otherwise. 3 TTLFS attempts to capture the signal that many firms (deliberately) choose not to file a financial report when in financial distress, and thus are more likely to default. In Appendix B.2 we document that our results are robust w.r.t. the approach that we use to deal with missing observations by reporting results where we only include firms for which data on all the financial ratios are available. 2 Imputation is implemented in a sequential procedure for a given variable according to: (i) a backward search for the last available observation for that particular firm in the past, (ii) a forward search for future observations for the firm, (iii) if these measures fail, a randomized draw from the data is done conditional on industry and default status. 3 See Appendix A.2 for more details about TTLFS. 7

9 For the remark variables, we use simple dummy variables by setting them to unity if certain remarks existed for the firm during the year prior to quarter, and 0 otherwise. An intuitively reasonable starting point was to find remark events that (i) lead default in time as much as possible and (ii) are highly correlated with default. As it turns out, many payment remark variables are either contemporaneously correlated with default or lack a significant correlation with default behavior. For our final model, we constructed the PAYREMARK variable as a composite dummy of four events: a bankruptcy petition, the issuance of a court order - because of absence during the court hearing - to pay a debt, the seizure of property, and havinganon-performingloan. TheTAXARREARSvariablereflects whether the firm is in various tax arrears. It should be emphasized, however, that these two remark variables do not imply a subsequent default incident. The shares of defaulted firms that have received payment remarks, or are in tax arrears, are about 0.15 and 0.41, respectively. Corresponding shares for non-defaulted firms are 0.00 and Hence, there are no tautological issues involved in using these variables to predict default events. Table A.2 in Appendix A.3 provides descriptive statistics for all firm-specific variables that are used in the subsequent analyses. We make use of four aggregate variables: the output gap (i.e., the deviation of GDP from its trend value), the yearly inflation rate (measured as the fourth difference of the GDP deflator), the repo interest rate (a short-term nominal interest rate, set by the Riksbank), and the real exchange rate. The output gap series is computed by HP-filtering GDP, where the smoothing coefficient is set to the standard value of The real exchange rate is measured as the trade weighted nominal exchange rate times trade weighted foreign price level (CPI deflators) divided by the domestic CPI deflator. During the sample period, the real exchange rate is characterized by an upward (depreciating) trend and it is therefore detrended with the HP-filter to achieve stationarity. Appendix A.2 provides a figure with the macro data and Appendix B.3 verifies that the results presented below are robust with respect to our detrending procedure of the real 8

10 exchange rate. 3 The default-risk models: Estimation and in-sample fit In this section, we examine if default risk at the firm level is affected by aggregate fluctuations over and above the set of firm-specific information that we have at our disposal. We study the in-sample gains of estimating separate models for each industry and assess the role of aggregate fluctuations for improving the models fit. The in-sample period is chosen to be For this period, we have a total of observations of which are defaults. The out-of-sample period, , is saved to allow for extensive model-evaluation exercises. and comprises a total of observations of which are defaults. Thus, the average default frequency per quarter equals about 1 percent in our dataset for the full sample period. This is somewhat higher than the 0.75 percent per quarter business failure rate reported for the US by, among others, Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1999), but if we exclude the banking crisis and instead consider the period , then the average unconditional default frequency essentially equals the value reported by Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist. Analyses of industry effects will be conducted at the one-digit level to ensure sufficiently many default observations in each industry in both the cross-sectional and the time series dimensions. In addition, we estimate the model for all firms jointly, and will refer to this model as the economy wide model. 3.1 The default-risk models The reduced-form statistical model that we employ for estimating probabilities of default for all Swedish incorporated firms is similar to the multiperiod logit approach used in Shumway (2001) and Campbell, Hilscher, and Szilagyi (2008). Using a reduced-form model both avoids the problem that the Merton (1974) model has, namely that it cannot be implemented for privately 9

11 held companies without very strong assumptions, and enables us to use a unified approach for all businesses, both privately and publicly held. As discussed in the introduction, there is also a recent theoretical literature - including papers by Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1999), Hackbarth, Miao and Morellec (2006) and Tang and Yan (2010) - which argues that both firmspecific and aggregate shocks can trigger simultaneous defaults. Thus we propose to estimate the following model: = + + where = ( 1 if (firm defaults) 0 if (firm stays in business) under the assumption that the vector of firm-specific regressors (i.e., ) and the macroeconomic variables we consider (collected in the vector ) are stochastically independent with respect to the error term. This approach also allows us to control for the competing risk of exiting firms due to other reasons than default (Allison, 1995). We also make the additional assumptions that, conditional on the extensive set of firm-specific and macroeconomic set of covariates we consider, the errors are independent between both firms and time points, i.e., ( )= ( ) ( ) for 6= and ( + )= ( ) ( + ) for 6= 0. These assumptions are rejected by Das, Duffie, Kapadia and Saita (2007) on US data. Lando and Nielsen (2010), however, revisit the relation between contagion through covariates and conditional dependence addressed in Das et al. and find that the assumption of conditional independence can no longer be rejected when the set of firm-specific and macroeconomic controls is slightly altered and expanded. Hence, conditional on an appropriate set of covariates, Lando and Nielson find no evidence that the default of a firm causes default intensities of other firms to increase, providing support for our assumptions for the error term. Moreover, for a similar model estimated on a subset of the data used in this paper, Carling, Roszbach and Rönnegård (2004) find that the estimated parameters are robust when the correlation between residuals is taken into account. These results, along with 10

12 the excellent out-of-sample performance of the model in the time and cross-section dimension documented in Section 4, provide support of our assumptions for the error term. Our theoretical basis for selecting the set of macroeconomic variables is that they should span both aggregate demand and supply type of shocks that hit the economy. The output gap is intended as an indicator of demand conditions, i.e., increased demand in the economy is expected to reduce default risk. We also include the nominal interest rate in because credit conditions facing firms, in particular firms in distress, are likely to be tightly linked to the interest rate. As one can plausibly argue that the real interest rate, rather than the nominal one, is what should affect the default frequency, we also include the inflation rate in. Moreover, apart from capturing the effects of supply shocks, higher inflation obviously implies higher nominal income for firms, which furthermore should tend to reduce default risk. However, it is also conceivable that higher inflation rates are associated with less certainty about correct relative prices and thus may lead to increased default risks. For these reasons, the sign of the inflation coefficient is unclear, and will depend on the relative strength of the underlying sources of macroeconomic fluctuations. Furthermore, given that the export-to-gdp ratio in Sweden was around 0 40 during the sample period, the real exchange rate is potentially an important variable, since a depreciation renders improved competitiveness to Swedish firms in the export sector Estimation results To document how aggregate variables contribute to the default risk models, we present estimation results for two specifications: one with and one without macroeconomic variables. Moreover, results are presented for ten industry-specific models and an economy-wide model where firms 4 In addition to these four variables, we have also experimented with a few other variables such as real housing prices, taken as deviations from linear/hp-trend; and a measure of the spread between the interest rate charged to non-financial firms and the policy rate set by the central bank. For our sample period, these variables are largely redundant given the set of included variables in the benchmark specification. 11

13 in all industries are jointly modelled. Table 1 contains estimation results for a model with firm-specific determinants of default risk only (i.e., the six financial ratios augmented with the dummy variables PAYDIV, TTLFS, PAYREMARK, and TAXARREARS), while Table 2 shows results with the macroeconomic variables added. The regressors have not been re-scaled to have the same mean, and therefore one cannot directly judge the importance of a particular variable from the size of its coefficient. However, by suitably transforming each variable, its marginal impact is calculated in Appendix B.4, verifying that such calculations yield similar rankings of importance as standard -statistics. Hence, the importance of each variable is below approximated with the size of its -statistic. Since the firms annual financial reports are typically submitted with a significant time lag, it cannot in general be assumed that accounting data for year are available during, or even at the end of, year and enable forecasted default risks for year +1. To account for this, all accounting data is lagged by four quarters in the estimations. For most firms, which report balance-sheet and income-statement data over calendar years, this means that data for year are assumed to have been available in the first quarter of year +1. It should be emphasized that our decision to lag the accounting data four quarters in the estimation in order to make the model operational in real time has minor implications for the estimated coefficients. When re-estimating the model using contemporaneous data instead, the estimation results were found to be very similar to the ones reported in Tables 1 and 2. The results in Table 1 show that the firm-specific information we consider is indeed important for explaining default behavior in both the industry-specific models and in the economy-wide model. In particular, the indicator variable TTLFS (which takes a value of 1 if a firm has not filed an annual report on time,and 0 otherwise)and the variables for remarks on firms payment records are very powerful predictors of default. Among the financial ratios we find the earnings ratio EBITDA/TA, leverage ratio TL/TA and the debt ratio TL/TS to be quite useful. 12

14 However, the roles played by financial ratios in the various industry models differ substantially; while accounting data are less important in the financial services (bank, finance and insurance) sector, it is more important in the manufacturing industry. The coefficients for the payment remarks and the indicator variable TTLFS are quite similar across industries. So to the extent that these variables are the more important ones for explaining firm default behavior, there is no clear gain at the firm-specific level from conditioning on industry. 5 TurningtotheresultsinTable2,wefind that the coefficients for the firm-specific variables in Table 1 do not change much when the model is augmented with the macroeconomic variables. Moreover, and despite the robustness of the firm-specific coefficients, we find that all coefficients for the macroeconomic variables are significant in the economy-wide model and have the expected signs. The possible exception is inflation, but for reasons discussed in Section 3.1, it is hard to have a strong view a priori on the sign of the inflation coefficient. Thenotionthatitis important to condition on macroeconomic variables in default risk modeling is further supported by the industry-specific model results. Table 2 shows that the impact of the macroeconomic factors is estimated to be more important in industries that are arguably more cyclical. For instance, the output gap is more important in the construction and the real estate sectors in comparison with other industries, and as expected the nominal interest rate is found to be very important for the financial services and the real estate sectors. The remaining macroeconomic variables, inflation and the real exchange rate, appear less important overall. However, it is reassuring to find that a depreciating real exchange rate (i.e., increasing values) is associated with asignificantly lower default risk in the manufacturing sector, which is the most export-oriented industry. The coefficient for the real exchange rate is also large for the financial services industry, 5 Notice that by defining a default event at the quarterly frequency, and by transforming yearly statements to quarterly ones, we could potentially underestimate the effects of the accounting variables. As a robustness check we therefore estimated the default-risk models on annual data and found that the coefficients for the accounting variables are quite similar to those reported in Table 1, see results in Appendix B.3. 13

15 possibly reflecting that Swedish credit conditions, which were very tight in the resolvement of the banking crises, subsequently eased when the krona was allowed to depreciate in November Regarding inflation, we can reject the view that it is only the real interest rate that matters for default risk at the firm level, with the possible exception of the financial services industry. 6 Finally, we would like to emphasize that the gain in using firm-specific data for default-risk modeling is substantial. OLS estimation (TSLS with lagged variables as instruments yielded very similar results) for a model of the average quarterly default rate on average financial ratios and the four macroeconomic variables yields: = 9 45 (10 67) 0 40 (0 17) µ EBITDA 0 27 (0 18) TA µ TL TS µ I TS 0 12 (0 06) 0 02 (0 04) (0 12) (0 16) µ TL TA µ µ LA (0 02) TL IP IP+EBITDA (0 04) (0 04) 0 02 (0 01) +ˆ (1) 2 =0 88 DW =1 98 Sample: ( =40).... If we compare the point estimates for the financial ratios in (1) with the economy-wide model in Table 2, we see that they differ substantially and the ratios I/TS and TL/TS appear with counterintuitive signs. The coefficients for the macroeconomic variables are more robust, with the exception of the nominal interest rate which has a counterintuitive sign. Since the average financial ratios are quite smooth over time, it is not surprising that we obtain spurious results when the firm-specific information is aggregated. Moreover, we notice that some explanatory 6 As a robustness check, we examined a model allowing for non-linear relationships between default and the financial ratios and found that the macroeconomic variables are still highly significant and quantitatively important. We used the cumulated distributions depicted in Figure A.1 in Appendix A to categorize the variables (3 categories for each variable). For instance, we classified EBITDA/TA into the decile-based categories 0 10, 10 90, , whereas TL/TA was classified into the categories 0 75, 75 90, This categorization resulted in an increase in pseudo 2 from 0 34 to 0 42 in the economy-wide Table 2 model, but the macroeconomic variables still enter highly significantlyandwithcoefficients very close to those reported in Table 2. 14

16 power is lost by aggregating data; the model in (1) yields an 2 of 0 88, which can be directly compared with the aggregated fit ( 2 =0 95) of the corresponding model in Table 2. The reduction in fit is primarily driven by the inability to take advantage of the dummy variables for payment remarks, dividends and failure to submit a financial statement in regressions at the aggregate level. 3.3 Assessing the models in-sample fit The last rows in Tables 1 and 2 report on the number of observations, the mean log-likelihood and the pseudo- 2. The latter measures the ability of the estimated models to explain default at the firm level and is computed using the method of McFadden (1974). Another important and interesting feature of the models is their aggregate performance over time, i.e., how well the models account for the average default frequency. Hence, we report what we label as industry or aggregate 2 s. These are calculated by aggregating all the fitted firm default probabilities in a particular industry model for each quarter and then using the resulting 40 time-series observations to compute the implied aggregate 2. To assess the gain in estimating separate industry-specific models, we also report the pseudo- and industry- 2 values conditional on the economy-wide model coefficients instead of the industry model coefficients. By comparing Tables 1 and 2, we see that the pseudo- 2 is not much affected by conditioning on macroeconomic factors in any of the industries, merely 1-2 percentage points. Tang and Yan (2010) find a somewhat larger role for macro factors: about 6 percentage points. However, the industry- 2 is doubled and sometimes even more than doubled by the introduction of macroeconomic variables. Thus, the firm-specific variables account for the cross-section of the default distribution, while the macroeconomic variables inthemodelplaytheroleofshiftingthemean of the default distribution in each period. This also implies that the model with firm-specific information cannot capture the upturns and downturns in the average default rate over time. This is visualized in Figure 1, where we plot the average default rate over time against the fitted 15

17 values from the economy-wide models with (Table 2) and without (Table 1) macroeconomic variables. The results to the right-hand side of the vertical line pertain to out-of-sample results and will be discussed in Section 4.1. According to Figure 1, the model with both microeconomic and macroeconomic variables included indeed appears able to replicate the extreme default rates during the deep recession/banking crisis in the beginning of the 1990s, as well as the downturn to moderate default rates towards the end of the in-sample period. This finding is very interesting, because it suggests that the extreme default rates recorded during the banking crisis in the early 1990s were not exceptional events that are uninformative in a model context. Rather, they appear to be consequences of unusually bad economic outcomes. An additional feature of interest in Tables 1 and 2 is that the fall in pseudo- 2 values associated with conditioning on the economy-wide model coefficients is distinct but limited, whereas the corresponding reduction in industry 2 is often quite substantial. In three cases (the agricultural, the bank, finance & insurance, and the non-classified sectors) the industry- 2 are negative conditional on the economy-wide model coefficients. At first sight this may seem strange, given that the industryspecific coefficients in Table 2 are not very different from the economy-wide model coefficients. However, these seemingly inconsistent results are driven by the unreported intercept, which is larger in the economy-wide model compared with the sector models. Therefore, it induces a systematic over-prediction of default risk in these sectors. A conceivable objection to our claim of the importance of conditioning on macroeconomic factors in default risk models is that the significance of these variables simply reflects a changing impact of the firm-specific variables over time. Accordingly, if one were to continuously reestimate the coefficients of the models in Table 1 using the most recent quarterly information only, then the fit of the models in terms of aggregate 2 would increase dramatically and make the macroeconomic variables redundant. Figure 2 displays the estimated coefficients for the financial ratios in the economy-wide model for such a set of separate cross-sectional models. 7 7 We have also conducted these cross-sectional regressions when imposing the restriction that the constant 16

18 These results are computed for the economy-wide model only, because there are not enough defaults available in each quarter to estimate industry-specific models. As can be seen from Figure 2, the coefficients for most ratios are highly unstable and some even switch sign over time. Accordingly, any out-of-sample forecasts beyond the very short horizon generated by any of these 40 models would be deficient. To be convincing, a model of firm-level defaults with time-varying coefficients for firm-specific variables would require an understanding of how the time-variation in its coefficients comes about. The irregular and economically implausible patterns in Figure 2, make such a model seem highly improbable. To further understand the role of macroeconomic variables for default risk, let us approach the issue from an opposite angle and study the importance of firm-specific variables in the models. One way to demonstrate the information loss due to omitting the microdata is to regress the average default frequency exclusively on the macroeconomic variables. When doing so we obtain the following result: = 0 40 (0 11) 0 20 (0 03) (0 02) (0 02) 0 03 (0 009) +ˆ 2 =0 81 DW =1 43 Sample: ( =40). (2) When comparing this regression with the economy-wide model in Table 2, we see that exclusion of the financial statement variables is associated with a loss of close to 15 percentage points of explanatory power. Moreover, omitting the firm-specific information introduces misspecification problems in (2) as indicated by the DW-statistic, in contrast to the results in (1), which has a DW-statistic around 2 and hence displays no signs of autocorrelation. A simple -test reveals that the loss of fit in(2) relative to (1) is significant at the 5-percent level (using asymptotic equals the estimated intercept in the economy-wide model in Table 1 and subtracting the panel mean from each regressor. So instead of running the regressions underlying Figure 2, i.e. = for each quarter, we estimated = This alternative estimation procedure yielded very similar results to those reported in Figure 2. 17

19 critical values). The autocorrelation problem in (2) turns out to induce further problems with out-of-sample stability for the model in (2), as documented in Section 4 (see Table 3). Our interpretation is that omitting firm-specific variables when modeling default risk attributes too much of the variation in default risk to the macroeconomic factors in-sample. The model therefore doesn t perform as well out-of-sample. 4 Out-of-sample performance of the estimated model In this section we investigate the robustness of the results in the previous section by examining the out-of-sample performance of the models of Tables 1 and 2 for the period We evaluate the models along two dimensions. First, we study the models performance at the industry and aggregate level, i.e., we assess their ability to predict future average default rates. The predictions we consider are static one-step-ahead forecasts because we do not have a complete model for all the regressors. Although there are no major fluctuations in the aggregate default rate during the out-of-sample period (see Figure 1), this period is nevertheless very informative about the out-of-sample performance of our models since there is still substantial variation in the macroeconomic variables, as displayed in Figure A.2. Second, we look into the models properties in predicting future default events at the firm level. To this end, there is a substantial amount of information ( default observations) to assess the stability of the models. 4.1 Evaluating the models at the aggregate and the industry level In Figure 1, the results to the right-hand side of the vertical bar show the one-step-ahead, out-of-sample performance at the aggregate level for the economy-wide model. Overall, the outof-sample fit is remarkably good, although there is a tendency for the model to under-predict during the years 2006 and Interestingly, the model is able to pick up the emerging spike 18

20 in the default frequency in the recent recession through the strong fall in the output gap from 4to-4percent. In Table 3, we report the root mean squared one-step-ahead prediction errors (RMSEs), for the estimated models of Tables 1 and 2. As a reference, we also show results for three reference time series models: a random walk, a 4-quarter moving-average model, and the model estimated on only macroeconomic data (eq. 2, denoted Industry OLS macroregression ). The results in Table 3 pertain to default risk models that have been re-estimated using macroeconomic variables that are lagged one quarter. This ensures that all models in Table 3 have been estimated on the same information set, thereby allowing for a fair comparison between the logit and the timeseries models. In the Industry OLS macroregression models an additional dummy for the third quarter is included. In order to assess to which extent the forecasting errors are quantitatively different from a statistical point of view, we perform the Diebold-Mariano test on the forecast errors underlying the computed RMSE differentials in the lower panel of Table 3. In the table the RMSE-ratios that are bolded (in italics) indicate that the forecasting performance is significantly better (worse) relative to the corresponding models in Table 2. 8 Finally, it is imperative to notice that the RMSEs are shown in percent, i.e., the actual and fitted default frequencies have been multiplied with a factor of 100 before the prediction errors are calculated. From inspection of Table 3, it is evident from the first row in the lower panel that the effect on forecasting performance from conditioning on both macro and firm-specific information is considerable. The largest gain is found for the economy-wide model where forecast precision increases by a factor of 3 6 when we include macroeconomic variables. Disregarding the not 8 Our application of the test suggested by Diebold and Mariano (1995) examines the null hypothesis: +1 = +1,where is the squared loss-function of the one-step-ahead forecast errors +1 for models and. Diebold and Mariano show that a test-statistic based on the loss differential, and suitably normalized by the asymptotic variance of, is asymptotically standard normal. 19

21 classified residual industry for which the model with macro variables is associated with a significant loss of out-of-sample accuracy, the corresponding factors for the industry-specific models range between 1.2 and 3.6 and constitute a significant improvement in 8 out of 9 cases. Moreover, the second row in the lower panel shows that the industry-specific models often generate significantly lower RMSEs compared with the industry models conditional on coefficients from the economy-wide model in Table 2, except for the manufacturing, retail and hotel & restaurant sectors where they are slightly, but not significantly, higher. By and large, the above findings constitute evidence that the industry-specific modelsare not over-parameterized with respect to the macroeconomic variables. Therefore it will typically be worthwhile to work with an industry-specific model if the focus is on understanding default behavior in a particular industry. However, if interest lies in modeling aggregate default behavior only, then the economy-wide default model appears to suffice. This tentative conclusion can be drawn from the two right-most columns of the second row in Table 3. In the second to last column, the forecasts computed with the industry-specific models have been weighted (according to industry-size) to a forecast for the aggregate default frequency. This results in a slightly lower RMSE (0 0716) incomparisonwiththermse(0 0802) for the economy-wide model. Although this difference in RMSE is moderate in comparison with the other models in absolute terms, it is still significant in favor of the industry models according to the D-M test. Comparing the industry models in Table 3 with the time series models, we see that while the random walk model is doing significantly better in 3 out of 10 sectors, and the 4-quarter moving-average specification is better 6 out of 10 times at the industry level, they are both significantly inferior at the aggregated industry level. This implies that they are also inferior in terms of RMSE fit to the economy-wide model specification in Table 2 (which conditions on aggregate fluctuations). The models that are based on OLS regressions for average industry default frequencies on the macroeconomic variables only are often associated with a significant 20

22 increase in RMSE (7 out of 10 industries) in comparison with the Table 2 models. To sum up, we have found strong evidence that the favorable fit in-sample of the estimated industry (and aggregate) models, conditional on macroeconomic variables, is preserved out-ofsample at the industry and aggregate level. This is reassuring for the hypothesis that aggregate variables matter because the in-sample and the out-of sample periods taken together cover several upturns and downturns in the Swedish economy. Finally, we have also documented that there are relatively small gains in terms of forecasting accuracy to be made by using industryspecific models rather than simply an economy-wide model, as long as an appropriate set of macroeconomic variables is included. 4.2 Evaluating the models at the firm and the industry level We now turn to an evaluation of the ability of the models to both rank firms according to their relative riskiness and to determine firms absolute risk level for the out-of-sample period. In addition, we report the industry-specific pseudo- 2 conditional on the industry-specific model coefficients of Table 2, as well as the pseudo- 2 calculated conditional on the economy-wide model coefficients. The results are displayed in Table 4. First, starting with the pseudo- 2 for the models with industry-specific coefficients and comparing the in-sample and out-of-sample results reported in Tables 2 and 4, respectively, we see that the explanatory power out-of-sample is in fact either higher than in-sample or unchanged in eight out of ten industries. Next we turn to the pseudo- 2 for the predictions based on the economy-wide model coefficients. The lower panel of Table 4 shows that the average explanatory power has increased substantially, from 0 34 in-sample to 0 38 out-of-sample. We also see, relative to Table 2, that the explanatory power has increased in all industries except for agriculture, real-estate and the construction sectors. Moreover, by comparing the pseudo- 2 values generated when using industry-specific coefficients with those obtained using economy-wide model coefficients (i.e. 21

23 the values in upper and lower panels of Table 4), we find that they are larger/smaller in four industries and similar otherwise. This implies that pseudo- 2 at the aggregate level is about the same (0 38) for the economy-wide model compared with an aggregation of pseudo- 2 over the industry-specific models (denoted Industry Aggregate in Table 4). These results provide support for two important conclusions. First, the industry models are not over-parameterized. Second, the reduced-form coefficients appear to be stable over time and the regressions thus reflect relationships that hold out-of-sample. Moving on to measures of relative risk, we follow Shumway (2001) and evaluate the models ability to rank firms according to their riskiness in terms of ex post default frequencies. At first glance, we see from Table 4 that the estimated models classify roughly percent of the defaulting firms in the riskiest decile. These numbers are about the same as those reported insample by Shumway for a data set that was substantially smaller and included only listed firms. Our models cover the entire population of Swedish incorporated businesses, of which only a very small subset is publicly listed on the stock exchange (slightly less than 500 out of ). We therefore conclude that our models are quite successful in ranking firms according to their level of default risk, and support our conclusion that the role of macroeconomic variables in our models of default risk is not driven by the omission of key microeconomic variables. Table 4 also reveals that the quality of the risk rankings does not depend on whether we condition on industry-specific coefficients or coefficients from the economy-wide model. This contrasts with our findings in the previous subsection, where we found that conditioning on industry-specific parameters improved the models empirical performance at the industry level. The explanation for these seemingly inconsistent results lies in the fact that the most important difference between the economy-wide and industry-specific models is due to the varying impact of the aggregate factors. Those factors have little impact on the firms relative risk ranking and hence their inclusion or omission has little impact on the models ability to risk-rank firms. 22

Firm Default and Aggregate Fluctuations

Firm Default and Aggregate Fluctuations Firm Default and Aggregate Fluctuations Tor Jacobson Rikard Kindell Jesper Lindé Kasper Roszbach June 17, 29 Abstract This paper studies the relation between macroeconomic uctuations and corporate defaults

More information

Aggregate shocks and Firm Default Risk

Aggregate shocks and Firm Default Risk Aggregate shocks and Firm Default Risk Tor Jacobson Jesper Lindé Rikard Nilsson Kasper Roszbach January 14, 28 Abstract In this paper we use a large panel data set to examine if there is a separate role

More information

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications 2013 2013 Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data A. Tsui C.Y. Xu Zhaoyong Zhang Edith Cowan University, zhaoyong.zhang@ecu.edu.au

More information

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s As part of its monetary policy strategy, the ECB regularly monitors the development of a wide range of indicators and assesses their implications

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage: Economics Letters 108 (2010) 167 171 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Economics Letters journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolet Is there a financial accelerator in US banking? Evidence

More information

BANK OF CANADA RENEWAL OF BACKGROUND INFORMATION THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET. May 2001

BANK OF CANADA RENEWAL OF BACKGROUND INFORMATION THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET. May 2001 BANK OF CANADA May RENEWAL OF THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET BACKGROUND INFORMATION Bank of Canada Wellington Street Ottawa, Ontario KA G9 78 ISBN: --89- Printed in Canada on recycled paper B A N K O F C

More information

Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez

Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez (Global Modeling & Long-term Analysis Unit) Madrid, December 5, 2017 Index 1. Introduction

More information

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy This online appendix is divided into four sections. In section A we perform pairwise tests aiming at disentangling

More information

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve Capacity Utilization As a Real-Time Predictor of Manufacturing Output Evan F. Koenig Research Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve indices

More information

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016)

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) 68-131 An Investigation of the Structural Characteristics of the Indian IT Sector and the Capital Goods Sector An Application of the

More information

A Statistical Analysis to Predict Financial Distress

A Statistical Analysis to Predict Financial Distress J. Service Science & Management, 010, 3, 309-335 doi:10.436/jssm.010.33038 Published Online September 010 (http://www.scirp.org/journal/jssm) 309 Nicolas Emanuel Monti, Roberto Mariano Garcia Department

More information

Determinants of Cyclical Aggregate Dividend Behavior

Determinants of Cyclical Aggregate Dividend Behavior Review of Economics & Finance Submitted on 01/Apr./2012 Article ID: 1923-7529-2012-03-71-08 Samih Antoine Azar Determinants of Cyclical Aggregate Dividend Behavior Dr. Samih Antoine Azar Faculty of Business

More information

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow, Co-movements of Shanghai and New York stock prices by time-varying regressions Gregory C Chow a, Changjiang Liu b, Linlin Niu b,c a Department of Economics, Fisher Hall Princeton University, Princeton,

More information

Article from: Product Matters. June 2015 Issue 92

Article from: Product Matters. June 2015 Issue 92 Article from: Product Matters June 2015 Issue 92 Gordon Gillespie is an actuarial consultant based in Berlin, Germany. He has been offering quantitative risk management expertise to insurers, banks and

More information

Svante Öberg: Potential GDP, resource utilisation and monetary policy

Svante Öberg: Potential GDP, resource utilisation and monetary policy Svante Öberg: Potential GDP, resource utilisation and monetary policy Speech by Mr Svante Öberg, First Deputy Governor of the Sveriges Riksbank, at the Statistics Sweden s annual conference, Saltsjöbaden,

More information

A Markov switching regime model of the South African business cycle

A Markov switching regime model of the South African business cycle A Markov switching regime model of the South African business cycle Elna Moolman Abstract Linear models are incapable of capturing business cycle asymmetries. This has recently spurred interest in non-linear

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang Pre-print version: Tang, Tuck Cheong. (00). "Does exchange rate volatility matter for the balancing item of balance of payments accounts in Japan? an empirical note". Rivista internazionale di scienze

More information

Chapter IV. Forecasting Daily and Weekly Stock Returns

Chapter IV. Forecasting Daily and Weekly Stock Returns Forecasting Daily and Weekly Stock Returns An unsophisticated forecaster uses statistics as a drunken man uses lamp-posts -for support rather than for illumination.0 Introduction In the previous chapter,

More information

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics Eric Zivot April 29, 2013 Lecture Outline The Leverage Effect Asymmetric GARCH Models Forecasts from Asymmetric GARCH Models GARCH Models with

More information

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University Colin Mayer Saïd Business School University of Oxford Oren Sussman

More information

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4 Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4.1 Introduction Modelling and predicting financial market volatility has played an important role for market participants as it enables

More information

Inflation Targeting and Revisions to Inflation Data: A Case Study with PCE Inflation * Calvin Price July 2011

Inflation Targeting and Revisions to Inflation Data: A Case Study with PCE Inflation * Calvin Price July 2011 Inflation Targeting and Revisions to Inflation Data: A Case Study with PCE Inflation * Calvin Price July 2011 Introduction Central banks around the world have come to recognize the importance of maintaining

More information

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios Amit Goyal Goizueta Business School Emory University Ivo Welch Yale School of Management Yale Economics Department NBER December 16, 2003 Abstract This

More information

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage Jin-Chuan Duan * and Yun Li (First draft: April 12, 2006) (This version: May 16, 2006) Abstract This paper identifies a key cause for the documented diversification

More information

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India Michael Hutchison and Rajeswari Sengupta and Nirvikar Singh University of California Santa Cruz 3. March 2010 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/21106/

More information

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender * COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY Adi Brender * 1 Key analytical issues for policy choice and design A basic question facing policy makers at the outset of a crisis

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Market Variables and Financial Distress. Giovanni Fernandez Stetson University

Market Variables and Financial Distress. Giovanni Fernandez Stetson University Market Variables and Financial Distress Giovanni Fernandez Stetson University In this paper, I investigate the predictive ability of market variables in correctly predicting and distinguishing going concern

More information

Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI

Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI Fifth joint EU/OECD workshop on business and consumer surveys Brussels, 17 18 November 2011 Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI Olivier BIAU

More information

Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:1, No:1 (2017) 1-13

Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:1, No:1 (2017) 1-13 Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:1, No:1 (2017) 1-13 Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis Type: Double Blind Peer Reviewed Scientific Journal Printed ISSN: 2521-6627 Online ISSN:

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Online Appendix to The Costs of Quantitative Easing: Liquidity and Market Functioning Effects of Federal Reserve MBS Purchases

Online Appendix to The Costs of Quantitative Easing: Liquidity and Market Functioning Effects of Federal Reserve MBS Purchases Online Appendix to The Costs of Quantitative Easing: Liquidity and Market Functioning Effects of Federal Reserve MBS Purchases John Kandrac Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Appendix. Additional

More information

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales VV Chari, LJ Christiano and P Kehoe January 2, 27 In this note, we examine the findings of Gertler and Gilchrist, ( Monetary Policy, Business

More information

The Brattle Group 1 st Floor 198 High Holborn London WC1V 7BD

The Brattle Group 1 st Floor 198 High Holborn London WC1V 7BD UPDATED ESTIMATE OF BT S EQUITY BETA NOVEMBER 4TH 2008 The Brattle Group 1 st Floor 198 High Holborn London WC1V 7BD office@brattle.co.uk Contents 1 Introduction and Summary of Findings... 3 2 Statistical

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus) Volume 35, Issue 1 Exchange rate determination in Vietnam Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus) Abstract This study investigates the determinants of the exchange rate in Vietnam and suggests policy

More information

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr.

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr. The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving James P. Dow, Jr. Department of Finance, Real Estate and Insurance California State University, Northridge

More information

PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3

PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3 PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3 Stress testing operational risk for capital planning and capital adequacy PART 2: Monday, March 18th, 2013, New York Presenter: Alexander Cavallo, NORTHERN TRUST 1 Disclaimer

More information

Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation

Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Wharton Research Scholars Wharton School 4-2011 Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation Peter Maa University of Pennsylvania Follow this and

More information

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade The Time Cost of Documents to Trade Mohammad Amin* May, 2011 The paper shows that the number of documents required to export and import tend to increase the time cost of shipments. However, this relationship

More information

Sustainable Financial Obligations and Crisis Cycles

Sustainable Financial Obligations and Crisis Cycles Sustainable Financial Obligations and Crisis Cycles Mikael Juselius and Moshe Kim 220 200 180 160 140 120 (a) U.S. household sector total debt to income. 10 8 6 4 2 0 2 (b) Nominal (solid line) and real

More information

INDICATORS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN MATURE ECONOMIES

INDICATORS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN MATURE ECONOMIES B INDICATORS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN MATURE ECONOMIES This special feature analyses the indicator properties of macroeconomic variables and aggregated financial statements from the banking sector in providing

More information

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves issn 1936-5330 Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves Brent Bundick Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City First Version: October 2007 This Version: June 2008 RWP 07-08 Abstract Piazzesi and Swanson

More information

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty Christopher F Baum Department of Economics, Boston College and DIW Berlin Mustafa Caglayan Department of Economics, University of Sheffield Oleksandr

More information

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Liuren Wu Baruch College, City University of New York Joint work with Jian Hua 6th Annual Conference of the Society for Financial Econometrics June 12-14,

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

A Micro Data Approach to the Identification of Credit Crunches

A Micro Data Approach to the Identification of Credit Crunches A Micro Data Approach to the Identification of Credit Crunches Horst Rottmann University of Amberg-Weiden and Ifo Institute Timo Wollmershäuser Ifo Institute, LMU München and CESifo 5 December 2011 in

More information

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES Mahir Binici Central Bank of Turkey Istiklal Cad. No:10 Ulus, Ankara/Turkey E-mail: mahir.binici@tcmb.gov.tr

More information

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality DORON NISSIM* Corporate disclosures are an important source of information for investors. Many studies have documented strong price

More information

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017 Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality June 19, 2017 1 Table of contents 1 Robustness checks on baseline regression... 1 2 Robustness checks on composition

More information

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies James Morley University of New South Wales 1. Introduction Garnier, Mertens, and Nelson (this issue, GMN hereafter) conduct model-based trend/cycle decomposition

More information

Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox

Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox Felix FitzRoy School of Economics and Finance University of St Andrews St Andrews, KY16 8QX, UK Michael Nolan* Centre for Economic Policy

More information

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy.

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy. This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/9880/ Monograph: Gascoigne, J. and Turner, P.

More information

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Properties of the estimated five-factor model Informationin(andnotin)thetermstructure Appendix. Additional results Greg Duffee Johns Hopkins This draft: October 8, Properties of the estimated five-factor model No stationary term structure model is

More information

Stock market firm-level information and real economic activity

Stock market firm-level information and real economic activity Stock market firm-level information and real economic activity F. di Mauro, F. Fornari, D. Mannucci Presentation at the EFIGE Associate Partner Meeting Milano, 31 March 2011 March 29, 2011 The Great Recession

More information

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops. Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Macroeconomic Models and Forecasts for Austria

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops. Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Macroeconomic Models and Forecasts for Austria Oesterreichische Nationalbank Eurosystem Workshops Proceedings of OeNB Workshops Macroeconomic Models and Forecasts for Austria November 11 to 12, 2004 No. 5 Comment on Evaluating Euro Exchange Rate Predictions

More information

CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY

CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY Chapter Overview This chapter has two major parts: the introduction to the principles of market efficiency and a review of the empirical evidence on efficiency

More information

Prediction errors in credit loss forecasting models based on macroeconomic data

Prediction errors in credit loss forecasting models based on macroeconomic data Prediction errors in credit loss forecasting models based on macroeconomic data Eric McVittie Experian Decision Analytics Credit Scoring & Credit Control XIII August 2013 University of Edinburgh Business

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY Alan J. Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko University of California, Berkeley January 2013 In this paper, we estimate the cross-country spillover effects of government

More information

Dnr RG 2013/ September Central Government Debt Management

Dnr RG 2013/ September Central Government Debt Management Dnr RG 2013/339 27 September 2013 Central Government Debt Management Proposed guidelines 2014 2017 SUMMARY 1 1 PREREQUISITES 2 1 The development of central government debt until 2017 2 PROPOSED GUIDELINES

More information

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle: Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia May 31, 214 Midwest Macro Conference Raju Huidrom Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle Background

More information

Commentary: Housing is the Business Cycle

Commentary: Housing is the Business Cycle Commentary: Housing is the Business Cycle Frank Smets Prof. Leamer s paper is witty, provocative and very timely. It is also written with a certain passion. Now, passion and central banking do not necessarily

More information

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHANNES KEPLER UNIVERSITY LINZ Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison by Burkhard Raunig and Johann Scharler* Working Paper

More information

Bank Contagion in Europe

Bank Contagion in Europe Bank Contagion in Europe Reint Gropp and Jukka Vesala Workshop on Banking, Financial Stability and the Business Cycle, Sveriges Riksbank, 26-28 August 2004 The views expressed in this paper are those of

More information

September 12, 2006, version 1. 1 Data

September 12, 2006, version 1. 1 Data September 12, 2006, version 1 1 Data The dependent variable is always the equity premium, i.e., the total rate of return on the stock market minus the prevailing short-term interest rate. Stock Prices:

More information

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin June 15, 2008 Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin Abstract The trade effect of the euro is typically

More information

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Anders Karlsson and Lars Nordén 1 Department of Corporate Finance, School of Business, Stockholm University, S-106 91 Stockholm, Sweden Abstract

More information

Practical Issues in the Current Expected Credit Loss (CECL) Model: Effective Loan Life and Forward-looking Information

Practical Issues in the Current Expected Credit Loss (CECL) Model: Effective Loan Life and Forward-looking Information Practical Issues in the Current Expected Credit Loss (CECL) Model: Effective Loan Life and Forward-looking Information Deming Wu * Office of the Comptroller of the Currency E-mail: deming.wu@occ.treas.gov

More information

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom Gaétan Stephan 1 University of Rennes 1, CREM April 2012 (Preliminary draft) Abstract We model the relation between output

More information

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They?

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? Massimiliano Marzo and Paolo Zagaglia This version: January 6, 29 Preliminary: comments

More information

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Has the Inflation Process Changed? Has the Inflation Process Changed? by S. Cecchetti and G. Debelle Discussion by I. Angeloni (ECB) * Cecchetti and Debelle (CD) could hardly have chosen a more relevant and timely topic for their paper.

More information

I. BACKGROUND AND CONTEXT

I. BACKGROUND AND CONTEXT Review of the Debt Sustainability Framework for Low Income Countries (LIC DSF) Discussion Note August 1, 2016 I. BACKGROUND AND CONTEXT 1. The LIC DSF, introduced in 2005, remains the cornerstone of assessing

More information

Quantity versus Price Rationing of Credit: An Empirical Test

Quantity versus Price Rationing of Credit: An Empirical Test Int. J. Financ. Stud. 213, 1, 45 53; doi:1.339/ijfs1345 Article OPEN ACCESS International Journal of Financial Studies ISSN 2227-772 www.mdpi.com/journal/ijfs Quantity versus Price Rationing of Credit:

More information

Predicting Turning Points in the South African Economy

Predicting Turning Points in the South African Economy 289 Predicting Turning Points in the South African Economy Elna Moolman Department of Economics, University of Pretoria ABSTRACT Despite the existence of macroeconomic models and complex business cycle

More information

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks Li Jing and Henry Thompson 2010 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/20654/ MPRA Paper No. 20654, posted 13. February

More information

Web Appendix for Testing Pendleton s Premise: Do Political Appointees Make Worse Bureaucrats? David E. Lewis

Web Appendix for Testing Pendleton s Premise: Do Political Appointees Make Worse Bureaucrats? David E. Lewis Web Appendix for Testing Pendleton s Premise: Do Political Appointees Make Worse Bureaucrats? David E. Lewis This appendix includes the auxiliary models mentioned in the text (Tables 1-5). It also includes

More information

REGIONAL WORKSHOP ON TRAFFIC FORECASTING AND ECONOMIC PLANNING

REGIONAL WORKSHOP ON TRAFFIC FORECASTING AND ECONOMIC PLANNING International Civil Aviation Organization 27/8/10 WORKING PAPER REGIONAL WORKSHOP ON TRAFFIC FORECASTING AND ECONOMIC PLANNING Cairo 2 to 4 November 2010 Agenda Item 3 a): Forecasting Methodology (Presented

More information

Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility. David A. Hsieh. Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC (919)

Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility. David A. Hsieh. Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC (919) Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility by David A. Hsieh Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC 27706 (919)-660-7779 October 1993 Prepared for the Conference on Financial Innovations: 20 Years

More information

Random Variables and Probability Distributions

Random Variables and Probability Distributions Chapter 3 Random Variables and Probability Distributions Chapter Three Random Variables and Probability Distributions 3. Introduction An event is defined as the possible outcome of an experiment. In engineering

More information

Quantitative Measure. February Axioma Research Team

Quantitative Measure. February Axioma Research Team February 2018 How When It Comes to Momentum, Evaluate Don t Cramp My Style a Risk Model Quantitative Measure Risk model providers often commonly report the average value of the asset returns model. Some

More information

Assessing the probability of financial distress of UK firms

Assessing the probability of financial distress of UK firms Assessing the probability of financial distress of UK firms Evangelos C. Charalambakis Susanne K. Espenlaub Ian Garrett First version: June 12 2008 This version: January 15 2009 Manchester Business School,

More information

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults March, 2018 Contents 1 1 Robustness Tests The results presented in the main text are robust to the definition of debt repayments, and the

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

Dynamic Corporate Default Predictions Spot and Forward-Intensity Approaches

Dynamic Corporate Default Predictions Spot and Forward-Intensity Approaches Dynamic Corporate Default Predictions Spot and Forward-Intensity Approaches Jin-Chuan Duan Risk Management Institute and Business School National University of Singapore (June 2012) JC Duan (NUS) Dynamic

More information

This short article examines the

This short article examines the WEIDONG TIAN is a professor of finance and distinguished professor in risk management and insurance the University of North Carolina at Charlotte in Charlotte, NC. wtian1@uncc.edu Contingent Capital as

More information

TRANSACTION- BASED PRICE INDICES

TRANSACTION- BASED PRICE INDICES TRANSACTION- BASED PRICE INDICES PROFESSOR MARC FRANCKE - PROFESSOR OF REAL ESTATE VALUATION AT THE UNIVERSITY OF AMSTERDAM CPPI HANDBOOK 2 ND DRAFT CHAPTER 5 PREPARATION OF AN INTERNATIONAL HANDBOOK ON

More information

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation? 2011 年 2 月第十四卷一期 Vol. 14, No. 1, February 2011 Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation? Tao Chen http://cmr.ba.ouhk.edu.hk Web Journal of Chinese Management Review Vol. 14 No 1 1 Does Commodity

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Investment Insight. Are Risk Parity Managers Risk Parity (Continued) Summary Results of the Style Analysis

Investment Insight. Are Risk Parity Managers Risk Parity (Continued) Summary Results of the Style Analysis Investment Insight Are Risk Parity Managers Risk Parity (Continued) Edward Qian, PhD, CFA PanAgora Asset Management October 2013 In the November 2012 Investment Insight 1, I presented a style analysis

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Putnam Institute JUne 2011 Optimal Asset Allocation in : A Downside Perspective W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Once an individual has retired, asset allocation becomes a critical

More information

In Search of Distress Risk

In Search of Distress Risk In Search of Distress Risk John Y. Campbell, Jens Hilscher, and Jan Szilagyi Presentation to Third Credit Risk Conference: Recent Advances in Credit Risk Research New York, 16 May 2006 What is financial

More information

2. Copula Methods Background

2. Copula Methods Background 1. Introduction Stock futures markets provide a channel for stock holders potentially transfer risks. Effectiveness of such a hedging strategy relies heavily on the accuracy of hedge ratio estimation.

More information

DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION

DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION APPENDIX DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION PART 1 SUMMARIZATION 1: BUILDING BLOCKS OF DATA ANALYSIS 294 PART 2 PART 3 PART 4 VISUALIZATION: GRAPHS AND TABLES FOR SUMMARIZING AND ORGANIZING DATA 296

More information

Assessment on Credit Risk of Real Estate Based on Logistic Regression Model

Assessment on Credit Risk of Real Estate Based on Logistic Regression Model Assessment on Credit Risk of Real Estate Based on Logistic Regression Model Li Hongli 1, a, Song Liwei 2,b 1 Chongqing Engineering Polytechnic College, Chongqing400037, China 2 Division of Planning and

More information

Macroeconomic announcements and implied volatilities in swaption markets 1

Macroeconomic announcements and implied volatilities in swaption markets 1 Fabio Fornari +41 61 28 846 fabio.fornari @bis.org Macroeconomic announcements and implied volatilities in swaption markets 1 Some of the sharpest movements in the major swap markets take place during

More information

Interdependencies between Expected Default Frequency and the Macro Economy

Interdependencies between Expected Default Frequency and the Macro Economy Interdependencies between Expected Default Frequency and the Macro Economy Per Åsberg Sommar and Hovick Shahnazarian Financial Stability Department, Sveriges Riksbank We use a vector error-correction model

More information

Per Capita Housing Starts: Forecasting and the Effects of Interest Rate

Per Capita Housing Starts: Forecasting and the Effects of Interest Rate 1 David I. Goodman The University of Idaho Economics 351 Professor Ismail H. Genc March 13th, 2003 Per Capita Housing Starts: Forecasting and the Effects of Interest Rate Abstract This study examines the

More information