Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Hedging in Continuous Time

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Hedging in Continuous Time"

Transcription

1 Woring Paper Series National Centre of Competence in Research Financial Valuation and Ris Management Woring Paper No. 824 Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Hedging in Continuous Time Yan Dolinsy Halil Mete Soner First version: October 212 Current version: January 213 This research has been carried out within the NCCR FINRISK project on Mathematical Methods in Financial Ris Management

2 MARTINGALE OPTIMAL TRANSPORT AND ROBUST HEDGING IN CONTINUOUS TIME YAN DOLINSKY AND H.METE SONER HEBREW UNIVERSITY OF JERUSALEM AND ETH ZURICH Abstract. The duality between the robust (or equivalently, model independent hedging of path dependent European options and a martingale optimal transport problem is proved. The financial maret is modeled through a risy asset whose price is only assumed to be a continuous function of time. The hedging problem is to construct a minimal super-hedging portfolio that consists of dynamically trading the underlying risy asset and a static position of vanilla options which can be exercised at the given, fixed maturity. The dual is a Monge-Kantorovich type martingale transport problem of maximizing the expected value of the option over all martingale measures that has the given marginal at maturity. In addition to duality, a family of simple, piecewise constant super-replication portfolios that asymptotically achieve the minimal super-replication cost is constructed. 1. Introduction The original transport problem proposed by Monge [18] is to optimally move a pile of soil to an excavation. Mathematically, given two measures ν and µ of equal mass, we loo for an optimal bijection of R d which moves ν to µ, i.e., loo for a map S so that ϕ(s(xdν(x = ϕ(xdµ(x, R d R d for all continuous functions ϕ. Then, with a given cost function c, the objective is to minimize c(x,s(x dν(x R d over all bijections S. In his classical papers [15, 16], Kantorovich relaxed this problem by considering a probability measure on R d R d, whose marginals agree with ν and µ, instead of a bijection. This generalization linearizes the problem. Hence, allows for an easy existence result and enables one to identify its convex dual. Indeed, the dual elements are real-valued continuous maps (g,h of R d satisfying the constraint (1.1 g(x+h(y c(x,y. Date: January 22, Mathematics Subject Classification. 91G1, 6G44. Key words and phrases. European Options, Robust Hedging, Min Max Theorems, Prohorov Metric, Optimal transport. Research partly supported by the European Research Council under the grant FiRM, by the ETH Foundation and by the Swiss Finance Institute. 1

3 2 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner The dual objective function is to maximize g(x dν(x+ h(y dµ(y R d R d overall(g, h satisfying the constraint(1.1. In the last decades an impressive theory has been developed and we refer the reader to [1, 23, 24] and to the references therein. In robust hedging problems, we are also given two measures. Namely, the initial and the final distributions of a stoc process. We then construct an optimal connection. In general, however, the cost functional depends on the whole path of this connection and not simply on the final value. Hence, one needs to consider processes instead of simply the maps S. The probability distribution of this process has prescribed marginals at final and initial times. Thus, it is in direct analogy with the Kantorovich measure. But, financial considerations restrict the process to be a martingale (see Definition 2.4. Interestingly, the dual also has a financial interpretation as a robust hedging (super-replication problem. Indeed, the replication constraint is similar to (1.1. The formal connection between the original Monge-Kantorovich problem and the financial problem is further discussed in Remar 2.7 and also in the papers [4] and [12]. We continue by describing the robust hedging problem. Consider a financial maret consisting of one risy asset with a continuous price process. As in the classical paper of Hobson [13], all call options are liquid assets and can be traded for a reasonable price that is nown initially. Hence, the portfolio of an investor consists of static positions in the call options in addition to the usual dynamically updated risy asset. This leads us to a similar structure as in [13] and in other papers that consider robust hedging of model-independent price bounds. Apart from the continuity of the price process no other model assumptions are placed on the dynamics of the price process. In this maret, we prove the Kantorovich duality, Theorem 2.6, and an approximation result, Theorem 2.8, for a general class of path-dependent options. The classical duality theorem, for a maret with a given semi-martingale, states that the minimal super-replication cost of a contingent claim is equal to the supremum of its expected value over all martingale measures that are equivalent to a given measure. We refer the reader to Delbaen & Schachermayer [1] (Theorem 5.7 for the general semi-martingale processes and to El-Karoui & Quenez [11] for its dynamic version in the diffusion case. Theorem 2.6 below, also provides a dual representation of the minimal super-replication cost but for the general model independent marets. The dual is given as the supremum of the expectations of the contingent claim over all martingale measures with a given marginal at the maturity but with no dominating measure. Since no probabilistic model is pre-assumed for the price process, the class of all martingale measures is quite large. Indeed, typically martingale measures are orthogonal to each other and this fact renders the problem difficult. However, the additional feature of the maret that the call prices are nown, introduces the new marginal constraint. This in turn, provides the connection to the problem of optimal transport. In the literature, there are two earlier results in this direction. In a purely discrete setup, a similar result was recently proved by Beiglboc, Henry-Labordère and Penner [4]. In their model, the investor is allowed to buy all call options at finitely many given maturities and the stoc is traded only at these possible

4 Martingale Optimal Transport 3 maturities. In this paper, however, the stoc is traded in continuous time together with a static position in the calls with one maturity. In [4] the dual is recognized as a Monge-Kantorovich type optimal transport for martingale measures and is essentially used. In continuous time, Galichon, Henry-Labordère and Touzi [12] prove a different duality and then use the dual to convert the problem to an optimal control problem. There are two main differences between our result and the one proved in [12]. The duality result, Proposition 2.1 in [12], states that the minimal super-replication cost is given as the infimum over Lagrange multipliers and supremum over martingale measures without the final time constraint and the Lagrange multipliers are related to the constraint. Also the problem formulation is different. The model in [12] assumes a large class of possible martingale measures for the price process. The duality is then proved by extending an earlier unconstrained result proved in [21]. As in the unconstrained model of [21, 22], the super-replication is defined not pathwise but rather probabilistically through quasi-sure inequalities. Namely, the superreplication cost is the minimal initial wealth from which one can super-replicate the option with probability one with respect to all measures in a given class. In general, these measures are not dominated with one measure. As already mentioned this is the main difficulty and differs the current problem from the classical duality discussed earlier. However, our duality result together with the results of [12] implies that these two approaches namely, robust hedging through the path-wise definition of this paper and the quasi-sure definition of [12, 21] yield the same value. This is proved in Section 3 below. Our second result provides a class of portfolios which are managed on a finite number of random times and asymptotically achieve the minimal super-replication cost. This result may have practical implications allowing us to numerically investigate the corresponding discrete hedges, but we relegate this to a future study. The robust hedging has been an active research area over the past decade. The initial paper of Hobson [13] studies the case of the loobac option. The connection to the Sorohod embedding is also made in this paper and an explicit solution for the minimal super-replication cost is obtained. This approach was further developed bybrown, HobsonandRogers[5]andCoxandObloj[7]andinseveralotherpapers. We refer the reader to the excellent survey of Hobson[14] and the references therein. Also a similar modeling approach was applied to volatility options by Carr and Lee [6]. We refer to the recent paper by Cox and Wang [8] for more information and a discussion of various constructions of the Root s solution of the Sorohod embedding. Also in a recent paper, Davis and Obloj [9] considered the variance swaps in a maret with finitely many put options. In particular, in [9] the class of admissible portfolios is enlarged and numerical evidence is obtained by analyzing the S&P5 index options data. As already mentioned above, the dual approach is used by Galichon, Henry- Labordère and Touzi [12] and Henry-Labordère and Touzi [17] as well. In these papers, the duality provides a connection to stochastic optimal control which can be then used to compute the solution in a more systematic manner. Our approach is to represent the original robust hedging problem as a limit of robust hedging problems which live on a sequence of countable spaces. For these type of problems, robust hedging is the same as the classical hedging, under the right choice of the probability measure. Thus we can apply the classical duality

5 4 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner results for super hedging of European options on a given probability space. The last step is to analyze the limit of the obtained prices. We combine methods from arbitrage free pricing and limit theorems for stochastic processes. The paper is organized as follows. Main results are formulated in the next section. In Section 3, the connection between the quasi sure approach and ours is proved. The last two sections are devoted to the proof of one inequality which implies the main results. Acnowledgements. The authors would lie to than Mathias Beiglboc, David Belius, Alex Cox, Jan Obloj, Walter Schachermayer and Nizar Touzi for insightful discussions and comments. In particular, Section 3 resulted from discussions with Obloj and Touzi and Shachermayer pointed out a mistae in an earlier version. 2. Preliminaries and main results The financial maret consists of a savings account which is normalized to unity B t 1 by discounting and of a risy asset S t, t [,T], where T < is the maturity date. Let s := S > be the initial stoc price and without loss of generality, we set s = 1. Denote by C + [,T] the set of all strictly positive functions f : [,T] R + which satisfy f = 1. We assume that S t is a continuous process. Then, any element of C + [,T] can be a possible path for the stoc price process S. Let us emphasis that this the only assumption that we mae on our financial maret. Denote by D[,T] the space of all measurable functions υ : [,T] R with the norm υ = sup t T υ t. Let G : D[,T] R be a given deterministic map. We then consider a path dependent European option with the payoff (2.1 X = G(S, where S is viewed as an element in D[,T] An assumption on the claim. Since our approach is through approximation, we need the regularity of the pay-off functional G. A discussion of this assumption is given in Remar 2.2. In particular, it is related to the classical Sorohod topology, and Asian and loobac type options satisfy the below condition. We need the following definition. Let D N [,T] be the subset of D[,T] that are piecewise constant with N possible jumps t = < t 1 < t 2 <... < t N T, i.e., v D N [,T] if and only if N v t = v i χ [ti 1,t i(t+v N+1 χ [tn,t](t, where v i := v ti 1. i=1 We mae the following standing assumption on G. Assumption 2.1. There exists a constant L > so that G(ω G( ω L ω ω, ω, ω D[,T]. Moreover, let υ, υ D N [,T] be such that υ i = υ i for all i = 1,...,N. Then, N G(υ G( υ L υ t t, =1 where as usual t := t t 1 and t := t t 1.

6 Martingale Optimal Transport 5 Remar 2.2. In our setup, the process S represents the discounted stoc price and G(S represents the discounted award. Let r > be the constant interest rate. Then, the payoff ( G(S := e rt H e rt S T, min t T ert S t, max t T ert S t, T e rt S t dt with a Lipschitz continuous function H : R 4 R satisfies the above assumption. The above condition on G is, in fact, a Lipschitz assumption with respect to a metric very similar to the Sorohod one. However, it is weaer than to assume Lipschitz continuity with respect to the Sorohod metric. Recall that this classical metric is given by d(f,g := inf λ sup t T max( f(t g(λ(t, λ(t t, where the infimum is taen over all time changes. A time change is a strictly increasing continuous function which satisfy λ( = and λ(t = T. We refer the reader to Chapter 3 in [3] for more information. In particular, while T S tdt is continuous with respect to the Sorohod metric in C[,T], it is not Lipschitz continuous in C[,T] and it is not even continuous in D[,T]. Although we assume S to be continuous, since in our analysis we need to consider approximations in D[,T], the above assumption is needed in order to include Asian options. Moreover, from our proof of the main results it can be shown that Theorems 2.6 and 2.8 can be extended to payoffs of the form ( e rt H e rt1 S t1,...,e rt S t, min t T ert S t, max t T ert S t, T e rt S t dt where H is Lipschitz and < t 1 <... < t T. Finally, one can extend the results to barrier options, by considering a discretization that is adapted to the barriers. In this paper, we choose not to include this extension to avoid more technicalities., 2.2. European Calls. Let µ be a given probability measure on R +. At time zero, the investor is allowed to buy any call option with with strie K, for a price C(K := (x K + dµ(x. The probability measure µ is assumed to be derived from observed call prices that are liquidly traded in the maret. One may also thin that µ describes the probabilistic belief of the firm for the stoc price at time T. Then, an arbitrage and an approximation arguments imply that the price of an option with the payoff g(s T with a bounded, measurable g must be given by gdµ. We then assume that this formula also holds for all g L 1 (R +,µ. Also, since C( is the price of a forward, it must be equal to the initial stoc price S which is normalized to one. Therefore, although the probability measure µ is quite general, in order to avoid arbitrage, it should satisfy that (2.2 C( = xdµ(x = S = 1.

7 6 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner Technically, we also assume that there exists p > 1 such that (2.3 x p dµ(x < Admissible portfolios. We continue by describing the continuous time trading in the underlying asset S. Since we do not assume any semi-martingale structure of the risy asset, this question is nontrivial. We adopt the path-wise approach of Hobson and require that the trading strategy (in the risy asset is of finite variation. Then, for any function h : [,T] R of finite variation and continuous function S C[,T], we use integration by parts to define t h u ds u := h t S t h S t S u dh u, where the last term in the above right hand side is the standard Stieltjes integral. We are now ready to give the definition of semi-static portfolios and superhedging. Recall the exponent p in (2.3. Definition We say that a map φ : A D[,T] D[,T] is progressively measurable, if for any v,ṽ A, (2.4 v u = ṽ u, u [,t] φ(v t = φ(ṽ t. 2. A semi-static portfolio is a pair π := (g,γ, where g L 1 (R +,µ and γ : C + [,T] D[,T] is a progressively measurable map of bounded variation. 3. The corresponding discounted portfolio value is given by, Z π t (S = g(s T χ {t=t} + t γ u (SdS u, t [,T], where χ A is the indicator of the set A. A semi-static portfolio is admissible, if there exists M > such that ( (2.5 Zt π (S M 1+ sup Su p, t [,T], S C + [,T]. u t 4. An admissible semi-static portfolio is called super-replicating, if Z π T(S G(S, S C + [,T]. 5. The (minimal super-hedging cost of G is defined by, { V(G := inf gdµ : γ such that π := (g,γ is super-replicating Notice that the set of admissible portfolios depend on the exponent p which appears in the assumption (2.3. We suppress this possible dependence to simplify the exposition. }.

8 Martingale Optimal Transport Martingale optimal transport. Since the dual formula refers to a probabilistic structure, we need to introduce that structure as well. Set Ω := C + [,T] and let S = (S t t T be the canonical process given by S t (ω := ω t, for all ω Ω. Let F t := σ(s s, s t be the canonical filtration. The following class of probability measures are central to our results. Recall that we have normalized the stoc prices to have initial value one. Therefore, below the probability measures need to satisfy this condition as well. Definition 2.4. A probability measure P on the space (Ω,F is a martingale measure, if the canonical process (S t T t= is a local martingale with respect to P and S = 1 P-a.s. For a probability measure µ on R +, M µ is the set of all martingale measures P such that the probability distribution of S T under P is equal to µ. Note that if µ satisfies (2.2, then the canonical process (S t T t= is a martingale (not only a local martingale under any measure P M µ. Remar 2.5. Observe that (2.2 yields that the set M µ is not empty. Indeed, consider a complete probability space (Ω W,F W,P W together with a standard one dimensional Brownian motion (W t t=, and the natural filtration Ft W which is the completion of σ{w s s t}. Then, there exists a function f : R R + such that the probability distribution of f(w T is equal to µ. Define the martingale M t := E W (f(w T Ft W, t [,T]. Inviewof(2.2, M = 1. SinceM isabrownian martingale, it is continuous. Moreover, since µ has support on the positive real line, f and consequently, M. Then, the distribution of M on the space Ω is an element in M µ. The following is the main result of the paper. An outline of its proof is given in the subsection 2.6, below. Theorem 2.6. Assume that the European claim G satisfies the Assumption 2.1 and the probability measure µ satisfies (2.2 and (2.3. Then, the minimal super-hedging cost is given by V(G = sup P M µ E P [G(S], where E P denotes the expectation with respect to P. Remar 2.7. One may consider the maximizer, if exists, of the expression sup E P [G(S], P M µ as the optimal transport of the initial probability measure ν = δ {1} to the final distribution µ. However, an additional constraint that the connection is a martingale imposed. This in turn places a restriction on the measures, namely (2.2. The penalty function c is replaced by a more general functional G. In this context, one may also consider general initial distributions ν rather than Dirac measures. Then, the martingale measures with given marginals corresponds to the Kantorovich generalization of the mass transport problem. The super-replication problem is also analogous to the Kantorovich dual. However, the dual elements reflect the fact that the cost functional depends on the whole path of the connection. The reader may also consult [4] for a very clear discussion of the connection between the robust hedging and the optimal transport.

9 8 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner 2.5. A discrete time approximation. Next we construct a special class of simple strategies which achieve asymptotically the super hedging cost V. ForapositiveintegerN andanys C + [,T], setτ (N (S =. Then, recursively define, (2.6 τ (N (S = inf { t > τ (N 1 (S : S t S (N τ (S = 1 } T, 1 N where we set τ (N (S = T, when the above set is empty. Also, define (2.7 H (N (S = min{ N : τ (N (S = T}. Observe that for any S C + [,T], H (N (S <. Denote by A N the set of all portfolios for which the trading in the stoc occurs only at the moments = τ (N (S < τ (N 1 (S <... < τ (N (S = T. Formally, H (N (S π := (g,γ A N, if it is progressively measurable in the sense of (2.4 and it is of the form γ t (S = H (N (S 1 = γ (Sχ (N (τ (S,τ (N (S](t, +1 for some γ (S s. Note that, γ (S can depend on S only through its values up to time τ (N (S, so that γ t is progressively measurable. Set { V N (G := inf } gdµ : γ such that π := (g,γ A N is super-replicating. It is clear that for any integer 1, V N (G V N (G V(G. The following result proves the convergence to V(G. This approximation result is the second main result of this paper. Also, it is the ey analytical step in the proof of duality. Theorem 2.8. Under the assumptions of Theorem 2.6, lim V N(G = V(G. N 2.6. Proofs of Theorems 2.6 and 2.8. In order to establish Theorem 2.6 and Theorem 2.8 it is sufficient to prove that (2.8 lim sup V N (G sup E P [G(S] N P M µ and V(G sup P M µ E P [G(S]. The first inequality is the difficult one and it will be proved in the last two sections. The second inequality is simpler and we provide its proof here. Let P M µ and let π = (g,γ be super-replicating. Since γ is progressively measurable in the sense of (2.4, the stochastic integral t γ u (SdS u

10 Martingale Optimal Transport 9 is defined with respect to P. Also P is a martingale measure and G satisfies the lower bound (2.5. Hence, the above stochastic integral is a P local martingale. Moreover, t γ u (SdS u G(S M(1+ sup S t p. t T Also in view of (2.3 and the Doob-Kolmogorov inequality, E P sup S t p C p E P S T p = C p x p dµ <. t T T Therefore, E P γ u(sds u. Since π is super-replicating, this together with (2.5 implies that ( T E P [G(S] E P γ u (SdS u +g(s T E P [g(s T ] = gdµ, where in the last equality we again used that the distribution of S T under P equals to µ. This completes the proof of the lower bound. Together with (2.8, which will be proved in the last sections, it also completes the proofs of the theorems. 3. Quasi sure approach and full duality An alternate approach to define robust hedging is to use the notion of quasi sure super-hedging as it was done in [12, 21]. Let us briefly recall this notion. Let Q be the set of all martingale measures P on the canonical space C + [,T] under which the canonical process S satisfies S = 1,P-a.s., has quadratic variation and satisfies E P sup t T S t <. In this maret, an admissible hedging strategy (or a portfolio is defined as a pair π = (g,γ, where g L 1 (R +,µ and γ is a progressively measurable process such that the stochastic integral t γ u ds u, t [,T] exists for any probability measure in the set P Q and satisfies (2.5 P-a.s. We refer the reader to [21] for a complete characterization of this class. In particular, one does not restrict the trading strategies to be of bounded variation. A portfolio π = (g, γ is called an (admissible quasi-sure super-hedge, provided that g(s T + T γ u ds u G(S, P a.s., for all P Q. Then, the minimal super-hedging cost is given by { } V qs (G := inf gdµ : γ such that π := (g,γ is a quasi-sure super-hedge. Clearly, V(G V qs (G. From simple arbitrage arguments it follows that V qs (G inf E P (G(S λ(s T + sup λ L 1 (R +,µ P Q λdµ

11 1 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner where we set E P ξ, if E P ξ =. Since infsup supinf, the above two inequalities yield, V(G V qs (G inf sup λ L 1 (R +,µ sup inf P Q E P P Qλ L 1 (R +,µ E P (G(S λ(s T + ( G(S λ(s T + λdµ λdµ. Now if P M µ, then the two terms with λ are equal. So we first restrict the measures to the set M µ and then use Theorem 2.6, to arrive at V(G V qs (G inf E P (G(S λ(s T + λdµ sup inf sup λ L 1 (R +,µ P Q E P P Qλ L 1 (R +,µ sup P M µ E P [G(S] = V(G. ( G(S λ(s T + λdµ Hence, all terms in the above are equal. We summarize this in the following which can be seen as the full duality. Proposition 3.1. Assume that the European claim G satisfies Assumption 2.1 and the probability measure µ satisfies (2.2,(2.3. Then, V(G = V qs (G = sup P M µ E P [G(S] = inf sup λ L 1 (R +,µ P Q = sup inf E P P Qλ L 1 (R +,µ E P (G(S λ(s T + ( G(S λ(s T + λdµ λdµ. 4. Proof of the main results The rest of the paper is devoted to the proof of ( Reduction to bounded claims. We start with a reduction to claims that are bounded from above. Towards this result, we first prove a technical result. Consider a claim with pay-off α K (S := S χ { S K} + S K. Recall that V N (α K is defined in subsection 2.5. Lemma 4.1. lim sup K lim supv N (α K =. N Proof. In this proof, we always assume that N > K > 1. Let τ = τ (N (S and n = H (N (S be as in (2.6, (2.7, respectively, and set θ := θ (K N (S = min{ : S τ K 1} n.

12 Martingale Optimal Transport 11 We next define a portfolio (g (N,K,γ (N,K A N as follows. For t (τ,τ +1 ] and =,1,...,n 1, set γ (N,K t (S = γ τ (N,K p 2 ( ( (S = max K(p 1 i Sp 1 τ i p2 (p 1 χ { θ} max θ i Sp 1 τ i and with c p := p/(p 1 define g (N,K by g (N,K (x = 1 K (1+((c px p c p + +((c p x p (c p (K 1 p N. We use Proposition 2.1 in [2] and the inequality x < 1+x p, x R +, to conclude that for any t [,T] where g (N,K (S t + t γ u ds u S t K + S t χ { St K}, S t := max u t S u. Therefore, π (N,K := (g N,K,γ (N,K satisfies (2.5 and super-replicates α K. Hence, V N (α K g (N,K dµ. Also, in view of (2.3, lim sup K lim sup N g (N,K dµ =. These two inequalities complete the proof of the lemma. A corollary of the above estimate is the following reduction to claims that are bounded from above. Lemma 4.2. If suffices to prove (2.8 for claims G that are non-negative, bounded from above and satisfying the Assumption 2.1. Proof. We proceed in two steps. First suppose that (2.8 holds for nonnegative claims that are bounded from above. Then, the conclusions of Theorem 2.6 and Theorem 2.8 also hold for such claims. Now let G be a non-negative claim satisfying Assumption 2.1. For K >, set G K := G K. Then, G K is bounded and (2.8 holds for G K. Therefore, In view of Assumption 2.1, lim supv N (G K sup E P [G K (S] sup E P [G(S]. N P M µ P M µ G(S G(+L S. Hence, the set {G(S K} is included in the set {L S +G( K} and G G K +(L S +G( Kχ {L S +G( K}. By the linearity of the maret, this inequality implies that V N (G V N (G K +V N ( (L S +G( Kχ{L S +G( K}.

13 12 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner Moreover, in view of the previous lemma, lim sup K Using these, we conclude that ( lim supv N (L S +G( Kχ{L S +G( K} =. N lim supv N (G sup E P [G(S]. N P M µ Hence, (2.8 holds for all functions that are non-negative and satisfy Assumption 2.1. By adding an appropriate constant this results extends to all claims that are bounded from below and satisfying Assumption 2.1. Now suppose that G is a general function that satisfies Assumption 2.1. For c >, set Ǧ c := G ( c. Then, Ǧ is bounded from below and (2.8 holds, i.e., lim sup N V N (G limsupv N (Ǧc = sup E P [Ǧc (S ]. N P M µ By Assumption 2.1, Ǧ c (S G(S+ě c (S where the error function is ě c (S := (L S G( cχ {L S G( c } (S. Since ě c and it satisfies the Assumption 2.1, In view of Lemma 4.1, lim sup c sup E P [ě c (S] = V(ě c = lim V N(ê c. P M µ N sup E P [ě c (S] = limsup P M µ c We combine the above inequalities to conclude that lim supv N (G limsup sup E P [Ǧc (S ] N c P M µ This exactly (2.8. lim supv N (ě c =. N sup E P [G(S]+limsup sup E P [ě c (S] P M µ c P M µ = sup P M µ E P [G(S] A countable class of piecewise constant functions. In this section, we provide a piece-wise constant approximation of any continuous function S. Fix a positive integer N. For any S C + [,T], let τ (N (S and H (N (S be the times defined in (2.6 and (2.7, respectively. To simplify the notation, we suppress their dependence on S and N and also set (4.1 n = H (N (S. We first define the obvious piecewise constant approximation Ŝ = Ŝ(N (S using these times. Indeed, set n 1 [ Ŝ t := S τ χ [τ,τ +1 (t+ S τn ] N sign(s T S τn 1 χ {T} (t, = where as usual sign(x = 1 if x, and sign(x = 1 for x <.

14 Martingale Optimal Transport 13 The function, that taes S to Ŝ is a map of C+ [,T] into the set of all functions with values in the target set A (N = {i/n : i =,1,2,...,}. Indeed, Ŝ is behind the definition of the approximating costs V N. However, this set of functions is not countable as the jump times are not restricted to a countable set. So, we provide yet another approximation by restricting the jump times as well. Let D[,T] be the space of all right continuous functions f : [,T] R + with left hand limits (càdlàg functions. For integers N,, let U (N := { i/(2 N : i = 1,2,..., } { 1/(i2 N : i = 1,2,..., }, be the sets of possible differences between two consecutive jump times. Next, we define a subset D (N of D[,T]. Definition 4.3. Afunctionf D[,T]belongstoD (N, ifitsatisfiesthefollowings, 1. f( = 1, 2. f is piecewise constant with jumps at times t 1,...,t n, where t = < t 1 < t 2 <... < t n < T, 3. for any = 1,...,n, f(t f(t 1 = 1/N, 4. for any = 1,...,n, t t 1 U (N. We emphasize, in the fourth condition, the dependence of the set U (N on. So as gets larger, jump times tae values in a finer grid. We now define an approximation F (N : C + [,T] D (N, as follow. Recall τ = τ (N (S, n = H (N (S from above and also from (2.6, (2.7. Set ˆτ :=, and for = 1,...,n, define ˆτ := ˆτ i, i=1 ˆτ i = max{ t U (N i : t < τ i = τ i τ i 1 }. It is clear that = ˆτ < ˆτ 1 <... < ˆτ n < T and ˆτ < τ for all =,...,n. We now define F (N (S by, (4.2 n 2 F (N t (S = [1 S τ1 ]+ = S τ+1 χ [ˆτ,ˆτ +1 (t [ + S τn ] N sign(s T S τn 1 χ [ˆτn 1,T](t, where we set ˆτ 1 =. Observe that the value of the -th jump of the process F (N (S equals to the value of the ( + 1-th jump of the discretization Ŝ of the original process S. Indeed, (4.3 F (N ˆτ m F (N ˆτ m 1 = S τm+1 S τm, m = 1,...,n 2, and F (N ˆτ n 1 F (N ˆτ n 2 = 1 N sign( S T S τn 1. This shift is essential in order to deal with some delicate questions of adeptness and predictability. We also recall that the jump times of Ŝ are the random times

15 14 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner τ s while the jump times of F (N (S are ˆτ s and that all these times depend both on N and S. Moreover, by construction, F (N (S D (N. But, it may not be progressively measurable as defined in (2.4. However, we use F (N only to lift progressively measurable maps defined on D (N to the initial space Ω = C + [,T] and this yields progressively measurable maps on Ω. This procedure is defined and the measurability is proved in Lemma 4.7, below. The following lemma shows that F (N is close to S in the sense of Assumption 2.1. We also point out that the following result is a consequence of the particular structure of D (N and in particular U (N s. Lemma 4.4. Let F (N be the map defined in (4.2. For any G satisfying the Assumption 2.1 with the constant L, G(S G(F (N (S 5L S N, S C+ [,T]. Proof. Define the map n 1 [ ˆF (N t (S := S τ χ [ˆτ,ˆτ +1 (t+ S τn ] N sign(s T S τn 1 χ [ˆτn,T](t. = First recall Assumption 2.1 and observe that Ŝ and ˆF = ˆF (N are lie the functions υ and υ in that definition. Hence, n G(Ŝ G(ˆF L S τ ˆτ. For < n, The definition of U (N Therefore, (4.4 =1 { } ˆτ = max t U (N : t < τ. implies that τ ˆτ 1 2 N, = 1,...,n 1. n 1 τ ˆτ 2 N = 1 N. =1 =1 Combining the above inequalities, we arrive at G(Ŝ G(ˆF L S N. Set F = F (N (S and directly estimate that + G( G(S G(F G(S G(Ŝ Ŝ G(ˆF + G(ˆF G(F L S L S Ŝ + G(ˆF G(F N + = 3L S. G(ˆF G(F N + Finally, we observe that by construction, ˆF F 2 G(F G(ˆF N, 2L N.

16 Martingale Optimal Transport 15 The above inequalities completes the proof of the lemma. Remar 4.5. The proof of the above Lemma provides one of the reasons behind the particular structure of U (N. Indeed, (4.4 is a ey estimate which provides a uniform upper bound for the sum of the differences over. Since there is no upper bound on, the approximating set U (N for the -th difference must depend on. Moreover, it should have a summable structure over. That explains the terms 2. On the other hand, the reason for the part {1/(i2 N : i = 1,2,...} in U (N is to mae sure that ˆτ >. For probabilistic reasons (i.e. adaptability, we want ˆτ τ. This forces us to approximate τ by ˆτ from below. This and ˆτ > would be possible only if U (N has a subsequence converging to zero. Hence, different sets of U (N s are also possible provided that they have these two properties A countable probabilistic structure. An essential step in the proof of(2.8 is a duality result for probabilistic problems. We first introduce this structure and then relate it to the problem V N. Let ˆΩ := D[,T] be the space of all right continuous functions f : [,T] R + with left hand limits (càdlàg functions. Denote by Ŝ = (Ŝt t T the canonical process on the space ˆΩ. The set D (N defined in Definition 4.3 is a countable subset of ˆΩ. We choose any probability measure ˆP (N on ˆΩ which satisfies ˆP (N( D (N = 1 and ˆP (N ({f} > ˆF (N t for all f D (N. Let, t [,T] by the filtration which is generated by the (N process Ŝ and satisfying the usual assumptions (right continuous and contains ˆP null sets. Under the measure ˆP, the canonical map Ŝ has finitely many jumps. Let = ˆτ (Ŝ < ˆτ 1(Ŝ <... < ˆτ Ĥ(Ŝ(Ŝ < T, be the jump times of Ŝ. Note that in Definition 4.3, the final jump time is always strictly less than T. Then,atradingstrategyonthefilteredprobabilityspace(ˆΩ, ˆF (N (N,( ˆF t T t=,ˆp (N is a càdlàg progressively measurable stochastic process (ˆγ t T t=. Thus, there exists a map φ : D[,T] D[,T], so that it is progressively measurable in the sense of (2.4 and ˆγ = φ(ŝ, ˆP-a.s. Since we may always wor with φ instead of ˆγ, there is no loss of generality in assuming that ˆγ is itself is progressively measurable in the sense of (2.4. We now give the probabilistic counterpart of the Definition 2.3. Definition A (probabilistic semi-static portfolio is a pair (h, ˆγ such that ˆγ : D[,T] D[,T] is càdlàg, progressively measurable and h : A (N R. 2. A semi-static portfolio is ˆP (N -admissible, if h is bounded and there exists M > such that (4.5 t ˆγ u- dŝu M, ˆP(N a.s., t [,T], where ˆγ u- is the left limit of the càdlàg function ˆγ at time u.

17 16 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner 3. An admissible semi-static portfolio is ˆP (N -super-replicating, if (4.6 h(ŝt+ T ˆγ u- dŝu G(Ŝ, ˆP(N a.s Approximating µ. Recall the set A N of portfolios used in the definition of V N in subsection 2.5. Next we provide a connection between the probabilistic super-replication and the discrete robust problem. However, h in Definition 4.6 above is defined only on A (N while the static part of the hedges in A N are functions defined on R +. So for a given h : A (N R, we define the following operator by g (N := L (N (h : R + R g (N (x := (1+ Nx Nxh( Nx /N+(Nx Nx h((1+ Nx /N, where for a real number r, r is the largest integer that is not larger than r. Next, define a measure µ (N on the set A (N by and for any positive integer, µ (N ({/N} := /N µ (N ({} := ( 1/N 1/N (Nx+1 dµ(x+ (1 Nxdµ(x (+1/N /N (1+ Nxdµ(x. This construction has the following important property. For any bounded function h : A (N R, let g (N = L (N (h be as above. Then, (4.7 hdµ (N = g (N dµ. In particular, by taing h 1, we conclude that µ (N is a probability measure. Also, since g (N converges pointwise to g, one may directly show (by Lebesgue s dominated convergence theorem that µ (N converges wealy to µ Probabilistic super-replication. We now introduce the super-replication problem by requiring that the inequalities in (4.6 hold ˆP (N -almost surely. Let G be a European claim as before and N be a positive integer. Then, the probabilistic super-replication problem is given by, { } ˆV N (G = inf hdµ (N : ˆγ s.t. (h,ˆγ is a ˆP (N admissible super hedge of G. Recall that in the probabilistic structure, admissibility and related notions are defined in Definition 4.6. We continue by establishing a connection between the probabilistic super hedging ˆV N and the discrete robust problem V N. Suppose that we are given a probabilistic semi-static portfolio ˆπ = (g,ˆγ in sense of Definition 4.6. We lift this portfolio to a semi-static portfolio π (N = (g (N,γ (N A N as defined in the subsection 2.5.

18 Martingale Optimal Transport 17 Indeed, let g (N be as in subsection 4.4 and let ˆγ t- be the left limit of the càdlàg function ˆγ at time t. We now define γ (N : C + [,T] D[,T] by n 1 γ (N t (S = =1 ˆγˆτ - ( F (N (S χ (τ,τ +1 ](t, where τ = τ (N (S is as in (2.6, n is as in (4.1 and F (N (S, ˆτ := ˆτ (S is as in (4.2. Notice that n, the number of jumps of S, is by construction exactly one more than the number of jumps of F (N. Also notice that γ (N t (S =, t [,τ 1 ]. Lemma 4.7. For any probabilistic semi-static portfolio (g,ˆγ, γ (N defined above is progressively measurable in the sense of (2.4. Proof. Let S, S C + [,T] be such that S u = S u for all u t for some t [,T]. We need to show that γ (N t (S = γ (N t ( S. Since the above clearly holds for t = and t = T, we may assume that t (,T. Set t (S := (N t (S := min{i 1,: τ (N i t } 1, so that t (S n and t (τ (N t(s,τ(n ]. t(s+1 It is clear that t (S = t ( S. If t (S = t ( S =, then γ (N t (S = γ (N t ( S =. We now assume that t (S > and use the definition of ˆτ to conclude that Hence, θ := ˆτ t(s = ˆτ t(s(s = ˆτ t( S ( S. γ (N t (S = ˆγ θ- (F (N (S, γ (N t ( S = ˆγ θ- (F (N ( S. Moreover, the definition of F (N implies that F (N u (S = F (N u ( S, u [,θ. Therefore, by the progressive measurability of ˆγ we have γ (N t (S = γ (N t ( S. The following lemma provides a natural and a crucial connection between the probabilistic super-replication and the discrete robust problem. Recall the set A N of portfolios used in the definition of V N in subsection 2.5. Lemma 4.8. Suppose G is bounded from above and satisfies the Assumption 2.1. Then, lim supv N (G limsup ˆV N (G. N N Proof. Set We first show that G (N (S := G(S 6L S N. V N (G (N ˆV N (G.

19 18 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner To prove the above inequality, suppose that a portfolio (h,ˆγ is a ˆP (N -admissible super hedge of G. Then, it suffices to construct a map γ (N : C + [,T] D[,T] such that the semi-static portfolio π (N := (g (N,γ (N is admisible, belongs to A N and super-replicates G (N in the sense of Definition 2.3. Letg (N beasinsubsection4.4andγ (N betheprobabilisticportfolioconsidered in Lemma 4.7. We claim that π (N is the desired portfolio. In view of Lemma 4.7, we need to show that π (N is in A N and super-replicates the G (N in the sense of Definition 2.3. To simplify the notation, we set F := F (N (S. Admissibility of γ (N. By construction trading is only at the random times τ s. Therefore, π (N A N provided that it satisfies the lower bound (2.5 for every t [,T]. Fix such a time point t [,T]. In view of (4.5, there exist M so that ˆγ u- (FdF u M, t [,T], F D (N. We claim that [,t] τ γ u (N (SdS u = ˆγ u- (FdF u M, [,ˆτ 1 ] for every n 1. Indeed, we use (4.3 and the definitions to compute that [,ˆτ 1 ] ˆγ u- (FdF u = = = 1 m=1 m=1 τ ˆγˆτm-(F ( 1 Fˆτm Fˆτm 1 = m=1 γ (N τ m+1 (F ( S τm+1 S τm = τ γ (N u (SdS u. τ 1 ˆγˆτm-(F ( S τm+1 S τm γ (N u (SdS u The last identity follows from the fact that γ (N is zero on the interval [,τ 1 ]. Now, for a given t [,T and S C + [,T], let n 1 be the largest integer so that τ t. Construct a function F D (N by, F [,ˆτ = F [,ˆτ, (i.e., Fu = F u, u [,ˆτ, and F u = 2Fˆτ 1 Fˆτ, u ˆτ. Note that the constructed function F depends on S and N, since both F and the stopping times τ depend on them. But we suppress these dependences. Since and since Fˆτ Fˆτ 1 = [ Fˆτ Fˆτ 1 ] = ±1/N, S t S τ 1/N, there exists λ [,1] (depending on t such that S t S τ = λ(fˆτ Fˆτ 1 +(1 λ( Fˆτ Fˆτ 1.

20 Martingale Optimal Transport 19 Since F and F agree on [,ˆτ, and ˆγ is progressively measurable ˆγ u (F = ˆγ u ( F for all u ˆτ. Therefore, t γ u (N (SdS u = λ ˆγ u- (FdF u +(1 λ ˆγ u- ( Fd F u. [,ˆτ ] [,ˆτ ] Also both F, F D (N, and ˆP(F,ˆP( F >. Using (4.5 we may conclude that ˆγ u- (FdF u M, and ˆγ u- ( Fd F u M. [,ˆτ ] Hence, π (N A N. Super-replication. We need to show that g (N (S T + T [,ˆτ ] γ (N u (SdS u G (N (S. We proceed almost exactly as in the proof of admissibility. Again we define a modification F D (N by F [,ˆτn 2 = F [,ˆτn 2 and F u = Fˆτn 2 for u ˆτ n 2. Set ˆλ := N S T S τn 1. Then ˆλ [,1] and by the construction of g (N, Hence, g (N (S T + = ˆλ T [ g (N (S T = ˆλh(F T +(1 ˆλh( F T. γ (N u (SdS u h(f T + T ˆλG(F+(1 ˆλG( F. ˆγ u- (FdF u ]+(1 ˆλ [ h( F T + Since F F 1/N, Assumption 2.1 and Lemma 4.4 imply that G(S G( F G(S G(F + G(F G( F 6L S N. Consequently, ˆλG(F+(1 ˆλG( F G (N (S and we conclude that π (N is super-replication G (N. Completion of the proof. We have shown that V N (G 6L S /N ˆV N (G. T ˆγ u- ( Fd F u ] Moreover, the linearity of the maret yields that super-replication cost is subadditive. Hence, Therefore, V N (G V N (6L S /N+V N (G 6L S /N. V N (G V N (6L S /N+ ˆV N (G.

21 2 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner Finally, by Lemma 4.1, lim sup V N (6L S /N =. N We use the above inequalities to complete the proof of the lemma First duality. Recall the countable set D (N ˆΩ and its probabilistic structure were introduced in subsection 4.3. We consider two classes of measures on this set. Definition We say that a probability measures Q on the space (ˆΩ, ˆF is a martingale measure, if the canonical process (Ŝt T t= is a local martingale with respect to Q. 2. M N is the set of all martingale measures that are supported on D (N. 3. For a given K >, M (K N is the set of all measures Q M N that satisfy (4.8 Q(ŜT = /N µ (N ({/N} < K N. = The following follows from nown duality results. We will combine it with 4.8 and Proposition 5.1, that will be proved in the next section to complete the proof of the inequality (2.8. Lemma 4.1. Suppose that G bounded from above by K and satisfies the Assumption 2.1. Then, for any positive integer N, [ ] ˆV N (G sup E Q G(Ŝ. Q M (K N Proof. Fix N and define the set Z = Z (N := {h : A (N R : h(x N, x}. Set ( V := inf sup E Q (G(Ŝ h(ŝt+ h Z Q M N Clearly, for any ǫ >, there exists h Z such that ( sup E Q G(Ŝ h(ŝt + Q M N hdµ (N. hdµ (N < V+ǫ. By construction, the support of the measure ˆP is ˆD (N. Also all elements of are piece-wise constant. Thus, ˆP almost surely, the canonical process Ŝ is trivially a semi-martingale. Hence, we may use the results of the (G(Ŝ h(s seminal paper [1]. In particular, by Theorem 5.7 in [1], for x > sup Q MN E Q T, there exists an admissible portfolio strategy ˆγ such that x+ T ˆγ u dŝu G(Ŝ h(ŝt, ˆP(N a.s. ˆD (N Thus, (h+x,ˆγ satisfies (4.5 (4.6, and ˆV N (G V+ǫ. We now let ǫ to zero to conclude that ( (4.9 ˆVN (G inf sup E Q (G(Ŝ h(ŝt+ hdµ (N. h Z Q M N

22 Martingale Optimal Transport 21 The next step is to interchange the order of the above infimum and supremum. Consider the vector space R A(N of all functions f : A (N R equiped with the topology of point-wise convergence. Clearly, this space is locally convex. Also, since A (N is countable, Z is a compact subset of R A(N. The set M N can be naturally considered as a convex subspace of the vector space R D(N. Now, define the function G : Z M N R, by G(h,Q = E Q (G(Ŝ h(ŝt + hdµ (N. Notice that G is affine in each of the variables. From the bounded convergence theorem, it follows that G is continuous in the first variable. Next, we apply the min-max theorem, Theorem 2, in [4] to G. The result is, This together with (4.9 yields, (4.1 ˆVN (G sup Q M N inf h Z inf sup G(h,Q = sup inf G(h,Q. h Z Q M N Q M N h Z ( E Q (G(Ŝ h(ŝt+ hdµ (N. Finally, for any measure Q M N, define h Q Z by ( h Q (/N = Nsign Q(ŜT = /N µ (N ({/N}, =,1,... In view of (4.1, ˆV N (G sup Q M N = sup Q M N (E Q (G(Ŝ+ { E Q (G(ˆB N h Q ndµ (N E Q h Q (ŜT } Q(ŜT = /N µ (N ({/N} = Suppose that Q M (K N. Then, N Q(ŜT = /N µ (N ({/N} K. = Since G is bounded by K, this implies that E Q (G(ˆB N Q(ŜT = /N µ (N ({/N}. = However, since G, we may assume that Q M (K N. Then, { } ˆV N (G E Q (G(ˆB N Q(ŜT = /N µ (N ({/N} sup Q M (K N sup E Q (G(Ŝ. Q M (K N =

23 22 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner 5. Approximation of Martingale Measures In this final section, we prove the asymptotic connection between the approximating martingale measures M (K N defined in Definition 4.9 and the continuous martingale measures M µ satisfying the marginal constraint at the final time, defined in Definition 2.4. The following proposition completes the proof of the inequality (2.8 and consequently the proofs of the main theorems when the claim G is bounded from above. The general case then follows from Lemma 4.2. Proposition 5.1. Suppose that G is bounded from above by K and satisfies the Assumption 2.1. Assume that µ satisfies (2.2-(2.3. Then, lim sup N sup Q M (K N E Q [ G(Ŝ ] sup P M µ E P [G(S]. We prove this result not through a compactness argument as one may expect. Instead, we show that any given measure Q M (K N has a lifted version in M µ that is close to Q in some sense. Indeed, the above proposition is a direct consequence of the below lemma. Recall the Lipschitz constant L in Assumption 2.1. Lemma 5.2. Under the hypothesis of Proposition 5.1, there exists a continuous function f K with f K ( =, so that for any Q M (K N and ǫ >, [ ] E Q G(Ŝ L N +f K(ǫ+ sup E P [G(S]. P M µ Proof. Fix ǫ (,1, a positive integer N and Q M (K N. Recall that G is bounded from above by K. Jump times. Since the probability measure Q is supported on the set D (N, the the canonical process Ŝ is a purely jump process under Q, with a finite number of jumps. Introduce the jump times by setting σ = and for >, σ = inf{t > σ 1 : Ŝt Ŝt-} T. Next we introduce the largest random time ˆN := min{ : σ = T}. Then, ˆN < almost surely and consequently, there exists deterministic positive integer m (depending on ǫ such that (5.1 Q( ˆN > m < ǫ. By the definition of the set D (N, there is a decreasing sequence of strictly positive numbers t, with t 1 = T, such that for i = 1,...,m, σ i σ i 1 {t } =1 {}, Q a.s. Wiener space. Let (Ω W,F W,P W be a complete { probability ( space together with } a standard m+2 dimensional Brownian motion W t = W (1, and the natural filtration F W t t,w (2 t,...,w (m+2 t = σ{w s s t}. The next step is to construct a t=

24 Martingale Optimal Transport 23 martingale Z on the Brownian probability space (Ω W,F W,P W together with a sequence of stopping times (with respect to the Brownian filtration τ 1 τ 2... τ m such that the distribution (under the Wiener measure P W of the random vector (τ 1,...,τ m,z τ1,...,z τm is equal to the distribution of the random vector (σ 1,...,σ m,ŝσ 1,...,Ŝσ m under the measure Q. Namely, ( (5.2 (τ1,...,τ m,z τ1,...,z τm,p W ( = (σ 1,...,σ m,ŝσ 1,...,Ŝσ m,q. The construction is done by induction, at each step we construct the stopping time τ and Z τ such that the conditional probability is the same as in the case of the canonical process Ŝ under the measure Q. Construction of τ s and Z. For an integer n and given x 1,...,x n, introduce the notation x n := (x 1,...,x n. Also set T := {t } =1. For = 1,...,m, define the functions Ψ,Φ : T { 1,1} 1 [,1] by (5.3 Ψ ( α ; β 1 := Q ( σ σ 1 α A, where and A := (5.4 Φ ( α ; β 1 = Q where B = { } σ i σ i 1 = α i, Ŝσ i Ŝσ i 1 = β i /N, i 1, (Ŝσ Ŝσ 1 = 1/N B, { } σ < T,σ j σ j 1 = α j, Ŝσ i Ŝσ i 1 = β i /N, j,i 1. As usual we set Q(. Next, for m, we define the maps Γ,Θ : T { 1,1} 1 [, ], as the unique solutions of the following equations, ( (5.5 P W W α (1 < Γ ( α ; β 1 = Φ ( α ; β 1, and ( (5.6 P W W (1 t l W (1 t l+1 < Θ ( α ; β 1 = Ψ ( α 1,t l ; β 1 Ψ ( α 1,t l+1 ; β 1, where l N is given by α = t l T. From the definitions it follows that Ψ ( α 1,t l ; β 1 Ψ ( α 1,t l+1 ; β 1. Thus if Ψ ( α 1,t l+1 ; β 1 = for some l, then also Ψ ( α 1,t l ; β 1 =. We set /. Set τ and define the random variables τ 1,...,τ m,y 1,...,Y m by the following recursive relations (5.7 τ 1 = =1 t χ {W (1 t W (1 t +1 >Θ 1(t } Y 1 = 2χ {W (2 {τ 1 >Γ 1(τ 1}} 1, j=+1 χ {W (1 t j W (1 t j+1 <Θ 1(t j},

25 24 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner and for i > 1 τ i Y i = τ i 1 + i ( = χ {τi<t} 2χ (i+1 {W τ i W τ (i+1 i 1 >Γ i( τ i, Y 1 i 1}, where i = t on the set A i B i, C i, and zero otherwise. These sets are given by, A i := { Y i 1 > }, B i, := {W (1 t +τ i 1 W (1 t +1 +τ i 1 > Θ i ( τ i 1,t ; Y i 1 }, C i, := {W (1 t j+τ i 1 W (1 t j+1+τ i 1 < Θ i ( τ i 1,t j ; Y i 1 }. j=+1 Since t is decreasing with t 1 = T, τ 1 τ 2... τ m and they are stopping times with respect to the Brownian filtration. Let m and ( α ; β 1 T { 1,1} 1. There exists m N such that α = t m T. From (5.7 (5.8, the strong Marov property and the independency of the Brownian motion increments it follows that (5.8 P W (τ τ 1 α ( τ 1 ; Y 1 = ( α 1 ; β 1 ( ( = P W W (1 t j+τ 1 W (1 t j+1+τ 1 < Θ ( α 1,t j ; β 1 = j=m j=m ( P W W (1 t j+τ 1 W (1 t j+1+τ 1 < Θ ( α 1,t j ; Y 1 = Ψ ( α, β 1, where the last equality follows from (5.6 and the fact that Similarly, from (5.5 and (5.8, we have (5.9 lim Ψ (α 1,...,α 1,t l,β 1,...,β 1 = 1. l ( P W Y = 1 τ < T, τ = α, Y 1 = β 1 ( = P W W (+1 W (+1 1 < Γ ( α ; β 1 i=1 αi i=1 αi = Φ ( α ; β 1. Using (5.3 (5.4 and (5.8 (5.9, we conclude that (( τ m ; 1N Y ( m,p W = ( σ m ; Ŝm,Q where Ŝ = Ŝσ Ŝσ 1, m. Continuous martingale. Set (5.1 Z t = 1 m N EW ( Y i Ft W, t [,T]. i=1

26 Martingale Optimal Transport 25 Since all Brownian martingales are continuous, so is Z. Moreover, Brownian motion increments are independent and therefore, (5.11 Z τ = 1 Y i, P W a.s., m. N i=1 By the construction of Y and τ s, we conclude that (5.2 holds with the process Z. Measure in M µ. The next step in the proof is to modify the martingale Z in such way that the distribution of the modified martingale is an element of M µ. For any two probability measures ν 1,ν 2 on R the Prohorov s metric is defined by d(ν 1,ν 2 = inf{δ > : ν 1 (A ν 2 (A δ +δ and ν 2 (A ν 1 (A δ +δ, A B(R}, where B(R is the set of all Borel sets A R and A δ := x A (x δ,x+δ is the δ neighborhood of A. It is well nown that convergence in the Prohorov metric is equivalent to wea convergence, (for more details on the Prohorov s metric see [19], Chapter 3, Section 7. Let ν 1 and ν 2, be the distributions of Ŝσ m and ŜT respectively, under the measure Q. In view of (5.1, d(ν 1,ν 2 < ǫ. Moreover, (4.8 implies that d(ν 2,µ (N < K N and µ (N converges to µ wealy. Hence, the preceding inequalities, together with this convergence yield that for all sufficiently large N, d(ν 1,µ < 2ǫ. Finally, we observe that in view of (5.2, (Z T,P W = ν 1. We now use Theorem 4 on page 358 in [19] and Theorem 1 in [2] to construct a measurable function ψ : R 2 R such that the random variable Λ := ψ(z T,W (m+2 T satisfies (5.12 (Λ,P W = µ and P W ( Λ Z T > 2ǫ < 2ǫ. We define a martingale by, Γ t = E W (Λ F W t, t [,T]. In view of (5.12, the distribution of the martingale Γ is an element in M µ. Hence, (5.13 sup P M µ E P [G(S] E W (G(Γ. We continue with the estimate that connects the distribution of Γ to Q M (K N. Observe that E W Λ = E W Z T = 1. This together with (5.12, positivity of Z and Λ, and the Holder inequality yields (5.14 E W Λ Z T = 2E W (Λ Z T + E W (Λ Z T = 2E W (Λ Z T + where p > 1 is as (2.3 and q = p/(p 1. 4ǫ+2E W (Λχ { Λ ZT >2ǫ} 4ǫ+2( x p dµ(x 1/p (2ǫ 1/q, We now introduce a stochastic process (Ẑt T t=, on the Brownian probability space, by, Ẑ t = Z τ for t [τ,τ +1, < m and for t [τ m,t], we set Ẑt = Z τm. On the space (ˆΩ, ˆF,{ ˆF t } T t=,ˆp (N let S t = Ŝt σ m, t [,T]. Recall that G is

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Model-independent bounds for Asian options Model-independent bounds for Asian options A dynamic programming approach Alexander M. G. Cox 1 Sigrid Källblad 2 1 University of Bath 2 CMAP, École Polytechnique University of Michigan, 2nd December,

More information

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models Alexander Cox 1 Jiajie Wang 2 1 University of Bath 2 Università di Roma La Sapienza Advances in Financial Mathematics, 9th January,

More information

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Model-independent bounds for Asian options Model-independent bounds for Asian options A dynamic programming approach Alexander M. G. Cox 1 Sigrid Källblad 2 1 University of Bath 2 CMAP, École Polytechnique 7th General AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Matteo Burzoni Marco Frittelli Marco Maggis June 30, 2015 Abstract In a model independent discrete time financial

More information

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund Alexander M. G. Cox Sam M. Kinsley University of Bath Recent Advances in Financial Mathematics, Paris, 10th January, 2017 A. M. G. Cox, S.

More information

Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Finance

Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Finance Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Finance Marcel Nutz Columbia University (with Mathias Beiglböck and Nizar Touzi) April 2015 Marcel Nutz (Columbia) Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Finance

More information

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences H. Mete Soner ETH Zürich and Swiss Finance Institute Joint with Matteo Burzoni, ETH Zürich Frank Riedel, University of Bielefeld Thera Stochastics in Honor of Ioannis

More information

Robust hedging with tradable options under price impact

Robust hedging with tradable options under price impact - Robust hedging with tradable options under price impact Arash Fahim, Florida State University joint work with Y-J Huang, DCU, Dublin March 2016, ECFM, WPI practice is not robust - Pricing under a selected

More information

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES D. S. SILVESTROV, H. JÖNSSON, AND F. STENBERG Abstract. A general price process represented by a two-component

More information

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims Beatrice Acciaio Gregor Svindland December 2011 Abstract We prove that in a discrete-time market model the lower arbitrage bound of an American

More information

Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and Peacocks

Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and Peacocks Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and CEREMADE, Université Paris Dauphine Collaboration with Pierre Henry-Labordère, Nizar Touzi 08 July, 2014 Second young researchers meeting on BSDEs, Numerics

More information

Model Free Hedging. David Hobson. Bachelier World Congress Brussels, June University of Warwick

Model Free Hedging. David Hobson. Bachelier World Congress Brussels, June University of Warwick Model Free Hedging David Hobson University of Warwick www.warwick.ac.uk/go/dhobson Bachelier World Congress Brussels, June 2014 Overview The classical model-based approach Robust or model-independent pricing

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile? How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile? A Summary of Arbitrage Restrictions and Smile Asymptotics Vimal Raval Imperial College London & UBS Investment Bank www2.imperial.ac.uk/ vr402 Joint Work with Mark

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

Weak Reflection Principle and Static Hedging of Barrier Options

Weak Reflection Principle and Static Hedging of Barrier Options Weak Reflection Principle and Static Hedging of Barrier Options Sergey Nadtochiy Department of Mathematics University of Michigan Apr 2013 Fields Quantitative Finance Seminar Fields Institute, Toronto

More information

Non replication of options

Non replication of options Non replication of options Christos Kountzakis, Ioannis A Polyrakis and Foivos Xanthos June 30, 2008 Abstract In this paper we study the scarcity of replication of options in the two period model of financial

More information

Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Hedging

Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Hedging Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Hedging Ecole Polytechnique, Paris Angers, September 3, 2015 Outline Optimal Transport and Model-free hedging The Monge-Kantorovitch optimal transport problem Financial

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Department of Banking and Finance University of Zurich April 22 2013 Math Finance Colloquium USC Change of the probability measure Change of

More information

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models Beatrice Acciaio the London School of Economics and Political Science (based on a joint work with C. Fontana and

More information

Optimal martingale transport in general dimensions

Optimal martingale transport in general dimensions Optimal martingale transport in general dimensions Young-Heon Kim University of British Columbia Based on joint work with Nassif Ghoussoub (UBC) and Tongseok Lim (Oxford) May 1, 2017 Optimal Transport

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance Alexander Cox Jiajie Wang University of Bath Bachelier 21, Toronto Financial Setting Option priced on an underlying asset S t Dynamics of S t unspecified,

More information

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics The Third Western Conference in Mathematical Finance November 14, 2009 How should an investor trade

More information

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure Yuri Kabanov 1,2 1 Laboratoire de Mathématiques, Université de Franche-Comté, 16 Route de Gray, 253 Besançon,

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies George Tauchen Duke University Viktor Todorov Northwestern University 2013 Motivation

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

On robust pricing and hedging and the resulting notions of weak arbitrage

On robust pricing and hedging and the resulting notions of weak arbitrage On robust pricing and hedging and the resulting notions of weak arbitrage Jan Ob lój University of Oxford obloj@maths.ox.ac.uk based on joint works with Alexander Cox (University of Bath) 5 th Oxford Princeton

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

Pathwise Finance: Arbitrage and Pricing-Hedging Duality

Pathwise Finance: Arbitrage and Pricing-Hedging Duality Pathwise Finance: Arbitrage and Pricing-Hedging Duality Marco Frittelli Milano University Based on joint works with Matteo Burzoni, Z. Hou, Marco Maggis and J. Obloj CFMAR 10th Anniversary Conference,

More information

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

Mathematical Finance in discrete time Lecture Notes for Mathematical Finance in discrete time University of Vienna, Faculty of Mathematics, Fall 2015/16 Christa Cuchiero University of Vienna christa.cuchiero@univie.ac.at Draft Version June

More information

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS MATHEMATICAL TRIPOS Part III Friday, 27 May, 2016 1:30 pm to 4:30 pm PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS Attempt no more than FOUR questions. There are SIX questions in total. The questions carry equal

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Bernard Bercu Bordeaux University, France IFCAM Summer School Bangalore, India, July 2015 Bernard Bercu Asymptotic results for discrete

More information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information Exponential utility maximization under partial information Marina Santacroce Politecnico di Torino Joint work with M. Mania AMaMeF 5-1 May, 28 Pitesti, May 1th, 28 Outline Expected utility maximization

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. 3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. Orientation. In the examples studied in Chapter 1, we worked with a single period model and Gaussian returns; in this Chapter, we shall drop these assumptions

More information

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that. 1. EXERCISES RMSC 45 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk Exercises 1 Exercises 1. (a) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-martingale. Show that E(X n ) = E(X ) n N (b) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-submartingale.

More information

No-Arbitrage Bounds on Two One-Touch Options

No-Arbitrage Bounds on Two One-Touch Options No-Arbitrage Bounds on Two One-Touch Options Yukihiro Tsuzuki March 30, 04 Abstract This paper investigates the pricing bounds of two one-touch options with the same maturity but different barrier levels,

More information

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes Math 6810 (Probability) Fall 2012 Lecture notes Pieter Allaart University of North Texas April 16, 2013 2 Text: Introduction to Stochastic Calculus with Applications, by Fima C. Klebaner (3rd edition),

More information

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model MATHEMATICAL COMMUNICATIONS 231 Math. Commun. 18(2013, 231 239 The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model Tatjana Slijepčević-Manger 1, 1 Faculty of Civil Engineering, University

More information

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis 1/18 : estimation and model analysis, EDHEC Business School (joint work with Rama COT) Modeling and managing financial risks Paris, 10 13 January 2011 2/18 Outline 1 2 of multi-asset models Solution to

More information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B 166 Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information by Hans Föllmer ) Martin Schweizer ) October 199 ) Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft,

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 6, 2012, no. 112, 5597-5602 Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities Nasir Rehman Department of Mathematics and Statistics

More information

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) 6: Multi-Period Market Models 1 / 55 Outline We will examine

More information

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs. Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs Andrea Cosso LPMA, Université Paris Diderot joint work with Francesco Russo ENSTA,

More information

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Xiaoguang Wang STAT 598W January 21th, 2014 (STAT 598W) Lecture 3 1 / 51 Outline 1 Some model independent definitions and principals

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand Alfredo Garcia and Robert L. Smith Department of Industrial and Operations Engineering Universityof Michigan, Ann Arbor MI 48109 December

More information

The Uncertain Volatility Model

The Uncertain Volatility Model The Uncertain Volatility Model Claude Martini, Antoine Jacquier July 14, 008 1 Black-Scholes and realised volatility What happens when a trader uses the Black-Scholes (BS in the sequel) formula to sell

More information

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance - - Introduction to Mathematical Finance - Lecture Notes by Ulrich Horst The objective of this course is to give an introduction to the probabilistic techniques required to understand the most widely used

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Robust Trading of Implied Skew

Robust Trading of Implied Skew Robust Trading of Implied Skew Sergey Nadtochiy and Jan Obłój Current version: Nov 16, 2016 Abstract In this paper, we present a method for constructing a (static) portfolio of co-maturing European options

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES from BMO martingales MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES CNRS - CMAP Ecole Polytechnique March 1, 2007 1/ 45 OUTLINE from BMO martingales 1 INTRODUCTION 2 DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES Time Consistency

More information

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia Marco Frittelli Università degli Studi di Firenze Winter School on Mathematical Finance January 24, 2005 Lunteren. On Utility Maximization in Incomplete Markets. based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH

INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH HAMPUS ENGSNER, MATHIAS LINDHOLM, AND FILIP LINDSKOG Abstract. We present an approach to market-consistent multi-period valuation

More information

Citation: Dokuchaev, Nikolai Optimal gradual liquidation of equity from a risky asset. Applied Economic Letters. 17 (13): pp

Citation: Dokuchaev, Nikolai Optimal gradual liquidation of equity from a risky asset. Applied Economic Letters. 17 (13): pp Citation: Dokuchaev, Nikolai. 21. Optimal gradual liquidation of equity from a risky asset. Applied Economic Letters. 17 (13): pp. 135-138. Additional Information: If you wish to contact a Curtin researcher

More information

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time 4 Martingales in Discrete-Time Suppose that (Ω, F, P is a probability space. Definition 4.1. A sequence F = {F n, n = 0, 1,...} is called a filtration if each F n is a sub-σ-algebra of F, and F n F n+1

More information

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach Giulia Di Nunno Third AMaMeF Conference: Advances in Mathematical Finance Pitesti, May 5-1 28 based on a work in progress with

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

Hedging under arbitrage

Hedging under arbitrage Hedging under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics AnStAp10 August 12, 2010 Motivation Usually, there are several trading strategies at one s disposal to obtain a given

More information

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices Dmitry Kramkov (joint work with Peter Bank) Carnegie Mellon University and University of Oxford 5th Oxford-Princeton Workshop on Financial

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014 MERTON PORTFOLIO PROBLEM WITH ONE INDIVISIBLE ASSET JAKUB TRYBU LA arxiv:143.3223v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 214 Abstract. In this paper we consider a modification of the classical Merton portfolio optimization

More information

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models José E. Figueroa-López 1 1 Department of Statistics Purdue University University of Missouri-Kansas City Department of Mathematics

More information

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility Nasir Rehman Allam Iqbal Open University Islamabad, Pakistan. Outline Mathematical

More information

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval A. N. Shiryaev M. V. Zhitlukhin arxiv:1212.379v1 [math.st] 15 Dec 212 December 18, 212 Abstract We consider optimal

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Optimal Production-Inventory Policy under Energy Buy-Back Program

Optimal Production-Inventory Policy under Energy Buy-Back Program The inth International Symposium on Operations Research and Its Applications (ISORA 10) Chengdu-Jiuzhaigou, China, August 19 23, 2010 Copyright 2010 ORSC & APORC, pp. 526 532 Optimal Production-Inventory

More information

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance Bernardo D Auria email: bernardo.dauria@uc3m.es web: www.est.uc3m.es/bdauria July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M The Financial Market The Financial Market We assume there are

More information

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon basso@unive.it, mnardon@unive.it Department of Applied Mathematics University Ca Foscari Venice Brownian motion p. 1 Brownian motion Brownian motion plays

More information

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods Finite difference and finite element methods Lecture 4 Outline Black-Scholes equation From expectation to PDE Goal: compute the value of European option with payoff g which is the conditional expectation

More information

A MODEL-FREE VERSION OF THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ASSET PRICING AND THE SUPER-REPLICATION THEOREM. 1. Introduction

A MODEL-FREE VERSION OF THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ASSET PRICING AND THE SUPER-REPLICATION THEOREM. 1. Introduction A MODEL-FREE VERSION OF THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ASSET PRICING AND THE SUPER-REPLICATION THEOREM B. ACCIAIO, M. BEIGLBÖCK, F. PENKNER, AND W. SCHACHERMAYER Abstract. We propose a Fundamental Theorem

More information

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View An Introduction to Point Processes from a Martingale Point of View Tomas Björk KTH, 211 Preliminary, incomplete, and probably with lots of typos 2 Contents I The Mathematics of Counting Processes 5 1 Counting

More information

A Robust Option Pricing Problem

A Robust Option Pricing Problem IMA 2003 Workshop, March 12-19, 2003 A Robust Option Pricing Problem Laurent El Ghaoui Department of EECS, UC Berkeley 3 Robust optimization standard form: min x sup u U f 0 (x, u) : u U, f i (x, u) 0,

More information

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5. MATH136/STAT219 Lecture 21, November 12, 2008 p. 1/11 Last Time Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.3 MATH136/STAT219

More information

Markets with convex transaction costs

Markets with convex transaction costs 1 Markets with convex transaction costs Irina Penner Humboldt University of Berlin Email: penner@math.hu-berlin.de Joint work with Teemu Pennanen Helsinki University of Technology Special Semester on Stochastics

More information

INTERIM CORRELATED RATIONALIZABILITY IN INFINITE GAMES

INTERIM CORRELATED RATIONALIZABILITY IN INFINITE GAMES INTERIM CORRELATED RATIONALIZABILITY IN INFINITE GAMES JONATHAN WEINSTEIN AND MUHAMET YILDIZ A. We show that, under the usual continuity and compactness assumptions, interim correlated rationalizability

More information

Arbitrage Bounds for Weighted Variance Swap Prices

Arbitrage Bounds for Weighted Variance Swap Prices Arbitrage Bounds for Weighted Variance Swap Prices Mark Davis Imperial College London Jan Ob lój University of Oxford and Vimal Raval Imperial College London January 13, 21 Abstract Consider a frictionless

More information

VALUATION OF FLEXIBLE INSURANCE CONTRACTS

VALUATION OF FLEXIBLE INSURANCE CONTRACTS Teor Imov r.tamatem.statist. Theor. Probability and Math. Statist. Vip. 73, 005 No. 73, 006, Pages 109 115 S 0094-90000700685-0 Article electronically published on January 17, 007 UDC 519.1 VALUATION OF

More information

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

Kim Weston (Carnegie Mellon University) Market Stability and Indifference Prices. 1st Eastern Conference on Mathematical Finance.

Kim Weston (Carnegie Mellon University) Market Stability and Indifference Prices. 1st Eastern Conference on Mathematical Finance. 1st Eastern Conference on Mathematical Finance March 216 Based on Stability of Utility Maximization in Nonequivalent Markets, Finance & Stochastics (216) Basic Problem Consider a financial market consisting

More information

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension Mathematical Statistics Stockholm University Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension Kristoffer Lindensjö Research Report 216:21 ISSN 165-377

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 23 Dec 2010

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 23 Dec 2010 ASYMPTOTIC PROPERTIES OF OPTIMAL TRAJECTORIES IN DYNAMIC PROGRAMMING SYLVAIN SORIN, XAVIER VENEL, GUILLAUME VIGERAL Abstract. We show in a dynamic programming framework that uniform convergence of the

More information

ROBUST STATIC HEDGING OF BARRIER OPTIONS IN STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODELS

ROBUST STATIC HEDGING OF BARRIER OPTIONS IN STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODELS ROBUST STATIC HEDGING OF BARRIER OPTIONS IN STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODELS J. H. MARUHN AND E. W. SACHS Abstract. Static hedge portfolios for barrier options are extremely sensitive with respect to changes

More information

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications Albert Cohen Actuarial Science Program Department of Mathematics Department of Statistics and Probability albert@math.msu.edu August 29, 2018 Outline

More information

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance Stochastic Finance C. Azizieh VUB C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance 1/91 Agenda of the course Stochastic calculus : introduction Black-Scholes model Interest rates models C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

More information

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies Jan Večeř, Columbia University, Department of Statistics, Mingxin Xu, Carnegie Mellon University, Department of Mathematical Sciences, Olympia

More information

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation 3.1 Itô Integral 3.1.1 Convergence in the Mean and Stieltjes Integral Definition 3.1 (Convergence in the Mean) A sequence {X n } n ln of random

More information

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Jan Obłój j.obloj@imperial.ac.uk based on joint works with L. Carraro, N. El Karoui, A. Meziou and M. Yor Welsh Probability Seminar, 17 Jan 28 Are the Azéma-Yor

More information

Path-properties of the tree-valued Fleming-Viot process

Path-properties of the tree-valued Fleming-Viot process Path-properties of the tree-valued Fleming-Viot process Peter Pfaffelhuber Joint work with Andrej Depperschmidt and Andreas Greven Luminy, 492012 The Moran model time t As every population model, the Moran

More information