Chapter 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Chapter 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility"

Transcription

1 Chapter 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility he implied volatility was first introduced in the paper [LR76] of H.A. Latané and R.J. Rendleman under the name the implied standard deviation. Latané and Rendleman studied standard deviations of asset returns, which are implied in actual call option prices when investors price options according to the Black Scholes model. For a general model of call option prices, the implied volatility can be obtained by inverting the Black Scholes call pricing function with respect to the volatility variable and composing the resulting inverse function with the original call pricing function. his chapter mainly concerns the asymptotics of the implied volatility at extreme strikes. In Sect. 9., we define the implied volatility in general models of call option prices and discuss its elementary properties. Implied volatility models free of static arbitrage are characterized in Sect. 9. see heorem 9.6. he rest of the chapter is devoted to sharp asymptotic formulas with error estimates for the implied volatility. We discuss asymptotic formulas of various orders, and show how certain symmetries hidden in stochastic asset price models allow to analyze the asymptotic behavior of the implied volatility for small strikes, by using information about its behavior for large strikes. hese symmetries become more explicit in the so-called symmetric models, which are also discussed in the present chapter. 9. Implied Volatility in General Option Pricing Models Fix >0 and >0. hen the function ρσ = C BS,,σ is increasing on 0,. his follows from the fact that the Greek vega is positive see Sect If 0 <<x 0 e r, then the range of the function ρ coincides with the interval x 0 e r,x 0, while for x 0 e r, the range of ρ is the interval 0,x 0. Definition 9. Let C be a call pricing function. For, 0,, the implied volatility I, associated with C is the value of the volatility σ in the Black Scholes model for which C, = C BS,,σ. he implied volatility I, is defined only if such a number σ exists and is unique. A. Gulisashvili, Analytically ractable Stochastic Stock Price Models, Springer Finance, DOI 0.007/ _9, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 0 43

2 44 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility It follows from the discussion above that if 0 <<x 0 e r, then the condition x 0 e r <C,<x 0 is necessary for the existence of the implied volatility I,. Similarly, if x 0 e r, then I, is defined if and only if 0 <C,<x 0. Note that the inequality C, < x 0 holds for all 0 and >0. Moreover, if, [0,, then x0 e r + C,. In the next definitions, we introduce special classes of call pricing functions. Definition 9. he class PF consists of all call pricing functions C, forwhich one of the following equivalent conditions holds:. C, > 0 for all >0and >0with x 0 e r.. P,>e r x 0 for all >0and >0with x 0 e r. 3. For every > 0 and all a>0 the random variable X is such that P [X <a] <. Definition 9.3 he class PF 0 consists of all call pricing functions C, for which one of the following equivalent conditions holds:. P,>0 for all >0and >0with <x 0 e r.. C, > x 0 e r for all >0and >0with <x 0 e r. 3. For every > 0 and all a>0 the random variable X is such that 0 < P [X <a]. Remark 9.4 Suppose the maturity >0 is fixed, and consider the pricing function C and the implied volatility I as functions of the strike price. IfC PF, then the implied volatility I is defined for large values of. his allows to study the asymptotic behavior of the implied volatility as. Similarly, if C PF 0, then Iexists for small values of. Finally, if C PF PF 0, then the implied volatility I,exists for all >0 and >0. 9. Implied Volatility Surfaces and Static Arbitrage Let I, with, 0, be a positive function of two variables, and suppose we would like to model the implied volatility surface by this function. hen the function C defined on [0, by C BS,, I,, if, 0,, C, = x 0 +, if = 0, 0, 9. x 0, if 0, = 0, where x 0 is the initial price of the asset in the Black Scholes model, should be a call pricing function. For the sake of simplicity, we will assume that r = 0. he next definition concerns the implied volatility in a no-arbitrage environment.

3 9. Implied Volatility Surfaces and Static Arbitrage 45 Definition 9.5 It is said that the function I modeling the implied volatility is free of static arbitrage if the model of call prices given by the function C in 9. isfree of static arbitrage see Definition 8.. Our next goal is to provide necessary and sufficient conditions for the absence of static arbitrage in a given implied volatility model. heorem 9.6 Suppose the function I models the implied volatility. Suppose also that for every >0the function I, is twice differentiable on 0,. hen I is free of static arbitrage if and only if the following conditions hold:. For all, 0,, I I + I I x 0 I 4 I + I I For every >0 the function I,is increasing on 0,. 3. For every >0, lim d,,i,=. Proof It suffices to prove that the conditions in heorem 8.3, formulated for the function C given by 9., are equivalent to conditions 3 in heorem 9.6. Fix >0, and differentiate the function C on 0, with respect to. his gives C = C BS C BS I,,I, +,,I, σ. Differentiating again, we obtain C = C BS C BS,,I, + σ + C BS σ,,i, I I,,I, + C BS I,,I, σ. Next, taking into account explicit formulas for the Greeks see Sect. 8.4, we see that for every >0the convexity of the function C, on 0, is equivalent to the following inequality: I + d,,i, I I d,, I, d,,i, + I I + I 0, >0. 9.3

4 46 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility It is not hard to see, using the definition of d and d, that 9.3 is equivalent to 9.. Hence the convexity of the function C0, on 0, is equivalent to the validity of 9.. We will next turn our attention to the convexity conditions for the function C, on [0,. Let us assume that condition in heorem 9.6 holds, and put ϕ = C,. hen the function ϕ is twice differentiable and convex on 0,. Moreover, the function ϕ is increasing on 0,, and it follows from 8.7 that for all 0 <x<y<, ϕ x ϕy ϕx y x ϕ y. 9.4 Using the definition of the Black Scholes call pricing function, we see that for all >0 and >0, It will be shown next that ϕ = x d,,i, 0 π e y d,,i, e y dy. 9.5 π lim d,,i, = Indeed, for small values of we have d,,i= x 0 + I x 0 I, 9.7 and 9.6 follows. Using 9.5, we obtain the following equality: dy lim C, = x herefore, the function C, is continuous on [0,. Our next goal is to prove the differentiability of this function from the right at = 0. It follows from 9.4 that there exists the limit M = lim 0 ϕ. In addition, 9.4 and 9.8 give M ϕs ϕ0 S = ϕs x 0 S ϕ S for all 0 <<S<. herefore M = ϕ + 0. Moreover, 9.5 and 9.7imply ϕ = x 0 x 0 π + π e y d,,i, e y d,,i, dy dy

5 9. Implied Volatility Surfaces and Static Arbitrage 47 = x 0 x 0 π e y d,,i, = x 0 x 0 e y π x 0 = x 0 + o dy + o dy + o as 0. herefore, M =, and it follows that for every >0 the function C, is convex on [0, use affine extrapolation. he next step in the proof deals with condition 3 in heorem 9.6. Our goal is to show that lim d,,i, = lim C, = We will first prove the following equality: lim d,,i, =. 9.0 Suppose d,,i, does not tend to as. hen there exists a sequence n such that d, n,i, n e y dy c>0 for all n. It follows from 9.5 that C, n <0forn>n 0, which is impossible. herefore, 9.0 holds. It will be shown next that we always have d,,i, e y dy 0 9. as. Reasoning as in 9.7, we see that for large values of, d,,i x Using formula 8.5, we obtain F d,,i, exp { d,,i, as, where F denotes the function on the left-hand side of 9.. It follows from 9.0 and 9. that 9. holds. Nowit isclearthat 9.5 impliestheequivalence in 9.9. Note that the condition on the right-hand side of 9.9 also holds for = 0. his follows from the definition of the function C. },

6 48 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility Next, we turn our attention to condition in heorem 9.6. It is not hard to see that this condition is equivalent to the following: On the other hand, + I 0, > C = C BS,,I+ C BS σ,,i I, and using the formulas for the Greeks in Sect. 8.4, we obtain C = exp π { d,,i, }[ + I ]. Now 9.3 implies that condition in heorem 9.6 is equivalent to the following condition. For all >0, the function C, is non-decreasing on 0,. For = 0, the same conclusion follows from the definition of the function C. In addition, the function C, is also non-decreasing on [0,. Indeed, for any volatility parameter σ in the Black Scholes model, we have x 0 + C BS,,σ, 0, 0. herefore, C0, C,. Let us denote by μ the second distributional derivative of the function C,, and suppose that the conditions in the formulation of heorem 9.6 hold for the function C. Recall that ϕ + 0 = x 0, ϕ + 0 =, and lim ϕ = 0. he function ϕ is non-decreasing see 9.4 and integrable on [0,. herefore, ϕ is non-positive. Our next goal is to prove that lim ϕ = Using 9.4, we see that ϕ ϕ ϕ, and it is clear that the previous estimate implies 9.4. Next, taking into account 9.4, we obtain μ [0, = lim ϕ ϕ + 0 =. Moreover, the integration by parts formula for Stieltjes integrals implies the following equality: xdμ x = ϕ + 0 lim ϕ + lim ϕ = x 0. [0, It follows that condition in heorem 8.3 is valid for the function C, provided that the conditions in the formulation of heorem 9.6 hold. Finally, it is not hard to see, taking into account what was said above and applying heorem 8.3, that heorem 9.6 holds.

7 9.3 Asymptotic Behavior of Implied Volatility Near Infinity Asymptotic Behavior of Implied Volatility Near Infinity In this section, we find sharp asymptotic formulas for the implied volatility I associated with a general call pricing function C. It is assumed that the maturity is fixed and the implied volatility is considered as a function of the strike price. We also assume that C PF. his guarantees the existence of the implied volatility for large values of the strike price. he next theorem provides an asymptotic formula for the implied volatility associated with a general call pricing function. heorem 9.7 Let C PF. hen I= + + O 9.5 as. heorem 9.7 and the mean value theorem imply the following statement: Corollary 9.8 For any call pricing function C PF, I= [ + ] + O 9.6 as. Proof of heorem9.7 he next lemma will be needed in the proof of heorem 9.7. Lemma 9.9 Let C be a call pricing function, and fix a positive continuous increasing function ψ, satisfying ψ as. Suppose φ is a positive function such that φ as and ψ φ exp { φ }. 9.7

8 50 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility hen the following asymptotic formula holds: I= x 0 e r + φ φ + O ψ φ 9.8 as. Remark 9.0 It is easy to see that if 9.7 holds, then C PF. Proof of Lemma 9.9 Let us compare the implied volatility I with a function Ĩ such that Our goal is to prove that I= Ĩ+ O as, where d, σ is defined in 8.9. It is not hard to see that the function ρ given by satisfies the equalities and 0 < Ĩ < I, > { exp d },Ĩ ρ = x 0 e r 9.0 d,ρ = 0 9. d,ρ = ρ. 9. Plugging 9. and 9. into the Black Scholes formula formula 8., we obtain x 0 C BS,ρ = } e r exp { y dy x π ρ as. Next, taking into account 9.3 and the fact that C BS,I = 0 as, we see that C BS, I < C BS, ρ for all > 0. herefore, I < ρ, > Here we use the fact that for every fixed >0 and >0 the vega is a strictly increasing function of σ.

9 9.3 Asymptotic Behavior of Implied Volatility Near Infinity 5 It is easy to see that for sufficiently large values of, the function increases. It follows from 9. and 9.4 that σ d, σ 9.5 d,i < 0, >. 9.6 Moreover, using the explicit expression for the vega see Sect. 8.4 and the mean value theorem, we get C BS,I CBS,Ĩ = x 0 { I Ĩ exp π d, λ }, >, 9.7 where Ĩ<λ<I. Since the function in 9.5 increases and 9.6 holds, d, I <d, λ < d,i < 0, >. 9.8 Now, using 9.7 and 9.8, we establish the validity of formula 9.0. Let us continue the proof of Lemma 9.9. Suppose Ĩ is a function satisfying the equality d, I = φ, > Such a function exists, since for large values of the function σ d, σ increases from to. It follows from 9.9 and from the definition of d that Ĩ= x 0 e r + φ φ Our next goal is to use formula 9.0 with Ĩ defined in However, we have to first prove inequality 9.9. Using 8., 8.5, and 9.9, we see that there exist constants c > 0 and c > 0 such that C BS,I CBS, I = C BS, I c ψ φ exp = c ψ φ exp { φ { φ { d, Ĩ exp d, Ĩ } { φ } c } c φ exp Since ψ as and 9.3 holds, we get C BS,I >CBS, I }, >. 9.3

10 5 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility for sufficiently large values of. Using the fact that the vega is an increasing function of σ, we obtain inequality 9.9. Now it is clear that 9.8 follows from 9.7, 9.0, and 9.9. he proof of Lemma 9.9 is thus completed. Let us return to the proof of heorem 9.7.Letψ be a positive increasing function such that ψ as. We also assume that the function ψ tends to infinity slower than the function. Put hen we have [ ] φ= + ψ. φ as. It follows that } ψexp { φ φ as. Using formula 9.8, we obtain I= x 0 e r + φ φ + O ψ 9.3 as. Now, it is not hard to see that 9.5 can be derived from 9.3, the mean value theorem, and Lemma 3.. his completes the proof of heorem Corollaries Our objective in this section is to replace the function C in formula 9.5 by another function C. Corollary 9. Let C PF, and suppose C is a positive function such that as. hen I= +

11 9.4 Corollaries 53 as. herefore, I= + O [ + ] + O as. Formula 9.33 can be established exactly as 9.5. Formula 9.34 follows from 9.33 and the mean value theorem. We can also replace a call pricing function C in 9.5 byafunction C under more general conditions. However, this may lead to a weaker error estimate. For instance, put τ= hen the following theorem holds: heorem 9. Let C PF, and suppose C is a positive function satisfying the following condition. here exist > 0 and c with 0 <c< such that τ<c 9.36 for all >, where τ is defined by hen as. I= + [ ] + O + τ 9.37

12 54 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility Proof It is not hard to check that 9.36impliestheformula as. Now using 9.5, 9.35, and the mean value theorem, we obtain he next statement follows from heorem 9. and the mean value theorem. Corollary 9.3 Let C PF, and suppose C is a positive function satisfying the following condition. here exist ν>0and 0 > 0 such that ν 9.38 for all > 0. hen as. I= [ + ] + O Remark 9.4 It is not hard to see that if as,orif9.38 holds, then as. Corollary 9.5 Let C PF, and suppose C is a positive function satisfying the condition 9.39 as. hen as. I Proof It follows from 9.6 that I [ + [ + ] 9.40 ] Λ 9.4

13 9.5 Extra erms: First-Order Asymptotic Formulas for Implied Volatility 55 where + + Λ =. + + We will next prove that Λ as.wehave Λ + Λ + Λ Λ = Λ + + where Λ = and Λ = It is not hard to show that for all positive numbers a and b, a + b a + b. herefore, Λ = Λ + Λ Λ + + Λ Λ + + Λ 9.4 for > 0. It follows from 9.39 and 9.4 that Λ as.next using 9.4 we see that 9.40 holds. his completes the proof of Corollary Extra erms: First-Order Asymptotic Formulas for Implied Volatility Formula 9.5 characterizes the asymptotic behavior of the implied volatility in terms of the call pricing function C, while in formula 9.33, the function C is replaced by a function C, equivalent to C in a certain sense. We call these formulas zero-order asymptotic formulas for the implied volatility. In an important recent paper [GL],. Gao and R. Lee obtained a hierarchy of higher-order asymptotic formulas generalizing formula 9.5. Note that formula 9.33 cannot be generalized in a similar way. In the present section we establish a first-order asymptotic formula, which is different from similar first-order formulas obtained in [GL]. Higher-order asymptotic formulas from [GL] are discussed in Sect Our proofs of abovementioned formulas are refinements of the proof of heorem 9.7 given in Sect. 9.3, and they differ from the proofs given in [GL]. For the sake of simplicity, we assume x 0 = and r = 0.

14 56 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility heorem 9.6 Let C PF, and suppose there exist a number λ>0 and a continuous function Λ satisfying the following conditions: Λ = o and as. hen = λ + O Λ 9.43 I= + λ + λ + π λ + as. λ + λ + π λ O Λ + O Proof Suppose ψ is a positive slowly increasing function such that ψ and as. Put ϕ = Λ + ψ 0 + A Λ + + [ + ψ Here A>0 is a constant that will be chosen later. We have { ϕ } exp = A [ + Aψ Λ + ] ]

15 9.5 Extra erms: First-Order Asymptotic Formulas for Implied Volatility 57 Lemma 9.7 Let Ĩ be the function, for which 9.9 holds with ϕ given by Set λ + λ A = π λ hen Ĩ I. Proof It follows from 8. and 8.5 that { ϕ } exp C BS,Ĩ = π ϕ π + ϕ as.using9.43, 9.45, and the formula we obtain + O ϕ h = + Oh, h 0, as. Moreover, we have ϕ = + O 3 + ϕ = λ λ O Λ + O as. Our next goal is to combine formulas It is not hard to see that there exists 0 > 0 such that C BS,I CBS,Ĩ = C BS,Ĩ > 0 for all > 0. Now Lemma 9.7 follows from the fact that the vega is an increasing function of σ.

16 58 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility Let us return to the proof of heorem 9.6. Since formula 9.7 holds, we have { ϕ } [ I Ĩ= O exp CBS ],Ĩ as. Now using formulas again, we obtain I= Ĩ [ + O ψ Λ + ] as. It follows from 9.30 and 9.45 that Ĩ= + + A + V + A + V, 9.5 where Λ + V= + ψ Λ + = O ψ 9.53 as. Applying the mean value theorem to 9.5 and taking into account 9.47, 9.5, and 9.53, we obtain 9.44 with an extra factor ψ in the error term. Finally, using Lemma 3., we get rid of the extra factor. his completes the proof of heorem 9.6. Formula 9.44 will be used in Sect. 0.5 to study the asymptotic behavior of the implied volatility in the correlated Heston model. 9.6 Extra erms: Higher-Order Asymptotic Formulas for Implied Volatility In this section, we discuss higher-order asymptotic formulas for the implied volatility obtained in [GL]. We restrict ourselves to second- and third-order formulas, since the higher-order cases can be treated similarly. Note that when the order grows, the formulas become more and more complicated. hat is why we decided to use simpler formulas from Sects. 9.3 and 9.4 in the rest of the present book.

17 9.6 Extra erms: Higher-Order Asymptotic Formulas for Implied Volatility 59 Let us begin with a second-order formula see [GL], formula 6. in Corollary 6.. Our presentation of this result of Gao and Lee is different from that in [GL]. he main idea is to replace the constant λ in heorem 9.6 by the function λ = and put Λ = 0. hen formula 9.47 takes the following form: + A = π + his choice of the function A leads to the cancellation of all the terms in the upper estimate for the function C BS, Ĩ, except for the higher-order error terms see the proof of heorem 9.6. o justify the previous statement, we will need the estimate 0 A = π = O aking into account the previous remarks, we see that the following assertion holds. heorem 9.8 Let C PF. hen I= + + A + A + O as, where the function A is defined by Our next goal is to establish a third-order asymptotic formula for the implied volatility see formula 9.68 below. he proof of this formula is similar to that of

18 60 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility formula 9.56, but is more involved. Put ϕ = + + A [ + B + ψ In 9.57, ψ is a positive continuous function such that ψ and ] ψ as. he function B, appearing in 9.57, will be chosen later. his function should satisfy the following condition: as.wehave { ϕ exp B = O } = A [ + B + ψ On the other hand, using 8. and 8.5, we obtain { ϕ } exp C BS,Ĩ = [ π ϕ + ϕ 5 + O as. Set h = + + A [ + B + ψ 9.59 ] ] ϕ ϕ 3 ]. 9.6

19 9.6 Extra erms: Higher-Order Asymptotic Formulas for Implied Volatility 6 Using 9.55, 9.58, and 9.59, we obtain h = O as. herefore, = πϕ + h π = π h + O h = A + π 8 π 3 + O as. Similarly, π + ϕ = π + O + 5 A + 8 π as. Moreover, = πϕ π 5 + O 9.64 and π + ϕ 3 = 4 π + 3 3

20 6 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility 5 + O 9.65 as. Our next goal is to combine formulas Recalling the cancellation properties of the function A, we see that the correct choice of the function B is as follows: B = 8 π A [ ] A Indeed, it is not hard to see that with this choice of B all the terms in the estimate for the difference C BS, Ĩ, containing the factor 3, cancel out. It follows that formula 9.66 can be rewritten in the following form: B = A Here we take into account It remains to prove that the function B satisfies condition It is not hard to see that this condition follows from formulas 9.55 and Analyzing the proof sketched above, we see that the following assertion holds. heorem 9.9 Let C PF. hen I = + + O [ + A + [ + A B ] + B ] 9.68

21 9.7 Symmetries and Asymptotic Behavior of Implied Volatility Near Zero 63 as, where the function A is defined by Formula 9.68 is a third-order asymptotic formula for the implied volatility in a general model of call prices. 9.7 Symmetries and Asymptotic Behavior of Implied Volatility Near Zero In this section, we turn our attention to the asymptotic behavior of the implied volatility as 0. It is interesting to mention that one can derive asymptotic formulas for the implied volatility at small strikes from similar results at large strikes, by taking into account certain symmetries existing in the world of stochastic asset price models. We will next describe those symmetries and explain what follows from them. Let C be a general call pricing function, and let X be the corresponding stock price process. his process is defined on a filtered probability space Ω, F, {F t }, P, where P is a risk-neutral probability measure. We assume that the interest rate r and the initial condition x 0 are fixed, and denote by μ the distribution of the random variable X. Put η = x 0 e r. We call η a symmetry transformation. It is easy to see that the Black Scholes pricing function C BS satisfies the following condition: C BS,,σ= x 0 e r + e r x 0 C BS,η, σ On the other hand, the put call parity formula implies that where G is given by C, = x 0 e r + e r x 0 G,η, 9.70 G, = It follows from 8.4 and 9.7 that η G, = x 0 dμ x x 0 e r 0 x 0 e r P,η. 9.7 η 0 xdμ x. 9.7 Define a family of Borel measures { μ } 0 on 0, as follows. For every Borel subset A of 0, put μ A = x 0 e r xdμ x η A

22 64 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility It is not hard to see that { μ } 0 is a family of probability measures. Moreover, for all >0 and 0, we have and d μ x = x 0 e r η 0 xdμ x 9.74 η xd μ x = x 0 e r dμ x It follows from 9.7, 9.74, and 9.75 that G, = e r xd μ x e r d μ x Remark 9.0 Suppose for every >0the measure μ is absolutely continuous with respect to the Lebesgue measure on 0,. Denote the Radon Nikodym derivative of μ with respect to the Lebesgue measure by D. hen, for every >0the measure μ admits a density D Y given by D x = x 0e r 3 x 3 D 0 x0 e r x, x >0. he next theorem has important consequences. For example, it will allow us to establish a link between the asymptotic behavior of the implied volatility at large and small strikes. heorem 9. Let C be a call pricing function and let P be the corresponding put pricing function. hen the function G defined by 9.7 is a call pricing function with the same interest rate r and the initial condition x 0 as the pricing function C. Moreover, if X is the stock price process associated with G, then for every >0 the measure μ defined by 9.73 is the distribution of the random variable X. Proof According to heorem 8.3, it suffices to prove that conditions 5 in the formulation of this theorem are valid for the function G. We have already shown that for every 0, μ is a probability measure. In addition, equality 8.8 holds for μ,by9.75. Put V,= xd μ x d μ x. hen G, = e r V,. Moreover, the function V, is convex on [0,, since its second distributional derivative coincides with the measure μ. his establishes conditions and in heorem 8.3. he equality G0,= x 0 + can be obtained using 9.7. hus condition 4 holds. Next, we see that 9.76

23 9.8 Symmetric Models 65 implies G, e r xd μ x, and hence lim G, = 0. his establishes condition 5. In order to prove the validity of condition 3 for G, we notice that 9.70 gives the following: G,e r = C,e r x 0 + x x 0 Now it is clear that condition 3 for G follows from the same condition for C. herefore, G is a call pricing function. his completes the proof of heorem 9.. Remark 9. It is not hard to see that if the call pricing function C in heorem 9. satisfies C PF, then G PF 0. Similarly, if C PF 0, then G PF. Let C be a call pricing function such that C PF PF 0. hen G PF PF 0, and hence the implied volatilities I C and I G associated with the pricing functions C and G, respectively, exist for all >0 and >0. Replacing σ by I C in 9.69 and taking into account 9.70 and the equality we see that herefore, the following lemma holds. C BS,,IC, = C,, C BS,η, I C, = G,η. Lemma 9.3 Let C PF PF 0, and let G be defined by hen for all >0 and >0. I C, = I G,η 9.78 Lemma 9.3 shows that the implied volatility associated with C can be obtained from the implied volatility associated with G by applying the symmetry transformation. 9.8 Symmetric Models he notion of a symmetric model is based on the symmetry properties of stochastic models discussed in the previous section.

24 66 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility Definition 9.4 A stochastic asset price model is called symmetric if, for every >0 the distributions μ and μ coincide. Lemma 9.5 he following statements hold:. Suppose for every >0 the measure μ admits a density D. hen the model is symmetric if and only if for all >0, D x = x 0 e r 3 x 3 D x0 e r x 9.79 almost everywhere with respect to the Lebesgue measure on 0,.. Suppose the asset price process X is strictly positive and for every >0the measure μ admits a density D. Define the -price process by X = X and denote by D the distribution density of X, >0. hen the model is symmetric if and only if D x = x 0e r e x D x + x0 e r almost everywhere with respect to the Lebesgue measure on R. 3. he model is symmetric if and only if for all >0 and >0, G, = C,. 4. he model is symmetric if and only if for all >0 and >0, C, = x 0 e r C, x 0 e r + x 0 e r. 5. Let C PF PF 0. hen the model is symmetric if and only if for all >0 and >0, I,= I, x 0 e r. Proof Part 3 of Lemma 9.5 follows from 8.3, 9.76, and from the fact that the measures μ and μ are the second distributional derivatives of the functions C, and G,, respectfully. Part 4 can be easily derived from As for part 5 of Lemma 9.5, it can be established using part 3 and Lemma 9.3. In addition, part follows from Definition 9.4 and Remark 9.0. Finally, the equivalence follows from the standard equalities D x = ex D e x and D y = y D y. his completes the proof of Lemma 9.5. Special examples of symmetric models are uncorrelated stochastic volatility models in a risk-neutral setting. Let us consider a stochastic model defined by { dxt = rx t dt + fy t X t dw t, 9.80 dy t = by t dt + σy t dz t, where W and Z are independent Brownian motions on Ω, F, {F t }, P, and suppose that the measure P is risk-neutral. Suppose also that the solvability conditions

25 9.8 Symmetric Models 67 discussed in Sect.. hold. It is clear that for such a model, formula 9.79 follows from formula 3.6. herefore, part of Lemma 9.5 shows that the model in 9.80 is symmetric. Remark 9.6 he symmetry condition for the implied volatility in part 4 of Lemma 9.5 becomes especially simple if the strike is replaced by the moneyness k defined by k =, >0. x 0 er In terms of the -moneyness, the symmetry condition can be rewritten as follows: Ik= I k for all <k<. For uncorrelated stochastic volatility models, the previous equality was first obtained in [R96]. In [CL09], P. Carr andr. Leeestablishedthatundercertainrestrictions, stochastic volatility models are symmetric if and only if ρ = 0. We will next prove this result of Carr and Lee. We restrict ourselves to models with time-homogeneous volatility equation. However, heorem 9.7 also holds when volatility equations are inhomogeneous see [CL09]. Let us consider the stochastic model given by { dxt = rx t dt + Y t X t dw t, 9.8 dy t = by t dt + σy t dz t. Itisassumedin9.8 that Z = ρ Z + ρw, where Z is a standard Brownian motion independent of W, and the correlation coefficient ρ is such that ρ. It is also assumed that the functions b and σ in 9.8 satisfy the linear growth condition and the Lipschitz condition, the function σ is positive, and for every ρ and every positive initial condition y 0 the solution Y to the second equation in 9.8 is a positive process. heorem 9.7 Suppose the model in 9.8 satisfies the conditions formulated above. In addition, suppose the discounted price process is a martingale. hen the model is symmetric if and only if ρ = 0. Remark 9.8 It is worth mentioning that the conditions in heorem 9.7 are rather restrictive. For example, this theorem is not applicable to the Stein Stein model, or the Heston model. Indeed, in the Stein Stein model the volatility process is not positive, while in the Heston model the function σ does not satisfy the Lipschitz condition. On the other hand, heorem 9.7 can be used to prove that a negatively correlated Hull White model cannot be symmetric. Indeed, in such a model the volatility process is a geometric Brownian motion, and hence it is a positive process. Moreover, the stock price process is a martingale use heorem.33. Note also that if a geometric Brownian motion Y is the solution to the equation dy t = νy t dt + ξy t dz t

26 68 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility with the initial condition y 0 > 0, then the process Ỹ = Y is also a geometric Brownian motion satisfying the equation ν dỹ t = ξ Ỹ t dt + ξ 8 Ỹt dz t with the initial condition y 0. Summarizing what was said above, we see that heorem 9.7 can be applied to the negatively correlated Hull White model. If the Hull White model is positively correlated, then heorem.33 implies that the stock price process is not a martingale. herefore, heorem 9.7 cannot be applied to such a model. It would be interesting to extend heorem 9.7 to a larger class of stochastic volatility models. Proof It has already been established that for ρ = 0, the model is symmetric. We will next prove the converse statement. With no loss of generality, we can assume r = 0. Fix ρ>0, and suppose the symmetry condition holds for the model given by { dxt = Y t X t dw t, dy t = by t dt + ρ σy t d Z t + ρσy t dw t. Using the Itô formula, we can rewrite the model above in terms of the -price process defined by X = X and X 0 = x 0. his gives dx t = Y t dt + Y t dw t, 9.8 dy t = by t dt + ρ σy t d Z t + ρσy t dw t. Let us fix >0. Since the process X is a martingale, the measure P determined from d P = x 0 X dp is a probability measure. Define a new process by Ŵ t = W t t 0 Ys ds, 0 t. It follows from Girsanov s theorem that the process Ŵ t, Z t, t [0,], isatwodimensional standard Brownian motion under the measure P. herefore, the same is true for the process W t, Z t,0 t, where W t = Ŵ t for all t [0,]. It is easy to see that under the measure P, the system in 9.8 can be rewritten as follows: d X t = Y t dt + Y t d W t, 9.83 dy t = ΦY t dt + ρ σy t d Z t + ρσy t d W t where Φu = bu + ρσu u.

27 9.8 Symmetric Models 69 Recall that, by our assumption, the model described by 9.8 issymmetric.using part of Lemma 9.5, we obtain E [ X ] = xd x dx = ue u D x u du + x 0 e u D u du 0 x 0 = E [ X X ] x 0 + E[X ]. x 0 x 0 Next, using the fact that the process X is a martingale, we see that E [ X ] [ = Ẽ X ] + x he next step in the proof is to take the expectation E in the first stochastic differential equation in 9.8, written in the integral form. his gives E [ X ] = Similarly, applying Ẽ to the first equation in 9.83, we obtain Ẽ [ X ] = 0 It follows from 9.84, 9.85, and 9.86 that 0 0 E[Y t ] dt = E[Y t ] dt + x Ẽ[Y t ] dt + x Ẽ[Y t ] dt We will next use a coupling argument. Consider the following processes: X, Y, W, Z under the measure P and X, Y, W, Z under the measure P. Applying the lemma formulated on p. 4 of [IW77], we see that there exist a filtered measure space Ω,F, F t, P and adapted stochastic processes X, Y, X, Y, W, and Z on Ω such that the following conditions hold: he processes X,Y,W, Z and X,Y,W,Z have the same law under the measures P and P, respectively. he processes X,Y, W, Z and X,Y,W,Z have the same law under the measures P and P, respectively. he process W,Z is a two-dimensional F t -Brownian motion under the measure P. It follows 9.8, 9.83, and the previous statements that under the measure P, dx t = Y t dt + Y t dw t, dy t = b Y t dt + ρ σ Y t dz t + ρσ Y t 9.88 dw t

28 70 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility and dx t = Y dy t = Φ Y t t dt + Y t dw t, dt + ρ σ Y t dz t + ρσy t dw t Moreover, 9.87 implies that 0 Ê [ Y t ] dt = 0 Ê [ Y t ] dt Now we are ready to finish the proof. Applying the strong comparison theorem for stochastic differential equations heorem 54 in [Pro04] to 9.88 and 9.89, we see that Y t >Y t for all 0 <t<. 9.9 Here we take into account that bu < Φu and the initial condition x 0,y 0 is the same for the processes X,Y and X,Y. However, 9.9 contradicts It follows that if ρ>0, then the model cannot be symmetric. he case where ρ<0is similar. his completes the proof of heorem Asymptotic Behavior of Implied Volatility for Small Strikes Lemma 9.3 and the results obtained in Sect. 9.3 imply sharp asymptotic formulas for the implied volatility as 0. heorem 9.9 Let C PF 0, and let P be the corresponding put pricing function. Suppose P P as 0, 9.9 where P is a positive function. hen the following asymptotic formula holds: I= P P P + O P P 9.93 as 0.

29 9.9 Asymptotic Behavior of Implied Volatility for Small Strikes 7 Corollary 9.30 he following asymptotic formula holds: [ I= as 0. P ] P + O P P An important special case of heorem 9.9 is as follows: Corollary 9.3 Let C PF 0, and let P be the corresponding put pricing function. hen [ ] I= P P as 0. + O P P Proof of heorem 9.9 Formulas 9.7 and 9.9 imply that G G as where G = P η Next, applying Corollary 9. to G and G, we get I G = + G G G G + O G 9.95 as. It follows from 9.78, 9.94, 9.95, and from the mean value theorem that I= x 0e r + x 0 e r P x 0 e r P

30 7 9 Asymptotic Analysis of Implied Volatility = + O x 0 e r P x 0 e r P P P + O P P P P as 0. his completes the proof of heorem Notes and References he books [FPS00, Reb04, Haf04, Fen05, Gat06, H-L09], the dissertations [Dur04, Rop09], the surveys [Ski0, CL0], and the papers [SP99, SH99, Lee0, CdF0, Lee04a, CGLS09, Fri0] are useful sources of information on the implied volatility. Section 9. is mostly adapted from [Rop0]. However, the conditions in heorem 9.6 are not exactly the same as in the similar result heorem.9 in [Rop0]. Moreover, heorem 9.6 is formulated in terms of the strike price, while the moneyness is used in [Rop0]. he asymptotic formulas for the implied volatility included in Sects. 9.3, 9.4, and 9.9 are taken from [Gul0]. he material in Sects. 9.7 and 9.8 symmetries and symmetric models comes mostly from [Gul0]. We send the interested reader to [CL09, eh09a, DM0, DMM0] for more information on symmetric models. he paper [GL] of. Gao and R. Lee is an important recent work on smile asymptotics. In Sects. 9.5 and 9.6 of this chapter, several theorems from [GL] are presented. hese theorems provide higher-order approximations for the implied volatility at extreme strikes. However, we have not touched upon the results in [GL] characterizing the asymptotic behavior of the implied volatility with respect to the maturity, or in certain combined regimes.

31

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

UNIFORM BOUNDS FOR BLACK SCHOLES IMPLIED VOLATILITY

UNIFORM BOUNDS FOR BLACK SCHOLES IMPLIED VOLATILITY UNIFORM BOUNDS FOR BLACK SCHOLES IMPLIED VOLATILITY MICHAEL R. TEHRANCHI UNIVERSITY OF CAMBRIDGE Abstract. The Black Scholes implied total variance function is defined by V BS (k, c) = v Φ ( k/ v + v/2

More information

Two-sided estimates for stock price distribution densities in jump-diffusion models

Two-sided estimates for stock price distribution densities in jump-diffusion models arxiv:5.97v [q-fin.gn] May Two-sided estimates for stock price distribution densities in jump-diffusion models Archil Gulisashvili Josep Vives Abstract We consider uncorrelated Stein-Stein, Heston, and

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque) Small time asymptotics for fast mean-reverting stochastic volatility models Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque) March 11, 2011 Frontier Probability Days,

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations Stan Stilger June 6, 1 Fouque and Tullie use importance sampling for variance reduction in stochastic volatility simulations.

More information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model he Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model Vladimir Vovk he Game-heoretic Probability and Finance Project Working Paper #39 September 6, 011 Project web site: http://www.probabilityandfinance.com

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ Algorithmic Quantitative Finance July 15, 2017 Christopher Ting July 15, 2017 1/33

More information

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options By Yasin LUT Supevisor:Prof. Tuomo Kauranne December 2010 Introduction Pricing an European call option Conclusion INTRODUCTION A stochastic

More information

Logarithmic derivatives of densities for jump processes

Logarithmic derivatives of densities for jump processes Logarithmic derivatives of densities for jump processes Atsushi AKEUCHI Osaka City University (JAPAN) June 3, 29 City University of Hong Kong Workshop on Stochastic Analysis and Finance (June 29 - July

More information

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 Stochastic Financial Modelling Time allowed: 2 hours Candidates should attempt all questions. Marks for each question

More information

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging Introduction and echniques Lecture 9 in Financial Mathematics UiO-SK451 Autumn 15 eacher:s. Ortiz-Latorre Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging 1 Risk Neutral Pricing Assume that we are in the basic

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

The stochastic calculus

The stochastic calculus Gdansk A schedule of the lecture Stochastic differential equations Ito calculus, Ito process Ornstein - Uhlenbeck (OU) process Heston model Stopping time for OU process Stochastic differential equations

More information

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation 3.1 Itô Integral 3.1.1 Convergence in the Mean and Stieltjes Integral Definition 3.1 (Convergence in the Mean) A sequence {X n } n ln of random

More information

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting Finance Stochast. 1, 251 257 1997 c Springer-Verlag 1997 A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting Tina Hviid Rydberg University of Aarhus, Department of Theoretical

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 18 Feb 2010

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 18 Feb 2010 CONVERGENCE OF HESTON TO SVI JIM GATHERAL AND ANTOINE JACQUIER arxiv:1002.3633v1 [q-fin.pr] 18 Feb 2010 Abstract. In this short note, we prove by an appropriate change of variables that the SVI implied

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem) Change of Measure Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem Radon-Nikodym derivative: Taking again our intuition from the discrete world, we know that, in the context of option pricing, we need to price the claim

More information

SOME APPLICATIONS OF OCCUPATION TIMES OF BROWNIAN MOTION WITH DRIFT IN MATHEMATICAL FINANCE

SOME APPLICATIONS OF OCCUPATION TIMES OF BROWNIAN MOTION WITH DRIFT IN MATHEMATICAL FINANCE c Applied Mathematics & Decision Sciences, 31, 63 73 1999 Reprints Available directly from the Editor. Printed in New Zealand. SOME APPLICAIONS OF OCCUPAION IMES OF BROWNIAN MOION WIH DRIF IN MAHEMAICAL

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS MATHEMATICAL TRIPOS Part III Thursday, 5 June, 214 1:3 pm to 4:3 pm PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS Attempt no more than FOUR questions. There are SIX questions in total. The questions carry

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance Alexander Cox Jiajie Wang University of Bath Bachelier 21, Toronto Financial Setting Option priced on an underlying asset S t Dynamics of S t unspecified,

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU IFS, Chengdu, China, July 30, 2018 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 7/30/2018 1 / 35 Interest Rates and Volatility Practitioners and

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation Peter Cassar May 0, 05 Assumptions of the Black-Scholes Model We have a risk free asset given by the price process, dbt = rbt The asset price follows a geometric

More information

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Local Volatility Dynamic Models René Carmona Bendheim Center for Finance Department of Operations Research & Financial Engineering Princeton University Columbia November 9, 27 Contents Joint work with Sergey Nadtochyi Motivation 1 Understanding

More information

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market Xiaowei Chen Uncertainty Theory Laboratory, Department of Mathematical Sciences Tsinghua University, Beijing 184, China chenxw7@mailstsinghuaeducn

More information

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Fuzzy Optim Decis Making 217 16:221 234 DOI 117/s17-16-9246-8 No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Xiaoyu Ji 1 Hua Ke 2 Published online: 17 May 216 Springer

More information

Interest rate models in continuous time

Interest rate models in continuous time slides for the course Interest rate theory, University of Ljubljana, 2012-13/I, part IV József Gáll University of Debrecen Nov. 2012 Jan. 2013, Ljubljana Continuous time markets General assumptions, notations

More information

A new approach for scenario generation in risk management

A new approach for scenario generation in risk management A new approach for scenario generation in risk management Josef Teichmann TU Wien Vienna, March 2009 Scenario generators Scenarios of risk factors are needed for the daily risk analysis (1D and 10D ahead)

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

Large Deviations and Stochastic Volatility with Jumps: Asymptotic Implied Volatility for Affine Models

Large Deviations and Stochastic Volatility with Jumps: Asymptotic Implied Volatility for Affine Models Large Deviations and Stochastic Volatility with Jumps: TU Berlin with A. Jaquier and A. Mijatović (Imperial College London) SIAM conference on Financial Mathematics, Minneapolis, MN July 10, 2012 Implied

More information

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems M.I.T. 15.450-Fall 2010 Sloan School of Management Professor Leonid Kogan Practice Problems 1. Consider a 3-period model with t = 0, 1, 2, 3. There are a stock and a risk-free asset. The initial stock

More information

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that. 1. EXERCISES RMSC 45 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk Exercises 1 Exercises 1. (a) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-martingale. Show that E(X n ) = E(X ) n N (b) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-submartingale.

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU CBOE Conference on Derivatives and Volatility, Chicago, Nov. 10, 2017 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 11/10/2017 1 / 33 Interest Rates

More information

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited Leonardo P. Santiago & Pirooz Vakili November 2004 Abstract In this paper we consider the question of whether an increase in uncertainty increases

More information

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES THE SOURCE OF A PRICE IS ALWAYS A TRADING STRATEGY SPECIAL CASES WHERE TRADING STRATEGY IS INDEPENDENT OF PROBABILITY MEASURE COMPLETENESS,

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014 MERTON PORTFOLIO PROBLEM WITH ONE INDIVISIBLE ASSET JAKUB TRYBU LA arxiv:143.3223v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 214 Abstract. In this paper we consider a modification of the classical Merton portfolio optimization

More information

Barrier Option Pricing Formulae for Uncertain Currency Model

Barrier Option Pricing Formulae for Uncertain Currency Model Barrier Option Pricing Formulae for Uncertain Currency odel Rong Gao School of Economics anagement, Hebei University of echnology, ianjin 341, China gaor14@tsinghua.org.cn Abstract Option pricing is the

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh The Black-Scholes Model In these notes we will use Itô s Lemma and a replicating argument to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula

More information

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing We shall go over this note quickly due to time constraints. Key concept: Ito s lemma Stock Options: A contract giving

More information

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Dynamic Relative Valuation Dynamic Relative Valuation Liuren Wu, Baruch College Joint work with Peter Carr from Morgan Stanley October 15, 2013 Liuren Wu (Baruch) Dynamic Relative Valuation 10/15/2013 1 / 20 The standard approach

More information

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market Journal of Uncertain Systems Vol.2, No., pp.7-2, 28 Online at: www.jus.org.uk Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market Zhongfeng Qin, Xiang Li Department of Mathematical Sciences Tsinghua University,

More information

Non-semimartingales in finance

Non-semimartingales in finance Non-semimartingales in finance Pricing and Hedging Options with Quadratic Variation Tommi Sottinen University of Vaasa 1st Northern Triangular Seminar 9-11 March 2009, Helsinki University of Technology

More information

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models Alexander Cox 1 Jiajie Wang 2 1 University of Bath 2 Università di Roma La Sapienza Advances in Financial Mathematics, 9th January,

More information

Derivative Securities

Derivative Securities Derivative Securities he Black-Scholes formula and its applications. his Section deduces the Black- Scholes formula for a European call or put, as a consequence of risk-neutral valuation in the continuous

More information

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria   web:   July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M Girsanov s Theorem Bernardo D Auria email: bernardo.dauria@uc3m.es web: www.est.uc3m.es/bdauria July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M Girsanov s Theorem Decomposition of P-Martingales as Q-semi-martingales Theorem

More information

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours This question paper consists of 3 printed pages FinKont KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 211/212) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours This exam paper

More information

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure Yuri Kabanov 1,2 1 Laboratoire de Mathématiques, Université de Franche-Comté, 16 Route de Gray, 253 Besançon,

More information

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson Economics is extremely useful as a form of employment

More information

On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models

On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models Hao Xing Fields Institute/Boston University joint work with Erhan Bayraktar, University of Michigan Kostas Kardaras, Boston University Probability

More information

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Introduction to Financial Derivatives 55.444 Introduction to Financial Derivatives Weeks of November 18 & 5 th, 13 he Black-Scholes-Merton Model for Options plus Applications 11.1 Where we are Last Week: Modeling the Stochastic Process for

More information

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View An Introduction to Point Processes from a Martingale Point of View Tomas Björk KTH, 211 Preliminary, incomplete, and probably with lots of typos 2 Contents I The Mathematics of Counting Processes 5 1 Counting

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

Time-changed Brownian motion and option pricing

Time-changed Brownian motion and option pricing Time-changed Brownian motion and option pricing Peter Hieber Chair of Mathematical Finance, TU Munich 6th AMaMeF Warsaw, June 13th 2013 Partially joint with Marcos Escobar (RU Toronto), Matthias Scherer

More information

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh Option Pricing Mrinal K. Ghosh 1 Introduction We first introduce the basic terminology in option pricing. Option: An option is the right, but not the obligation to buy (or sell) an asset under specified

More information

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility Abstract We try to understand the Berestycki, Busca, and Florent () (BBF) result in the context of the work presented in Lectures and. Implied Volatility from Local Volatility. Current Plan as of March

More information

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps Jhonny Gonzalez School of Mathematics The University of Manchester Magical books project August 23, 2012 Clip for this slide Pricing

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance , Application of Real Analysis in Finance Workshop for Young Mathematicians in Korea Seungkyu Lee Pohang University of Science and Technology August 4th, 2010 Contents 1 BINOMIAL ASSET PRICING MODEL Contents

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

WKB Method for Swaption Smile

WKB Method for Swaption Smile WKB Method for Swaption Smile Andrew Lesniewski BNP Paribas New York February 7 2002 Abstract We study a three-parameter stochastic volatility model originally proposed by P. Hagan for the forward swap

More information

1 The continuous time limit

1 The continuous time limit Derivative Securities, Courant Institute, Fall 2008 http://www.math.nyu.edu/faculty/goodman/teaching/derivsec08/index.html Jonathan Goodman and Keith Lewis Supplementary notes and comments, Section 3 1

More information

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather Review of some financial models for MAT 483 Parity and Other Option Relationships The basic parity relationship for European options with the same strike price and the same time to expiration is: C( KT

More information

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I) Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I) Paul J. Atzberger General comments or corrections should be sent to: paulatz@cims.nyu.edu 1 Introduction When using the Black-Scholes-Merton model to price derivative

More information

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations Anne EYRAUD-LOISEL Workshop : Enlargement of Filtrations and Applications to Finance and Insurance May 31st - June 4th, 2010, Jena

More information

Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions. Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid

Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions. Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid alejandro.balbas@uc3m.es Content Introduction. Describing volatility derivatives. Pricing and

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.7J Fall 213 Lecture 19 11/2/213 Applications of Ito calculus to finance Content. 1. Trading strategies 2. Black-Scholes option pricing formula 1 Security

More information

1 Geometric Brownian motion

1 Geometric Brownian motion Copyright c 05 by Karl Sigman Geometric Brownian motion Note that since BM can take on negative values, using it directly for modeling stock prices is questionable. There are other reasons too why BM is

More information

Path Dependent British Options

Path Dependent British Options Path Dependent British Options Kristoffer J Glover (Joint work with G. Peskir and F. Samee) School of Finance and Economics University of Technology, Sydney 18th August 2009 (PDE & Mathematical Finance

More information

S t d with probability (1 p), where

S t d with probability (1 p), where Stochastic Calculus Week 3 Topics: Towards Black-Scholes Stochastic Processes Brownian Motion Conditional Expectations Continuous-time Martingales Towards Black Scholes Suppose again that S t+δt equals

More information

European call option with inflation-linked strike

European call option with inflation-linked strike Mathematical Statistics Stockholm University European call option with inflation-linked strike Ola Hammarlid Research Report 2010:2 ISSN 1650-0377 Postal address: Mathematical Statistics Dept. of Mathematics

More information

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default T. Bielecki, M. Jeanblanc and M. Rutkowski Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, 6 February 2006 1 Based on N. Vaillant (2001) A

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 1 Jun 2009

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 1 Jun 2009 Asymptotic Formulas with Error Estimates for Call Pricing Functions and the Implied Volatility at Etreme Strikes Archil Gulisashvili arxiv:0906.0394v [q-fin.pr] Jun 009 Abstract In this paper, we obtain

More information

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching Science Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 2016; 4(6): 263-268 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/sjams doi: 10.11648/j.sjams.20160406.13 ISSN: 2376-9491 (Print); ISSN: 2376-9513 (Online)

More information

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

25857 Interest Rate Modelling 25857 UTS Business School University of Technology Sydney Chapter 20. Change of Numeraire May 15, 2014 1/36 Chapter 20. Change of Numeraire 1 The Radon-Nikodym Derivative 2 Option Pricing under Stochastic

More information

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Matematiikan päivät, Tampere, 4-5. January 2006 Tommi Sottinen University of Helsinki 4.1.2006 Outline 1. The classical pricing model:

More information

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Introduction to Financial Derivatives 55.444 Introduction to Financial Derivatives Weeks of November 19 & 6 th, 1 he Black-Scholes-Merton Model for Options plus Applications Where we are Previously: Modeling the Stochastic Process for Derivative

More information

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06 Dr. Maddah ENMG 65 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06 Chapter 11 Models of Asset Dynamics () Random Walk A random process, z, is an additive process defined over times t 0, t 1,, t k, t k+1,, such that z( t )

More information

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES D. S. SILVESTROV, H. JÖNSSON, AND F. STENBERG Abstract. A general price process represented by a two-component

More information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information Exponential utility maximization under partial information Marina Santacroce Politecnico di Torino Joint work with M. Mania AMaMeF 5-1 May, 28 Pitesti, May 1th, 28 Outline Expected utility maximization

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods Finite difference and finite element methods Lecture 4 Outline Black-Scholes equation From expectation to PDE Goal: compute the value of European option with payoff g which is the conditional expectation

More information

Stochastic Volatility

Stochastic Volatility Stochastic Volatility A Gentle Introduction Fredrik Armerin Department of Mathematics Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden Contents 1 Introduction 2 1.1 Volatility................................

More information

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model (joint work with J. Dong and L. Korobenko) A. Deniz Sezer University of Calgary April 28, 2016 Merton s model of corporate debt A corporate bond is a contingent

More information

Hedging under arbitrage

Hedging under arbitrage Hedging under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics AnStAp10 August 12, 2010 Motivation Usually, there are several trading strategies at one s disposal to obtain a given

More information

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components: 1 Mathematics in a Pill The purpose of this chapter is to give a brief outline of the probability theory underlying the mathematics inside the book, and to introduce necessary notation and conventions

More information