A Cautious Note on the Design of Volatility Derivatives

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Cautious Note on the Design of Volatility Derivatives"

Transcription

1 A Cautious Note on the Design of Volatility Derivatives arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 18 Jul 2010 Abstract Eckhard Platen and Leunglung Chan July 20, 2010 This cautious note aims to point at the potential risks for the financial system caused by various increasingly popular volatility derivatives including variance swaps on futures of equity indices. It investigates the pricing of variance swaps under the 3/2 volatility model. Carr with Itkin and Sun have discussed the pricing of variance swaps under this type of model. This paper studies a special case of this model and observes an explosion of prices for squared volatility and variance swaps. It argues that such a price explosion may have deeper economic reasons, which should be taken into account when designing volatility derivatives Mathematics Subject Classification: Primary 62P05; secondary 60G35, 62P20 JEL Classification: G10, G13 Key words: 3/2 volatility model, variance swap, numéraire portfolio, squared Bessel process 1 Introduction A significant source of risk in a financial market is the uncertainty of volatility. During the recent financial turmoil, volatility risk was of extreme importance to investors and derivative traders. Additionally, due to the large and frequent shifts in volatility of various assets in the recent past, there is a growing practical need to develop appropriate models for valuing volatility based financial instruments and hedging volatility risk. In 1993, the School of Finance and Economics and Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Technology, Sydney, PO Box 123, Broadway, NSW 2007, Australia, Eckhard.Platen@uts.edu.au School of Finance and Economics, University of Technology, Sydney, Australia; E- mail: Leunglung.Chan@uts.edu.au

2 E. Platen, L. Chan 2 Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) introduced a volatility index, the VIX, see Figure 1, based on the implied volatilities of options on the S&P 500 index, see Figure 2. The volatility of this diversified index has attracted the most attention in the current literature on volatility derivatives. As such, we take as the security of interest a similarly diversified equity index and study its volatility and related derivatives. Some of the pioneering papers related to volatility indices is Whaley (1993) Figure 1: VIX from 1990 to Figure 2: S&P 500 from 1990 to Variance and volatility swaps have been traded in over-the-counter markets since the collapse of Long Term Capital Management in late In particular, variance swaps on stock indices have been quoted and traded actively, and have been used as a hedge for volatility risk. Investors and fund managers alike, have developed an interest in volatility derivatives since these instruments may substantially increase the value of their holdings, even if the equity market experiences a major crash. At least theoretically, these derivatives can provide some protection against severe market downturns. How effective such portfolio insurance is, from a macro-economic view point, remains an open question. Particularly, when a large and increasing number of pension funds, insurance companies and other investors continue to request this type of insurance.

3 E. Platen, L. Chan 3 There exists substantial literature on volatility modeling, and one may refer to Cont and Tankov (2004) as one of the many references. Several papers, which explore stochastic volatility modeling, have pointed at the seemingly undesirable property of some squared volatility models, where their moments of higher order than one may become infinite in finite time. Examples are given in Andersen and Piterbarg (2007), Lion and Musiela (2007) and Glasserman and Kim (2010). Furthermore, there exist various papers discussing the problem of pricing and hedging variance swaps, including Brenner et al. (1993), Grünbuchler and Longstaff (1996), Carr and Madan (1999), Chriss and Morokoff (1999), Demeterfi et al. (1999), Brockhaus and Long (2000), Matytsin (2000), Javaheri et al. (2002), Swishchuk (2004), Howison et al. (2004), Carr et al. (2005), Windcliff et al. (2006), Zhang and Zhu (2006), Zhu and Zhang (2007), Sepp (2007) and Elliott, Siu and Chan (2007). Recently, CarrandSun(2007),aswellas,ItkinandCarr(2009)discussedin two interesting papers the pricing of variance swaps under the well-known 3/2 volatility model. Versions of 3/2 volatility models were studied, for instance, in Cox et al. (1980, 1985), Platen (1997), Ahn and Gao (1999), Heston (1999), Lewis (2000), Andreasen (2001), Platen (2001) and Spencer (2003). The current paper studies a special case of the 3/2 volatility model, and shows that the price of a variance swap explodes under this realistic model. This raises important questions on the design of variance swaps and other volatility index derivatives. The total face value of these derivatives can easily reach, in a few years, values on the macro-economic scale. This paper emphasizes that the consequences of such massive exposure of the economy to this strongly nonlinear type of leveraged position has to be prudently analyzed. It argues that the infinite price obtained for squared volatility as payoff, may have deep economic reasons. More precisely, in the case of a major market downturn there may not be enough liquid capital available in the financial system to deliver the payoffs demanded by the holders of squared volatility contracts and variance swaps on equity indices. Regulators and politicians have to be made aware of this looming problem within the financial system. For instance, in the case of a similarly severe market downturn, as experienced in the recent financial crisis, issuers of contracts paying uncapped squared volatility, as variance swaps on equity indices, could loose significantly more capital than liquidly available to them. Bailouts of financial institutions of similar magnitudes to those recently experienced may again be necessary to save or restore the functionality of the financial system. As will be proposed in this paper, the introduction of sufficiently high knock-out barriers would make, from a macro-economic perspective, derivative contracts more viable instruments and could prevent another looming financial crisis. The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 introduces variance swaps and

4 E. Platen, L. Chan 4 provides some remarks on the theoretical underpinning of the popular logcontract hedging. Section 3 studies the risk neutral 3/2 volatility model. Section 4 considers the real world 3/2 volatility model. Section 5 introduces real world pricing. The pricing of squared volatility as payoff is discussed in Section 6. Finally, Section 7 concludes. 2 Variance Swaps A variance swap is a forward contract on annualized variance, which is the square of the realized annualized volatility. Let σ0,t 2 denote the realized annualized variance of the log-returns of a diversified equity index or related futures over the life of the contract, such that σ 2 0,T := 1 T T 0 σ 2 udu. (2.1) Assume that one can trade the futures or index price at discrete times t i = i for i {0,1,...} with time step size > 0. The period between two successive potential trading times is typically the length of one day. If F ti denotes the equity index price at time t i, then the return G ti for the period before this time is defined as G ti = F t i F ti 1 F ti 1 (2.2) for i {1, 2,...}. In practice, variance swaps are often written on the realized variance evaluated from daily closing prices of the form ˆσ 2 0,t n := N n n i=1 ( G ti ) 2 N n n i=1 { ( )} 2 Fti ln := σ 0,t 2 F n, (2.3) ti 1 where T = t n = n i=1 (t i t i 1 ) = n, and N is the number of trading days N per year. Hence, variance swaps with idealized payoffs, depending on the realized variance, as defined in (2.1), are only approximations to those of the actual contracts. As indicated in (2.3), returns or log-returns may both be used to define payoffs on realized variance. Furthermore, by (2.1) and (2.3) it becomes clear that the basic elements of these types of payoffs are some form of squared volatility to be paid at a given time. This is why the paper focuses on the pricing of a payoff that delivers squared volatility. As is common in most of the literature, let (Ω,A T,A,Q) denote some assumed risk neutral, filtered probability space. Here Q is denoting the assumed risk neutral probability measure. The filtration A = (A t ) t [0,T] models the evolution of the market information over time, where A t describes the information available at time t [0,T]. Let K v denote the delivery price for realized variance and L the notional amount of the swap

5 E. Platen, L. Chan 5 in dollars per annualized variance point. Then, the payoff of the variance swap at expiration time t n is given by L( σ 2 0,t n K v ). Intuitively, the buyer of the variance swap will receive L dollars for each point by which the realized annual variance σ 2 0,t n has exceeded K v. Under the risk neutral approach, the value of the variance swap can be evaluated as the expectation of its discounted payoff with respect to the assumed risk neutral measure Q. This value is equivalent to the value of a forward contract on future realized variance with strike price K v. For simplicity, assume throughout the paper that the interest rate is zero. The risk neutral value of the variance swap ˆV at time t = 0 over the period [0,t n ] is then given by the expression ˆV = E Q [L( σ 2 0,t n K v )] = LE Q ( σ 2 0,t n ) LK v, (2.4) where E Q denotes expectation under the assumed risk neutral measure Q. Hence, the valuation of the variance swap relies on calculating the risk neutral expectation of the realized variance E Q ( σ 2 0,t n ). Note by (2.3) and (2.1) that this involves the computation of a sum of risk neutral expectations of squared volatility. Therefore, the problem can be reduced to evaluating the risk neutral expectation of squared volatility, as was mentioned earlier in the introduction. To highlight some of the critical issues with the current methodology, recall the popular log-contract hedging approach to realized annualized variance, for instance described in Neuberger (1994), Dupire (1993), Demeterfi et al. (1999) and Carr and Lee (2009). In the above literature the payoff σ 2 0,t n appearing in (2.3) is usually approximated by the expansion σ 2 0,t n = + n i=1 2N n ( 1 1 ) [ Ft0 (F ti F ti 1 )+ F ti 1 F t0 0 ] n n F t0 2N nk 2(F t n K) + dk N 3n i=1 G 3 t i + i=1 2N nk 2(K F t n ) + dk O(G 4 t i ), (2.5) wherethereturng ti << 1isassumedtobe small. HereO(G q t i )estimates a term that is smaller in absolute value than some constant multiplied by G ti q when G ti asymptotically vanishes. The first two terms on the righthand side of (2.5) are the profit and losses from a dynamic position in the equity index and a static position ( in options ) on the index. For the dynamic component, one holds 2N 1 n F ti 1 1 F t0 futures contracts on the equity index from day t i 1 to day t i. For the static component, one holds 2N dk European puts having a strike K dk below the initial index nk 2 value F t0. One also holds 2N dk European calls having a strike K dk nk 2 greater than the initial index value F t0. As such, one ends up holding more puts than calls. In the literature it is argued that the third and fourth

6 E. Platen, L. Chan 6 terms on the right hand side of the expression (2.5) represent the most significant source of error when approximating the payoff σ 2 0,t n. Note that the fourth power of the return appears in the remainder term. This paper emphasizes that the expansion (2.5) is of a pathwise nature and relies on the assumption that G ti is sufficiently small for all scenarios. This is a rather delicate assumption, as will be discussed below. It was shown in Platen and Rendek (2008), that the Student-t distribution with approximately four degrees of freedom is the typical estimated log-return distribution of diversified world stock indices when such indices are denominated in different currencies. Similar empirical evidence is provided in Markowitz and Usmen (1996a, 1996b). It is well-known that the fourth moment of the Student-t distribution with four degrees of freedom is infinite. In view of the expansion (2.5) this raises the important question whether the assumption of a vanishing remainder term in (2.5) is sensible in reality. Additionally, it will turn out that the real world 3/2 volatility model generates Student-t distributed log-returns for the equity index with four degrees of freedom. It is a fact that extreme log-returns of diversified equity indices occur in reality and under the 3/2 volatility model with a real world probability that is not negligible. One may question whether it is prudent to assume in (2.5) that G ti is always sufficiently small. More precisely, when pricing, one has to deal with expectations. Hence, the final termof(2.5)createsaprobleminthisrespect asitwillbeinfinitewhen taking expectation under realistic model assumptions that generate Student-t distributed log-returns with four degrees of freedom. Even when the degrees of freedom are slightly higher than four, thus generating theoretically a finite expectation, the corresponding expected value of annualized variance is still enormous. Therefore, extreme caution should be taken when pricing and hedging volatility derivatives using the type of expansion given in (2.5). To visualize this problem, Figure 3 exhibits the cumulative fourth term on the right hand side of (2.5), using S&P 500 daily log-return data, from 1990 until For instance, during the period September to October 2008 the term G 4 t i increased by approximately 300% in just a few days. This demonstrates, at least visually, that the fourth term in (2.5) cannot be simply neglected as a higher order remainder term. Some severe approximation error has to be expected when following the methodology described in (2.5).

7 E. Platen, L. Chan x Figure 3: The cumulative fourth term, n i=1 O(G4 t i ), using daily S&P 500 data from 1990 to Risk Neutral 3/2 Volatility Model The authors of the two interesting papers: Carr and Sun (2007) and Itkin and Carr (2009), derived under some assumed risk neutral probability measure a 3/2 volatility model as the generic stochastic volatility model that naturally emerges under two plausible assumptions. These assumptions are the, so called, stationary volatility ratio hypothesis and the maturity independent diffusion hypothesis. The first assumes that the ratio of the volatility of the variance swap rate to the instantaneous volatility of the underlying asset only depends on the variance swap rate and maturity, but does not depend on calendar time. The second hypothesis requires that the risk-neutral process for the instantaneous variance is a diffusion process whose coefficients are independent of the variance swap maturity date. For a detailed description of these assumptions and the derivation of the risk neutral 3/2 volatility model, the reader is referred to Carr and Sun (2007). This model, which will be described in detail further below, reflects well empirical evidence for short term volatility derivatives and realized volatility. Some of this evidence is provided in Poteshman (1998), Chacko and Viceira (1999), Ishida and Engle (2002), Jones (2003), Javaheri (2004), Bakshi et al. (2004) and Platen and Rendek (2008). Because of the strong empirical support that the 3/2 volatility model attracts this paper places it in a broader setting, and discusses it from a more general perspective. In particular, it studies its dynamics under the real world probability measure P. More precisely, it links it to the Minimal Market Model (MMM), described in Platen (2001) and Platen and Heath (2006). The MMM, being derived theoretically from macro-economic considerations, represents a 3/2 volatility model of the above type when formulated formally under some assumed risk neutral measure, as will be shown below.

8 E. Platen, L. Chan 8 As before, denote by F t the price at time t [0,T],T <, of the underlying asset, which one can interpret as a diversified equity index, for instance, the S&P 500 total return index. The instantaneous variance of this index shall be denoted by v t, which represents its squared volatility. To remain close to the work by Carr and his co-authors this section models the stochastic processes under some assumed risk neutral probability measure Q. It assumes, as in Carr and Sun (2007), that the equity index F t or its futures satisfies the following stochastic differential equation (SDE): df t = F t vt d Z t, (3.1) and its squared volatility v t the SDE: ( ) dv t = p(t)v t +qvt 2 dt+ǫv 3/2 t d W t, (3.2) t [0,T]. Here p(t), t [0,T], and q are assumed to be given real valued, deterministic quantities. Furthermore, Z = { Zt,t [0,T]} and W = { W t,t [0,T]} represent dependent Q-standard Wiener processes. The dependence between Z and W is modeled by the covariation [ Z, W] t = ρt, (3.3) for t [0,T], with given constant correlation parameter ρ [ 1,1]. One notes the power 3/2 for the squared volatility v t in the diffusion coefficient of the SDE (3.2) from which the model derives its name. It is well-known that the movements of the squared volatility of a diversified equity index are in reality strongly negatively correlated to those of the index itself. This stylized empirical fact has been known as the leverage effect, see Black (1976). Realistic calibrations identify a negative correlation parameter ρ relatively close to 1. Therefore, before going into the analysis of any multi-factor model, the authors of this paper consider it to be crucially important to clarify first the key properties of its most likely onefactor version. Therefore, the paper studies below a 3/2 volatility model where ρ = 1, and thus, a single Wiener process is driving the dynamics of the index, as well as that of its volatility. To be even more precise and avoid any ambiguity, it considers the one-factor model which follows from (3.1) by setting v t = αexp{ηt} F t. (3.4) Here α > 0 is a scaling parameter, and η > 0 will play the role of the long term average growth rate of the index F t under the real world probability measure P. This growth rate becomes important when one requests that the squared volatility process v = {v t,t 0} should have some stationary density under P.

9 E. Platen, L. Chan 9 The relation (3.4) yields, by (3.1), the SDE Ft αexp{ η df t = F t} 2 t d Z t = αexp{ η 2 t} F t d Z t (3.5) for t 0. Under the assumed risk neutral measure Q this is the SDE of a time transformed squared Bessel process of dimension zero, see Revuz and Yor (1999). One confirms by application of the Itô formula to (3.4) that by using (3.5) one obtains for v t a 3/2 volatility model with SDE ( dv t = d α exp{ηt} ) F t = αexp{ηt} F 2 t (F t vt d Z t ) + αexp{ηt} F t v t dt+η αexp{ηt} dt F t = v t ( η +v t )dt v 3 2 t d Z t (3.6) for t [0,T] with v t > 0. In particular, the squared volatility satisfies the SDE (3.2) for the parameter choice ρ = 1, p(t) = η, q = 1 and ǫ = 1. The squared volatility process characterized by the SDE (3.6) has nonlinear drift and diffusion coefficients. At first glance, this seems to make it difficult to obtain rather clear statements about its probabilistic properties. However, due to the fact that F t in (3.5) is a squared Bessel process, which is an extremely well-studied diffusion process, one knows analytically the probability law of v t and many other properties. To exploit this one may study the expression R t = α v t = F t exp{ ηt}, (3.7) as in Carr and Sun (2007), and obtains by the Itô formula the SDE dr t = α ) ] [v vt 2 t (η +v t dt v 3 2 t d Z t + α v 3 vt 3 t dt = ( αη α+α)dt+αv 1/2 t d Z t v t = ηr t dt+ αr t d Z t. (3.8) Under the assumed risk neutral measure Q, not only the squared Bessel process F but also thesquare rootprocess R = {R t,t [0, )}isofdimension δ = 0, see Revuz and Yor (1999). It is well-known that both processes hit the level zero with strictly positive Q-probability in any nonzero finite time period. In such an event the volatility explodes, see (3.7). This gives an indication that the expectation of the squared volatility v T = α R T may become infinite under Q. Indeed, the first negative risk neutral moment of the squared Bessel process R of dimension δ = 0 is infinite, see Revuz and

10 E. Platen, L. Chan 10 Yor (1999). Consequently, the risk neutral expectation of squared volatility has under the above 3/2 volatility model an infinite value, that is, E Q (v T ) =. (3.9) Thus, the typical payoffs that constitute the building blocks of a variance swap onadiversified equity indexdo notappear tohave afiniterisk neutral price under the above 3/2 volatility model. As mentioned in the introduction, other volatility models, in particular those that model the leverage effect, may create similar volatility explosions and infinite prices under an assumed risk neutral measure, see Andersen and Piterbarg(2007), Lion and Musiela (2007) and Glasserman and Kim(2010). The current paper focuses in the following on the aforementioned 3/2 volatility model to highlight the type of problems that can emerge under risk neutral volatility explosions. At this point it is appropriate to mention that the assumptions leading to the SDE (3.6) in relation to the parameter choice for the risk neutral 3/2 volatility model are slightly different from those imposed in Carr and Sun (2007) and Itkin and Carr (2009). In particular, these authors require in the SDE (3.2) that the relation q < ǫ2 holds. As a consequence, 2 the dimension δ of their square root process R under the assumed risk neutral measure Q is greater than two. Their condition aims to secure a zero risk neutral probability for the event that the volatility will explode in finite time. The current paper argues that there is no need to restrict the volatility dynamics to avoid a volatility explosion under some assumed risk neutral measure. Since the reasoning of Carr and his co-authors, who favour a 3/2 type volatility model, is rather compelling, it considers below a real world 3/2 model with the same structural properties that the risk neutral one suggests, however, adjusted to a description under the real world probability measure P. What really matters are the dynamics of the volatility process under the real world probability measure P. Under this probability measure the volatility should remain finite, as observed in reality. Still it should reach occasionally very extreme levels with nonnegligible probabilities. It has been shown in Platen and Heath (2006), and will be discussed in Section 5, that the formal risk neutral price of a nonnegative contingent claim can be significantly higher than the price to be identified in Section 5 under the real world probability measure, this price being the minimal possible price for a replicable contingent claim. This means, if there would be no volatility explosion under the real world probability measure, then there may still be a chance that the price of squared volatility, and thus that of a variance swap could remain finite for a 3/2 volatility model.

11 E. Platen, L. Chan 11 4 Real World 3/2 Volatility Model To study realistic dynamics of the underlying diversified equity index and its volatility under the real world probability measure, this paper adopts the benchmark approach described in Platen and Heath (2006). This approach is rather general and does not require the restrictive assumption on the existence of an equivalent risk neutral probability measure. It only assumes the existence of the numéraire portfolio, see Long (1990), Becherer (2001), Karatzas and Kardaras (2007) and Kardaras and Platen (2008). If there exists an equivalent risk neutral probability measure for a given model, then the benchmark approach recovers fully the results of the risk neutral approach. Otherwise, it still provides a sound pricing methodology, as will be explained in Section 5. Under the real world probability measure P one needs additionally to model the drift in the SDE for the real world dynamics of the diversified index F t. It has been shown in Platen (2005) that such a well diversified index of a large equity market is, under weak assumptions, well approximated by the numéraire portfolio. The numéraire portfolio is known to be the growth optimal portfolio of the market, which maximizes expected logarithmic utility, see Kelly (1956). This fact allows one to determine its SDE under the real world probability measure P by log-utility maximization. Assuming from now on that F t models the value of a continuous numéraire portfolio at time t, it follows that its volatility v t becomes the market price of risk, and its risk premium the squared volatility v t. Details on these statements can be found in Platen and Heath (2006). The SDE for F t under the real world probability measure P has the form: df t = F t ( v t dt+ v t dz t ). (4.1) Here Z t = Z t t 0 vs ds, (4.2) forms a Wiener process under the real world probability measure P, and vt is the market price of risk, which provides the link to the process Z. The squared volatility for the above 3/2 volatility model satisfies by (3.6) and (4.2) the SDE dv t = ηv t dt v 3/2 t dz t (4.3) for t [0,T], where Z is the Wiener process as given in (4.2) under P. The real world dynamics of the process Y = {Y t = 1 v t,t 0} of the inverse squared volatility is given by Y t = 1 v t = R t α = F t αexp{ηt}. (4.4)

12 E. Platen, L. Chan 12 Using the Itô formula one obtains by (4.4) and (4.3) for Y t the SDE ) dy t = (1 ηy t dt+ Y t dz t, (4.5) being a square root process of dimension δ = 4, see Revuz and Yor (1999). The only parameter in the SDE (4.5) is the net growth rate η. Note, by using (3.4) and (4.4) it follows that the index F t can be expressed as the product of an exponential function and a square root process of dimension δ = 4, that is, F t = αexp{ηt}y t (4.6) for t [0,T]. Obviously, the square root process Y has a stationary density. Furthermore, it is known that it never hits zero. Therefore, the above 3/2 volatility model has no volatility explosion because Y t is never hitting zero. Additionally, the parameter η can be interpreted as the long term growth rate of the discounted diversified equity index. This growth rate is the key macro-economic variable. To elaborate on the interpretation of the real world dynamics of the diversified index one notes from (4.6) and (4.5) that the index F t satisfies the SDE df t = αexp{ηt}dt+ αexp{ηt}f t dz t, (4.7) where Z is a P-Wiener process. Essentially, the deterministic drift in (4.7) models the increase per unit of time in the underlying fundamental value oftheequityindexf t. Ontheotherhand, theremainingmartingaletermin (4.7) reflects the speculative fluctuations of the index. This parsimonious model makes good economic sense, in particular, in the very long term. Remarkably, it has only two parameters, α and η. Furthermore, it coincides with the stylized MMM proposed in Platen (2001), see also Platen and Heath (2006) Figure 4: Logarithm of the discounted S&P 500 from 1920 to 2010.

13 E. Platen, L. Chan 13 Figure 4 shows the logarithm of the discounted S&P 500 total return index, observed inusdollarsfrom1920until March Onenotesits longterm growth with seemingly stationary fluctuations around the average growth. By taking the logarithm on both sides of (4.6) it follows that ln(f t ) = ηt+ln(y t )+ln(α). The slope of the fitted line in Figure 4 equals the net growth rate η, which turns out to be approximately 5% for the US market, see also Dimson, Marsh andstaunton (2002). The value ln(y t ) isthe logarithmof the square root process at time t and is modeled in (4.5) as a diffusion process with a stationary probability density. This fits well what one observes in Figure 4. The scaling parameter α can be fitted by ensuring that the average of Y t equals 1 η. Under the real world probability measure the above model appears to be a reasonable model for the dynamics of a well diversified equity index, e.g. the discounted S&P 500 total return index. Carr and Sun (2007) and Itkin and Carr (2009) use very different arguments, compared to the macro-economic argument presented above, to obtain a 3/2 volatility model. Recall that under the real world probability measure P the above square root process Y = {Y t,t [0,T]} has dimension δ = 4, and is a scalar diffusion process with stationary density that never reaches zero under P. Under the assumed risk neutral measure Q the dimension δ of R, and thus the dimension of the square root process Y, is zero. Consequently, there is a strictly positive risk neutral probability for the event that this process hits zero in a finite time period, see Revuz and Yor (1999). As a result, the measures Q and P do not have the same events of measure zero. This leads to the conclusion that under the above 3/2 volatility model the putative risk neutral measure Q is not equivalent to the real world probability measure P. In a complete market one has for the corresponding Radon-Nikodym derivative Λ Q t at time t the expression Λ Q t = ( Ft F 0 ) 1, (4.8) which forms under the above 3/2 volatility model the inverse of a squared Bessel process of dimension δ = 4 under P. It is well-known that in a continuous market this process is a local (A,P)-martingale but not a true (A,P)-martingale, see Revuz and Yor (1999). More precisely, Λ Q is a non-negative strict (A, P)-local martingale, and thus, a strict (A, P)- supermartingale. The above 3/2 volatility model is an example of a viable financial market model, as discussed in Loewenstein and Willard (2000), where the traditional notion of no-arbitrage, see Delbaen and Schachermayer (1998), cannot be verified. Therefore, a more general pricing method than the classical risk neutral one is needed to price derivatives.

14 E. Platen, L. Chan 14 5 Real World Pricing It is the aim of this section to price derivatives under the real world probability measure. Since an equivalent risk neutral probability measure does not exist under the above model, one can follow Platen and Heath (2006) and can use the numéraire portfolio as numéraire. In this context the following notion turns out to be crucial: [ ] U Definition 5.1 A price process U = {U t,t [0,T]}, with E T F T <, is called fair if the corresponding benchmarked price process Û = {Ût = U t F t,t [0,T]} forms an (A,P)-martingale, that is, ] Û t = E [Û T A t (5.1) for all 0 t T T. AsshowninPlatenandHeath(2006),inthegivengeneralsetting, whichassumes the existence of the numéraire portfolio process F = {F t,t [0,T]}, any benchmarked nonnegative portfolio is a supermartingale. The minimal supermartingale, which replicates a given benchmarked contingent claim, is the corresponding martingale. Since the minimal price is economically the reasonable price for a replicable claim, it is the fair price that should determine the value of a derivative if no other constraint exists. For a replicable contingent claim H T, payable at time T [0,T] with E( H T ) <, F T this yields the real world pricing formula ( ) V t = F t E H T A t (5.2) for all t [0, T], T [0,T]. Now, one can discuss the link between real world pricing and classical risk neutral pricing. As shown in Platen and Heath (2006), and as already indicated in (4.8), in a complete market the Radon-Nikodym derivative process Λ Q = {Λ Q t,t [0,T]} for the putative risk-neutral probability measure Q is given by the ratio F T Λ Q t = dq dp A t = F 0 F t. (5.3) Using this notion, one obtains from the real world pricing formula (5.1) the equivalent expression ( Λ Q ) T V t = E H T A t (5.4) Λ Q t for all t [0, T], T [0,T]. Recall that zero interest rates are assumed, for simplicity.

15 E. Platen, L. Chan 15 In a complete market the Radon-Nikodym derivative process Λ Q equals the normalized benchmarked savings account. If the savings account would be a fair price process, that is, a martingale, then the candidate Radon- Nikodym derivative process Λ Q would bean(a,p)-martingale. This would guarantee that the risk-neutral probability measure Q exists. In this case, one would obtain from (5.3) by the Bayes rule the standard risk neutral pricing formula with V t equal to E Q (H T A t ). However, when looking at discounted long term S&P 500 total return index data, one observes that Λ Q t exhibits in the long run much smaller values than at the beginning. This is a reflection of the existence of the equity premium. It suggests that it may not be realistic to interpret Λ Q as an (A,P)-martingale when modeling over long periods of time. Note that in the above 3/2 volatility model the Radon-Nikodym derivative is not a martingale because it is a strict supermartingale. Moreover, it follows from (5.3) by the supermartingale property of the Radon-Nikodym derivative that Λ Q t E t (Λ Q T) (5.5) for 0 t T T. Therefore, as indicated earlier, for any nonnegative contingent claim H T the application of formal risk neutral pricing would produce a price greater than or equal to the corresponding real world price. This can be seen when re-expressing (5.4) using (5.5) as the inequality V t E ( Λ Q T E Λ Q t ( Λ Q T Λ Q t H T A t ) A t ). (5.6) Theright handside oftheaboveinequality represents theformal riskneutral price, which can be substantially greater than the real world price. The concept of real-world pricing generalizes classical risk neutral pricing. It does not impose the restrictive condition that Λ Q has to form an (A, P)-martingale. As a consequence, real world pricing removes from the assumptions of Carr and Sun (2007) and Itkin and Carr (2009) the necessity to require the condition q < ǫ2, which prevented under the assumed 2 risk neutral probability the volatility from exploding. The freedom gained allows one to focus on the real world dynamics of the 3/2 volatility model, which is a realistic model from the perspective of short term volatility derivatives, as has been discussed in Carr and Sun (2007) and Itkin and Carr (2009). 6 Valuation of Squared Volatility Note that when pricing volatility derivatives one has to determine the expectations of payoffs or higher order moments of the squared volatility v T

16 E. Platen, L. Chan 16 at some maturity date T [0,T]. For the above 3/2 volatility model this can be achieved by using the explicitly known transition density of a time transformed squared Bessel process of dimension δ = 4, see Revuz and Yor (1999). For completeness, the transition density function p(ϕ t,x t ;ϕ T,x T) of a time-transformed squared Bessel process X = {X ϕt, ϕ t [ϕ 0,ϕ T]} of dimension δ = 4 is summarized below. It refers to a move from x t = X ϕt at some transformed time ϕ t to the level x T = X ϕ T at a later transformed time ϕ T. From Revuz and Yor (1999) one has the transition density 1 p(ϕ t,x t ;ϕ T,x T) = 2(ϕ T ϕ t ) ( x T x t )ν { 2 exp x } ( ) t +x T xt x T I ν 2(ϕ T ϕ t ) ϕ T ϕ t (6.1) for ϕ t [ϕ 0,ϕ T], where I ν is the modified Bessel function of the first kind with index ν = 1. For ϕ (0, ) one can show that the moment of order β has the value E(X β ϕ A 0) = { (2ϕ) β exp{ X 0 } 2ϕ k=0 ( ) k X 0 Γ(β+k+ δ 2 ) 2ϕ k!γ(k+ δ 2 ) for β > 2 otherwise. (6.2) Note for β 2 the corresponding moment does not exist because it is infinite. Let the ϕ-time be given in the form ϕ t = ϕ 0 + α ( ) exp{ηt} 1 4η (6.3) for t [0, ), see Delbaen and Shirakawa (1997). Given a squared Bessel process X of dimension δ = 4 in ϕ-time one obtains by setting X ϕt = F t the square root process Y = {Y t = Xϕ t,t [0, )} of dimension δ = 4 αexp{ηt} in t time for t [0, ). Recall that by (3.7) and X ϕt = F t one has the squared volatility in the form v t = αexp{ηt} X ϕt = 1 Y t, (6.4) which leads to the expression ( ) ( ) E v T αexp{η T} = E F T X 2 ϕ T ( 1 = αexp{η T}E X 2 ϕ T ). (6.5) Since β = 2, it follows by relation (6.2) that ( ) E v T = (6.6) F T

17 E. Platen, L. Chan 17 for 0 < T T. This provides the insight that even under real world pricing squared volatility as a payoff still demands an infinite price, which destroys the hope, formulated at the end of Section 5, that real world pricing may allocate a finite price to the squared volatility as payoff. Note that the volatility itself does not explode under P when using the real world 3/2 volatility model. It is the interplay between volatility and the index that creates a probability law which yields the infinite expectation in (6.6). The following discusses the question whether the above price explosion for squared volatility as a payoff is just a mathematical curiosity under the discussed model or whether it has deeper economic reasons, which should be taken into account in financial modeling and the design of volatility derivatives. Recall from (3.4) that the benchmarked squared volatility at time T is of the form v T F T = αexp{η T}. (6.7) F 2 T On the other hand, the benchmarked index remains simply a constant. If theindexf T falls, thenthebenchmarkedsquaredvolatility v T increases significantly and vice versa. More precisely, one observes an inverse quadratic F T relationship. One may wonder if such a strong nonlinearity in the payoff structure is sustainable in reality, in particular, from a macro-economic point of view. Potentially, in the coming years large pension funds and many other investors may seek protection against a downturn in the market by holding the floating part of a variance swap or a similar volatility derivative. To illustrate the looming problem, Figure 5 exhibits the normalized benchmarked squared VIX, from 1990 until One notes the enormous increase in September and October If one would simulate a corresponding scenario under the 3/2 volatility model, then the trajectory would have similar extreme spikes but also similar longer periods with relatively low benchmarked squared volatility. The benchmarked squared Figure 5: Normalized benchmarked squared VIX from 1990 to 2010.

18 E. Platen, L. Chan 18 volatility increased in Figure 5 by approximately 2, 000% during a short time period in This demonstrates the extreme movements that a benchmarked payoff of squared volatility can exhibit. If those financial institutions, which typically issue on a large scale volatility derivatives with benchmarked payoffs of the type (6.7), were to have most of their capital invested in the equity market, then the authors doubt that they would have enough liquid capital to deliver the demanded payoffs inthe event of a market crash of the kind seen in 2008, or even a more severe one such as the one before the great depression. It is probably reasonable to predict that when most large pension funds, insurers and many investors hold variance swaps on equity indices on a large scale, the market would suffer a liquidity crisis with major bankruptcies and it would probably need larger bailout funding than that provided during the recent financial crisis. The strong nonlinearity of the benchmarked payoffs would require crippling bailouts in the event of a decline in the index, as experienced with the great depression. In summary, the authors of this paper are deeply concerned about the rapidly developing exposure to volatility derivatives in financial markets. In particular, the currently traded standard variance swaps on equity indices could severely de-stabilize the financial system. The consequences of such destabilization should not be underestimated. Pensions could be lost to a large extent and large financial institutions may have to declare bankruptcy. It is certain that the global market will again move substantiallydownward inthelongrun. Thisissimply a consequence ofitsrandom nature. Professionals responsible for designing derivatives, politicians who need to safeguard their financial market, and regulators who oversee the provision of regulatory capital for institutions with derivative portfolios should take action to mitigate the systemic risks that could accumulate over the coming years due to a poor design of volatility derivatives. What is it that could help to reduce significantly the risks that have been pointed out above? Assume for the moment that there would be no bailout of large issuers of volatility derivatives in the case of a severe market downturn. One could then argue that even if the standard payoff structure of a variance swap on an equity index does not declare a knock-out barrier or cap, in reality, such a barrier is implicitly present due to the limited liquid capital and likely default of the issuer as a result of such a rare but extreme event. The introduction of some barrier in the design of the payoff would make volatility derivatives less expensive, and less risky for the issuer. It would also make the risks for both counter parties more transparent. Variance swaps designed for single stocks have often a cap, which acts in the direction indicated above. Such a cap is part of the design to cover the case of bankruptcy of the respective company. However, variance swaps on equity indices, which are of primary interest to institutional and large investors, typically do not have such a cap or knock-out barrier. One does typically not imagine that large parts of the industry that issues these instruments could face bankruptcy. To make these volatility deriva-

19 E. Platen, L. Chan 19 tives more realistic and even calculable, it should become mandatory that variance swaps on equity indices or similar payoff structures must include some knock-out barrier level. The volatility derivative payoff remains then bounded even when the equity index falls significantly below the knockout barrier and pushes the index volatility high up. Mathematically, such a knock-out barrier would make most common volatility derivative prices finite. The real world pricing formula of such a derivative with a knock-out barrier B would be of the form ( H(v T) Ṽ t = F 0 E 0 1 {τ> T} ), (6.8) F T where τ = inf{t 0 : F t < B} is the knock-out time. Here H(v T) is the payoff and B > 0 denotes the knock-out barrier level. One could set B slightly above the minimum level for the index, where the issuer of the derivative can most likely still serve its obligations in the case of a downturn. The price of the above barrier type option can be obtained by calculating the conditional expectation in (6.8) using standard numerical methods, for instance, finite-difference methods or Fourier and Laplace transform methods, described e.g. in Carr and Sun (2007) and Itkin and Carr (2009). 7 Conclusions This study has formally pointed at the potential risk of a liquidity crisis for the financial system that currently has been building up through various increasingly popular volatility derivatives, in particular, variance swaps on equity indices. It studies the case of the 3/2 volatility model and obtains infinite prices for payoffs delivering squared volatility. It has been argued that these price explosions may have deeper economic reasons. Consequently, care should be taken when designing volatility derivatives such as variance swaps on equity indices. The mandatory inclusion of knock-out barriers has been recommended to keep the emerging systemic risk manageable. BIBLIOGRAPHY Ahn, D.,& Gao, B.(1999). A parametric nonlinear model of term structure dynamics. Review of Financial Studies, 12, Andersen, L.B.G., & Piterbarg, V.(2007). Moment explosions in stochastic volatility models. Finance and Stochastics, 11, Andreasen, J. (2001). Credit explosives. working paper, Bank of America.

20 E. Platen, L. Chan 20 Bakshi, G., Ju, N., & Yang, H. (2004). Estimation of continuous time models with an application to equity volatility. Working paper, University of Maryland. Becherer, D. (2001). The numeraire portfolio for unbounded semimartingale. Finance and Stochastics, 5, Black, F. (1976). Studies in stock price volatility change. Proceedings of the 1976 Business Meeting of the Business and Economic Statistic Section, American Statistical Association, Brenner, M., & Galai, D. (1993). Hedging volatility in foreign currencies. Journal of Derivatives, 1, Brockhaus, O., & Long, D.(2000). Volatility swaps made simple. Risk, 2, Carr, P., & Madan, D. (1999). Introducing the covariance swap. Risk, February, Carr, P., Geman, H., Madan, D., & Yor, M. (2005). Pricing options on realized variance. Finance and Stochastics, 9, Carr, P., & Lee, R. (2009). Volatility derivatives. Annual Review Finance Economics, 1, Carr, P., & Sun, J. (2007). A new approach for option pricing under stochastic volatility. Review of Derivatives Research, 10, Chacko, G. & Viceira, L. (1999). Spectral GMM estimation of continuoustime processes. Working paper, Harvard University. Chriss, N.& Morokoff, W.(1999). Market risk of variance swaps. Risk, 12, Cont, R., & Tankov, P. (2004). Financial modelling with jump processes (1st ed.). Financial Mathematics Series, Chapman& Hall/CRC. Cox, J., Ingersoll, J., & Ross, S. (1980). An analysis of variable rate loan contracts. Journal of Finance, 35, Cox, J., Ingersoll, J., & Ross, S. (1985). A theory of the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica, 53, Delbaen, F., & Schachermayer, W. (1998). The fundamental theorem of asset pricing for unbounded stochastic processes. Mathematische Annalen, 312, Delbaen, F., & Shirakawa, H. (1997). Squared Bessel processes and their applications to the square root interest rate model. Working paper,

21 E. Platen, L. Chan 21 Department of Industrial Engineering and Management, Tokio Institute of Technology Demeterfi, K., Derman, E., Kamal, M., & Zou, J. (1999). A guide to volatility and variance swaps. The Journal of Derivatives, 6, Dimson, E., Marsh, P., & Staunton, M. (2002). Triumph of the Optimists: 101 Years of Global Investment Returns(1st ed.). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Dupire, B. (1993). Model art. Risk, September, Elliott, R. J., Siu, T.K., & Chan, L. (2007). Pricing volatility swaps under Heston s stochastic volatility model with regime switching. Applied Mathematical Finance, 14, Glasserman, P., & Kim, K.K. (2010). Moment explosions and stationary distributions in affine diffusion models. Mathematical Finance, 20, Grünbuchler, A., & Longstaff, F. (1996). Valuing futures and options on volatility. Journal of Banking and Finance, 20, Heston, S. (1999). A simple new formula for options with stochastic volatility. Technical report, Washington university of St. Louis. Howison, S., Rafailidis, A., & Rasmussen, H. (2004). On the pricings and hedging of volatility derivatives. Applied Mathematical Finance, 11, Ishida, I., & Engle, R. (2002). Modelling variance of variance: The square root, the affine, and the CEV GARCH models. Working paper, NYU. Itkin, A., & Carr, P. (2009). Pricing swaps and options on quadratic variation under stochastic time change models-discrete observations case. Review of Derivatives Research, In Press Javaheri, A., Wilmott, P., & Haug, E.G. (2002). GARCH and volatility swaps. Wilmott Magazine, Javaheri, A. (2004). The volatility process: A study of stock market dynamics via parametric stochastic volatility models and a comparison to the information embedded in option prices. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Mines ParisTech, Paris, France. Jones, C. (2003). The dynamics of stochastic volatility: evidence from underlying and options markets. Journal of Econometrics, 116, Karatzas, I., & Kardaras, C. (2007). The numeraire portfolio in semimartingale financial models. Finance and Stochastics, 11, Kardaras, C., & Platen, E. (2008). On the semimartingale property of

22 E. Platen, L. Chan 22 discounted asset-price processes. Working paper, University of Boston. Kelly, J. R. (1956). A new interpretation of information rate. Bell System Technical Journal, 35, Lewis, A.L. (2000). Option valuation under stochastic volatility. Finance Press, Newport Beach. Lions, P., & Musiela, M. (2007). Correlations and bounds for stochastic volatility models. Annales de I Institut Henri Poincaré, 24, Loewenstein M., & Willard, G.A.(2000). Local martingales, arbitrage, and viability: free snacks and cheap thrills. Econometric Theory, 16, Long, J.B. (1990). The numeraire portfolio. Economics, 26, Journal of Financial Matytsin, A. (2000). Modeling volatility and volatility derivatives. Working paper, Columbia University. Markowitz, H., & Usmen, N. (1996a). The likelihood of various stock market return distributions, Part 1: Principles of inference. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 13, Markowitz, H., & Usmen, N. (1996b). The likelihood of various stock market return distributions, Part 2: Empirical results. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 13, Neuberger, A. (1994). The log contract. Journal of Portfolio Management, Platen, E. (1997). A non-linear stochastic volatility model. Technical report, Australian National University, Canberra, Financial Mathematics Research Reports. FMRR Platen, E. (2001). A minimal financial market model. In Trends in Mathematics, Birkhäuser. Platen, E. (2005). Diversified portfolios with jumps in a benchmark framework. Asia-Pacific Financial Markets, 11, Platen, E., & Heath, D. (2006). A Benchmark Approach to Quantitative Finance (1st ed.). Springer Finance. New York: Springer. Platen, E. & Rendek, R. (2008). Empirical evidence on Student-t logreturns of diversified world stock indices. Journal of Statistical Theory and Practice, 2, Poteshman, A. (1998). Estimating a general stochastic variance model from option prices. Working paper, University of Chicago.

Law of the Minimal Price

Law of the Minimal Price Law of the Minimal Price Eckhard Platen School of Finance and Economics and Department of Mathematical Sciences University of Technology, Sydney Lit: Platen, E. & Heath, D.: A Benchmark Approach to Quantitative

More information

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case Guang-Hua Lian Collaboration with Robert Elliott University of Adelaide Feb. 2, 2011 Robert Elliott,

More information

Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions. Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid

Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions. Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid alejandro.balbas@uc3m.es Content Introduction. Describing volatility derivatives. Pricing and

More information

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing Rama Cont Yu Gu Abstract When the underlying asset is a continuous martingale, call option prices solve the Dupire equation, a forward parabolic

More information

A Brief Introduction to Stochastic Volatility Modeling

A Brief Introduction to Stochastic Volatility Modeling A Brief Introduction to Stochastic Volatility Modeling Paul J. Atzberger General comments or corrections should be sent to: paulatz@cims.nyu.edu Introduction When using the Black-Scholes-Merton model to

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching Science Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 2016; 4(6): 263-268 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/sjams doi: 10.11648/j.sjams.20160406.13 ISSN: 2376-9491 (Print); ISSN: 2376-9513 (Online)

More information

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I) Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I) Paul J. Atzberger General comments or corrections should be sent to: paulatz@cims.nyu.edu 1 Introduction When using the Black-Scholes-Merton model to price derivative

More information

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics The Third Western Conference in Mathematical Finance November 14, 2009 How should an investor trade

More information

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Hans U. Gerber and Gérard Pafumi Switzerland Abstract In the first part of the paper the surplus of a company is modelled by a Wiener process.

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

Lecture 5: Volatility and Variance Swaps

Lecture 5: Volatility and Variance Swaps Lecture 5: Volatility and Variance Swaps Jim Gatheral, Merrill Lynch Case Studies in inancial Modelling Course Notes, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences, all Term, 21 I am grateful to Peter riz

More information

Numerical Solution of Stochastic Differential Equations with Jumps in Finance

Numerical Solution of Stochastic Differential Equations with Jumps in Finance Numerical Solution of Stochastic Differential Equations with Jumps in Finance Eckhard Platen School of Finance and Economics and School of Mathematical Sciences University of Technology, Sydney Kloeden,

More information

Exploring Volatility Derivatives: New Advances in Modelling. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

Exploring Volatility Derivatives: New Advances in Modelling. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY Exploring Volatility Derivatives: New Advances in Modelling Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY bdupire@bloomberg.net Global Derivatives 2005, Paris May 25, 2005 1. Volatility Products Historical Volatility

More information

A Two-Factor Model for Low Interest Rate Regimes

A Two-Factor Model for Low Interest Rate Regimes QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE Research Paper 130 August 2004 A Two-Factor Model for Low Interest Rate Regimes Shane Miller and Eckhard Platen ISSN 1441-8010

More information

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

The Birth of Financial Bubbles The Birth of Financial Bubbles Philip Protter, Cornell University Finance and Related Mathematical Statistics Issues Kyoto Based on work with R. Jarrow and K. Shimbo September 3-6, 2008 Famous bubbles

More information

CEV Implied Volatility by VIX

CEV Implied Volatility by VIX CEV Implied Volatility by VIX Implied Volatility Chien-Hung Chang Dept. of Financial and Computation Mathematics, Providence University, Tiachng, Taiwan May, 21, 2015 Chang (Institute) Implied volatility

More information

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model American Journal of Theoretical and Applied Statistics 2018; 7(2): 80-84 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/ajtas doi: 10.11648/j.ajtas.20180702.14 ISSN: 2326-8999 (Print); ISSN: 2326-9006 (Online)

More information

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives John Crosby Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Presentation at Baruch College, in New York, 16th November 2010

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005 Valuation of Volatility Derivatives Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 005 Paris May 4, 005 he opinions expressed in this presentation are those of the author alone, and do not necessarily

More information

Hedging under arbitrage

Hedging under arbitrage Hedging under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics AnStAp10 August 12, 2010 Motivation Usually, there are several trading strategies at one s disposal to obtain a given

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis 1/18 : estimation and model analysis, EDHEC Business School (joint work with Rama COT) Modeling and managing financial risks Paris, 10 13 January 2011 2/18 Outline 1 2 of multi-asset models Solution to

More information

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models Alexander Cox 1 Jiajie Wang 2 1 University of Bath 2 Università di Roma La Sapienza Advances in Financial Mathematics, 9th January,

More information

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Martin Schenk Actuarial & Insurance Solutions SAV 7 March 2014 Agenda Introduction Deterministic vs. stochastic approach Mathematical model Application

More information

Interest rate models in continuous time

Interest rate models in continuous time slides for the course Interest rate theory, University of Ljubljana, 2012-13/I, part IV József Gáll University of Debrecen Nov. 2012 Jan. 2013, Ljubljana Continuous time markets General assumptions, notations

More information

Modeling and Pricing of Variance Swaps for Local Stochastic Volatilities with Delay and Jumps

Modeling and Pricing of Variance Swaps for Local Stochastic Volatilities with Delay and Jumps Modeling and Pricing of Variance Swaps for Local Stochastic Volatilities with Delay and Jumps Anatoliy Swishchuk Department of Mathematics and Statistics University of Calgary Calgary, AB, Canada QMF 2009

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU CBOE Conference on Derivatives and Volatility, Chicago, Nov. 10, 2017 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 11/10/2017 1 / 33 Interest Rates

More information

On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models

On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models Hao Xing Fields Institute/Boston University joint work with Erhan Bayraktar, University of Michigan Kostas Kardaras, Boston University Probability

More information

An Efficient Numerical Scheme for Simulation of Mean-reverting Square-root Diffusions

An Efficient Numerical Scheme for Simulation of Mean-reverting Square-root Diffusions Journal of Numerical Mathematics and Stochastics,1 (1) : 45-55, 2009 http://www.jnmas.org/jnmas1-5.pdf JNM@S Euclidean Press, LLC Online: ISSN 2151-2302 An Efficient Numerical Scheme for Simulation of

More information

The Pricing of Variance, Volatility, Covariance, and Correlation Swaps

The Pricing of Variance, Volatility, Covariance, and Correlation Swaps The Pricing of Variance, Volatility, Covariance, and Correlation Swaps Anatoliy Swishchuk, Ph.D., D.Sc. Associate Professor of Mathematics & Statistics University of Calgary Abstract Swaps are useful for

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach

Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach Steven L. Heston and Saikat Nandi Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 98-20 December 1998 Abstract: This

More information

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Week 13 Haijun Li Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Week 13 1 / 28 Outline 1 Simulation

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Pricing Volatility Derivatives under the Modified Constant Elasticity of Variance Model

Pricing Volatility Derivatives under the Modified Constant Elasticity of Variance Model Pricing Volatility Derivatives under the Modified Constant Elasticity of Variance Model Leunglung Chan and Eckhard Platen June 4, 25 Abstract his paper studies volatility derivatives such as variance and

More information

Model Estimation. Liuren Wu. Fall, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, / 16

Model Estimation. Liuren Wu. Fall, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, / 16 Model Estimation Liuren Wu Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College Fall, 2007 Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, 2007 1 / 16 Outline 1 Statistical dynamics 2 Risk-neutral dynamics 3 Joint

More information

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES Along with providing the way uncertainty is formalized in the considered economy, we establish in this chapter the

More information

RISK-NEUTRAL VALUATION AND STATE SPACE FRAMEWORK. JEL Codes: C51, C61, C63, and G13

RISK-NEUTRAL VALUATION AND STATE SPACE FRAMEWORK. JEL Codes: C51, C61, C63, and G13 RISK-NEUTRAL VALUATION AND STATE SPACE FRAMEWORK JEL Codes: C51, C61, C63, and G13 Dr. Ramaprasad Bhar School of Banking and Finance The University of New South Wales Sydney 2052, AUSTRALIA Fax. +61 2

More information

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery Peter Carr and Jiming Yu Courant Institute, New York University September 13, 2012 Carr/Yu (NYU Courant) Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery September 13, 2012 1 / 30 P, Q,

More information

Pricing Variance Swaps on Time-Changed Lévy Processes

Pricing Variance Swaps on Time-Changed Lévy Processes Pricing Variance Swaps on Time-Changed Lévy Processes ICBI Global Derivatives Volatility and Correlation Summit April 27, 2009 Peter Carr Bloomberg/ NYU Courant pcarr4@bloomberg.com Joint with Roger Lee

More information

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Local Volatility Dynamic Models René Carmona Bendheim Center for Finance Department of Operations Research & Financial Engineering Princeton University Columbia November 9, 27 Contents Joint work with Sergey Nadtochyi Motivation 1 Understanding

More information

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives John Schoenmakers 9th Summer School in Mathematical Finance

More information

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting Finance Stochast. 1, 251 257 1997 c Springer-Verlag 1997 A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting Tina Hviid Rydberg University of Aarhus, Department of Theoretical

More information

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets Markus Pelger October 21, 2016 Abstract We model asset prices in the most general sensible form as special semimartingales. This approach allows

More information

O N MODEL UNCERTAINTY IN

O N MODEL UNCERTAINTY IN O N MODEL UNCERTAINTY IN CREDIT- EQUITY MODELS Jan-Frederik Mai XAIA Investment GmbH Sonnenstraße 19, 331 München, Germany jan-frederik.mai@xaia.com Date: March 1, 1 Abstract Credit-equity models are often

More information

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Department of Banking and Finance University of Zurich April 22 2013 Math Finance Colloquium USC Change of the probability measure Change of

More information

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging Johannes Muhle-Karbe TU München Joint work with Jan Kallsen and Richard Vierthauer Workshop "Finance and Insurance", Jena Overview Introduction Utility-based

More information

Changing Probability Measures in GARCH Option Pricing Models

Changing Probability Measures in GARCH Option Pricing Models Changing Probability Measures in GARCH Option Pricing Models Wenjun Zhang Department of Mathematical Sciences School of Engineering, Computer and Mathematical Sciences Auckland University of Technology

More information

Estimation of Stochastic Volatility Models with Implied. Volatility Indices and Pricing of Straddle Option

Estimation of Stochastic Volatility Models with Implied. Volatility Indices and Pricing of Straddle Option Estimation of Stochastic Volatility Models with Implied Volatility Indices and Pricing of Straddle Option Yue Peng Steven C. J. Simon June 14, 29 Abstract Recent market turmoil has made it clear that modelling

More information

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance Alexander Cox Jiajie Wang University of Bath Bachelier 21, Toronto Financial Setting Option priced on an underlying asset S t Dynamics of S t unspecified,

More information

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation International Journal of Mathematics and Soft Computing Vol.5, No.2 (2015), 69-74. ISSN Print : 2249-3328 ISSN Online: 2319-5215 Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation Purity J. Kiptum 1,

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

January 16, Abstract. The Corresponding Author: RBC Financial Group Professor of Finance, Haskayne School of

January 16, Abstract. The Corresponding Author: RBC Financial Group Professor of Finance, Haskayne School of Pricing Volatility Swaps Under Heston s Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching Robert J. Elliott Tak Kuen Siu Leunglung Chan January 16, 26 Abstract We develop a model for pricing volatility

More information

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management Basic Concepts and Techniques of Risk Management Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

SYLLABUS. IEOR E4728 Topics in Quantitative Finance: Inflation Derivatives

SYLLABUS. IEOR E4728 Topics in Quantitative Finance: Inflation Derivatives SYLLABUS IEOR E4728 Topics in Quantitative Finance: Inflation Derivatives Term: Summer 2007 Department: Industrial Engineering and Operations Research (IEOR) Instructor: Iraj Kani TA: Wayne Lu References:

More information

A VALUATION MODEL FOR INDETERMINATE CONVERTIBLES by Jayanth Rama Varma

A VALUATION MODEL FOR INDETERMINATE CONVERTIBLES by Jayanth Rama Varma A VALUATION MODEL FOR INDETERMINATE CONVERTIBLES by Jayanth Rama Varma Abstract Many issues of convertible debentures in India in recent years provide for a mandatory conversion of the debentures into

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

Introduction Credit risk

Introduction Credit risk A structural credit risk model with a reduced-form default trigger Applications to finance and insurance Mathieu Boudreault, M.Sc.,., F.S.A. Ph.D. Candidate, HEC Montréal Montréal, Québec Introduction

More information

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017 VALUATION OF EQUITY WARRANTS FOR UNCERTAIN FINANCIAL MARKET FOAD SHOKROLLAHI arxiv:17118356v2 [q-finpr] 23 Nov 217 Department of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Vaasa, PO Box 7, FIN-6511 Vaasa,

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term.

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term. Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term. G. Deelstra F. Delbaen Free University of Brussels, Department of Mathematics, Pleinlaan 2, B-15 Brussels, Belgium

More information

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices Dmitry Kramkov (joint work with Peter Bank) Carnegie Mellon University and University of Oxford 5th Oxford-Princeton Workshop on Financial

More information

Valuation of a New Class of Commodity-Linked Bonds with Partial Indexation Adjustments

Valuation of a New Class of Commodity-Linked Bonds with Partial Indexation Adjustments Valuation of a New Class of Commodity-Linked Bonds with Partial Indexation Adjustments Thomas H. Kirschenmann Institute for Computational Engineering and Sciences University of Texas at Austin and Ehud

More information

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards Chapter 7 Forwards and Futures Copyright c 2008 2011 Hyeong In Choi, All rights reserved. 7.1 Basics of forwards and futures The financial assets typically stocks we have been dealing with so far are the

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

European option pricing under parameter uncertainty

European option pricing under parameter uncertainty European option pricing under parameter uncertainty Martin Jönsson (joint work with Samuel Cohen) University of Oxford Workshop on BSDEs, SPDEs and their Applications July 4, 2017 Introduction 2/29 Introduction

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU IFS, Chengdu, China, July 30, 2018 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 7/30/2018 1 / 35 Interest Rates and Volatility Practitioners and

More information

Estimation of the Diffusion Function for a Diversified World Stock Index

Estimation of the Diffusion Function for a Diversified World Stock Index Estimation of the Diffusion Function for a Diversified World Stock Index This version: 12 February 2011 Katja Ignatieva a, Eckhard Platen b a Macquarie University Sydney, Australia and Goethe University

More information

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration Denis Belomestny Weierstraß Institute Berlin Vienna, 16 November 2007 Denis Belomestny (WIAS) Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration Vienna, 16 November

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS Commun. Korean Math. Soc. 23 (2008), No. 2, pp. 285 294 EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS Kyoung-Sook Moon Reprinted from the Communications of the Korean Mathematical Society

More information

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling Interest rate modeling Abstract In this paper, three models were used to forecast short term interest rates for the 3 month LIBOR. Each of the models, regression time series, GARCH, and Cox, Ingersoll,

More information

No arbitrage conditions in HJM multiple curve term structure models

No arbitrage conditions in HJM multiple curve term structure models No arbitrage conditions in HJM multiple curve term structure models Zorana Grbac LPMA, Université Paris Diderot Joint work with W. Runggaldier 7th General AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference Lausanne, 7-10

More information

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay Solutions to Final Exam Problem A: (42 pts) Answer briefly the following questions. 1. Questions

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 18 Feb 2010

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 18 Feb 2010 CONVERGENCE OF HESTON TO SVI JIM GATHERAL AND ANTOINE JACQUIER arxiv:1002.3633v1 [q-fin.pr] 18 Feb 2010 Abstract. In this short note, we prove by an appropriate change of variables that the SVI implied

More information

Weighted Variance Swap

Weighted Variance Swap Weighted Variance Swap Roger Lee University of Chicago February 17, 9 Let the underlying process Y be a semimartingale taking values in an interval I. Let ϕ : I R be a difference of convex functions, and

More information

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Xiaoguang Wang STAT 598W January 21th, 2014 (STAT 598W) Lecture 3 1 / 51 Outline 1 Some model independent definitions and principals

More information

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments Tom Hurd Financial Mathematics at McMaster www.phimac.org Thanks to Tahir Choulli and Shui Feng Financial Mathematics Seminar

More information

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance Bernardo D Auria email: bernardo.dauria@uc3m.es web: www.est.uc3m.es/bdauria July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M The Financial Market The Financial Market We assume there are

More information

Statistical Models and Methods for Financial Markets

Statistical Models and Methods for Financial Markets Tze Leung Lai/ Haipeng Xing Statistical Models and Methods for Financial Markets B 374756 4Q Springer Preface \ vii Part I Basic Statistical Methods and Financial Applications 1 Linear Regression Models

More information

ESTIMATION OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS: MARKET VS. REPRESENTATIVE AGENT THEORY

ESTIMATION OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS: MARKET VS. REPRESENTATIVE AGENT THEORY ESTIMATION OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS: MARKET VS. REPRESENTATIVE AGENT THEORY Kai Detlefsen Wolfgang K. Härdle Rouslan A. Moro, Deutsches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung (DIW) Center for Applied Statistics

More information

Modeling the Implied Volatility Surface. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives and Risk Management 2003 Barcelona May 22, 2003

Modeling the Implied Volatility Surface. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives and Risk Management 2003 Barcelona May 22, 2003 Modeling the Implied Volatility Surface Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives and Risk Management 2003 Barcelona May 22, 2003 This presentation represents only the personal opinions of the author and not those

More information

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING Daniel Dufresne Centre for Actuarial Studies University of Melbourne November 29 (To appear in Risks and Rewards, the Society of Actuaries Investment Section Newsletter)

More information

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing We shall go over this note quickly due to time constraints. Key concept: Ito s lemma Stock Options: A contract giving

More information

A Closed-form Solution for Outperfomance Options with Stochastic Correlation and Stochastic Volatility

A Closed-form Solution for Outperfomance Options with Stochastic Correlation and Stochastic Volatility A Closed-form Solution for Outperfomance Options with Stochastic Correlation and Stochastic Volatility Jacinto Marabel Romo Email: jacinto.marabel@grupobbva.com November 2011 Abstract This article introduces

More information

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo Computational Finance Workshop, Shanghai, July 4, 2008 Overview Overview Single factor

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Asset Markets and Monetary Policy

Asset Markets and Monetary Policy Asset Markets and Monetary Policy Eckhard Platen 1 and Willi Semmler 2 June 5, 2009 Abstract. Monetary policy has pursued the concept of inflation targeting. This has been implemented in many countries.

More information

arxiv:cond-mat/ v2 [cond-mat.str-el] 5 Nov 2002

arxiv:cond-mat/ v2 [cond-mat.str-el] 5 Nov 2002 arxiv:cond-mat/0211050v2 [cond-mat.str-el] 5 Nov 2002 Comparison between the probability distribution of returns in the Heston model and empirical data for stock indices A. Christian Silva, Victor M. Yakovenko

More information

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

25857 Interest Rate Modelling 25857 UTS Business School University of Technology Sydney Chapter 20. Change of Numeraire May 15, 2014 1/36 Chapter 20. Change of Numeraire 1 The Radon-Nikodym Derivative 2 Option Pricing under Stochastic

More information

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Fuzzy Optim Decis Making 217 16:221 234 DOI 117/s17-16-9246-8 No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Xiaoyu Ji 1 Hua Ke 2 Published online: 17 May 216 Springer

More information

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE DOI: 1.1214/ECP.v7-149 Elect. Comm. in Probab. 7 (22) 79 83 ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS in PROBABILITY OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE FIMA KLEBANER Department of Mathematics & Statistics,

More information

Risk-Neutral Valuation

Risk-Neutral Valuation N.H. Bingham and Rüdiger Kiesel Risk-Neutral Valuation Pricing and Hedging of Financial Derivatives W) Springer Contents 1. Derivative Background 1 1.1 Financial Markets and Instruments 2 1.1.1 Derivative

More information

Valuation of Defaultable Bonds Using Signaling Process An Extension

Valuation of Defaultable Bonds Using Signaling Process An Extension Valuation of Defaultable Bonds Using ignaling Process An Extension C. F. Lo Physics Department The Chinese University of Hong Kong hatin, Hong Kong E-mail: cflo@phy.cuhk.edu.hk C. H. Hui Banking Policy

More information

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1 Computational Finance Computational Finance p. 1 Outline Binomial model: option pricing and optimal investment Monte Carlo techniques for pricing of options pricing of non-standard options improving accuracy

More information

A Consistent Pricing Model for Index Options and Volatility Derivatives

A Consistent Pricing Model for Index Options and Volatility Derivatives A Consistent Pricing Model for Index Options and Volatility Derivatives 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Society Thomas Kokholm Finance Research Group Department of Business Studies Aarhus School of

More information