Macro factors and sovereign bond spreads: a quadratic no-arbitrage model

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Macro factors and sovereign bond spreads: a quadratic no-arbitrage model"

Transcription

1 Macro factors and sovereign bond spreads: a quadratic no-arbitrage model Peter Hördahl y Bank for International Settlements Oreste Tristani z European Central Bank May 3 Abstract We construct a quadratic, no-arbitrage model for credit risky sovereign bonds, based on macroeconomic factors, and show that it captures well both the dynamics and the cross-section of euro area yield spreads before and during the sovereign debt crisis. It is also capable of capturing key aspects of observed spread volatilities. The model s performance in forecasting -year spreads is at least comparable to that of professional forecasters. In the model, default intensities are closely related to macroeconomic factors: they increase during economic down-turns and when public debt increases. The recent rise of default intensities in Southern European countries can therefore be closely associated with domestic developments in macro fundamentals. Moreover, we provide evidence that risk-neutral default intensities, and hence also sovereign bond spreads, depend non-linearly on debt-to-gdp ratios. In all countries but Greece, however, the bulk of the increase in spreads on longer term sovereign bonds is not associated with higher default intensities, but with a surge in distress risk premia. Such premia are predominantly driven by a factor that is common across countries, and which could be the manifestation of self-ful lling market dynamics. JEL classi cation numbers: F34, G, G5 Keywords: Sovereign bond yields, a ne quadratic term structure, scal policy, credit risk, reduced form credit models. We would like to thank Michael Bauer, Darrell Du e, Redouane Elkamhi, Jean-Paul Renne, Ken Singleton, and seminar participants at the BIS, the 7th International Conference on Computing in Economics and Finance, the European Economic Association meetings, the Banque de France conference on The Economics of Sovereign Debt and Default, and the 3 Bank of Canada conference on Advances in Fixed Income Modelling for helpful comments and suggestions. The opinions expressed are personal and should not be attributed to the Bank for International Settlements or the European Central Bank. y Bank for International Settlements, Monetary and Economic Department, Centralbahnplatz, CH-4, Basel, Switzerland. Phone: ; Fax: ; peter.hoerdahl@bis.org. z European Central Bank, DG Research, Kaiserstrasse 9, D - 63, Frankfurt am Main, Germany. Phone: ; Fax: ; oreste.tristani@ecb.int.

2 Introduction From late 9 onwards, yields on bonds issued by several euro area countries rose sharply above comparable yields on German government bonds. Sovereign credit spreads for Southern euro area countries Greece, Italy, Portugal, Spain (and Ireland) which had averaged only a few tens of basis points for most of the period since the introduction of the euro, surged to several hundred basis point (see Figure a). Conditional yield volatilities also increased sharply, in parallel with the increase in spreads (see Figure b). More than three years hence, and after a restructuring of Greek debt, bond yields in Southern euro area countries continue to hover around high levels. The crisis has sparked a lively debate on the underlying causes of the observed high government bond yields. One viewpoint is that these high yields are simply a re ection of large increases in budget de cits and/or debts, which have eroded markets con dence in countries ability to repay their debt obligations. The opposite point of view is that high spreads are the result of self-ful lling dynamics, i.e. the fact that su ciently high real yields could ultimately trigger a default in any country with an outstanding stock of government debt. Our paper aims to identify some stylised facts to inform this debate. We therefore construct a model of sovereign spreads which is consistent with both the fundamental and the self-ful lling explanations of the crisis. Speci cally, we allow spreads to be related to both macroeconomic variables and an unobservable common factor. The macro variables, namely expectations of public debt-to-gdp ratios and of rates of growth of GDP, aim to proxy the notion of sustainability of the intertemporal government budget constraint. Consistently with the recent theoretical literature including Corsetti et al., ; Bi, ; Juessen at al. we allow for yields dependence on debt-to-gdp to be non-linear. Speci cally, we rely on a quadratic model of countries default intensities, that has well-known advantages in terms of tractability compared to alternative non-linear speci cations. The model allows for the possibility of spreads increasing more than proportionally to debt, when debt levels become su ciently high. Contrary to a simpler a ne Gaussian speci cation, it also allows us to capture some of the time variation in conditional variances which is apparent from gure. As already mentioned, we also allow an unobservable factor to in uence spreads. See e.g. Calvo (988), Jeanne (), Corsetti and Dedola (), Roch and Uhlig ().

3 This factor could be an indication that spread dynamics are unrelated to the relevant macroeconomic variables and re ect instead sunspot-like dynamics. We allow this single, common factor to a ect yields in all countries, in order to capture the idea of cross-country contagion unrelated to common dynamics in fundamentals. Alternatively, the common factor may simply re ect additional relevant information a ecting bonds across all sovereigns that is not incorporated in our observable macro variables. The common factor and the macroeconomic variables are modelled as a vector autoregression (VAR). The VAR has the advantage of being empirically exible, while incorporating, in reduced form, all relevant linkages between the variables of interest. When confronted with euro area data over the EMU period, our model captures quite well both the dynamics and the cross-section of euro area sovereign bond spreads. It can also capture some key elements of observed spread volatilities. Both in sample and out of sample, the model s forecasting performance is at least comparable to that of professional forecasters, as surveyed by Consensus Economics. Our estimated model is able to partly disentangle default probabilities from risk premia e ects on spreads. Speci cally, we can identify and estimate a component of spreads due to distress risk premia, i.e. compensation for unpredictable variation in default intensities, and an expected default component that is free of this premium. Both components are related to the state variables of the model. To disentangle these components from the data we use jointly three sources of information: the time series of credit spreads, their cross section along the term structure, and their cross-country developments. Intuitively, our results can be understood as follows. The time series information suggests that, since 9, spreads have been exceptionally high by EMU standards. Since this high-spread episode is accompanied by high volatility, the persistence of the processes driving the increase in spreads is estimated to be moderate. Default intensities are expected to go back to lower levels as shocks are reabsorbed, and future default probabilities are therefore expected to fall over the medium term. As we discuss later on, this expected default component may still incorporate a risk premium to compensate investors for jump-at-default risk. This premium cannot be identi ed using the data at hand; see e.g. Singleton (6). Remolona et al. (8) suggest one way of estimating the jumpat-default risk premium component using credit rating data. We adopt the distress risk premium label of Longsta et al. () to distinguish it from the the jump-at-default premium. 3

4 In the absence of distress premia, the term structure of credit spreads should therefore be downward sloping. This is closer to the truth in the case of Greece. As a result, a relatively larger share of the high spread on longer-term Greek bonds is interpreted by the model as due to an increase in the expected default component. In the other countries, however, the term structure of credit spreads is relatively atter. Given that the time series information suggests that default intensities are expected to fall over the future, this means that distress premia have played a key role in keeping long-term spreads high recently. The cross-country information is crucial to identify the role of the unobservable factor in driving credit spreads, which it does mainly through its impact on distress risk premia. We assume that, in each country, the market prices of distress risk and hence risk premia can vary in relation to changes in both debt-to-gdp and GDP growth of that country. Moreover, we adopt a exible speci cation which allows for such relationships to be country-speci c. This implies that any common uctuations in countries distress risk premia which can be associated with changes in the country s macroeconomic and scal variables are identi ed as country-speci c. Only the remaining, systematic variation in premia which is both common across countries, and not associated with observable macroeconomic uctuations, is attributed to the common factor. Our results suggest that while much of the increase in distress risk premia during the sovereign debt crisis can be associated with rising debt-to-gdp, changes in the unobservable common factor accounts for a large portion of the surge in. The default intensities, net of distress risk premia, are instead more closely related to macroeconomic fundamentals: they increase during recessions and when the debt-to-gdp ratio rises. Speci cally, they increase nonlinearly in the level of public debt. For example, according to our estimates, a further percentage point increase in the debt-to-gdp ratio would have led to an immediate basis points increase in -year spreads in Greece at the end of, while the same debt increase would have been negligible for Greek spreads in, for example, January. Our modeling approach is related to a number of papers that study the price of credit risky securities and/or their relationship to macroeconomic variables. A rst group of papers analyses sovereign spreads or credit default swaps (CDS) in a dynamic, no-arbitrage setting e.g. Du e, Pedersen and Singleton (3), Pan and Singleton (8) and Longsta, Pan, Pedersen and Singleton (). They estimate a single-factor model for each of the sovereigns they consider and then 4

5 investigate how credit risk covaries across countries. Ang and Longsta () use a multi-factor speci cation to compare spreads on US States and on European countries, and nd evidence that common ( systemic ) credit risk plays a greater role for the euro area than for the US. All these models only use yield spreads or CDS data and make no attempt to relate yields to macroeconomic information. Various papers, including Alesina et al. (99), Ardagna et al. (7), Bernoth et al. (6), study the relationship between sovereign spreads at speci c maturities and macroeconomic variables in a cross-section framework. These papers however, do not impose no arbitrage restrictions and focus on one speci c yield maturity. As a result, they nd only mild evidence for non-linearities in the relationship between yields and macro variables. They are also unable to distinguish between default risk and distress risk premia. Finally, Borgy et al. (), who are closest to our study, include macro factors in a no-arbitrage model of credit spreads. However they rely on an a ne framework and, as a result, do not allow for nonlinearities. Moreover, they explicitly rule out feedback e ects from higher yields to the level of government debt. They also assume that default in any country is unrelated to the default events of other sovereigns. In contrast to all these papers, we extend the sovereign bond pricing framework from a linear to a non-linear setting. Speci cally, we allow the default intensity of a credit-risky country to depend on our scal forecast variable in a linear-quadratic way. As a result, we end up with a quadratic pricing framework, which we nd to work well in capturing some of the extreme sovereign credit spread widening witnessed in recent months. We also explicitly allow for correlated default probabilities across countries. The correlation can be induced by the one factor driving sovereign spreads that is common across all countries in our analysis. This factor can potentially capture contagion e ects. Finally, we adopt a relatively richer speci cation of the factor dynamics in each country, which allows for feedback e ects from the other factors GDP growth and the common factor to the debt/gdp level. We show that this is important for the model to be consistent, to rst order, with the possibility of feed-back e ects from higher yields to the level of government debt. The paper is organised as follows. Section presents and motivates our modelling approach. It argues that a quadratic speci cation is consistent with the results of the theoretical literature and with empirically observed patterns. We describe the data in section 3, which also provides some information on the unscented Kalman lter that we use to estimate the model. We present our results in three separate 5

6 sections. Section 4 focuses on in sample t and on the model s decomposition of expected default intensities and distress risk premia. In Section 5 we show our model s ability to forecast yields, both in sample and out of sample, and to match the changes in conditional volatilities apparent from the data. We conclude that the empirical performance of the model is good. We therefore proceed to compute its implications in terms of estimated default probabilities for the countries in our sample. We also compute impulse responses to illustrate the model s ability to account for interactions between the state variables. Finally, Section 7 o ers some concluding remarks. Model and estimation Our empirical speci cation builds on the class of reduced-form credit pricing models in which assumptions are made about the process for default intensity, as in Lando (998) and Du e and Singleton (999). In this framework, default is assumed to be doubly stochastic, meaning that default arrives randomly according to a Poisson process with some intensity and that, in addition, this intensity process varies randomly over time. The advantage of this approach is that it gives rise to tractable pricing formulas. Speci cally, in discrete time and assuming zero recovery, for a given risk-neutral default intensity process and a given risk-free interest rate process r; the price at t of a zero-coupon defaultable bond with n periods to maturity is (see e.g. Du e and Singleton, 3): B t+n t = E Q t 3 nx (r t+j + t+j ) A5 ; () j= where E Q t [] denotes the expected value under the risk-neutral probability measure. In case of non-zero (possibly stochastic) recovery, Lando (998) shows that the price can be written as in (), with an added term that captures the risk-neutral expectation of the recovery value in case of default. In some cases, notably under the assumption of fractional recovery of the market value (RMV) of the bond, it is possible to obtain closed-form solutions for defaultable bonds (Du e and Singleton, 999). We therefore assume RMV and proceed by setting up our empirical speci cation in discrete time. This involves specifying (i) the relevant state variables and their dynamics; (ii) the relationship between default intensities and the state variables; and (iii) the pricing kernel. 6

7 . The state vector We specify our model directly in terms of sovereign yield spreads. 3 In each country i, the risk-neutral default intensities of risky bonds, t, are assumed to depend on a vector of state variables Xt i which in turn follows a vector AR() process 4 X i t = i X i t + i " i t: () In each country issuing risky bonds, X i t comprises three elements. The rst one is an unobservable factor C t, which is common across countries. The second element is the country s expected rate of growth of real GDP, g i t. The nal element is the expected debt-to-gdp ratio d i t. 5 We therefore have X i t = C t ; g i t; d i t ; and we assume that the covariance matrix is diagonal with elements diag i = ; i g ; i d. The i matrix is speci ed as follows i = 6 4 ; i ; i 3; i 3; i 3; : This structure for i is motivated by the following considerations. For the common factor, we adopt an identi cation assumption. Speci cally, we assume that C t is a simple autoregressive process whose level is not a ected by any of the other state variables in any country, i.e. C t = ; C t + " C t. We wish to think of C t as a factor capturing e ects that are directly unrelated to macroeconomic developments. These e ects could be the product of self-ful lling expectations, which have an impact on yields independently of a country s scal stance or growth performance. This is in line with results in Calvo (988) and Cole and Kehoe () and more recently Cooper (), Corsetti and Dedola (), Jeanne (), Roch and Uhlig (). These papers show that multiple equilibria can characterise sovereign bond markets due to expectations coordination problems. Self-ful lling developments in other countries may act as an area-wide coordination device and therefore lead to crosscountry contagion. It is this type of contagion, which is unrelated to fundamentals, which we wish to capture with the C t factor. We therefore assume that the rst 3 Here, we follow much of the literature and assume that the risk-neutral default intensity of each country is independent from the risk-free short-term interest rate; see e.g. Pan and Singleton (8) and Longsta et al. (). 4 The state variables are here speci ed in deviation from their respective mean values. 5 We discuss the exact de nition of these macro factors in the next section. 7

8 row of i has zeros everywhere except for the rst element and that its innovations are uncorrelated with those in the macro variables. The assumption of a unitary standard deviation is a normalisation to allow econometric identi cation. By contrast, we allow for non-zero values of all elements in the last row of i. This ensures that developments in both the common factor and the rate of growth of GDP can feed back on the debt-to-gdp level. Allowing for non-zero coe cients i 3; and i 3; is important to capture, to rst order, feedback e ects from higher yields to higher debt through the increase in the costs of servicing the debt. This point can be illustrated through a simple government budget constraint D t = S t + ~r t D t, where S t is the nominal primary surplus, D t is the nominal debt at t, which has to be nanced at some one-period interest rate ~r t (assuming that the debt is rolled over each period). Assume for simplicity that the main driver of uctuations in risky yields is the spread relative to the risk-free yield, which in turn is driven by the default risk, i t. Assume further that the spread is a given function of some state variables X t : t = F (X t ). Then, in reduced form, the debt accumulation equation will be D t = S t + F (X t ) D t, which to rst order can be approximated as bd t = a X t + a b Dt + u t (3) where a F (X) and a F (X) are constant parameters vectors and u t (S=D) S b t. Equation (3) demonstrates that debt will in general react to all the state variables which a ect sovereign spreads. It is therefore important to allow for non-zero elements i 3; and i 3; in the i matrix. In principle we could also allow for feedback of debt and the common factor on growth. In a simple preliminary bivariate VAR regressions of GDP growth and debt-to-gdp ratios, however, we nd that the feedback coe cient of debt levels on growth are quantitatively negligible. We therefore assume that GDP growth can be described by a simple autoregression to reduce the overall number of parameters to be estimated.. Default intensity We next need an assumption for the risk-neutral default intensity in each country i; i t. The literature has largely adopted an a ne speci cation, which has well know advantages for tractability. However, there are theoretical and empirical results in the literature which suggest that an a ne model may not be the right choice when 8

9 specifying sovereign default intensities. Speci cally, a few recent structural models suggest that sovereign yields spreads over a default-free benchmark are likely to be nonlinear functions of scal conditions see e.g. Bi (), Juessen et al. () and Corsetti et al. (). These models explicitly take into account the fact that governments can only repay bonds up to a level given by the expected present discounted value of government net surpluses over all future dates. Such level, denoted as the scal limit, will uctuate over time in reaction to changes in the state of the economy, e.g. due to productivity shocks that can change the economy s growth potential. From the private sector s perspective, the possibility that the government will default on its debt once the scal limit is reached generates a non-linearity on bond prices as a function of government debt. When the economy is far from the scal limit, there is no reason to expect a default on government debt and sovereign spreads will be low. However, as government debt increases and the economy is hit by recessionary shocks, the probability of default increases rapidly as the scal limit is approached. Beyond some value, bond yields therefore become very steep, nonlinear functions of the state variables that drive the economy towards the scal limit. There is also some stylised empirical evidence of a nonlinear relationship between scal fundamentals and either the level of yields or proxies for credit risk. Based on quarterly data for OECD countries over the period , Alesina et al. (99) nd evidence of a threshold e ect. They separate the countries into two groups, depending on whether their public debt, relative to GDP, is below or above a certain level. They then regress the spread between public and private returns on public debt-to-gdp levels and nd positive and highly signi cant coe cients only for the countries with high debt levels. Ardagna et al. (7) focus on yearly data on 6 OECD countries over a maximum time span from 96 to and test explicitly for non-linearity by including the squared term of the debt-to-gdp ratio in a regression of long term interest rates. The coe cient on the square term is significant over di erent subsamples and estimation methods. Bernoth et al. (4) also nd signi cant nonlinear e ects for scal variables as determinants of bond yield di erentials on EU eurobonds issued between 99 and. Motivated by the aforementioned results, we allow for a nonlinear relationship between spreads and the debt-to-gdp level in each country. The advantage of casting such a nonlinear relationship within an explicit, no-arbitrage framework is that we will be able to exploit the cross-sectional information provided by the 9

10 term structure of credit spreads. No-arbitrage restrictions also have the advantage of helping discipline inference and allowing us to partially disentangle credit risk premia from default probabilities. To allow for a nonlinear relationship between spreads and debt levels without losing the tractability of the general a ne world, 6 we adopt an a ne-quadratic speci cation for the risk-neutral default intensities, such that i t = i + i X i t + X i t i X i t: (4) Here, motivated by the aforementioned empirical evidence, we assume that the quadratic term in i t is only a function of debt-to-gdp. This means that i will only include one non-zero element, dd ; corresponding to squared debt-to-gdp. Beyond capturing the theoretical nonlinearities mentioned above, a quadratic speci cation for the default intensities has the advantage of generating time variation in the conditional variance of yields, even if the state vector is Gaussian. As we have already highlighted in the introduction, time-variation in spread variances is clearly a stylised fact in the crisis a fact that can potentially be captured by a quadratic term structure model. Any improvement in capturing time-variation in spread volatilities would be useful when pricing derivative contracts or for risk management considerations. Allowing for heteroskedastic second moments is also important to attain reliable estimates of the uncertainty surrounding forecasts of future interest rate levels. Finally, it is important to note that our model allows for cross-country correlation in default intensities. Speci cally, movements in the common factor C t have the potential to drive default intensities in the same direction in all countries. When observing common cross-country dynamics in credit spreads, we can therefore disentangle whether they are due to correlated developments in country-speci c fundamentals, or instead to some form of nancial contagion. We talk about the rst type of correlation when spreads are a ected by domestic, macroeconomic determinants, which move in the same direction in all countries. We talk about contagion when spreads are all driven by the common factor. 6 In general, a Gaussian quadratic term structure model can be rewritten as an a ne term structure model with heteroskedastic innovations.

11 .3 Bond prices In a discrete-time setting, we can write the price of a credit-risky bond at t as the expected value of the product of the pricing kernel, m t;t+ ; and the value of the bond one period ahead. Speci cally, the price at t of a risky bond maturing at t + n can be written as with boundary condition B t+n t = E t mt;t+ B t+n t+ >t+ + Z t+ <t+ ; B t+n t+n = E t+n [m t+n ;t+n ( >t+n + Z t+n <t+n )] ; where Z t is the recovery payment, denotes the time of default and >t+ is an indicator variable that takes the value one if > t + : In general, the expectation E t [ >t+k ] is the probability of survival until t + k: 7 E t [ >t+k ] = E t "exp!# kx t+i : Under a RMV assumption, the expected recovery payment is a fraction of the bond price at t + ; conditional on no default, i.e. for an n-period bond i= E t [Z t+ ] = E t ( Lt+ ) B t+n t+ ; where L t+ is the (risk-neutral) fractional loss rate. Assuming that the loss rate is a constant L, we have, under RMV, B t+n t = E t mt;t+ ( L ( exp ( t+ ))) B t+n t+ : In discrete time, we can make the following approximation L ( exp ( t+ )) exp ( t+ ) : This approximation holds exactly for L = : For L di erent from, we should view as re ecting adjusted default intensities, rather than actual intensities. This is 7 This would be the true, objective survival probability only if denoted the objective default intensities. Instead, as mentioned earlier, denotes the risk-neutral arrival intensity of default.

12 analogous to the use of recovery-adjusted default intensities in continuous time models with RMV (e.g. Du e and Singleton, 999). Given this approximation, we can write B t+n t = E t mt;t+ exp ( t+ ) B t+n t+ : The pricing kernel m t;t+ is assumed to depend on the state variables X t : Specifically, m t;t+ = exp ( r t ) t+ = t, where t+ is assumed to follow the log-normal process t+ = t exp t t t" t+ ; which results in 8 m t;t+ = exp r t t t t" t+ : At this point we only need to specify the market prices of risk, denoted as i t for country i. We rely on the Du ee () essentially a ne speci cation and assume i t = 6 4 C;i g;i d;i i C;C i g;g i d;c i d;g i d;d Xi t: (5) where the zeros are imposed for symmetry with the i matrix. It is important to note that premia resulting form non-zero market prices of risk represent compensation for the risk of unpredictable changes in the default intensities, over and above the possible compensation required for the risk associated with a drop in the bond price in the event of default. Consistent with the terminology introduced in Pan and Singleton (8), we therefore refer to premia due to default intensity risk as distress premia. Given the aforementioned assumptions, the price of an n-period bond can be written as B t+n t = exp A n + B n X t + X tc n X t : (6) for constants A n, B n and C n that are de ned in the appendix and that can be obtained using simple recursions. 9 8 Under our assumption that the default intensities are independent of the factors driving the risk-free interest rate r, this rate will drop out later on when we focus on bond spreads relative to a safe benchmark. 9 We will be working in spread-space rather than yield or price space, but the spread expressions are analogous.

13 3 Data and estimation method 3. Data Our data is monthly and covers the period from the introduction of the euro, January 999, to end-november. We consider government bonds of ve euro area countries: Greece, Portugal, Spain, France and Italy, and we regard German government bonds as proxies for credit risk-free euro-denominated bonds. In order to construct sovereign spreads, we rst estimate zero-coupon yields for these countries based on end-of-month prices of all available government bonds, as reported by Bloomberg, using the Nelson-Siegel model. We select six maturities to be used in subsequent estimations, namely, 3, 4, 5, 7 and years. For these maturities, we take the estimated zero-coupon yields for each of our ve countries and subtract the corresponding German yield to obtain zero-coupon sovereign spreads. Concerning the macroeconomic variables, we follow Laubach (9) and rely on forecasts, rather than o cial published data. The problem with using o cial data is that both GDP growth and public debt data are subject to considerable revisions over time, and it would therefore be important to keep track of the di erent vintages of data releases. While these are not readily available for all the countries we consider, we do have access to the di erent vintages of macroeconomic forecasts prepared twice a year by the European Commission. Such forecasts have the additional advantage of relating to a medium-term horizon roughly one and two years ahead. They should therefore represent better proxies for the sustainability of government nances than current debt-to-gdp data. And their forward-looking nature should be closer to what investors care about when pricing sovereign bonds than o cial data, which is always released with a considerable lag. More speci cally, we use data from both the Spring and Fall forecasts. For the date released in the Spring, the forecasts cover the current and next year, i.e. until the end of the current year and until the end of the following year. For the Fall forecast, the horizons extend through the next and the following years. By including this data, we are implicitly assuming that the forecasts by the European Commission are close to those made by the private sector when taking their pricing decisions. We obviously exclude bonds that are not euro denominated or in ation-index linked, and those that pay oating rates or have other non-standard features. 3

14 There are two nal choices we need to make when using these data. The rst one has to do with their frequency. Our yields are sampled at monthly frequency, while the forecasts are only available twice per year. To simplify the estimation of our term structure model, we pre- lter monthly data from the European Commission forecasts using the Kalman lter and a simple autoregressive law of motion. Here, we take as input data expected debt-to-gdp and GDP growth roughly one year ahead, which is constructed using the two published forecasts on either side of the one-year horizon. At this stage, we do not use any yield information at all. We use the resulting ltered monthly series of one-year ahead expectations as our macro data in the subsequent estimation of the term structure model. The second choice is related to the long run means of debt-to-gdp and GDP growth. A key issue regards the sustainable debt-to-gdp ratio in each country. Debt could be stabilised around di erent levels, each requiring di erent primary surpluses. In turn, nonlinear e ects of debt should kick in only when debt deviates signi cantly from the sustainable level. As a result, a certain debt-to-gdp ratio could be perceived as sustainable, or unsustainable, in di erent countries. To allow for this possibility, we use debt-to-gdp ratios in deviation from the historical precrisis mean, i.e. from 999 to 6. GDP growth is simply measured in deviation from the sample mean. The resulting macro data are shown in Figure. 3. Estimation method In our setup, yields on credit risky bonds are non-linear functions of the state variables. As a result, we cannot use the standard Kalman lter approach to estimate the model. We therefore rely on the unscented Kalman lter of Julier and Uhlmann (997, 4) to construct the likelihood function. The unscented Kalman lter relies on a deterministic sampling technique to pick sigma points around the mean of some underlying random variable. The sigma points are then propagated through the non-linear functions of interest, in order to recover the rst two moments of the non-linear system. These can subsequently be used in the updating step of the lter. In our application, the transition equation is the state variable VAR, X t = X t + " t ; (7) Including 7- in the calculation of the mean values would, in our view, skew these values towards unsustainable levels. 4

15 while the observation equation can be written as z t = (X t ) + t ; (8) where z t is a vector of observables, () is a non-linear function, and where the observation error vector t is assumed to have zero mean and a diagonal covariance matrix ~ R: In our case, the observation vector consists of n s zero-coupon spreads for each country i; stacked in s i t; and a vector f i t that contains data on the expected scal position and expected GDP growth rate of country i; based on forecasts of the debt to GDP ratio and GDP growth as described above. Given data for m countries, we can de ne the observation vector as z t 6 4 The function (X t ) will then contain the non-linear model expressions for the spreads, n ln Bt+n t (less the risk-free yield), with the bond price Bt t+n given by (6), and = vectors selecting the appropriate elements in X t corresponding to the observable macro variables. s t. s m t f ṭ. f m t Similar to the standard Kalman lter, the unscented lter relies on a linear updating rule according to 3 : 7 5 ^X tjt = ^X tjt + ~ K t z t ^z tjt ; (9) where ^X tjt = ^X t jt ; ~K t = P xz(tjt ) P h i ^z tjt = E ^Xtjt ; zz(tjt ) ; and where P zz is the innovation covariance matrix and P xz is the cross covariance Greece adopted the euro in, and therefore enters the data set only at this point. 5

16 matrix. The updated state is associated with updated covariance 3 P xx(tjt) = P xx(tjt ) ~ Kt P xx(tjt ) ~ K t ; () where P xx(tjt ) = P xx(t jt ) + : For an n x -dimensional state vector X; a set of n x + sigma points { ; { ; :::; { nx with associated weights $ ; $ ; :::; $ nx are chosen (see the Appendix [to come] for details). For each sigma point i, the nonlinear transformation in (8) is applied Z i = ({ i ) : The covariance matrices P xx ; P zz and P xz are then approximated using { i and the transformed points Z i. Based on the obtained forecasts of the states and the associated covariances, we de ne the log-likelihood function in the usual way and proceed to estimate the model using the maximum likelihood method. 4 Estimation results In this section we present the main results on our model s ability to t sovereign spreads data. Table reports the estimated parameter values. Figure 3 shows actual and tted yields for the ve countries in our estimation sample. 4 All in all, our model can t the data well. The standard deviations of the measurement errors on spreads vary between around 5 and basis points for France, Italy and Spain and between 8 and 6 basis points for Portugal. Unsurprisingly, measurement errors tend to be larger when spreads surge over the most recent part of the sample. In the case of Greece, where the -year spread reached levels of around 7 basis points towards the end of the sample, the corresponding measurement error standard deviation is 95 basis points. The values for longer-maturity Greek spreads range from 45 to 6 basis points. In our model, part of the spreads are explained by the estimated common 3 In practice, we rely on the square-root verion of the unscented Kalman lter by van der Merwe and Wan (), which guarantees positive semi-de niteness of the state covariances and improves numerical stability during the estimation. 4 In this gure, and most of the subsequent ones, we show only the period from 4 onwards instead of the full sample period, in order to provide a less compressed picture of the crisis period. 6

17 factor, which is displayed in Figure 4. We discuss the role of this factor in more detail below. We also note that the non-linear features of the model seem crucial in capturing spread dynamics during the sovereign debt crisis. Figure 5 displays the di erence between the full estimated non-linear model, and a version of the model that relies on a linear approximation around the mean values of the state variables. While an estimated linear model may improve on the result of the linearized model, it would probably have a hard time capturing the most recent surge in sovereign spreads unless country-speci c latent variables were introduced. Figure 6 shows snapshots of the term structure of credit spreads before (December 6) and during (November ) the sovereign debt crisis. All term structures tended to be at around zero or slightly upward sloping in 6, prior to the sovereign debt crisis. At the end of, credit spreads were substantially higher across all maturities and in all countries. From the maturity perspective, however, the striking development in countries under stress is that their term structure of credit spreads becomes downward sloping. This property is only mildly apparent in Spain and Italy, but more clear in the case of Portugal, and striking for Greece. This feature of the data helps explain our ndings on the importance of distress risk premia in the various countries. Since default intensities are stationary, any increase in their levels is eventually expected to be reabsorbed. In the absence of distress premia, this implies that the term structure of credit spreads should be downward sloping. When the observed spreads term structure is also downward sloping, the spread on longer-term bonds can be easily consistent with the expected future path of default intensities. There is no need for distress risk premia. If, however, the observed term structure is relatively at, it is much harder to explain long term spreads without distress risk premia. Based on the slope of the term structures of credit spreads during the crisis, therefore, one can expect distress risk premia to play a relatively larger role in Spain and Italy, compared to Portugal and, especially, Greece. This intuition is con rmed by Figure 7, which shows -year sovereign spreads including and excluding distress risk premia. These premia (i.e. the di erence between the two curves in Figure 7) are negative but relatively small everywhere in the early years of EMU a result consistent with the view of an under-pricing of sovereign credit risks in the euro area in those years. In and especially, they increase dramatically in all countries. In all countries but Greece, their increase accounts for over 7% of the total increase in spreads at the end of the sample. In 7

18 Greece, however, they account for about 5% of the increase in total spreads. According to our estimates, sovereign spreads in November would have hovered around percentage point in Spain and Italy, around 3 percentage points in Portugal, and around percentage points in Greece, had distress premia been zero. Figure 8 presents a decompositions of the expected default component i.e. the part of the spread that is not due to the distress risk premium for -year bonds, to disentangle the role of the various factors. 5 At each point in time, and for each country, the decomposition plots four components: the constant, the component due to the common factor, the component due to GDP growth and the component due to debt-to-gdp. A notable feature of the decomposition is that the common component plays a relatively minor role in explaining default risk. Its contribution reaches a maximum level of just over 3 percentage point in Greece at the end of the sample, when the overall expected default component exceeds percentage points, and in Portugal it explains about a quarter of the rise in expected default. In all other countries, the contribution of the common component is almost negligible. The bulk of the deviation of the expected default component from its mean is instead explained, primarily, by variations in the debt-to-gdp component and, to some extent, by changes in the rate of growth of GDP. The level of debt sustains the increase in spreads since late 9. This is striking not only in Greece, where the debt-to-gdp ratio increased dramatically over the crisis period; it is also true in the other countries, France included. The expected default component also increases during recessions. It therefore increases signi cantly everywhere at the time of the Great recession, when public debts soar and growth tanks. In France, Italy and Spain, default intensities are subsequently brought down somewhat by the (partial) economic rebound; in Greece, however, the prolonged, deep recession contributes to keeping the expected default component high throughout the sovereign crisis period. Figure 9 presents a corresponding decomposition for distress risk premia. In contrast to the expected default component, the unobservable common factor plays an important role in explaining the recent surge in distress risk premia. Speci cally, it accounts for more than 5% of the increase in premia in Italy and in Spain at the 5 Again, it should be noted that this corresponds to expectations under the objective probability measure P for the risk-neutral default intensities, which we obtain by setting all market price of risk parameters to zero. 8

19 end of the sample. The level of public debt, however, continues to play an important role in all countries. With the exception of Portugal, risk premia also tend to increase during recessions, which is consistent with the evidence for term premia on default risk-free bonds (e.g. Cochrane and Piazzesi, 5). 5 Spread forecasts and volatilities We have imposed no-arbitrage restrictions on our model of sovereign spreads. In our setup, the evolution of the state variables is speci ed in reduced form, and the speci cation of the prices of risk is very exible. It is therefore not too surprising that the model can t the data well. A much tougher speci cation test is to check the model s forecasting ability, as shown by Du ee (). In this section, we therefore report results of a forecasting test. We conclude the section with a test of the model s ability to match the volatilities of spreads. 5. Forecasts One key di culty in assessing the model s forecasting ability is that most of the information used to estimate our parameters comes from the crisis period. The sample would be too short and too little informative, if we attempted to estimate the model on pre-crisis data only. To perform a forecasting exercise, we therefore proceed as follows. We start by looking at in-sample forecasts. Speci cally, starting in January 9, we take the model as given but update our macroeconomic information only when it arrives that is, only twice per year, when the Commission forecasts are released. We then forecast yields year ahead over the crisis period. A relatively good forecasting performance would indicate that the model captures well the persistence of yields data, when the model nonlinearities become important. We use two benchmarks in this test. The rst is a random walk model. The second are forecasts by professional forecasters, as reported by Consensus Economics. We focus on France, Italy and Spain, as these are the only countries in for which Consensus forecasts are available. Our second exercise is a truly out-of-sample forecast. We compute year ahead forecasts over the December - November period, which was not included in the information set for estimation. In this case, realised one-year ahead data are 9

20 not available. We therefore only compare our model to Consensus forecasts. Figure compares -year ahead forecasts for our model and Consensus. In the cases of Consensus, the mean, the maximum and the minimum of the crosssectional forecast distribution are reported. Average root mean squared errors over the 9- period are reported in table [to be added]. In-sample our model forecasts as well as, or better than Consensus. Its performance is especially good for Italy in the early phases of the sovereign debt crisis, until the summer of ; -year ahead forecasts are almost on top of realised data. Over the same period, the model also does quite well for France and clearly better than Consensus for Spain. In the subsequent phase of the crisis, year ahead forecast errors increase dramatically. Nevertheless, our model continues doing better than the average Consensus forecast most of the time, especially so in the case of Italy. Our of sample forecasts for 3 tend to be aligned with Consensus. They are somewhat above the Consensus mean for Spain and Italy, slightly below the mean for France. Since professional forecasts are often a hard benchmark to beat, we tentatively conclude that our model has a reasonably good out-of-sample forecasting performance. 5. Volatilities We have already emphasised that, contrary to a simpler a ne Gaussian speci cation, our model also allows for time variation in conditional variances. The ability of a quadratic speci cation to match changes in conditional second moments is, however, tightly constrained: variances can only increase when yields do more precisely, when the quadratic component in the yields equation becomes large. The correlation between yield levels and conditional volatilities is obviously a feature of the sovereign bond crisis. In Figure and, however, we explore more formally our model s ability to capture the dynamics of conditional second moments of yields. As in Jacobs and Karoui (9), volatilities are de ned as the sum of the conditional standard deviations of the state vector and the measurement error shocks. Speci cally, Figure shows the term structure of average -step ahead conditional volatilities and Figure displays the time series of -step ahead conditional volatilities for the 5-year maturity. In both cases, we compare our estimates to those obtained through a GARCH(,) model. The gures suggest that our quadratic speci cation can capture some key fea-

21 tures of the GARCH estimates. We capture the overall, downward sloping shape of the average term structure of volatilities in most countries (Figure ). Our model does especially well for Greece and, at short and medium maturities, Portugal and Spain. Only in France does it suggest, counterfactually, a downward-sloping term structure of volatilities, although the magnitudes are tiny. These results are broadly con rmed along the time series dimension. Consistently with the GARCH estimates, conditional volatilities measured through our model increase dramatically for the countries hardest hit during the sovereign bond crisis years at the end of the sample. The increase, however, is always smaller than in the GARCH estimates. All in all, we view the results on variances as a con rmation that a quadratic model is strictly preferable to an a ne Gaussian speci cation, in terms of modelling the dynamics of euro sovereign yields spreads over recent years. Of course, there are other options available to allow for nonlinear e ects. One example which permits more exibility in the speci cation of volatilities is a regime switching model as in Monfort and Renne (). 6 A few implications of the model 6. Default probabilities Given our estimates, we can derive (risk neutral) probabilities that a particular country may default over a certain future horizon. Since our intensities t are recovery-adjusted default intensities, we rst need make an explicit assumption on the recovery value in case of default. Under the RMV assumption, the adjusted intensities relate to the true (risk-neutral) intensities t by exp ( t+ ) = exp t+ + ( L) exp t+ : A rst-order approximation gives t+ L t+: Hence, by making an explicit assumption on L and scaling the adjusted default intensities accordingly, we can obtain default probabilities for any given horizon k

22 in the same way as we price bonds (see the appendix for details): P D (t; t + k) = E t "exp L!# kx t+i : Here, the expectation E t [] is taken under the objective probability measure P, obtained by setting all risk price parameters in (5) to zero. Figure 3 displays one-year ahead default probabilities under the assumption that the recovery value is equal to 5% of the market value. Consistently with our estimates of a large distress risk premium component in the wide spreads of Italy and Spain, we nd that -year ahead default probabilities in these countries are relatively small even at the peak of the crisis. In our sample, these probabilities are estimated not to exceed 7% in Italy, 5% in Spain and % in France. At the opposite side of the spectrum is Greece, where distress risk premia were proportionately smaller. For this country, the -year ahead default probability is estimated to reach almost 8% in November. A restructuring of the Greek debt was eventually agreed in March. It is important to keep in mind that uncertainty surrounding such estimates increases markedly during the crisis. i= Error bands are especially large in Greece. Secondly, as already pointed out, while we remove the distress risk premium component to obtain these default probabilities, they are still not objective probabilities of default. Instead, they are the probabilities that would be observed if investors were not requiring any compensation for unexpected losses due to default. 6. Impulse responses Figures 4 and 5 present nonlinear impulse responses from our model. Impulse responses are computed as the di erence of two conditional forecasts: one including a selected shock, the other not including the shock. Since yields are nonlinear functions of the states, their impulse responses will be state dependent. To explore this property of the model, we compare impulse responses early in the sample in Figure 4 and the end of it in Figure 5. Note that only the impulse responses of yields change, since the state variables follow a linear process. We focus on adverse shocks, namely shocks which are likely to lead to an increase in yield spreads. Speci cally, we consider an increase in the debt to GDP ratio, a fall in GDP growth, and given our estimates of the common factor a downward shock to this factor. In terms of size, we look at a standard deviation

Macro factors and sovereign bond spreads: aquadraticno-arbitragemodel

Macro factors and sovereign bond spreads: aquadraticno-arbitragemodel Macro factors and sovereign bond spreads: aquadraticno-arbitragemodel Peter Hˆrdahl a, Oreste Tristani b a Bank for International Settlements, b European Central Bank 17 December 1 All opinions are personal

More information

The term structure of euro area sovereign bond yields

The term structure of euro area sovereign bond yields The term structure of euro area sovereign bond yields Peter Hördahl y Bank for International Settlements Oreste Tristani z European Central Bank 3 May Preliminary and incomplete Abstract We model the dynamics

More information

STOCK RETURNS AND INFLATION: THE IMPACT OF INFLATION TARGETING

STOCK RETURNS AND INFLATION: THE IMPACT OF INFLATION TARGETING STOCK RETURNS AND INFLATION: THE IMPACT OF INFLATION TARGETING Alexandros Kontonikas a, Alberto Montagnoli b and Nicola Spagnolo c a Department of Economics, University of Glasgow, Glasgow, UK b Department

More information

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Stephen R. Bond Institute for Fiscal Studies and Nu eld College, Oxford Måns Söderbom Centre for the Study of African Economies,

More information

Appendix to: The Myth of Financial Innovation and the Great Moderation

Appendix to: The Myth of Financial Innovation and the Great Moderation Appendix to: The Myth of Financial Innovation and the Great Moderation Wouter J. Den Haan and Vincent Sterk July 8, Abstract The appendix explains how the data series are constructed, gives the IRFs for

More information

Working Paper Series. A macro-financial analysis of the corporate bond market. No 2214 / December 2018

Working Paper Series. A macro-financial analysis of the corporate bond market. No 2214 / December 2018 Working Paper Series Hans Dewachter, Leonardo Iania, Wolfgang Lemke, Marco Lyrio A macro-financial analysis of the corporate bond market No 2214 / December 2018 Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported

More information

Predicting Sovereign Fiscal Crises: High-Debt Developed Countries

Predicting Sovereign Fiscal Crises: High-Debt Developed Countries Predicting Sovereign Fiscal Crises: High-Debt Developed Countries Betty C. Daniel Department of Economics University at Albany - SUNY Christos Shiamptanis Department of Economics Wilfrid Laurier University

More information

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure Comment on Dewachter and Lyrio s "Learning, Macroeconomic Dynamics, and the Term Structure of Interest Rates" 1 by Jordi Galí (CREI, MIT, and NBER) August 2006 The present paper by Dewachter and Lyrio

More information

Banking Concentration and Fragility in the United States

Banking Concentration and Fragility in the United States Banking Concentration and Fragility in the United States Kanitta C. Kulprathipanja University of Alabama Robert R. Reed University of Alabama June 2017 Abstract Since the recent nancial crisis, there has

More information

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations J. Scott Davis y Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas February 202 Abstract This paper introduces a model where agents are unsure

More information

Statistical Evidence and Inference

Statistical Evidence and Inference Statistical Evidence and Inference Basic Methods of Analysis Understanding the methods used by economists requires some basic terminology regarding the distribution of random variables. The mean of a distribution

More information

Working Paper Series. risk premia. No 1162 / March by Juan Angel García and Thomas Werner

Working Paper Series. risk premia. No 1162 / March by Juan Angel García and Thomas Werner Working Paper Series No 112 / InFLation risks and InFLation risk premia by Juan Angel García and Thomas Werner WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 112 / MARCH 2010 INFLATION RISKS AND INFLATION RISK PREMIA 1 by Juan

More information

Are Financial Markets Stable? New Evidence from An Improved Test of Financial Market Stability and the U.S. Subprime Crisis

Are Financial Markets Stable? New Evidence from An Improved Test of Financial Market Stability and the U.S. Subprime Crisis Are Financial Markets Stable? New Evidence from An Improved Test of Financial Market Stability and the U.S. Subprime Crisis Sandy Suardi (La Trobe University) cial Studies Banking and Finance Conference

More information

Forecasting Economic Activity from Yield Curve Factors

Forecasting Economic Activity from Yield Curve Factors ATHENS UNIVERSITY OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES 11-2013 Forecasting Economic Activity from Yield Curve Factors Efthymios Argyropoulos and Elias Tzavalis 76 Patission

More information

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and investment is central to understanding the business

More information

Faster solutions for Black zero lower bound term structure models

Faster solutions for Black zero lower bound term structure models Crawford School of Public Policy CAMA Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis Faster solutions for Black zero lower bound term structure models CAMA Working Paper 66/2013 September 2013 Leo Krippner

More information

McCallum Rules, Exchange Rates, and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

McCallum Rules, Exchange Rates, and the Term Structure of Interest Rates McCallum Rules, Exchange Rates, and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Antonio Diez de los Rios Bank of Canada antonioddr@gmail.com October 29 Abstract McCallum (1994a) proposes a monetary rule where

More information

Loss Functions for Forecasting Treasury Yields

Loss Functions for Forecasting Treasury Yields Loss Functions for Forecasting Treasury Yields Hitesh Doshi Kris Jacobs Rui Liu University of Houston October 2, 215 Abstract Many recent advances in the term structure literature have focused on model

More information

Manchester Business School

Manchester Business School Three Essays on Global Yield Curve Factors and International Linkages across Yield Curves A thesis submitted to The University of Manchester for the degree of Doctoral of Philosophy in the Faculty of Humanities

More information

Equity Returns and the Business Cycle: The Role of Supply and Demand Shocks

Equity Returns and the Business Cycle: The Role of Supply and Demand Shocks Equity Returns and the Business Cycle: The Role of Supply and Demand Shocks Alfonso Mendoza Velázquez and Peter N. Smith, 1 This draft May 2012 Abstract There is enduring interest in the relationship between

More information

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen Online Appendix Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen Appendix A: Analysis of Initial Claims in Medicare Part D In this appendix we

More information

Economic and Financial Determinants of Credit Risk Premiums in the Sovereign CDS Market

Economic and Financial Determinants of Credit Risk Premiums in the Sovereign CDS Market Economic and Financial Determinants of Credit Risk Premiums in the Sovereign CDS Market Hitesh Doshi Kris Jacobs Carlos Zurita University of Houston University of Houston University of Houston February

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

Essays on the Term Structure of Interest Rates and Long Run Variance of Stock Returns DISSERTATION. Ting Wu. Graduate Program in Economics

Essays on the Term Structure of Interest Rates and Long Run Variance of Stock Returns DISSERTATION. Ting Wu. Graduate Program in Economics Essays on the Term Structure of Interest Rates and Long Run Variance of Stock Returns DISSERTATION Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate

More information

SOVEREIGN CDS PREMIA DURING THE CRISIS AND THEIR INTERPRETATION AS A MEASURE OF RISK

SOVEREIGN CDS PREMIA DURING THE CRISIS AND THEIR INTERPRETATION AS A MEASURE OF RISK SOVEREIGN CDS PREMIA DURING THE CRISIS AND THEIR INTERPRETATION AS A MEASURE OF RISK Sovereign CDS premia during the crisis and their interpretation as a measure of risk The authors of this article are

More information

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints The University of Hong Kong From the SelectedWorks of Yulei Luo 00 Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints Yulei Luo, The University of Hong Kong Eric Young, University of Virginia Available

More information

Discussion Papers in Economics. No. 13/22. The US Economy, the Treasury Bond Market and the Specification of Macro-Finance Models.

Discussion Papers in Economics. No. 13/22. The US Economy, the Treasury Bond Market and the Specification of Macro-Finance Models. Discussion Papers in Economics No. 13/22 The US Economy, the Treasury Bond Market and the Specification of Macro-Finance Models Peter Spencer Department of Economics and Related Studies University of York

More information

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns 1/ 38 Introduction We analyze the Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model (ICAPM) of Robert Merton (1973). The standard single-period CAPM holds when

More information

Working Paper. An affine factor model of the Greek term structure. Hiona Balfoussia MAY 2008ORKINKPAPERWORKINKPAPERWORKINKPAPERWORKINKPAPERWO

Working Paper. An affine factor model of the Greek term structure. Hiona Balfoussia MAY 2008ORKINKPAPERWORKINKPAPERWORKINKPAPERWORKINKPAPERWO BANK OF GREECE EUROSYSTEM Working Paper An affine factor model of the Greek term structure Hiona Balfoussia 72 MAY 2008ORKINKPAPERWORKINKPAPERWORKINKPAPERWORKINKPAPERWO BANK OF GREECE Economic Research

More information

Retrieving inflation expectations and risk premia effects from the term structure of interest rates

Retrieving inflation expectations and risk premia effects from the term structure of interest rates ATHENS UNIVERSITY OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES 22-2013 Retrieving inflation expectations and risk premia effects from the term structure of interest rates Efthymios

More information

Labor Force Participation Dynamics

Labor Force Participation Dynamics MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Labor Force Participation Dynamics Brendan Epstein University of Massachusetts, Lowell 10 August 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/88776/ MPRA Paper No.

More information

Rare Disasters, Credit and Option Market Puzzles. Online Appendix

Rare Disasters, Credit and Option Market Puzzles. Online Appendix Rare Disasters, Credit and Option Market Puzzles. Online Appendix Peter Christo ersen Du Du Redouane Elkamhi Rotman School, City University Rotman School, CBS and CREATES of Hong Kong University of Toronto

More information

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Ozan Eksi TOBB University of Economics and Technology November 2 Abstract The standard new Keynesian

More information

Rue de la Banque No. 52 November 2017

Rue de la Banque No. 52 November 2017 Staying at zero with affine processes: an application to term structure modelling Alain Monfort Banque de France and CREST Fulvio Pegoraro Banque de France, ECB and CREST Jean-Paul Renne HEC Lausanne Guillaume

More information

Discussion of Fiscal Positions and Government Bond Yields in OECD Countries by Joseph W. Gruber and Steven B. Kamin

Discussion of Fiscal Positions and Government Bond Yields in OECD Countries by Joseph W. Gruber and Steven B. Kamin Discussion of Fiscal Positions and Government Bond Yields in OECD Countries by Joseph W. Gruber and Steven B. Kamin Christian Grisse Federal Reserve Bank of New York SCIEA conference, Atlanta, April 29,

More information

Credit Risk Modelling Under Distressed Conditions

Credit Risk Modelling Under Distressed Conditions Credit Risk Modelling Under Distressed Conditions Dendramis Y. Tzavalis E. y Adraktas G. z Papanikolaou A. July 20, 2015 Abstract Using survival analysis, this paper estimates the probability of default

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MACRO FACTORS IN BOND RISK PREMIA. Sydney C. Ludvigson Serena Ng. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MACRO FACTORS IN BOND RISK PREMIA. Sydney C. Ludvigson Serena Ng. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MACRO FACTORS IN BOND RISK PREMIA Sydney C. Ludvigson Serena Ng Working Paper 11703 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11703 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue

More information

Welfare analysis of currency regimes with defautable debt

Welfare analysis of currency regimes with defautable debt Welfare analysis of currency regimes with defautable debt December 30, 2011 Abstract We modify the Cole and Kehoe ([5], [6] and [7]) general equilibrium model with defaultable debt denominated in a foreign

More information

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH South-Eastern Europe Journal of Economics 1 (2015) 75-84 THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH IOANA BOICIUC * Bucharest University of Economics, Romania Abstract This

More information

FINANCIAL MARKETS IN EARLY AUGUST 2011 AND THE ECB S MONETARY POLICY MEASURES

FINANCIAL MARKETS IN EARLY AUGUST 2011 AND THE ECB S MONETARY POLICY MEASURES Chart 28 Implied forward overnight interest rates (percentages per annum; daily data) 5. 4.5 4. 3.5 3. 2.5 2. 1.5 1..5 7 September 211 31 May 211.. 211 213 215 217 219 221 Sources:, EuroMTS (underlying

More information

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Has the Inflation Process Changed? Has the Inflation Process Changed? by S. Cecchetti and G. Debelle Discussion by I. Angeloni (ECB) * Cecchetti and Debelle (CD) could hardly have chosen a more relevant and timely topic for their paper.

More information

HOW HAS CDO MARKET PRICING CHANGED DURING THE TURMOIL? EVIDENCE FROM CDS INDEX TRANCHES

HOW HAS CDO MARKET PRICING CHANGED DURING THE TURMOIL? EVIDENCE FROM CDS INDEX TRANCHES C HOW HAS CDO MARKET PRICING CHANGED DURING THE TURMOIL? EVIDENCE FROM CDS INDEX TRANCHES The general repricing of credit risk which started in summer 7 has highlighted signifi cant problems in the valuation

More information

Fiscal Consolidations in Currency Unions: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

Fiscal Consolidations in Currency Unions: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes Fiscal Consolidations in Currency Unions: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes Christopher J. Erceg and Jesper Lindé Federal Reserve Board June, 2011 Erceg and Lindé (Federal Reserve Board) Fiscal Consolidations

More information

Government Debt After The Crisis

Government Debt After The Crisis Government Debt After The Crisis Rome, July 24, 2009 I Motivation I I I I I Conclusion I Automatic stabilisers and discretionary policy led to huge increase in scal de cits I Equity stakes in banking

More information

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

1. Money in the utility function (continued) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (continued) a. Welfare costs of in ation b. Potential non-superneutrality

More information

Optimal Liquidation Strategies in Illiquid Markets

Optimal Liquidation Strategies in Illiquid Markets Optimal Liquidation Strategies in Illiquid Markets Eric Jondeau a, Augusto Perilla b, Michael Rockinger c July 2007 Abstract In this paper, we study the economic relevance of optimal liquidation strategies

More information

What Are the Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks? A VAR-Based Comparative Analysis

What Are the Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks? A VAR-Based Comparative Analysis What Are the Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks? A VAR-Based Comparative Analysis Dario Caldara y Christophe Kamps z This draft: September 2006 Abstract In recent years VAR models have become the main econometric

More information

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1 Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Philippe Bacchetta Eric van Wincoop January 10, 007 1 Prepared for the May 007 issue of the American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings.

More information

Mean-Variance Analysis

Mean-Variance Analysis Mean-Variance Analysis Mean-variance analysis 1/ 51 Introduction How does one optimally choose among multiple risky assets? Due to diversi cation, which depends on assets return covariances, the attractiveness

More information

Models of the TS. Carlo A Favero. February Carlo A Favero () Models of the TS February / 47

Models of the TS. Carlo A Favero. February Carlo A Favero () Models of the TS February / 47 Models of the TS Carlo A Favero February 201 Carlo A Favero () Models of the TS February 201 1 / 4 Asset Pricing with Time-Varying Expected Returns Consider a situation in which in each period k state

More information

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing Guido Ascari and Lorenza Rossi University of Pavia Abstract Calvo and Rotemberg pricing entail a very di erent dynamics of adjustment

More information

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing /49 Introduction We present models of asset pricing where investors preferences are subject to psychological biases or where investors

More information

Effective Tax Rates and the User Cost of Capital when Interest Rates are Low

Effective Tax Rates and the User Cost of Capital when Interest Rates are Low Effective Tax Rates and the User Cost of Capital when Interest Rates are Low John Creedy and Norman Gemmell WORKING PAPER 02/2017 January 2017 Working Papers in Public Finance Chair in Public Finance Victoria

More information

Melbourne Institute Working Paper Series Working Paper No. 22/07

Melbourne Institute Working Paper Series Working Paper No. 22/07 Melbourne Institute Working Paper Series Working Paper No. 22/07 Permanent Structural Change in the US Short-Term and Long-Term Interest Rates Chew Lian Chua and Chin Nam Low Permanent Structural Change

More information

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model T.Huw Edwards Dept of Economics, Loughborough University and CSGR Warwick UK Tel (44)01509-222718 Fax 01509-223910 T.H.Edwards@lboro.ac.uk

More information

Fiscal Risk in a Monetary Union

Fiscal Risk in a Monetary Union Fiscal Risk in a Monetary Union Betty C Daniel Christos Shiamptanis UAlbany - SUNY Ryerson University May 2012 Daniel and Shiamptanis () Fiscal Risk May 2012 1 / 32 Recent Turmoil in European Financial

More information

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies Nathan Foley-Fisher Bernardo Guimaraes August 2009 Abstract We empirically analyse the appropriateness of indexing emerging market sovereign

More information

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University Business School Seminars at University of Cape Town

More information

Quasi-Fiscal Policies of Independent Central Banks and Inflation

Quasi-Fiscal Policies of Independent Central Banks and Inflation CAEPR Working Paper #020-2009 Quasi-Fiscal Policies of Independent Central Banks and Inflation Seok Gil Park Indiana University October 30, 2009 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social

More information

EC3311. Seminar 2. ² Explain how employment rates have changed over time for married/cohabiting mothers and for lone mothers respectively.

EC3311. Seminar 2. ² Explain how employment rates have changed over time for married/cohabiting mothers and for lone mothers respectively. EC3311 Seminar 2 Part A: Review questions 1. What do we mean when we say that both consumption and leisure are normal goods. 2. Explain why the slope of the individual s budget constraint is equal to w.

More information

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Introducing nominal rigidities. Introducing nominal rigidities. Olivier Blanchard May 22 14.452. Spring 22. Topic 7. 14.452. Spring, 22 2 In the model we just saw, the price level (the price of goods in terms of money) behaved like an

More information

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice 1/ 57 Introduction Assuming that asset prices follow di usion processes, we derive an individual s continuous

More information

Lecture 3: Forecasting interest rates

Lecture 3: Forecasting interest rates Lecture 3: Forecasting interest rates Prof. Massimo Guidolin Advanced Financial Econometrics III Winter/Spring 2017 Overview The key point One open puzzle Cointegration approaches to forecasting interest

More information

Stock market information and the real exchange rate - real interest rate parity

Stock market information and the real exchange rate - real interest rate parity Stock market information and the real exchange rate - real interest rate parity Juha Junttila y Marko Korhonen January 26, 2010 Abstract The real exchange rate is one of the key fundamental macroeconomic

More information

Disentangling the Impact of Eurozone Interest Rate Movements on CEECs Business Cycle Fluctuations: The Role of Country Spread

Disentangling the Impact of Eurozone Interest Rate Movements on CEECs Business Cycle Fluctuations: The Role of Country Spread Disentangling the Impact of Eurozone Interest Rate Movements on CEECs Business Cycle Fluctuations: The Role of Country Spread by Ildiko Magyari Submitted to Central European University Department of Economics

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

How Do Exchange Rate Regimes A ect the Corporate Sector s Incentives to Hedge Exchange Rate Risk? Herman Kamil. International Monetary Fund

How Do Exchange Rate Regimes A ect the Corporate Sector s Incentives to Hedge Exchange Rate Risk? Herman Kamil. International Monetary Fund How Do Exchange Rate Regimes A ect the Corporate Sector s Incentives to Hedge Exchange Rate Risk? Herman Kamil International Monetary Fund September, 2008 Motivation Goal of the Paper Outline Systemic

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy

Optimal Monetary Policy Optimal Monetary Policy Graduate Macro II, Spring 200 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims Here I consider how a welfare-maximizing central bank can and should implement monetary policy in the standard

More information

Regime Switching in Volatilities and Correlation between Stock and Bond markets. By Runquan Chen DISCUSSION PAPER NO 640 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Regime Switching in Volatilities and Correlation between Stock and Bond markets. By Runquan Chen DISCUSSION PAPER NO 640 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES ISSN 0956-8549-640 Regime Switching in Volatilities and Correlation between Stock and Bond markets By Runquan Chen DISCUSSION PAPER NO 640 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES September 2009 Runquan Chen was a research

More information

Do Sticky Prices Increase Real Exchange Rate Volatility at the Sector Level?

Do Sticky Prices Increase Real Exchange Rate Volatility at the Sector Level? Do Sticky Prices Increase Real Exchange Rate Volatility at the Sector Level? Mario J. Crucini y, Mototsugu Shintani z and Takayuki Tsuruga x First Draft: July 2009, This Draft: March 2010 Abstract We introduce

More information

QUADRATIC TERM STRUCTURE MODELS IN DISCRETE TIME

QUADRATIC TERM STRUCTURE MODELS IN DISCRETE TIME QUADRATIC TERM STRUCTURE MODELS IN DISCRETE TIME Marco Realdon 5/3/06 Abstract This paper extends the results on quadratic term structure models in continuous time to the discrete time setting. The continuous

More information

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010 Booms and Busts in Asset Prices Klaus Adam Mannheim University & CEPR Albert Marcet London School of Economics & CEPR May 2010 Adam & Marcet ( Mannheim Booms University and Busts & CEPR London School of

More information

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles Conférence organisée par la Chaire des Amériques et le Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne, Université Paris I Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles Sarquis J. B. Sarquis

More information

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model Bianca De Paoli November 2008 1 Fiscal Policy in a New Keynesian Model 1.1 Positive analysis: the e ect of scal shocks How do scal shocks a ect in ation?

More information

Uncertainty and the Dynamics of R&D*

Uncertainty and the Dynamics of R&D* Uncertainty and the Dynamics of R&D* * Nick Bloom, Department of Economics, Stanford University, 579 Serra Mall, CA 94305, and NBER, (nbloom@stanford.edu), 650 725 3786 Uncertainty about future productivity

More information

MACROECONOMIC SOURCES OF RISK

MACROECONOMIC SOURCES OF RISK MACROECONOMIC SOURCES OF RISK IN THE TERM STRUCTURE CHIONA BALFOUSSIA MIKE WICKENS CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 1329 CATEGORY 5: FISCAL POLICY, MACROECONOMICS AND GROWTH NOVEMBER 2004 An electronic version

More information

Investor Information, Long-Run Risk, and the Duration of Risky Cash Flows

Investor Information, Long-Run Risk, and the Duration of Risky Cash Flows Investor Information, Long-Run Risk, and the Duration of Risky Cash Flows Mariano M. Croce NYU Martin Lettau y NYU, CEPR and NBER Sydney C. Ludvigson z NYU and NBER Comments Welcome First draft: August

More information

Value at risk models for Dutch bond portfolios

Value at risk models for Dutch bond portfolios Journal of Banking & Finance 24 (2000) 1131±1154 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Value at risk models for Dutch bond portfolios Peter J.G. Vlaar * Econometric Research and Special Studies Department,

More information

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle Antonio Conti January 21, 2010 Abstract While New Keynesian models label money redundant in shaping business cycle, monetary aggregates

More information

AN ANALYTICAL AND EMPIRICAL MEASURE OF THE DEGREE OF CONDITIONAL CONSERVATISM. Jeffrey L. Callen and Dan Segal October 10, 2008

AN ANALYTICAL AND EMPIRICAL MEASURE OF THE DEGREE OF CONDITIONAL CONSERVATISM. Jeffrey L. Callen and Dan Segal October 10, 2008 AN ANALYTICAL AND EMPIRICAL MEASURE OF THE DEGREE OF CONDITIONAL CONSERVATISM Jeffrey L. Callen and Dan Segal October 10, 2008 Rotman School of Management University of Toronto 105 St. George Street Toronto,

More information

Is the US current account de cit sustainable? Disproving some fallacies about current accounts

Is the US current account de cit sustainable? Disproving some fallacies about current accounts Is the US current account de cit sustainable? Disproving some fallacies about current accounts Frederic Lambert International Macroeconomics - Prof. David Backus New York University December, 24 1 Introduction

More information

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model Guido Ascari University of Pavia Nicola Branzoli University of Pavia October 27, 2006 Abstract This note shows that full price indexation

More information

Carbon Price Drivers: Phase I versus Phase II Equilibrium?

Carbon Price Drivers: Phase I versus Phase II Equilibrium? Carbon Price Drivers: Phase I versus Phase II Equilibrium? Anna Creti 1 Pierre-André Jouvet 2 Valérie Mignon 3 1 U. Paris Ouest and Ecole Polytechnique 2 U. Paris Ouest and Climate Economics Chair 3 U.

More information

Starting with the measures of uncertainty related to future economic outcomes, the following three sets of indicators are considered:

Starting with the measures of uncertainty related to future economic outcomes, the following three sets of indicators are considered: Box How has macroeconomic uncertainty in the euro area evolved recently? High macroeconomic uncertainty through its likely adverse effect on the spending decisions of both consumers and firms is considered

More information

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Liuren Wu Baruch College, City University of New York Joint work with Jian Hua 6th Annual Conference of the Society for Financial Econometrics June 12-14,

More information

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University Ithaca, NY 14853 yw57@cornell.edu Abstract

More information

Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation: Empirical Evidence for African and Asian Firms

Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation: Empirical Evidence for African and Asian Firms Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation: Empirical Evidence for African and Asian Firms Stephen R. Bond Nu eld College and Department of Economics, University of Oxford and Institute for Fiscal Studies Måns

More information

Predictability of Stock Market Returns

Predictability of Stock Market Returns Predictability of Stock Market Returns May 3, 23 Present Value Models and Forecasting Regressions for Stock market Returns Forecasting regressions for stock market returns can be interpreted in the framework

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

Risk Premia and Seasonality in Commodity Futures

Risk Premia and Seasonality in Commodity Futures Risk Premia and Seasonality in Commodity Futures Constantino Hevia a Ivan Petrella b;c;d Martin Sola a;c a Universidad Torcuato di Tella. b Bank of England. c Birkbeck, University of London. d CEPR March

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

A Macro-Finance Approach to Exchange Rate Determination*

A Macro-Finance Approach to Exchange Rate Determination* A Macro-Finance Approach to Exchange Rate Determination* Yu-chin Chen (University of Washington) Kwok Ping Tsang (Virginia Tech) April 2010 Abstract. The nominal exchange rate is both a macroeconomic variable

More information

Investments. Session 10. Managing Bond Portfolios. EPFL - Master in Financial Engineering Philip Valta. Spring 2010

Investments. Session 10. Managing Bond Portfolios. EPFL - Master in Financial Engineering Philip Valta. Spring 2010 Investments Session 10. Managing Bond Portfolios EPFL - Master in Financial Engineering Philip Valta Spring 2010 Bond Portfolios (Session 10) Investments Spring 2010 1 / 54 Outline of the lecture Duration

More information

Multivariate Statistics Lecture Notes. Stephen Ansolabehere

Multivariate Statistics Lecture Notes. Stephen Ansolabehere Multivariate Statistics Lecture Notes Stephen Ansolabehere Spring 2004 TOPICS. The Basic Regression Model 2. Regression Model in Matrix Algebra 3. Estimation 4. Inference and Prediction 5. Logit and Probit

More information

Network Effects of the Productivity of Infrastructure in Developing Countries*

Network Effects of the Productivity of Infrastructure in Developing Countries* Public Disclosure Authorized WPS3808 Network Effects of the Productivity of Infrastructure in Developing Countries* Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Christophe Hurlin ** Abstract

More information

Nonlinear Kalman Filtering in Affine Term Structure Models. Peter Christoffersen, Christian Dorion, Kris Jacobs and Lotfi Karoui

Nonlinear Kalman Filtering in Affine Term Structure Models. Peter Christoffersen, Christian Dorion, Kris Jacobs and Lotfi Karoui Nonlinear Kalman Filtering in Affine Term Structure Models Peter Christoffersen, Christian Dorion, Kris Jacobs and Lotfi Karoui CREATES Research Paper 2012-49 Department of Economics and Business Aarhus

More information

Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment

Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Jason Beeler and John Y. Campbell October 0 Beeler: Department of Economics, Littauer Center, Harvard University,

More information

The Japanese Saving Rate

The Japanese Saving Rate The Japanese Saving Rate Kaiji Chen, Ayşe Imrohoro¼glu, and Selahattin Imrohoro¼glu 1 University of Oslo Norway; University of Southern California, U.S.A.; University of Southern California, U.S.A. January

More information

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle: Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia May 31, 214 Midwest Macro Conference Raju Huidrom Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle Background

More information

The Economics of State Capacity. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th Tim Besley LSE

The Economics of State Capacity. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th Tim Besley LSE The Economics of State Capacity Ely Lectures Johns Hopkins University April 14th-18th 2008 Tim Besley LSE The Big Questions Economists who study public policy and markets begin by assuming that governments

More information