The Sound of Many Funds Rebalancing

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Sound of Many Funds Rebalancing"

Transcription

1 The Sound of Many Funds Rebalancing Alex Chinco and Vyacheslav Fos December 5, 2017 Abstract This paper proposes that long rebalancing cascades generate noise in financial markets. There are two components to our analysis. First, to show that long rebalancing cascades can generate noise, we analyze a random-networks model where it s possible to predict whether a particular stock s demand will be affected by a long rebalancing cascade but not how the stock s demand will be affected due to computational complexity. Then, to show that long rebalancing cascades actually do generate noise in real-world financial markets, we study the end-of-day holdings of exchange-traded funds (ETFs). We demonstrate the existence of long ETF rebalancing cascades, and we document evidence of market participants treating the resulting demand shocks as noise. Taken together, these two components suggest that noise can be an externality imposed by a collection of funds following simple rebalancing rules and not just the result of individual investors who each behave randomly. JEL Classification. G02, G12, G14 Keywords. Noise, Indexing, Thresholds We thank Kerry Back, Nick Barberis, Zahi Ben-David, James Choi, Tony Cookson, Xavier Gabaix, Itay Goldstein, Sam Hartzmark, Ralph Koijen, Pete Kyle, Chris Parsons, and Jeff Pontiff as well as seminar participants at CalTech, Colorado, Illinois, Maryland, Yale, the Young Scholars Finance Consortium, the FINRA Market-Structure Conference, the SFS Calvalcade, the Conference on the Econometrics of Financial Markets, and the Helsinki Behavioral Finance Conference for extremely helpful comments and suggestions. Current Version: University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, College of Business; alexchinco@gmail.com. Boston College, Carroll School of Management; fos@bc.edu. 1

2 1 Introduction Noise makes financial markets possible but also makes them imperfect (Black, 1985). Imagine you re a trader who s just discovered that stock Z is under-priced. In a market without noise, there s no way for you to take advantage of this discovery. The moment you try to buy a share, other traders will immediately realize that you must have uncovered some good news. And, you won t find anyone willing to sell at the old price (Milgrom and Stokey, 1982). Noise pulls the rug out from under this no-trade theorem. In a market with noise, someone is always trying to buy or sell stock Z for erratic non-fundamental reasons. So, when you try to buy a share, it won t raise too many eyebrows. Because your buy order could just be some more random noise, other traders won t immediately realize that you must have uncovered some good news. The existence of this plausible cover story allows you to both trade on and profit from your discovery. But, where exactly does this all-important noise come from? Who generates it? And, what are their erratic non-fundamental reasons for trading? The standard answer to these two questions is that i) noise comes from individual investors, and ii) their demand looks erratic and unrelated to fundamentals because individual investors are just plain bad traders. These are the standard answers for a reason. Not only do individual investors suffer from all sorts of behavioral biases when they trade (Barberis and Thaler, 2003) but they also trade far too often (Barber and Odean, 2000). So, individual investors clearly generate noise. But, are they the only source? It seems unlikely. The role of individual investors in financial markets has steadily declined over the past few decades. To give one representative statistic, individual investors held 47.9% of all U.S. equity in 1980, but that percentage was down to only 21.5% in 2007 (French, 2008). Yet, we haven t seen a corresponding drop in trading volume. Motivated by this logical gap, we propose another noise-generating mechanism: long rebalancing cascades (stock A s price jumps, which causes a fund to buy stock A and sell stock B, which causes a second fund to sell stock B and buy stock C, which causes... ). There are two parts to our analysis. First, we analyze a random-networks model to show how long rebalancing cascades can generate noise. Then, to show that long rebalancing cascades actually do generate noise in real-world financial markets, we study the end-of-day holdings of exchange-traded funds (ETFs). Theoretical Model. Our hypothesis that noise comes from long rebalancing cas- 2

3 cades was sparked by a second trend that s shaped financial markets over the past few decades, the rise of index-linked investing (Wurgler, 2010). At the same time as individual investors were shrinking in importance, passive investing indexing was becoming popular as an alternative to active investment management, while active managers... were becoming more index-like in their investing (Stambaugh, 2014). In fact, the number of indexes now exceeds the number of U.S. stocks. 1 Most of these new index-like funds were not created in Jack Bogle s image, however. Many include stocks based on custom criteria, such as having low volatility or high dividends, 1 and involve threshold-based portfolio rules. For example, the PowerShares S&P 500 Low-Volatility ETF [SPLV] tracks the quintile of S&P 500 stocks with the lowest volatility. We say that this fund uses a threshold-based rule because an arbitrarily small change in a stock s volatility can move it from 101st to 100th place on the low-volatility leaderboard. When this happens, the low-volatility ETF has to exit its position in one stock and build a new position in another. This rebalancing activity will affect both the stock being added to as well as the stock being deleted from the low-volatility index in equal-but-opposite ways. For example, due to the additional buying pressure, the price of the stock being added will rise while the price of the stock being deleted will fall. So, because there are so many of these index-like funds tracking so many different threshold-based benchmarks, a small change in stock A s price can cause some fund to buy stock A and sell stock B, which can then cause a second fund following a different index to sell stock B and buy stock C, which can then cause... We use a random-networks model to theoretically study how this sort of alternating buy-sell-buy-sell sequence might result in apparently random demand shocks (a.k.a., noise) even though the individual funds are following simple deterministic rebalancing rules. Each node in the network corresponds to a stock. And, two nodes are connected with an edge, not if the corresponding stocks both belong to the same benchmark index, but rather if a change in one of the stock s characteristics would cause it to swap places with the other stock in some fund s benchmark index. Thus, a node with many edges corresponds to a stock that s on the cusp of a rebalancing threshold for many different funds. The model explains how, even if it s possible to compute the likelihood that stock Z will be affected by a long rebalancing cascade that starts with an initial shock to stock A, it can still be computationally intractable to predict the direction, buy? or sell?, of the resulting demand shock. 1 Bloomberg. 5/12/2017. There Are Now More Indexes Than Stocks. 3

4 Economists have long had the intuition that apparent randomness might just be the result of computational complexity. For instance, way back in 1921 John Maynard Keynes pointed out that, although the population of France isn t random, whether or not this number happens to be an even or odd number at any given instant may as well be. Yet, in the past, this intuition has remained just that an intuition. The goal of analyzing this random-networks model is to describe precisely why it s computationally intractable to predict how a long rebalancing cascade will affect the demand for stock Z in as transparent a way as possible. The goal is to give a concrete foundation for this long-held intuition, making it possible to identify other situations where the same logic applies. Rebalancing Cascades. After describing how long rebalancing cascades can transform simple deterministic rules into apparently random demand shocks, we next give empirical evidence that this transformation actually takes place in the real-world. With this goal in mind, we first pick both i) a particular group of funds following threshold-based strategies and ii) a set of initial shocks. Then, we show that, in the wake of these initial shocks, it s possible to compute which stock Zs are most likely to be hit by a long rebalancing cascade involving this group of funds but not the direction of the resulting demand shock. For our particular group of funds, we study ETFs. This might seem like an odd choice at first. If you ask a random person on the street to name an ETF, you re probably going to get The SPDR S&P 500 ETF [SPY] for an answer. But, while this is the oldest and most well-known ETF, it is no longer representative of the industry as a whole. The vast majority of ETFs now track niche self-defined indexes. A recent article in the Financial Times described how Exxon Mobile was held by ETFs following numerous threshold-based indexes like active beta, momentum, dividend growth, deep value, quality, and total earnings. 2 And, more and more people are talking about how ETF rebalancing can influence trading in individual stocks. 3 We get data on each ETF s end-of-day portfolio holdings from XpressFeed. This data covers every trading day from January 2010 to December We restrict our sample to include only those ETFs that rebalance their positions daily think about the PowerShares S&P 500 Low-Volatility ETF rather than the SPDR S&P 500 ETF. To be sure, these ETFs are smaller than the broad market-index funds, but their rebalancing activity can still affect the underlying stocks because they tend 2 Financial Times. 10/7/2017. On The Perverse Economic Effects Created by ETFs. 3 Bloomberg. 4/10/2015. Tail Can Wag Dog When ETFs Influence Single Stocks, Goldman Says. 4

5 to do their trading during the final 20 or 30 minutes of the trading day. 4 It s also important to emphasize that we net out changes in ETF holdings due to creations and redemptions, which are executed as in-kind transfers for tax reasons (Madhavan, 2016) and so can t generate the distortions that underpin long rebalancing cascades. Then, for our set of initial shocks, we use M&A announcements, referring to the target of the announcement as stock A. This data comes from Thomson Financial. M&A deals are a natural choice for the initial shocks because, in the words of Andrade et al. (2001), a profusion of event studies has demonstrated that mergers seem to create shareholder value, with most of the gains accruing to the target company. While M&A targets are certainly not random, the exact date of the announcement (Tuesday, Wednesday, or Thursday?) effectively is. Here s how we structure our empirical tests. Following the announcement of each stock A as an M&A target, we collect the set of stock Zs that are unrelated to stock A. For a stock Z to be unrelated to a particular stock A, it has to be twice removed in the network of ETF holdings at the time of the M&A announcement. It can t have been recently held by any ETF that also recently held stock A. And, it can t have been held by any ETF that also held a stock that was held by another ETF that held stock A. The chain has to be A B C Z or longer. Note that, because there are smart-beta ETFs focusing on large-cap, value, and industry-specific benchmarks, this twice-removed criteria implies that the set of stock Zs doesn t share well-known characteristics such as size, book-to-market, or industry with the stock A. The random-networks model we study suggests that, all else equal, a stock that is on the cusp of more funds respective rebalancing thresholds will be more likely to be hit by a long rebalancing cascade. So, we split each set of stock Zs into two subsets: those with an above-median number of neighboring stocks, which are on the cusp of many different ETFs rebalancing thresholds, and those with a belowmedian number, which aren t. Consistent with our economic story, we find that ETF rebalancing volume grows by 169% more for the above-median group of stock Zs than for the below-median group in the 5 days immediately following an M&A announcement. But, we also find that this percentage increase in ETF order flow is no more likely to be made up of buy orders than of sell orders. In other words, we document that it s possible to predict which stock Zs are most likely to be affected by a long ETF rebalancing cascade but not the direction of the resulting demand shock. Demand Noise. Finally, after showing that long ETF rebalancing cascades are 4 Wall Street Journal. 5/27/2015. Stock-Market Traders Pile In at the Close. 5

6 equally likely to result in buy and sell orders for stock Z from a statistical perspective, we conclude our analysis by giving supporting evidence that market participants also treat the demand shocks coming from long ETF rebalancing cascades as noise. Specifically, we find that above-median subset of stock Zs tends to have higher liquidity than the below-median subset. This result is consistent with a model where the above-median stock Zs has higher demand-noise volatility. 1.1 Related Literature This paper connects to three main strands of literature. Noise. The problem we study is motivated by the central role that noise plays in asset-pricing theory. Noise plays a starring role in your favorite information-based asset pricing (Grossman and Stiglitz, 1980; Hellwig, 1980; Admati, 1985; Kyle, 1985) or limits-to-arbitrage model (Shleifer and Summers, 1990; Shleifer and Vishny, 1997; Gromb and Vayanos, 2010). This paper proposes an explanation for noise that does not rely on individual investors behaving randomly. Indexing. Our proposed explanation then connects our paper to the literature on index inclusion (Wurgler, 2010). These papers can be classified into two broad groups. The first group studies the predictable effects of stock A s inclusion in an index for stock A itself. For instance, Chang et al. (2014) shows that getting added to the Russell 2000 results in a price increase. For other examples involving ETFs, see Ben-David et al. (2016), Brown et al. (2016), and Israeli et al. (2017). The second group studies the predictable change in the correlation between the behavior of stocks A and B after stock A gets added to an index that stock B already belongs to. For instance, Barberis et al. (2005) shows that a stock s beta with the S&P 500 jumps sharply after it gets added to the index. For other well-known examples, see Greenwood and Thesmar (2011), Vayanos and Woolley (2013), and Anton and Polk (2014). In contrast to these papers, we focus on the unpredictable consequences of stock A s index inclusion for an unrelated stock Z as highlighted in Figure 1. Thresholds. And, this explanation implies that noise can be an externality imposed by funds following many different threshold-based rebalancing rules, which further connects our analysis to work studying simple financial decision rules. While we focus on ETFs, our central insight also applies to quantitative hedge funds following strategies like value and momentum (Khandani and Lo, 2007; Lou and Polk, 2013) and pension funds with strict portfolio mandates (Pennacchi and Rastad, 2011). Many 6

7 Amplification: Comovement: Demand Noise: (this paper) A buy A buy A buy A buy B buy B sell B sell C buy C buy Z sell Z buy Figure 1: How This Paper Is Different. There is an existing literature on index-linked investing. Papers in this literature fall into two broad groups. The first group studies how supplementary trading due to index inclusion can amplify initial shocks to stock A (Row 1). The second group of papers studies how stock A s returns suddenly move a lot more like stock B s returns whenever stock A and stock B happen to belong to the same index (Row 2). By contrast, this paper focuses on the unpredictable consequences of stock A s index inclusion, not for stock A or stock B, but for a seemingly unrelated stock Z (Rows 3 and 4). of these funds use strict portfolio rules with the form: Buy the top 30% and sell the bottom 30% of stocks when sorting on X. More generally, people use threshold-based rules to make all sorts of financial decisions (Gabaix, 2014). The existing literature measures the cost of using an overly simple rule in terms of losses in expected utility. Whereas, we look at how simple decision rules can affect demand volatility. 2 Theoretical Model This section introduces a random-networks model where stocks (the nodes) are connected to one another via fund rebalancing rules (the edges). In the model, an initial shock to a randomly selected stock A has the potential to trigger a long rebalancing cascade if there are many different funds following many different rebalancing rules. The model is designed to explain why predicting the effect of a long rebalancing cascade on the demand for any particular stock Z is computationally infeasible, making the resulting demand shock seem like noise. 2.1 Model Setup Here s how the random-networks model is set up. Nodes, Edges, and Neighbors. Consider a market with S 1 stocks indexed by s {1,..., S} def = S. Each of these stocks will correspond to a node in our network. In the analysis below, we will often look at the limiting case as the market gets infinitely 7

8 large, S. We will often refer to arbitrary stocks A, B, C,..., s, s,..., Z S when describing properties of the network. In addition to the S stocks, this market also contains a large collection of funds following a diverse collection of rebalancing rules equivalently, tracking a diverse collection of benchmark indexes. These rebalancing rules will define the edges in our network. Two nodes will be connected with an edge, not if the corresponding stocks are held by the same fund, but rather if a shock to one of the stocks would cause some fund to swap out its position in that stock for a new position in the other. If stock s and stock s share an edge, then we will call them neighbors. A node with many neighbors corresponds to a stock on the cusp of many funds rebalancing thresholds. def We use N s to denote stock s s neighbors and N s = N s to denote the size of this set. All neighbors are not created equal, though. To illustrate, consider the situation where stock s and stock s are the 2001st and 2000th largest stocks in the Russell universe. On one hand, a positive shock to stock A has the potential to move it from 2001st to 2000th position in the Russell ecosystem, which would force any fund tracking the Russell 2000 to swap its existing position in stock B for a new position in stock s. But, on the other hand, if stock s dropped from 2001st to 2002nd position, then these same funds wouldn t have to change a thing. With this asymmetry in mind, we use directed edges. If a negative shock to stock s would cause some funds to sell stock s and buy stock s, then we will draw an arrow from stock s to stock s. Whereas, if a positive shock to stock s would cause some fund to buy stock s and sell stock s, then we will draw an arrow from stock s to stock s. An arrow will always point towards the stock that realizes a positive shock. This distinction divides each stock s collection of neighbors into two different subsets. If s N + s, then there is an arrow pointing from stock s to stock s. This means that either a negative shock to stock s or a positive shock to stock s would cause some fund to dump its position in stock s and build a new position in stock s. We refer to this set as stock s s positive neighbors. Conversely, if s N s, then there is an arrow pointing from stock s to stock s. This means that either a positive shock to stock s or a negative shock to stock s would cause some fund to dump its position in stock s and build a new position in stock s. We refer to this set as stock s s negative neighbors. Clearly, if stock s is a positive neighbor to stock s, then stock s is a negative neighbor to stock s. Figure 2 gives some small-scale examples of this network structure. Degree Distribution. We want our random-networks model to capture the idea that 8

9 B C A N + A N A N A Figure 2: Nodes, Edges, and Neighbors. Nodes denote the same 3 stocks (A, B, and C) in various network configurations. Table reports number of neighbors for stock A in each configuration. There is an arrow from stock A to stock B if a negative shock to stock A would result in a positive shock to stock B or a positive shock to stock B would result in a negative shock to stock A. If there is an arrow from stock B to stock A, then stock B is a positive neighbors to stock A, B N + A. If there is an arrow from stock A to stock B, then stock B is a negative neighbor to stock A, B N A. long rebalancing cascades are possible if there are many funds following many different trading strategies. In this setting, nodes in the network will be densely connected to one another via a large number of edges. Ideally, there would be a single parameter that controls how dense these connections are i.e., a single parameter that controls how likely it is that two stocks are on the cusp of some fund s rebalancing rule. A natural way to do this is to study a family of random networks whose edges have been assigned according to some probabilistic rule. Then, a single parameter can control the likelihood that an edge connects any randomly selected ordered pair of stocks. We will assume that i) there is an arrow from stock s to stock s with probability κ/s for some parameter 0 κ < log(s) and that ii) the presence or absence of an arrow between any two stocks will be independent of the presence or absence of any other arrow. Given these two assumptions, the number of positive and negative neighbors for each stock s will obey a Poisson distribution as S : N ± s Poisson(κ) (1) See Appendix A for details. Again, this statistical rule is helpful because it means that market connectedness can be summarized using a single parameter: κ = E[N ± s ] (2) If κ 0, then the market is fragmented; the typical stock will tend to have very few neighbors. By contrast, if κ 0, then the market is densely connected. State Variables. We ve just seen how stocks in the model are connected to one 9

10 another via a network formed by various funds respective rebalancing rules. But, what we really want to know is: How do these connections propagate shocks through the market from one stock to the next? So, we need to introduce a set of state variables to keep track of how each stock has been affected by the network. X A s (t) { 1, 0, + 1} denote the current state of stock s following an initial shock to stock A at time t = 1. If X A s (t) = +1, then a rebalancing cascade has caused some fund to build a new position in stock s. Whereas, if X A s (t) = 1, then the opposite outcome has taken place, and a rebalancing cascade has caused some fund to exit its position in stock s. We will use the convention that all S stocks start out in their original state at time t = 0: Let X A s (0) = 0 for all s {1,..., S} (3) Then, at time t = 1, we assume that nature randomly selects one of the S stocks in the market and changes its state. We will refer to this randomly selected initial stock as stock A and assume that the initial shock is positive without loss of generality: X A A (1) = X A A (1) X A A (0) = +1 (4) Updating Rule. To see whether the state of stock s at time t will be affected by a rebalancing cascade that started with an initial shock to stock A at time t = 1, we first identify the subset of stock s s neighbors which realized shocks with the appropriate sign at time (t 1): U + def A s (t) = { s N s + X A s (t 1) < 0, s / U A s (t 1) } (5a) U def A s (t) = { s Ns X A s (t 1) > 0, s / U + A s (t 1) } (5b) Recall that a fund s rebalancing decision will have equal-buy-opposite effects on the stock being added to and the stock being removed from its portfolio. So, U + A s (t) represents the set of positive neighbors to stock s which realized negative shocks at time (t 1); whereas, U A s (t) represents the set of negative neighbors to stock s which realized positive shocks at time (t 1). The additional restrictions that s / U A s (t 1) and s / U + A s (t 1) in Equations (5a) and (5b) prevent a time (t 2) shock to stock s from affecting stock s at time (t 1) and then immediately rebounding back again to affect stock s at time t. Without this additional restriction, a rebalancing cascade would not have a well-defined direction. Finally, we use U A s (t) def = U + A s (t) U A s (t) to denote the combined set containing both kinds of recently updated neighbors for stock s at time t and assume U A s (1) = U A s (0) = 0 for all s S as initial conditions. 10

11 Then, following an initial shock to stock A at time t = 1, we compute the state of each stock s at times t 2 as follows: U A s (t) def = sign [ s U A s (t) X A s (t 1) ] (6a) X A s (t) = sign[x A s (t 1) U A s (t)] (6b) The state of stock s can change in 3 different ways at time t in response to an initial shock to stock A at time t = 1. First, stock s can realize a negative shock, X A s (t) 0, if most of its recently updated neighbors just realized positive shocks, U A s (t) = +1. This is what happens when several of stock s s neighbors get added to various benchmark indexes at stock s s expense. Second, stock s can realize a positive shock, X A s (t) 0, if most of its recently updated neighbors just realized negative shocks, U A s (t) = 1. This is what happens when stock s gets added to several funds benchmark indexes. And third, stock s might realize no shock at all, X A s (t) = 0, if the positive and negative shocks to its recently updated neighbors exactly cancel each other out, U A s (t) = 0. Color Coding. If stock s N s +, then we will draw an arrow from stock s to stock s in our diagrams, s s. But, there are two ways that this edge could transmit a shock. Stock s could be positively affected by a negative shock to stock s, or stock s could be negatively affected by a positive shock to stock s. We use colors to distinguish between these two possibilities, using the convention that edges in a cascade will always have a different color than the stock that initiated the rebalancing decision. We will represent cases where a negative shock to stock s causes some fund to sell stock s and buy stock s as s s. By contrast, we will represent cases where a positive shock to stock s causes the same fund to buy stock s and sell stock s as s s. Discussion. At this point, we re done describing the model s setup. But, before moving on to the model s analysis, it s worth pausing for a moment to talk about two important details. The first is that the model doesn t include a constrained optimization problem, which is unusual for theoretical models in economics. Economists usually apply network theory by adding a network structure to an existing assetpricing model and showing that this additional structure distorts how agents were previously solving their original constrained optimization problem (e.g., see Duffie et al., 2009; Ozsoylev and Walden, 2011; Atkeson et al., 2015). But, we re trying to make a different kind of point. We re trying to show that long rebalancing cascades can qualitatively change the 11

12 A B C A B C A B C A B C A B C X A A (t) X B A (t) X C A (t) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 t = 3 t = Figure 3: Feedback Effects. An example rebalancing cascade on a network with 3 stocks. An arrow from stock B to stock A means that stock B is positive neighbor for stock A, B N + A. A node is colored blue if X A s(t) = +1; it s colored red if X A s (t) = 1; and, it s colored black if X s,a (t) = 0. At time t = 0, all 3 stocks start out with unchanged fundamentals, X A s (0) = 0 for all s {A, B, C}. At time t = 1, stock A realizes a positive shock, X A A (1) = +1, which is denotes by a blue star. This initial shock causes a fund to rebalance its position at time t = 2, buying stock A and selling stock B so that X A B (2) = 1. This secondary shock causes another fund to rebalance its position at time t = 3, selling stock B and buying stock C so that X A C (3) = +1. Finally, this tertiary shock causes one last fund to rebalance its position at time t = 4, buying stock C and selling stock A so that X A A (4) = 1. kind of constrained optimization problem that agents have to solve by introducing noise. More is different. And, the goal of the model is to show why. How is it that long cascades are able to turn simple deterministic rebalancing rules into apparently random demand shocks? This is a question about how stocks in the model are connected to one another not about any particular optimization problem agents are solving. So, we ve structured our model accordingly. The second important detail is that our model allows for feedback effects as illustrated in Figure 3. An initial positive shock to stock A might force a size-based fund to buy stock A and sell stock B, which might force a momentum-based fund to sell stock B and buy stock C, which might force a volatility-based fund to buy stock C and sell stock A, bringing the cascade full circle. Feedback effects are going to play a central role in the analysis below. But, it is crucial to point out that this loop stops once it returns to stock A. The updating rule in Equation (6a) implies that stock B s state will remain unchanged so long as X A A (t) = 0, which in turn implies that a rebalancing cascade can last no more than T def = (S + 1) periods. We ve made infinite feedback loops off limits to make our theoretical analysis more straightforward. But, rebalancing cascades would 12

13 clearly be more complex if they contained infinite feedback loops. So, if anything, this assumption that we ve made for analytical tractability works against us. 2.2 Likelihood We want to show that, while it s possible to compute which stocks are most likely to be hit by a long rebalancing cascade, it s computationally infeasible to predict the direction of this impact. So, in this subsection, we start by characterizing the probability that a particular stock will be hit by a long rebalancing cascade. Cascade Inclusion. Let I A s denote an indicator variable for whether the state of stock s S would ever be affected by a rebalancing cascade that starts with stock A: def ] I A s = max (7) t T [ 1{ XA s(t) 0} If I A s = 1, then we will say that stock s was included in the cascade started by an initial shock to stock A. Whereas, if I A s = 0, then the state of stock s would remain at X A s (t) = 0 for the entire duration of a rebalancing cascade starting with stock A. Note that stock A, which realized the initial shock, is always included in any resulting cascade, I A A = 1, since X A A (1) = +1 by construction. And, this fact remains true even if the state of stock A eventually returns to X A A (T ) = 0 due to some later feedback effect, just as we saw happen in Figure 3. We then use the variable L A [1, S] to denote the length of the rebalancing cascade that would be triggered by an initial shock to a randomly selected stock A at time t = 1: def L A = S s=1 I A s (8) The average rebalancing cascade has to have a length of at least E[L A ] = 1, and this can only occur if initial shocks never ever cause any funds to rebalance. Similarly, the average rebalancing cascade can have a length of no more than E[L A ] = S, and this can only occur if an initial shock to an stock always results in a rebalancing cascade that includes every stock in the market. Percolation Threshold. The length of the typical rebalancing cascade that would be set off by an initial shock to a randomly selected stock A changes dramatically as market connectivity crosses a critical threshold of κ = 1. This point is called a percolation threshold in the random-networks literature (Bollobás, 2001). Proposition 2.2 (Percolation Threshold). The expected cascade length in a large 13

14 20 E[L s ] κ λ κ Figure 4: Percolation Threshold, Below. x-axis: expected number of positive/negative neighbors for each stock in the network, κ. y- axis: expected cascade length, E[L s ], as given by Equation (9). Dashed line: percolation threshold at κ = 1. : sample averages in 1000 simulations of a random network with 5000 nodes. Figure 5: Percolation Threshold, Above. x-axis: expected number of positive/negative neighbors for each stock, κ. y-axis: expected fraction of stocks included in a cascade, λ, as given by solution to Equation (10). Dashed line: κ = 1. : sample averages in 1000 simulations of a random network with 5000 nodes. market is given by lim E[L A] = S 1 1 κ if κ [0, 1) if κ > 1 (9) Let λ def = lim S E[L A /S] denote the fraction of stocks involved in an average cascade. If κ > 1, then λ satisfies the equation λ = 1 e κ λ (10) Figure 4 plots the expected cascade length, E[L A ], as a function of overall market connectivity, κ. It shows that increasing the number of neighbors per stock increases the expected cascade length. If the typical stock has less than 2 neighbors, one positive and one negative, then at some point this chain reaction will peter out i.e., cascades will have finite length. This is the region in Figure 4 to the left of κ = 1. If the expected cascade length is finite, then each individual rebalancing cascade will include an infinitesimal fraction of the countably infinite number of stocks in the market as S. This corresponds to the line at λ = 0 for all κ < 1 in Figure 5. But, as soon as the expected cascade length becomes infinite for κ > 1, the typical rebalancing cascade will then impact a finite fraction of this infinitely large market. And, as a result, Figure 5 shows that λ > 0 as soon as as κ > 1. Likelihood of Impact. We can use the result in Proposition 2.2 to make predictions about which stocks are most likely to be hit by a long rebalancing cascade. Bayes rule tells us that, conditional on an overall level of market connectivity, the probability 14

15 stock s with N s ± neighbors will be involved in a cascade is given by: Pr[I A s = 1 N ± s, κ] Pr[N ± s I A s = 1, κ] E[I A s κ] (11) This brings us to the following corollary, which states that stocks with more neighbors are more likely to be impacted by a long rebalancing cascade. Corollary 2.2 (Likelihood of Impact). The probability that a randomly selected stock s will be included in a rebalancing cascade that starts with an initial shock to a randomly selected stock A at time t = 1 is increasing in its number of positive/negative neighbors: N ± s E[I A s N ± s, κ] > 0 (12) Thus, to sum up, long rebalancing cascades occur in densely connected markets with κ > 1, and stocks with more neighbors are more likely to be affected by these cascades. 2.3 Direction We ve seen how to predict which stocks are more likely to be hit by long rebalancing cascades. So, now let s investigate why it s so hard to predict how these long rebalancing cascades will affect the demand for each stock. Direction of Effect. Let D A s denote the final state of stock s at the conclusion of a rebalancing cascade that started with stock A: def D A s = X A s (T ) (13) Recall that the final data T = S + 1. If D A s = +1, then the net effect of the rebalancing cascade on the demand for stock s was positive. If D A s = 1, then the net effect was negative. And, if D A s = 0, then either stock s wasn t involved in the cascade or there was a feedback loop that canceled out any initial effect that the cascade had, just as diagrammed in Figure 3. Whether vs. How. Before getting to the math, let s first build some intuition for what we want to prove. Take a look at Figure 6. Both panels display cascades unfolding on 4 different networks. The nodes and edges are just as described in Subsection 2.1. The thick edges denote the rebalancing decisions that were made in response to an initial positive shock to stock A, which is represented by the large blue star. The gray shaded edges denote the potential rebalancing decisions that were not triggered by this initial shock to shock A. We are interested in how each of the 4 cascades eventually affects the demand 15

16 for stock Z, which will be represented by the color of the large square. A large blue square will denote a positive impact on stock Z, D A Z = +1; whereas, a large red square will denote a negative impact on stock Z, D A Z = 1. Panel (a, left) does not report how each edge was involved in the rebalancing cascade or how stock Z was eventually affected. Panel (b, right) does. We ve omitted the arrows representing the direction of each edge to avoid visual clutter, so now s s denotes a negative shock to stock s causing some fund to sell stock s and buy stock s while s s denotes exact same transaction triggered by a positive shock to stock s. Looking at the left panel, you can easily tell whether stock Z will be involved in each of the 4 cascades. In all but the bottom-right network, there is a clear path from the large blue star denoting stock A to the large black square denoting stock Z. But, while it s easy to trace out this path, which immediately reveals whether stock Z will be hit by the rebalancing cascade, there s no easy way to predict how stock Z will be effected by looking at the left panel. There s nothing in the left panel that would make you think that the upper-left network should result in a positive shock to stock Z, D A Z = +1. The only way to figure this out is by pressing play and seeing how the cascade unfolds. This is what we want to show mathematically. Root of the Problem. The source of the computational complexity lies in the facts that i) rebalancing cascades have an alternating buy-sell-buy-sell structure and ii) they follow threshold-based rules. These two facts imply that evaluating how a long rebalancing cascade involving L A stocks will affect the demand for stock Z is equivalent to evaluating the output of a logical circuit with L gates. Tiny changes in the fine-grained structure of a logical circuit can flip the sign of its output. So, predicting how a long rebalancing cascade will impact stock Z means keeping track of every minute detail of how the cascade unfolds. There are no shortcuts. This is the root of the problem. To illustrate, imagine that stock A realizes a positive shock at time t = 1 and there s an alternating buy-sell-buy-sell-buy path from stock A to stock Z that would result in a positive shock to stock Z, ˆDA Z = +1, if it were the only branch of the cascade. But, suppose that stock A also has another neighbor that doesn t sit on this branch, which means that there might be another way for the initial shock to propagate through the network and affect stock Z. Depending on how this second branch of the cascade unfolds, it could either reinforce or interfere with the original path and alter your original guess of D A Z = +1. This is the situation outlined in the dashed box at the top of Figure 7. 16

17 (a) Whether? (b) How? Figure 6: Whether vs. How. Both panels display the same 4 rebalancing cascades unfolding on the same collection of 4 random networks. Nodes and edges are as described in Section 2.1; however, we ve omitted the arrows representing the direction of each edge to avoid visual clutter. Thick edges denote rebalancing decisions made in response to an initial positive shock to stock A, which is represented by a large blue star. Gray shaded edges denote potential rebalancing decisions that were not involved in the rebalancing cascade. Stock Z in each network is represented by the large square. We are interested in how each rebalancing cascade will affect the demand for stock Z, and we represent this outcome with by the color of the large square in the right panel. Blue denotes a positive impact, D A Z = +1; whereas, red denotes a negative impact Z, D A Z = 1. Panel (a, left) does not report how each edge was involved in the rebalancing cascade. Panel (b, right) does. s s denotes a negative shock to stock s causing some fund to sell stock s and buy stock s; whereas, s s denotes the same event triggered by a positive shock to stock s. While it was easy to figure out whether stock Z is involved in each cascade by inspecting the left panel, there s simply no way to predict how stock Z will be effected i.e., is the large square in the right panel blue or red? without actually calculating how the entire cascade plays out. 17

18 ?? A Z Case 0: Case 1: Case 2: Case 3: Case 4: Figure 7: Root of the Problem. Dashed box shows situation where stock A, which has N + A = 2 positive neighbors, realizes a positive shock and one of those neighbors is involved in an alternating buy-sell-buy-sell-buy path from stock A to stock Z that would result in a positive shock to stock Z, ˆD A Z = +1, if it were the only branch of the cascade. Remaining panels, labeled Case 0,..., 4, show various ways that stock A s second positive neighbor might be involved in the rebalancing cascade, too. The rebalancing cascade s effect on stock Z will be positive unless this second path reconnects with the first path in exactly 2 steps. This example illustrates how, to predict how a long rebalancing cascade will affect the demand for stock Z, you have to keep track precise details about the cascade s global structure. 18

19 The remaining panels show various ways that this second branch might unfold. If the second branch of the cascade never reconnects as in Case 0, then your original guess of ˆD A Z = +1 will be correct. And, if this second branch reconnects in 1, 3, or 4 steps, then your original guess will also be correct. But, if the second branch happens to reconnect in exactly 2 steps, then your original guess will be wrong. This subtle change in the details of how the alternative branch of the cascade unfolded made the difference between the rebalancing cascade having a positive effect on stock Z and the rebalancing cascade have no effect on stock Z at all. Thus, predicting how a long rebalancing cascade will affect the demand for some stock Z is complex because you have to keep track of the cascade s global structure. To figure out how stock Z will be affected by a long rebalancing cascade, you have to check every detail of how the entire cascade unfolds. Computational Complexity. The proposition below encapsulates this basic insight. Proposition 2.3 (Computational Complexity). Suppose that there is alternating buysell-buy-sell path of rebalancing decisions from stock A to stock Z that would result in a demand shock of ˆDA Z to stock Z if it were the only branch in the cascade. If κ > 1 and at least 2 stocks on this path have 3 or more neighbors, then not only is determining whether D A Z = ˆD A Z an NP-complete problem but Pr[D A Z = d ˆD A Z ] = Pr[D A Z = d] for each d { 1, 0, 1} with high probability as κ. What this result is saying is that, in a market with many funds following many different rebalancing rules, figuring out how one particular branch of a long rebalancing cascade affects the demand for stock Z doesn t tell you anything about the net effect of the entire rebalancing cascade on the demand for stock Z. So, even if you know that stock Z will be affected by a long rebalancing cascade, you may as well just flip a coin when it comes to predicting how stock Z will be affected. Note that NP completeness is a statement about how fast the difficulty of a problem grows as its size increases. So, saying that determining whether D A Z = ˆD A Z is NP-complete problem means that this problem gets really hard really fast as the number of stocks grows large S. See Appendix A for details. Densely Connected. There are 3 important details about this result that are worth emphasizing. The first is that rebalancing cascades are only hard to predict in a densely connected market with κ > 1. If κ [0, 1), then the number of stocks in any secondary branch of the cascade that links stock A and stock Z will tend to be finite. So, the difficulty of figuring out whether this secondary chain will change 19

20 ˆD A Z will be capped as the market grows large, S. Corollary 2.3a (Densely Connected). Determining whether D A Z = ˆD A Z is not an NP-complete problem when κ [0, 1). Alternating Pattern. The second important detail is that rebalancing cascades are only hard to predict if they involve an alternating sequence of buy and sell orders. In a world where a positive shock to one stock can only ever result in a positive shock another stock, predicting how stock Z will be affected by a long rebalancing cascade starting with stock A is equivalent to predicting whether stock Z will be affected because all stocks will be affected in the exact same way. Thus, the alternating buy-sell-buy-sell nature of portfolio rebalancing rules plays a key role in the result. Corollary 2.3b (Alternating Pattern). Determining whether D A Z = ˆD A Z is not an NP-complete problem in a market with one-direction shocks. Threshold-Based Rules. The third and final important detail is that rebalancing cascades are only hard to predict if they involve threshold-based rules. To see why this is the case, just imagine changing the updating rule defined in Equation (6) to something that did not involve a threshold. For example, suppose that the update to stock s at time t is the average the shocks to its recently updated neighbors and this update altered the state of stock s by θ (0, 1): Ũ A s (t) def 1 = s U A s (t) U A s (t) X A s (t 1) (14a) X A s (t) = θ { X A s (t 1) ŨA s(t) } (14b) In this sort of market, longer chains will have smaller effects on the demand for stock Z in the same way that an AR(1) process s impulse-response function will be weaker at longer horizons. As a result, you could get a pretty good estimate of how a long rebalancing cascade starting with stock A would affect the demand for stock Z by checking the directions of the shortest paths from stock A to stock Z. Corollary 2.3c (Threshold-Based Rules). Determining whether D A Z = ˆD A Z is not an NP-complete problem in a market without threshold-based rebalancing rules. 3 Rebalancing Cascades The previous section explained how a long cascade might theoretically be able to transform a collection of simple deterministic rebalancing rules into random demand 20

21 shocks. This section gives empirical evidence that the transformation actually does take place in real-world financial markets. To do this, we focus on a particular group of funds following threshold-based strategies and study the rebalancing cascades that emerge following a set of initial shocks. Then, we show that, while it s possible to compute which stocks are most likely to be hit by each cascade, it s not possible to predict the direction of the resulting demand shock. 3.1 Group of Funds We choose exchange-traded funds (ETFs) as our particular group of funds following threshold-based strategies. Benchmark Variety. There are 3 reasons for this choice. The first is that we need a large group of funds following a very heterogeneous collection of trading strategies. Prior to January 2008, ETFs all looked like the SPDR S&P 500 ETF [SPY] in that they all tracked some sort of pre-existing market index, like the S&P 500. But, in early 2008, the SEC changed its guidelines so that an ETF could track its own selfdefined benchmark. After this change, Invesco PowerShares was free to create an ETF tracking the returns of the quintile of S&P 500 stocks with the lowest historical volatility even though there was no pre-existing low-volatility S&P 500 index. All Invesco had to do was promise to announce the identities and weights involved in the benchmark one day in advance. Now, there are more ETFs than stocks. 5 From ProShares we have CLIX (100% long internet retailers and 50% short bricks-and-mortar U.S. retailers) and EMTY (which just bets against bricks-and-mortar retailers)... meanwhile from EventShares, we have policy-factor ETFs... like... GOP (full of oil drillers, gun manufacturers, and so on that would benefit from Republican policies) and DEMS (with companies that should do well under Democrats, such as clean-energy companies). There is also an ETF called TAXR that invests in companies poised to benefit most from a successful attempt to pass a tax reform bill. 6 The sheer number and variety of these so-called smart-beta ETFs has become something of a hot-button issue of late. To be sure, niche funds tend to be smaller. But, even the rebalancing activity of small ETFs can affect a stock s fundamentals because ETFs do all of their rebalancing during the final 20 to 30 minutes of the trading day. Manager Discretion. The second reason for this choice is that ETF managers have 5 Bloomberg. 5/16/2017. Mutual Funds Ate the Stock Market. Now ETFs Are Doing It. 6 Financial Times. 11/21/2017. A ROSE by any other ticker symbol... 21

22 less ability to deviate from their stated benchmark than mutual-fund or hedge-fund managers. This is due to the underlying structure of the ETF market (Madhavan, 2016; Ben-David et al., 2017). The company running an ETF (a.k.a., its sponsor ) has an obligation to create or redeem shares of the ETF at the end-of-day market value of its stated benchmark. If an ETF s price is higher than the end-of-day market value of its benchmark, then an arbitrageur can sell shares of the ETF back to its sponsor and use the proceeds to buy shares of the underlying assets in the benchmark index. Conversely, if an ETF s price is lower than the end-of-day market value of its benchmark, then an arbitrageur can sell shares of the assets in the benchmark and use the proceeds to buy shares of the ETF from its sponsor. Thus, ETF managers will always hold a basket of securities that closely mirrors the end-of-day market value of their stated benchmark. Following this logic through to it s natural conclusion, if arbitrageurs are constantly asking an ETF sponsor to create or redeem lots of shares, then the sponsor must be losing lots of money. So, just like you d expect, creations and redemptions are only a small fraction of daily trading volume for ETFs, and these trades involve less than 0.5% percent of ETFs net assets (Investment Company Institute, 2015). Instead, ETF trading volume primarily comes from managers rebalancing activity just prior to market close. This end-of-day trading is how ETF sponsors make sure that there is very little difference between the market value of their end-of-day holdings and the market value of their stated benchmark. An ETF manager who does the bulk of his rebalancing right at market close will incur higher trading costs. But, the typical investor in a smart-beta ETF is not looking for a cheap way to buy and hold a broad market portfolio. ETF investors traded $20 trillion worth of shares last year even though ETFs only have $2.5 trillion in assets. That s 800% asset turnover, which is about 3-times more than stocks. 7 An investor interested in holding a smart-beta ETF is looking for quick access to a very targeted position. He d rather the ETF manager have slightly higher trading costs and be much more faithful to his stated benchmark. For a niche ETF, the additional trading costs incurred by the end-of-day trading are nothing compared to the costs associated with replicating the entire position from scratch. Data Availability. The third and final reason for choosing ETFs is data availability. Other papers in the ETF literature, such as Ben-David et al. (2016), impute daily portfolio positions from end-of-quarter financial statements. But, we are interested 7 Bloomberg. 3/3/ Ways Passive Investing Is Actually Quite Active. 22

The Sound of Many Funds Rebalancing

The Sound of Many Funds Rebalancing The Sound of Many Funds Rebalancing Alex Chinco and Vyacheslav Fos April 4, 2017 Abstract This paper proposes that long rebalancing cascades (stock A s price jumps, which causes a fund to buy stock A and

More information

Steve Keen s Dynamic Model of the economy.

Steve Keen s Dynamic Model of the economy. Steve Keen s Dynamic Model of the economy. Introduction This article is a non-mathematical description of the dynamic economic modeling methods developed by Steve Keen. In a number of papers and articles

More information

Algorithmic Trading Session 4 Trade Signal Generation II Backtesting. Oliver Steinki, CFA, FRM

Algorithmic Trading Session 4 Trade Signal Generation II Backtesting. Oliver Steinki, CFA, FRM Algorithmic Trading Session 4 Trade Signal Generation II Backtesting Oliver Steinki, CFA, FRM Outline Introduction Backtesting Common Pitfalls of Backtesting Statistical Signficance of Backtesting Summary

More information

Yao s Minimax Principle

Yao s Minimax Principle Complexity of algorithms The complexity of an algorithm is usually measured with respect to the size of the input, where size may for example refer to the length of a binary word describing the input,

More information

Binary Options Trading Strategies How to Become a Successful Trader?

Binary Options Trading Strategies How to Become a Successful Trader? Binary Options Trading Strategies or How to Become a Successful Trader? Brought to You by: 1. Successful Binary Options Trading Strategy Successful binary options traders approach the market with three

More information

Descriptive Statistics (Devore Chapter One)

Descriptive Statistics (Devore Chapter One) Descriptive Statistics (Devore Chapter One) 1016-345-01 Probability and Statistics for Engineers Winter 2010-2011 Contents 0 Perspective 1 1 Pictorial and Tabular Descriptions of Data 2 1.1 Stem-and-Leaf

More information

Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application

Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application Vivek H. Dehejia Carleton University and CESifo Email: vdehejia@ccs.carleton.ca January 14, 2008 JEL classification code:

More information

Sublinear Time Algorithms Oct 19, Lecture 1

Sublinear Time Algorithms Oct 19, Lecture 1 0368.416701 Sublinear Time Algorithms Oct 19, 2009 Lecturer: Ronitt Rubinfeld Lecture 1 Scribe: Daniel Shahaf 1 Sublinear-time algorithms: motivation Twenty years ago, there was practically no investigation

More information

MA 1125 Lecture 05 - Measures of Spread. Wednesday, September 6, Objectives: Introduce variance, standard deviation, range.

MA 1125 Lecture 05 - Measures of Spread. Wednesday, September 6, Objectives: Introduce variance, standard deviation, range. MA 115 Lecture 05 - Measures of Spread Wednesday, September 6, 017 Objectives: Introduce variance, standard deviation, range. 1. Measures of Spread In Lecture 04, we looked at several measures of central

More information

3 Price Action Signals to Compliment ANY Approach to ANY Market

3 Price Action Signals to Compliment ANY Approach to ANY Market 3 Price Action Signals to Compliment ANY Approach to ANY Market Introduction: It is important to start this report by being clear that these signals and tactics for using Price Action are meant to compliment

More information

Formulating Models of Simple Systems using VENSIM PLE

Formulating Models of Simple Systems using VENSIM PLE Formulating Models of Simple Systems using VENSIM PLE Professor Nelson Repenning System Dynamics Group MIT Sloan School of Management Cambridge, MA O2142 Edited by Laura Black, Lucia Breierova, and Leslie

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013 Best Reply Behavior Michael Peters December 27, 2013 1 Introduction So far, we have concentrated on individual optimization. This unified way of thinking about individual behavior makes it possible to

More information

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ Christopher Ting : christopherting@smu.edu.sg :

More information

We use probability distributions to represent the distribution of a discrete random variable.

We use probability distributions to represent the distribution of a discrete random variable. Now we focus on discrete random variables. We will look at these in general, including calculating the mean and standard deviation. Then we will look more in depth at binomial random variables which are

More information

Probability. An intro for calculus students P= Figure 1: A normal integral

Probability. An intro for calculus students P= Figure 1: A normal integral Probability An intro for calculus students.8.6.4.2 P=.87 2 3 4 Figure : A normal integral Suppose we flip a coin 2 times; what is the probability that we get more than 2 heads? Suppose we roll a six-sided

More information

Differences in the prices of physical ETF s and synthetic ETF s

Differences in the prices of physical ETF s and synthetic ETF s A Work Project, presented as part of the requirements for the Award of a Masters Degree in Finance from the NOVA School of Business and Economics. Differences in the prices of physical ETF s and synthetic

More information

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )] Problem set 1 Answers: 1. (a) The first order conditions are with 1+ 1so 0 ( ) [ 0 ( +1 )] [( +1 )] ( +1 ) Consumption follows a random walk. This is approximately true in many nonlinear models. Now we

More information

Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach

Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach John T. Harvey Professor of Economics Department of Economics Box 98510 Texas Christian University Fort Worth, Texas 7619 (817)57-730 j.harvey@tcu.edu

More information

Understanding ETF Liquidity

Understanding ETF Liquidity Understanding ETF Liquidity 2 Understanding the exchange-traded fund (ETF) life cycle Despite the tremendous growth of the ETF market over the last decade, many investors struggle to understand the mechanics

More information

15 Week 5b Mutual Funds

15 Week 5b Mutual Funds 15 Week 5b Mutual Funds 15.1 Background 1. It would be natural, and completely sensible, (and good marketing for MBA programs) if funds outperform darts! Pros outperform in any other field. 2. Except for...

More information

15-451/651: Design & Analysis of Algorithms October 23, 2018 Lecture #16: Online Algorithms last changed: October 22, 2018

15-451/651: Design & Analysis of Algorithms October 23, 2018 Lecture #16: Online Algorithms last changed: October 22, 2018 15-451/651: Design & Analysis of Algorithms October 23, 2018 Lecture #16: Online Algorithms last changed: October 22, 2018 Today we ll be looking at finding approximately-optimal solutions for problems

More information

FTS Real Time Project: Smart Beta Investing

FTS Real Time Project: Smart Beta Investing FTS Real Time Project: Smart Beta Investing Summary Smart beta strategies are a class of investment strategies based on company fundamentals. In this project, you will Learn what these strategies are Construct

More information

HOW TO PROTECT YOURSELF FROM RISKY FOREX SYSTEMS

HOW TO PROTECT YOURSELF FROM RISKY FOREX SYSTEMS BestForexBrokers.com Identifying Flaws in Profitable Forex Systems HOW TO PROTECT YOURSELF FROM RISKY FOREX SYSTEMS JULY 2017 Disclaimer: BestForexBrokers.com and this report are not associated with myfxbook.com

More information

Stock Market Forecast: Chaos Theory Revealing How the Market Works March 25, 2018 I Know First Research

Stock Market Forecast: Chaos Theory Revealing How the Market Works March 25, 2018 I Know First Research Stock Market Forecast: Chaos Theory Revealing How the Market Works March 25, 2018 I Know First Research Stock Market Forecast : How Can We Predict the Financial Markets by Using Algorithms? Common fallacies

More information

Evaluating Performance

Evaluating Performance Evaluating Performance Evaluating Performance Choosing investments is just the beginning of your work as an investor. As time goes by, you ll need to monitor the performance of these investments to see

More information

The following content is provided under a Creative Commons license. Your support

The following content is provided under a Creative Commons license. Your support MITOCW Recitation 6 The following content is provided under a Creative Commons license. Your support will help MIT OpenCourseWare continue to offer high quality educational resources for free. To make

More information

15-451/651: Design & Analysis of Algorithms November 9 & 11, 2015 Lecture #19 & #20 last changed: November 10, 2015

15-451/651: Design & Analysis of Algorithms November 9 & 11, 2015 Lecture #19 & #20 last changed: November 10, 2015 15-451/651: Design & Analysis of Algorithms November 9 & 11, 2015 Lecture #19 & #20 last changed: November 10, 2015 Last time we looked at algorithms for finding approximately-optimal solutions for NP-hard

More information

,,, be any other strategy for selling items. It yields no more revenue than, based on the

,,, be any other strategy for selling items. It yields no more revenue than, based on the ONLINE SUPPLEMENT Appendix 1: Proofs for all Propositions and Corollaries Proof of Proposition 1 Proposition 1: For all 1,2,,, if, is a non-increasing function with respect to (henceforth referred to as

More information

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005 Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation Practice Problems (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005 {This posting has more information than is needed for the corporate

More information

Using Fractals to Improve Currency Risk Management Strategies

Using Fractals to Improve Currency Risk Management Strategies Using Fractals to Improve Currency Risk Management Strategies Michael K. Lauren Operational Analysis Section Defence Technology Agency New Zealand m.lauren@dta.mil.nz Dr_Michael_Lauren@hotmail.com Abstract

More information

Module 3: Factor Models

Module 3: Factor Models Module 3: Factor Models (BUSFIN 4221 - Investments) Andrei S. Gonçalves 1 1 Finance Department The Ohio State University Fall 2016 1 Module 1 - The Demand for Capital 2 Module 1 - The Supply of Capital

More information

Market Microstructure Invariants

Market Microstructure Invariants Market Microstructure Invariants Albert S. Kyle and Anna A. Obizhaeva University of Maryland TI-SoFiE Conference 212 Amsterdam, Netherlands March 27, 212 Kyle and Obizhaeva Market Microstructure Invariants

More information

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Putnam Institute JUne 2011 Optimal Asset Allocation in : A Downside Perspective W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Once an individual has retired, asset allocation becomes a critical

More information

TradeOptionsWithMe.com

TradeOptionsWithMe.com TradeOptionsWithMe.com 1 of 18 Option Trading Glossary This is the Glossary for important option trading terms. Some of these terms are rather easy and used extremely often, but some may even be new to

More information

ECON Microeconomics II IRYNA DUDNYK. Auctions.

ECON Microeconomics II IRYNA DUDNYK. Auctions. Auctions. What is an auction? When and whhy do we need auctions? Auction is a mechanism of allocating a particular object at a certain price. Allocating part concerns who will get the object and the price

More information

Essays on Some Combinatorial Optimization Problems with Interval Data

Essays on Some Combinatorial Optimization Problems with Interval Data Essays on Some Combinatorial Optimization Problems with Interval Data a thesis submitted to the department of industrial engineering and the institute of engineering and sciences of bilkent university

More information

Real Estate Private Equity Case Study 3 Opportunistic Pre-Sold Apartment Development: Waterfall Returns Schedule, Part 1: Tier 1 IRRs and Cash Flows

Real Estate Private Equity Case Study 3 Opportunistic Pre-Sold Apartment Development: Waterfall Returns Schedule, Part 1: Tier 1 IRRs and Cash Flows Real Estate Private Equity Case Study 3 Opportunistic Pre-Sold Apartment Development: Waterfall Returns Schedule, Part 1: Tier 1 IRRs and Cash Flows Welcome to the next lesson in this Real Estate Private

More information

Exploiting the Inefficiencies of Leveraged ETFs

Exploiting the Inefficiencies of Leveraged ETFs Exploiting the Inefficiencies of Leveraged ETFs [Editor s Note: Here at WCI we try to keep things as simple as possible, most of the time. Not today though. Today we re going to be discussing leveraged

More information

Reinforcement Learning Analysis, Grid World Applications

Reinforcement Learning Analysis, Grid World Applications Reinforcement Learning Analysis, Grid World Applications Kunal Sharma GTID: ksharma74, CS 4641 Machine Learning Abstract This paper explores two Markov decision process problems with varying state sizes.

More information

TraderEx Self-Paced Tutorial and Case

TraderEx Self-Paced Tutorial and Case Background to: TraderEx Self-Paced Tutorial and Case Securities Trading TraderEx LLC, July 2011 Trading in financial markets involves the conversion of an investment decision into a desired portfolio position.

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Low Volatility Portfolio Tools for Investors

Low Volatility Portfolio Tools for Investors Low Volatility Portfolio Tools for Investors By G. Michael Phillips, Ph.D., with contributions from James Chong, Ph.D. and William Jennings, Ph.D. Introduction Reprint from November 2011 The world is a

More information

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis Oktay Akkus Department of Economics University of Chicago Ali Hortacsu Department of Economics University of Chicago VERY Preliminary Draft:

More information

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 The Greeks Introduction We have studied how to price an option using the Black-Scholes formula. Now we wish to consider how the option price changes, either

More information

Are You Smarter Than a Monkey? Course Syllabus. How Are Our Stocks Doing? 9/30/2017

Are You Smarter Than a Monkey? Course Syllabus. How Are Our Stocks Doing? 9/30/2017 Are You Smarter Than a Monkey? Course Syllabus 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Human Psychology with Investing / Indices and Exchanges Behavioral Finance / Stocks vs Mutual Funds vs ETFs / Introduction to Technology Analysis

More information

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms 19 Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms Vol I Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms Annika Westphäling * Four eyes see more than two that information gets more precise being aggregated

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates

Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates No. 16-23 Anat Bracha Abstract: While the current European Central Bank deposit rate and 2-year German government bond yields are negative, the U.S. 2-year

More information

Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model University College Dublin, Advanced Macroeconomics Notes, 2015 (Karl Whelan) Page 1 Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model In the previous set of notes, we introduced the IS-MP-PC model. We will move on now to examining

More information

Problem Set 1 Due in class, week 1

Problem Set 1 Due in class, week 1 Business 35150 John H. Cochrane Problem Set 1 Due in class, week 1 Do the readings, as specified in the syllabus. Answer the following problems. Note: in this and following problem sets, make sure to answer

More information

Futures and Forward Markets

Futures and Forward Markets Futures and Forward Markets (Text reference: Chapters 19, 21.4) background hedging and speculation optimal hedge ratio forward and futures prices futures prices and expected spot prices stock index futures

More information

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure Yosuke Kimura Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo March 20, 2017 Abstract This paper considers the relationship between stock

More information

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley.

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley. Appendix: Statistics in Action Part I Financial Time Series 1. These data show the effects of stock splits. If you investigate further, you ll find that most of these splits (such as in May 1970) are 3-for-1

More information

If you are over age 50, you get another $5,500 in catch-up contributions. Are you taking advantage of that additional amount?

If you are over age 50, you get another $5,500 in catch-up contributions. Are you taking advantage of that additional amount? Let s start this off with the obvious. I am not a certified financial planner. I am not a certified investment counselor. Anything I know about investing, I ve learned by making mistakes, not by taking

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 207 Introduction This note works through some simple two-period consumption-saving problems. In

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2018 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

ETF Arbitrage and Return Predictability

ETF Arbitrage and Return Predictability David C. Brown University of Arizona Shaun William Davies University of Colorado Boulder Matthew Ringgenberg University of Utah January 5, 2018 American Finance Association Annual Meeting 1 / 16 Motivation

More information

Casino gambling problem under probability weighting

Casino gambling problem under probability weighting Casino gambling problem under probability weighting Sang Hu National University of Singapore Mathematical Finance Colloquium University of Southern California Jan 25, 2016 Based on joint work with Xue

More information

Handout 4: Deterministic Systems and the Shortest Path Problem

Handout 4: Deterministic Systems and the Shortest Path Problem SEEM 3470: Dynamic Optimization and Applications 2013 14 Second Term Handout 4: Deterministic Systems and the Shortest Path Problem Instructor: Shiqian Ma January 27, 2014 Suggested Reading: Bertsekas

More information

PAIRS TRADING (just an introduction)

PAIRS TRADING (just an introduction) PAIRS TRADING (just an introduction) By Rob Booker Trading involves substantial risk of loss. Past performance is not necessarily indicative of future results. You can share this ebook with anyone you

More information

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy We now proceed to study optimal fiscal policy. We should make clear at the outset what we mean by this. In general, fiscal policy entails the government choosing its spending

More information

Optimization Prof. A. Goswami Department of Mathematics Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur. Lecture - 18 PERT

Optimization Prof. A. Goswami Department of Mathematics Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur. Lecture - 18 PERT Optimization Prof. A. Goswami Department of Mathematics Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur Lecture - 18 PERT (Refer Slide Time: 00:56) In the last class we completed the C P M critical path analysis

More information

Standard Decision Theory Corrected:

Standard Decision Theory Corrected: Standard Decision Theory Corrected: Assessing Options When Probability is Infinitely and Uniformly Spread* Peter Vallentyne Department of Philosophy, University of Missouri-Columbia Originally published

More information

RATIONAL BUBBLES AND LEARNING

RATIONAL BUBBLES AND LEARNING RATIONAL BUBBLES AND LEARNING Rational bubbles arise because of the indeterminate aspect of solutions to rational expectations models, where the process governing stock prices is encapsulated in the Euler

More information

Appendix A: Introduction to Queueing Theory

Appendix A: Introduction to Queueing Theory Appendix A: Introduction to Queueing Theory Queueing theory is an advanced mathematical modeling technique that can estimate waiting times. Imagine customers who wait in a checkout line at a grocery store.

More information

Monetary Policy Revised: January 9, 2008

Monetary Policy Revised: January 9, 2008 Global Economy Chris Edmond Monetary Policy Revised: January 9, 2008 In most countries, central banks manage interest rates in an attempt to produce stable and predictable prices. In some countries they

More information

Daily Stock Returns: Momentum, Reversal, or Both. Steven D. Dolvin * and Mark K. Pyles **

Daily Stock Returns: Momentum, Reversal, or Both. Steven D. Dolvin * and Mark K. Pyles ** Daily Stock Returns: Momentum, Reversal, or Both Steven D. Dolvin * and Mark K. Pyles ** * Butler University ** College of Charleston Abstract Much attention has been given to the momentum and reversal

More information

1. A is a decision support tool that uses a tree-like graph or model of decisions and their possible consequences, including chance event outcomes,

1. A is a decision support tool that uses a tree-like graph or model of decisions and their possible consequences, including chance event outcomes, 1. A is a decision support tool that uses a tree-like graph or model of decisions and their possible consequences, including chance event outcomes, resource costs, and utility. A) Decision tree B) Graphs

More information

Short Selling Stocks For Large And Fast Profits. By Jack Carter

Short Selling Stocks For Large And Fast Profits. By Jack Carter Short Selling Stocks For Large And Fast Profits By Jack Carter 2017 Disclaimer: No financial advice is given or implied. Publisher is not registered investment advisor or stockbroker. Information provided

More information

Decision Trees: Booths

Decision Trees: Booths DECISION ANALYSIS Decision Trees: Booths Terri Donovan recorded: January, 2010 Hi. Tony has given you a challenge of setting up a spreadsheet, so you can really understand whether it s wiser to play in

More information

The purpose of this appendix is to show how Projected Implied Volatility (PIV) can

The purpose of this appendix is to show how Projected Implied Volatility (PIV) can Volatility-Based Technical Analysis: Strategies for Trading the Invisible By Kirk Northington Copyright 2009 by Kirk Northington APPENDIX B The PIV Options Advantage Using Projected Implied Volatility

More information

ECON 214 Elements of Statistics for Economists 2016/2017

ECON 214 Elements of Statistics for Economists 2016/2017 ECON 214 Elements of Statistics for Economists 2016/2017 Topic The Normal Distribution Lecturer: Dr. Bernardin Senadza, Dept. of Economics bsenadza@ug.edu.gh College of Education School of Continuing and

More information

January 26,

January 26, January 26, 2015 Exercise 9 7.c.1, 7.d.1, 7.d.2, 8.b.1, 8.b.2, 8.b.3, 8.b.4,8.b.5, 8.d.1, 8.d.2 Example 10 There are two divisions of a firm (1 and 2) that would benefit from a research project conducted

More information

Getting started with WinBUGS

Getting started with WinBUGS 1 Getting started with WinBUGS James B. Elsner and Thomas H. Jagger Department of Geography, Florida State University Some material for this tutorial was taken from http://www.unt.edu/rss/class/rich/5840/session1.doc

More information

This presentation is part of a three part series.

This presentation is part of a three part series. As a club treasurer, you ll have certain tasks you ll be performing each month to keep your clubs financial records. In tonights presentation, we ll cover the basics of how you should perform these. Monthly

More information

Christiano 362, Winter 2006 Lecture #3: More on Exchange Rates More on the idea that exchange rates move around a lot.

Christiano 362, Winter 2006 Lecture #3: More on Exchange Rates More on the idea that exchange rates move around a lot. Christiano 362, Winter 2006 Lecture #3: More on Exchange Rates More on the idea that exchange rates move around a lot. 1.Theexampleattheendoflecture#2discussedalargemovementin the US-Japanese exchange

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

The Assumption(s) of Normality

The Assumption(s) of Normality The Assumption(s) of Normality Copyright 2000, 2011, 2016, J. Toby Mordkoff This is very complicated, so I ll provide two versions. At a minimum, you should know the short one. It would be great if you

More information

Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates

Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates Christiano 362, Winter 2003 February 21 Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates 1. Fixed versus flexible exchange rates: overview. Over time, and in different places, countries have adopted a fixed exchange

More information

Follow Price Action Trends By Laurentiu Damir Copyright 2012 Laurentiu Damir

Follow Price Action Trends By Laurentiu Damir Copyright 2012 Laurentiu Damir Follow Price Action Trends By Laurentiu Damir Copyright 2012 Laurentiu Damir All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical,

More information

Reinforcement Learning. Slides based on those used in Berkeley's AI class taught by Dan Klein

Reinforcement Learning. Slides based on those used in Berkeley's AI class taught by Dan Klein Reinforcement Learning Slides based on those used in Berkeley's AI class taught by Dan Klein Reinforcement Learning Basic idea: Receive feedback in the form of rewards Agent s utility is defined by the

More information

Some Characteristics of Data

Some Characteristics of Data Some Characteristics of Data Not all data is the same, and depending on some characteristics of a particular dataset, there are some limitations as to what can and cannot be done with that data. Some key

More information

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr.

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr. The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving James P. Dow, Jr. Department of Finance, Real Estate and Insurance California State University, Northridge

More information

Investment Section INVESTMENT FALLACIES 2014

Investment Section INVESTMENT FALLACIES 2014 Investment Section INVESTMENT FALLACIES 2014 INVESTMENT SECTION INVESTMENT FALLACIES A real-world approach to Value at Risk By Nicholas John Macleod Introduction A well-known legal anecdote has it that

More information

Finally, a Practical Solution for Decomposing Returns into Alpha and Beta (Traditional Or Smart )

Finally, a Practical Solution for Decomposing Returns into Alpha and Beta (Traditional Or Smart ) Finally, a Practical Solution for Decomposing Returns into Alpha and Beta (Traditional Or Smart ) by Peter Hecht, Managing Director at Evanston Capital Management **Originally featured in Pensions & Investments,

More information

PRICE ACTION CONTEXT

PRICE ACTION CONTEXT TRADING WITH PRICE ACTION CONTEXT CHRIS CAPRE 2ndSkiesForex.com If you think this ebook is going to be about learning a price action setup, you re wrong. It ll be about something much more powerful. For

More information

Absolute Alpha with Moving Averages

Absolute Alpha with Moving Averages a Consistent Trading Strategy University of Rochester April 23, 2016 Carhart (1995, 1997) discussed a 4-factor model using Fama and French s (1993) 3-factor model plus an additional factor capturing Jegadeesh

More information

Chris Capre, Founder - Second Skies

Chris Capre, Founder - Second Skies Getting an Edge Learn What to Pay Attention to and How Things Work in the Forex Market If you've read Jack Schwager's 'The New Market Wizards,' he finds there are three things the best of the best traders

More information

Let Diversification Do Its Job

Let Diversification Do Its Job Let Diversification Do Its Job By CARL RICHARDS Sunday, January 13, 2013 The New York Times Investors typically set up a diversified investment portfolio to reduce their risk. Just hold a good mix of different

More information

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS 247 16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS Let us associate each state S with a numeric utility U(S), which expresses the desirability of the state A nondeterministic action A will have possible outcome states Result

More information

Iterated Dominance and Nash Equilibrium

Iterated Dominance and Nash Equilibrium Chapter 11 Iterated Dominance and Nash Equilibrium In the previous chapter we examined simultaneous move games in which each player had a dominant strategy; the Prisoner s Dilemma game was one example.

More information

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap Peter N Bell University of Victoria 12. April 2012 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/38347/ MPRA Paper

More information

Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market

Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market Esen Onur 1 and Ufuk Devrim Demirel 2 September 2009 VERY PRELIMINARY & INCOMPLETE PLEASE DO NOT CITE WITHOUT AUTHORS PERMISSION

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

Harmonic Volatility Line Indicator

Harmonic Volatility Line Indicator Harmonic Volatility Line Indicator Subtitle: Alternative Approach to Gann s Angle Author: Young Ho Seo Finance Engineer and Quantitative Trader Book Version: 1.7 (13 May 2017) Total Pages counted in MS-Word:

More information

6.041SC Probabilistic Systems Analysis and Applied Probability, Fall 2013 Transcript Lecture 23

6.041SC Probabilistic Systems Analysis and Applied Probability, Fall 2013 Transcript Lecture 23 6.041SC Probabilistic Systems Analysis and Applied Probability, Fall 2013 Transcript Lecture 23 The following content is provided under a Creative Commons license. Your support will help MIT OpenCourseWare

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 202A DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 203 D. Romer FORCES LIMITING THE EXTENT TO WHICH SOPHISTICATED INVESTORS ARE WILLING TO MAKE TRADES THAT MOVE ASSET PRICES BACK TOWARD

More information

Stock Repurchase with an Adaptive Reservation Price: A Study of the Greedy Policy

Stock Repurchase with an Adaptive Reservation Price: A Study of the Greedy Policy Stock Repurchase with an Adaptive Reservation Price: A Study of the Greedy Policy Ye Lu Asuman Ozdaglar David Simchi-Levi November 8, 200 Abstract. We consider the problem of stock repurchase over a finite

More information

FIGURE A1.1. Differences for First Mover Cutoffs (Round one to two) as a Function of Beliefs on Others Cutoffs. Second Mover Round 1 Cutoff.

FIGURE A1.1. Differences for First Mover Cutoffs (Round one to two) as a Function of Beliefs on Others Cutoffs. Second Mover Round 1 Cutoff. APPENDIX A. SUPPLEMENTARY TABLES AND FIGURES A.1. Invariance to quantitative beliefs. Figure A1.1 shows the effect of the cutoffs in round one for the second and third mover on the best-response cutoffs

More information