Staatswissenschaftliche Fakultät. Faculty of Economics, Law and Social Sciences. Discussion Paper No.: E

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Staatswissenschaftliche Fakultät. Faculty of Economics, Law and Social Sciences. Discussion Paper No.: E"

Transcription

1 Staatswissenschaftliche Fakultät Faculty of Economics, Law and Social Sciences Discussion Paper No.: E Are Non-Binding Contracts Really not Worth the Paper? Bernd Irlenbusch Für den Inhalt des Diskussionspapiers sind die jeweiligen Autoren/innen allein verantwortlich. ISSN (Print) ISSN X (Internet)

2 Are Non-Binding Contracts Really not Worth the Paper? BERND IRLENBUSCH Abstract This paper experimentally investigates behavior in sequential one-shot transactions which are governed by non-binding contracts. In a second, incomplete information treatment, contracts are binding for some players. While according to traditional game-theoretical analysis no trade is expected in the first treatment, full trade should result in the latter. However, we find that trade is even higher in the non-binding contract treatment. On the one hand, non-binding contracts although they are cheap talk do guide behavior, especially at the beginning of a business relationship, while reciprocal reactions prevail later on. On the other hand, in the treatment with binding contracts cooperative behavior appears to be crowded out. Keywords Incomplete Contracts, Cheap Talk, Promises, Trust, Reciprocity, Experiments JEL Classification Codes C72, C91, K12 Acknowledgements Many thanks to three anonymous referees and to Klaus Abbink, Heike Hennig- Schmidt, Rosemarie Nagel, Elke Renner, Bettina Rockenbach, Abdolkarim Sadrieh, Lars Schade, Patrick Schmitz and Reinhard Selten for valuable comments. Suggestions from Ron Harstad helped to give the paper a more concise shape. Financial support from the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft through Sonderforschungsbereich 303 at the University of Bonn and grant KR2077/2-1, the Ministerium für Wissenschaft und Forschung des Landes Nordrhein-Westfalen and the European Union through the EU- TMR Research Network ENDEAR (FMRX-CT ) is gratefully acknowledged. Address University of Erfurt Department of Economics Nordhäuser Strasse 63 D Erfurt, Germany phone +49 (0) fax +49 (0) bernd.irlenbusch@uni-erfurt.de

3 1 Introduction "Non-binding contracts are not worth the paper they are written on!" At first glance this advice appears to be quite plausible. However, in daily life it has often been observed that business partners refer to non-binding agreements rather than to legal sanctions in order to adjust their relationships or to settle disputes. Legal sanctions are often unnecessary and may even have undesirable consequences. This is the case not only because of their costs but rather because reference to legal norms might be interpreted as a betrayal of trust or even a form of unkind action. It is argued that insisting upon a strict legal analysis of the relation or the dispute is likely to close down any further reference to norms of goodwill or cooperation. In a remarkable study MACAULAY (1963), for example, finds overwhelming support for these observations in interviews he conducted with businessmen and lawyers on noncontractual relations in everyday business life. The fact that parties often abstain from using legal sanctions is closely related to the observation that most contracts are vague or silent on a number of key features, i.e., they are incomplete. If the enforcement of contracts by legal means is often considered not to be a valid option, it might be too costly to be precise and complete on every contingency that might occur. TIROLE (1999) emphasizes the importance of the understanding of incomplete contracting for a wide range of economic issues and argues that the topic is left largely unexplored and poorly understood. Important questions are: When and why are incomplete contracts a suitable choice? Are there circumstances under which complete contracts might even be outperformed by incomplete contracts? This paper introduces an experiment which is designed to gain insights into the effectiveness of contracts that are incomplete and which are therefore to a large degree non-binding. One of the most important questions in this study is whether non-binding contracts affect the behavior of the contracting parties. Emphasis is put on efficiency aspects, especially with respect to promise-keeping, as well as trust and the social norm of reciprocity. A key research issue of this paper is the influence of the use of legal institutions on the behavior of contracting parties. Do legal sanctions undermine the effectiveness of social norms which are likely to guide behavior especially in the absence of legal enforcement measures. The influence of non-binding contracts on behavior is contrasted with behavior induced by partially binding contracts. The experiment follows a model introduced by HART and HOLMSTRÖM (1987). In a simple buyer/seller relation units of a fictitious commodity and money are exchanged in a sequential manner, i.e., payments and deliveries are performed in an alternating order. First the seller proposes a contract to the buyer by specifying how much money he desires in return for a fixed number of units. In our first treatment the contract is non-binding for both parties, i.e., the buyer does not have to make the specified payments, nor is the seller forced to deliver the units. Since in reality there is very often uncertainty as to whether the parties can be forced to adhere to the contract, we performed a second, incomplete information treatment in which the contract is binding for some buyers. There are at least two main reasons why a contract is non-binding: (i) parties cannot enforce the obligations that are written in the contract or (ii) business partners do not really want to go to court, for example, because they do not want to break a social norm or damage their reputation. In a game-theoretical sense our non-binding contract is mere cheap talk. The contract is a non-binding, costless, non-verifiable message that may affect the listeners beliefs but not necessarily players payoffs. On 1

4 the one hand, cheap talk can be valuable for signaling players private information 1. On the other hand, cheap talk is found to be effective in signaling players intentions regarding future decisions. In our setting the non-binding contracts may be regarded as promises. Although, in general, promises are not seen as enforceable, FRIED (1981) interprets legal contracts as mutual promises. SCHELLING (1989) argues that promises are often used instead of legal provisions because the agreement cannot be enforced anyhow 2. The experiment we analyze in this paper spans two lines of experimental research on incomplete contracts. The first line consists of experimental studies that have demonstrated that trade is possible even under non-binding agreements. This finding is to a large degree attributed to social preferences exhibited by a considerable number of contractors. Social preferences incline persons not only to care about their own material well-being but also about the material well-being of members of a reference group. The social norm of reciprocity induces social preferences, which are conditioned on the behavior and on the intentions of the reference persons. 3 For example, if a buyer perceives an action of the seller as friendly, he values the seller s payoff positively. Analogously, the seller s payoff is valued negatively by the buyer if the seller s action is regarded to be unfriendly. The importance of the norm of reciprocity for the behavior of economic actors is confirmed in numerous studies. In their seminal experimental work, FEHR, KIRCHSTEIGER, and RIEDL (1993) find that "firms" who pay more than they have to are reciprocally rewarded with voluntarily higher effort contributions by their "workers." BERG, DICKHAUT, and MCCABE (1995) introduce the two-player, two-stage investment game. During the first stage the investor can invest an arbitrary fraction of a given amount. The tripled investment is given to the trustee, who in turn decides whether to send some of this money back to the investor. A view of man as a rational money-maximizer predicts that the trustee has no incentive to return anything. This will be anticipated by the investor, which implies that neither the investor nor the trustee will send anything. But in fact a considerable number of subjects invest a positive amount some even everything. In return most of the trustees reward trust by sending money back. Only few trustees who received a positive amount return nothing. It is hypothesized that this result arises from the expectation among some investors that the trustees will behave reciprocally 4. FEHR, 1 For overviews see FARRELL and RABIN (1996), CRAWFORD (1998), BROSIG, OCKENFELS, and WEIMANN (2003). PALFREY and ROSENTHAL (1991) report on a three-person public goods experiment with simultaneous, non-binding announcements. Subjects had considerable success in efficiently eliciting the contributions required for provision of the public good from the subjects whose privately known costs were lowest. Interestingly enough, more rounds of announcements performed even better. COOPER, DEJONG, FORSYTHE, and ROSS (1989), for example, study the effect of explicit communication in the Battle of the Sexes game. When both subjects make announcements they perform significantly better than they do without communication. 2 SCHELLING (1989) characterizes a promise as follows: (i) what is promised must appear to the second party, the one to whom the promise is made, as being in his interest; (ii) it should be something that one would not ordinarily be expected to do without the promise; (iii) it should be something that the second party perceives to be within the promisor s control; 3 For the influence of the reciprocity norm on behavior and its modeling see RABIN (1993), DUFWENBERG and KIRCHSTEIGER (1999), and FALK and FISCHBACHER (2000). Two important models of other-regarding preferences that deal with inequity aversion are FEHR and SCHMIDT (1999) and BOLTON OCKENFELS (2000). 4 Evidence for the importance of the reciprocity norm is reported in several other studies, for example, GÜTH, OCKENFELS, and WENDEL (1994), JACOBSEN and SADRIEH (1996), GÜTH, KLOSE, KÖNIGSTEIN, and 2

5 GÄCHTER, and KIRCHSTEIGER (1997) test for the reciprocity norm in a market setting with more sellers than buyers. They find that the sellers deliver higher quality if buyers offer them higher payments beforehand. In contrast to these observations DUFWENBERG and GNEEZY (2000) do not find a correlation between the amount given to the trustee and the amount returned to the trustor. Instead, their study shows that the amount which is sent back by the trustee correlates with his belief about the trustor s expectations of what will be returned. FEHR and SCHMIDT (2000) and FEHR, KLEIN, and SCHMIDT (2002) find that fairness considerations have a significant impact on the optimal provision of incentives in a moral hazard context. Incentive contracts that are optimal in the presence of merely selfish actors become inferior to incomplete contracts when some agents are concerned about fairness. The second body of literature relevant to our study originates from the field of social psychology (e.g., DECI 1975, DECI and RYAN 1985) and argues that explicit incentives, for example, monetary incentives or threats of punishment, might have substantial countervailing effects on motivation. The importance of the hidden costs of incentives has recently also been investigated by an increasing number of economists (FREY 1997, GNEEZY and RUSTICHINI 2000, FEHR and GÄCHTER 2002, BOHNET, FREY, and HUCK (2001), FEHR and ROCKENBACH 2003, IRLENBUSCH and SLIWKA 2003). FREY (1993) and SLIWKA (2002) offer models that predict the crowding out of voluntary cooperative behavior by incentive contracts. The paper proceeds as follows. The next section describes the model which serves as the basis for the experiment. Section three deals with some game-theoretical aspects of the model presented. The experimental design is reported in section four; section five outlines the experimental results and section six concludes the paper. 2 A Simple Model of Non-Binding Contracts The model used in the experiment described below is introduced in HART and HOLMSTRÖM (1987). Consider a buyer B and a seller S who wish to trade two units of an item which has the value v for the buyer. Also delivery causes costs c for the seller. If the item is not delivered it causes no costs and is of no value either. Assume that v > c > 0, i.e., it is profitable to trade the item. Both the buyer and the seller know the value v and the costs c. One single buyer is matched with one single seller. We assume that the trade is performed in a sequence, i.e., delivery and payment are made sequentially over five stages 5. The buyer has to make a first payment, then the seller has to decide whether she wants to deliver the first unit of the item. Thereafter, again, it is the turn of the buyer to make a second payment, followed by a second delivery decision by the seller and a third payment by the buyer, i.e., the number of payments exceeds the number of deliveries by one. The i th payment from the buyer to the seller is denoted by r i, r i 0, i = 1, 2, 3. The j th delivery from the seller to the buyer is denoted by d j, d j {0,1}, j = 1, 2. If the seller delivers the j th unit we have d j = 1 otherwise d j = 0. The sequence of trade can be depicted as follows: SCHWALBACH (1998), ABBINK, IRLENBUSCH, and RENNER (2000), CLARK and SEFTON (2001), VAN DER HEIJDEN, NELISSEN, POTTERS, and VERBON (2001), GÄCHTER and FALK (2002), CHARNESS forthcoming. 5 Similar sequential experimental games are also analyzed, for example, in SELTEN and STOECKER (1986), CAMERER and WEIGELT (1988), OCHS and ROTH (1989), MCKELVEY and PALFREY (1992), and NERAL and OCHS (1992). 3

6 Trading phase: B S B S B p 1 d 1 p 2 d 2 p 3 Before trading the seller offers the buyer a contract. The contract specifies the payments which have to be made in order for units to be delivered. Hence, the contract consists of individual payments. We denote the proposed payments as p i, p i 0, i = 1, 2, 3 and restrict the values for the i th payment r i as well as for the i th proposed payment p i to non-negative integers out of an interval of [0,..., M]. We are assuming a world of voluntary contracts, i.e., nobody is forced to trade. Therefore, we model the proposed contract as a take-it-or-leave-it-offer 6, i.e., the buyer is asked whether he accepts the contract or not. We denote this decision by a. If the contract is accepted (a = 1) the trade is performed successively, otherwise (a = 0) no trade occurs. If there is no trade, both the seller and the buyer receive a payoff of zero. The contract is binding for some players but not binding for others. A seller is never bound to a contract. At each delivery stage she can freely decide whether or not to deliver. We are assuming there are two types of buyers. Whereas a restricted buyer has to abide by a contract, an unrestricted buyer does not have to do so 7. An unrestricted buyer can simply refuse to pay or can deviate from the payment agreed upon in the contract. Abiding by a contract means that a buyer makes a payment at least as large as the payment specified in the contract, i.e., p i r i, i = 1, 2, 3. However, even a restricted buyer does not have to adhere to a contract if his trading partner has already previously broken the contract. We are using a model of incomplete information, i.e., a buyer knows his own type, but the corresponding seller does not. However, it is common knowledge that the fraction of restricted buyers in the population is θ (0 = θ = 1). 3 Game-Theoretical Analysis This section deals with some game-theoretical considerations of the described model 8. We assume that agents are rational and aim to maximize their expected payoff. 3.1 Unrestricted Buyers For the moment let us concentrate on the case θ = 0, i.e., it is common knowledge that all players are unrestricted. By a simple backward induction argument one can see 6 We aimed to simplify the bargaining process. For a more detailed discussion of take-it-or-leave-it-offers in bargaining contexts, see the ultimatum game literature, for example, GÜTH, SCHMITTBERGER, and SCHWARZE (1982), CAMERER and THALER (1995). 7 We distinguish between restricted and unrestricted buyers to capture the inherent uncertainty of incomplete contracts whether they are exogenously enforceable or not. HART and HOLMSTRÖM (1987) call the two types of buyers to be honest or dishonest. Recent studies on social preferences provide a justification for this naming. They find that there is considerable heterogeneity among humans with respect to selfish behavior, for an overview see FEHR and FISCHBACHER (2002). Note that traders who are non-selfish might additionally be restricted, for example by guilt or reputation. 8 HART and HOLMSTRÖM (1987) provide a brief equilibrium analysis. For details see IRLENBUSCH (1999). 4

7 that for every accepted contract there is a unique way of behaving in a subgame perfect equilibrium. The buyer does not pay anything at the final stage. This is anticipated by the seller and she does not deliver the final unit. Again, this is anticipated by the buyer and he will not make the last but one payment. This argument can be extended back to the beginning of the game. Hence, in a subgame perfect equilibrium no trade occurs. This is true independently of the proposed contract. Regardless of whether the seller delivers or not, in a subgame perfect equilibrium the buyer does not pay anything. Regardless of whether the buyer pays anything or not in a subgame perfect equilibrium, the seller does not deliver. Note, however, that given this behavior, the buyer is indifferent between accepting and rejecting the contract. To sum up, if it is common knowledge that the buyer is unrestricted in a subgame perfect equilibrium the buyer does not pay anything nor does the seller deliver any unit. Note that this is true irrespective of the values for v and c. 3.2 Restricted and Unrestricted Buyers Let us now consider the case 0 < θ < 1, which means that the buyer is restricted with a strictly positive probability. Figure 1 sketches the corresponding game tree, with truncated branches 9. The root of the game tree symbolizes the chance move with a known probability of θ which determines whether the buyer is restricted or not. The branches shown in Figure 1 essentially represent sequences of actions in the event that the seller S cannot distinguish between a restricted and an unrestricted buyer B. The fact that the seller does not know whether her trading partner is restricted or unrestricted is indicated by the three information sets with two decision nodes which belong to the seller 10. The first of these information sets represents the contract proposal. The following two denote the delivery decisions. The truncated branches have to be labeled with payoff-pairs, which result if the agents play the subgame perfect equilibrium strategies in the subsequent subgames. For example, if the buyer pays less than agreed on in the contract he reveals himself to be unrestricted and thus by a backward induction argument one can see that in the following subgames no deliveries and payments will be performed. If the seller does not deliver even a restricted buyer is not bound to the contract anymore and, thus, it is dominant not to trade afterwards. In the following we give an idea of the analysis of the setting used in the experiment. Since we now have a game of imperfect information we are focussing on the concept of sequential equilibrium (KREPS and WILSON 1982) when referring to an equilibrium. For simplicity we will concentrate on those equilibria in which on the equilibrium path the restricted buyer does not pay more than the amount prescribed in the contract. 11 DEFINITION: Let β be a sequential equilibrium in pure behavioral strategies and let p be the contract which is proposed on the equilibrium path of β. We call β a proposal- 9 At first glance the game tree looks rather complicated. However, as described below, in the experiment the game is not introduced to the subjects by showing them the game tree, but by explaining the sequence of actions. 10 In fact, these information sets are the only ones in which the seller cannot distinguish between a restricted and an unrestricted buyer if we concentrate on those strategies where buyers do not pay more than is prescribed by the contract (see below for the definition of a proposal-confirming equilibrium). 11 The omitted equilibria essentially result in equal efficiency and payoffs for both players. 5

8 confirming equilibrium if on the equilibrium path the restricted buyer does not pay more than what is proposed in p. B is restricted θ B is unrestricted (1 -θ) reject B (a = 0) B S (p 1, p 2, p 3 ) (p 1, p 2, p 3 ) B accept (a = 1) accept (a = 1) B r 1 = p r 1 1 = p 1 reject (a = 0) r 1 = 0 d 1 = 0 B d 1 = 1 r 2 = p 2 S d 1 = 1 r 2 = p 2 d 1 = 0 B r 2 = 0 d 2 = 0 B d 2 = 1 S d 2 = 1 d 2 = 0 B r 3 = 0 r 3 = p 3 r 3 = p 3 Seller s payoff: Π S = a (r 1 + r 2 + r 3 (d 1 + d 2 )c) Buyer s payoff: Π B = a ((d 1 + d 2 )v r 1 r 2 r 3 ) FIGURE 1 GAME TREE FOR n=3 WITH TRUNCATED BRANCHES AFTER NO PAYMENT AND NO DELIVERY. Let us first assume that there exist contracts which in a proposal-confirming equilibrium result in a strictly positive payoff for the seller. In fact - as we will see below - this is the case for the parameter values chosen in the experiment. It is immediately evident that if a contract is acceptable for a restricted buyer, then an unrestricted buyer will also accept the contract, since in any case he is able to imitate the restricted buyer by choosing the same actions. Thus, it is not possible for the seller to initially discriminate between a restricted and an unrestricted buyer by making different contract proposals. After the buyer has accepted the contract either both players follow their agreement or one of the players is the first to break the contract. An initial contract violation can only occur either if the seller does not deliver or an unrestricted buyer makes a payment which is lower than the payment agreed upon in the contract. Note, however, that after a contract is broken even a previously restricted buyer is no longer bound to the contract. This means that after an initial contract violation, it is common knowledge that both players are unrestricted afterwards. Knowing this, a simple backward induction argument reveals that in equilibrium trade becomes impossible after a contract violation (the argument is analogous to the one in section 3.1). Thus, in equilibrium, trade (i.e., deliveries and payments according to the contract) is only possible in an uninterrupted sequence from the outset. Once trade has been broken off, there is no way to take it up again. 6

9 Furthermore, if an unrestricted buyer breaks a contract, paying nothing dominates making a positive payment. From the rules of the game it follows that only the seller and an unrestricted buyer can break a contract first. Thus, in equilibrium an accepted contract may induce the seller or the unrestricted buyer to stop trading at different points in time. These two points in time essentially characterize the exchange phase which follows an accepted contract. If the contract induces the seller not to deliver the first unit, no buyer would be willing to make a positive first payment because trade would stop thereafter. Thus, the contract proposed in equilibrium should induce the seller either to deliver both units or to deliver the first but not the second unit. If it is profitable for a restricted buyer to make the first payment, it is also profitable for an unrestricted buyer. However, for an unrestricted buyer it is always dominant not to make the last payment. Thus, it is not immediately clear whether the contract proposed in equilibrium induces the unrestricted buyer to make the second payment or not. This leaves us with three possible types of contract which each induce different behavior in the trading phase. In the case of the first type of contract in equilibrium all players abide by the contract except that the unrestricted buyer does not make the last payment. In the case of the second type of contract, in equilibrium the contract is completely fulfilled if the buyer is restricted. But if the buyer is unrestricted, he has an incentive to break the contract after the first delivery. The third type of contract gives the seller incentives to deliver only the first unit and, thus, the second payment is only made by a restricted buyer. These three combinations of behavior are the only ones which in equilibrium may follow a contract that is accepted and that guarantees a strictly positive payoff for the seller. In our second experimental treatment we use the following parameters: c = 5, v = 20, and θ =.5. Given this parameter constellation one can show that every contract of the first type results in a higher seller payoff than a contract of the second or third type. Thus, in a proposal-confirming equilibrium only contracts of the first type are proposed 12. To summarize, these equilibrium contracts provide the seller with incentives to deliver both units. Therefore, a restricted buyers is forced to pay exactly what is written in the contract. This is true for all three installments. An unrestricted buyer imitates a restricted buyer in the beginning of trade, i.e. he pays the first two installments as they are agreed upon in the contract. However, in equilibrium an unrestricted buyer does not pay anything after he has received the second unit. To simplify experimentation we restrict the payments which are proposed in the contract as well as those amounts which are actually paid to integers. From the constraints described in the Appendix one can derive all contracts which might be proposed in a proposal-confirming equilibrium. These are shown in Table 1. In every contract almost the total surplus from trading is transferred to the seller, i.e., the sum of the three payments essentially corresponds to the buyer s value of the two units. This result is due to the take-it-or-leave-it structure of the present bargaining situation. In equilibrium buyers of both types pay the first two installments as they are specified in the contract. Interestingly, within a certain range the amount of payment can be shifted between the first two installments. In an equilibrium contract a third payment is proposed which is high enough to provide the seller in expectation with an 12 The proof is given in the Appendix. 7

10 incentive to deliver the second item, i.e., the expected third payment has to cover the cost of delivery 13. Note that an unrestricted buyer does not pay the last installment. Therefore, the third payment should be as small as possible, given the abovementioned constraint. The variation in the sellers expected payoffs from various equilibrium contracts results from different actions on the equilibrium path in case of indifference. TABLE 1 PROPOSAL-CONFIRMING EQUILIBRIUM CONTRACTS FOR θ =.5 Expected seller s payoff = p 1 {8,..., 23} p 1 {7,..., 23} p 1 {9,..., 24} p 1 {8,..., 24} p 1 {9,..., 24} p 1 {10,...,25} p 2 = 28 - p 1 p 3 = 11 p 2 = 27 - p 1 p 3 = 13 p 2 = 29 - p 1 p 3 = 10 p 2 = 28 - p 1 p 3 = 12 p 2 = 29 - p 1 p 3 = 11 p 2 = 30 - p 1 p 3 = 10 The following section describes the experimental setup. 4 Experimental Design and Experimental Procedure Two different treatments were conducted. In the first treatment U the contract is completely non-binding (θ = 0), i.e., all participants are unrestricted. As we have seen in the third section, in equilibrium there is no trade at all, if the subjects are rational and merely money maximizing. In the second treatment RU a fraction of buyers is bound to the contract. As a first step towards our investigation into legal binds, we chose to implement a setting in which half of the buyers are restricted, i.e., θ =.5. From a traditional game-theoretical point of view this modification dramatically changes the usefulness of contracts, since both units are delivered in a proposalconfirming equilibrium as shown above. The set of business relations with restricted buyers in treatment RU is indicated by the symbol RU R. Analogously, the set of business relations with unrestricted buyers in treatment RU is denoted by RU U. The experiment was conducted at the Laboratorium für experimentelle Wirtschaftsforschung at the University of Bonn. The subjects were recruited by advertising the experiment on posters. Most of them were students from various disciplines, although the majority were law and economics students. In total 120 students participated in the experiment 60 students per treatment. It is important to note that one person was allowed to participate only once, i.e., in only one business relationship 14. The treatments were performed as a Mensa Experiment, i.e., due to the short decisionmaking period in the one-shot setting the lab was taken to a convenient location for the participants: Two teams of laboratory staff members were placed in separate university buildings - one in the canteen (called Mensa) and one in a lecture building. The distance between the buildings and the large number of people milling around 13 This characteristic of the equilibrium contracts is in line with the notion of relational contracts which is used to describe (informal) agreements sustained by the value of future transactions within the same relationship (MACAULAY 1963, MACNEIL 1978, 1980, GRANOVETTER 1985, BERNSTEIN 1992, GREIF 1993, BAKER, GIBBONS, MURPHY 2002). These contracts are sometimes also called self-enforcing or implicit contracts (TELSER 1981, BULL 1987, MACLEOD and MALCOMSON 1989). 14 The influence of non-binding contracts on behavior in a repeated setting is investigated in IRLENBUSCH, forthcoming. 8

11 increased anonymity. The two teams communicated via telephone. 15 Instruction sheets were handed out to those who registered to participate. 16 The instructions framed the decision situation as a trading situation in which the seller could propose a contract to the buyer. The buyer could reject or accept the contract and could make payments. The seller could make deliveries. Participants were given enough time to read the instructions carefully. The experimenters answered any remaining questions. A business relation was established by matching two participants from different buildings - one participant in the canteen and one in the lecture building. The matching was done randomly and anonymously and was fixed for the whole business relationship. Participants took a seat in a cubicle. First of all each participant had to throw a die. The numbers thrown by two matched participants determined their roles. Both subjects were equally likely to become the seller or the buyer. After the roles were determined in treatment RU, the buyer had to throw the die again in order to define his type. If the die showed an even number the buyer was restricted, otherwise he was unrestricted. Note that the type of buyer was not revealed to the seller. In treatment U it was not necessary to determine the buyer s type because it was common knowledge that all buyers were unrestricted. Sellers as well as buyers received an initial endowment of 20 units of the fictitious currency unit, called "talers." The endowment was common knowledge. After the roles and the buyer s type were determined, the seller had to offer a contract by simultaneously specifying p 1, p 2, and p 3 on a decision sheet. The contract offered (as well as all following decisions) was transmitted via telephone by one of our team members to the other site. On the other site the experimenter who was in charge of the telephone filled in a copy of the decision sheet. Afterwards, he passed it over to another experimenter, who gave it to the matched participant. The buyer had to decide whether he accepted the contract or not. If the buyer rejected the contract, the business relation was over. Both participants buyer and seller were paid their endowment. If the buyer accepted the contract he immediately had to make his first payment r 1. Now it was the seller s turn to decide whether she wanted to deliver the first unit. If the unit was delivered, the seller's capital balance was reduced by c = 5 talers and the buyer's capital balance increased by v = 20 talers. In the following the decisions concerning r 2, d 2, and r 3 took place analogously. Note that in treatment RU it was the duty of our teams to check that restricted buyers did not break a contract first. In the end buyer and seller were paid their final capital balances. All talers were changed into DM at an exchange rate of 1 DM ( 0.51 ) for 5 talers. On average a business relation lasted for approximately 15 minutes. In both treatments we had 30 business relationships each, i.e., we collected 30 statistically independent observations in each treatment. In the next section we provide the results obtained from the experiment. 15 Participants were informed that there was another site on the campus at which the trading partners were recruited, i.e., in principle participants from the Mensa could go to the other site in the lecture building to verify that there indeed was another recruitment site and vice versa. Although participants could not listen to the telephone calls, they could see the experimenter who was handling their decision sheet and the telephone on their site. 16 Instruction sheets and the decision sheet can be found in the Appendix. 9

12 5 Experimental Results A first impression of the experimental results can be obtained from a brief look at the data collected in both treatments, which is provided in the Appendix 17. We start our analysis with a short discussion of rejections and payments. Afterwards, we pose one of the central questions of the present study, namely whether the efficiencies obtained in the two treatments reflects the results from the traditional game-theoretical prediction. We investigate the influence of non-binding contracts and outline the observed evidence for reciprocal behavior. In order to look for potential crowding out effects induced by binding contracts we conclude our analysis by investigating behavioral differences between both treatments. All of our statistical tests preserve the independence of observations. If one compares the installments proposed in the contracts to the installments that are actually paid, one obtains the following intuitive result: One can reject the null hypothesis that the sum of the installments proposed in the contract is as high as the sum of the actual payments in favor of the alternative hypothesis that actual payments are lower (Wilcoxon signed-rank test, one-tailed, p = for both treatments). Whereas in treatment U two contract proposals are rejected we find seven rejections in treatment RU five by restricted buyers and two by unrestricted ones. From a traditional game-theoretical point of view it is difficult to justify the four contract rejections by unrestricted buyers because a rejection is weakly dominated. A reason for rejection could be that the contract proposal is somehow interpreted by the buyer as a signal that the seller is not trustworthy. If one compares those contracts in both treatments which are accepted by an unrestricted buyer with the four rejected ones, one recognizes that the third installment is significantly lower in the rejected contract proposals (p = 0.016, Mann-Whitney U test, one-tailed). Thus, in those contracts the seller gives herself very low incentives to deliver the second unit because the contract promises her only a small third installment. The buyer may interpret this to mean that the seller does not really want to deliver the second unit and therefore it may be taken as a reason for distrust and rejection. Similarly, if one compares the four contracts which are rejected by a restricted buyer with those that are accepted, we see that the sums of all three payments are significantly higher in the rejected ones (p = 0.001, Mann-Whitney U test, one-tailed). Delivery of one unit creates a surplus of (v c) = 15 talers. The surplus can be divided between seller and buyer by payments, for example, if both units are delivered, a total payment of 25 talers would equally divide the surplus. In fact this division is proposed by five contracts in treatment U and by three contracts in treatment RU. However, most of the contracts proposed by the seller promise a lower payoff to the buyer. In fact one can reject the hypothesis that the seller s and buyer s payoffs resulting from contracts are equal in favor of the alternative hypothesis that 17 In the following we exclude pair 21 of treatment U and pair 16 of treatment RU from the analysis of the contracts. The proposed contract (50, 80, 120) in treatment U is the only one which cannot be fulfilled. It is not clear why the seller proposes a contract with such high installments. Maybe by this she wants to express her right to claim a high profit. Another explanation would be that she does not care what she proposes since the contract is non-binding anyway. The proposed contract (25, 5, 5) in treatment RU is not feasible because the initial endowment of the (restricted) buyer is too low to make the first payment. Thus, the contract has to be rejected. Figure A.1 and Figure A.2 in the Appendix show the decisions taken by the participants in treatment U and treatment RU respectively. For an additional investigation of treatment U see IRLENBUSCH and SCHADE (1999). 10

13 seller s payoffs are higher (p = for both treatments, Wilcoxon signed-rank test, one-tailed). Note that there are no apparent differences between treatments in payoffs intended by the contracts Buyer s payoff [taler] d 1 + d 2 = 2 d 1 + d 2 = 1 d 1 + d 2 = 0 [taler] Treatment U Treatment RU restricted buyers Treatment RU unrestricted buyers Seller s payoff FIGURE 2 SELLER/BUYER ACTUAL PAYOFFS Figure 2 shows the payoffs achieved in those business relations in which the contract is accepted 18. The three lines represent the different possible efficiency levels, i.e., no unit, one unit, or two units are delivered. The dashed line is the equal payoff line. Interestingly, in treatment RU the payoff of unrestricted buyers is positive only in two business relationships, while in treatment U buyers normally earn positive amounts. Observation 1: In both treatments sellers tend to earn more than buyers. (p = for both treatments, Wilcoxon signed-rank test, one-tailed). The most frequent observations in treatment U are four combinations of 15/15 taler payoffs for buyers and sellers. In treatment RU there is no equal payoff division. Interestingly, the payoff differences (seller s payoff buyer s payoff) in those business relations in which both units are delivered are lower than those of the others in the same treatment (p = for treatment U, p = for treatment RU, Mann-Whitney U test, one-tailed). 5.1 Do Non-Binding Contracts Prevent Trade? In the third section we saw that from a traditional game-theoretical point of view trade is impossible in treatment U because the contract is mere cheap talk. The situation is different in treatment RU. Here in a proposal-confirming equilibrium an unrestricted buyer hides his type by behaving exactly like a restricted buyer - at least except for the last payment. Thus, whereas in the first treatment in equilibrium no delivery is obtainable, delivery of both units should be observed in the second treatment. Since surplus is created only by deliveries, we define efficiency as the fraction of actually delivered units in relation to potentially delivered ones, which means that in a single 18 A more detailed payoff comparison between treatments can be found in the Appendix (Table A.4). 11

14 business relation efficiencies of.0,.5, and 1 can be achieved depending on how many units are delivered: zero, one, or two. As one can see from Table 2 on average the efficiency obtained in treatment U is even higher than in treatment RU. In fact one can weakly reject the null hypothesis that efficiencies obtained in treatment U and treatment RU are equal in favor of the alternative hypothesis that efficiencies in treatment U are higher (p = 0.091, Mann-Whitney U test, one-tailed): Observation 2: Efficiency tends to be higher in treatment U than in treatment RU. The difference in efficiency between the treatments is even more pronounced if one concentrates on those business relations of treatment RU in which buyers are unrestricted, i.e., if one compares the 30 business relations of U with the 14 business relations of RU U. One can clearly reject the null hypothesis that efficiencies are equal in the setting U and the setting RU U in favor of the alternative hypothesis that efficiencies in treatment U are higher (p = 0.012, Mann-Whitney U test, one-tailed). TABLE 2 EFFICIENCIES OBSERVED IN THE TWO TREATMENTS Efficiency Average (a, d 1, d 2 ) = (0, -, -) (1, 0, 0) (1, 1, 0) (1, 0, 1) (1, 1, 1) # in U # in RU # in RU U RU U denotes those business relations of treatment RU in which the buyer is unrestricted. The acceptance decision is denoted by a = 1 and a rejection is denoted by a = 0. If the ith unit is delivered, this is denoted by d i = 1 and if delivery of the ith unit is refused, this is denoted by d i = 0 (i = 1, 2). Since the experimental findings described in this section cast serious doubts on the predictive power of the theoretical analysis given above, in the following we provide a deeper analysis of the observed behavior. 5.2 Do Non-Binding Contracts Influence Actual Behavior? In treatment U relatively high efficiency is achieved. Although from a game-theoretical point of view the non-binding contracts are cheap talk, this section analyses whether, nevertheless, the contracts have some influence on actual behavior. If this is the case, the availability of non-binding contracts might be one explanation for the unexpected high number of deliveries. This section and section 5.3 therefore concentrate on treatment U. A first hint that non-binding contracts do systematically influence behavior is evident from the comparison of total payments proposed in the contract and those amounts actually paid: Observation 3: In treatment U total proposed and actual payments are correlated. (p = 0.035, Spearman's rank correlation, one-tailed). Interestingly, an analogous correlation cannot be found in the other treatment, neither for RU nor for RU U 19. Especially the fact that we do not observe a correlation between proposed and actual payments in the business relations of treatment RU, in which the buyer is unrestricted, 19 The relations between proposed payments and actual payments in all three settings are illustrated in the Appendix (Figure A.3). 12

15 supports the conjecture that the existence of binding contracts may reduce cooperation. Trading behavior in treatment U seems to be more tightly connected to the contracts than in treatment RU, when both contractors are unrestricted like in treatment U. The possibility to be bound to the contract seem to induce unrestricted buyers in treatment RU to ignore the contract to a greater extent than this is the case with unrestricted buyers in treatment U. This suggests that the mere existence of contract enforcement measures might lead to some crowding out of the motivation to voluntarily follow a contract. Let us have a look at the first installments (see Figure A.2). In 14 out of 27, i.e., in over 50% of the business relations in which the contract is accepted, the first payment is performed as proposed, i.e., p 1 = r 1. Additionally, on the basis of all 27 business relations, p 1 and r 1 are highly positively correlated (p = 0.000, Spearman's rank correlation, one-tailed). It is interesting that analogous claims do not hold for the other two installments. Apparently, the buyers tie their decisions concerning later payments more loosely to the contract than it is the case with the first payment. In almost three quarters of all business relations with accepted contracts, namely 20 out of 27, the first unit is delivered as agreed in the contract. Thus, at least at the beginning of the business relation the seller adheres to the contract. Delivery of the second unit is made less frequently. But even at the second delivery stage there are indications that the contract has some influence on the chosen action: the second unit is delivered in those business relations in which the proposal for the third installment in the contract p 3 is higher (p = 0.002, Mann-Whitney U test, one-tailed). It is possible that a seller prefers to deliver the second unit if the contract promises her a higher third payment. Interestingly, the sums of the three proposed installments are lower in those business relations in which no unit is delivered (p = 0.043, Mann-Whitney U test, one-tailed). We use the term "overpayment" if a buyer pays more than what is agreed upon in the contract, i.e., p i < r i. Overpayments do not occur at the first and third installments but there are four overpayments (up to five talers) in the second installment. In three of these cases overpayment is successful in the sense that the second unit is delivered in one case even though the first delivery is refused. This observation might be a first hint of reciprocal behavior. Maybe the overpayments are made precisely because the buyers trust the sellers will perform a similarly friendly act afterwards. An alternative explanation is the let-down-aversion observed by DUFWENBERG and GNEEZY (2000). It could be that a seller delivers the second unit because she does not want to disappoint a buyer who overpaid 20. Further indications of a strong influence of reciprocity are given below. If p i > r i this is termed an "underpayment." If one assumes that the contract has an influence on actual behavior, one might conjecture that underpayments affect subsequent decisions concerning delivery. This is exactly the case for the second delivery. In business relations in which the second unit is delivered we observe a lower previous underpayment (p 2 r 2 ) (p = 0.037, Mann- Whitney U test, one-tailed). It is interesting that a comparable effect of underpayment for the first installment is not significant. 20 I am grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing out this explanation. 13

16 5.3 The Impact of Trust and Reciprocal Behavior in Treatment U In our view it is quite astonishing how unambiguously the traditional game-theoretical prediction under the standard assumptions of rationality and self-interest is rejected at the beginning of a business relation: 100% of the buyers pay strictly positive amounts as first installments. This is a clear indication that buyers trust they will receive a unit from the sellers if they have previously paid a certain amount. On the one hand, trust is possibly based on the promise made in the contract. On the other hand, buyers seem to trust that sellers will follow the norm of reciprocity, i.e., if a buyer voluntarily pays a considerable amount the seller should feel obliged to deliver. In almost three quarters of all business relations with accepted contracts the first unit is delivered. But, surprisingly, no apparent significant influence of the amount of the first installments on the delivery decisions can be detected. The same is true for the size of the underpayments. Thus, we have to assume that the delivery decisions of the first unit are not primarily regarded as reciprocal reactions following the first installments. Instead, the sellers might be led by their promises in the contract. Trust in future reciprocal behavior of the buyers may be an additional driving force. If the first unit has been previously delivered, buyers pay a positive figure significantly more often in the second installment, i.e., r 2 > 0, (p = 0.036, Fisher exact test, onetailed). We interpret this observation as a reciprocal reaction of the buyer to the experienced behavior of the seller. The buyers seem to be more willing to pay a positive amount if the sellers adhere to the contract. The second installments r 2 are higher in those business relations in which the second units are delivered (p = 0.002, Mann-Whitney U test, one-tailed). Again this must be seen as evidence for reciprocal behavior this time by the sellers. It seems to be easier for a seller to deliver the second unit if she has been treated generously by the buyer beforehand. Additionally, there is another indication of reciprocal behavior of the buyer at the third installment. In five business relations a positive third installment is made, i.e., r 3 > 0. In four of these cases both units are previously delivered. According to the Fisher exact test this means that the third installment is significantly more often positive if both units are delivered (p = 0.024, one-tailed). A buyer who receives both units seems to feel more obliged to pay something positive at the end than a buyer who receives fewer units. To sum up, in treatment U we find several indications that at the beginning of a business relation participants prefer (more or less unconditionally) to adhere to the contract. They might do so because they want to keep their promise or trust in positive future reactions 21. In the course of the business relation they tend to make their actions reciprocally dependant on the behavior of their counterparts. 5.4 Binding Contracts Reduce Cooperation In the introduction we mentioned that MACAULAY (1963) argues that business partners often close down reference to social norms of goodwill and cooperation if legal arrangements are used. Several observations in our study are in line with his findings. In treatment U buyers more often pay what is proposed in the contract at the first installment, i.e., r 1 = p 1, compared to unrestricted buyers in treatment RU (p = 0.009, Fisher exact test, one-tailed). Furthermore, in treatment RU buyers who 21 I am grateful to an anonymous referee for clarifying that an additional explanation for the fulfillment of the contract at the beginning of the trading phase might be reputation building (KREPS and WILSON 1982, SELTEN and STOECKER 1986). 14

THEORIES OF BEHAVIOR IN PRINCIPAL-AGENT RELATIONSHIPS WITH HIDDEN ACTION*

THEORIES OF BEHAVIOR IN PRINCIPAL-AGENT RELATIONSHIPS WITH HIDDEN ACTION* 1 THEORIES OF BEHAVIOR IN PRINCIPAL-AGENT RELATIONSHIPS WITH HIDDEN ACTION* Claudia Keser a and Marc Willinger b a IBM T.J. Watson Research Center and CIRANO, Montreal b BETA, Université Louis Pasteur,

More information

Bonn Econ Discussion Papers

Bonn Econ Discussion Papers Bonn Econ Discussion Papers Discussion Paper 24/2003 Incomplete and Asymmetric Surplus Information in Labor Relations by Heike Hennig-Schmidt, Bettina Rockenbach, Abdolkarim Sadrieh October 2003 Bonn Graduate

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Leonardo Felli 7 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Contract Theory has become only recently a subfield of Economics. As the name suggest the main object of the analysis is a contract. Therefore

More information

Topic 3 Social preferences

Topic 3 Social preferences Topic 3 Social preferences Martin Kocher University of Munich Experimentelle Wirtschaftsforschung Motivation - De gustibus non est disputandum. (Stigler and Becker, 1977) - De gustibus non est disputandum,

More information

Other Regarding Preferences

Other Regarding Preferences Other Regarding Preferences Mark Dean Lecture Notes for Spring 015 Behavioral Economics - Brown University 1 Lecture 1 We are now going to introduce two models of other regarding preferences, and think

More information

Limitations of Dominance and Forward Induction: Experimental Evidence *

Limitations of Dominance and Forward Induction: Experimental Evidence * Limitations of Dominance and Forward Induction: Experimental Evidence * Jordi Brandts Instituto de Análisis Económico (CSIC), Barcelona, Spain Charles A. Holt University of Virginia, Charlottesville VA,

More information

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 12

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 12 CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 12 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO May 24, 2016 Announcements Homework #4 is due next week. Review of Last Lecture In extensive games with imperfect information,

More information

Psychology and Economics Field Exam August 2012

Psychology and Economics Field Exam August 2012 Psychology and Economics Field Exam August 2012 There are 2 questions on the exam. Please answer the 2 questions to the best of your ability. Do not spend too much time on any one part of any problem (especially

More information

Economics and Computation

Economics and Computation Economics and Computation ECON 425/563 and CPSC 455/555 Professor Dirk Bergemann and Professor Joan Feigenbaum Reputation Systems In case of any questions and/or remarks on these lecture notes, please

More information

A Theory of Value Distribution in Social Exchange Networks

A Theory of Value Distribution in Social Exchange Networks A Theory of Value Distribution in Social Exchange Networks Kang Rong, Qianfeng Tang School of Economics, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, Shanghai 00433, China Key Laboratory of Mathematical

More information

A Theory of Value Distribution in Social Exchange Networks

A Theory of Value Distribution in Social Exchange Networks A Theory of Value Distribution in Social Exchange Networks Kang Rong, Qianfeng Tang School of Economics, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, Shanghai 00433, China Key Laboratory of Mathematical

More information

Social preferences I and II

Social preferences I and II Social preferences I and II Martin Kocher University of Munich Course in Behavioral and Experimental Economics Motivation - De gustibus non est disputandum. (Stigler and Becker, 1977) - De gustibus non

More information

Cooperation and Rent Extraction in Repeated Interaction

Cooperation and Rent Extraction in Repeated Interaction Supplementary Online Appendix to Cooperation and Rent Extraction in Repeated Interaction Tobias Cagala, Ulrich Glogowsky, Veronika Grimm, Johannes Rincke July 29, 2016 Cagala: University of Erlangen-Nuremberg

More information

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation Reputations arise in situations where there is an element of repetition, and also where coordination between players is possible. One definition of leadership is that

More information

Ostracism and the Provision of a Public Good Experimental Evidence

Ostracism and the Provision of a Public Good Experimental Evidence Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods Bonn 2005/24 Ostracism and the Provision of a Public Good Experimental Evidence Frank P. Maier-Rigaud Peter Martinsson Gianandrea

More information

Public Goods Provision with Rent-Extracting Administrators

Public Goods Provision with Rent-Extracting Administrators Supplementary Online Appendix to Public Goods Provision with Rent-Extracting Administrators Tobias Cagala, Ulrich Glogowsky, Veronika Grimm, Johannes Rincke November 27, 2017 Cagala: Deutsche Bundesbank

More information

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome.

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome. AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED Alex Gershkov and Flavio Toxvaerd November 2004. Preliminary, comments welcome. Abstract. This paper revisits recent empirical research on buyer credulity

More information

Suggested solutions to the 6 th seminar, ECON4260

Suggested solutions to the 6 th seminar, ECON4260 1 Suggested solutions to the 6 th seminar, ECON4260 Problem 1 a) What is a public good game? See, for example, Camerer (2003), Fehr and Schmidt (1999) p.836, and/or lecture notes, lecture 1 of Topic 3.

More information

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Ahmer Tarar Department of Political Science Texas A&M University 4348 TAMU College Station, TX 77843-4348 email: ahmertarar@pols.tamu.edu

More information

Contracts, Reference Points, and Competition

Contracts, Reference Points, and Competition Contracts, Reference Points, and Competition Behavioral Effects of the Fundamental Transformation 1 Ernst Fehr University of Zurich Oliver Hart Harvard University Christian Zehnder University of Lausanne

More information

Finitely repeated simultaneous move game.

Finitely repeated simultaneous move game. Finitely repeated simultaneous move game. Consider a normal form game (simultaneous move game) Γ N which is played repeatedly for a finite (T )number of times. The normal form game which is played repeatedly

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński Decision Making in Manufacturing and Services Vol. 9 2015 No. 1 pp. 79 88 Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment Andrzej Paliński Abstract. This paper presents a model of bank-loan repayment as

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Relational Incentive Contracts

Relational Incentive Contracts Relational Incentive Contracts Jonathan Levin May 2006 These notes consider Levin s (2003) paper on relational incentive contracts, which studies how self-enforcing contracts can provide incentives in

More information

Chapter 7 Review questions

Chapter 7 Review questions Chapter 7 Review questions 71 What is the Nash equilibrium in a dictator game? What about the trust game and ultimatum game? Be careful to distinguish sub game perfect Nash equilibria from other Nash equilibria

More information

Fairness and the Optimal Allocation of Ownership Rights

Fairness and the Optimal Allocation of Ownership Rights Discussion Paper No. 11 Fairness and the Optimal Allocation of Ownership Rights Ernst Fehr* Susanne Kremhelmer** Klaus M. Schmidt*** July 2004 *Ernst Fehr, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics,

More information

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Chapter 5 Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Until now we implicitly adopted a view that a Nash equilibrium is a desirable outcome of a strategic game. In this chapter we consider two alternative

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Those taking the FINAL have THREE hours Part A (Glaeser): 55

More information

Information and Evidence in Bargaining

Information and Evidence in Bargaining Information and Evidence in Bargaining Péter Eső Department of Economics, University of Oxford peter.eso@economics.ox.ac.uk Chris Wallace Department of Economics, University of Leicester cw255@leicester.ac.uk

More information

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts 6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts Asu Ozdaglar MIT February 9, 2010 1 Introduction Outline Review Examples of Pure Strategy Nash Equilibria

More information

BOUNDS FOR BEST RESPONSE FUNCTIONS IN BINARY GAMES 1

BOUNDS FOR BEST RESPONSE FUNCTIONS IN BINARY GAMES 1 BOUNDS FOR BEST RESPONSE FUNCTIONS IN BINARY GAMES 1 BRENDAN KLINE AND ELIE TAMER NORTHWESTERN UNIVERSITY Abstract. This paper studies the identification of best response functions in binary games without

More information

January 26,

January 26, January 26, 2015 Exercise 9 7.c.1, 7.d.1, 7.d.2, 8.b.1, 8.b.2, 8.b.3, 8.b.4,8.b.5, 8.d.1, 8.d.2 Example 10 There are two divisions of a firm (1 and 2) that would benefit from a research project conducted

More information

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5 Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Oct. 23, 2015 Administrative Stuff Homework 2 is due next week. Due to the change in material covered, I have decided to change the grading system

More information

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games CPSC 532l Lecture 10 Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games CPSC 532l Lecture 10, Slide 1 Lecture Overview 1 Recap 2 Stochastic Games 3 Bayesian Games 4 Analyzing Bayesian

More information

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games Game Theory Wolfgang Frimmel Repeated Games 1 / 41 Recap: SPNE The solution concept for dynamic games with complete information is the subgame perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE) Selten (1965): A strategy

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Answer Key: Problem Set 4 Answer Key: Problem Set 4 Econ 409 018 Fall A reminder: An equilibrium is characterized by a set of strategies. As emphasized in the class, a strategy is a complete contingency plan (for every hypothetical

More information

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2013 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems Microeconomics II CIDE, MsC Economics List of Problems 1. There are three people, Amy (A), Bart (B) and Chris (C): A and B have hats. These three people are arranged in a room so that B can see everything

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions 1. (45 points) Consider the following normal form game played by Bruce and Sheila: L Sheila R T 1, 0 3, 3 Bruce M 1, x 0, 0 B 0, 0 4, 1 (a) Suppose

More information

Holdup: Investment Dynamics, Bargaining and Gradualism

Holdup: Investment Dynamics, Bargaining and Gradualism Holdup: Investment Dynamics, Bargaining and Gradualism Indian Statistical Institute, Lincoln University, University of Sydney October, 2011 (Work in Progress) Holdup: Motivating example What is holdup?

More information

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions? March 3, 215 Steven A. Matthews, A Technical Primer on Auction Theory I: Independent Private Values, Northwestern University CMSEMS Discussion Paper No. 196, May, 1995. This paper is posted on the course

More information

Social Norms, Information and Trust among Strangers: Theory and Evidence

Social Norms, Information and Trust among Strangers: Theory and Evidence Social Norms, Information and Trust among Strangers: Theory and Evidence John Duffy a Huan Xie b and Yong-Ju Lee c December 2009 Abstract How do norms of trust and reciprocity arise? We investigate this

More information

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions. Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions. Ilan Kremer and Andrzej Skrzypacz March 21, 2002 1 Introduction In many papers considering the sale of many objects in a sequence of auctions the seller

More information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Topic 5: Information Economics 21, Summer 2002 Andreas Bentz Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Introduction

More information

ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES

ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES Direct Tests of Models of Social Preferences and a New Model By James C. Cox and Vjollca Sadiraj Abstract: Departures from economic man behavior in many games in which

More information

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9 CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO May 22, 2015 Announcements HW #3 is due next week. Ch. 6.1: Ultimatum Game This is a simple game that can model a very simplified

More information

Sequential-move games with Nature s moves.

Sequential-move games with Nature s moves. Econ 221 Fall, 2018 Li, Hao UBC CHAPTER 3. GAMES WITH SEQUENTIAL MOVES Game trees. Sequential-move games with finite number of decision notes. Sequential-move games with Nature s moves. 1 Strategies in

More information

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015. FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.) Hints for Problem Set 2 1. Consider a zero-sum game, where

More information

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE Problem Set 1 These questions will go over basic game-theoretic concepts and some applications. homework is due during class on week 4. This [1] In this problem (see Fudenberg-Tirole

More information

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore*

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore* Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts by Oliver Hart and John Moore* Since Ronald Coase s famous 1937 article (Coase (1937)), economists have grappled with the question of what characterizes

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 More on strategic games and extensive games with perfect information Block 2 Jun 11, 2017 Auctions results Histogram of

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 22 COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY Correlated Strategies and Correlated

More information

Preliminary Notions in Game Theory

Preliminary Notions in Game Theory Chapter 7 Preliminary Notions in Game Theory I assume that you recall the basic solution concepts, namely Nash Equilibrium, Bayesian Nash Equilibrium, Subgame-Perfect Equilibrium, and Perfect Bayesian

More information

Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game

Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game Parkash Chander * and Myrna Wooders May 1, 2011 Abstract We propose a new concept of core for games in extensive form and label it the γ-core of an extensive

More information

HW Consider the following game:

HW Consider the following game: HW 1 1. Consider the following game: 2. HW 2 Suppose a parent and child play the following game, first analyzed by Becker (1974). First child takes the action, A 0, that produces income for the child,

More information

Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital. Prabal Roy Chowdhury

Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital. Prabal Roy Chowdhury Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital Prabal Roy Chowdhury Introduction: The focus of this paper is dynamic aspects of micro-lending, namely sequential lending

More information

Economics 109 Practice Problems 1, Vincent Crawford, Spring 2002

Economics 109 Practice Problems 1, Vincent Crawford, Spring 2002 Economics 109 Practice Problems 1, Vincent Crawford, Spring 2002 P1. Consider the following game. There are two piles of matches and two players. The game starts with Player 1 and thereafter the players

More information

The Intuitive and Divinity Criterion: Explanation and Step-by-step examples

The Intuitive and Divinity Criterion: Explanation and Step-by-step examples : Explanation and Step-by-step examples EconS 491 - Felix Munoz-Garcia School of Economic Sciences - Washington State University Reading materials Slides; and Link on the course website: http://www.bepress.com/jioe/vol5/iss1/art7/

More information

Homework #2 Psychology 101 Spr 03 Prof Colin Camerer

Homework #2 Psychology 101 Spr 03 Prof Colin Camerer Homework #2 Psychology 101 Spr 03 Prof Colin Camerer This is available Monday 28 April at 130 (in class or from Karen in Baxter 332, or on web) and due Wednesday 7 May at 130 (in class or to Karen). Collaboration

More information

Extensive-Form Games with Imperfect Information

Extensive-Form Games with Imperfect Information May 6, 2015 Example 2, 2 A 3, 3 C Player 1 Player 1 Up B Player 2 D 0, 0 1 0, 0 Down C Player 1 D 3, 3 Extensive-Form Games With Imperfect Information Finite No simultaneous moves: each node belongs to

More information

Supplementary Appendix Punishment strategies in repeated games: Evidence from experimental markets

Supplementary Appendix Punishment strategies in repeated games: Evidence from experimental markets Supplementary Appendix Punishment strategies in repeated games: Evidence from experimental markets Julian Wright May 13 1 Introduction This supplementary appendix provides further details, results and

More information

The Value of Temptation

The Value of Temptation The Value of Temptation Claudia V. Goldman Sarit Kraus 2,3 clag@cs.umass.edu sarit@cs.biu.ac.il Department of Computer Science University of Massachusetts Amherst, MA 0003 ph.: -43-545985 2 Department

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to GAME THEORY PROBLEM SET 1 WINTER 2018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to andrey.zhukov@aalto.fi. Materials from Osborne and Rubinstein

More information

Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments

Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments Carl T. Bergstrom University of Washington, Seattle, WA Theodore C. Bergstrom University of California, Santa Barbara Rodney

More information

Econ 711 Homework 1 Solutions

Econ 711 Homework 1 Solutions Econ 711 Homework 1 s January 4, 014 1. 1 Symmetric, not complete, not transitive. Not a game tree. Asymmetric, not complete, transitive. Game tree. 1 Asymmetric, not complete, transitive. Not a game tree.

More information

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Davit Khantadze September 30, 017 Abstract We are interested in optimal signals for the sender when the decision maker (receiver) has to make two separate decisions.

More information

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY HANDOUT ON PERFECT BAYESIAN EQUILIBRIUM- III Semi-Separating equilibrium

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY HANDOUT ON PERFECT BAYESIAN EQUILIBRIUM- III Semi-Separating equilibrium ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY HANDOUT ON PERFECT BAYESIAN EQUILIBRIUM- III Semi-Separating equilibrium Let us consider the following sequential game with incomplete information. Two players are playing

More information

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017 ECON 459 Game Theory Lecture Notes Auctions Luca Anderlini Spring 2017 These notes have been used and commented on before. If you can still spot any errors or have any suggestions for improvement, please

More information

A Model of (the Threat of) Counterfeiting

A Model of (the Threat of) Counterfeiting w o r k i n g p a p e r 04 01 A Model of (the Threat of) Counterfeiting by Ed Nosal and Neil Wallace FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland are preliminary

More information

CONVENTIONAL FINANCE, PROSPECT THEORY, AND MARKET EFFICIENCY

CONVENTIONAL FINANCE, PROSPECT THEORY, AND MARKET EFFICIENCY CONVENTIONAL FINANCE, PROSPECT THEORY, AND MARKET EFFICIENCY PART ± I CHAPTER 1 CHAPTER 2 CHAPTER 3 Foundations of Finance I: Expected Utility Theory Foundations of Finance II: Asset Pricing, Market Efficiency,

More information

International Journal of Industrial Organization

International Journal of Industrial Organization International Journal of Industrial Organization 8 (010) 451 463 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect International Journal of Industrial Organization journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ijio

More information

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam Summer 2018 Microeconomics Qualifying Exam There are 100 points possible on this exam, 50 points each for Prof. Lozada s questions and Prof. Dugar s questions. Each professor asks you to do two long questions

More information

Bargaining or Searching for a Better Price? - An Experimental Study

Bargaining or Searching for a Better Price? - An Experimental Study Bargaining or Searching for a Better Price? - An Experimental Study Anita Gantner Department of Economics University of Innsbruck October 14, 2008 Abstract This experimental study investigates two bargaining

More information

Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring.

Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring. Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring. Olivier Compte First Version: June 2001 This Version: November 2003 Abstract In principal-agent relationships, a termination threat is often thought

More information

Theoretically robust but empirically invalid? An experimental investigation into tax equivalence

Theoretically robust but empirically invalid? An experimental investigation into tax equivalence Econ. Theory 16, 719 734 (2000) Theoretically robust but empirically invalid? An experimental investigation into tax equivalence Rudolf Kerschbamer and Georg Kirchsteiger Department of Economics, University

More information

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment University of Konstanz Department of Economics Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment Florian Baumann and Tim Friehe Working Paper Series 2011-08 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/workingpaperseries

More information

Web Appendix: Proofs and extensions.

Web Appendix: Proofs and extensions. B eb Appendix: Proofs and extensions. B.1 Proofs of results about block correlated markets. This subsection provides proofs for Propositions A1, A2, A3 and A4, and the proof of Lemma A1. Proof of Proposition

More information

Iterated Dominance and Nash Equilibrium

Iterated Dominance and Nash Equilibrium Chapter 11 Iterated Dominance and Nash Equilibrium In the previous chapter we examined simultaneous move games in which each player had a dominant strategy; the Prisoner s Dilemma game was one example.

More information

Economics 502 April 3, 2008

Economics 502 April 3, 2008 Second Midterm Answers Prof. Steven Williams Economics 502 April 3, 2008 A full answer is expected: show your work and your reasoning. You can assume that "equilibrium" refers to pure strategies unless

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW DO INFORMAL AGREEMENTS AND RENEGOTIATION SHAPE CONTRACTUAL REFERENCE POINTS? Ernst Fehr Oliver D. Hart Christian Zehnder

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW DO INFORMAL AGREEMENTS AND RENEGOTIATION SHAPE CONTRACTUAL REFERENCE POINTS? Ernst Fehr Oliver D. Hart Christian Zehnder NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW DO INFORMAL AGREEMENTS AND RENEGOTIATION SHAPE CONTRACTUAL REFERENCE POINTS? Ernst Fehr Oliver D. Hart Christian Zehnder Working Paper 17545 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17545

More information

IPR Protection in the High-Tech Industries: A Model of Piracy

IPR Protection in the High-Tech Industries: A Model of Piracy IPR Protection in the High-Tech Industries: A Model of Piracy Thierry Rayna August 2006 Abstract This article investigates the relation between the level of publicness of digital goods i.e. their degree

More information

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017 G5212: Game Theory Mark Dean Spring 2017 Modelling Dynamics Up until now, our games have lacked any sort of dynamic aspect We have assumed that all players make decisions at the same time Or at least no

More information

Do Government Subsidies Increase the Private Supply of Public Goods?

Do Government Subsidies Increase the Private Supply of Public Goods? Do Government Subsidies Increase the Private Supply of Public Goods? by James Andreoni and Ted Bergstrom University of Wisconsin and University of Michigan Current version: preprint, 1995 Abstract. We

More information

On Delays in Project Completion With Cost Reduction: An Experiment

On Delays in Project Completion With Cost Reduction: An Experiment On Delays in Project Completion With Cost Reduction: An Experiment June 25th, 2009 Abstract We examine the voluntary provision of a public project via binary contributions when contributions may be made

More information

Self-Serving Bias and Ultimatum Bargaining

Self-Serving Bias and Ultimatum Bargaining Self-Serving Bias and Ultimatum Bargaining Simone Kohnz August 2004 Abstract There is strong evidence that in bargaining situations with asymmetric outside options people exhibit self-serving biases concerning

More information

GAME THEORY: DYNAMIC. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. Frank Cowell: Dynamic Game Theory

GAME THEORY: DYNAMIC. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. Frank Cowell: Dynamic Game Theory Prerequisites Almost essential Game Theory: Strategy and Equilibrium GAME THEORY: DYNAMIC MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell April 2018 1 Overview Game Theory: Dynamic Mapping the temporal

More information

ECON 803: MICROECONOMIC THEORY II Arthur J. Robson Fall 2016 Assignment 9 (due in class on November 22)

ECON 803: MICROECONOMIC THEORY II Arthur J. Robson Fall 2016 Assignment 9 (due in class on November 22) ECON 803: MICROECONOMIC THEORY II Arthur J. Robson all 2016 Assignment 9 (due in class on November 22) 1. Critique of subgame perfection. 1 Consider the following three-player sequential game. In the first

More information

Rational Allocation of Attention in Decision-Making

Rational Allocation of Attention in Decision-Making Rational Allocation of Attention in Decision-Making Stefanie Yvonne Schmitt This version: July 29, 2016 Abstract This paper proposes a model of attention allocation in decision-making. Attention has various

More information

Supplementary Material for: Belief Updating in Sequential Games of Two-Sided Incomplete Information: An Experimental Study of a Crisis Bargaining

Supplementary Material for: Belief Updating in Sequential Games of Two-Sided Incomplete Information: An Experimental Study of a Crisis Bargaining Supplementary Material for: Belief Updating in Sequential Games of Two-Sided Incomplete Information: An Experimental Study of a Crisis Bargaining Model September 30, 2010 1 Overview In these supplementary

More information

Advanced Micro 1 Lecture 14: Dynamic Games Equilibrium Concepts

Advanced Micro 1 Lecture 14: Dynamic Games Equilibrium Concepts Advanced Micro 1 Lecture 14: Dynamic Games quilibrium Concepts Nicolas Schutz Nicolas Schutz Dynamic Games: quilibrium Concepts 1 / 79 Plan 1 Nash equilibrium and the normal form 2 Subgame-perfect equilibrium

More information

Notes for Section: Week 4

Notes for Section: Week 4 Economics 160 Professor Steven Tadelis Stanford University Spring Quarter, 2004 Notes for Section: Week 4 Notes prepared by Paul Riskind (pnr@stanford.edu). spot errors or have questions about these notes.

More information

Chapter 33: Public Goods

Chapter 33: Public Goods Chapter 33: Public Goods 33.1: Introduction Some people regard the message of this chapter that there are problems with the private provision of public goods as surprising or depressing. But the message

More information

Rethinking Incomplete Contracts

Rethinking Incomplete Contracts Rethinking Incomplete Contracts By Oliver Hart Chicago November, 2010 It is generally accepted that the contracts that parties even sophisticated ones -- write are often significantly incomplete. Some

More information

April 29, X ( ) for all. Using to denote a true type and areport,let

April 29, X ( ) for all. Using to denote a true type and areport,let April 29, 2015 "A Characterization of Efficient, Bayesian Incentive Compatible Mechanisms," by S. R. Williams. Economic Theory 14, 155-180 (1999). AcommonresultinBayesianmechanismdesignshowsthatexpostefficiency

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017 Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 017 1. Sheila moves first and chooses either H or L. Bruce receives a signal, h or l, about Sheila s behavior. The distribution

More information

Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint

Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint Robert Baumann College of the Holy Cross Bryan Engelhardt College of the Holy Cross September 24, 2012 David L. Fuller Concordia University Abstract We show

More information

Alternative sources of information-based trade

Alternative sources of information-based trade no trade theorems [ABSTRACT No trade theorems represent a class of results showing that, under certain conditions, trade in asset markets between rational agents cannot be explained on the basis of differences

More information