University of Wisconsin-Madison, Department of Agricultural Economics Staff Paper Series. January 1994 No. 368

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "University of Wisconsin-Madison, Department of Agricultural Economics Staff Paper Series. January 1994 No. 368"

Transcription

1 Copyright (c) 1994 by Lisa C Smith. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies. University of Wisconsin-Madison, Department of Agricultural Economics Staff Paper Series January 1994 No. 368 STRUCTURAL ADJUSTMENT AND WELFARE IN RURAL AFRICA: THE ROLE OF RESOURCE CONTROL IN HOUSEHOLDS By Lisa C. Smith University of Wisconsin-Madison

2 OUTLINE I. Introduction II. Structural Adjustment in Sub-Saharan Africa III. Conceptual Framework: Welfare Provisioning in Households A. Model of Time and Income Allocation B. Gender-Differentiated Allocational Priorities, Access and Power C. Allocative Inefficiency IV. Structural Adjustment Policy Impacts on Household Welfare A. Expenditure Switching Policies B. Reductions in Government Expenditures on Social Services V. Conclusion

3 I. INTRODUCTION Structural adjustment programs supported by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank have been implemented in over thirty Sub-Saharan African countries. The goal of these programs is to rectify macroeconomic imbalances (fiscal and balance of payments deficits) and low economic growth associated with the economic crisis of the 1970 s. Until recently, the programs success was mainly gauged in terms of macro-level indicators, such as deficit reductions and increases in economic growth. For the effects of the policies on the people living in countries undergoing adjustment, it was assumed that economy-wide improvements would eventually lead to improvements in their welfare as well (Anyaoku 1989; Jolly 1988). By the early 1980 s it became apparent that the changes induced during structural adjustment can entail burdens for some groups of people and benefits for others: some people find themselves coping with the negative impacts of policy reforms, while others thrive by taking advantage of new opportunities for raising their incomes (Haddad 1991; World Bank 1991). Concern arose about the effects of the programs on economically poor groups of people in particular. In the 1990 s, stemming the tide of poverty and enhancing the welfare of the poor through promoting their active participation in bringing about economic growth and through improving their access to social services has become a fundamental objective of (the World Bank s) structural adjustment programs (World Bank 1993a). Numerous attempts have been made to gather evidence of the impacts of policies associated with structural adjustment programs on peoples welfare. Many studies give evidence of strong negative impacts of the policies. A study undertaken by the Commonwealth Secretariat (1989:70), for example, claims that structural adjustment policies leading to "reductions in household incomes, increases in food prices and cut backs in health services... have been the main causes for the deterioration in children s nutrition and health during the 1980 s observed in many countries." The study cites evidence of increased incidences of malnutrition during the early 1980 s in as many as twenty-five adjusting countries. Another study claims that there has been "a widespread deterioration in the nutritional status of children and pregnant and lactating mothers in both rural and urban areas in countries with IMF Stabilization and World Bank structural adjustment programs" (Elson 1989:16). 1

4 It is difficult, however, to verify whether current negative welfare patterns found in many adjusting countries result directly from structural adjustment policies themselves. They could stem from economic conditions and government policies that existed prior to the implementation of adjustment measures (Elson 1991; Behrman 1988). For this reason, in addressing welfare concerns surrounding the policies, economists in particular have taken an inferential as opposed to empirical approach. Detailed models linking macro-level changes to micro-level outcomes such as household incomes and consumption have been developed (see for example Sarris 1992; Sahn 1991). Such models have been helpful for identifying the potential impacts of structural adjustment policies on household-level variables. However, they have been criticized for their failure to treat sub-household level processes and non-market processes as important and significant determinants of welfare outcomes (Elson 1991; Csete 1992). In particular, they fail to consider differences in the constraints and decision making processes of individual household members, which can place limits on the ability of households as a whole to react to adjustment policies in a way that maintains and/or enhances household welfare. This paper contributes to the conceptual understanding of how structural adjustment policies impact rural Sub-Saharan African peoples welfare by exploring the policies intermediate impacts on the allocation of economic resources within households. Although the dependent variable of the study is household welfare, the study s examination of resource allocation is focused at the intrahousehold level. In particular, the differential resource allocation behaviors of women and men in households, including how they use the economic resources (time and income) they control to contribute to their households welfare and how they obtain these resources, are examined. Recognizing the existence of households in which there is only one main adult decision maker (the proportion of female headed households in rural Sub-Saharan Africa, for instance, is estimated to be 25 percent (Due 1991)), the paper concentrates on households containing both male and female adults as primary decision makers. 2

5 Throughout the paper, "welfare" is defined to be the physical well-being of human beings. 1 Variables most closely associated with physical well-being are peoples states of health and nutrition. Child and adult mortality rates in Sub-Saharan Africa, associated with low levels of health and nutrition, remain the highest in the world. In 1990, the number of lost disability-adjusted life years (DALYs), a measure combining the loss of life from premature death with the loss of healthy life from disability, was higher in Sub-Saharan Africa than in any other area of the world (World Bank 1993b). Attention to improving human welfare in Sub-Saharan Africa is timely and crucial, not only as a goal in itself, but also for maintaining the productivity of Africa s "human capital" in the coming decades. The effects of two types of structural adjustment policies on human welfare will be investigated in this paper. These are policies that promote the production of tradeable goods in agricultural sectors (expenditure switching policies) and policies that reduce public provision of social services (expenditure reduction policies). Two main questions are examined: (1) How are time and income allocated in households? A general conceptual framework for understanding the micro-foundations of welfare provisioning in rural Sub-Saharan African households is developed. After concluding that many intrahousehold level processes related to gender differences are fundamental to welfare provisioning in households, this conceptual framework is used to ask: (2) Given the intrahousehold level processes identified, what can be inferred about the possible welfare impacts of structural adjustment policies? To be considered are the avenues through which adjustment policies, mediated by their effects on resource allocation in households, impact peoples welfare. II. STRUCTURAL ADJUSTMENT POLICY IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA In the 1980 s many Sub-Saharan African countries experienced severe economic distress in the form of balance of payments and budget deficits, high inflation rates, and low economic growth. Although the causes of these problems have varied by country, four major contributing factors have been identified. The first is external shocks stemming from higher oil prices since the 1970 s, lower prices for countries primary commodities, and increases in the real interest rate on commercial debt. The second is environmental shocks resulting from 1 The paper thus departs from the use of the term welfare in the field of welfare economics in which, under the nonpaternalism postulate, a person s welfare is identified with the person s (own perception of) the utility they receive from any resource allocation (Boadway and Bruce 1984). 3

6 increased variability in rainfall patterns. The last two factors are over-expansionary fiscal and monetary policies and domestic pricing policies biased against agriculture, the sector which is the greatest source of production in most Sub-Saharan African countries. Structural adjustment 2 policies are aimed at rectifying macroeconomic imbalances and restoring sustainable economic growth. They include relatively short-term stabilization policies, which have the specific goal of reducing inviable fiscal and balance of payments deficits. They also include longer term policies that address the more fundamental distortions underlying macroeconomic imbalances, such as policies to improve resource allocation, increase economic efficiency, expand growth potential and increase resilience to shocks. The three main types of structural adjustment policies implemented in Sub-Saharan African countries are currency devaluation, liberalization of product markets and reductions in government expenditures. Government expenditure reduction is aimed at reducing government budget deficits. It may take place in the form of reductions in expenditures on social services (for example, health and education services and staple foods subsidization) and/or on economic infrastructure (for example, road building and repair and investments in marketing facilities). Devaluation and liberalization policies, together referred to as "expenditure switching" policies, induce a fundamental restructuring of a country s product and factor markets. The goal of currency devaluation is to depreciate an economy s real exchange rate (the price of nontradeables relative to tradeables 3 ) inducing a shift from the production of nontradeable products into the marketed production of tradeable products. Devaluation also removes rationing in the foreign exchange market and increases supplies of consumer goods, giving producers incentives to increase their output for sale on the market. The goal of liberalization is to bring the domestic relative prices of tradeable products into line with world relative prices through removing controls on trade, such as import controls, tariffs, or export taxes and subsidies. Removing such controls generally leads to 2 The term "structural adjustment" is used to encompass both stabilization and structural adjustment policies. 3 If the price of a product is determined by world market conditions, it is classified as a "tradeable" good. Tradeable products produced domestically include exports and unprotected import substitutes. If the price of a product is determined by domestic supply and demand, the product is classified as "nontradeable". 4

7 an increase in a country s terms of trade (the domestic price of exports relative to imports), shifting output towards the production of exports and unprotected import substitutes, which are tradeables, and out of protected imports substitutes, which are nontradeables (World Bank 1991). Thus, both devaluation and liberalization are expected to induce increases in the production of tradeable relative to nontradeable products. In order for such a shift to come about, reallocations of labor and other factors of production from nontradeable to tradeable production must take place. Agriculture is the most important tradeable sector in Sub-Saharan African countries. It is in the agricultural sector that most export production and tradeable food production takes place. At the same time as it is the site of the greatest potential increase in tradeable production, the agricultural sector is the source of employment, income and consumption for the large majority of people in Sub-Saharan Africa. In the following section a conceptual framework for tracing the impacts of expenditure switching and expenditure reduction (specifically, reductions in expenditures on social services) policies on household welfare--including children s, men s and women s welfare--will be developed. 5

8 III. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK: WELFARE PROVISIONING IN HOUSEHOLDS Most agricultural production in Sub-Saharan Africa takes place on family farms, in which relations between people who are linked through family ties, including marriage, are important for the allocation of labor and other inputs into production. The African household is commonly composed of several nuclear families, each made up of a husband, one or more wives, and the children born to each wife. Complex economic interactions between members of separate nuclear families and, within families, between wives of the same nuclear family, may take place. In the following conceptual framework, this complex reality is sacrificed in order most clearly to illustrate the significance of the distinct behaviors of women and men for welfare provisioning in family-based production units of rural Sub-Saharan Africa. I consider a two decision maker economic unit or "household," made up of a woman and a man (the decision makers) and their children. I also assume that production takes place with only the use of the decision makers labor. The conceptual framework is presented in diagrammatic form in Figure 1, which will be referred to throughout this section. Figure 1 shows, for our hypothetical two-person household, links between time allocation, income generation, income allocation, and household welfare. A. Model of Time and Income Allocation Patterns of time and income allocation in households are thought to be founded on social roles underlying household members obligations to provide welfare. Social roles that are germane to welfare provisioning can be usefully classified into the categories of production and reproduction. The role of production is associated with the transformation of physical product to be used for direct consumption by household members, for exchange, or for sale on the market. The role of reproduction, which is directly associated with peoples physical well-being, can be further broken down into subcategories of generational reproduction and daily reproduction. Generational reproduction involves the bearing and early nurturing of infants and the care and upbringing of children. Daily reproduction involves recurrent tasks of securing the dayto-day 6

9 7

10 material survival of the household, such as cooking, collecting water and firewood, and cleaning (Ellis 1992). These role categories will be employed below to provide useful distinctions between categories of time and income allocation. Time Allocation Time is the most basic resource with which welfare is provided in households. How household members time is allocated among different activities is thus key to human welfare. Individuals may spend time in the provision of services to others and to themselves by engaging in activities that directly enhance their and other household members physical well-being, i.e., in "reproductive" activities. Time thus spent falls under the role category of reproduction. Individuals may also provide welfare indirectly by contributing to the availability of what will be termed "welfare inputs," defined to be material goods that enhance the physical wellbeing of household members. Time thus spent falls under the role category of production. Examples of welfare inputs are food, clothing, and medicine. Welfare inputs can be provided in two ways. The first is through time spent producing goods, such as food, that are directly consumed by household members. Such time is referred to as time in "production for consumption". The second is through time spent in production for cash income, the income from which can be used to purchase welfare inputs. Reproductive activities and production for consumption are classified as "nonmarket" work, production for cash income as "market" work. For our two-person hypothetical household, Figure 1 shows the links between, on the one hand, household members time allocated among reproductive activities, production for consumption and production for cash income (market work) and, on the other, household welfare. Time spent in reproductive activities feeds directly into household welfare. Time spent in production for consumption feeds indirectly into household welfare through contributing to the quantities of goods available for consumption by household members. Time spent in market work also ultimately feeds indirectly into household welfare through contributing to goods consumed by household members. However, the manner in which the cash income generated is allocated among purchased welfare inputs and other goods depends on a complex decision making process involving transfers of income between household members. This process will be elaborated below. 8

11 The allocation of household members time among the activity categories delineated above and their non-work time is constrained by their time endowments (twenty-four hours a day). Denoting the woman "agent f" (indexed i=f) and the man "agent m" (indexed i=m), household members time constraints can be characterized as: [1] where T i R = agent i s time in reproductive activities = agent i s time in production for consumption i T M = agent i s time in market work i T o = agent i s non-work time T = agent i s time endowment. T PC i Income Generation and Allocation In rural Sub-Saharan African households, agricultural production commonly takes place in a combination of joint, or "communal," and individual, or "personal," production activities. In personal production the majority of labor is provided by one individual household member; in communal production, labor is provided by all active household members. 4 Traditionally almost all of both communal and personal agricultural production was of food for direct consumption by household members. In modern times in most areas of Sub-Saharan Africa, at least some agricultural produce is sold on the market for cash income. In addition, many people have become involved in non-agricultural income generating activities such as food processing, handicraft production for sale, and trade (these are mainly personal production activities). A communal-personal dichotomy in labor allocation to income generating activities, whether they be agricultural or non-agricultural, has evolved parallel to subsistence agricultural production. 4 This common pattern is described in Whitehead (1990), Saul (1989), McMillan (1986), Roberts (1988), Koopman (1991), Guyer (1981), Davison (1988), David (1991), Webb (1989), and Dey (1992). Although in some areas men and women exchange labor in their personal production activities, in this analysis such labor exchanges will be ignored. 9

12 For our two-member household, agents time in market work (T M i ) can thus be further disaggregated into personal (MP) and communal (MC) market work (see Figure 1): [2] Composite production functions for communal and personal income generating production, respectively, can be characterized as [3] [4] where V MC and V i MP are purchased inputs into communal and personal income generating production. In Sub-Saharan African households, cash incomes received by different household members from income generating production are generally not pooled (Guyer 1988; Fapohunda 1988). Social norms govern who in households receives income from different activities and who pays for productive inputs. In general, for communal production this individual is a man, while for personal production it is the individual earner, which may be a man or a woman (see references in footnote 4). Although incomes received by household members are not generally pooled, household members often make transfers of cash income to each other. 5 Thus, their income constraints can be characterized as being separate, yet linked through income transfers. Let the categories into which cash income is allocated by agents m and f be their purchases of welfare inputs (denoted X W i ), their purchases of inputs into income generating production (V MP f for agent f; V MP m and V MC for agent m), and their purchases of "other goods" (denoted X o i ). 6 Agents income constraints restrict their total expenditures on these goods to 1) the income they receive from income generating production, plus 2) the income transfers they receive from outside of the household (their exogenous incomes), plus 3) the income 5 Discussion of income transfers can be found in Guyer (1988 and 1989), Jones (1986), Afonja (1990), David (1991), Roberts (1988), and Whitehead (1990). 6 These variables represent composite commodities combining all of the agents purchases falling into each category. 10

13 transfers they receive from the other agent. Let t be the net cash income received by agent f from agent m. Then agent f s and agent m s income constraints, respectively, can be characterized as [5] [6] where E i = agent i s exogenous income p i w = the price of welfare inputs purchased by agent i i p o = the price of other goods purchased by agent i v i = the price of purchased inputs into agent i s personal income generating production q i = the price of output from agent i s personal income generating production v c = the price of purchased inputs into communal income generating production q c = the price of output from communal income generating production Resource Control and Decision Making Resource control can be defined as the ability to decide how a resource is allocated. In the case of time allocation control is the ability to decide how time is allocated among different activities. In the case of income allocation control is the ability to decide how income is allocated among different purchases. Thus, resource control in households is germane to the decision making process in them. The degree of control over time and income by different household members is influenced by social norms governing decision making and by the balance of bargaining power in households. In the literature on decision making in Sub-Saharan African households two major themes emerge. The first is that men and women often function in separate economic spheres in which they make independent decisions regarding the allocation of resources they control (Whitehead 1990; Guyer 1986; Saul 1989; Fapohunda 1988; Palmer 1988). The second is that with the rise of commercialization has come increased conflict between women and men over the activities and purchases to which time and income are allocated. This conflict is manifested in negotiation between women and men over resource control itself. As noted above, the product of agricultural production traditionally remained primarily in the form of food. Customs and norms governed the distribution of this product to meet the consumption needs of households and their social obligations. With the rise of commercialization has come sales of agricultural produce and new non-agricultural income generating activities, along with a range of goods for purchase on the market. 11

14 Consequently, a portion of households product is in the form of cash income rather than food, and a selection of goods to purchase with this income is available. Money, as a generalized means of exchange, typically brings with it wider choices for allocation than does physical product. The transformation from subsistence to semicommercialized households has brought with it conflicts among household members over who earns income, who controls it, and how it is allocated. 7 Thus, although men and women commonly function in separate spheres of economic activity in which they make independent decisions, at times they are brought into a joint decision making unit in which conflicts are resolved. Social norms governing decision making over the allocation of inputs into communal and personal production influence control over labor in households. The primary decision maker for communal income generating production is usually a male adult, who makes decisions regarding the allocation of household members labor and other productive inputs. For personal income generating production the individual earner is the primary decision maker for allocation of labor and other inputs. However, because men receive the income generated in communal production while women contribute labor to it, the conflict between women and men surrounding income is manifested in negotiation between them over the time women spend in communal income generating production (T f MC ) and over transfers of income between women and men (t). Because neither men nor women make completely independent decisions regarding the allocation of women s labor to communal income generating production (this is negotiated), neither have full control over it. 8 Although women do not fully control the amount of time they spend in communal income generating production, they do make independent decisions over the allocation of their time in other activities. In terms of agent f s time constraint (equation [1] for i=f), the time agent f controls independently is the left hand side of 7 Discussion of such conflicts and some examples are given in Whitehead 1990, David 1991, Dey 1992, Guyer 1989, Holmboe-Wattesen and Wandel 1988, Jones 1986, Obbo 1990, Roberts 1988, Saul 1989, and Pankhurst See references in footnote 4 and Guyer 1981, Roberts 1988, and Koopman 1991 for viewpoints on men s control of women s labor in Sub-Saharan African households. 12

15 [7] Since men generally make independent decisions regarding the allocation of their time among all activities, they fully control their own time (the left hand side of equation [1] for i=m). Social norms governing who receives income from different income generating activities have been described above. Income accrual of household members is translated into income controlled by them through the mediation of income transfers. In general, a person who receives income from any activity is likely to be the person who controls it. However, where income transfers take place and are negotiated over, both men and women do not independently control all of the income they receive. By definition, they do make independent decisions over the allocation of the income they control, i.e., the income they receive net of transfers (the right hand sides of equations [5] and [6]). The outcome of negotiation between agents with differing interests is thought to be determined by their relative bargaining powers. Bargaining power gives a person the ability to influence the outcome of negotiation with others in the person s own interests. In general, in the household context, bargaining power is thought to be determined by the opportunity cost of being a member of the household, or how "well" individual members could do if they were to leave the household. A significant economic determinant of this opportunity cost is thought to be the ability to earn income independently of other household members. Such ability gives a person a measure of independence from other household members, increasing their capability of providing for themselves if they leave the household (Folbre 1988; Pollack 1985). Figure 1 lays out the process through which time spent by men and women in market work feeds into household welfare. The dashed lines indicate an arena of negotiation. Both women and men provide labor to communal market work. With changes in households economic environments such as those which come with commercialization, negotiation takes place over women s labor allocated to communal market work. Men and women also provide labor to personal market work. Men receive income earned in communal market work and in their own personal market work, while women receive income earned in their own personal market work. The income controlled by women and men is made up of the income they receive from market work net of income transfers between them, over which negotiation takes place. Finally, men and women make independent 13

16 decisions over the allocation of income they control to purchased goods. If these goods are welfare inputs, they enhance household welfare. The decision making process described above involves a combination of unilateral and joint decision making. Joint decision making (negotiation) takes place over the time and income controlled by different household members, i.e., over the distribution of resource control, while unilateral decision making takes place over the allocation of time and income they control. In the following section a formal mathematical model of this decision making process is presented. Model of Decision Making Let welfare provisioning in households be governed by the following function: where [8] [9] 14

17 The inputs into welfare provisioning are women s and men s purchased welfare inputs (X i W ) and the time they spend providing welfare, either directly through reproductive activities (T i R ) or indirectly through production for consumption (T i PC ). 9 Let agents allocational priorities among household welfare (W), other purchased goods (X i o ) and their and the other agent s non-work time (T i o ) be governed by utility functions: [10] In the model presented below, a game theoretic approach is taken, which allows modeling the decision making of multiple agents with differing interests. Game theoretic models can be classified into two types, noncooperative and cooperative. In noncooperative models each agent makes decisions unilaterally (given their expectations of other agents choices), while in cooperative models agents make decisions jointly. 10 The complexity of a decision making process involving both unilateral and joint decision making (the latter determining constraints for the former) can be simplified for modeling purposes by separating them into a twostage game theoretic framework as do Carter and Katz (1994) in their "Conjugal Contract" model. In the first stage, choice over the unilaterally-decided variables takes place. This is modeled as a noncooperative game. 11 Agents choose their allocation of time to welfare provisioning (T W i ), personal market work (T MP i ), and non-work (T o i ) unilaterally. They also choose the allocation of the income they control among welfare inputs (X W i ), productive inputs (V MP i ), and other goods (X o i ) unilaterally. In addition, agent m 9 Household welfare is treated as a "z-good" as in Household Production Models (Becker 1965). Time in welfare provisioning could be modeled as entering indirectly into equation [8] as an input into a large number of production functions for produced welfare inputs. These could be, for example, food, cooked food, clean water, or child care. To simplify, the exact products being produced (in the case of T PC i )or service being provided (in the case of T R i ) are not given explicit production functions. It is assumed that household members take into account the myriad of goods and services into which their welfare provisioning time enters as they allocate their time to welfare provisioning (T W i ). 10 Cooperative bargaining models were first adapted to the analysis of household decision making by Manser and Brown (1980) and McElroy and Horney (1981). Jones (1983) used a cooperative bargaining model for analysis of intrahousehold resource allocation in the African context. Noncooperative game theory has been used for the analysis of household decision making by, among others, Chiappori (1992), Ulph (1988), and Lundberg and Pollack (1992). 11 In particular, it is modelled as a two person strictly competitive game of complete information, meaning that no coordination between agents is needed for equilibrium strategies to be chosen (Carter and Katz 1994). 15

18 unilaterally chooses agent m s time allocated to communal market work (T m MC ) and income allocated to purchased inputs into communal income generating production (V MC ). In the second stage, choice over the jointly-decided variables takes place. These are the net transfers of income from agent m to agent f (t) and the amount of time agent f spends in communal market work (T f MC ). Choice over the jointly-decided variables is modeled as a Nash cooperative bargaining game in which agents negotiate over alternative Pareto optimal outcomes by maximizing a Nash objective function. Mathematically the objective function is the product of the agents gains from membership in the household, represented by the differences between their utilities in the current state and their maximum possible utilities if the household unit were to dissolve. The latter are referred to as "fall-back positions". The Nash objective function reflects the bargaining power effects of the opportunity cost of being a household member: the more attractive an individual s opportunities outside of the household, the more strongly are the individual s allocational priorities reflected in the final levels of the jointly-decided variables. Fall-back positions can be represented mathematically by specifying an indirect utility function for each household member giving maximum utility levels if they are no longer part of the household unit. 12 For women, economic variables affecting these fall-back positions are the prices associated with their personal income generating activities, the prices of the products they would purchase if they were to leave the household, and their exogenous incomes. For men, along with these variables are added the prices associated with communal income generating activities. The fall-back positions are determined by maximization of agents utility functions subject to the time and income constraints they would face if they were to leave the household. 12 Divorce is an option in many areas of Sub-Saharan Africa. See Pool 1972, Trincaz 1983, Guyer 1990, David 1991; Hanger and Moris 1973 and Capron 1973 for discussion of and examples of marital instability in African families. 16

19 Let the fall-back positions for agent f and agent m, respectively, be: [11] [12] where p i, i=f,m are the prices of goods purchased by the agents if they are no longer part of the household unit. The model is as follows. STAGE ONE: Unilateral Decision Making Over Allocation Each agent s utility function is maximized given fixed levels of (or given their expectations of) the other agent s choice variables and the jointly-decided variables. Agent f chooses T f W,T f o,t f MP,X f W,X f o, and V f MP to maximize subject to Agent m chooses T W m,t o m,t MP m,t MC m,x W m,x o m,v MP m and V MC to maximize subject to where the productions functions are given in equations [3] and [4]. This process yields a system of reactions functions, each giving agents choice variables as functions of the other agent s choice variables (along with the jointly-decided variables). Solved simultaneously, the system 17

20 yields a reduced-form equation for each unilaterally-decided choice variable conditional on the levels of the jointly-decided variables (which are given as parametric in the first stage). The conditional reduced-form equations are [13] [14] [15] where [16] These equations give the optimal levels of the unilaterally-decided variables for each possible (t,t f MC ) combination. STAGE TWO: Joint Decision Making Over Distribution Agents jointly choose t and T f MC to maximize subject to [17] [18] where the fall-back positions are given in equations [11] and [12], and equation [17] is the Nash objective function. Equation [18] limits resource allocation to outcomes in which both agents have positive utility gains from membership in the household. Equilibrium reduced-form equations for the jointly-decided variables are: where 18

21 [19] [20] The optimal levels of income transfers and of agent f s time in communal market work are "constrained Pareto optimal." That is, given that time and income controlled by agents are optimally allocated to unilaterallydecided variables (from the point of view of their allocational priorities), no agent can be made better off without the other agent being made worse off. Reduced-Form Equation for Household Welfare Substituting equations [19] and [20] into equations [13] in turn yields equilibrium reduced-form equations for time and income allocated to welfare provisioning: [21] [22] Finally, substituting equations [21] and [22] into equation [8] yields an equilibrium reduced-form equation for household welfare: [23] Without going into the optimality conditions and comparative statics effects which the above model generates, 13 immediately apparent from equation [23] is the separate, rather than additive, appearance of the exogenous components of agents incomes. Exogenous incomes enter separately into equation [23] for two reasons. First, agents do not pool their incomes. They make decisions over their expenditures independently 13 A more formal analysis of similar models can be found in Katz (1992), Carter and Katz (1994), and Smith (forthcoming). 19

22 subject to separate budget constraints. Second, the incomes that accrue to them, including their exogenous incomes, enhance their bargaining powers. Equation [23] is derived from a complex mathematical model of decision making, which remains a gross oversimplification of reality. Its usefulness lies in permitting identification of key contact points between changes in households economic environments and household welfare. According to the model, changes in the prices (and exogenous incomes) faced by household members affect household welfare through changes in both market and non-market time allocation and, mediated by changes in income controlled by household members, through changes in household members expenditures on purchased goods. B. Gender-Differentiated Allocational Priorities, Access and Power In the model presented above, agents are treated symmetrically with the exceptions that 1) agent m s allocation of labor to communal production is a unilateral decision while the allocation of agent f s labor to it is a joint decision and 2) agent m receives the income from communal production and purchases inputs into it. Three social factors underlay additional differences in the patterns of men s and women s time and income allocation in rural Sub-Saharan African households. The first factor is women s and men s differing responsibilities for allocating time to welfare provisioning (T i W, i=f,m) and for allocating income to welfare inputs (X i W, i=f,m). These responsibilities influence their allocational priorities. The second factor is men s and women s differential independent access to productive resources. The last factor is differences in women s and men s bargaining powers. Men and women in Sub-Saharan African households tend to have distinct individual responsibilities for family maintenance (Guyer 1988). Many differences in the responsibilities accorded to them are thought to be founded on their differing social roles. Biophysical circumstances account for women s almost exclusive role in generational reproduction: only women can bear and breast feed children. Although both women and men are physically capable of carrying out tasks associated with the role of daily reproduction, in most societies this role is joined with generational reproduction as the almost exclusive domain of women. The role of production is by contrast shared by both men and women (Ellis 1992; Joekes et al 1988). 20

23 The role of reproduction is more closely linked with peoples physical well-being than is the role of production. Correspondingly, women tend to be more directly involved in welfare provisioning than men (Lele 1991; Commonwealth Secretariat, 1989). Evidence from time allocation studies reveal that a far greater amount of women s time is spent in reproductive activities than men s (i.e., T f R >T m R ). By contrast, both women and men are highly engaged in productive activities, i.e., in production for household consumption and/or in market work (World Bank 1991; Davison 1988), with differences in their time spent in these activities varying by region. Given such a division of labor in households, male and female labor can be characterized as having low substitutability in reproductive activities (Ellis 1992). With regard to income allocation, the general consensus is that (in developing countries) men tend to use a larger proportion of income than women for productive, household maintenance and social investment, and for their personal consumption; women tend to use a larger proportion of income than men for meeting daily household consumption needs, such as food, clothing and health care (Kennedy and Bouis 1993; Joekes et al 1988; Blumberg 1989; Bruce and Dwyer 1988; Lele 1986; Koopman 1991). In many areas of rural Sub-Saharan Africa women are responsible for paying for food while men are responsible for paying for clothing, medical expenses and taxes (Elson 1990a), and men are more likely than women to spend income on luxury goods, such as alcohol and tobacco (Haddad and Hoddinott 1991; Holmboe-Ottesen and Wandel 1991; David 1991). Expenditure patterns vary from household to household. Both women and men may make necessary expenditures on welfare inputs. The key factor to note is that these expenditures tend to differ systematically, meaning that the levels of income controlled by different household members (the right hand sides of equations [5] and [6]) matters for the final mix of purchased welfare inputs (X f W and X m W ). The second social factor leading to differences in men s and women s resource allocation is that women tend to have more limited access to productive resources and markets than men. Examples of these resources are land, labor, technology, information and credit (Joekes et al 1988; World Bank 1991; Stamp 1989). Such limited access, along with constraints on women s time in other activities, constrains women s ability to engage in personal cash income generating production. 21

24 Finally, women are thought to have less bargaining power than men. This means that men s ability to influence the outcome of negotiations in their own interests is greater than women s. That Sub-Saharan African women spend more total time working than men (Koopman 1991; Mehra 1991) may be a manifestation of this balance of bargaining power in favor of men. Cultural norms and advantages and disadvantages based on gender are important factors leading to differences in women s and men s bargaining powers (Folbre 1991; Bossen 1989). In general, since women are more dependent than men on the resources which membership in households as marriage partners allows, the negative economic consequences of marital dissolution are often greater for women than for men (Blau 1989; Pollack 1985). 14 C. Allocative Inefficiency If household members had common allocational priorities, resource control and bargaining power differentials would not matter for resource allocation in households. Allocation of time would be based on these common priorities and on household members comparative advantages in different activities. Joint rationality would prevail in the maximization of household income. Income accruing to household members would be perfectly substitutable and (given expenditure responsibilities) transfers would flow freely so as to meet common allocational priorities. Income allocation would take place as if it were subject to the constraint of pooled household income. However, differences in men s and women s allocational priorities mean that resource control and bargaining power matter for resource allocation in households. They combine to produce two types of allocative inefficiency from the point of view of total household resources. The first is inefficiency in the allocation of time to income generating activities. The second is inefficiency in the allocation of time and income to welfare provisioning. Allocative inefficiency in income generation exists because of incentive incompatibilities between women and men in providing labor to communal market work (Collier 1990). Since women do not receive the product of their labor in such work, if they do not expect to gain control of income generated through transfers from men, they may have low incentive to participate. Whether women are able to resist doing so (or to 14 See Pankhurst (1991, p. 620 and footnote 5) for an example from Zimbabwe of women s post-divorce position relative to men s. 22

25 negotiate an acceptable level of income transfers) depends on many factors, among which is their bargaining power relative to men. If communal market work yields the highest returns to labor, where women are able to resist allocating labor to it in favor of their personal (less remunerative) market work, time allocation to market work is inefficient from the point of view of the household s total time endowment (Dey 1992; Jones 1983; Whitehead 1990). Both men and women provide inputs into welfare provisioning and benefit from increased levels of household welfare. However, they tend to make separate decisions--from the point of view of their own allocational priorities--regarding the allocation of the time they control to welfare provisioning (T i W ) and the income they control to welfare inputs (X i W ). In addition to this underlying factor, inefficiencies in welfare provisioning stem from 1) the non-pooling of household income; and 2) the low substitutability of women s and men s time in reproductive activities, with women s contribution generally being to the exclusion of men. Where household members have common allocational priorities, purchased inputs into welfare provisioning are chosen so as to maximize household welfare subject to the constraints of welfare provisioning technology (equation [8]) and total household income. However, if household members have differing allocational priorities and incomes are not pooled, the final mix of purchased welfare inputs may not maximize household welfare given these constraints. In this case, income allocated to welfare inputs is inefficient from the point of view of total household resources. Situations can arise where a reduction in one household member s real income (either the income they receive or the prices of goods they purchase) is not accompanied by increased transfers of cash income from other household members or changes in their expenditure patterns. A reduction in the welfare input purchases of the person whose real income is reduced could occur even when sufficient income is available in the household for these purchases. Similarly, an increase in one household member s real income may not be accompanied by increased transfers to other household members so that a corresponding increase in the latters welfare input purchases does not take place (Elson 1990b; Guyer 1988). Linked to the low substitutability of men s and women s time in reproductive activities, inefficiencies in the allocation of time to welfare provisioning may also arise. If changes in the prices associated with income generating production lead to women spending more time in market work (T f M =T f MP +T f MC increases), they may 23

26 spend less time in reproductive activities (T f R may decrease). If substitute labor is not available, this shift could have an adverse impact on household, especially children s, welfare. However, reductions in women s time spent in reproductive activities, such as child care, could be compensated by increases in income earned and spent by women on welfare inputs, such as food (Cornia, Jolly and Stewart 1987). In a review of studies in developing countries, Leslie (1988) finds that overall there is not much evidence of a negative effect of maternal remunerated employment on children s nutrition, one measure of children s welfare. However, the studies reviewed presumably refer to income that is earned and controlled by women. Women s reproductive activities are mostly to the exclusion of men, and women generally make independent decisions regarding the allocation of the time they control to such activities. However, in order to make efficient (welfare maximizing) decisions about the balance of their time between reproductive activities and market work from the point of view of their allocational priorities and constraints women need to be able to make independent decisions regarding their time in market work as well. Women do not make independent decisions over the allocation of their time to communal market work and over the allocation of the income they earn in it. Given women s lower bargaining power than men s, if women and men have differing allocational priorities, any increased time women spend in communal market work may not be accompanied by increases in the income they control. Transfers of income from men to women can be fluctuating and discretional (see Guyer 1988), nonexistent, or lower than the value of the product women produce. Thus reductions in (women s) time allocated to reproductive activities in households due to increased time in communal market work may not be compensated by increases in purchases of welfare inputs. IV. STRUCTURAL ADJUSTMENT POLICY IMPACTS ON HOUSEHOLD WELFARE In this section, using the conceptual framework presented above, I examine the possible effects of structural adjustment policies--expenditure switching policies and reductions in government expenditures on social services--on rural Sub-Saharan African households welfare. These measures can eventually impact household welfare through changing the level of purchased welfare inputs available in households and/or the amount of time spent by household members in welfare provisioning. 24

27 A. Expenditure Switching Policies Expenditure switching policies, including devaluation and liberalization, shift relative prices in favor of tradeable products. Higher prices for tradeable products give incentives to producers to reallocate productive resources, including labor, towards tradeable production. In response, agricultural households which produce tradeable crops at the onset of adjustment are expected to increase their production and sale of these crops. Households that produce nontradeable crops are expected to shift crop composition towards tradeable crops. 15 Increases in tradeables production in the agricultural sector could take place in the form of increases in the production of export crops and/or of tradeable food crops for sale on the market, both of which are cash crops. 16 Expenditure switching policies thus promote not only increased production of tradeable products, but also increased production of cash crops (as opposed to products destined for consumption in the households in which they are produced) in general. If households increase their production of cash crops, a larger proportion of their product will be in the form of cash income, and a larger proportion of their consumption, including consumption of welfare inputs, will need to be met through purchases on the market. Such tradeable-led commercialization may thus bring with it conflicts between household members surrounding income allocation, along with corresponding allocational inefficiencies in both income generation and welfare provisioning. In most rural areas of Sub-Saharan Africa, both men s and women s time are highly concentrated in agricultural production. Increases in both women s and men s time in market work may take place as a result of expenditure switching policy-induced incentives. Although the policies are pursued through changing market variables, i.e., prices, they may also have impacts on non-market variables through changing the allocation of time in households. Increases in the market work time of household members induce changes in their allocation 15 The prices of intermediate inputs into production will affect the rates of return that can be obtained. Here it will be assumed that the net effect of relative price changes is to increase the profitability of tradeable relative to nontradeable production during structural adjustment. 16 Whether food crops are tradeables or nontradeables depends on the degree to which world market prices influence their domestic prices. In some areas food is a tradeable product while in others it is not. Some staple foods produced in Sub-Saharan African countries, yams for example, are intrinsically nontradeables. Some foods that could be traded on world markets, such as many grains, are nontradeables within the rural economy due to storage and transportation costs. In countries where food produced is an unprotected import substitute, food is a tradeable commodity (Collier 1990). Food crops that are consumed primarily within households without entering the market are nontradeables. 25

Inside the Household

Inside the Household Inside the Household Spring 2016 Inside the Household Outline for Today I model II Evidence on : Lundberg, Pollak and Wales III Evidence on : Duflo IV Cooperative models V Noncooperative models VI Evidence

More information

Using Household Production Models to Understand Environmental Health Outcomes in Developing Countries

Using Household Production Models to Understand Environmental Health Outcomes in Developing Countries International Journal of Behavioral Science KARNJANA SANGLIMSUWAN Copyright 2012 by Behavioral Science Research Institute 2012, Vol. 7, No.1, 99-108 ISSN: 1906-4675 Using Household Production Models to

More information

The Collective Model of Household : Theory and Calibration of an Equilibrium Model

The Collective Model of Household : Theory and Calibration of an Equilibrium Model The Collective Model of Household : Theory and Calibration of an Equilibrium Model Eleonora Matteazzi, Martina Menon, and Federico Perali University of Verona University of Verona University of Verona

More information

Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan

Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan Hwei-Lin Chuang* Professor Department of Economics National Tsing Hua University Hsin Chu, Taiwan 300 Tel: 886-3-5742892

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Tracking Government Investments for Nutrition at Country Level Patrizia Fracassi, Clara Picanyol, 03 rd July 2014

Tracking Government Investments for Nutrition at Country Level Patrizia Fracassi, Clara Picanyol, 03 rd July 2014 Tracking Government Investments for Nutrition at Country Level Patrizia Fracassi, Clara Picanyol, 03 rd July 2014 1. Introduction Having reliable data is essential to policy makers to prioritise, to plan,

More information

Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623

Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623 Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623 J.R.Walker March 20, 2012 Suppose that births are biological feasible in the first two periods of a family s life cycle, but

More information

Including Unpaid Work in Modeling

Including Unpaid Work in Modeling Including Unpaid Work in Modeling By Rania Antonopoulos Levy Economics Institute and GEM-IWG Global Conference on Unpaid Work and the Economy: Gender, Poverty, and the Millennium Development Goals October

More information

Family Bargaining and Retirement Behavior. Shelly Lundberg * University of Washington. October 1998

Family Bargaining and Retirement Behavior. Shelly Lundberg * University of Washington. October 1998 Forthcoming in: Behavioral Dimensions of Retirement Economics, ed. Henry Aaron, Russell Sage/Brookings, 1999. Family Bargaining and Retirement Behavior Shelly Lundberg * University of Washington October

More information

Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe

Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe The Effect of Partial and Full Retirement Decision of Husbands and Wives on Their Partners Partial and Full Retirement Decision Gülin Öylü MSc Thesis 07/2017-006

More information

Week 1. H1 Notes ECON10003

Week 1. H1 Notes ECON10003 Week 1 Some output produced by the government is free. Education is a classic example. This is still viewed as a service and valued at the cost of production which is primarily the salary of the workers

More information

Social Security: Is a Key Foundation of Economic Security Working for Women?

Social Security: Is a Key Foundation of Economic Security Working for Women? Committee on Finance United States Senate Hearing on Social Security: Is a Key Foundation of Economic Security Working for Women? Statement of Janet Barr, MAAA, ASA, EA on behalf of the American Academy

More information

2 A Conceptual Framework for Understanding Poverty and Social Impacts

2 A Conceptual Framework for Understanding Poverty and Social Impacts 2 A Conceptual Framework for Understanding Poverty and Social Impacts This chapter presents the main concepts underlying poverty and social impact analysis. It addresses seven key areas: What is being

More information

Glossary. Average household savings ratio Proportion of disposable household income devoted to savings.

Glossary. Average household savings ratio Proportion of disposable household income devoted to savings. - 440 - Glossary Administrative expenditure A type of recurrent expenditure incurred to administer institutions that directly and indirectly participate in the delivery of services. For example, in the

More information

Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002

Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002 The University of British Columbia Department of Economics Economics 351: Women in the Economy Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002 I. For each of the following questions, circle the letter corresponding

More information

Family consumption and time use How is intra-household consumption and time use impacted by income decrease, following an economic recession?

Family consumption and time use How is intra-household consumption and time use impacted by income decrease, following an economic recession? Family consumption and time use How is intra-household consumption and time use impacted by income decrease, following an economic recession? Sif Sigfúsdóttir Helga Kristjánsdóttir Hagfræðideild Ritstjóri:

More information

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries BACKGROUND PAPER FOR THE WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2008 Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries Larry Karp The findings, interpretations, and conclusions

More information

Country Report of Yemen for the regional MDG project

Country Report of Yemen for the regional MDG project Country Report of Yemen for the regional MDG project 1- Introduction - Population is about 21 Million. - Per Capita GDP is $ 861 for 2006. - The country is ranked 151 on the HDI index. - Population growth

More information

Session 5 Evidence-based trade policy formulation: impact assessment of trade liberalization and FTA

Session 5 Evidence-based trade policy formulation: impact assessment of trade liberalization and FTA Session 5 Evidence-based trade policy formulation: impact assessment of trade liberalization and FTA Dr Alexey Kravchenko Trade, Investment and Innovation Division United Nations ESCAP kravchenkoa@un.org

More information

Equity and Development: Through a Gender Lens

Equity and Development: Through a Gender Lens Equity and Development: Through a Gender Lens Presentation by Diane Elson 2016 Leontief Prize Award Ceremony March 10, 2016 Leontief invented a way of looking at economies, in terms the structure of resource

More information

PRODUCTIVE SECTOR COMMERCE PDNA GUIDELINES VOLUME B

PRODUCTIVE SECTOR COMMERCE PDNA GUIDELINES VOLUME B PRODUCTIVE SECTOR COMMERCE PDNA GUIDELINES VOLUME B 2 COMMERCE CONTENTS n INTRODUCTION 2 n ASSESSMENT PROCESS 3 n PRE-DISASTER SITUATION 4 n FIELD VISITS FOR POST-DISASTER DATA COLLECTION 5 n ESTIMATION

More information

Exchange Rate Volatility, Trade, and Capital Flows under Alternative Exchange Rate Regimes

Exchange Rate Volatility, Trade, and Capital Flows under Alternative Exchange Rate Regimes Exchange Rate Volatility, Trade, and Capital Flows under Alternative Exchange Rate Regimes Piet Sercu Catholic University of Leuven Raman Uppal University of British Columbia PUBLISHED BY THE PRESS SYNDICATE

More information

Closure in CGE Models

Closure in CGE Models in CGE Models Short Course on CGE Modeling, United Nations ESCAP Professor Department of Economics and Finance Jon M. Huntsman School of Business Utah State University jgilbert@usu.edu September 24-26,

More information

GUIDELINES FOR CONDUCTING A PROVINCIAL PUBLIC EXPENDITURE REVIEW (PPER) OF THE AGRICULTURE SECTOR

GUIDELINES FOR CONDUCTING A PROVINCIAL PUBLIC EXPENDITURE REVIEW (PPER) OF THE AGRICULTURE SECTOR Socialist Republic of Vietnam MINISTRY OF FINANCE VIE/96/028: Public Expenditure Review Phase GUIDELINES FOR CONDUCTING A PROVINCIAL PUBLIC EPENDITURE REVIEW (PPER) OF THE AGRICULTURE SECTOR DECEMBER 2001

More information

CHAPTER 11 CONCLUDING COMMENTS

CHAPTER 11 CONCLUDING COMMENTS CHAPTER 11 CONCLUDING COMMENTS I. PROJECTIONS FOR POLICY ANALYSIS MINT3 produces a micro dataset suitable for projecting the distributional consequences of current population and economic trends and for

More information

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth Shelly J. Lundberg University of Washington and Jennifer Ward-Batts University of Michigan Prepared for presentation at the Second Annual

More information

Public Economics (ECON 131) Section #4: Labor Income Taxation

Public Economics (ECON 131) Section #4: Labor Income Taxation Public Economics (ECON 131) Section #4: Labor Income Taxation September 22 to 27, 2016 Contents 1 Implications of Tax Inefficiencies for Optimal Taxation 2 1.1 Key concepts..........................................

More information

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Journal of Economic Integration 20(4), December 2005; 631-643 Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Noritsugu Nakanishi Kobe University Toru Kikuchi Kobe University

More information

FREE TRADE AND PROTECTIONISM BENONI DIMULESCU

FREE TRADE AND PROTECTIONISM BENONI DIMULESCU FREE TRADE AND PROTECTIONISM BENONI DIMULESCU Benoni DIMULESCU, Ph.D. Candidate University of Craiova Key words: free trade, protectionism, tariff, quantitative restriction, subsidy Abstract: One of the

More information

Static and Intertemporal Household Decisions

Static and Intertemporal Household Decisions Static and Intertemporal Household Decisions Pierre-Andre Chiappori and Maurizio Mazzocco Current Draft, July 2014. Chiappori: Columbia University, Department of Economics. Mazzocco: University of California

More information

The following box outlines the basic steps in economic analysis. The last

The following box outlines the basic steps in economic analysis. The last 4 The Groundwork for Economic Analysis 11 The following box outlines the basic steps in economic analysis. The last three are often given most attention in how to guidelines and this is understandable

More information

Globalisation, Gender and Growth

Globalisation, Gender and Growth Globalisation, Gender and Growth Ray Rees University of Munich and CESifo Ray Riezman University of Iowa, CESifo and GEP October 18, 2008 Abstract We consider the e ect of globalisation on fertility, human

More information

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Lesotho

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Lesotho Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Lesotho Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis IFS Briefing Note 118 James Browne The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis 1. Introduction 1 James Browne Institute

More information

Static and Intertemporal Household Decisions

Static and Intertemporal Household Decisions Static and Intertemporal Household Decisions Pierre-Andre Chiappori and Maurizio Mazzocco Current Draft, September 2015. Abstract We discuss the most popular static and dynamic models of household behavior.

More information

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS OF FLORIDA AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS TO CUBA

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS OF FLORIDA AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS TO CUBA GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS OF FLORIDA AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS TO CUBA Michael O Connell The Trade Sanctions Reform and Export Enhancement Act of 2000 liberalized the export policy of the United States with

More information

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Trade, Development and Growth. January For students electing

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Trade, Development and Growth. January For students electing WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics Trade, Development and Growth January 2012 For students electing APEC 8701 and APEC 8703 option Instructions * Identify yourself by

More information

Centre for Economic Policy Research

Centre for Economic Policy Research Australian National University Centre for Economic Policy Research DISCUSSION PAPERS GENDER, TIME USE AND MODELS OF THE HOUSEHOLD Paticia Apps* DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 464 June 2003 ISSN: 1442-8636 ISBN:

More information

Business Cycles II: Theories

Business Cycles II: Theories Macroeconomic Policy Class Notes Business Cycles II: Theories Revised: December 5, 2011 Latest version available at www.fperri.net/teaching/macropolicy.f11htm In class we have explored at length the main

More information

Equivalence Scales Based on Collective Household Models

Equivalence Scales Based on Collective Household Models Equivalence Scales Based on Collective Household Models Arthur Lewbel Boston College December 2002 Abstract Based on Lewbel, Chiappori and Browning (2002), this paper summarizes how the use of collective

More information

INNOVATIONS FOR POVERTY ACTION S RAINWATER STORAGE DEVICE EVALUATION. for RELIEF INTERNATIONAL BASELINE SURVEY REPORT

INNOVATIONS FOR POVERTY ACTION S RAINWATER STORAGE DEVICE EVALUATION. for RELIEF INTERNATIONAL BASELINE SURVEY REPORT INNOVATIONS FOR POVERTY ACTION S RAINWATER STORAGE DEVICE EVALUATION for RELIEF INTERNATIONAL BASELINE SURVEY REPORT January 20, 2010 Summary Between October 20, 2010 and December 1, 2010, IPA conducted

More information

An overview of the South African macroeconomic. environment

An overview of the South African macroeconomic. environment An overview of the South African macroeconomic environment 1 Study instruction Study Study guide: study unit 1 Study unit outcomes Once you have worked through this study unit, you should be able to give

More information

Chapter URL:

Chapter URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Effect of Education on Efficiency in Consumption Volume Author/Editor: Robert T. Michael

More information

Social costs tend to persist over a person s lifetime while most tangible costs are one-off

Social costs tend to persist over a person s lifetime while most tangible costs are one-off Social costs tend to persist over a person s lifetime while most tangible costs are one-off 2. The social impact of natural disasters Key points The total economic cost of natural disasters is a complex

More information

Chapter 4 Read this chapter together with unit four in the study guide. Consumer Choice

Chapter 4 Read this chapter together with unit four in the study guide. Consumer Choice Chapter 4 Read this chapter together with unit four in the study guide Consumer Choice Topics 1. Preferences. 2. Utility. 3. Budget Constraint. 4. Constrained Consumer Choice. 5. Behavioral Economics.

More information

Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination

Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination By POL ANTRÀS AND ROBERT W. STAIGER The terms-of-trade theory of trade agreements holds that governments are attracted to trade agreements as a means

More information

WIDER Working Paper 2015/066. Gender inequality and the empowerment of women in rural Viet Nam. Carol Newman *

WIDER Working Paper 2015/066. Gender inequality and the empowerment of women in rural Viet Nam. Carol Newman * WIDER Working Paper 2015/066 Gender inequality and the empowerment of women in rural Viet Nam Carol Newman * August 2015 Abstract: This paper examines gender inequality and female empowerment in rural

More information

An Enhancement of Modern Free Trade Area Theory. Earl L. Grinols Peri Silva. October 2003

An Enhancement of Modern Free Trade Area Theory. Earl L. Grinols Peri Silva. October 2003 An Enhancement of Modern Free Trade Area Theory Earl L. Grinols Peri Silva October 2003 Abstract This paper constructs a simplified framework for analyzing the welfare effects of free trade areas. We provide

More information

NET FISCAL INCIDENCE AT THE REGIONAL LEVEL : A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH VOTING. Saloua Sehili

NET FISCAL INCIDENCE AT THE REGIONAL LEVEL : A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH VOTING. Saloua Sehili NET FISCAL INCIDENCE AT THE REGIONAL LEVEL : A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH VOTING Saloua Sehili FRP Report No. 20 September 1998 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS This report is based on the author s dissertation:

More information

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Congo

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Congo Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update Briefing note for countries on the 2018 Statistical Update Introduction Congo This briefing note is organized into ten sections. The first

More information

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics June. - 2011 Trade, Development and Growth For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option Instructions

More information

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY Once there is imperfect competition in trade models, what happens if trade policies are introduced? A literature has grown up around this, often described as strategic

More information

Integrating a Gender Perspective into Time Use Statistics

Integrating a Gender Perspective into Time Use Statistics Integrating a Gender Perspective into Time Use Statistics Availability of Gender Statistics Frequency of production of different types of gender statistics 100.0 ECA region 90.0 Sexual and reproductive

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

PRODUCTIVE SECTOR MANUFACTURING PDNA GUIDELINES VOLUME B

PRODUCTIVE SECTOR MANUFACTURING PDNA GUIDELINES VOLUME B PRODUCTIVE SECTOR MANUFACTURING PDNA GUIDELINES VOLUME B 2 MANUFACTURE CONTENTS n INTRODUCTION 4 n ASSESSMENT PROCESS 5 n PRE-DISASTER SITUATION 6 n FIELD VISITS FOR POST-DISASTER DATA COLLECTION 6 n ESTIMATING

More information

National Minimum Wage in South Africa: Quantification of Impact

National Minimum Wage in South Africa: Quantification of Impact National Minimum Wage in South Africa: Quantification of Impact Asghar Adelzadeh, Ph.D. Director and Chief Economic Modeller Applied Development Research Solutions (ADRS) (asghar@adrs-global.com) Cynthia

More information

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno Fabrizio Perri Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR fperri@umn.edu December

More information

Eswatini (Kingdom of)

Eswatini (Kingdom of) Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update Briefing note for countries on the 2018 Statistical Update Introduction (Kingdom This briefing note is organized into ten sections. The

More information

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Nigeria

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Nigeria Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update Briefing note for countries on the 2018 Statistical Update Introduction Nigeria This briefing note is organized into ten sections. The

More information

INCREASING THE RATE OF CAPITAL FORMATION (Investment Policy Report)

INCREASING THE RATE OF CAPITAL FORMATION (Investment Policy Report) policies can increase our supply of goods and services, improve our efficiency in using the Nation's human resources, and help people lead more satisfying lives. INCREASING THE RATE OF CAPITAL FORMATION

More information

STRUCTRAL CHANGE, DISCRIMINATION AND FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

STRUCTRAL CHANGE, DISCRIMINATION AND FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION DOI: 10.19275/RSEP013 Received: 21.04.2017 Accepted: 10.06.2017 STRUCTRAL CHANGE, DISCRIMINATION AND FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION Marie Scheitor University of Greifswald, Germany E-mail: marie.scheitor@uni-greifswald.de

More information

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Introduction Intermediate Macroeconomics Consumption/Saving, Ricardian

More information

Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development

Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development Plenty of good land, and liberty to manage their own affairs their own way, seem to be the two great causes of prosperity of all new colonies. Adam

More information

EFFECT OF PUBLIC EXPENDITURES ON INCOME DISTRIBUTION WITH SPECIAL REFERENCE TO VENEZUELA

EFFECT OF PUBLIC EXPENDITURES ON INCOME DISTRIBUTION WITH SPECIAL REFERENCE TO VENEZUELA EFFECT OF PUBLIC EXPENDITURES ON INCOME DISTRIBUTION WITH SPECIAL REFERENCE TO VENEZUELA BY L. URDANETA DE FERRAN Banco Central de Venezuela Taxes as well as government expenditures tend to transform income

More information

Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017

Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017 Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017 1. Governments should act to further the public interest. This statement would probably receive general agreement, but it is not always

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

CHAPTER.5 PENSION, SOCIAL SECURITY SCHEMES AND THE ELDERLY

CHAPTER.5 PENSION, SOCIAL SECURITY SCHEMES AND THE ELDERLY 174 CHAPTER.5 PENSION, SOCIAL SECURITY SCHEMES AND THE ELDERLY 5.1. Introduction In the previous chapter we discussed the living arrangements of the elderly and analysed the support received by the elderly

More information

BROAD DEMOGRAPHIC TRENDS IN LDCs

BROAD DEMOGRAPHIC TRENDS IN LDCs BROAD DEMOGRAPHIC TRENDS IN LDCs DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGES are CHALLENGES and OPPORTUNITIES for DEVELOPMENT. DEMOGRAPHIC CHALLENGES are DEVELOPMENT CHALLENGES. This year, world population will reach 7 BILLION,

More information

Trade and Development

Trade and Development Trade and Development Table of Contents 2.2 Growth theory revisited a) Post Keynesian Growth Theory the Harrod Domar Growth Model b) Structural Change Models the Lewis Model c) Neoclassical Growth Theory

More information

Toward Active Participation of Women as the Core of Growth Strategies. From the White Paper on Gender Equality Summary

Toward Active Participation of Women as the Core of Growth Strategies. From the White Paper on Gender Equality Summary Toward Active Participation of Women as the Core of Growth Strategies From the White Paper on Gender Equality 2013 Summary Cabinet Office, Government of Japan June 2013 The Cabinet annually submits to

More information

Appendix 2 Basic Check List

Appendix 2 Basic Check List Below is a basic checklist of most of the representative indicators used for understanding the conditions and degree of poverty in a country. The concept of poverty and the approaches towards poverty vary

More information

Underutilized Capital David Dollar and Shang-Jin Wei

Underutilized Capital David Dollar and Shang-Jin Wei What's New Site Map Site Index Contact Us Glossary A quarterly magazine of the IMF June 2007, Volume 44, Number 2 Search Finance & Development Search Advanced Search About F&D Subscribe Back Issues Write

More information

Working Paper #1. Optimizing New York s Reforming the Energy Vision

Working Paper #1. Optimizing New York s Reforming the Energy Vision Center for Energy, Economic & Environmental Policy Rutgers, The State University of New Jersey 33 Livingston Avenue, First Floor New Brunswick, NJ 08901 http://ceeep.rutgers.edu/ 732-789-2750 Fax: 732-932-0394

More information

ECONOMICS PUBLIC SECTOR. of the JOSEPH E. STIGUTZ. Second Edition. W.W.NORTON & COMPANY-New York-London. Princeton University

ECONOMICS PUBLIC SECTOR. of the JOSEPH E. STIGUTZ. Second Edition. W.W.NORTON & COMPANY-New York-London. Princeton University ECONOMICS of the PUBLIC SECTOR a Second Edition JOSEPH E. STIGUTZ Princeton University W.W.NORTON & COMPANY-New York-London Contents Preface Part One xxi Introduction 1 The Public Sector in a Mixed Economy

More information

For students electing Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) & Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) option

For students electing Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) & Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) option WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics Jan. - 2014 Trade, Development and Growth For students electing Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) & Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) option Instructions

More information

Economic activity framework

Economic activity framework CHAPTER 7 LABOR MARKET ACTIVITIES Background Economic activity and employment are shaped by many factors, including the size of the ing-age, educational and skill level of the labor force, and availability

More information

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate University of British Columbia Department of Economics, International Finance (Econ 556) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout #3 1 1 on-traded goods and the real exchange rate So far we have looked at environments

More information

Principles and Main Elements of Social Strategy. E.Sh. Gontmakher, V.V. Trubin

Principles and Main Elements of Social Strategy. E.Sh. Gontmakher, V.V. Trubin Principles and Main Elements of Social Strategy E.Sh. Gontmakher, V.V. Trubin March 23, 2000 1. When Russia undertook systemic reforms in the 1990s, it had a quite heavy burden in the form of the people

More information

I. Interest Groups and the Government Budget

I. Interest Groups and the Government Budget Economics 203: How the Economy Influences Policy Fall 2005 Casey B. Mulligan We have studied extensively how government policy affects the economy. At least as important are effects of the economy on policy.

More information

Women s economic empowerment in the changing world of work:

Women s economic empowerment in the changing world of work: Women s economic empowerment in the changing world of work: Reflections from South Asia Jayati Ghosh For UN-ESCAP Bangkok 23 February 2017 Gender discrimination has been crucial for growth in Asian region,

More information

CHAPTER 03. A Modern and. Pensions System

CHAPTER 03. A Modern and. Pensions System CHAPTER 03 A Modern and Sustainable Pensions System 24 Introduction 3.1 A key objective of pension policy design is to ensure the sustainability of the system over the longer term. Financial sustainability

More information

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy We now proceed to study optimal fiscal policy. We should make clear at the outset what we mean by this. In general, fiscal policy entails the government choosing its spending

More information

Globalization and the Feminization of Poverty within Tradable and Non-Tradable Economic Activities

Globalization and the Feminization of Poverty within Tradable and Non-Tradable Economic Activities Istanbul Technical University ESRC Research Papers Research Papers 2009/02 Globalization and the Feminization of Poverty within Tradable and Non-Tradable Economic Activities Raziye Selim and Öner Günçavdı

More information

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Life-cycle Labour Supply The simple static labour supply model discussed so far has a number of short-comings For example, The

More information

The World Economy from a Distance

The World Economy from a Distance The World Economy from a Distance It would be difficult for any country today to completely isolate itself. Even tribal populations may find the trials of isolation a challenge. Most features of any economy

More information

STEP 7. Before starting Step 7, you will have

STEP 7. Before starting Step 7, you will have STEP 7 Gap analysis Handing out mosquito nets in Bubulo village, Uganda Photo credit: Geoff Sayer/Oxfam Step 7 completes the gap-analysis strand. It should produce a final estimate of the total shortfall

More information

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS Determination of Income and Employment Chapter 4 We have so far talked about the national income, price level, rate of interest etc. in an ad hoc manner without investigating the forces that govern their

More information

Explaining Dualism in a Gender Perspective: Gender, Class and the Crisis

Explaining Dualism in a Gender Perspective: Gender, Class and the Crisis Explaining Dualism in a Gender Perspective: Gender, Class and the Crisis Marcella Corsi, Sapienza University of Rome marcella.corsi@uniroma1.it Abstract In the economic literature, several scholars have

More information

Oman. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Oman. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Oman Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

The Effect of Gender-Based Returns to Borrowing on Intra-Household Resource Allocation in Rural Bangladesh

The Effect of Gender-Based Returns to Borrowing on Intra-Household Resource Allocation in Rural Bangladesh The Effect of Gender-Based Returns to Borrowing on Intra-Household Resource Allocation in Rural Bangladesh Saad Alam University of St Thomas, MN, USA Abstract Income from rural microcredit borrowing can

More information

Chapter 11: General Competitive Equilibrium

Chapter 11: General Competitive Equilibrium Chapter 11: General Competitive Equilibrium Economies of Scope Constant Returns to Scope Diseconomies of Scope Production Possibilities Frontier Opportunity Cost Condition Marginal Product Condition Comparative

More information

STUDENTSFOCUS.COM BA ECONOMIC ANALYSIS FOR BUSINESS

STUDENTSFOCUS.COM BA ECONOMIC ANALYSIS FOR BUSINESS STUDENTSFOCUS.COM DEPARTMENT OF MANAGEMENT STUDIES BA 7103 -ECONOMIC ANALYSIS FOR BUSINESS Meaning of economics. UNIT 1 Economics deals with a wide range of human activities to satisfy human wants. It

More information

The Goods Market and the Aggregate Expenditures Model

The Goods Market and the Aggregate Expenditures Model The Goods Market and the Aggregate Expenditures Model Chapter 8 The Historical Development of Modern Macroeconomics The Great Depression of the 1930s led to the development of macroeconomics and aggregate

More information

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Matthias Doepke (Northwestern) Michèle Tertilt (Mannheim)

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Matthias Doepke (Northwestern) Michèle Tertilt (Mannheim) Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Matthias Doepke (Northwestern) Michèle Tertilt (Mannheim) Evidence Evidence : Evidence : Evidence : Evidence : : Evidence : : Evidence : : Evidence

More information

A N ENERGY ECONOMY I NTERAC TION MODEL FOR EGYPT

A N ENERGY ECONOMY I NTERAC TION MODEL FOR EGYPT A N ENERGY ECONOMY I NTERAC TION MODEL FOR EGYPT RESULTS OF ALTERNATIVE PRICE REFORM SCENARIOS B Y MOTAZ KHORSHID Vice President of the British University in Egypt (BUE) Ex-Vice President of Cairo University

More information

WJEC (Wales) Economics A-level Trade Development

WJEC (Wales) Economics A-level Trade Development WJEC (Wales) Economics A-level Trade Development Topic 1: Global Economics 1.1 International trade Notes International trade This is the exchange of goods and services across international borders. The

More information

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018 Summary of Keister & Moller 2000 This review summarized wealth inequality in the form of net worth. Authors examined empirical evidence of wealth accumulation and distribution, presented estimates of trends

More information

SECTION A: (MICRO-ECONOMICS) NB: Answer only three (3) questions in this section. Production possibilities curve Opportunity cost (5 marks)

SECTION A: (MICRO-ECONOMICS) NB: Answer only three (3) questions in this section. Production possibilities curve Opportunity cost (5 marks) SECTION A: (MICRO-ECONOMICS) NB: Answer only three (3) questions in this section QUESTION 1 (a) Define the following terms: (i) (ii) Production possibilities curve Opportunity cost (5 marks) (b) Assume

More information

Trade Liberalization and Gains from Uganda s Lint Export

Trade Liberalization and Gains from Uganda s Lint Export American Journal of Economics 2015, 5(5): 458-462 DOI: 10.5923/j.economics.20150505.02 Trade Liberalization and Gains from Uganda s Lint Export T. Odongo Department of Finance, Makerere University Business

More information

Chapter 4 Monetary and Fiscal. Framework

Chapter 4 Monetary and Fiscal. Framework Chapter 4 Monetary and Fiscal Policies in IS-LM Framework Monetary and Fiscal Policies in IS-LM Framework 64 CHAPTER-4 MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICIES IN IS-LM FRAMEWORK 4.1 INTRODUCTION Since World War II,

More information