Do Borrowing Constraints Matter? An Analysis of Why the Permanent Income Hypothesis Does Not Apply in Japan

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Do Borrowing Constraints Matter? An Analysis of Why the Permanent Income Hypothesis Does Not Apply in Japan"

Transcription

1 Do Borrowing Constraints Matter? An Analysis of Why the Permanent Income Hypothesis Does Not Apply in Japan Miki Kohara and Charles Yuji Horioka August 2005 Abstract In this paper, we use micro data on young married households from the Japanese Panel Survey of Consumers, conducted by the Institute of Research on Household Economics, to shed light on (1) the prevalence of borrowing constraints in Japan, (2) what households are borrowing-constrained in Japan, (3) whether the life cycle/permanent income hypothesis (LCPIH) holds in Japan, and (4) whether the presence of borrowing constraints, the presence of income risk, or the presence of precautionary motives for saving is the reason why the LCPIH does not hold in Japan. To summarize our main ndings, we nd (1) that about 8 percent of young married Japanese households are borrowing-constrained, (2) that the husband s educational attainment is the most important determinant of whether or not a household is borrowing-constrained, (3) that the Euler equation implication is rejected for both the full sample and for the subsample of unconstrained households, (4) that the Euler equation implication is rejected for both low income volatility and high income volatility households, and (5) that the Euler equation implication is rejected for households with precautionary motives for saving but cannot be rejected for households without precautionary motives for saving. These results suggest that the LCPIH does not apply in Japan and that the presence of precautionary motives for saving (not the presence of borrowing constraints or the presence of income volatility) is the main reason for why it does not apply. 1

2 1 Introduction If the life cycle/permanent income hypothesis (hereafter LCPIH) holds, changes in consumption should not be sensitive to changes in current income. On the other hand, if this hypothesis does not hold (for example, because households are borrowing-constrained), changes in consumption will be sensitive to changes in current income. Thus, a commonly used test of the validity of the LCPIH is to estimate an Euler equation to see whether changes in consumption are sensitive to changes in current income. If the LCPIH does not hold and the reason is the existence of borrowing constraints, we would expect changes in consumption to be sensitive to changes in current income in the case of borrowing-constrained households but not in the case of unconstrained households. In this paper, we use micro data on young married households from the Japanese Panel Survey of Consumers, conducted by the Institute of Research on Household Economics, to shed light on (1) the prevalence of borrowing constraints in Japan, (2) what households are borrowing-constrained in Japan, (3) whether the LCPIH holds in Japan, and (4) whether the presence of borrowing constraints, the presence of income risk, or the presence of precautionary motives for saving is the reason why the LCPIH does not hold in Japan. To summarize our main ndings, we nd (1) that about 8 percent of young married Japanese households are borrowing-constrained, (2) that the husband s educational attainment is the most important determinant of whether or not a household is borrowing-constrained, (3) that the Euler equation implication is rejected for both the full sample and for the subsample of unconstrained households, (4) that the Euler equation implication is rejected for both low income volatility and high income volatility households, and (5) that the Euler equation implication is rejected for households with precautionary motives for saving but cannot be rejected for households without precautionary motives for saving. These results suggest that the LCPIH does not apply in Japan and that the presence of precautionary motives for saving (not the presence of borrowing constraints or the presence of income volatility) is the main reason for why it does not apply. The paper is organized as follows: in section 2, we present the theoretical model; in section 3, we describe the data and analyze what households are borrowing-constrained in Japan; in section 4, we present the results of our Euler equation tests; and section 5 concludes. 2

3 2 The Model 2.1 Consumption Smoothing Consumption smoothing behavior is characterized by the Euler equation. Assume that the consumer holds A t of total assets at the beginning of period t and purchases a total of N t of assets at (the end of) t. These are real expenditure on total assets 1. The consumer earns labor income of w t h t, where w is the exogenous real wage that is constant across individuals and h is work hours, and spends it on the consumption of goods, c, and the purchase of assets, N. The saving constraint faced by the consumer is described as S t = N t A t = w t h t c t : The consumer also faces an asset accumulation constraint of A t+1 = N t (1+r t+1 ) where r t+1 is the interest rate at the beginning of period t + 1. Assume that all agents face the same interest rate. Individuals live for a nite lifetime T and leave no bequests at T + 1. Consumers allocate all of their time, say 24 hours a day, between work, h t, and leisure, l t, which creates another constraint (a time constraint). Standardizing time to one, h t + l t = 1: These constraints can be combined into one constraint as follows N t N t 1 (1 + r t ) = w t h t c t : Suppose that the individual s n utility is stationary and additively separable PT o 1 over time and written as E t k=t u(c (1+) k t k ) ;where E t is an expectation operator conditional on information available at t, u is a function that is increasing and concave in c t and is the rate of time preference, which is assumed to be homogeneous over individuals and time. We assume that utility is not a function of leisure. The representative consumer s maximization problem can be written as a dynamic programming problem. Maximizing V t = u(c t ; l t ) + 1 E 1+ tv t+1 (A t+1 ; w t+1 ), we obtain the rst order condition (the Euler equation for 1 + r t+1 E t = 0; t 1 t+1 implying consumption at t should be chosen so that the expected discounted gain of saving now for the future is equal to marginal utility in this period. In addition, assume, as is often done, that utility is isoelastic, u(c it ) = c 1 it =1, where is the risk aversion parameter. Marginal utility is convex and allows for precautionary saving as a special case. If it is assumed 1 We can write the multiple asset case in the same way but using a vector, N k (N 1;k ; :::; N J;k ), where N j;k is the j th asset the household holds at the end of k. 3

4 that lnc i;t+1 and r t+1 have a joint normal distribution, equation (1) becomes lnc i;t+1 E t ln c i;t+1 = 1 (E t r t+1 ) + 1 2!2 i;t: (2) In the last term,! 2 i;t is a measure of uncertainty, is equal to the variance of ( ln c i;t+1 r t+1 =), and shows a precautionary motive for saving. There are at least two ways to test the validity of equation (2). The rst way is to test a structural form, estimating utility function parameters using Generalized Method of Moments (nonlinear instrumental variable) estimation. This is a direct test using the Euler equation, whose error term should be orthogonal to information before t. GMM estimation is bene cial in the sense that we can avoid the approximation of linear marginal utility in consumption, the assumption of distribution, and the assumption of income exogeneity. However, many researchers have for a long time used another way to test the Euler equation implication. This is a test of the reduced form Euler equation with additional variables in past information sets. It tests the validity of this additional information (for example, income changes) predicted by previous information. Additional variables should not explain consumption changes if the Euler equation holds. For example, consumption changes should not react to predicted income changes. That is, we test whether = 0 in the equation ln c i;t+1 = 1 F t + 2 X i;t !2 i;t + ln y e i;t+1 + " i;t+1 ; (3) where ln yi;t+1 e is income predicted by individuals using the information available to them. This is calculated as tted values from the rst stage estimation of ln y i;t+1. F t is a time-varying variable including 1 (E t r t+1 ). Preference shifts, described as X i;t, could a ect the consumption plan at any point in time. The third term is the conditional variance of the uncertain components. One of our main focuses is to review past studies using proper data on consumption smoothing. Thus, we conduct this reduced form exclusion test. The null hypothesis is that the Euler equation holds and individuals smooth consumption changes against predicted income changes. That is, = 0: consumption does not react to predicted income changes. Most past studies drop the term of precautionary motive for savings, 1 2!2 i;t, simply assuming that it is the same across individuals. In many cases, we cannot avoid assuming this because information is seldom available 4

5 on precautionary motives. The exception is Jappelli and Pista erri (2000), where a nominal (observable) income variance is included as a proxy for the uncertainty term! 2 i;t into one of the explanatory variables. Jappelli and Pista erri (2000) emphasize the importance of including this term; if we ignore this term and if ln y e i;t+1 is related to uncertainty or precautionary saving motives, measures not the sensitivity of consumption to income but the e ect of uncertainty on consumption. This method could, however, be problematic for the following reasons. First, income uncertainty is only one of many uncertainties individuals face and is not a su cient indicator of general uncertainty. Second, even if uncertainty consists only of income uncertainty, using actual income uncertainty as a proxy for! 2 i;t as well as ln y e i;t+1 may raise a problem due to the correlation between the two. Fortunately, our data set collects the data needed to calculate income variances as a proxy of income uncertainty and also collects data on the existence of precautionary motives for saving. Therefore, we test the Euler equation implication using equation (3) dropping the third term of 1 2!2 i;t, but estimating the equation separately for high and low uncertainty groups Violation of Consumption Smoothing If markets are complete and there exist appropriate securities against any future state, each household s consumption is fully insured against any idiosyncratic shock. Households can smooth consumption changes completely, sharing risks with each other. Previous studies have tested this implication of consumption full insurance and most have rejected it. Although it is important to nd a situation (if any) where full insurance holds, the rejection of the implication is not surprising. A more interesting issue is what can and what cannot explain the violation of the implication. For example, the existence of borrowing constraints may cause the Euler equation implication to be rejected. Many studies have, for a long time, inquired into the existence of borrowing constraints and the di erences in consumption behavior between borrowing-constrained and unconstrained households. Households would fail to smooth consumption if they encountered an 2 Since our data are panel data on households, we conduct IV estimation controlling for household-speci c di erences by: (a) taking the rst di erence of all variables in the speci cation of the equation (3), (b) applying xed e ects estimation, and (c) applying random e ects estimation. 5

6 unexpected shock and could not borrow to carry out their original plans. Thus, unconstrained households do not react to income shocks, while constrained households react strongly. Based on this analogy, many researchers have tested the Euler equation such as equation (3) and have interpreted as the proportion of borrowing-constrained households. There exist many other auxiliary assumptions that are imposed to derive the Euler equation and its test implication. For example, we ignore the possibility of the existence of precautionary saving (the di erence in uncertainty among households) on the assumption that it is same across time and individuals. Once we have rejected the Euler equation implication, we should seek the reason for it, checking each possible explanation one by one. The following parts focus on the existence of borrowing constraints, which is the most frequently used explanation for the violation of the Euler equation implication. Speci cally, we identify unconstrained households using unique information on households borrowing constraints and test the Euler equation implication using this subsample. If the existence of borrowing constraints is the primary explanation for the violation of the Euler equation implication, we should nd evidence of the Euler equation implication for this sample but not for the full sample. However, if other explanations for the violation of the Euler equation implication matter, we will not nd support for this implication even for the unconstrained sample. We will discuss other possible explanations for the violation of the Euler equation implication later after we have examined the empirical results for borrowing constraints. 3 The Data 3.1 JPSC Data This paper uses micro data from the Japanese Panel Survey of Consumption, (hereafter the JPSC) (in Japanese, Shouhi Seikatsu ni kansuru Paneru Chousa), a panel survey conducted by the Institute for Research on Household Economics (in Japanese, Kakei Keizai Kenkyuusho). This survey has surveyed young married and unmarried women (those between the ages of 24 and 34 in 1993) once a year since 1993, and this paper uses the waves from this survey. Because JPSC is a panel survey, we can calculate changes in consumption from year to year, which is precisely the variable we 6

7 need to test our theoretical model. We con ne our analysis to the subsample of married women because most young single Japanese women live with their parents and rely on their parents income but precise information is not available on their parents income and consumption. Note that married women are asked not only about themselves but also about other household members. Borrowing constraints. The rst and most important variable used in our analysis is the one pertaining to borrowing constraints. The JPSC asks three unique questions about borrowing constraints: (1) Have you (or your spouse) ever had a loan application turned down? (2) Have you (or your spouse) ever had the loan amount reduced when you applied for a loan? (3) Have you (or your spouse) ever decided against applying for a loan because you expected your loan application to be turned down? Following Jappelli (1990), we refer to households answering "yes" to these questions as "rejected," "reduced," and "discouraged" borrowers, respectively. Households that replied "yes" to one or more of these questions were regarded as being borrowing-constrained. Unfortunately, this information is available only for the rst survey. Thus, we had no choice but to assume that borrowing constraints remain unchanged over the sample period. This is exactly what Jappelli (1990) and Jappelli, Pischke, and Souleles (1998) assume, even though it may be too strong an assumption. We will return to this point in the last part of this section. Consumption. The JPSC collects data on consumption (living expenses) by all household members during the month of September. In the regressions, we use the growth rate of monthly consumption. The data on monthly consumption have at least two advantages: rst, they include all consumption goods and services, unlike in the case of PSID, which collects data only on food consumption. Thus, we need not make any assumptions about the separability of consumption. Second, using the change in consumption between two non-sequential months has the advantage of avoiding, to some extent, potential serious problems raised by consumption durability and habit formation 3. Income. The JPSC collects data on several measures of income, includ- 3 The change in monthly consumption could be biased if the household engages in purchases of big-ticket items such as homes and cars. The JPSC asks about spending on living expenses during the previous month excluding spending on most big-ticket items. The survey asks separately about purchases nanced by loans. Thus, we can exclude the possibility that consumption growth is overestimated as a result of purchases of big-ticket items. 7

8 ing annual (total) income, annual labor income, and monthly labor income. Annual (total) income and annual labor income are inclusive of taxes so we need to estimate taxes in order to calculate after-tax income. We use after-tax monthly labor income in the main Euler equation for at least three reasons: rst, we wanted the period and timing of consumption and income to match. If we use annual income, there is a danger of underestimating the degree of consumption smoothing simply because annual income is more stable than monthly income or consumption. Another reason for using monthly income is that using annual income would require us to waste the last year of data since the survey asks about annual income in the previous year. Finally, the use of monthly labor income helps to reduce the amount of household heterogeneity because data on monthly labor income are not available for the self-employed. We sum the monthly labor incomes of all household members and use the growth rate of total monthly labor income in the regressions. Household characteristics. Following the past literature on testing the LCPIH and the existence of borrowing constraints by estimating an Euler equation, we take the husband s age, the household s consumption needs, as proxied by the number of family members, and year dummies. Although we tried including many other time-variant and time-invariant variables that might possibly in uence consumption, particularly that of young Japanese households such as those included in our sample, all of the variables we tried including had little e ect and their inclusion was not supported statistically 4. Time-invariant variables such as residential area dummies are anyway dropped from xed e ects estimation. In estimating expected income change, we use previous year s income change and husband s educational attainment as instruments, adding to the explanatory variables for consumption. The total number of married women (households) was about 1000 in most years. We kept an observation if it contained enough information for at least a one-year panel. Thus, the sample we used is unbalanced panel. After eliminating observations with missing values for one or more of the variables included in the regressions, we were left with 1058 households (5674 household-years) in the full sample and 980 households (4243 householdyears) in the unconstrained sample 5. 4 For example, neither a dummy variable for those who had their rst baby during the current year, which could make a big di erence in consumption patterns, nor a dummy variable for those who starting living with their parents during the current year, which is often observed in Japan as the parents get older, did not change the results below. 5 Observations lying outside of the mean plus or minus two standard deviations range 8

9 3.2 Who is Constrained? Before estimating the Euler equation, we summarize the characteristics of borrowing-constrained households. Table 1 summarizes the borrowing motives of households that are currently in debt. Although housing and car purchases are the main reasons for borrowing, a few households do in fact borrow to nance living expenses. More than half of the sample is currently in debt, which suggests that borrowing plays an important role in household planning. Many past studies have tried to distinguish borrowing-constrained households from unconstrained households. Since direct data on borrowing constraints are usually not available, most previous studies have tried to predict who is borrowing-constrained using a variety of indicators. In our case as well as in the case of Jappelli (1990), however, direct information is available on whether or not a given household is borrowing-constrained. Thus, following Jappelli (1990), we analyze what determines whether a given household is borrowing-constrained by regressing a dummy variable that equals one if the household is borrowing-constrained and zero otherwise on various household characteristics using probit estimation. The household characteristics we use include assets, income, husband s age and educational attainment, household size, homeownership, debt, city size, and region. We use two measures of assets: Asset1, which is de ned as holdings of bank and postal deposits, bonds, and equities, and Asset2, which is de ned as Asset1 plus life and non-life insurance, land, and housing. Debt is de ned as the amount of outstanding debt. The other variables are described in the last section. Table 2 shows the characteristics of borrowing-constrained and unconstrained households separately. Borrowing-constrained households, especially "reduced" households have lower incomes, assets, husband s employment rate, and husband s educational attainment than unconstrained households. "Discouraged" borrowers also have similar characteristics to "denied" and "reduced" households. This nding underscores the importance of differentiating "discouraged" households from those completely free from borrowing constraints and grouping them together with borrowing-constrained households. Who is borrowing-constrained? Table 3 shows the estimation results of our probit analysis of who is borrowing constrained. The left-hand column of Table 3 shows the results based on the narrower de nition of assets (Asset1), were regarded as outliers and dropped from the sample. 9

10 while the right-hand column shows the results based on the broader de nition of assets (Asset2). Household assets and income are two variables of interest since most past studies have used the ratio of assets to income as an indicator of whether or not a given household is borrowing-constrained, but neither assets nor income are major determinants of whether or not a given household is borrowing-constrained, regardless of which measure of assets is used. Income and Asset2 are not relevant at all, and Asset1 has very little effect on reducing the probability of being borrowing-constrained 6. Our results are very di erent from the results Jappelli (1990) obtained using U.S. data that households with less income or assets indeed face a higher probability of being borrowing-constrained. By contrast, the most relevant variable in the case of Japan is not income or assets but the husband s educational attainment. Educational attainment could be an indicator of current as well as future income, and a household in which the educational attainment of the husband (usually the household head and main income earner) is relatively low might be regarded as having insu cient ability to repay loans. These results have important implications for analyses of borrowing constraints. Although asset holdings may be a signi cant determinant of the probability of being borrowing-constrained in the U.S., it is not a signi cant determinant in Japan. We turn now to a check of the accuracy of indicators used by previous studies to identify borrowing-contrained and unconstrained households. Following previous studies, we group the sample into hypothetically borrowingconstrained and unconstrained households using various indicators and then compare these households to actually borrowing constrained and unconstrained households. The results are shown in Table 4. The rst three indicators, which were originally proposed by Zeldes (1989), are the most frequently used indicators in many countries and are constructed by taking the ratio of asset holdings to income. Since households who have adequate amounts of assets relative to income can dissave their assets when necessary and protect their consumption against unexpected income shocks, households with a high asset-income ratio are regarded as being 6 The self-employed may need to borrow and may face borrowing constraints more frequently than others. Also, employment conditions such as tenure and rm size often a ect household decisions in Japan. Thus, we conducted the estimation including variables relating to the husband s self-employement, tenure, and rm size, but none of their coe cients were signi cant. 10

11 unconstrained. The rst indicator is whether or not the household s holdings of nancial assets are more than twice as much as their monthly income, and the second one is whether or not the household s holdings of total assets ( nancial assets plus housing equity) are more than twice their monthly income. The third indicator classi es households with no nancial assets as being borrowing-constrained and households whose holdings of nancial assets are more than twice their monthly income as being unconstrained. The fourth indicator is whether or not the household owns one or more credit cards. If it owns one ore more credit cards, it can nance its consumption even when it experiences an unexpected income decline. This indicator is close to the one suggested by Shintani (1994), who classi es households as being unconstrained if they own one or more credit cards or one or more cards with a free-loan feature because they need to pass a credit check in order to receive one or both kinds of cards. The fth indicator, proposed by Hayashi (1985b), classi es households as unconstrained if they consume less than 85% of their annual disposable income (minus all debt outstanding plus 20% of their nancial assets). Finally, since we found from Table 3 that educational attainment is a signi cant indicator of being unconstrained, we propose a new indicator identifying college graduates as being unconstrained. In addition, we construct another new indicator that is the same as the rst indicator suggested by Zeldes (1989) except that nancial assets are replaced by a broader concept of assets namely, nancial assets plus housing equity plus life insurance. Table 4 shows the results. The shaded areas indicate the proportion of households identi ed properly. The results are summarized in Table 5. As expected, the husband s educational attainment identi es unconstrained households well, as does Hayashi s indicator (his consumption-income ratio). By contrast, Zeldes s asset-income ratio is better at identifying borrowingconstrained households, but even so, about 50% are misclassi ed. This nding is similar to Jappelli s (1990) nding for U.S. households that using the asset-income ratio leads to serious misclassi cation of constrained and unconstrained households. Moreover, misclassi cation is even more serious in the case of Japanese households. We should identify unconstrained households using information on educational attainment or the consumption-income ratio rather than using information on the asset-income ratio. Moreover, it may not be possible to identify borrowing constrained households regardless of what indicator is used. 11

12 4 The Results 4.1 Euler Equation Test In this section, we present the results of our Euler equation tests, but we rst present the descriptive statistics for the sample used in the estimation in Table 6. First, we estimated the Euler equation for the full sample using simple IV estimation. The results are reported in part (a) of Table 7 (see Appendix for the rst stage regression results), and as can be seen from this table, the coe cient of expected income changes is 0.12 and it is signi cant at the one percent signi cance level. We strongly reject the applicability of the Euler equation implication. Parts (b) and (c) of Table 7 are the results of IV estimations controlling for individual e ects as xed e ects model, or rondom e ects model, respectively. Although the Wu-Hausman test shows that individual e ects are not correlated with the explanatory variables so that the random e ects model is good enough to be estimated, the xed e ects model estimator is still consistent (but ine cient) and may still be preferred if individual e ects relating to the household s consumption and income changes is correlated with the other explanatory variables. The coe cient of expected income is about 0.13 and 0.12 in the xed e ects and random e ects models, respectively. Both coe cients are signi cant at the one percent signi cance level. Thus, we again reject the Euler equation implication. The coe cient of expected income changes in (b) might be upward biased because the process of taking the di erence from the mean (withinestimator) to remove xed e ects makes income changes "transitory or surprising" rather than "expected or permanent" whereas we want to see the reaction of consumption to the latter. A larger coe cient in the xed e ects model relative to the random e ects model may re ect this possibility. A coe cient of at least 0.12 is broadly consistent with previous studies for many countries. However, we will show soon that comparing coe cients in this way is not meaningful. Although there is variation in the magnitude of the coe cients, the test implications are the same: the Euler equation implication is rejected. Households do not smooth consumption changes over even expected income changes. 12

13 4.2 Do Borrowing Constraints Matter? Most of the past literature attributes the violation of the Euler equation implication to the existence of liquidity constraints. Using this analogy, the coe cient of expected income changes, such as the 0.12 value shown in Table 7, is sometimes interpreted as the ratio of constrained households. However, this is not correct. As we have already shown, 8% of our sample is actually constrained, while the results in Table 7 suggest that at least 12 percent of our sample is constrained. If the existence of borrowing constraints are the reason for the violation of the Euler equation implication, we would expect to nd that the Euler equation implication is applicable or close to applicable in the sample of unconstrained households. Table 8 shows the results for the sample of unconstrained households, and as this table shows, the coe cient of expected income changes stays at about the same magnitude and signi cance level. The di erence in the coe cients of expected income changes between the full and unconstrained samples is quite small and not signi cant at a one percent signi cance level (see the bottom row of Table 8). Thus, the Euler equation does not hold even for unconstrained households, which suggests that the existence of borrowing constraints are not the reason for the violation of the Euler equation implication. Many past studies that identify unconstrained households using the level of the asset-income ratio make the conclusions even more ambiguous. In the previous section, we found that splitting the sample by the asset-income ratio itself is questionable, especially when we are interested in the behavior of unconstrained households. In addition to this problem, the sensitivity of consumption to expected income changes as measured by the above type of Euler equation does not show what proportion of households are borrowingconstrained. The results obtained in this paper suggest that the existence of borrowing constraints are not be a major reason for the violation of Euler equation implication. 4.3 Other possible explanations If borrowing constraints are not the explanation, what is the explanation for the violation of the Euler equation implication? The existence of precautionary saving or di erences in households level of uncertainty are possible explanations of the violation of the Euler equation implication. Our basic 13

14 estimation model excludes this possibility, assuming that time and individual xed e ects can control for it, which may be too strong an assumption. Thus, we split the sample into low income volatility and high income volatility households and into households with precautionary motives for saving and households without precautionary motives for saving and estimated the Euler equation for each subsample. When splitting the sample by the amount of income volatility, income volatility was measured as the variance in the husband s annual labor income during the previous four years. High income volatility households were de ned as households whose income volatility is higher than the median, and low income volatility households were de ned as households whose income volatility is lower than the median. When splitting the sample by the presence or absence of precautionary motives for saving, households with precautionary motives for saving were de ned as households with a positive amount of precautionary saving and households without precautionary motives for saving were de ned as households with no precautionary saving. The high (low) income volatility sample has 728 (775) households and 2269 (2762) household-years, while the sample with (without) precautionary motives for saving has 908 (727) households and 3651 (2023) household-years. The estimation results are shown in Table 9, and as this table shows, the coe cient of expected income changes is statistically signi cant and of roughly the same magnitude for both low income volatility and high income volatility households. It is slightly higher for high income volatility households when IV with rst di erences is used but somewhat higher for low volatility households when IV with xed e ects or IV with random e ects are used. Thus, it appears that income volatility is not the explanation for the violation of the Euler equation implication either. Turning to the impact of precautionary motives for saving, Table 10 shows that the coe cient of expected income changes is statistically signi cant and in the 0.15 to 0.16 range in the case of households with precautionary motives for saving but statistically insigni cant and in the 0.05 to 0.09 range in the case of households without precautionary motives for saving. This suggests that precautionary motives for saving are the primary explanation for the violation of the Euler equation implication. The existence of consumption durability is another possible explanation for the rejection of the Euler equation implication. If a commodity is durable and expenditure on that commodity is increased in the present period, expenditure will be depressed in the next period although people indeed enjoy 14

15 consuming that commodity. Households can derive bene ts from consuming now rather than later, showing excess sensitivity of consumption 7. In this case, the error terms in the equation (3) contains the e ects past consumption and are correlated with the explanatory variables (Mankiw (1982), Hayashi (1985b, 1999)). This is, however, less serious in our results, since the survey we used measures consumption at separate time periods one year apart). Furthermore, data problems are also a possible explanation for the rejection of the Euler equation implication. If we do not have data on total consumption but only on consumption of a certain good, we need to assume separability between goods. If we cannot obtain the appropriate micro data to test the Euler equation implication, we have to assume that aggregation is possible. If we cannot nd valid instruments in the limited information set, there exists misspeci cation of the stochastic structure of income. The last problem is related to informational constraints on households. However, these problems are not critical in the present analysis. Our consumption data is total consumption expenditure, and moreover, our data set contains data on a large number and variety of household attributes, making it easier to nd appropriate instruments. Thus, the only explanation for the violation of the Euler equation implication that is potentially relevant in the case of the present analysis and that we have not yet investigated is the assumption of separability between consumption and leisure. 5 Conclusion In this paper, we used micro data on young married households from the Japanese Panel Survey of Consumers, conducted by the Institute of Research on Household Economics, to shed light on (1) the prevalence of borrowing constraints in Japan, (2) what households are borrowing-constrained in Japan, (3) whether the life cycle/permanent income hypothesis (LCPIH) holds in Japan, and (4) whether the presence of borrowing constraints, the 7 The misspeci cation of the assumption that consumption and leisure are separable is yet another possible explanation for the violation of the Euler equation implication. Unless this assumption is imposed, we cannot derive the above type of Euler equation test, where the consumption decision is made independently of the leisure decision. Habit formation is also an example of nonseparable consumption over time. In this case, consumption must increase over time and households try to save now for future consumption, showing excess smoothness of consumption. 15

16 presence of income risk, or the presence of precautionary motives for saving is the reason why the LCPIH does not hold in Japan. To summarize our main ndings, we found (1) that about 8 percent of young married Japanese households are borrowing-constrained, (2) that the husband s educational attainment is the most important determinant of whether or not a household is borrowing-constrained, (3) that the Euler equation implication is rejected for both the full sample and for the subsample of unconstrained households, (4) that the Euler equation implication is rejected for both low income volatility and high income volatility households, and (5) that the Euler equation implication is rejected for households with precautionary motives for saving but cannot be rejected for households without precautionary motives for saving. These results suggest that the LCPIH does not apply in Japan and that the presence of precautionary motives for saving (not the presence of borrowing constraints or the presence of income volatility) is the main reason for why it does not apply. Turning to the policy implications of our ndings, our nding that the presence of precautionary motives for saving is the main reason why the LCPIH does not apply in Japan implies that the best way to make Japanese consumers better o and to enable them to optimize their consumption paths is to reduce uncertainties about the future so that households do not feel the need to do saving for precautionary motives. Possible ways to achieve this would be to improve the safety net for those who experience job loss, income loss, illness, accidents, natural disasters, and other unforeseen emergencies, to relax borrowing constraints so that those experiencing unforeseen emergencies can borrow as much as they need to tide them over, and to revamp the public old-age pension, health insurance, and long-term care insurance programs so that worry about life during retirement is alleviated. 16

17 References [1] Arellano, M., and Bond, S., (1991), Some Tests of Speci cation for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations, Review of Economic Studies, 58, [2] Campbell, J. H. and Mankiw, G. N. (1991), The Response of Consumption to Income: A Cross-Country Investigation, European Economics Review, 35, [3] Hayashi, F. (1985a), The Permanent Income Hypothesis and Consumption Durability: Analysis Based on Japanese Panel Data, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, [4] Hayashi, F. (1986), An Extension of the Permanent Income Hypothesis and Its Test (in Japanese) Keizai Bunseki (Economic Analysis), 101, 1-23, Institute of Economic Reserach, Economic Planning Agency of the Japanese Government. [5] Hayashi, F. (1997), Understanding Saving (Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press). [6] Institute for Research on Household Economics, Japanese Panel Survey of Consumers, 1993 through [7] Jappelli, T. (1990), Who Is Credit Constrained in the U.S. Economy? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105, [8] Jappelli. T., and Pistaferri, L., (2000), Using Subjective Income Expectations to Test for Excess Sensitivity of Consumption to Predicted Income Growth, European Economic Review, 44, [9] Jappelli, T., Pischke, J., and Souleles, N. S. (1998), Testing for Liquidity Constraints in Euler Equations with Complementary Data Sources, Review of Economics and Satistics, 80, [10] Mankiw, N. G., (1982), Hall s Consumption Hypothesis and Durable Goods, Journal of Monetary Economics, 10, [11] Ogawa, K. (1990), Cyclical Variations in Liquidity-Constrained Consumers: Evidence from Macro Data in Japan, Journal of the Japanese and International Ecnomy, 4,

18 [12] Runkle, D. E., (1991), Liquidity Constraints and the Permanentincome Hypothesis, Journal of Monetary Economics, 27, [13] Shibata, A. and Shintani, M. (1998), Capital Mobility in the World Economy: An Alternative Test, Journal of International Money and Finance, 17, [14] Shintani, M. (1994), Nippon no Shouhisha to Ryuudousei Seiyaku, (Japanese Consumers and Liquidity Constraints: A Test Based on Credit Information), Osaka Economic Papers, 44, [15] Wakabayashi, M., and Horioka, C. Y. (2005), "Borrowing Constraints and Consumption Behavior in Japan," Discussion Paper No. 640, Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University. [16] Zeldes, S. P. (1989), Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation, Journal of Political Economy, 97,

19 Table 1. Borrowing Motives All 784 households Borrowing? No / Yes 47.59% / 52.41% If yes, housing 45.9% to finance: car 39.1% durables 10.1% clothing 8.7% leisure 4.6% children' s education 3.6% children's marriage 1.4% payment for accidents 5.6% living expenses 5.3% repayment of debt 5.1% new business 1.2% others 4.3% Note. 1. Households answering "yes" to "Borrowing?" are households that are currently in debt, and the figures in the second line and below show the proportion of households currently in debt that are borrowing for each motive. Since some households are borrowing for more than one motive, the figures sum to more than These data are from the first wave of the Japanese Panel Survey of Consumers, 1993.

20 Table 2. Characteristics of Constrained and Unconstrained Households All Sample Unconstrained Constrained 541 households 92.23% 7.76% Denied (59.52%) Reduced (11.90%) Gave up (71.43%) Mean Std.Dev. Mean Std.Dev. Mean Std.Dev. Mean Std.Dev. Mean Std.Dev. Mean Std.Dev. HusAge HusCollege % 36.8% 48.3% 39.7% 49.0% 2.4% 15.4% 4.0% 20.0% 0.0% 0.0% 3.3% 18.3% HusEmployed % 99.6% 6.1% 99.8% 4.5% 97.6% 15.4% 96.0% 20.0% 100.0% 0.0% 96.7% 18.3% NumFamily Homeown % 23.7% 42.6% 24.0% 42.8% 21.4% 41.5% 20.0% 40.8% 0.0% 0.0% 23.3% 43.0% Asset1 (\10 thousand) Asset2 (\10 thousand) Debt (\10 thousand) Income (\10 thousand) Consumption (\ thousand) Notes. 1. The data are from the first wave of the Japanese Panel Survey of Consumers, "Constrained" households include 'rejected, 'reduced' and 'discouraged' households. Since some households experienced two or more of the three events, the totals sum to more than 100%. 3. HusAge, HusCollege and HusEmployed denote the husband's age, college graduation, and employment status, respectively. 4. NumFamily denotes the number of family (household) members. 5.. Asset1 denotes the household's total holdings of bank and postal deposits, bonds, and equities. Asset2 includes, in addition to Asset1, the paid-in value of life and non-life insurance and the value of land and housing they own. In units of 10,000 yen. 6. Income is the annual disposable income of all household members (in units of 10,000 yen). 7. Consumption is monthly expenditure (in units of 1,000 yen). ]

21 Table 3. Who Is Constrained? Dependent Variable: "Constrained" =1 if either rejected, reduced, or discouraged. Coefficient Coefficient HusAge (0.0046) (0.0069) HusAge*HusAge (0.0001) (0.0001) Income (0.0001) (0.0003) Income*Income (0.0000) (0.0000) Income*HusAge (0.0000) (0.0000) Asset ** (0.0002) Asset1*Asset (0.0000) Asset1*Income (0.0000) Asset1*HusAge (0.0000) Asset (0.0000) Asset2*Asset (0.0000) Asset2*Income (0.0000) Asset2*HusAge (0.0000) HusCollege *** *** (0.0165) (0.0202) HusEmployed (0.2376) NumFamily (0.0023) (0.0041) Homeown (0.0074) (0.0572) Debt * (0.0000) (0.0000) AreaScale_med ** * (0.0115) (0.0156) AreaScale_small ** * (0.0075) (0.0104) Number of obs (households) Log likelihood Likelihood Ratio Notes: 1. The coefficients show marginal effects. 2. For the definitions of the variables, see the text and the notes to Table AreaScale_med and AreaScale_small are dummy variables indicating that the household lives in medium-sized and and small-sized cities, respectively, rather than in a large metropolitan area. Metropolitan areas denote the thirteen ordinance-designated cities. 4. The equation also includes eight regional dummies.

22 Table 4. Indicators of Constrained Households used in the Past Literature PanelA- appropriateness of the past indicators PanelB- other possible indicators Asset (Basic Split)* Actually Basic Split by widely defined assets** Actually 701sample unconstrained constrained 535sample unconstrained constrained The indicator unconstrained The indicator unconstrained predicts: (71.81) (35.59) predicts: (90.06) (66.67) constrained constrained (28.19) (64.41) (9.94) (33.33) Asset (Total Wealth Split) Actually 462sample unconstrained constrained College Graduates (husband) Actually The indicator unconstrained sample unconstrained constrained predicts: (79.50) (56.52) The indicator unconstrained constrained predicts: (96.90) (92.54) (20.50) (43.48) constrained (3.10) (7.46) Asset (Extreme Split) Actually 582sample unconstrained constrained The indicator unconstrained *Saving accounts and time deposits predicts: (85.69) (47.73) **Saving accounts and time deposits, life and non-life insurance, and land constrained and house values (14.31) (52.27) Credit Card Holders Actually 816sample unconstrained constrained The indicator unconstrained predicts: (91.07) (93.94) constrained (8.93) (6.06) Consumption-Income Ratio Actually 581sample unconstrained constrained The indicator unconstrained predicts: (92.50) (83.33) constrained (7.50) (16.67)

23 Table5. Which indicator should be used? Asset (Basic Split) Asset (Extreme Split) Basic Split by widely defined assets* Asset (Total Wealth Split) Basic Split by widely defined assets* Basic Split by widely defined assets* Asset (Extreme Split) Asset (Extreme Split) Asset (Total Wealth Split) Asset (Total Wealth Split) Asset (Basic Split) Asset (Basic Split)

24 Table 6. Descriptive Statistics for the Euler Equation Estimation The entire sample (number of the observations (households) = The unconstrained sample (number of the observations 5674 (1058) ) (households) = 4243 (980) ) Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Consumption change rates Income change rates Income Change rates at one year before Income Change rates at two years before HusAge family size change rates Husage*HusCollege The sample with high income volatility (number of the The sample with low income volatility (number of the observations observations (households) = 2269 (728) ) (households) = 2762 (775) ) Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Consumption change rates Income change rates Income Change rates at one year before Income Change rates at two years before HusAge family size change rates Husage*HusCollege The sample with precautionary motives (number of the The sample without precautionary motives (number of the observations (households) = 3651 (908) ) observations (households) = 2023 (727) ) Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Consumption change rates Income change rates Income Change rates at one year before Income Change rates at two years before HusAge family size change rates Husage*HusCollege Note 1. HusCollege and Husage are same definitions in table 2. Husage*HusCollege is intersection term between Husage and HusCollege. Family size is the number of faily members. Consumption and income changes are changes in monthly values. Changes are all taken as growth rates.

Do Borrowing Constraints Matter? An Analysis of Why the Permanent Income Hypothesis Does Not Apply in Japan

Do Borrowing Constraints Matter? An Analysis of Why the Permanent Income Hypothesis Does Not Apply in Japan Do Borrowing Constraints Matter? An Analysis of Why the Permanent Income Hypothesis Does Not Apply in Japan Miki Kohara and Charles Yuji Horioka y November 30, 2005 Abstract We use micro data on young

More information

DO BORROWING CONSTRAINTS MATTER? AN ANALYSIS OF WHY THE PERMANENT INCOME HYPOTHESIS DOES NOT APPLY IN JAPAN*

DO BORROWING CONSTRAINTS MATTER? AN ANALYSIS OF WHY THE PERMANENT INCOME HYPOTHESIS DOES NOT APPLY IN JAPAN* Discussion Paper No. 663 DO BORROWING CONSTRAINTS MATTER? AN ANALYSIS OF WHY THE PERMANENT INCOME HYPOTHESIS DOES NOT APPLY IN JAPAN* Miki Kohara and Charles Yuji Horioka June 2006 The Institute of Social

More information

Statistical Evidence and Inference

Statistical Evidence and Inference Statistical Evidence and Inference Basic Methods of Analysis Understanding the methods used by economists requires some basic terminology regarding the distribution of random variables. The mean of a distribution

More information

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Stephen R. Bond Institute for Fiscal Studies and Nu eld College, Oxford Måns Söderbom Centre for the Study of African Economies,

More information

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and investment is central to understanding the business

More information

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen Online Appendix Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen Appendix A: Analysis of Initial Claims in Medicare Part D In this appendix we

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 26/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case

More information

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality . 1 Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality Lutz Hendricks Iowa State University, CESifo, CFS March 28, 2004. 1 Introduction 2 Wealth is highly concentrated in U.S. data: The richest 1% of households

More information

STOCK RETURNS AND INFLATION: THE IMPACT OF INFLATION TARGETING

STOCK RETURNS AND INFLATION: THE IMPACT OF INFLATION TARGETING STOCK RETURNS AND INFLATION: THE IMPACT OF INFLATION TARGETING Alexandros Kontonikas a, Alberto Montagnoli b and Nicola Spagnolo c a Department of Economics, University of Glasgow, Glasgow, UK b Department

More information

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

1. Money in the utility function (continued) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (continued) a. Welfare costs of in ation b. Potential non-superneutrality

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation Pai-Ling Yin First Draft: October 2002 This Draft: June 2005 Abstract This paper proposes tests to empirically examine whether auction prices aggregate information

More information

BORROWING CONSTRAINTS, THE COST OF PRECAUTIONARY SAVING AND UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE

BORROWING CONSTRAINTS, THE COST OF PRECAUTIONARY SAVING AND UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE BORROWING CONSTRAINTS, THE COST OF PRECAUTIONARY SAVING AND UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE Thomas Crossley Hamish Low THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES WP05/02 BORROWING CONSTRAINTS, THE COST OF PRECAUTIONARY SAVING

More information

1 Unemployment Insurance

1 Unemployment Insurance 1 Unemployment Insurance 1.1 Introduction Unemployment Insurance (UI) is a federal program that is adminstered by the states in which taxes are used to pay for bene ts to workers laid o by rms. UI started

More information

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth Florian Misch a, Norman Gemmell a;b and Richard Kneller a a University of Nottingham; b The Treasury, New Zealand March

More information

Cardiff University CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL. Cardiff Economics Working Papers No. 2005/16

Cardiff University CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL. Cardiff Economics Working Papers No. 2005/16 ISSN 1749-6101 Cardiff University CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL Cardiff Economics Working Papers No. 2005/16 Simon Feeny, Max Gillman and Mark N. Harris Econometric Accounting of the Australian Corporate Tax

More information

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market Liran Einav 1 Amy Finkelstein 2 Paul Schrimpf 3 1 Stanford and NBER 2 MIT and NBER 3 MIT Cowles 75th Anniversary Conference

More information

Appendix to: The Myth of Financial Innovation and the Great Moderation

Appendix to: The Myth of Financial Innovation and the Great Moderation Appendix to: The Myth of Financial Innovation and the Great Moderation Wouter J. Den Haan and Vincent Sterk July 8, Abstract The appendix explains how the data series are constructed, gives the IRFs for

More information

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function Eurilton Araújo Insper Working Paper WPE: 23/2008 Copyright Insper. Todos os direitos reservados. É proibida a reprodução

More information

Rare Disasters, Credit and Option Market Puzzles. Online Appendix

Rare Disasters, Credit and Option Market Puzzles. Online Appendix Rare Disasters, Credit and Option Market Puzzles. Online Appendix Peter Christo ersen Du Du Redouane Elkamhi Rotman School, City University Rotman School, CBS and CREATES of Hong Kong University of Toronto

More information

Poverty of widows in Europe

Poverty of widows in Europe Poverty of widows in Europe Anikó Bíró Central European University, The University of Edinburgh October 7, 2011 Abstract In this paper I investigate the relationship between widowhood and poverty among

More information

Chapter 3. Wage Elasticity of Labor Supply: A Survey-Based Experimental Approach *

Chapter 3. Wage Elasticity of Labor Supply: A Survey-Based Experimental Approach * Chapter 3 Wage Elasticity of Labor Supply: A Survey-Based Experimental Approach * Fumio Ohtake, Osaka University Shinji Takenaka, Osaka University Kengo Yasui, Osaka University Abstract This research is

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Policy, 8/2 206 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal behavior and steady-state

More information

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model T.Huw Edwards Dept of Economics, Loughborough University and CSGR Warwick UK Tel (44)01509-222718 Fax 01509-223910 T.H.Edwards@lboro.ac.uk

More information

The E ect of Housing on Portfolio Choice

The E ect of Housing on Portfolio Choice The E ect of Housing on Portfolio Choice Raj Chetty Harvard and NBER Adam Szeidl Central European University and CEPR October 2014 Abstract Economic theory predicts that home ownership should have a negative

More information

Estimating the Return to Endogenous Schooling Decisions for Australian Workers via Conditional Second Moments

Estimating the Return to Endogenous Schooling Decisions for Australian Workers via Conditional Second Moments Estimating the Return to Endogenous Schooling Decisions for Australian Workers via Conditional Second Moments Roger Klein Rutgers University Francis Vella Georgetown University March 2006 Preliminary Draft

More information

The ratio of consumption to income, called the average propensity to consume, falls as income rises

The ratio of consumption to income, called the average propensity to consume, falls as income rises Part 6 - THE MICROECONOMICS BEHIND MACROECONOMICS Ch16 - Consumption In previous chapters we explained consumption with a function that relates consumption to disposable income: C = C(Y - T). This was

More information

Precautionary Savings and Income Uncertainty: Evidence from Japanese Micro Data

Precautionary Savings and Income Uncertainty: Evidence from Japanese Micro Data MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES/OCTOBER 2003 Precautionary Savings and Income Uncertainty: Evidence from Japanese Micro Data Keiko Murata This paper tests the existence of precautionary savings using subjective

More information

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Stephen R. Bond Nu eld College, Department of Economics and Centre for Business Taxation, University of Oxford, U and Institute

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Principles of Econometrics Mid-Term

Principles of Econometrics Mid-Term Principles of Econometrics Mid-Term João Valle e Azevedo Sérgio Gaspar October 6th, 2008 Time for completion: 70 min For each question, identify the correct answer. For each question, there is one and

More information

Banking Concentration and Fragility in the United States

Banking Concentration and Fragility in the United States Banking Concentration and Fragility in the United States Kanitta C. Kulprathipanja University of Alabama Robert R. Reed University of Alabama June 2017 Abstract Since the recent nancial crisis, there has

More information

Precautionary Corporate Liquidity

Precautionary Corporate Liquidity Precautionary Corporate Liquidity Kaiji Chen y University of Oslo Zheng Song z Fudan University Yikai Wang University of Zurich This version: February 8th, 21 Abstract We develop a theory of corporate

More information

The Japanese Saving Rate

The Japanese Saving Rate The Japanese Saving Rate Kaiji Chen, Ayşe Imrohoro¼glu, and Selahattin Imrohoro¼glu 1 University of Oslo Norway; University of Southern California, U.S.A.; University of Southern California, U.S.A. January

More information

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II ECON 532) Practice Problems III Q: Consumption Theory CARA utility) Consider an individual living for two periods, with preferences Uc 1 ; c 2 ) = uc 1

More information

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints The University of Hong Kong From the SelectedWorks of Yulei Luo 00 Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints Yulei Luo, The University of Hong Kong Eric Young, University of Virginia Available

More information

CREDIT constraints faced by households have potentially

CREDIT constraints faced by households have potentially JOB LOSS, CREDIT CONSTRAINTS, AND CONSUMPTION GROWTH Thomas F. Crossley and Hamish W. Low* Abstract We use direct evidence on credit constraints to study their importance for household consumption growth

More information

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing /49 Introduction We present models of asset pricing where investors preferences are subject to psychological biases or where investors

More information

Faster solutions for Black zero lower bound term structure models

Faster solutions for Black zero lower bound term structure models Crawford School of Public Policy CAMA Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis Faster solutions for Black zero lower bound term structure models CAMA Working Paper 66/2013 September 2013 Leo Krippner

More information

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics Roberto Perotti November 20, 2013 Version 02 Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics 1 The intertemporal government budget constraint Consider the usual

More information

The E ects of Adjustment Costs and Uncertainty on Investment Dynamics and Capital Accumulation

The E ects of Adjustment Costs and Uncertainty on Investment Dynamics and Capital Accumulation The E ects of Adjustment Costs and Uncertainty on Investment Dynamics and Capital Accumulation Guiying Laura Wu Nanyang Technological University March 17, 2010 Abstract This paper provides a uni ed framework

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES ISSN 1471-0498 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES HOUSING AND RELATIVE RISK AVERSION Francesco Zanetti Number 693 January 2014 Manor Road Building, Manor Road, Oxford OX1 3UQ Housing and Relative

More information

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing Guido Ascari and Lorenza Rossi University of Pavia Abstract Calvo and Rotemberg pricing entail a very di erent dynamics of adjustment

More information

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. No 449. Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. No 449. Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS No 449 Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation Stephen R. Bond, Måns Söderbom and Guiying Wu May 2010

More information

Carbon Price Drivers: Phase I versus Phase II Equilibrium?

Carbon Price Drivers: Phase I versus Phase II Equilibrium? Carbon Price Drivers: Phase I versus Phase II Equilibrium? Anna Creti 1 Pierre-André Jouvet 2 Valérie Mignon 3 1 U. Paris Ouest and Ecole Polytechnique 2 U. Paris Ouest and Climate Economics Chair 3 U.

More information

Are Financial Markets Stable? New Evidence from An Improved Test of Financial Market Stability and the U.S. Subprime Crisis

Are Financial Markets Stable? New Evidence from An Improved Test of Financial Market Stability and the U.S. Subprime Crisis Are Financial Markets Stable? New Evidence from An Improved Test of Financial Market Stability and the U.S. Subprime Crisis Sandy Suardi (La Trobe University) cial Studies Banking and Finance Conference

More information

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Expository note for the course MakØk3 Blok 2, 200/20 January 7, 20 This note shows in

More information

Determinants of Ownership Concentration and Tender O er Law in the Chilean Stock Market

Determinants of Ownership Concentration and Tender O er Law in the Chilean Stock Market Determinants of Ownership Concentration and Tender O er Law in the Chilean Stock Market Marco Morales, Superintendencia de Valores y Seguros, Chile June 27, 2008 1 Motivation Is legal protection to minority

More information

Revisiting the cost of children: theory and evidence from Ireland

Revisiting the cost of children: theory and evidence from Ireland : theory and evidence from Ireland Olivier Bargain (UCD) Olivier Bargain (UCD) () CPA - 3rd March 2009 1 / 28 Introduction Motivation Goal is to infer sharing of resources in households using economic

More information

Lecture Notes 1

Lecture Notes 1 4.45 Lecture Notes Guido Lorenzoni Fall 2009 A portfolio problem To set the stage, consider a simple nite horizon problem. A risk averse agent can invest in two assets: riskless asset (bond) pays gross

More information

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model Bianca De Paoli November 2008 1 Fiscal Policy in a New Keynesian Model 1.1 Positive analysis: the e ect of scal shocks How do scal shocks a ect in ation?

More information

Financial Wealth, Consumption Smoothing, and Income Shocks due to Job Loss

Financial Wealth, Consumption Smoothing, and Income Shocks due to Job Loss Financial Wealth, Consumption Smoothing, and Income Shocks due to Job Loss Hans G. Bloemen * and Elena G. F. Stancanelli ** Working Paper N o 2003-09 December 2003 *** * Free University Amsterdam, Department

More information

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1 Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Philippe Bacchetta Eric van Wincoop January 10, 007 1 Prepared for the May 007 issue of the American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings.

More information

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2) MakØk3, Fall 2010 (blok 2) Business cycles and monetary stabilization policies Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

More information

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Ozan Eksi TOBB University of Economics and Technology November 2 Abstract The standard new Keynesian

More information

Estimating Welfare in Insurance Markets using Variation in Prices

Estimating Welfare in Insurance Markets using Variation in Prices Estimating Welfare in Insurance Markets using Variation in Prices Liran Einav 1 Amy Finkelstein 2 Mark R. Cullen 3 1 Stanford and NBER 2 MIT and NBER 3 Yale School of Medicine November, 2008 inav, Finkelstein,

More information

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Sta Report November 2009 Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Fuel-Switching Capability

Fuel-Switching Capability Fuel-Switching Capability Alain Bousquet and Norbert Ladoux y University of Toulouse, IDEI and CEA June 3, 2003 Abstract Taking into account the link between energy demand and equipment choice, leads to

More information

Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation: Empirical Evidence for African and Asian Firms

Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation: Empirical Evidence for African and Asian Firms Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation: Empirical Evidence for African and Asian Firms Stephen R. Bond Nu eld College and Department of Economics, University of Oxford and Institute for Fiscal Studies Måns

More information

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from: Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ On the Implementation of Markov-Perfect Monetary Policy Michael Dotsey y and Andreas Hornstein

More information

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model Guido Ascari University of Pavia Nicola Branzoli University of Pavia October 27, 2006 Abstract This note shows that full price indexation

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Internet Appendix for Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

Internet Appendix for Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Internet Appendix for Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Christian Julliard London School of Economics Anisha Ghosh y Carnegie Mellon University March 6, 2012 Department of Finance and

More information

Value at risk models for Dutch bond portfolios

Value at risk models for Dutch bond portfolios Journal of Banking & Finance 24 (2000) 1131±1154 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Value at risk models for Dutch bond portfolios Peter J.G. Vlaar * Econometric Research and Special Studies Department,

More information

What Makes Family Members Live Apart or Together?: An Empirical Study with Japanese Panel Study of Consumers

What Makes Family Members Live Apart or Together?: An Empirical Study with Japanese Panel Study of Consumers The Kyoto Economic Review 73(2): 121 139 (December 2004) What Makes Family Members Live Apart or Together?: An Empirical Study with Japanese Panel Study of Consumers Young-sook Kim 1 1 Doctoral Program

More information

Effective Tax Rates and the User Cost of Capital when Interest Rates are Low

Effective Tax Rates and the User Cost of Capital when Interest Rates are Low Effective Tax Rates and the User Cost of Capital when Interest Rates are Low John Creedy and Norman Gemmell WORKING PAPER 02/2017 January 2017 Working Papers in Public Finance Chair in Public Finance Victoria

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Problem Set # Public Economics

Problem Set # Public Economics Problem Set #3 14.41 Public Economics DUE: October 29, 2010 1 Social Security DIscuss the validity of the following claims about Social Security. Determine whether each claim is True or False and present

More information

What should regulators do about merger policy?

What should regulators do about merger policy? Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 623±627 What should regulators do about merger policy? Anil K Kashyap * Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, IL 60637,

More information

Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers

Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers Elif Incekara y Department of Economics, Pennsylvania State University June 006 Abstract In this paper, we show that the consumer might be unresponsive

More information

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS 5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS We studied how individual consumers and rms behave in Part I of the book. In Part II of the book, we studied how individual economic agents make decisions when there are strategic

More information

Estimating the Incidences of the Recent Pension Reform in China: Evidence from 100,000 Manufacturers

Estimating the Incidences of the Recent Pension Reform in China: Evidence from 100,000 Manufacturers Estimating the Incidences of the Recent Pension Reform in China: Evidence from 100,000 Manufacturers Zhigang Li Mingqin Wu Feb 2010 Abstract An ongoing reform in China mandates employers to contribute

More information

Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements

Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements Mostafa Beshkar (University of New Hampshire) Eric Bond (Vanderbilt University) July 17, 2010 Prepared for the SITE Conference, July

More information

Working Paper Series The Cyclical Price of Labor When Wages Are Smoothed WP 10-13

Working Paper Series The Cyclical Price of Labor When Wages Are Smoothed WP 10-13 Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/economic_ research/working_papers/index.cfm The Cyclical Price of Labor When Wages Are Smoothed

More information

Consumption Taxes and Divisibility of Labor under Incomplete Markets

Consumption Taxes and Divisibility of Labor under Incomplete Markets Consumption Taxes and Divisibility of Labor under Incomplete Markets Tomoyuki Nakajima y and Shuhei Takahashi z February 15, 216 Abstract We analyze lump-sum transfers nanced through consumption taxes

More information

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model Zhiwei Xu (xuzhiwei@sjtu.edu.cn) Solow model (Solow, 1959) is the starting point of the most dynamic macroeconomic theories. It introduces dynamics and transitions into

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY Summer 2011 Examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours + 10 minutes reading time. This paper contains seven questions in three

More information

A Dynamic Model of Entrepreneurship with Borrowing Constraints: Theory and Evidence

A Dynamic Model of Entrepreneurship with Borrowing Constraints: Theory and Evidence A Dynamic Model of Entrepreneurship with Borrowing Constraints: Theory and Evidence Francisco J. Buera UCLA December 2008 Abstract Does wealth beget wealth and entrepreneurship, or is entrepreneurship

More information

The MM Theorems in the Presence of Bubbles

The MM Theorems in the Presence of Bubbles The MM Theorems in the Presence of Bubbles Stephen F. LeRoy University of California, Santa Barbara March 15, 2008 Abstract The Miller-Modigliani dividend irrelevance proposition states that changes in

More information

State Dependence in a Multinominal-State Labor Force Participation of Married Women in Japan 1

State Dependence in a Multinominal-State Labor Force Participation of Married Women in Japan 1 State Dependence in a Multinominal-State Labor Force Participation of Married Women in Japan 1 Kazuaki Okamura 2 Nizamul Islam 3 Abstract In this paper we analyze the multiniminal-state labor force participation

More information

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr.

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr. The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving James P. Dow, Jr. Department of Finance, Real Estate and Insurance California State University, Northridge

More information

PPP Strikes Out: The e ect of common factor shocks on the real exchange rate. Nelson Mark, University of Notre Dame and NBER

PPP Strikes Out: The e ect of common factor shocks on the real exchange rate. Nelson Mark, University of Notre Dame and NBER PPP Strikes Out: The e ect of common factor shocks on the real exchange rate Nelson Mark, University of Notre Dame and NBER and Donggyu Sul, University of Auckland Tufts University November 17, 2008 Background

More information

Family Status Transitions, Latent Health, and the Post- Retirement Evolution of Assets

Family Status Transitions, Latent Health, and the Post- Retirement Evolution of Assets Family Status Transitions, Latent Health, and the Post- Retirement Evolution of Assets by James Poterba MIT and NBER Steven Venti Dartmouth College and NBER David A. Wise Harvard University and NBER May

More information

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations J. Scott Davis y Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas February 202 Abstract This paper introduces a model where agents are unsure

More information

Risk Tolerance and Risk Exposure: Evidence from Panel Study. of Income Dynamics

Risk Tolerance and Risk Exposure: Evidence from Panel Study. of Income Dynamics Risk Tolerance and Risk Exposure: Evidence from Panel Study of Income Dynamics Economics 495 Project 3 (Revised) Professor Frank Stafford Yang Su 2012/3/9 For Honors Thesis Abstract In this paper, I examined

More information

Intertemporal Substitution in Labor Force Participation: Evidence from Policy Discontinuities

Intertemporal Substitution in Labor Force Participation: Evidence from Policy Discontinuities Intertemporal Substitution in Labor Force Participation: Evidence from Policy Discontinuities Dayanand Manoli UCLA & NBER Andrea Weber University of Mannheim August 25, 2010 Abstract This paper presents

More information

Family Financing and Aggregate Manufacturing. Productivity in Ghana

Family Financing and Aggregate Manufacturing. Productivity in Ghana Family Financing and Aggregate Manufacturing Productivity in Ghana Preliminary and incomplete. Please do not cite. Andrea Szabó and Gergely Ujhelyi Economics Department, University of Houston E-mail: aszabo2@uh.edu,

More information

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business Discussion Papers In Economics And Business Rational Consumers Kohei Kubota and Mototsugu Fukushige Discussion Paper 09-15-Rev. Graduate School of Economics and Osaka School of International Public Policy

More information

insignificant, but orthogonality restriction rejected for stock market prices There was no evidence of excess sensitivity

insignificant, but orthogonality restriction rejected for stock market prices There was no evidence of excess sensitivity Supplemental Table 1 Summary of literature findings Reference Data Experiment Findings Anticipated income changes Hall (1978) 1948 1977 U.S. macro series Used quadratic preferences Coefficient on lagged

More information

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations Online Appendix of Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality By ANDREAS FAGERENG, LUIGI GUISO, DAVIDE MALACRINO AND LUIGI PISTAFERRI This appendix complements the evidence

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? AEA Papers and Proceedings 2018, 108: 401 406 https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181116 In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? By Barbara A. Butrica and Nadia S. Karamcheva*

More information

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking (preliminary draft) Ying Syuan Li National Taiwan University Yiting Li National Taiwan University April 2009 Abstract We consider an economy where people have the needs

More information

What You Don t Know Can t Help You: Knowledge and Retirement Decision Making

What You Don t Know Can t Help You: Knowledge and Retirement Decision Making VERY PRELIMINARY PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE COMMENTS WELCOME What You Don t Know Can t Help You: Knowledge and Retirement Decision Making February 2003 Sewin Chan Wagner Graduate School of Public Service New

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus Summer 2009 examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2008/2009 syllabus Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours. This paper contains nine questions in three sections. Answer question one

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

HOW IMPORTANT IS DISCOUNT RATE HETEROGENEITY FOR WEALTH INEQUALITY?

HOW IMPORTANT IS DISCOUNT RATE HETEROGENEITY FOR WEALTH INEQUALITY? HOW IMPORTANT IS DISCOUNT RATE HETEROGENEITY FOR WEALTH INEQUALITY? LUTZ HENDRICKS CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 1604 CATEGORY 5: FISCAL POLICY, MACROECONOMICS AND GROWTH NOVEMBER 2005 An electronic version

More information

Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns

Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns Carlo Favero July 2012 Favero, Xiamen University () Demographics & Stock Market July 2012 1 / 37 Outline Return Predictability and the dynamic dividend growth

More information