Because of long lead times associated with product development and building capacity, a supplier must

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Because of long lead times associated with product development and building capacity, a supplier must"

Transcription

1 MANUFACTURING & SERVICE OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT Vol. 9, No. 1, Winter 2007, pp issn eissn informs doi /msom INFORMS Simple Relational Contracts to Motivate Capacity Investment: Price Only vs. Price and Quantity Terry A. Taylor Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, New York, New York and Tuck School of Business, Dartmouth College, Hanover, New Hampshire 03755, Erica L. Plambeck Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Stanford, California 94305, Because of long lead times associated with product development and building capacity, a supplier must initiate investment in capacity when the product development effort is ongoing. Because the product is ill defined at this point in time, the buyer is unable to commit to the future terms of trade through a courtenforceable contract. Instead, to provide incentives for capacity investment, the buyer informally promises future terms of trade. The prospect of future interaction creates an incentive for the buyer to pay the supplier as promised. We characterize optimal price-only and price-and-quantity promises and compare their performance. If the production cost is low and either the capacity cost is low or the discount factor is high, then the buyer should promise to purchase a specific quantity rather than simply promise to pay a per unit price; otherwise, the buyer should simply promise to pay a specified unit price. Key words: relational contracts; supply chain management; capacity investment; price-only contracts History: Received: January 28, 2006; accepted: August 20, Introduction Partners in a supply chain often rely on informal agreements in addition to contracts. In a typical scenario, a supplier must build capacity contemporaneously with the buyer s product-development effort because of the long lead times associated with each process. While the product development is ongoing, the product specification is evolving, which makes the buyer unable to commit to the future terms of trade through a court-enforceable contract (because the firms cannot specify the product to be delivered, they cannot specify the quantity to be delivered or the unit price). When the product development effort is finished and the product s specifications are completely determined, the firms can write a court-enforceable contract that specifies the terms of trade. However, if the supplier were to delay making capacity investments until this point, the resulting delay in getting the product to market would be unacceptable. Consequently, prior to initiating capacity investment, the supplier must rely on informal assurances from the buyer as to what unit price the buyer intends to pay and perhaps the quantity the buyer intends to purchase. The prospect of repeated interaction and the associated future value of a trusting, cooperative relationship provide an incentive for the buyer to pay the supplier as promised. In effect, the firms cannot adopt a formal contract before the supplier invests in capacity, so they adopt an informal agreement to create incentives for capacity investment. These dynamics arise frequently in innovative, high-tech industries such as electronics and semiconductor equipment manufacturing. For example, Toshiba informally promises the price per unit it will pay for electronic components while the design is still evolving, in order to give its supplier enough time to prepare for production. Because the design is changing significantly until large-scale production begins, Toshiba and its supplier do not commit to a formal contract until just before large-scale production begins (Sako 1992). In the semiconductor equipment industry, buyers informally commit to order quantities. Typically, in advance of placing a binding order, the buyer shares a demand forecast with its supplier. The forecast serves 94

2 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS 95 as an informal or soft order, intended to guide the supplier s production decisions (Cohen et al. 2003, Johnson 2003). In both the electronics and semiconductor equipment industries, the extent to which a supplier commits production resources on the basis of a buyer s informal promise to purchase depends on the extent to which the supplier views the promise as being credible. In the electronics example, long-term trading relationships generally ensure that Toshiba will adhere to its promised price, so its suppliers prepare for production on the basis of this promise. In the semiconductor equipment industry, if a buyer either purchases in line with the forecast or compensates her supplier on canceling soft orders, the supplier will tend to commit production resources on the basis of the buyer s forecast. However, to the extent that the buyer cancels soft orders without compensating the supplier, the supplier will tend not to commit production resources before receiving a firm order. This paper describes how a buyer should make promises to purchase, describing whether the buyer should merely make a unit-price promise or if she should also make a purchase-quantity promise. In deciding what type of promise to make and how large it should be, the buyer must balance two concerns. If the promise is stingy, the supplier may invest little in capacity, constraining the buyer s ability to satisfy market demand. If the promise is highly generous, the supplier may find it too good to be true and conclude that the buyer will not adhere to her promise. We show how to optimally balance these two concerns. To do so we analyze a stylized repeated game of new product introduction and capacity investment. For each new product, the supplier must invest in capacity when the product development effort is ongoing, well in advance of the selling season. At this point, because the product is ill defined, the production cost, retail price, and demand are uncertain, and the buyer is unable to commit to the future terms of trade through a court-enforceable contract and so instead promises to purchase. The buyer s promised terms are an important component of a relational contract, which describes the firms informal agreement about how they will behave. Roughly speaking, a relational contract specifies for every period the buyer s promised terms, the supplier s capacity investment, and whether the firms will adhere to the buyer s promised terms. The relational contract must be self-enforcing: in each period the parties adhere to their informal agreement because failure to do so will destroy trust and hence the value of future cooperation. Taylor and Plambeck (2003) characterize a selfenforcing relational contract that maximizes total expected discounted profit and allows the buyer to capture any fraction of the gain from cooperation. 1 This optimal relational contract is stationary (payment terms and capacity investment are the same in every period, on the equilibrium path). Nevertheless, even in the simplest setting, where the production cost is zero, this optimal relational contract can be very complex and thus difficult to implement. The buyer s promised order quantity and payment to the supplier are piecewise linear, increasing functions of her realized demand; in some cases, the order quantity function exhibits multiple discontinuities. Another complex feature is that the firms make a fixed transfer payment at the beginning of each period that is not contingent on any action by either firm. This feature could be criticized on the grounds that a manager might find it undesirable to make a payment with no strings attached. Consequently, to provide guidance to managers involved in procurement, it is important to examine relational contracts that are simple enough to be implemented and that do not have noncontingent transfer payments. In this paper, we consider two simple, plausible kinds of promises to purchase that a buyer may make. In a price-only (P) relational contract, the buyer promises to pay a specified price per unit but does not commit to purchase a specific quantity. In a price-andquantity (PQ) relational contract, the buyer promises to purchase a specified number of units for a specified price. We focus on these two forms of relational contracts for three reasons. First, in designing a contract or relational contract, firms trade off complexity 1 Taylor and Plambeck (2003) employ the same basic modeling framework as in this paper, although they allow for certain extensions (e.g., nonlinear capacity cost) that this paper does not, and this paper allows for extensions (e.g., uncertain retail price) that they do not. Both papers results apply to the core setting of fixed retail price and linear capacity cost; the differences in the extensions do not drive the differences in the results.

3 96 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS versus performance. The simplest form of a procurement agreement is simply to specify a unit price (P); arguably the next simplest form is to specify both a price and a quantity (PQ). Second, the supply chain contracting literature has extensively studied P contracts owing to their simplicity and has compared the formal contracts of these two forms. Third, the PQ relational contract is motivated by the use of soft orders, which are promises, but not legally binding commitments, to purchase a specified quantity. In designing a relational contract, we take the perspective of the buyer: We identify the buyer s promise to purchase that maximizes her expected discounted profit, subject to the constraints that the relational contract is self-enforcing and takes the simple P (or PQ) form. In addition to characterizing the buyer s optimal P and PQ relational contracts, we characterize when the buyer should offer which type of relational contract: If the production cost is low and either the capacity cost is low or the discount factor is high, then the buyer should promise to purchase a specified quantity (i.e., employ the PQ relational contract). Otherwise, the buyer should simply promise to pay a specified unit price. Finally, we characterize conditions under which these two simple promises perform nearly as well as the complex optimal relational contract Literature Review The supply chain contracting literature examines the impact of court-enforceable contracts on capacity and inventory decisions. If both price and capacity are contractible, then by properly specifying the terms of the contract, the buyer can maximize the total supply chain profit and appropriate it entirely (Cachon and Lariviere 2001). When capacity is not contractible, firms may employ contracts that only specify the unit price. A number of papers (e.g., Van Mieghem 1999, Cachon and Lariviere 2001, Lariviere and Porteus 2001, Özer and Wei 2006) consider P contracts in newsvendor settings. Cachon and Lariviere (2001) consider asymmetric demand forecast information and examine how a buyer can signal her private information through the contract she offers. Özer and Wei (2006) extend Cachon and Lariviere (2001) and further examine how a supplier can screen buyers with private demand forecast information by offering a menu of contracts. Corbett (2001) and Ha (2001) allow for asymmetric cost information. Van Mieghem (1999) observes that firms may be unable to commit to a per unit price before the supplier invests in capacity. Furthermore, even if firms can write P contracts, they may be better off not doing so and instead agreeing to negotiate after demand is observed. Other research considers formal contracts that expand the terms of trade beyond the unit price in newsvendor settings, examining returns (e.g., Pasternack 1985), quantity-flexibility contracts (e.g., Tsay 1999), revenue sharing (e.g., Cachon and Lariviere 2005), quantity discounts (e.g., Tomlin 2003), and channel rebates (e.g., Taylor 2002). Cachon (2003) and Chen (2003) provide comprehensive reviews of the supply chain contracting literature. In contrast to the aforementioned papers, which employ formal, court-enforceable contracts to coordinate capacity or inventory decisions, we focus on informal agreements that are sustained by repeated interaction (relational contracts). In this vein, Debo and Sun (2004) consider a repeated game in which the supplier sets the wholesale price and the buyer must order before realizing demand. Debo and Sun show that the firms can increase their per period expected profit by adopting an informal agreement in which the supplier offers a price that is lower than his optimal stage-game price, and the buyer responds by ordering a quantity that is larger than her myopically optimal order quantity. The informal agreement is sustained by the threat of punishing deviation by noncooperative behavior in all subsequent periods (i.e., the firms employ trigger strategies). Ren et al. (2005) consider a repeated game in which the buyer shares forecast information and then the supplier builds capacity. Their relational contract specifies the price per unit and punishment (noncooperation for a specified number of periods) when the buyer reports a high forecast but realized demand is low. When the discount factor is sufficiently large, the buyer reports the forecast truthfully, but the system is not perfectly coordinated because the punishment occurs with positive probability. Tunca and Zenios (2006) model the interplay between relational contracts and supply auctions, with multiple suppliers that differ in quality. For a review

4 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS 97 of the economics and sociology literature on relational contracts, see Plambeck and Taylor The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces a single-period game. Sections 3 and 4 characterize optimal P and PQ relational contracts. Section 5 characterizes when the buyer prefers each type of relational contract; 6 discusses the implications of relaxing our assumptions, and 7 provides concluding remarks. Proofs of all our analytic results are in Taylor and Plambeck (2007). 2. The Single-Period Game Consider a simple two-firm supply chain for an innovative product. The downstream firm, denoted the buyer, sells the product to a market in which demand is uncertain. The buyer (she) purchases the product from an upstream supplier (he). The supplier must invest in production capacity before the demand is revealed and before the firms can contract for production. This section describes the physical model of capacity investment and examines the case where the firms interact only once. Subsequent sections consider the implications of repeated interaction. Demand is a random variable with distribution function and density, where > 0 for 0 m, where m, and = 0 otherwise. Let r denote the retail price, c the per unit cost of capacity, and p the per unit cost of production. The firms have common information about the distribution of demand, and the salvage value of excess product or capacity is assumed to be negligible. The sequence of events is as follows: 1. The supplier invests in production capacity K and incurs cost ck (unobserved by the buyer). 2. The buyer observes demand (privately). 3. The firms contract on the wholesale price per unit w. The buyer orders, and the supplier produces and delivers. Because the product is ill defined when the supplier initiates his capacity investment (Step 1), at that time the firms are unable to write a court-enforceable procurement contract. However, close to the selling season (Step 3), the product is well defined and the firms can contractually specify the price and quantity. The assumption that the buyer does not observe the supplier s capacity is motivated by the observation that typically the buyer is unable to determine how many physical and human assets the supplier has dedicated to the buyer s product. The assumption that only the buyer observes the realized demand is motivated by the observation that a supplier often lacks visibility into the specifics of the buyer s end market (e.g., individual customers, orders); this assumption is inessential, as all the results extend when it is relaxed. Similarly, the assumption that both firms know the supplier s capacity cost c is inessential. However, the assumption that the production cost and retail price are commonly observed is essential for our analysis and results (see 6). The retail price assumption is reasonable when the buyer targets a price point and the supplier has a general understanding of the product s positioning in the end market. The assumption that both firms observe the production cost is reasonable if the bulk of the cost is from commodity material or labor inputs or if the buyer is otherwise able to become familiar with the production technology and associated costs. In 6, we describe how the results extend when the retail price, production cost, and realized capacity are stochastic, and when the supplier has private information about the cost of capacity. These generalizations are important because our focus is on innovative products, that is, products that are ill-defined at the time when the supplier initiates capacity investment. At this time, it is natural that the retail price, production cost, and effectiveness of a dollar investment in capacity would be uncertain. We postpone the extensions to 6 to convey the main insights in the simplest framework and make it clear that the relaxations do not drive the main results. We assume that in this single-period game, the firms split the ex post gain from trade r p min K according to the generalized Nash bargaining solution, with share 0 1 for the supplier. Specifically, the buyer contracts to pay w = r + 1 p per unit and purchases the efficient quantity q = min K. 2 The profit for the supplier (excluding the sunk cost of 2 Suppose that the supplier and buyer bargain noncooperatively by making alternating offers of the per unit price, as in Rubinstein (1982). Then in the unique subgame perfect equilibrium, by the theorem on page 106 of Rubinstein (1982), the price r + 1 p is immediately offered and accepted. The parameter 0 1 depends on which firm makes the first offer, the time between offers, and the discount factor. The trick in extending Rubinstein s

5 98 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS capacity) is r p min K, and the profit for the buyer is 1 r p min K. The economics literature on incomplete contracts and on relational contracts adopts this generalized Nash bargaining solution (e.g., Grossman and Hart 1986, Baker et al. 2002). The Nash bargaining solution is the unique outcome that satisfies a set of axiomatic properties, including Pareto optimality and independence of irrelevant alternatives (Nash 1950). Anticipating the per unit price r + 1 p, the supplier s expected profit when he builds K units of capacity is r p E min K ck (1) The supplier faces a newsvendor problem, and his optimal capacity is K 1 1 c/ r p +. The supplier s and buyer s expected profit are S = r p E min K ck B = 1 r p E min K In contrast, the expected profit of the total supply chain r p E min K ck is maximized at capacity K 1 1 c/ r p +. If the supplier captures all the gain from trade so that all system revenue accrues to him ( = 1), then he will build the first best level of capacity K. If the buyer captures a portion of the gain from trade < 1, then the supplier will build a level of capacity that is smaller than the first best K. This is a classic hold-up problem: The supplier invests too little because he will capture only a fraction of the return on investment. If the capacity cost is sufficiently high c r p, then the supplier s incentive to invest is eliminated, K = Optimal Price-Only Relational Contract Now suppose that the firms produce and sell a succession of distinct products, repeating the game theorem to this setting with private information is to recognize that the expected profit after contracting on per unit price w is r w E min K for the buyer and w p E min K for the supplier. The private information is embedded in the constant multiplier E min K and does not affect the subgame perfect equilibrium. described in 2 in periods t = 1 2 Because the product produced in each period is distinct, the supplier must make a new capacity investment in each period. (This does not necessarily mean that the supplier builds a new production facility every period; instead, the capacity could be thought of as reserved for the buyer s specific product.) The firms may have alternatives to working with one another. For example, at the beginning of each period, a supplier may instead contract to supply a different product to a different buyer. We denote the supplier s outside option single-period expected profit S. Let B denote the analogous quantity for the buyer. So that the outside options are viable, we assume that they generate at least the noncooperative equilibrium expected profit derived in 2: B B and S S. The boundary case B = B and S = S captures the situation in which the firms do not have viable outside options. To reflect that the potential value that can be created is greater inside rather than outside the supplier-buyer relationship, assume that the sum of the outside option profits is strictly less than the profit of the two-firm integrated system. Although for simplicity we suppose that the supplier is willing to participate if the relational contract gives him at least his per period outside option profit, all our results extend when the supplier insists on receiving a portion of the gain from cooperation (see 6). With repeated interaction, the firms can adopt an informal agreement about the terms of trade that will give the supplier a greater return on capacity investment than the noncooperative outcome of 2. Under a P relational contract, the buyer promises to pay the supplier w for each unit she buys. However, the buyer does not commit to purchase a specific quantity; rather, she is free to order the quantity that maximizes her profit. In maximizing expected profit, one can restrict attention to P relational contracts in which w p r, so that the buyer will procure the efficient quantity min K. (If w>r, the buyer would order zero, regardless of realized demand. If w<p, the supplier would produce zero regardless of the buyer s order.) In each period in which either firm refuses to transact, the firms pursue their outside options, which results in expected profit of B for the buyer and for the supplier in that period. In each period S

6 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS 99 in which both firms transact, the sequence of events is exactly as specified in 2, except the last step is replaced by the following: 3. If both firms adhere to the proposed terms, they codify price w per unit in a court-enforceable contract. The buyer orders and the supplier produces and delivers quantity min K. Otherwise, if one or both firms do not adhere, noncooperative bargaining occurs, as in 2: The supplier produces and delivers min K, and the buyer pays r + 1 p per unit. The firms are infinitely lived and risk neutral. At the end of each period their game terminates with probability, and the common discount factor is. The termination probability may be a measure of the stability of the firms, economic conditions, or the riskiness of the product market. The discount factor reflects the firms cost of capital and the length of time between successive products. Short (long) development and production lead times and frequent (infrequent) product introductions will tend to be associated with high (low) discount factors. The effective discount factor is = 1. We assume that both firms employ trigger strategies, as is standard in the economics literature on relational contracts (Baker et al. 2001, 2002; Levin 2003). A trigger strategy is to transact and to adhere to the promised payment w in every period until one firm refuses to do so, and then to refuse transact and refuse to adhere in all subsequent periods. A P relational contract specifying per unit price w is self-enforcing if the trigger strategies constitute a perfect public equilibrium (PPE). As defined in Fudenberg et al. (1994), a PPE is a profile of public strategies that, for each period t and public history at the beginning of period t, constitute a Nash equilibrium from that time onward. If the firms coordinate on a self-enforcing P relational contract, neither party will subsequently wish to deviate from it unilaterally. We say that a relational contract of a particular form is optimal if it is self-enforcing and no other selfenforcing relational contract of that form generates strictly greater expected profit for the buyer. An optimal P relational contract is characterized by max w (2) w p r subject to where K P w 1 1 c/ w p + (3) w p E min K P w ck P w S (4) w p E min K P w { w p E min K P w ck P w } r p E min K P w S (5) r w min K P w w 1 r p min K P w B w r w E min K P w for 0 m (6) denotes the buyer s expected profit per period when the per unit price is w. Constraint (3) has the supplier choosing his capacity optimally. To understand this, note that the supplier s expected profit when he builds K units of capacity is w p E min K ck the supplier faces a newsvendor problem, and the optimal capacity is K P w ; P is mnemonic for price only. Constraint (4) ensures that the supplier s expected single-period profit under the relational contract is greater than his outside option profit. The supplier could refuse to sign a contract employing the proposed unit price, in which case the firms would trade at the noncooperative price r+ 1 p in that period. Because the firms follow trigger strategies, refusal to adhere to the proposed price would result in expected profit of S for the supplier in all subsequent periods. Constraint (5) ensures that the supplier s expected profit when he adheres exceeds his profit when he reneges. After observing the demand, but without knowing the supplier s capacity choice, the buyer could refuse to sign a contract employing the proposed unit price. Constraint (6) ensures that the buyer s expected profit when she adheres exceeds her profit when she reneges. Our assumption that the firms follow trigger strategies is without loss of generality in maximizing expected profit, because the strongest equilibrium punishment for reneging on payment terms is refusal

7 100 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS to transact in all subsequent periods. If the firms anticipated that cooperation would resume after a finite number of periods of punishment, the effect on the contract design problem would be to increase the right-hand side of constraints (5) and (6) and thus decrease the optimal objective value. However, in the event that one firm did violate the relational contract and both firms subsequently refused to transact, the firms could increase their future profits by renegotiating their relational contract and resuming cooperation. This raises a question for experimental and empirical research: Is cooperation restored after a firm breaks a promise? If so, how quickly? In a laboratory experiment using a repeated trust game, Schweitzer et al. (2005) observed that when a subject is deceived by its partner (the partner promises to make a payment in return for cooperative action and breaks that promise), in subsequent periods the subject tends to distrust his partner and to behave noncooperatively. Even when the deceived subject receives a promise, an apology, and a series of cooperative actions from his partner, noncooperative behavior persists. In a similar vein, Fehr et al. (1997) and references therein provide extensive experimental evidence that people are frequently willing to forgo large amounts of money to punish unfair behavior. According to Helper (1991), U.S. auto manufacturers that violated relational contracts for capacity investment and cut the legs out from more than one supplier in the 1970s subsequently had great difficulty building trust and collaborative relationships with suppliers. This experimental and empirical evidence that breaking a promise causes significant and enduring harm provides support for our model formulation with trigger strategies. However, a more complex behavioral model may produce richer managerial insights. Atkins et al. (2006) propose an alternative to trigger strategies, in which the duration of punishment is proportional to the magnitude of deviation from the agreement. An introduction to the economics literature on renegotiation in repeated games is in Abreu and Pearce (1991). We now turn to characterizing an optimal P relational contract more precisely. We can without loss of generality restrict attention to P relational contracts in which the proposed price exceeds the noncooperative price: w r + 1 p (7) If (7) were violated, the supplier would build less than the noncooperative capacity K, which would push the total system expected profit below its level without cooperation B + S. The supplier s participation constraint (4) simplifies to a constraint that the promised price be sufficiently large: w w where w is the unique solution to w p E min K P w ck P w = S when S > S and w = r+ 1 p otherwise. Note w r + 1 p, where the inequality is strict if and only if S > S Because the promised price is greater than the noncooperative outcome price, the supplier s adherence constraint (5) is satisfied. The final constraint that remains is the buyer s adherence constraint (6), which can be rewritten as 1 1 w B w r 1 p min K P w for 0 m (8) The left-hand side of (8) is the present value of the gain from the buyer s ongoing cooperation, and the right-hand side is the buyer s one-period gain from reneging. The buyer s reneging temptation is most acute when demand is large; the buyer s maximal one-period gain from reneging is w r 1 p K P w (9) Thus, the P relational contract design problem can be rewritten as where max w w r w (10) subject to A w 0 (11) A w 1 1 w B w r 1 p K P w

8 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS 101 When the wholesale price is contractible, the smallest optimal price for the buyer is } w P c {w w = min arg max w w w r c is mnemonic for contractible. Note that if the buyer s expected profit when the wholesale price is contractible is less than her outside option w P c B (12) then P relational contracts are ineffective: the buyer cannot increase her profit by simply promising to pay a specified price per unit. Proposition 1 characterizes an optimal P relational contract. Define P min { w such that w>max r+ 1 p c+p w w and A w 0 } P min { A w P c 0} If (12) does not hold, then 0 < P P < 1. The last part of the proposition considers a mild technical restriction on the demand distribution / lim x x = 0 (13) x 0 which is satisfied by commonly used demand distributions (e.g., normal, lognormal, Weibull, gamma, beta, exponential, uniform, triangular, Pareto with finite mean). However, it may be violated by distributions with heavy tails (e.g., Pareto with infinite mean). Equation (13) holds if has an increasing generalized failure rate, infinite support, a finite second moment, and if lim x 0 x 1 x exists (see Lariviere 2006, Theorem 4). Proposition 1. If B + S > B + S and either 12 holds or < P, then no self-enforcing P relational contract exists. Otherwise, an optimal P relational contract has optimal unit price w P, which is increasing in and satisfies w P = r+ 1 p if < P or 12 holds; otherwise r + 1 p wc P if P P =wc P if P If 13 holds, then there exists c>0 such that if c c, then 12 holds. When the capacity cost is small (c c), the supplier s noncooperative capacity K is sufficiently large that commitment to pay any price higher than the noncooperative price will reduce the buyer s profit. Consequently, in this parameter region, P relational contracts are ineffective. For the remainder of this section, we will focus on the case c c r. Then, P relational contracts are effective only when the discount factor is sufficiently high. If is small, then the buyer s ongoing expected discounted profit from cooperation is small, so the promise of a high price is not credible, and consequently, the buyer must promise a low price. (Although both firms would prefer a higher price, the resulting reneging temptation for the buyer is too high for such a promise to be credible.) As the discount factor increases, promises of larger wholesale prices become credible and are optimal: w P is increasing in. Consequently, under the optimal P relational contract, the supplier s capacity K P w P and the buyer and supplier s expected profits per period, which we denote P B and P S, also increase with. Thus, buyers in industries marked by long development times between successive product generations, high capital costs, and/or low continuation probabilities (resulting from, for instance, uncertain technologies or a turbulent economic environment) should promise relatively low wholesale prices. If any of these factors should change favorably (e.g., the development time shrinks), the buyer should respond by promising a higher wholesale price. This will result in a higher capacity investment by the supplier and greater profits for both firms. Nonetheless, the buyer should always promise a wholesale price that is lower than the price she would offer if the price were contractible: w P wc P. Further, because wp <r, the supplier strictly underinvests in capacity, and total system expected profit is bounded away from the first best even as 1. As one would expect, as the supplier s outsideoption profit S increases, the promised unit price increases. In contrast, as the buyer s outside-option profit B increases, the promised price decreases. Perhaps surprisingly, both of these changes in bargaining positions reduce the buyer s profit under the relational contract P B. Having a stronger outside option constrains the buyer s credible promises and reduces

9 102 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS her profit. When S and/or B are sufficiently large, P relational contracts are not effective. 4. Optimal Price-and-Quantity Relational Contract When demand in a period is low, the supplier suffers under an informal agreement that only specifies a unit price, because he is unable to recoup the costs of his capacity investment. A buyer s informal commitment to purchase a specified quantity protects the supplier from this fate. Under a PQ relational contract, the buyer promises to purchase Q units and to pay the supplier wq. After capacity has been built but prior to production, the firms contractually specify the terms of trade: If both firms adhere to the promised terms, they codify those terms in a formal contract. The supplier is only able to adhere to the terms if he has sufficient capacity K Q. If the supplier has built more than Q units of capacity and demand exceeds Q, then the firms will split the additional gains from trade according to the noncooperative solution (i.e., the buyer would acquire the additional units at per unit price r + 1 p). Thus, a supplier that builds enough capacity to meet the buyer s promised order will build capacity max K Q. An optimal PQ relational contract is characterized by max E[ r min Q wq + 1 r p w Q min K Q +] (14) subject to w p Q + r p E min K Q + c max K Q S (15) 1 1{ w p Q + r p E min K Q + c max K Q } r p E min K ck S for K 0 Q (16) w p Q + 1 1{ w p Q + r p E min K Q + c max K Q } r p E min Q S (17) r min Q wq+ 1 1 {remin Q wq+ 1 r p E min K Q + } 1 r p min Q B for 0 m (18) Constraint (15) ensures that the supplier s expected single-period profit under the relational contract is greater than his outside option profit. Constraint (16) ensures that the supplier builds enough capacity to meet the buyer s promised purchase quantity. If the supplier failed to do so, the firms would in that period split the gains from trade according to the noncooperative outcome price r+ 1 p. Because the firms follow trigger strategies, failure to build adequate capacity results in expected profit of S for the supplier in all subsequent periods, which explains the right-hand side of (16). The supplier could renege by refusing to sign a contract to supply Q units in return for payment wq. If the supplier reneges, the firms split the gains from trade according to the noncooperative solution in that period, and the supplier receives expected profit of S in all subsequent periods. Constraint (17) ensures that the supplier s expected profit when he adheres exceeds his profit when he reneges. After observing demand, the buyer could renege by refusing to sign a contract to buy Q units for the per unit price of w and insisting instead on purchasing at the noncooperative outcome price. Constraint (18) ensures that the buyers s expected profit when she adheres exceeds her profit when she reneges. The buyer s one-period gain from reneging when she observes demand is wq r + 1 p min Q The buyer s reneging temptation is most acute when demand is small (the buyer s maximal one-period gain from reneging is wq); this is the reverse of the case under the P relational contract. It is instructive to compare the buyer s maximal reneging temptation under a PQ and P relational contract. Consider an informal agreement of each type where the capacity investment and unit price are the same. Because the PQ relational contract involves an additional promise (quantity in addition to price), the buyer s maximal reneging temptation is higher under the PQ relational contract.

10 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS 103 By following through on the commitment to purchase Q units, the buyer is able to verify that the supplier has Q units of capacity. However, this monitoring is costly to the total supply chain in that it requires the supplier to produce Q even when end demand <Q. If the production cost is very high, such monitoring will be very costly, rendering PQ relational contracts ineffective. We focus on the case where the production cost is sufficiently small that PQ relational contracts are of potential value. To make this notion precise, it is helpful to specify the maximum expected profit that a buyer could receive under a PQ relational contract. If the price and quantity were contractible, the contract design problem would be (14) (15): The constraints ensuring that the firms adhere, (16) (18), would be dropped. A solution has purchase commitment Q c = 1 1 c+p /r + and per unit payment satisfying wc PQ =c+p+ S /Q c ; c is mnemonic for contractible. Assume that the maximum profit that the buyer could receive under a PQ relational contract is larger than her outside option: r mine Q c c+p Q c S > B (19) this will hold when p, B, and S are sufficiently small. Any solution to problem (14) (18) with Q<K can be replicated with Q = K and an appropriately chosen w; so without loss of generality we can restrict attention to Q K. Then (14) (18) simplifies to max w Q E rmin Q wq (20) subject to w c p Q S (21) 1 1 w c p Q S r p Emin Q w p Q (22) 1 1 remin Q wq B wq (23) Because the relational contract must leave the supplier better off than he was under the noncooperative outcome, the promised price is sufficiently high that the supplier will never find it attractive to renege (the right-hand side of (22) is negative). In other words, the supplier s participation constraint (21) implies the supplier s adherence constraint (22). To characterize the optimal PQ relational contract, we first characterize the optimal promised unit price for any given quantity, and then turn to the optimal promised quantity. If it is optimal to promise a strictly positive quantity, then because as w decreases, the objective function increases, constraint (21) tightens, and constraint (23) loosens, an optimal PQ relational contract w PQ Q PQ satisfies w PQ =c+p+ S /Q PQ (24) Thus, under an optimal PQ relational contract, the supplier s expected per period profit is S. In identifying a PQ relational contract that is self-enforcing, the only constraint of (21) (23) that remains is the buyer s adherence constraint (23), which simplifies to Q 0, where Q = 1 1{ } remin Q c+p Q B S c+p Q S Therefore, the PQ relational contract design problem can be written as Let max remin Q c+p Q S (25) Q subject to Q 0 (26) PQ min { Q such that remin Q c+p Q B S >0 and Q 0 } PQ min Q c 0 Q max Q Q 0 Note that 0< PQ < PQ <1. Recall that K>0 if and only if c< r p. Proposition 2. If B + S > B + S and/or c< r p and if < PQ, then no self-enforcing PQ relational contract exists. Otherwise, an optimal PQ relational contract w PQ Q PQ has 0 0 if < PQ w PQ Q PQ = c+p+ S /Q Q if PQ PQ c+p+ S /Q c Q c if PQ

11 104 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS If the discount factor is small, then the buyer cannot increase her profit by promising to purchase a specified quantity. However, for larger discount factors, the buyer benefits by promising to purchase a positive quantity. Because Q is increasing in, both the optimal quantity commitment Q PQ and the promised payment wq PQ are increasing in. Thus, under the optimal PQ relational contract, as the discount factor increases, the buyer promises to buy a larger quantity and pay a larger price. When is sufficient large and the production cost is zero, p =0, the promised quantity commitment coincides with the first best capacity investment Q PQ = K and the first best is achieved. In contrast, when p>0, Q PQ < K and the first best is not achieved. Recall that under the optimal P relational contract, the promised per unit price w P is increasing in. In contrast, the buyer s promised price per unit in the optimal PQ relational contract, w PQ, is decreasing in. Nonetheless, the contracts are similar in that as the discount factor increases, under both contracts, the supplier s capacity and the buyer s expected per period profit increase. The next section compares the performance of the simple P and PQ relational contracts with one another and with the optimal relational contract derived in Taylor and Plambeck (2003). 5. Performance Evaluation of Simple Relational Contracts When price and quantity are noncontractible, the buyer can increase her profit by making promises about how she will purchase. An important decision facing any buyer is what kind of promise to make to the supplier. Theorem 1 provides clear conditions under which the buyer should make only a unit-price promise and conditions under which the buyer should make a quantity promise in addition to a unit-price promise. We extend our definition of P B so that it denotes the buyer s expected profit per period under the optimal P relational contract, if such a contract exists, and denotes the buyer s outside-option profit, otherwise. Let PQ denote the analogous quantity under the optimal PQ relational contract. Figure 1 Capacity cost c Buyer s Preferred Relational Contract when Production Cost Is Small High Low Price only Price and quantity Low Discount factor δ Theorem 1. (a) If c c, then P B PQ B Price and quantity Price and quantity High where the inequality is strict if and only if PQ. (b) If p is sufficiently small, then there exists 0 1 such that if >, then P B < PQ B (c) There exists 0 1 such that if <, then P B PQ B where the inequality is strict if B = B, S = S, c> r p and P. If the capacity cost is low, then the buyer should make a unit-price and quantity promise, that is, use a PQ relational contract (part (a)). Similarly, if the discount factor is high and the unit production cost is low, then the buyer should use a PQ relational contract (part (b)). In contrast, if the capacity cost is high and the discount factor is low, then the buyer should not promise to purchase a specified quantity and instead only commit to paying a specified price per unit, that is, use a P relational contract (part (c)). 3 Similarly, if the production cost is sufficiently high that (19) is violated, then the buyer should use a P relational contract. Figure 1 depicts the buyer s weakly preferred relational contract when the production cost is small. To see the intuition, first consider the case where the capacity cost is low. As discussed above, when the capacity cost is low, the P relational contract fails to 3 Although this result is shown only for the case where each firm s outside-option profit is equal to its noncooperative outcome profit, the result is robust to this assumption, provided that the deviations from the noncooperative profits are not too large.

12 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS 105 increase the buyer s profit because paying a price that is higher than the noncooperative price reduces the buyer s profit. In contrast, a low capacity cost does not hamper the effectiveness of a PQ relational contract in the same way. By properly tying the promised payment to a specified quantity, the buyer increases the supplier s capacity investment and the buyer s expected profit. If the discount factor is high and the production cost is low, then the buyer should use a PQ relational contract. Observe that as 1, the PQ contract design problem essentially reduces to the contract design problem where the price and quantity are contractible (20) (21). To see the intuition for why, in this context, low production costs favor PQ relational contracts, consider the special case where the production cost is zero. If the price and quantity are contractible, the buyer can, by formally committing to purchase K units for c K + S, capture the profit of the integrated system, less the supplier s outside option profit, S. In contrast, if the buyer formally commits only to a unit price, the buyer s profit is strictly smaller (Cachon and Lariviere 2001). Thus, when is large, the buyer is better off promising to purchase a specified quantity. The intuition continues to apply when the cost of production is positive but small. In this case, although the PQ relational contract requires wasteful production at times, this cost is relatively small. In contrast, if the production cost is sufficiently high that (19) is violated, then the costs of monitoring the supplier s capacity are too high for a PQ relational contract to be effective; consequently, the buyer should instead use a P relational contract. If the cost of capacity is high and the discount factor is low, then the buyer should use a P relational contract. When the capacity cost is high, a P relational contract is effective for the buyer because it is optimal for the buyer to promise to pay a unit price that is higher than the noncooperative price. Although PQ relational contracts are effective for the buyer when the discount factor is high, they are substantially less effective when the discount factor is low. By committing the buyer to purchase a specified quantity, a PQ contract entails an additional promise that is not in the P contract. Because a buyer promises more under a PQ contract, she has more to gain by reneging. Consequently, a P relational contract, with its lower reneging temptation, is superior when the discount factor is low. The insights from Theorem 1 are best illustrated and extended by a numerical example. Figure 2 compares the buyer s profit under the optimal P and PQ relational contracts. The panels depict the regions in which the buyer strictly prefers either the P or PQ relational contract. In the black region, the buyer cannot increase her profit from the noncooperative outcome through either relational contract. In all panels parameters are: B = B, S = S, r =10, =0 5, and is a Normal random variable with mean 5 and standard deviation s, truncated such that its probability mass is distributed over 0. The top panels of Figure 2 show the buyer s preferred relational contract as a function of the capacity cost and discount factor; in both panels s =3; the production cost is p =0 inthe left panel and p =3 in the right panel. Consistent with Propositions 1 and 2, for any fixed capacity cost, the relational contracts fail to improve over the noncooperative outcome if the discount factor is sufficiently small. This is the case either when capacity is expensive, in which case it is difficult to provide credible incentives for the supplier to invest in capacity, or when capacity is cheap, in which case the gain from cooperation is small. Consistent with Theorem 1, the top left panel illustrates that if the capacity cost is low or the discount factor is high, then the buyer (weakly) prefers the PQ relational contract; otherwise, the buyer (weakly) prefers the P relational contract. Comparing the top right panel with the top left panel shows that when the production cost increases, P and PQ relational contracts are effective for a smaller range of parameters, and PQ relational contracts become comparatively less attractive. The bottom panels in Figure 2 show the buyer s preferred relational contract as a function of the standard deviation of demand s and the discount factor ; in both panels p =0; the capacity cost is c =5 5 inthe left panel and c =4 5 in the right panel. Again, consistent with Theorem 1, the panels illustrate that if the discount factor is high, the buyer prefers the PQ relational contract.

13 106 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 9(1), pp , 2007 INFORMS Figure 2 Buyer s Preferred Relational Contract Capacity cost c Price only Price and quantity Capacity cost c Price only Price and qty Discount factor δ Discount factor δ Standard deviation s Price only Price and quantity Discount factor δ Standard deviation s Price only Price and quantity Discount factor δ Notes. The regions marked price only and price and quantity indicate that the buyer s profit under the optimal relational contract of the specified form strictly exceeds the profit under the optimal relational contract of the other form. In the black region the buyer cannot increase her profit from the noncooperative outcome through either relational contract. The impact of demand uncertainty on the relative attractiveness of the P and PQ relational contracts depends crucially on the firms profits outside the relationship B S, and hence on the cost of capacity. When the capacity cost is high (c> r p ), the firms profits outside of the relationship are zero, B = S =0, and are unaffected by the standard deviation of demand. Therefore, in the high-capacity-cost case (bottom left panel), the impact of demand uncertainty is relatively easy to understand. At moderate discount factors, increasing the standard deviation makes the P relational contract more attractive than the PQ relational contract. As demand uncertainty increases, the buyer s expected discounted profit under a relational contract decreases, which limits how much the buyer can credibly promise. Thus, it becomes attractive to drop the additional purchase-quantity promise and instead only promise a unit price. This result may be reversed in the low-capacitycost case (c< r p, as shown in the bottom right panel. Here, at moderate discount factors, increasing the standard deviation makes the PQ relational contract more attractive than the P relational contract. The key to the reversal in results is that when the capacity cost is low, the firms profits outside of the relationship B, S are positive and are decreasing in the demand uncertainty. As demand uncertainty increases, it becomes less attractive for the firms to renege, because they will do poorly outside of the cooperative relationship. Thus, making the additional purchase-quantity promise is credible and attractive. Having compared the optimal P and PQ relational contracts in terms of performance, we briefly comment on how they compare in terms of unit prices and capacities. It is intuitive that the optimal unit price would be higher in the P relational contract w P w PQ, because the supplier needs to be compensated for bearing the cost of the imbalance between capacity and demand. It is straightforward to establish this analytically for the case when the supplier lacks a viable outside option S = S, and in an extensive numerical study with S > S we never observed a counterexample. In contrast, the optimal capacity may be higher under the P or PQ relational contract (sufficient conditions for each can be established as a corollary to Theorem 1). Because, as demonstrated in Taylor and Plambeck (2003), the optimal relational contract may be rather complex, we have focused on simple relational contracts that are easy to describe and implement. This

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Online Appendix for Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Giacomo Rodano Bank of Italy Nicolas Serrano-Velarde Bocconi University December 23, 2014 Emanuele Tarantino University of Mannheim 1 1 Reorganization,

More information

Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information. Appendix

Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information. Appendix Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information Ilan Lobel Appendix Wenqiang iao {ilobel, wxiao}@stern.nyu.edu Stern School of Business, New York University Appendix A: Proofs Proof

More information

Relational Incentive Contracts

Relational Incentive Contracts Relational Incentive Contracts Jonathan Levin May 2006 These notes consider Levin s (2003) paper on relational incentive contracts, which studies how self-enforcing contracts can provide incentives in

More information

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 287 March 2001 Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Harold L. Cole University of California, Los Angeles and Federal Reserve Bank

More information

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts 6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts Asu Ozdaglar MIT February 9, 2010 1 Introduction Outline Review Examples of Pure Strategy Nash Equilibria

More information

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi 10.1287/mnsc.1110.1334ec e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM informs 2011 INFORMS Electronic Companion Trust in Forecast Information Sharing by Özalp Özer, Yanchong Zheng,

More information

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore*

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore* Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts by Oliver Hart and John Moore* Since Ronald Coase s famous 1937 article (Coase (1937)), economists have grappled with the question of what characterizes

More information

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Harold L. Cole and Narayana Kocherlakota Working Paper 604 September 2000 Cole: U.C.L.A. and Federal Reserve

More information

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 5: Repeated Games

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 5: Repeated Games Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 5: Repeated Games Haifeng Huang University of California, Merced Repeated games Repeated games: given a simultaneous-move game G, a repeated game of G is an extensive

More information

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games Game Theory Wolfgang Frimmel Repeated Games 1 / 41 Recap: SPNE The solution concept for dynamic games with complete information is the subgame perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE) Selten (1965): A strategy

More information

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec pp. ec1 ec23

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec pp. ec1 ec23 MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi 101287/mnsc10800894ec pp ec1 ec23 e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM informs 2008 INFORMS Electronic Companion Strategic Inventories in Vertical Contracts by Krishnan

More information

January 26,

January 26, January 26, 2015 Exercise 9 7.c.1, 7.d.1, 7.d.2, 8.b.1, 8.b.2, 8.b.3, 8.b.4,8.b.5, 8.d.1, 8.d.2 Example 10 There are two divisions of a firm (1 and 2) that would benefit from a research project conducted

More information

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Christopher Phelan Working Paper 676 December 2009 Phelan: University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Bargaining + Theory of the Firm 1 Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics December 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Bargaining + Theory of the Firm 1 Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics December 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Bargaining + Theory of the Firm 1 Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics December 2016 1 Axiomatic bargaining theory Before noncooperative bargaining theory, there was

More information

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment Suehyun Kwon CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 6280 CATEGORY 12: EMPIRICAL AND THEORETICAL METHODS DECEMBER 2016 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded

More information

February 23, An Application in Industrial Organization

February 23, An Application in Industrial Organization An Application in Industrial Organization February 23, 2015 One form of collusive behavior among firms is to restrict output in order to keep the price of the product high. This is a goal of the OPEC oil

More information

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A.

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. THE INVISIBLE HAND OF PIRACY: AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE INFORMATION-GOODS SUPPLY CHAIN Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. {antino@iu.edu}

More information

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE Answers to Problem Set 2 [1] (a) This is standard (we have even done it in class). The one-shot Cournot outputs can be computed to be A/3, while the payoff to each firm can

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Chapter 5 Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Until now we implicitly adopted a view that a Nash equilibrium is a desirable outcome of a strategic game. In this chapter we consider two alternative

More information

CONTRACT THEORY. Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

CONTRACT THEORY. Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England r CONTRACT THEORY Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England Preface xv 1 Introduction 1 1.1 Optimal Employment Contracts without Uncertainty, Hidden

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Leonardo Felli 7 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Contract Theory has become only recently a subfield of Economics. As the name suggest the main object of the analysis is a contract. Therefore

More information

Competition among Risk-Averse Newsvendors

Competition among Risk-Averse Newsvendors Competition among Risk-Averse Newsvendors Philipp Afèche Nima Sanajian Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto February 2013 We study in the classic newsvendor framework inventory competition

More information

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games CPSC 532l Lecture 10 Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games CPSC 532l Lecture 10, Slide 1 Lecture Overview 1 Recap 2 Stochastic Games 3 Bayesian Games 4 Analyzing Bayesian

More information

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions. Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions. Ilan Kremer and Andrzej Skrzypacz March 21, 2002 1 Introduction In many papers considering the sale of many objects in a sequence of auctions the seller

More information

,,, be any other strategy for selling items. It yields no more revenue than, based on the

,,, be any other strategy for selling items. It yields no more revenue than, based on the ONLINE SUPPLEMENT Appendix 1: Proofs for all Propositions and Corollaries Proof of Proposition 1 Proposition 1: For all 1,2,,, if, is a non-increasing function with respect to (henceforth referred to as

More information

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games Economics Letters 6 (999) 9 6 A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games Michael R. Baye *, John Morgan a, b a Indiana University, Kelley School of Business, 309 East Tenth St., Bloomington, IN 4740-70,

More information

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty Chifeng Dai Department of Economics Southern Illinois University Carbondale, IL 62901, USA August 2014 Abstract We study optimal

More information

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Ahmer Tarar Department of Political Science Texas A&M University 4348 TAMU College Station, TX 77843-4348 email: ahmertarar@pols.tamu.edu

More information

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly Chapter 13 Application: Implicit Cartels This chapter discusses many important subgame-perfect equilibrium strategies in optimal cartel, using the linear Cournot oligopoly as the stage game. For game theory

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring.

Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring. Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring. Olivier Compte First Version: June 2001 This Version: November 2003 Abstract In principal-agent relationships, a termination threat is often thought

More information

Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital. Prabal Roy Chowdhury

Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital. Prabal Roy Chowdhury Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital Prabal Roy Chowdhury Introduction: The focus of this paper is dynamic aspects of micro-lending, namely sequential lending

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Answer Key: Problem Set 4 Answer Key: Problem Set 4 Econ 409 018 Fall A reminder: An equilibrium is characterized by a set of strategies. As emphasized in the class, a strategy is a complete contingency plan (for every hypothetical

More information

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation Reputations arise in situations where there is an element of repetition, and also where coordination between players is possible. One definition of leadership is that

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions 1. (45 points) Consider the following normal form game played by Bruce and Sheila: L Sheila R T 1, 0 3, 3 Bruce M 1, x 0, 0 B 0, 0 4, 1 (a) Suppose

More information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information - preliminary and incomplete, please do not cite - Working Paper R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information Andreas Frick Heidrun C. Hoppe-Wewetzer Georgios Katsenos June 28, 2016 Abstract

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

Alternating-Offer Games with Final-Offer Arbitration

Alternating-Offer Games with Final-Offer Arbitration Alternating-Offer Games with Final-Offer Arbitration Kang Rong School of Economics, Shanghai University of Finance and Economic (SHUFE) August, 202 Abstract I analyze an alternating-offer model that integrates

More information

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions? March 3, 215 Steven A. Matthews, A Technical Primer on Auction Theory I: Independent Private Values, Northwestern University CMSEMS Discussion Paper No. 196, May, 1995. This paper is posted on the course

More information

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion?

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion? Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion? Patrick Rey and Michael D. Whinston 1 Introduction In a recent paper, Marx and Shaffer (2007) study a model of vertical contracting between a manufacturer and two

More information

Economics and Computation

Economics and Computation Economics and Computation ECON 425/563 and CPSC 455/555 Professor Dirk Bergemann and Professor Joan Feigenbaum Reputation Systems In case of any questions and/or remarks on these lecture notes, please

More information

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default 0.287/MSOM.070.099ec Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default Robert Swinney Serguei Netessine The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, 904

More information

Game Theory Fall 2003

Game Theory Fall 2003 Game Theory Fall 2003 Problem Set 5 [1] Consider an infinitely repeated game with a finite number of actions for each player and a common discount factor δ. Prove that if δ is close enough to zero then

More information

Infinitely Repeated Games

Infinitely Repeated Games February 10 Infinitely Repeated Games Recall the following theorem Theorem 72 If a game has a unique Nash equilibrium, then its finite repetition has a unique SPNE. Our intuition, however, is that long-term

More information

S atisfactory reliability and cost performance

S atisfactory reliability and cost performance Grid Reliability Spare Transformers and More Frequent Replacement Increase Reliability, Decrease Cost Charles D. Feinstein and Peter A. Morris S atisfactory reliability and cost performance of transmission

More information

Bank Leverage and Social Welfare

Bank Leverage and Social Welfare Bank Leverage and Social Welfare By LAWRENCE CHRISTIANO AND DAISUKE IKEDA We describe a general equilibrium model in which there is a particular agency problem in banks. The agency problem arises because

More information

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers WP-2013-015 Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers Amit Kumar Maurya and Shubhro Sarkar Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai August 2013 http://www.igidr.ac.in/pdf/publication/wp-2013-015.pdf

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Internet Appendix for Financial Contracting and Organizational Form: Evidence from the Regulation of Trade Credit

Internet Appendix for Financial Contracting and Organizational Form: Evidence from the Regulation of Trade Credit Internet Appendix for Financial Contracting and Organizational Form: Evidence from the Regulation of Trade Credit This Internet Appendix containes information and results referred to but not included in

More information

Manufacturer s control of retail price

Manufacturer s control of retail price Page of 0 0 Submitted to manuscript Please, provide the mansucript number! Manufacturer s control of retail price Ilia Tsetlin, Nils Rudi, V. Padmanabhan INSEAD, Ayer Rajah Avenue, Singapore {ilia.tsetlin,

More information

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items Nir Shabbat - 05305311 December 5, 2012 Introduction The paper I read is called Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items by Sergiu Hart

More information

This short article examines the

This short article examines the WEIDONG TIAN is a professor of finance and distinguished professor in risk management and insurance the University of North Carolina at Charlotte in Charlotte, NC. wtian1@uncc.edu Contingent Capital as

More information

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM Course content Why do firms exist? And why do some firms cease to exist? How are firms financed? How are firms managed? These questions are analysed by using various models

More information

Game Theory Fall 2006

Game Theory Fall 2006 Game Theory Fall 2006 Answers to Problem Set 3 [1a] Omitted. [1b] Let a k be a sequence of paths that converge in the product topology to a; that is, a k (t) a(t) for each date t, as k. Let M be the maximum

More information

DISRUPTION MANAGEMENT FOR SUPPLY CHAIN COORDINATION WITH EXPONENTIAL DEMAND FUNCTION

DISRUPTION MANAGEMENT FOR SUPPLY CHAIN COORDINATION WITH EXPONENTIAL DEMAND FUNCTION Acta Mathematica Scientia 2006,26B(4):655 669 www.wipm.ac.cn/publish/ ISRUPTION MANAGEMENT FOR SUPPLY CHAIN COORINATION WITH EXPONENTIAL EMAN FUNCTION Huang Chongchao ( ) School of Mathematics and Statistics,

More information

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems Microeconomics II CIDE, MsC Economics List of Problems 1. There are three people, Amy (A), Bart (B) and Chris (C): A and B have hats. These three people are arranged in a room so that B can see everything

More information

Economics 209A Theory and Application of Non-Cooperative Games (Fall 2013) Repeated games OR 8 and 9, and FT 5

Economics 209A Theory and Application of Non-Cooperative Games (Fall 2013) Repeated games OR 8 and 9, and FT 5 Economics 209A Theory and Application of Non-Cooperative Games (Fall 2013) Repeated games OR 8 and 9, and FT 5 The basic idea prisoner s dilemma The prisoner s dilemma game with one-shot payoffs 2 2 0

More information

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome.

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome. AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED Alex Gershkov and Flavio Toxvaerd November 2004. Preliminary, comments welcome. Abstract. This paper revisits recent empirical research on buyer credulity

More information

Contracting with suppliers prone to default is an increasingly common problem in some industries, particularly

Contracting with suppliers prone to default is an increasingly common problem in some industries, particularly MANUFACTURING & SERVICE OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT Vol. 11, No. 1, Winter 2009, pp. 109 127 issn 1523-4614 eissn 1526-5498 09 1101 0109 informs doi 10.1287/msom.1070.0199 2009 INFORMS Long-Term Contracts Under

More information

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments Kentaro Tomoeda October 31, 215 Abstract This article analyzes the implementability of efficient investments for two commonly used mechanisms in single-item

More information

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization 12 December 2006. 0.1 (p. 26), 0.2 (p. 41), 1.2 (p. 67) and 1.3 (p.68) 0.1** (p. 26) In the text, it is assumed

More information

BARGAINING AND REPUTATION IN SEARCH MARKETS

BARGAINING AND REPUTATION IN SEARCH MARKETS BARGAINING AND REPUTATION IN SEARCH MARKETS ALP E. ATAKAN AND MEHMET EKMEKCI Abstract. In a two-sided search market agents are paired to bargain over a unit surplus. The matching market serves as an endogenous

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging

Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging René Caldentey Martin Haugh Stern School of Business NYU Integrated Risk Management in Operations and Global Supply Chain Management: Risk, Contracts and Insurance

More information

Repeated Games. September 3, Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality. Finitely Repeated Games. Infinitely Repeated Games

Repeated Games. September 3, Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality. Finitely Repeated Games. Infinitely Repeated Games Repeated Games Frédéric KOESSLER September 3, 2007 1/ Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality Finitely Repeated Games Infinitely Repeated Games Automaton Representation of Strategies The One-Shot

More information

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence A The infinite horizon model This section defines the equilibrium of the infinity horizon model described in Section III of the paper and characterizes

More information

Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game

Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game Parkash Chander * and Myrna Wooders May 1, 2011 Abstract We propose a new concept of core for games in extensive form and label it the γ-core of an extensive

More information

Contracting with externalities and outside options

Contracting with externalities and outside options Journal of Economic Theory ( ) www.elsevier.com/locate/jet Contracting with externalities and outside options Francis Bloch a,, Armando Gomes b a Université de la Méditerranée and GREQAM,2 rue de la Charité,

More information

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Marc Ivaldi Vicente Lagos Preliminary version, please do not quote without permission Abstract The Coordinate Price Pressure

More information

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Evaluating Strategic Forecasters Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Motivation Forecasters are sought after in a variety of

More information

Price Discrimination As Portfolio Diversification. Abstract

Price Discrimination As Portfolio Diversification. Abstract Price Discrimination As Portfolio Diversification Parikshit Ghosh Indian Statistical Institute Abstract A seller seeking to sell an indivisible object can post (possibly different) prices to each of n

More information

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017 G5212: Game Theory Mark Dean Spring 2017 Bargaining We will now apply the concept of SPNE to bargaining A bit of background Bargaining is hugely interesting but complicated to model It turns out that the

More information

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma Recap Last class (September 20, 2016) Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma Today (October 13, 2016) Finitely

More information

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Journal of Economics and Finance Volume 24 Number 1 Spring 2000 Pages 56-63 Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Veronika Grimm and Ulrich Schmidt* Abstract This paper considers the classical independent

More information

A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities

A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities Ali CHEAITOU Euromed Management Marseille, 13288, France Christian VAN DELFT HEC School of Management, Paris (GREGHEC) Jouys-en-Josas,

More information

STRATEGIC VERTICAL CONTRACTING WITH ENDOGENOUS NUMBER OF DOWNSTREAM DIVISIONS

STRATEGIC VERTICAL CONTRACTING WITH ENDOGENOUS NUMBER OF DOWNSTREAM DIVISIONS STRATEGIC VERTICAL CONTRACTING WITH ENDOGENOUS NUMBER OF DOWNSTREAM DIVISIONS Kamal Saggi and Nikolaos Vettas ABSTRACT We characterize vertical contracts in oligopolistic markets where each upstream firm

More information

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure Corporate Financial Management Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure As we discussed in previous lectures, two extreme results, namely the irrelevance of capital structure and 100 percent

More information

Sequential-move games with Nature s moves.

Sequential-move games with Nature s moves. Econ 221 Fall, 2018 Li, Hao UBC CHAPTER 3. GAMES WITH SEQUENTIAL MOVES Game trees. Sequential-move games with finite number of decision notes. Sequential-move games with Nature s moves. 1 Strategies in

More information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Topic 5: Information Economics 21, Summer 2002 Andreas Bentz Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Introduction

More information

CHAPTER 14: REPEATED PRISONER S DILEMMA

CHAPTER 14: REPEATED PRISONER S DILEMMA CHAPTER 4: REPEATED PRISONER S DILEMMA In this chapter, we consider infinitely repeated play of the Prisoner s Dilemma game. We denote the possible actions for P i by C i for cooperating with the other

More information

Switching Costs and Equilibrium Prices

Switching Costs and Equilibrium Prices Switching Costs and Equilibrium Prices Luís Cabral New York University and CEPR This draft: August 2008 Abstract In a competitive environment, switching costs have two effects First, they increase the

More information

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2013 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Chapter 7 Review questions

Chapter 7 Review questions Chapter 7 Review questions 71 What is the Nash equilibrium in a dictator game? What about the trust game and ultimatum game? Be careful to distinguish sub game perfect Nash equilibria from other Nash equilibria

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

Liquidity and Risk Management

Liquidity and Risk Management Liquidity and Risk Management By Nicolae Gârleanu and Lasse Heje Pedersen Risk management plays a central role in institutional investors allocation of capital to trading. For instance, a risk manager

More information

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015. FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.) Hints for Problem Set 2 1. Consider a zero-sum game, where

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1 Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose,

More information

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. August 2010

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. August 2010 Department of Agricultural Economics PhD Qualifier Examination August 200 Instructions: The exam consists of six questions. You must answer all questions. If you need an assumption to complete a question,

More information

Formal Contracts, Relational Contracts, and the Holdup Problem

Formal Contracts, Relational Contracts, and the Holdup Problem Formal Contracts, Relational Contracts, and the Holdup Problem Hideshi Itoh Hodaka Morita September 3, 2004 We are grateful to Murali Agastya, Shingo Ishiguro, Shinsuke Kambe, Kieron Meagher, Bill Schworm,

More information

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment Avihai Lifschitz Tel Aviv University This Draft: October 2015 Abstract This paper develops a dynamic model of the labor market, in which the employed workers,

More information

Problem Set 2 Answers

Problem Set 2 Answers Problem Set 2 Answers BPH8- February, 27. Note that the unique Nash Equilibrium of the simultaneous Bertrand duopoly model with a continuous price space has each rm playing a wealy dominated strategy.

More information

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Corporate Control Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Managerial Discipline and Takeovers Managers often don t maximize the value of the firm; either because they are not capable

More information

Where do securities come from

Where do securities come from Where do securities come from We view it as natural to trade common stocks WHY? Coase s policemen Pricing Assumptions on market trading? Predictions? Partial Equilibrium or GE economies (risk spanning)

More information

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade Jesse A. Schwartz Kennesaw State University Quan Wen Vanderbilt University May 2012 Abstract In a bilateral bargaining problem with private

More information

Repeated Games. Econ 400. University of Notre Dame. Econ 400 (ND) Repeated Games 1 / 48

Repeated Games. Econ 400. University of Notre Dame. Econ 400 (ND) Repeated Games 1 / 48 Repeated Games Econ 400 University of Notre Dame Econ 400 (ND) Repeated Games 1 / 48 Relationships and Long-Lived Institutions Business (and personal) relationships: Being caught cheating leads to punishment

More information

HW Consider the following game:

HW Consider the following game: HW 1 1. Consider the following game: 2. HW 2 Suppose a parent and child play the following game, first analyzed by Becker (1974). First child takes the action, A 0, that produces income for the child,

More information