CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS AND ORGANIZATION RESEARCH PAPER SERIES

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS AND ORGANIZATION RESEARCH PAPER SERIES"

Transcription

1 Information and the Optimal Ownership Structure of Firms Niko Matouschek USC Center for Law, Economics & Organization Research Paper No. C02-11 CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS AND ORGANIZATION RESEARCH PAPER SERIES Sponsored by the John M. Olin Foundation University of Southern California Law School Los Angeles, CA This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at

2 Information and the Optimal Ownership Structure of Firms Niko Matouschek Kellogg School of Management Northwestern University January 22, 2001 Abstract I develop a property rights theory of the firm in which managers bargain over the sharing of quasi-rents in the presence of private information. I analyze the interdependence between the ownership structure of firms and the bargaining inefficiency that is due to the presence of private information and derive the optimal ownership structure that minimizes the bargaining inefficiency. I first assume that managers can only contract over the ownership structure and show that they optimally choose one that minimises (maximises) their aggregate disagreement payoff if the minimum expected quasi-rents are large (small). I then extend my analysis and allow the managers to contract over the ownership structure and the bargaining game that is played ex post. I show that the main results continue to hold if and only if ownership structures are deterministic and cannot be made contingent on information that is revealed ex post. Department of Management and Strategy, Kellogg School of Management, 2001 Sheridan Road, Evanston, IL n-matouschek@kellogg.nwu.edu. This paper is based on Chapter 2 of my PhD thesis and an earlier version was circulated under the title: "Increasing Lock-In to Facilitate Decision Making: A Property Rights Theory of the Firm with Private Information." I am particularly grateful to Leonardo Felli, Oliver Hart, John Moore, and Andrea Part for their help and support. I would also like to thank Antoine Faure-Grimaud, Catherine de Fontenay, David de Meza, Alexander Mürmann, François Ortalo-Magné, Marco Ottaviani, Michele Piccione, Paolo Ramezzana, Sönje Reiche, Frédéric Robert-Nicoud, Kathy Spier, Jonathan Thomas, and Richard Walker as well as seminar participants at ESSET 2000 in Gerzensee, the Young Economist 2000 conference in Oxford, and the Stockholm School of Economics for very useful comments and discussions. All remaining errors are, of course, my own. Financial support by the Centre for Economic Performance, the London School of Economics, STICERD, and the Stockholm School of Economics is gratefully acknowledged.

3 1 Introduction Managers who bargain with each other over the sharing of quasi-rents often do so in the presence of private information. For instance, suppliers often know more about the costs of producing specialized inputs while downstream firms often know more about how much they value such inputs. It is well known that, under fairly general conditions, voluntary bilateral bargaining in the presence of private information must be inefficient, in the sense that not all gains from trade are realized instantaneously (see Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983)). In this paper I argue that the size of the bargaining inefficiency that arises when two managers bargain over the sharing of quasi-rents in the presence of private information depends crucially on the ownership structure of their firms. I formally model this interdependence and derive the optimal ownership structure that minimizes the bargaining inefficiency. Economists have believed for a long time that informational imperfections are an important factor in determining the boundaries of firms. This belief can be traced back to Coase (1937) who argues that the resources used to discover and haggle over the terms of trade constitute a major cost of market transactions and that these costs can be reduced if the transactions are brought into the firm 1. Similarly, the modern transaction cost theory of the firm, as developed by Williamson (1975, 1985), argues that bargaining between firms over the sharing of quasi-rents can be costly due to the presence of private information and that these haggling costs can be reduced if the firms integrate 2. This literature, however, does not describe explicitly the mechanism through which integration leads to a reduction in the bargaining inefficiency. It essentially assumes that managers have less scope to act less opportunistically if a transaction takes place within a firm rather than across two independent firms and that, due to this behavioral change, integration can lead to a reduction in the bargaining inefficiency 3. 1 Coase (1937), p See, for instance, Williamson (1975), p Williamson (1975) stresses four reasons why integration can reduce inefficiencies that are due to the presence of private information: first, integrated firms can create better incentives to induce managers to act less opportunistically than non-integrated firms. Second, integrated firms have stronger auditing powers than non-integrated firms. Third, integrated firms can settle disputes more efficiently than non-integrated firms. Fourth, integration facilitates communication (see Williamson (1975), p.31-1

4 The conceptual framework of the property rights theory of the firm that I adopt in this paper allows me to be more precise about the mechanism through which integration, or any other ownership change, affects the bargaining inefficiency that arises when managers have private information. In the property rights theory, as developed by Grossman and Hart (1986) and Hart and Moore (1990), changes in the ownership structure of firms only affect the behavior of managers by changing the disagreement payoffs they realize if they do not agree to trade with each other. I show that by altering the disagreement payoffs, ownership changes can have significant effects on how efficiently managers bargain with each other in the presence of private information and that the ownership structures that minimize the bargaining inefficiency are frequently observed in the real world. To illustrate my main arguments, consider the following basic set up. There are two managers, a buyer and a seller, and two machines, a 1 and a 2. The seller can use a 2 to produce either a widget that is specialized to the buyer s needs or a standard widget that can be sold on a spot market. The buyer can use a 1 to turn either the special or astandardwidgetintoafinal good. The managers trade payoffs, that is the seller s cost of producing the special widget and the buyer s valuation of it, are independent and privately known only to the respective manager. Also, these payoffs areindependent of the ownership structure since, if trade takes place, both managers have access to both machines regardless of who owns them. For simplicity, suppose that the managers disagreement payoffs, that is the payoff each manager realizes if the special widget is not traded, are common knowledge. In contrast to the trade payoffs, the disagreement payoffs do depend on the ownership structure since, in the case of disagreement, only the owner of a machine can use it. Finally, suppose that sometimes there are positive quasi-rents, that is the gains from trading the special widget are larger than the sum of both managers disagreement payoffs, and that sometimes the quasi-rents are negative. Ex post the managers bargain over the price of the special widget. If they agree on a price, they simply transfer the special widget and if they do not agree, they just realize 37). All these arguments essentlially assume a restriction on the contracts that can be written between independent firms compared to those that can be written between internal divisions. 2

5 their respective disagreement payoffs. Note that because of the presence of bilateral private information the managers will sometimes not agree to trade the special widget although there are positive gains from trade. In this sense bargaining is inefficient. Ex ante, before learning the realization of their trade payoffs and engaging in bargaining, the managers contract over the ownership structure, that is they contract over who owns what machine. For simplicity suppose that only the ownership structure is contractible and that the ex post bargaining game is given exogenously 4. The key question then is what ownership structure the managers agree on or, equivalently, what ownership structure minimizes the bargaining inefficiency. It turns out that the answer to this question is surprisingly simple. The managers either choose the ownership structure that minimizes their expected quasi-rents (or, equivalently, maximizes their aggregate disagreement payoff) or they choose the one that maximizes their expected quasi-rents (or, equivalently, minimizes their aggregate disagreement payoff). Which one of the two they choose depends crucially the minimum expected quasi-rents, that is it depends on how high the expected quasi-rents are if the aggregate disagreement payoff is maximized. In particular, the managers choose the ownership structure that minimizes the expected quasi-rents if, for a given distribution of trade payoffs, the minimum expected quasi-rents are small and they choose the ownership structure that maximizes the expected quasi-rents otherwise. To get an intuition for why this result holds, consider the trade-off themanagersface when they decide on an ownership change. Such a change has no effect on the size of the expected bargaining inefficiency if it simply leads to a redistribution of disagreement payoffs between the managers without altering the aggregate disagreement payoff. A change in the ownership structure that leads to a reduction in the aggregate disagreement payoff, however, does affect the bargaining inefficiency. On the one hand, such a change increases the probability that efficient trading opportunities are realized which, ceteris paribus, reduces the bargaining inefficiency. On the other hand, it also increases the cost of disagreement and might even induce the managers to trade too often; ceteris 4 In the formal analysis I allow the managers to choose both their disagreement payoffs andthe bargaining game they play ex post. 3

6 paribus these two effects increase the bargaining inefficiency. If the aggregate disagreement payoff is large, the managers disagree very often and, as a result, the costs of a marginal reduction in the aggregate disagreement payoff are large and indeed dominate the benefit. Thus, if the aggregate disagreement payoff is large, reducing it marginally is inefficient. If the aggregate disagreement payoff is small, however, the managers do not disagree very often and a marginal reduction in the aggregate disagreement payoff is welfare enhancing. The result that welfare is decreasing in the aggregate disagreement payoff if the aggregate disagreement payoff is small and that it is increasing if the aggregate disagreement payoff is large is key in myanalysis. Itimplies,notonlythatthemanagersalwayseitherwanttominimizeor maximize the aggregate disagreement payoff, but also that they want to do the former if the maximum aggregate disagreement payoff is large and that they want to do the latter otherwise. There are four ownership structures that can be optimal in my model: buyerintegration, seller-integration, non-integration, and joint ownership. All of them are, of course, frequently observed in the real world. The property rights literature has been criticized for not predicting often enough the optimality of joint ownership and of asset clusters, such as buyer- and seller-integration (see, for instance, Holmström (1999)). My analysis shows that joint ownership and asset clusters can be optimal in a property rights model in which ex post bargaining is inefficient due to the presence of private information. Managers often take actions that increase the expected quasi-rents in their trading relationships but do not maximize them 5. For instance, managers sometimes exchange ugly princess hostages (see, for example, Williamson (1985) and, in the context of military conflicts, Schelling (1960)). The term refers to a practice in which managers exchange ownership of assets that are very valuable to themselves but which have little or no value to the other party. In the Japanese car industry, for instance, it can be observed that physical assets which are specific to a particular car manufacturer are 5 To maximize their expected quasi-rents, the managers would need to agree on joint ownership. Joint ownership maximizes expected quasi-rents since it prevents either manager from using the assets without the agreement of the other. 4

7 often owned by its supplier 6. Also, firms sometimes increase expected quasi-rents by selling off assets that can be used unilaterally during a conflict. For instance, after settling a costly dispute about their alliance, KLM and Northwest Airlines deliberately increased their interdependence by eliminating their duplicate support operations 7. It is also well known that firms sometimes use exclusive sourcing arrangements to increase expected quasi-rents. It is often argued informally that managers take such actions to ensure that their trading relationships work well and that conflicts are settled quickly. My model shows that increasing expected quasi-rents can indeed reduce the probability of ex post disagreements. However, to provide an explanation for why managers might want to increase expected quasi-rents but not maximize them, my model would need to be extended to include an additional cost of reducing the aggregate disagreement payoff. I conjecture that this could be done, for instance, by allowing for ex ante investments. This paper is related to the literature on the property rights theory of the firm that was first introduced by Grossman and Hart (1986) and Hart and Moore (1990), and was developed further in a number of papers, including de Meza and Lockwood (1998), Rajan and Zingales (1998), Baker, Gibbons, and Murphy (1999). This literature assumes that bargaining between managers is efficient and studies the role of asset ownership in determining ex ante investment inefficiencies. In contrast to this literature, I study the role of asset ownership in determining ex post bargaining inefficiencies rather than ex ante investment inefficiencies. I do so, not because I think that investment inefficiencies are not an important factor in determining the boundaries of firms, but because I think that ex post inefficiencies also play an important role. There are only very few papers inthepropertyrightsliteraturethatallowforexpostinefficiency and, to my knowledge, none are related to the issues addressed here 8. Apart from the property rights literature, my paper is also related to Arrow (1975) and Riordan (1990) who study vertical integration under imperfect information. The key assumption in their models is that vertical integration reduces the amount of private 6 Holmström and Roberts (1998), p Holmström and Roberts (1998), p Hart and Moore (1999), for instance, study the design of a firm s constitution when ex post asymmetric information prevents recontracting. 5

8 information. Thus, for instance, a downstream firm is assumed to know less about an independent upstream firm than it knows about an inhouse supplier. This assumption contrasts with recent papers by Aghion and Tirole (1997) and Dessein (1999) which showthattheincentives ofagentstotransmit information to a principal may actually be reduced, and thus informational asymmetries be increased, when a principal gains more control over an agent s actions. In contrast to Arrow (1975) and Riordan (1990), I therefore assume that ownership changes do not affect the amount of private information per se and instead merely determine the managers disagreement payoffs. Technically, the general model that I present in the second half of the paper is closely related to Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983). Among other important results, they derive the optimal mechanism for a bilateral bargaining situation with two-sided asymmetric information. The key difference between their analysis and mine is that they derive the optimal mechanism for given disagreement payoffs while I solve for the optimal mechanism and the optimal disagreement payoffs. In spite of this difference I can draw extensively on their results in solving the model. I show that the efficiency of the bargaining mechanism depends only on the aggregate disagreement payoff and not on the distribution if individual disagreement payoffs. Also, I show that it is always optimal to either choose the maximum or the minimum aggregate disagreement payoff and that the former is optimal if the maximum aggregate disagreement payoff is large while the latter is optimal otherwise. In the next section I present the basic set-up, solve for the optimal ownership structure, and discuss the implications of the analysis. In this section I simplify the analysis by assuming that contracts are incomplete, in the sense that the managers cannot contract ex ante over the bargaining game that takes place ex post, and by restricting attention to uniform distributions. The main worry with this approach, of course, is that the results may rely crucially on these simplifying assumptions 9. To address this concern I generalize the simple model in section 3 by allowing the managers to contract over the ownership structure and the bargaining game and by allowing for more general 9 Aghion, Dewatripont, and Rey (1994) study renegotiation design as a solution to the hold-up problem and show that contracts can solve the hold-up problem if they can assign bargaining power to one agent and specify the default option when renegotiation fails. 6

9 distributions. The analysis in this section shows that the main results of the simple modelcontinuetoholdifandonlyifownershipstructurescannotbemadecontingent on information that is revealed ex post. Finally, in section 4 I briefly discuss other applications of the analysis and conclude. 2 The Simple Model with Incomplete Contracting There are two risk neutral and liquidity unconstrained managers, a buyer (she) and a seller (he), and two assets a 1 and a 2. The assets are owned by the managers. The set of assets owned only by the buyer is denoted by A b {a 1,a 2 } and that owned only by the seller is denoted by A s {a 1,a 2 }. The ownership structure is given by A =(A b,a s ). The managers can either trade with each other or with third parties in the market. If the managers trade with each other, they both have access to both assets, regardless of the ownership structure. The seller can then use the assets to produce an input at cost c < and the buyer can use them to turn the input into a final good that she values at π <. It is common knowledge that the trade payoffs π and c are independently drawn from a uniform distribution with support [0, 1] 10. If the managers trade with third parties, each can only use the assets over which he or she has sole ownership rights. The individual disagreement payoffs that the buyer and the seller then realize are denoted by b(a b ) and s(a s ) respectively. The aggregate disagreement payoff is denoted by d(a) b(a b )+s(a s ). All disagreement payoffs are common knowledge. Ex ante the managers contract over the ownership structure A without yet knowing the realizations of the trade payoffs π and c. In this simple model they cannot contract over anything but A; in particular, they cannot contract over the bargaining game that takes place ex post. For the time being I justify this assumption informally by supposing that the complex nature of the input makes it impossible to describe it in any ex ante contract 11. At the interim stage, the buyer learns the realization of π and the seller learns the 10 In section 3 I relax this assumption and allow for more general distributions. 11 In section 3 I relax this assumption and allow the managers to contract over the ownership structure and the ex post bargaining game. 7

10 realization of c. Ex post, the managers then bargain over the price of the input. The exogenously given bargaining game takes the form of a simple double auction: the buyer and the seller respectively submit sealed bids p b < and p s <. If p b p s,tradetakes place at price p = 1(p 2 b + p s ). The buyer s payoff is then given by π p and the seller s by p c. If p b <p s, trade does not take place and the managers realize their respective disagreement payoffs b(a b ) and s(a s ). I denote the ownership structure that minimizes the aggregate disagreement payoff by A arg min A d(a) and the ownership structure that maximizes the aggregate disagreement payoff by A arg max A d(a). The corresponding aggregate disagreement payoffs are denoted by d d(a) and d d(a). Also, I assume that the bounds on the aggregate disagreement payoffs satisfy 1 =d d 1. These assumptions simply ensure that, at least sometimes, trading the special widget is (weakly) optimal and, at least sometimes, not trading it is (weakly) optimal. I make these assumptions only because they simplify the exposition. It would be trivial to analyze the implications of relaxing them. I refer to an ownership structure in which the buyer owns both assets as buyer integration and define seller integration accordingly. Under non-integration each manager owns one asset and under joint ownership both managers own both assets. Finally, I refer to E c,π [π c d π c d 0] as the expected quasi-rents and to E c,π π c d π c d 0 as the minimum expected quasi-rents. Before moving on to the analysis, it is useful to make a number of conceptual observations. First, in the model I adopt all the key assumptions of the property rights literature. In particular, I follow the literature by assuming that contracts are incomplete and that asset ownership determines the disagreement payoffs but not the trade payoffs. Second, I also follow the property rights literature by assuming that the managers can contractually commit ex ante to ownership structures that might be inefficient if disagreement occurs ex post. This assumption is as strong, or as weak, in my model, in which disagreement can occur on the equilibrium path, as in the standard property rights model (see Hart (1995)), in which equilibrium only takes place off the equilibrium 8

11 path 12. Third, I assume that the distribution of the trade payoffs isindependentof the ownership structure. As noted in the introduction, I make this assumption since I do not want the ownership structure to have a direct effect on the amount of private information. Finally, I assume that there is only uncertainty about the managers trade payoffs and not about their disagreement payoffs. This is not a critical restriction. A model with uncertainty over the disagreement payoffs givesthesameresultsasthose described below as long as ownership changes are assumed to shift the distributions of the disagreement payoffs. Theimportantpointhereisonlythatthereservationpayoffs, that is the difference between the trade and the disagreement payoffs, are uncertain. 2.1 The Analysis I firstsolvethebargaininggamethattakesplaceexpostandthenderivetheoptimal ownership structure on which the managers agree ex ante The Bargaining Stage At the ex post bargaining stage the buyer and the seller play a double auction to determine the terms of trade (taking the ownership structure as given). It is well known (see, for example, Chatterjee and Samuelson (1983)) that the double auction can have many Bayesian Nash equilibria. I focus on the linear Bayesian Nash equilibrium in which the managers strategies are linear functions of their trade payoffs. Idosoprimarily because Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983) have shown that if the players reservation prices are uniformly distributed on [0, 1] this linear Bayesian Nash equilibrium is the most efficient Bayesian Nash equilibrium of the double auction, and indeed of any voluntary bargaining game. Thus, at least for a part of the parameter space, the bargaining inefficiency on which I focus is not an artifact of the particular bargaining game or equilibrium I consider but is the minimum bargaining inefficiency that must arise in this economic setting. 12 I conjecture that my main results could be derived in a model in which the managers can renegotiate the ownership structures ex post as long as this renegotiation is costly. Renegotiation may be costly, for instance, because each manager has private information about how much they value the asset outside of the trading relationship. 9

12 The following proposition describes the equilibrium strategies and differs from the standard analysis of the double auction (see, for instance, Gibbons (1992)) only by allowing explicitly for non-zero disagreement payoffs. Proposition 1 The strategies ep b (π) p b (π) = ep s (1) if π 1 (5 + 3d(A)) 4 if π > 1 (5 + 3d(A)) 4 and where and ep s (c) p s (c) = ep b (0) ep b (π) = 1 12 (1 9b(A b)+3s(a s )) π ep s (c) = 1 12 (3 3b(A b)+9s(a s )) c, if c 1 (1 + 3d(A)) 4 if c< 1 (1 + 3d(A)), 4 form a linear Bayesian Nash equilibrium of the double auction. Proof: see appendix. For the remainder of the paper, when I refer to the equilibrium of the double auction, I mean the linear Bayesian Nash equilibrium in which the players adopt the strategies p b (π) and p s (c). It is important to observe that for any d(a) [ 1, 1) this equilibrium is ex post inefficient. To see this, note that in equilibrium trade takes place if and only if π c d(a)+ 1 (1 d(a)). 4 Thus, ex post efficient trading opportunities are not realized for any π c (d(a),d(a)+ 1 (1 d(a))). The inefficiency of the double auction, which was firstanalyzedinchatterjee and Samuelson (1983), is also illustrated in Figure 1: for any d (A) [ 1, 1) ex 4 post efficiencyrequirestradetotakeplaceinthe trade areabovetheboldline(g(a, c)) 10

13 and no trade to take place in the no trade area below the bold line (g(a, c)). The double auction does not achieve ex post efficiency since it does not realize efficient trading opportunities in the inefficiency area between the two diagonal lines g(a, c) and h(a, c) The Contracting Stage Ex ante the managers contract over the ownership structure A. Since they are risk neutral and not wealth constrained they agree on the ownership structure that maximizes social welfare, independent of its ex post distribution. Formally, the managers choose the optimal ownership structure that solves max W (d(a)), (1) A where W (d (A)) denotes social welfare and is given by W (d (A)) d (A)+E c,π [(π c d (A))q(c, π,d(a))], (2) for 1 if π c d (A)+ 1 (1 d (A)) 4 q (c, π,d(a)) 0 otherwise. Note that social welfare depends on the aggregate disagreement payoff d(a) and not on the distribution of the individual disagreement payoffs b(a b ) and s(a s ). Thisisthecase since, first, social welfare puts equal weight on each manager s individual payoff and, second, in the equilibrium of the double auction the probability of trade depends on the sum of the disagreement payoffs and not on their distribution. Therefore a change in the ownership structure only affects efficiency if it alters the aggregate disagreement payoff and not if it simply leads to a redistribution of disagreement payoffs fromone manager to the other. This establishes the following lemma. 11

14 Lemma 2 The efficiency of any ownership structure A depends on the aggregate disagreement payoff d(a) and not on the distribution of the individual disagreement payoffs b(a b ) and s(a s ). The key to solving the contracting problem (1) is to understand how a change in the aggregate disagreement payoff affects social welfare. Suppose the managers consider a change in the ownership structure from A to A 0 and that this leads to a reduction in the aggregate disagreement payoff from d to d 0 d(a 0 ) < d. The effect on social welfare of such a change is given by W (d 0 ) W (d) = (d d 0 )(1 q(c, π,d(a 0 ))) + (3) E c,π (π c d)(q(c, π,d(a 0 )) q(c, π,d(a))). On the one hand, the managers realize a lower aggregate payoff if they disagree even after the ownership change. This effect is always negative and is captured by the first term on the RHS of (3). On the other hand, however, a reduction in the aggregate disagreement payoff alsocommitsatleastoneofthemanagerstoamorecautious bargaining strategy. This increases the probability that trade takes place ex post. In particular, for any realizations of π and c that satisfy π c 3 4 d0 + 1, 3d trade will take place only after the ownership change. The second term on the RHS of (3) captures the welfare implication of the increase in the probability of trade. Its sign is ambiguous and depends crucially on the size of the reduction in the aggregate disagreement payoff. If the reduction is small, in the sense that 3 4 d0 + 1 d, the gains π c from each of the 4 additional trades are larger than the aggregate disagreement payoff d. Thus, in this case the increase in the probability of trade is unambiguously welfare improving. For larger reductions in the aggregate disagreement payoff, however, some of the additional trades the managers realize are ex ante inefficient, in the sense that they satisfy π c<d. While these trades are ex post efficient given d 0, the managers would be better off realizing the maximum aggregate disagreement payoff than engaging in these trades. Thus, for large reductions in the aggregate disagreement payoff, thatisfor 3 4 d0 + 1 < d, 4 the increased probability of trade has an ambiguous effect on social welfare. 12

15 These effects are also illustrated in Figures 2 and 3. For A = A the equilibrium of the double auction is inefficient since trade does not take place for realizations of π and c between g(a, c) and h(a, c). As shown in Figure 2, an ownership change that leads to a small reduction in the aggregate disagreement payoff shifts down h(,c) to a position somewhere above g(a, c). Thus the managers realize more efficient trades (the area between h(a, c) and h(a 0,c)) but also receive a lower payoff in the case of disagreement (below h(a 0,c)). Figure 3 shows that an ownership change that leads to a large reduction in the aggregate disagreement payoff shifts h(,c) to a position below g(a, c). Thus, such a change not only increases the probability of efficient trades (the area between h(a, c) and g(a, c)) and the cost of disagreement (the area below h(a 0,c)) but also increases the probability that the managers realize ex ante inefficient trades (the area between g(a, c) and h(a 0,c)). Faced with this trade-off, what ownership structure should the managers choose? It turns out the answer to this question is surprisingly straightforward: Proposition 3 At the ex ante stage it is weakly optimal for the parties to agree on the ownership structure ( A if d A dcrit = A otherwise, where d crit Proof: follows that Let d [ 1, 1] and consider the social welfare function W (d). From (2) it W (d) = 1 (1 + 3d)(9 + 10d 64 3d2 ) if 1 d (1 + 3d)(5 + 3d)2 if 1 d 1 3 and 64 d) (1 32 d)2 if 1 d 1 3 W 0 (d) = 3 (5 + 3d)(1 d)+ 1 ( d)2 if 1 d

16 The only stationary point is therefore given by d = 7 and, since W = 3, this 8 stationary point is a local minimum. Also, W ( 1) = W Thus, the solution to (1) is given by A if d and by A otherwise. Thus the managers optimally choose the ownership structure that minimizes their expected quasi-rents if, for a given distribution of trade payoffs, the minimum expected quasi-rents are small (i.e. when d is large) and they choose the ownership structure that maximizes their expected quasi-rents otherwise. To see the intuition for this proposition consider firstfigure4thatplotsthesocial welfare function W (d) for d [ 1, 1]. The key feature of W (d) is that it only has one interior stationary point and that this stationary point is a minimum. This not only implies that only A and A can be optimal but also that the former is optimal if d is small and that the latter is optimal if d is large. To understand why the social welfare function has this shape, consider the welfare effect of a marginal increase in d. It follows from the analysis above that the welfare benefit of a marginal increase in d is given by the higher payoff the managers realize in the case of disagreement while the welfare cost is given by the reduction in the probability that efficient trades take place 13. If d is small, disagreement does not occur very often. Thus, the welfare benefit ofanincrease in d is quite small and is indeed dominated by the welfare cost. The larger d, however, themorelikelyitisthatdisagreementoccursandthusthelargerthewelfarebenefit ofa further in increase in d. For d large enough, the welfare benefit ofafurtherincreasein d eventually dominates the welfare cost. The property that a marginal increase in d is welfare reducing for small d and welfare enhancing for large d is the key reason behind the main results of the simple model as summarized in Proposition Discussion The ownership structures that the model predicts are widely observed in the real world. To see this, suppose, without loss of generality, that a 1 is more useful to the buyer than 13 Above I showed that another benefit associatedwithanincreaseind is the reduction in the probability that managers realize ex ante inefficient trades. Note that this second benefit effect does not opperate on the margin, i.e. it is only realized for sufficiently large discrete changes in d. 14

17 a 2 and that a 2 is more useful to the seller than a 1. Thus, b(a 1 )+s(a 2 ) b(a 2 )+s(a 1 ). Furthermore, consider the following definitions: Definition 4 The assets a 1 and a 2 are non-synergistic if and only if b(a 1 )+s(a 2 ) max [b (a 1,a 2 )+s( ),b( )+s (a 1,a 2 )]. Definition 5 The assets a 1 and a 2 are buyer-synergistic if and only if b (a 1,a 2 )+s( ) max [b(a 1 )+s(a 2 ),b( )+s (a 1,a 2 )]. Definition 6 The assets a 1 and a 2 are seller-synergistic if and only if b( )+s (a 1,a 2 ) max [b(a 1 )+s(a 2 ),b(a 1,a 2 )+s( )]. Hence, assets are buyer-synergistic if, in the case of disagreement, the aggregate payoff is higher under buyer-integration than under seller- or non-integration. Similarly, assets are seller-synergistic if, in the case of disagreement, the aggregate payoff is higher under seller-integration than under buyer- or non-integration. The assets are non-synergistic if, in the case of disagreement, the aggregate payoff is higher under non-integration than under either buyer- or seller-integration. Finally, note that joint ownership of assets minimizes the aggregate disagreement payoff since, under this arrangement, neither manager can use the assets in the case of disagreement. It then immediately follows from Proposition 3 that the optimal ownership structure is given by joint ownership if d d crit A buyer-integration if d>d crit and assets are buyer-synergistic = seller-integration if d>d crit and assets are seller-synergistic non-integration if d>d crit and assets are non-synergistic Thus, joint ownership is optimal when, for a given distribution of trade payoffs, the minimum expected quasi-rents are large, i.e. when d is small. This is true independent 15

18 of whether the assets are synergistic or non-synergistic. Intuitively, when the minimum expected quasi-rents are large, the managers do not disagree very often. Thus the welfare costs of further increasing the quasi-rents by moving to joint ownership are quite small and are indeed dominated by the welfare gain. In the basic property rights model with ex ante investments joint ownership cannot be optimal (see Hart (1995)). Since joint ownership arrangements are, however, frequentlyobservedintherealworlditisimportanttodeveloptheoreticargumentsthat might explain their existence. A number of recent papers have extended the basic property rights model and shown that under certain conditions joint ownership can provide optimal investment incentives 14. This paper suggests an additional reason for why joint ownership may be optimal, namely that it minimizes ex post bargaining inefficiencies. Joint ownership is not optimal when, for a given distribution of trade payoffs, the minimum expected quasi-rents are small, i.e. when d is large. Instead, in this case integration is optimal if the assets are synergistic and non-integration is optimal if the assets are non-synergistic. When the minimum expected quasi-rents are small, the managers disagree very often. The welfare cost of a reduction in the aggregate disagreement payoff is therefore quite large and dominates the welfare benefit. The property rights literature has been criticized for not predicting asset clusters often enough (see Holmström (1999)). Asset clusters are, of course, observed very often since most firms own large numbers of assets while their workers typically have no ownership rights over the assets they use in the production process. In a recent paper Holmström (1999, p.88) asks: So why do firms own essentially all the nonhuman assets it uses in production? Why do workers - or for that matter any other stakeholder - rarely own any such assets? This strikes me as one of the most basic regularities that a theory of the firm needs to explain. In my model asset clusters arise when assets are synergistic and, for a given distribution of trade payoffs, the minimum expected quasi 14 Rajan and Zingales (1998) show that joint ownership can be optimal in a property rights model if the investments reduce the players outside options. Halonen (1995) shows that in an infinitely repeated game with ex ante investments joint ownership can be optimal for reputational reasons. Also, de Meza and Lockwood (1998) and Chiu (1998) show that joint ownership can be optimal when ex post bargaining takes the form of a Rubinstein alternating offers game with outside options. 16

19 rents are small. In this case the managers know that they will disagree very often and simply want to ensure that they realize as high a payoff as possible whenever they do disagree. When assets are synergistic this is achieved by clustering the ownership rights of all assets and giving them to the party that has the highest outside value for the assets. It is reassuring that all four potentially optimal ownership structures can be commonly observed. However, it of course remains an open empirical question whether they actually arise under the conditions predicted by the model. Note, though, that since the predictions in my model only depend on the level of the expected quasi-rents and the nature of the productive assets, and not on marginal investment incentives, they should, in principle, be easier to test empirically than the predictions of the existing property rights models (for a discussion of the empirical evidence of the property rights theory see Whinston (2000)). 3 The General Model with Complete Contracting Inowextendthesimplemodelbyallowingthemanagerstocontractovertheownership structure and the bargaining game that determines the price of the widget ex post. Also, I now allow for more general distributions of the trade payoffs. I firstshowthatthe main results of the simple model continue to hold in this more general set up. In section 3.4 I then argue that the results do not hold once I also allow for contingent ownership structures, that is once I allow for ownership structures to depend on information that is revealed after the initial contracting stage. The general model differs from that introduced in section 2 in four ways. First, at the ex ante stage the managers can now contract, not only over the ownership structure of the assets, but also over the ex post bargaining game that determines the price of the input. The managers can choose any bargaining game that satisfies the balanced budget constraint. Thus, I only require the payments to the seller to always equal the payments from the buyer. Second, the cumulative density functions of the trade payoffs π [π, π] and c [c, c] are now given by F b (π) and F s (c) respectively. I assume that the density functions f b (π) and f s (c) are continuous and strictly positive and that the 17

20 distributions satisfy the monotone hazard rate conditions d dπ ( f b (π) 1 F b (π) ) 0, π [π, π], and d dc ( f s(c) ) 0, c [c, c]. F s (c) Third, the bounds on the disagreement payoffs must now satisfy d<π c and d > π c. The first restriction ensures that, at least sometimes, there are gains from trade while the second restriction ensures that, at least sometimes, there are no gains from trade. These restrictions simplify the exposition and it is trivial to analyze the implications of relaxing them. Finally, I now assume that the managers can decide whether or not to participate in the ex post bargaining game after learning the realizations of the trade payoffs at the interim stage. If either the buyer or the seller decides not to participate in the bargaining game each manager realizes his or her respective disagreement payoff b(a) and s(a) 15. Before proceeding with the analysis, it is useful to note again how this general set up relates to the model analyzed in Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983). The key difference between their analysis and mine is that they solve for the optimal mechanism for given disagreement payoffs while I solve for the optimal mechanism and the optimal disagreement payoffs. My solution draws on their analysis, nevertheless. Another paper that is related to the general model that I study here is Cramton, Gibbons, and Klemperer (1987). They extend Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983) by allowing for more general ownership arrangements over the good that is to be traded (and also by allowing for more than two players). In contrast, I retain the assumption in Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983) that the seller initially owns the good that is to be traded but allow for general ownership arrangements over the assets that are required in producing it. The next section introduces the concept of a direct bargaining mechanism that I use in section 3.2 to solve the model. Section 3.3 gives a simple example of the general model with uniform distributions of trade payoffs and section 3.4 discusses the implications of allowing for contingent ownership structures. 15 The results in the simple model would be unchanged if I altered it by allowing the managers to opt out of the bargaining game at the interim stage. 18

21 3.1 The Direct Bargaining Mechanism In the analysis I make use of the well-known Revelation Principle which states that, for any Bayesian Nash equilibrium of any bargaining game, there exists a Bayesian incentive compatible direct mechanism that leads to the same outcome (see, for example, Myerson (1979, 1981)). Thus, instead of studying the very large set of all possible indirect bargaining games to which the parties can commit, I can restrict myself, without loss of generality, to Bayesian incentive compatible direct mechanisms. In a direct bargaining mechanism the players make reports of their trade payoffs after learning the realizations at the interim stage. A mediator then decides on the probability of trade and on the expected price. Denoting the buyer s and the seller s reports by bπ and bc respectively, a direct mechanism is then characterized by two functions: the probability of trade q(bc, bπ) and the expected price of the good t(bc, bπ). For a given mechanism (q( ),t( )), it is useful to define q s (bc) E π [q(bc, π)], q b (bπ) E c [q(c, bπ)], t s (bc) E π [t(bc, π)], and t b (bπ) E c [t(c, bπ)]. Thus, q s (bc) and t s (bc) respectively denote the seller s expected probability of trade and the transfer he expects to receive, given that he announces bc and that the buyer truthfully reveals her type. Similarly, q b (bπ) and t b (bπ) respectively denote the buyer s expected probability of trade and the transfer she expects to make if she announces bπ and the seller truthfully reveals his type. Furthermore, let U b (π) t b (π)+[1 q b (π)] b(a b )+πq b (π) and U s (c) t s (c)+[1 q s (c)] s(a s ) cq s (c) be the buyer s and the seller s expected utility from truthfully reporting their own type when the other party is also expected to be truthful. A direct mechanism is Bayesian incentive compatible if it is a Bayesian Nash equilibrium for the players to report their true trade payoffs. This will be the case if and 19

22 only if the Bayesian incentive compatibility constraints and U b (π) b(a b )+(π b(a b ))q b (π 0 ) t b (π 0 ) π, π 0 [π, π] (IC) U s (c) s(a s )+t s (c 0 ) (c + s(a s ))q s (c 0 ) c, c 0 [c, c]. are satisfied. A Bayesian incentive compatible mechanism is interim individually rational if, after learning their own type at the interim stage, each party prefers participating in the mechanism to realizing its disagreement payoff. For this to be the case the interim individual rationality constraints U b (π) b(a b ) π [π, π] (IR) and U s (c) s(a s ) c [c, c] need to be satisfied. 3.2 The Analysis At the ex ante stage, the risk neutral and liquidity unconstrained managers agree on the incentive compatible and individually rational mechanism (q( ),t( )) andonthe ownership structure A that maximize expected social welfare W (d(a), q( )), defined as W (d(a), q( )) d(a)+e π,c [(π c d(a))q(c, π)]. (4) Formally, the contracting problem can be stated as max W (d(a), q( )) subject to IC and IR. (5) A,q( ),t( ) To derive the solution to this contracting problem, consider the following two wellknown lemmas. 20

23 Lemma 7 Amechanism(q( ),t( )) is Bayesian incentive compatible if and only if q s (c) is non-increasing, q b (π) is non-decreasing, and U s (c) =U s (c)+ U b (π) =U b (π)+ Z c c Z π π q s (t)dt, q b (t)dt. Proof: see appendix. I can therefore replace the (IC) constraint in the contracting problem (5) by the (four) conditions specified in the lemma. The last two of these conditions can be used further to prove the next lemma. Lemma 8 A Bayesian incentive compatible and interim individually rational mechanism (q( ),t( )) satisfies U s (c)+u b (π) d(a) =E c,π [(π c d(a) 1 F b(π) f b (π) Proof: see appendix. The optimal trading rule and ownership structure therefore solve F s(c) )q(c, π)] 0. f s (c) s.t. E c,π [(π c d(a) 1 F b(π) f b (π) max W (d(a),q( )) (6) q( ),A F s(c) f s (c) )q(c, π)] 0, (IR* ) q s (c) is non-increasing, and q b (π) is non-decreasing. (IC * ) Given the solution to this problem, the optimal transfer rule can then be derived using Lemmas 7 and 8. It turns out, and I verify this claim below, that the (IC * ) constraints in the contracting problem (6) are not binding. Two observations can then be made. First, the individual disagreement payoffs enter the contracting problem symmetrically and additively. Thus, just as in the simple model, the aggregate disagreement payoff, and 21

24 not the distribution of the individual disagreement payoffs, matters in the contracting problem. Second, a marginal change in the aggregate disagreement payoff affects the contracting problem in two ways. On the one hand, for a given trading rule, an increase in the aggregate disagreement payoff increases the payoff the managers realize in the case of disagreement. This effect is clearly welfare improving. On the other hand, however, a marginal increase in the aggregate disagreement payoff also makes the participation constraint more binding and thus reduces the set of feasible trading rules. Other things equal this effect is welfare reducing. In this general model the managers therefore face a very similar trade-off to the trade-off in the simple model. The following proposition shows that the solutions to the contracting problems are also very similar in the two models. Proposition 9 The optimal ownership structure and trading rule are given by A = q (c, π) = ( A if d(a) dcrit A otherwise. ( 1 if π c d(a ) λ(d(a )) [ 1 F b(π) 1+λ(d(A )) f b + F s(c) ] (π) f s (c) 0 otherwise. where d crit [, ] and λ(d(a )) (0, ). Proof: In the contracting problem (6), replace the discrete variable d(a) with the continuously defined d (, ). The augmented contracting problem that needs to be considered is therefore given by s.t. max W (d, q( )) (7) q( ) [0,1],d [d,d] E c,π [(π c d 1 F b(π) f b (π) F s(c) f s (c) )q(c, π)] 0, (IR** ) q s (c) is non-increasing, and q b (π) is non-decreasing. (IC ** ) 22

25 I first solve for the optimal disagreement payoff d and trading rule q ( ) that solve (7) subject to (IR ** ) and then confirm that q ( ) also satisfies the (IC ** )constraint. The Lagrangian that I need to consider is then given by L(q( ),d,λ) d + E c,π [π c d + λ(π c d 1 F b(π) f b (π) F s(c) )]q(c, π), f s (c) where λ [0, ) is the Lagrangian multiplier. InLemma10Ishowthatthe(IR ** ) constraint must be binding at the optimum 16. The necessary first order conditions are therefore given by L(q( ),d,λ) 0 if q( ) =1 L(q( ),d,λ) 0 if d = d = =0 if 0 <q( ) < 1 = =0 if d <d<d q( ) d 0 if q( ) =0, 0 if d = d, and L(q( ),d,λ) λ For a given d, the optimal trading rule then is =0. q(c, π, d,λ(d)) = ( 1 if π c d λ(d) [ 1 F b(π) 1+λ(d) f b + F s(c) ] (π) f s (c) 0 otherwise, where λ(d) solves L(q(c, π, d,λ), d,λ) =0. (8) λ InLemma11Ishowthatforanyd (, ) there exists a λ(d) > 0 that solves (8) 17. To find the optimal disagreement payoff d, consider the bordered Hessian H(q( ),d,λ) 2 L(q( ),d,λ) λ 2 2 L(q( ),d,λ) λ d 2 L(q( ),d,λ) λ q( ) 2 L(q( ),d,λ) λ d 2 L(q( ),d,λ) d 2 2 L(q( ),d,λ) d q( ) 2 L(q( ),d,λ) λ q( ) 2 L(q( ),d,λ) d q( ) 2 L(q( ),d,λ) q( ) 2. Evaluated for q(c, π, d,λ(d)) and λ(d) its determinant is given by 16 I relegate this lemma to the appendix since it follows immediately from Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983). 17 I also relegate this lemma to the appendix since it follows immediately from Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983). 23

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 26 January 2015 Failure of the Coase Theorem Recall that the Coase Theorem implies that two parties, when faced with a potential

More information

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore*

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore* Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts by Oliver Hart and John Moore* Since Ronald Coase s famous 1937 article (Coase (1937)), economists have grappled with the question of what characterizes

More information

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Coase (1937) If the market is an efficient method of resource allocation, as argued by neoclassical economics, then why do so many transactions

More information

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham So far we have considered efficient auctions What about maximizing the seller s revenue? she may be willing to risk failing to sell the good she may be

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions 1. (45 points) Consider the following normal form game played by Bruce and Sheila: L Sheila R T 1, 0 3, 3 Bruce M 1, x 0, 0 B 0, 0 4, 1 (a) Suppose

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2018 1 / 36 Coase (1937) If the market is an efficient method of resource allocation, as argued by neoclassical economics, then why do so many transactions

More information

Rethinking Incomplete Contracts

Rethinking Incomplete Contracts Rethinking Incomplete Contracts By Oliver Hart Chicago November, 2010 It is generally accepted that the contracts that parties even sophisticated ones -- write are often significantly incomplete. Some

More information

Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin. The allocation of authority under limited liability

Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin. The allocation of authority under limited liability Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin Nr. 2005/25 VOLKSWIRTSCHAFTLICHE REIHE The allocation of authority under limited liability Kerstin Puschke ISBN

More information

Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs

Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs Daniel Müller and Patrick W. Schmitz 207 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/90784/ MPRA

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights? Leonardo Felli 15 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5 Property Rights Theory The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights? For an answer we need to distinguish

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012 The Revenue Equivalence Theorem Note: This is a only a draft

More information

The Optimality of Being Efficient. Lawrence Ausubel and Peter Cramton Department of Economics University of Maryland

The Optimality of Being Efficient. Lawrence Ausubel and Peter Cramton Department of Economics University of Maryland The Optimality of Being Efficient Lawrence Ausubel and Peter Cramton Department of Economics University of Maryland 1 Common Reaction Why worry about efficiency, when there is resale? Our Conclusion Why

More information

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Mechanism Design and Auctions Multiagent Systems (BE4M36MAS) Mechanism Design and Auctions Branislav Bošanský and Michal Pěchouček Artificial Intelligence Center, Department of Computer Science, Faculty of Electrical Engineering, Czech

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

Delegation of Decision-Making in Organizations. Margaret A. Meyer Nuffield College and Department of Economics Oxford University

Delegation of Decision-Making in Organizations. Margaret A. Meyer Nuffield College and Department of Economics Oxford University Delegation of Decision-Making in Organizations Margaret A. Meyer Nuffield College and Department of Economics Oxford University 2017 What determines the degree to which decision-making is centralized (concentrated

More information

The Role of Exclusive Contracts in Facilitating Market Transactions *

The Role of Exclusive Contracts in Facilitating Market Transactions * The Role of Exclusive Contracts in Facilitating Market Transactions * Niko Matouschek Northwestern University Paolo Ramezzana Bates White, LLC Abstract We examine the relationship between market conditions

More information

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade Jesse A. Schwartz Kennesaw State University Quan Wen Vanderbilt University May 2012 Abstract In a bilateral bargaining problem with private

More information

Relational Contracts and the Theory of the Firm: A Renegotiation-Proof Approach

Relational Contracts and the Theory of the Firm: A Renegotiation-Proof Approach Relational Contracts and the Theory of the Firm: A Renegotiation-Proof Approach M. Deniz Yavuz January 15, 2007 deniz.yavuz@asu.edu, Arizona State University. I would like to thank Benjamin Polak for his

More information

Relational Incentive Contracts

Relational Incentive Contracts Relational Incentive Contracts Jonathan Levin May 2006 These notes consider Levin s (2003) paper on relational incentive contracts, which studies how self-enforcing contracts can provide incentives in

More information

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions? March 3, 215 Steven A. Matthews, A Technical Primer on Auction Theory I: Independent Private Values, Northwestern University CMSEMS Discussion Paper No. 196, May, 1995. This paper is posted on the course

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Leonardo Felli 7 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Contract Theory has become only recently a subfield of Economics. As the name suggest the main object of the analysis is a contract. Therefore

More information

Competition for goods in buyer-seller networks

Competition for goods in buyer-seller networks Rev. Econ. Design 5, 301 331 (2000) c Springer-Verlag 2000 Competition for goods in buyer-seller networks Rachel E. Kranton 1, Deborah F. Minehart 2 1 Department of Economics, University of Maryland, College

More information

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments Kentaro Tomoeda October 31, 215 Abstract This article analyzes the implementability of efficient investments for two commonly used mechanisms in single-item

More information

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Online Appendix for Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Giacomo Rodano Bank of Italy Nicolas Serrano-Velarde Bocconi University December 23, 2014 Emanuele Tarantino University of Mannheim 1 1 Reorganization,

More information

Alternative sources of information-based trade

Alternative sources of information-based trade no trade theorems [ABSTRACT No trade theorems represent a class of results showing that, under certain conditions, trade in asset markets between rational agents cannot be explained on the basis of differences

More information

Formal Contracts, Relational Contracts, and the Holdup Problem

Formal Contracts, Relational Contracts, and the Holdup Problem Formal Contracts, Relational Contracts, and the Holdup Problem Hideshi Itoh Hodaka Morita September 3, 2004 We are grateful to Murali Agastya, Shingo Ishiguro, Shinsuke Kambe, Kieron Meagher, Bill Schworm,

More information

Auction Theory Lecture Note, David McAdams, Fall Bilateral Trade

Auction Theory Lecture Note, David McAdams, Fall Bilateral Trade Auction Theory Lecture Note, Daid McAdams, Fall 2008 1 Bilateral Trade ** Reised 10-17-08: An error in the discussion after Theorem 4 has been corrected. We shall use the example of bilateral trade to

More information

How to Sell a (Bankrupt) Company

How to Sell a (Bankrupt) Company How to Sell a (Bankrupt) Company Francesca Cornelli London Business School and CEPR Leonardo Felli London School of Economics and CEPR December 2010 Abstract. The restructuring of a bankrupt company often

More information

Transaction Costs and the Robustness of the Coase Theorem

Transaction Costs and the Robustness of the Coase Theorem Transaction Costs and the Robustness of the Coase Theorem Luca Anderlini (Southampton University and Georgetown University) Leonardo Felli (London School of Economics) June 2001 Abstract. This paper explores

More information

Backward Integration and Risk Sharing in a Bilateral Monopoly

Backward Integration and Risk Sharing in a Bilateral Monopoly Backward Integration and Risk Sharing in a Bilateral Monopoly Dr. Lee, Yao-Hsien, ssociate Professor, Finance Department, Chung-Hua University, Taiwan Lin, Yi-Shin, Ph. D. Candidate, Institute of Technology

More information

April 29, X ( ) for all. Using to denote a true type and areport,let

April 29, X ( ) for all. Using to denote a true type and areport,let April 29, 2015 "A Characterization of Efficient, Bayesian Incentive Compatible Mechanisms," by S. R. Williams. Economic Theory 14, 155-180 (1999). AcommonresultinBayesianmechanismdesignshowsthatexpostefficiency

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 9 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3 Consider now a different cause for the failure of the Coase Theorem: the presence of transaction costs. Of course for this to be an interesting

More information

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations Leslie M. Marx Duke University Greg Shaffer University of Rochester December 2006 Abstract When two sellers negotiate terms of trade with a common buyer, the

More information

Notes on Auctions. Theorem 1 In a second price sealed bid auction bidding your valuation is always a weakly dominant strategy.

Notes on Auctions. Theorem 1 In a second price sealed bid auction bidding your valuation is always a weakly dominant strategy. Notes on Auctions Second Price Sealed Bid Auctions These are the easiest auctions to analyze. Theorem In a second price sealed bid auction bidding your valuation is always a weakly dominant strategy. Proof

More information

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Journal of Economics and Finance Volume 24 Number 1 Spring 2000 Pages 56-63 Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Veronika Grimm and Ulrich Schmidt* Abstract This paper considers the classical independent

More information

Incomplete contracts and optimal ownership of public goods

Incomplete contracts and optimal ownership of public goods MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Incomplete contracts and optimal ownership of public goods Patrick W. Schmitz September 2012 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/41730/ MPRA Paper No. 41730, posted

More information

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1 Auction Theory II Lecture 19 Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1 Lecture Overview 1 Recap 2 First-Price Auctions 3 Revenue Equivalence 4 Optimal Auctions Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 2 Motivation

More information

Does Competition Solve the Hold-up Problem?

Does Competition Solve the Hold-up Problem? Does Competition Solve the Hold-up Problem? Leonardo Felli (London School of Economics) Kevin Roberts (Nuffield College, Oxford) October 2015 Abstract. In an environment in which heterogenous buyers and

More information

Independent Private Value Auctions

Independent Private Value Auctions John Nachbar April 16, 214 ndependent Private Value Auctions The following notes are based on the treatment in Krishna (29); see also Milgrom (24). focus on only the simplest auction environments. Consider

More information

Exit Options in Incomplete Contracts with Asymmetric Information

Exit Options in Incomplete Contracts with Asymmetric Information Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin 2008/23 Exit Options in Incomplete Contracts with Asymmetric Information Helmut Bester ; Daniel Krähmer 3-938369-94-9

More information

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions. Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions. Ilan Kremer and Andrzej Skrzypacz March 21, 2002 1 Introduction In many papers considering the sale of many objects in a sequence of auctions the seller

More information

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty Chifeng Dai Department of Economics Southern Illinois University Carbondale, IL 62901, USA August 2014 Abstract We study optimal

More information

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts 6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts Asu Ozdaglar MIT February 9, 2010 1 Introduction Outline Review Examples of Pure Strategy Nash Equilibria

More information

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening NMI Workshop, ISI Delhi August 3, 2015 Motivation A seller wants to sell an object to a prospective buyer(s). Buyer has imperfect private information θ about

More information

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM Course content Why do firms exist? And why do some firms cease to exist? How are firms financed? How are firms managed? These questions are analysed by using various models

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH http://www.kier.kyoto-u.ac.jp/index.html Discussion Paper No. 657 The Buy Price in Auctions with Discrete Type Distributions Yusuke Inami

More information

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information November 25, 2013 1 Single-Agent Problems 1. Nonlinear Pricing with Two Types Suppose a seller of wine faces two types of customers, θ 1 and θ 2, where θ 2 >

More information

Procurement with Unforeseen Contingencies

Procurement with Unforeseen Contingencies Procurement with Unforeseen Contingencies Fabian Herweg University of Bayreuth, CESifo, and CEPR Klaus M. Schmidt University of Munich, CESifo and CEPR This version: November 6, 2016 VERY PRILIMINARY Please

More information

Does Competition Solve the Hold-up Problem?

Does Competition Solve the Hold-up Problem? Does Competition Solve the Hold-up Problem? Leonardo Felli (London School of Economics) Kevin Roberts (Nuffield College, Oxford) February 2000 Preliminary Version Comments Welcome Abstract. In an environment

More information

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Ahmer Tarar Department of Political Science Texas A&M University 4348 TAMU College Station, TX 77843-4348 email: ahmertarar@pols.tamu.edu

More information

An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting

An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting Ph.D. Seminar in Corporate Finance Lecture 4 An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting (Aghion-Bolton, Review of Economic Studies, 1982) S. Viswanathan The paper analyzes capital structure

More information

Practice Problems. w U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Practice Problems. w U(w, e) = p w e 2, Practice Problems nformation Economics (Ec 55) George Georgiadis Problem. Static Moral Hazard Consider an agency relationship in which the principal contracts with the agent. The monetary result of the

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński Decision Making in Manufacturing and Services Vol. 9 2015 No. 1 pp. 79 88 Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment Andrzej Paliński Abstract. This paper presents a model of bank-loan repayment as

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

DOES COMPETITION SOLVE THE HOLD-UP PROBLEM? *

DOES COMPETITION SOLVE THE HOLD-UP PROBLEM? * DOES COMPETITION SOLVE THE HOLD-UP PROBLEM? * by Leonardo Felli London School of Economics and Political Science and Kevin Roberts Nuffield College, Oxford Contents: Abstract 1. Introduction 2. Related

More information

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy Yangbo Song Economics Department, UCLA June 30, 2014 Yangbo Song UCLA June 30, 2014 1 / 31 Game theory Game theory is a methodology used to analyze strategic situations in

More information

Multi-agent contracts with positive externalities

Multi-agent contracts with positive externalities Multi-agent contracts with positive externalities Isabelle Brocas University of Southern California and CEPR Preliminary and incomplete Abstract I consider a model where a principal decides whether to

More information

Simple Efficient Contracts in Complex Environments

Simple Efficient Contracts in Complex Environments Simple Efficient Contracts in Complex Environments 5REHUW(YDQV 0DUFK &:3( 1RWWREHTXRWHGZLWKRXWSHUPLVVLRQ Simple Efficient Contracts in Complex Environments Robert Evans St. John s College, Cambridge, UK.

More information

CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #18: Multi-Parameter Revenue-Maximization

CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #18: Multi-Parameter Revenue-Maximization CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #18: Multi-Parameter Revenue-Maximization Tim Roughgarden March 5, 2014 1 Review of Single-Parameter Revenue Maximization With this lecture we commence the

More information

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University Auctions Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University AE4M36MAS Autumn 2014 - Lecture 12 Where are We? Agent architectures (inc. BDI

More information

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems Microeconomics II CIDE, MsC Economics List of Problems 1. There are three people, Amy (A), Bart (B) and Chris (C): A and B have hats. These three people are arranged in a room so that B can see everything

More information

Auction Theory: Some Basics

Auction Theory: Some Basics Auction Theory: Some Basics Arunava Sen Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi ICRIER Conference on Telecom, March 7, 2014 Outline Outline Single Good Problem Outline Single Good Problem First Price Auction

More information

Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard with Multidimensional Types

Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard with Multidimensional Types 6631 2017 August 2017 Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard with Multidimensional Types Suehyun Kwon Impressum: CESifo Working Papers ISSN 2364 1428 (electronic version) Publisher and distributor: Munich

More information

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Joan Llull Structural Micro. IDEA PhD Program I. Dynamic Discrete Games with Imperfect Information A. Motivating example: firm entry and

More information

Optimal Delay in Committees

Optimal Delay in Committees Optimal Delay in Committees ETTORE DAMIANO University of Toronto LI, HAO University of British Columbia WING SUEN University of Hong Kong July 4, 2012 Abstract. We consider a committee problem in which

More information

Entry Barriers. Özlem Bedre-Defolie. July 6, European School of Management and Technology

Entry Barriers. Özlem Bedre-Defolie. July 6, European School of Management and Technology Entry Barriers Özlem Bedre-Defolie European School of Management and Technology July 6, 2018 Bedre-Defolie (ESMT) Entry Barriers July 6, 2018 1 / 36 Exclusive Customer Contacts (No Downstream Competition)

More information

Debt Contracts and Cooperative Improvements

Debt Contracts and Cooperative Improvements Debt Contracts and Cooperative Improvements Stefan Krasa Tridib Sharma Anne P. Villamil February 9, 2004 Abstract In this paper we consider a dynamic game with imperfect information between a borrower

More information

THE MIRRLEES APPROACH TO MECHANISM DESIGN WITH RENEGOTIATION (WITH APPLICATIONS TO HOLD-UP AND RISK SHARING) By Ilya Segal and Michael D.

THE MIRRLEES APPROACH TO MECHANISM DESIGN WITH RENEGOTIATION (WITH APPLICATIONS TO HOLD-UP AND RISK SHARING) By Ilya Segal and Michael D. Econometrica, Vol. 70, No. 1 (January, 2002), 1 45 THE MIRRLEES APPROACH TO MECHANISM DESIGN WITH RENEGOTIATION (WITH APPLICATIONS TO HOLD-UP AND RISK SHARING) By Ilya Segal and Michael D. Whinston 1 The

More information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Topic 5: Information Economics 21, Summer 2002 Andreas Bentz Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Introduction

More information

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models Preliminary Lecture Notes Hongbin Cai and Xi Weng Department of Applied Economics, Guanghua School of Management Peking University November 2014 Contents 1 Static Moral Hazard

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017 Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 017 1. Sheila moves first and chooses either H or L. Bruce receives a signal, h or l, about Sheila s behavior. The distribution

More information

Practice Problems. U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Practice Problems. U(w, e) = p w e 2, Practice Problems Information Economics (Ec 515) George Georgiadis Problem 1. Static Moral Hazard Consider an agency relationship in which the principal contracts with the agent. The monetary result of

More information

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University Auctions Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University AE4M36MAS Autumn 2015 - Lecture 12 Where are We? Agent architectures (inc. BDI

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 22 COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY Correlated Strategies and Correlated

More information

The inadequacy of specificity and role of importance in explaining hold-up

The inadequacy of specificity and role of importance in explaining hold-up The inadequacy of specificity and role of importance in explaining hold-up Jakob Lage Hansen LINK Department of Industrial Economics and Strategy Copenhagen Business School Howitzvej 60, 2000 Frederiksberg,

More information

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam Summer 2018 Microeconomics Qualifying Exam There are 100 points possible on this exam, 50 points each for Prof. Lozada s questions and Prof. Dugar s questions. Each professor asks you to do two long questions

More information

Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives. Alan V. S. Douglas

Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives. Alan V. S. Douglas Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives by Alan V. S. Douglas JEL classification codes: G3, D82. Keywords: Capital structure, Optimal Compensation, Manager-Owner and Shareholder-

More information

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types Dilip Mookherjee Boston University Ec 703b Lecture 1 (text: FT Ch 7, 243-257) DM (BU) Mech Design 703b.1 2019 1 / 1 Introduction Introduction to Mechanism

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Bargaining + Theory of the Firm 1 Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics December 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Bargaining + Theory of the Firm 1 Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics December 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Bargaining + Theory of the Firm 1 Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics December 2016 1 Axiomatic bargaining theory Before noncooperative bargaining theory, there was

More information

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Economic Theory 14, 247±253 (1999) Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Christopher M. Snyder Department of Economics, George Washington University, 2201 G Street

More information

Double Auction Markets vs. Matching & Bargaining Markets: Comparing the Rates at which They Converge to Efficiency

Double Auction Markets vs. Matching & Bargaining Markets: Comparing the Rates at which They Converge to Efficiency Double Auction Markets vs. Matching & Bargaining Markets: Comparing the Rates at which They Converge to Efficiency Mark Satterthwaite Northwestern University October 25, 2007 1 Overview Bargaining, private

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017 Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 07. (40 points) Consider a Cournot duopoly. The market price is given by q q, where q and q are the quantities of output produced

More information

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Chapter 5 Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Until now we implicitly adopted a view that a Nash equilibrium is a desirable outcome of a strategic game. In this chapter we consider two alternative

More information

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Juyan Zhang and Yi Zhang December 20, 2010 Abstract We investigate hold-up with simultaneous and sequential investment. We show that if the encouragement

More information

Bilateral trading with incomplete information and Price convergence in a Small Market: The continuous support case

Bilateral trading with incomplete information and Price convergence in a Small Market: The continuous support case Bilateral trading with incomplete information and Price convergence in a Small Market: The continuous support case Kalyan Chatterjee Kaustav Das November 18, 2017 Abstract Chatterjee and Das (Chatterjee,K.,

More information

Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding October 24, Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding

Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding October 24, Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding 1 Examples of Multiunit Auctions Spectrum Licenses Bus Routes in London IBM procurements Treasury Bills Note: Heterogenous vs Homogenous Goods 2 Challenges in Multiunit

More information

Homework 3: Asymmetric Information

Homework 3: Asymmetric Information Homework 3: Asymmetric Information 1. Public Goods Provision A firm is considering building a public good (e.g. a swimming pool). There are n agents in the economy, each with IID private value θ i [0,

More information

The Fundamental Transformation Reconsidered: Dixit vs. Williamson

The Fundamental Transformation Reconsidered: Dixit vs. Williamson The Fundamental Transformation Reconsidered: Dixit vs. Williamson Antonio Nicita * and Massimiliano Vatiero ** Abstract Comparing the literature on hold-up with the one on strategic entry deterrence leads

More information

All Equilibrium Revenues in Buy Price Auctions

All Equilibrium Revenues in Buy Price Auctions All Equilibrium Revenues in Buy Price Auctions Yusuke Inami Graduate School of Economics, Kyoto University This version: January 009 Abstract This note considers second-price, sealed-bid auctions with

More information

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Evaluating Strategic Forecasters Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Motivation Forecasters are sought after in a variety of

More information

LI Reunión Anual. Noviembre de Managing Strategic Buyers: Should a Seller Ban Resale? Beccuti, Juan Coleff, Joaquin

LI Reunión Anual. Noviembre de Managing Strategic Buyers: Should a Seller Ban Resale? Beccuti, Juan Coleff, Joaquin ANALES ASOCIACION ARGENTINA DE ECONOMIA POLITICA LI Reunión Anual Noviembre de 016 ISSN 185-00 ISBN 978-987-8590-4-6 Managing Strategic Buyers: Should a Seller Ban Resale? Beccuti, Juan Coleff, Joaquin

More information

International Journal of Industrial Organization

International Journal of Industrial Organization International Journal of Industrial Organization 8 (010) 451 463 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect International Journal of Industrial Organization journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ijio

More information

On the Impossibility of Core-Selecting Auctions

On the Impossibility of Core-Selecting Auctions On the Impossibility of Core-Selecting Auctions Jacob K. Goeree and Yuanchuan Lien November 10, 009 Abstract When goods are substitutes, the Vickrey auction produces efficient, core outcomes that yield

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion?

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion? Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion? Patrick Rey and Michael D. Whinston 1 Introduction In a recent paper, Marx and Shaffer (2007) study a model of vertical contracting between a manufacturer and two

More information

Short-term, Long-term, and Continuing Contracts

Short-term, Long-term, and Continuing Contracts Short-term, Long-term, and Continuing Contracts Maija Halonen-Akatwijuka and Oliver Hart Essex University, 12 June 2015 1 A large literature in economics and law has studied why parties write long-term

More information

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Juyan Zhang and Yi Zhang February 20, 2011 Abstract We investigate hold-up in the case of both simultaneous and sequential investment. We show that if

More information