The stylized Kaldor facts are named after Nicholas Kaldor who uncovered them in 1957:

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The stylized Kaldor facts are named after Nicholas Kaldor who uncovered them in 1957:"

Transcription

1 Chapter V Growth Professor Thomas Chaney 1 Basic stylized facts of growth The Kaldor facts The stylized Kaldor facts are named after Nicholas Kaldor who uncovered them in 1957: 1. Labor productivity has grown at a sustained rate. 2. Capital per worker has also grown at a sustained rate. 3. The real interest rate, or return on capital, has been stable. 4. The ratio of capital to output has also been stable. 5. Capital and Labor have captured stable shares of national income. 6. Among the fast growing countries of the world, there is an appreciable variation in the rate of growth of the order of 2-5 percent. Fact 1 was meant to reject both what is called the classical growth theory (such as Malthus) and the Marxist growth theory, where the world converges to a steady state with zero growth. Fact 2 suggests that capital accumulation is part of the story, as in Marxist theories. However, facts 3-5 reject the marxist theory of growth, where the collusive behavior of capitalists (capital owners) generates a gradual reduction of the share of labor (until the revolution hits, at which points things are really not very clear in Marx s work). 61

2 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 62 The Solow neoclassical growth model Bob Solow offered in 1956 a neoclassical growth model, that can adequately deal with facts 3-5. By introducing exogenous technological progress, he can also explain facts 1 and 2. Solow recognizes therefore the central role of technological progress in generating sustained growth. However, he also points out very explicitly that in a competitive equilibrium and within a neoclassical framework, there is no money left on the table to reward innovators. So there is no explanation for endogenous technological progress. This is a very important insight. Consider a production function that combines capital, K, and labor, L, ( workers and machines ) to produce some final output, Y, and assume that this production function is characterized by constant returns to scale, Y = F (L, K) s.t. 8 >0, F( L, K) = F (L, K) Now, take the derivative of the constant returns to scale condition with respect to, F (L, In a competitive equilibrium, factors are paid their marginal product. The reason is simple: if say wages are below the marginal product of labor (the contribution of one additional worker to output), then a competitive firm should hire at least one more worker (the extra output [benefit] exceeds the extra cost); conversely, if the wage is above the marginal product of labor, then a competitive firm should fire at least one worker (the benefit from paying fewer workers exceeds the cost of producing a bit less). That implies that, F (L, K) =wl + rk where w is the wage rate and r the cost of capital. In other words, the value of output (F (L, K)) is just enough to pay workers (wl) and machines (rk). There is no money left on the table. In particular, there is no money left to reward innovators. But Solow also shows us that capital accumulation alone (building more machines) can generate growth only for a while. Eventually, the only way to grow is to innovate (build better machines). He therefore points that ultimately, growth must be driven by technological progress. But at the same time, he shows that within a purely competitive equilibrium, the market cannot provide private incentives for innovations. There are two solutions to this puzzle: either innovation is not motivated by private incentives (this is to a large extent the case for fundamental research); or

3 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 63 we do not live in a perfectly competitive world, so that innovators can extract some rents and be rewarded for their effort in generating innovations. Both seem to be true, but the second one is much harder to model rigorously: as one moves away from the assumption of a perfectly competitive world, many of the elegant results of economic theory disappear, and things become very messy. Paul Romer is one of the first to address this question headfirst. He shows how a monopolistic market, i.e. a market with monopoly power but also with very many competitors so that each is in some sense atomistic, can give private incentives to innovate. This work builds on the technical innovations of Joe Stiglitz and Avinash Dixit that devised a simple way to formally treat such a case of monopolistic competition. This was the advent of what became known as endogenous growth theories, in the sense that those theories had an explicit story for where innovations come from, and why they are made (instead of simply assuming that they happen ). The new Kaldor facts Chad Jones and Paul Romer list a series of 6 new stylized facts about growth as of In a sense, they are all related to Kaldor s fact number 6, which remains largely unexplained even after 50 years of research on growth. Here are the new facts: 1. Increases in the extent of the market. Increased flows of goods, ideas, finance and people - via globalization, as well as urbanization - have increased the extent of the market for all workers and consumers. 2. Accelerating growth. For thousands of years, growth in both population and per capita GDP has accelerated, rising from virtually zero to the relatively rapid rates observed in the last century. 3. Variation in modern growth rates. The variation in the rate of growth of per capita GDP increases with the distance from the technology frontier. 4. Large income and total factor productivity (TFP) differences. Differences in measured inputs explain less than half of the enormous cross-country differences in per capita GDP. 5. Increase in human capital per worker. Human capital per worker is rising dramatically throughout the world.

4 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 64 cr C..I 90.01_ ~~~ Population (Billions) Figure V.1: Population growth versus population 6. Long-run stability of relative wages. The rising quantity of human capital, relative to unskilled labor, has not been matched by a sustained decline in its relative price. 2 A simple model of (semi) endogenous growth: Kremer 1991 Michael Kremer offers an elegant model to explain a series of stylized facts about growth in the very long run (over many thousands of years). He offers both empirical evidence, as well as a theoretical explanation, for fact 2 of Jones and Romer. His model is one of endogenous technological progress, in the sense that the flow of ideas generated depends on several variables that are evolving over time, and in turn influences those variables. It is however not a model of a market economy, so Kremer does not try and explain how the private incentives to innovate may be shaped by market forces. Since he is interested in growth over the very long run, not assuming a market economy is probably a wise choice: in prehistorical times, or even in pre-homo sapiens time, markets were not very developed (even though this is more of a conjecture than a fact). The main empirical fact he wants to explain is that the human population, at least over the first 1 Million years (from 1 Million B.C. to 1940), increased at a rate roughly proportional to the size of the population. That corresponds to a growth that is substantially faster than exponential growth, which would correspond to a constant growth rate. In other words, population growth accelerated continuously until the mid-20th century.

5 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 65 Population as a measure of world GDP. Kremer focuses on the size of the human population, and not on the size of the world income, for two reasons. The first is driven by data availability: going back far into the past, while archeologists have a relatively good idea of the size of the human population at a given point in time, they have very scant evidence (if at all) on the standard of living back then. The second and more fundamental reason is a Malthusian type argument: for most of history, almost all humans were barely surviving. That is, the standards of living were just enough for humans to survive and for women to bear children. Direct evidence on actual data on the standards of living (we can do that with historical data going back all the way to Antiquity) suggests that this is indeed the case. We also have indirect evidence from the study of health of early humans that they did not have a very comfortable life. But we don t know exactly how uncomfortable. We know that they produced enough to survive (as did people until the 18th Century), but not much more. If it is indeed the case that until very late (18th, 19th or even mid-20th Century), the vast majority of humans were simply earning a subsistence wage (call it ȳ), then the total human GDP was simply P ȳ, this subsistence wage (ȳ) multiplied by the number of humans (P ). Aslongasȳ is constant, aggregate GDP growth is simply equal to population growth. A simple model of accelerating population growth. Kremer builds a very simple model of economic growth. It is based on three simple assumptions. First, he assumes the existence of an aggregate production function, which satisfies some simple properties. Second, he assumes a Malthusian type of force. Third, he assumes that humans come up with new ideas, at least some times. Writing down these three assumptions formally as three equations, one gets a very stylized representation of a growing world economy. 1. Aggregate production function. The first ingredient of this model is to have a production function. A production function defines how much output of a particular good can be produced for any combination of inputs. For instance, for a firm where workers combines iron ore and coal in order to produce steel, the production function would be a mathematical function of 3 variables. This function tells us, for a given of workers, that are combining a given number of tons of iron ore and of tons of coal (inputs = what goes in), how many tons of steel can be produced (output = what comes out). Note that we are only defining the best possible way for that particular firm to combine inputs into output. While you can always do worse (throw away some steel for instance), the production function tells

6 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 66 us the maximum amount of output that can be produced for a given combination of inputs. In the same way as one can define a production function for an individual firm, one can do so for an entire country. The concept of an aggregate production function is somewhat harder to grasp. Consider for instance a simplified view of the economy, where there is a single output (call it units of GDP, number of real euros, instead of the sum of all cars, pants, apples, oranges... etc produced in a country), and only two inputs, labor and land. This production function tells us, for a country with that many million of workers, and that many thousands of km 2,howlargeis the GDP. It s a summary of everything that is happening inside the country. Let s turn to Michael Kremer s model now. He assumes that there is one type of output (that could be number of calories of food produced, as for most of mankind s history, that was the main consumption), called Y. It is produced by combining workers (measured by the size of the population, p), land (measured by T, which we shall assume is constant over time, and normalized to 1), and ideas (summarized by a number, A). We will assume the following simple production function, Y = AP T 1, with 0 < <1 (V.1) This type of production function, linear in logs (take the log of Y and check that it is a linear function of the log of P,thelogofT and the log of A) is called a Cobb-Douglas function, named after Charles Cobb and Paul Douglas. While this particular mathematical function is very specific, it is (i) very convenient [easy to manipulate], but also (ii) it describes the actual process of aggregate production in the data quite well. It has several important properties, that happen to hold approximately in the data. First, this function exhibits constant returns to scale with respect to land and labor. This means that if there are twice as many humans and twice as much land, output will be exactly twice as large. This seems like a natural assumption, given that if given new land and more humans, one can always replicate everything. Second, and this is a direct corollary of the CRS assumption above, this function exhibits decreasing returns to scale with respect to labor. This means that with the same amount of land, if one doubles up the number of humans, output will grow, but by less than a factor of two. A consequence of this property is that for a given level of technology A, output per capita (how much there is to eat for the average human) will be a decreasing function of the size of the

7 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 67 population, y Y P = A T < 0 In other words, if we have a given amount of land to harvest, the more we are, the less we will be able to eat per person, unless we find a smarter way to use this given amount of land. This assumption will naturally give rise to a Malthusian trap, as we will see below. Third, and also as a corollary to the CRS assumption above, this production function exhibits increasing returns to scale with respect to labor (P ), land(t ) and ideas (A). This means that if we double up the number of ideas, humans and land, we will more than double up total output. This assumption will naturally lead to a sustained economic growth, as we will see below. 2. Malthusian trap. The second ingredient of the model is to assume a link between how well off humans are, and how many babies they make. It is a very stylized representation of both some biological evidence (when a man and a woman are healthy, they are able to bear and raise children; when they are ill nourished, less so), and some behavioral evidence (men and women, when they can, tend to like having babies). Formally, this means that there is a subsistence level of income per capita, ȳ, such that above this threshold, population grows, and below, it shrinks. In other words, when humans are well fed and in good health (y >ȳ), there natural tendency to want to have babies means that couples have on average more than two viable kids over their lifetime, so that population grows; when humans are ill nourished or sick (y <ȳ), they tend to die young (before they can have kids), they tend to be less fertile, and their children are not very likely to survive, couples have less than two viable kids on average, and population shrinks. Formally, we have, 8 >< > 0 if y>ȳ P =0 if y =ȳ >: < 0 if y<ȳ where I use the physics convention For a variable that is a function of time, putting a dot over that variable means how much that variable grows (or shrinks) from one period to the next. This biological/behavioral assumption, combined with the assumption of decreasing returns to scale with respect to labor, implies that the size of the population will tend to be determined by this subsistence level ȳ, P = ȳ 1 1 A (V.2)

8 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 68 If population is strictly above this P, then because of decreasing returns, output per capita will be strictly below the subsistence level ȳ, and population will shrink back down towards P (remember, more humans means less to eat for each of us). If population is strictly below this P, then output per capita will be strictly above the subsistence level ȳ, and population will grow back up towards P. A population size exactly equal to P is the only stable state. We call that a Malthusian trap, following the work of Thomas Malthus. It s a trap in the sense that humans desire to have children, combined with the limitation of our capacity to produce, forces us to earn just a subsistence income. The above equation also shows that the only way to escape such a Malthusian trap is to have new ideas, meaning increase A. It does not strictly speaking allow us to escape the trap (we still only earn a subsistence income), but at least, it allows us as a specie to grow. This is the next and final ingredient of the model. 3. Building on the shoulders of giants The final ingredient of Kremer s model has to do with the process through which new ideas are generated. Kremer assumes simply that any human has some chance of coming up with a great idea. Such a great idea will allow all humans to produce more efficiently. Think for instance of the neolithic revolution, by which someone somewhere around Mesopotamia roughly 12,000 years ago figured out how to grow wheat. This technological innovation may have taken a little while to be adopted by every human on the planet, but eventually, it did. We will make two assumptions for the process through which ideas are generated. First, the average number of ideas per person per period is some constant number, g. There will of course be a tremendous amount of randomness in the process of coming up with ideas (most of us never get to have a single idea that benefits mankind in our whole life); but with a large enough population, the law of large number means that the total number of ideas will simply be proportional to the size of the human population. The second assumption is that new ideas are improvements above and beyond what we already know. In other words, the more ideas we already have, or equivalently, the more efficient we are at producing, the better the new ideas will be. We can now formally express the link between the size of the human population (P ) and how the stock of ideas (A) grows, Solving the model. A A = gp (V.3)

9 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 69 We now have all the ingredients we need to solve the model! We have three equations, (V.1), (V.2) and(v.3), with three unknowns, P, Y and A. Equation(V.1) tells us how ideas and workers together can produce food. Equation (V.2) tells us how the available amount of food in turn determines the size of the population. And Equation (V.3) tells us how new ideas are invented by people. This is a relatively simple dynamic system: humans and ideas give food (V.1), food allows us to make babies (V.2), and those babies will themselves have new ideas (V.3), so that the next generation will have more people and more ideas, and they will be able to produce more food (V.1), which in turn will allow them to have babies of their own... etc. While this simple story in words makes sense, having equations allows to characterize precisely how this system will evolve. That means solving this system of 3 equations with 3 unknowns. First a little bit of math: for a variable X t that is a function of time, we Ẋ X X t ln X In words, the derivative of the log of X with respect to time of that variable Ẋ ln X is equal to the growth rate. This result is very useful, and important to remember. We can now take the log of Equation (V.2), and then take the derivative with respect to time, and get, ln P =lnȳ ln A P P = 1 A 1 A Plugging this expression into Equation (V.3), we solve the model and get the main testable prediction that Kremer brings to the data, P P = g 1 P In words, the growth rate of the population is proportional to the size of the population. This is exactly what we see in the data, as shown on Figure V.1. At least, this is true for most of human history, i.e. until the mid-20 th century. One can also say that the model is not really rejected by what happens in the data after The model actually tells us that as long as mankind is stuck in a Malthusian trap, we should expect the relationship between population growth and the size of the population, which implies a faster than exponential growth rate of the population. It also implicitly tells us that if mankind escapes from this Malthusian trap (for instance, people decide to have fewer babies, even though

10 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 70 they could very well have more, as is the case in most countries in the world today), then we should not expect the same relation between population growth and population size. But of course, one then has to write another model, where mankind can escape from the Malthusian trap is was stuck in for one million years. This is the second part of the Kremer paper, which is technically harder, and which I will not go over. 3 A simple model of exogenous growth: Solow 1956 We now turn to a more conventional, and influential, model of economic growth, the neoclassical growth model developed by Bob Solow in Solow shows that capital accumulation alone cannot generate sustained growth in the long run, but it can explain the convergence of income between initially different countries. I will go over this model rather quickly. Solow with neither population growth and nor technological progress Set-up. We represent the aggregate production of a country at time t, i.e., it s GDP, as Y t. This output is produced by combining capital and labor according to the constant returns to scale production function, Y t = F (K t,l) To start, I assume that the population is fixed, L is constant over time. Every period, a constant fraction of the stock of capital is lost to depreciation. This depreciation rate is meant to capture both the attrition of time, as machines eventually break down, natural or man-made disasters that wipe out part of a country s capital as bombs and hurricanes destroy buildings and machines, but also the obsolescence of old machines (you guys probably never even heard of Windows 95). In addition, agents can invest into building new capital. To do so, they use part of their production to produce new machines. For simplicity, I abstract from the complex decision of how much of one s income to save, and assume instead that everyone saves a constant fraction s to build new/replace old machines. The law of motion for capital is therefore, K = sf (K, L) K (V.4) where K represents the change in the stock of capital from one year to the next, and where I omit time subscripts for concision. The first term represents investment into new machines, and the second term represents the loss of existing machines to depreciation.

11 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 71 Model in per capita terms. Ultimately, we care not so much about the total production of a country, but rather about how much each person in that country earns. I will therefore express all variables in per capita term. I denote all per capita variables with lower case letters: x X L. To express the model in per capita terms, I use the property of a constant returns to scale (homogeneous of degree one) function: F (K, L) =LF K L, 1 and introduce the notation f (k) =F (k, 1), where f (k) = Y L summarized by a very simply difference equation, represents GDP per capita. The Solow growth model can be k = sf (k) k (V.5) Steady state. If the function f (k) is increasing, convex, and sufficiently steep around zero, then this dynamic system converges to a steady state such that, sf (k )= k At the steady state level of capital per worker k, investment (sf (k )) is just enough to replace depreciated capital ( k ), and the economy neither grows nor shrinks from one period to the next ( k, y = 0). If the stock of capital per worker k is below k, then the economy grows towards its steady state ( k, y>0), if it is above, it shrinks ( k, y<0). This result comes from the assumption of decreasing returns with respect to capital in the aggregate, for which there is strong empirical evidence. The very first few machines are tremendously productive, and they easily overcome the (small) depreciation of existing machines. This is why starting from a small level of capital per worker; the economy grows at a fast pace. Once most workers are equipped with capital, additional investment only brings about little increase in production, which can barely replace the (large) depreciation of existing capital, if at all; the economy grows at a slow pace, or even shrinks. This result also shows that in the long run, and in a world of decreasing returns to scale with respect to capital, economic growth in the long run cannot come only from capital accumulation. For a little while, the accumulation of capital brings the economy closer to its steady state. But once the steady state is reached, growth stops. Solow with population growth but no technical progress I now introduce a constant (exogenous) population growth rate, n, L L = n

12 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 72 The model remains almost identical, except that population growth now has to be accounted for. First, I rewrite the increase in the stock of capital per workers as K L = k + kn.1 Plugging in Equation (V.4), I get the following law of motion for capital per worker (k) in the presence of population growth, k = sf (k) ( + n) k (V.6) This expression very much resembles the law of motion in the absence of population growth in Equation (V.6), except that the depreciation is augmented by the population growth n. The intuition for this result is simple. When population grows, new workers are born without capital. Their parents therefore have to share their existing capital with them, so that everything is as if population growth eats up the existing capital stock. Capital accumulation must not only replace depreciated machines, but also provide new machines for newborn workers. This system also reaches a steady state level of capital per worker k at which growth stops, sf (k )=( + n) k Once again, due to the assumption of decreasing returns with respect to capital, capital accumulation can generate growth for some time, but ultimately, output per worker stops growing. The economy as a whole does grow in the steady state, but only at the speed of population growth. The world becomes richer because there are more workers, but the income of each individual worker remains constant. The primary lesson from Solow s growth model is that ultimately, growth of income per capita cannot come from either capital accumulation, or from population growth. It must come from some other (mysterious) source... Solow does not offer any explicit answer as to where this mysterious source might lie, but he does give us several tools to analyze this mystery. That is why he got the Nobel prize after all. First, he tells us what the world would look like if such a mysterious source of growth does exist, and he tells us what this source should be (basically, technical progress). He also tells us how to measure such a dark and mysterious source of growth (growth accounting). Finally, he explains why capital accumulation in his simple model can explain why some countries that are K To derive this result, I first use the quotient rule (derivative of a ratio of functions) to get L t = (@K t /@t)l t K t (@L t /@t) L 2 t = (@K t/@t) L t K t (@L t /@t) L t L t. I then use the following approximation, the previous equation as k K k L.Withtheconstantpopulationgrowthrate, L L bit, I get the proposed K = k + kn. L L L = n, andrearranginga

13 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 73 initially poor do seem to catch up to richer countries (think of Germany or Japan after WWII). Let look at each of those contributions in turn. Solow with population growth and technical progress The easiest way to introduce technical progress is to assume that over time, workers become more and more efficient. In other words, what could be produced with 10 workers can now be produced with fewer. This corresponds to the notion of labor augmenting technological progress. Formerly, we introduce L and A, L = AL where A is a term that captures the level of advancement of labor productivity, and L measures the number of efficiency units of labor. IfA goes from 1 to 2, it means that the same number of workers can now produce what twice as many workers could. An increase in A corresponds to labor augmenting technological progress. I assume with Solow that for some mysterious reason, A grows at a constant rate g over time, A A = g This form of technical progress may corresponds to either learning by doing (over time, workers get better at performing the same task), technological innovations (workers learn about a more efficient way of performing the same task), better management practices (the same number of workers perform more tasks as they waste less of their time)... etc. We can now rewrite the basic Solow model to incorporate technical progress. Output is produced combining capital and effective workers, Y = F K, L The stock of effective workers grows at the constant rate L L = g + n.2 The model is exactly isomorphic to the Solow model with population growth but without technical progress, except 2 To derive this result, I use the following approximation, ln A +lnl, Igettheproposed X t/@t X t ln X Then, noting that ln L = L ln L ln ln A A + L L = g + n

14 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 74 that every variable has to be expressed in per effective unit of labor, instead of per worker. The law of motion for the stock of capital per unit of effective worker is given by, k = sf k ( + g + n) k (V.7) The stock of capital per effective worker converges towards a steady state k defined by the condition, sf k =( + g + n) k (V.8) But while k does converge to a steady state, output per worker keeps growing forever. So instead of getting stuck in a steady state, the economy converges to a steady state growth path. Along that path, all variables grow at the rate of technical progress g. To see this, note that along this path, we have y t = Yt L t = F(Kt, L t) L t = L k tf( k ) L t = A t f. Output per unit of effective worker, f k, is fixed, but A t grows at a constant (exogenous) rate g. Along the steady state growth path, we have, Y Y = g + n, y y = g and ỹ ỹ =0 We now turn to the question of measuring the various sources of economic growth in the data. Growth accounting and Solow residuals While Solow does not offer an explicit theory of what the ultimate source of technical progress is, he offers a simple way to quantify in the data the relative contributions of factor accumulation and technical progress to economic growth. It is easiest to understand his method growth growth accounting using a particular functional form for the production function F, namely the Cobb- Douglas production function, Y t = A t F (K t,l t )=A t K t L 1 t where is a parameter that governs the relative importance of capital versus labor in the production process, and A t is called total factor productivity (note that this A t is not the same as A t in the previous section). Taking the logarithm of this expression, differencing over 2 consecutive years, and using the approximation we can write, X t g X for the growth rate g X of a variable X, g Y = g A + g K +(1 ) g L Going to the data, it is easy to measure the growth rate of aggregate output (GDP growth), as well as the growth rate of the stock of capital, and the growth rate of the population. Putting

15 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 75 together data for many years (t) and many countries (c), we can use econometric techniques to estimate the following equation, g Y (c, t) =b g K (c, t)+ \ (1 )g L (c, t)+bu (c, t) The coefficients b and \ (1 ) are precisely estimated, they approximately sum up to 1, with b 1 3. The error term bu (c, t) is called the Solow residual. It is a measure of the contribution of technical progress to economic growth. More precisely, it is a measure of all the growth that cannot be explained either by capital accumulation or population growth. In that sense, this is not a test of the Solow growth model. Rather, under the assumption that the Solow model is true, it is a measure of the contribution of technical progress to economic growth. Convergence and conditional convergence in the Solow model One of the key early contributions of Solow is to show that while capital accumulation alone cannot sustain growth in the long run, it can explain why some countries (or regions within a country) that are initially poorer catch up to their richer neighbors. The simplest version of this prediction of the Solow model only receives very mild support from the data, and is blatantly rejected by the data in many cases. A more nuanced version of this prediction however finds strong support from the data. Combining Equations (V.7) for the law of motion of k, the stock of capital per unit of effective worker, and Equation (V.8) for the definition of the steady state level of k, we get,! k k =( + g + n) ỹ/ k 1 ỹ / k Because of decreasing returns with respect to capital, the ratio of output per unit of capital, (V.9) decreases with k. The above equation therefore implies that the lower the initial stock of capital of a country (the lower k), the faster it will grow. As a country catches up to its steady state level of output per unit of capital ỹ, growth slows down. In other words, countries that are k initially poorer will grow at a faster pace, and converge towards other wealthier countries. We should observe convergence in income per capita over time. A naive interpretation of this prediction from the Solow model is that the level of output per worker across countries should converge: initially poorer countries will grow at a faster pace than richer ones, closing the gap between them. If one looks at individual regions within a country, US States within the US for instance, there is strong evidence of convergence. In the case of US, ỹ k

16 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 76 the income gap between rich and poor States closes by about 2% per year, so that half the gap is eliminated in 35 years. There is equally strong evidence of convergence between European regions over the period , with the income gap also closing at about 2% per year. There is also strong evidence of convergence between OECD countries (Western Europe, North America, Japan and Oceania mainly). This evidence however is very problematic, and may very well be due to what is called selection bias. To be a member of the OECD, a country has to be rich at the time when they join the organization, around 1960 for most members. So by definition, countries that were initially poor must have grown faster than their initially richer counterparts for them to be equally rich by Not surprisingly, we will find that for this very selected sample of countries, poorer countries grew faster than richer ones. If one looks at all the countries in the world, and plots their initial income say around 1960 versus their growth rate over the period for instance, there is clear pattern of an upward sloping relationship. In other words, it does not seem that initially poor countries grew faster than initially rich ones. This is however not evidence against the notion of convergence in the Solow model. What the theory predicts is not necessarily that all countries should converge to the same level of capital per worker k, but rather that they should converge to their own level of k. This steady state level k in the Solow model depends on various parameters that may very well (and actually do) vary across countries. For instance, a higher savings rate, a lower population growth all increase the steady state k. In other words, convergence in the Solow model should be conditional on a country s characteristics, and not absolute. Robert Barro and Xavier Sala-i- Martin show evidence that conditional convergence does seem to hold, even when all countries are included. The Golden rule savings rate The last point I will make about the Solow model concerns the distinction between income and actual consumption. So far, we have only described the growth of aggregate income (Y ). While aggregate income is often a good proxy for the level of physical well being in a country, it is not exactly what people care about. In particular, only a fraction of this income is actually spent on consumption, while the rest is invested in order to increase future production, but not consumed by any actual person. People usually care about what they consume. Trivially, in the Solow model, if one were to increase the savings rate to 100%, one would achieve the highest possible growth rate, but nothing would be left to consume, and everyone would starve to death. This is obviously not

17 CHAPTER V. GROWTH 77 a very desirable outcome. On the other extreme, if the savings rate falls to zero, then depreciation would gradually eat up any existing stock of capital, and eventually, output would drop to zero, and everyone again would starve to death. Not a very desirable outcome either. Within the Solow model, we can answer a simple question: what is the savings rate that would maximize not the steady state level of output per effective worker ỹ, but rather the steady state level of consumption per effective worker, c? This optimal savings rate is called the golden rule savings rate. By construction, total output is divided between consumption and investment, so that C = Y I and c =ỹ ĩ. In the steady state, we have ĩ =( + g + n) k so that c = f k ( + g + n) k. The optimal savings rate will therefore correspond to a steady state level k that solves, max f k k ( + g + n) k To solve this (unconstrained) maximization program, we take the first order condition, and find that a solution must be such that f k 0 = + g + n. The savings rate such that this condition holds in the steady state is the golden rule savings rate. At this point, the marginal product of capital per effective worker f k 0 exactly equals the effective depreciation rate of capital per effective worker. Given the decreasing returns with respect to capital, this point is where the distance between what is being produced and what is being saved (which in the steady state exactly equals the [effective] depreciation of capital) is the largest. In other words, it corresponds to the maximum level of consumption.

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

Introduction to economic growth (2)

Introduction to economic growth (2) Introduction to economic growth (2) EKN 325 Manoel Bittencourt University of Pretoria M Bittencourt (University of Pretoria) EKN 325 1 / 49 Introduction Solow (1956), "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic

More information

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn: Chapter 5 The Solow Growth Model By Charles I. Jones Additions / differences with the model: Capital stock is no longer exogenous. Capital stock is now endogenized. The accumulation of capital is a possible

More information

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn: Chapter 5 The Solow Growth Model By Charles I. Jones Additions / differences with the model: Capital stock is no longer exogenous. Capital stock is now endogenized. The accumulation of capital is a possible

More information

The Facts of Economic Growth and the Introdution to the Solow Model

The Facts of Economic Growth and the Introdution to the Solow Model The Facts of Economic Growth and the Introdution to the Solow Model Lorenza Rossi Goethe University 2011-2012 Course Outline FIRST PART - GROWTH THEORIES Exogenous Growth The Solow Model The Ramsey model

More information

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics 202: Dynamic Macroeconomics Solow Model Mausumi Das Delhi School of Economics January 14-15, 2015 Das (Delhi School of Economics) Dynamic Macro January 14-15, 2015 1 / 28 Economic Growth In this course

More information

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth J.R. Walker U.W. Madison Econ448: Human Resources and Economic Growth Summary Solow Model [Pop Growth] The simplest Solow model (i.e., with exogenous population

More information

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT I. MOTIVATING QUESTION Does the Saving Rate Affect Growth? In the long run, saving does not affect growth, but does affect the level of per capita output.

More information

1 Four facts on the U.S. historical growth experience, aka the Kaldor facts

1 Four facts on the U.S. historical growth experience, aka the Kaldor facts 1 Four facts on the U.S. historical growth experience, aka the Kaldor facts In 1958 Nicholas Kaldor listed 4 key facts on the long-run growth experience of the US economy in the past century, which have

More information

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth The analysis of why some countries have achieved a high and rising standard of living, while others have

More information

E-322 Muhammad Rahman CHAPTER-6

E-322 Muhammad Rahman CHAPTER-6 CHAPTER-6 A. OBJECTIVE OF THIS CHAPTER In this chapter we will do the following: Look at some stylized facts about economic growth in the World. Look at two Macroeconomic models of exogenous economic growth

More information

ECON 6022B Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

ECON 6022B Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011 ECON 6022B Problem Set Suggested Solutions Fall 20 September 5, 20 Shocking the Solow Model Consider the basic Solow model in Lecture 2. Suppose the economy stays at its steady state in Period 0 and there

More information

LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model

LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model Development of the model The Neo-classical model was an extension to the Harrod-Domar model that included a new term productivity growth The most important

More information

ECON 450 Development Economics

ECON 450 Development Economics ECON 450 Development Economics Classic Theories of Economic Growth and Development The Empirics of the Solow Growth Model University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Summer 2017 Introduction This lecture

More information

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 7 Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright Chapter 7 Topics Economic growth facts Malthusian model of economic growth Solow growth model Growth accounting 1-2 U.S. Per Capita Real Income Growth

More information

ECO 4933 Topics in Theory

ECO 4933 Topics in Theory ECO 4933 Topics in Theory Introduction to Economic Growth Fall 2015 Chapter 2 1 Chapter 2 The Solow Growth Model Chapter 2 2 Assumptions: 1. The world consists of countries that produce and consume only

More information

Check your understanding: Solow model 1

Check your understanding: Solow model 1 Check your understanding: Solow model 1 Bill Gibson March 26, 2017 1 Thanks to Farzad Ashouri Solow model The characteristics of the Solow model are 2 Solow has two kinds of variables, state variables

More information

MA Macroeconomics 11. The Solow Model

MA Macroeconomics 11. The Solow Model MA Macroeconomics 11. The Solow Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Autumn 2014 Karl Whelan (UCD) The Solow Model Autumn 2014 1 / 38 The Solow Model Recall that economic growth can come from capital

More information

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS LECTURE 4 Douglas Hanley, University of Pittsburgh ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THIS LECTURE Why do countries grow economically? Why do some countries grow faster than others? Why has

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

The Role of Physical Capital

The Role of Physical Capital San Francisco State University ECO 560 The Role of Physical Capital Michael Bar As we mentioned in the introduction, the most important macroeconomic observation in the world is the huge di erences in

More information

Topic 3: Endogenous Technology & Cross-Country Evidence

Topic 3: Endogenous Technology & Cross-Country Evidence EC4010 Notes, 2005 (Karl Whelan) 1 Topic 3: Endogenous Technology & Cross-Country Evidence In this handout, we examine an alternative model of endogenous growth, due to Paul Romer ( Endogenous Technological

More information

1 Chapter 1: Economic growth

1 Chapter 1: Economic growth 1 Chapter 1: Economic growth Reference: Barro and Sala-i-Martin: Economic Growth, Cambridge, Mass. : MIT Press, 1999. 1.1 Empirical evidence Some stylized facts Nicholas Kaldor at a 1958 conference provides

More information

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K Economics 285 Chris Georges Help With Practice Problems 3 Chapter 8: 1. Questions For Review 1,4: Please see text or lecture notes. 2. A note about notation: Mankiw defines k slightly differently in Chs.

More information

EC 205 Macroeconomics I

EC 205 Macroeconomics I EC 205 Macroeconomics I Macroeconomics I Chapter 8 & 9: Economic Growth Why growth matters In 2000, real GDP per capita in the United States was more than fifty times that in Ethiopia. Over the period

More information

Business Cycles II: Theories

Business Cycles II: Theories Macroeconomic Policy Class Notes Business Cycles II: Theories Revised: December 5, 2011 Latest version available at www.fperri.net/teaching/macropolicy.f11htm In class we have explored at length the main

More information

Growth, Capital Accumulation, and the Economics of Ideas

Growth, Capital Accumulation, and the Economics of Ideas Chapter 8 MODERN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Third Edition Growth, Capital Accumulation, and the Economics of Ideas Outline The Solow Model and Catching-Up Growth The Investment Rate and Conditional Convergence

More information

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale:

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale: Romer01a.doc The Solow Growth Model Set-up The Production Function Assume an aggregate production function: F[ A ], (1.1) Notation: A output capital labor effectiveness of labor (productivity) Technical

More information

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model Zhiwei Xu (xuzhiwei@sjtu.edu.cn) Solow model (Solow, 1959) is the starting point of the most dynamic macroeconomic theories. It introduces dynamics and transitions into

More information

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section (jwjung@ucdavis.edu) Department of Economics, UC Davis November 4, 2014 Slides revised: November 4, 2014 Outline 1 2 Fall 2012 Winter 2012 Midterm:

More information

Notes on classical growth theory (optional read)

Notes on classical growth theory (optional read) Simon Fraser University Econ 855 Prof. Karaivanov Notes on classical growth theory (optional read) These notes provide a rough overview of "classical" growth theory. Historically, due mostly to data availability

More information

Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Savings, Investment and Economic Growth Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth In this chapter we begin our investigation of the determinants of economic growth. We focus primarily on the relationship between savings, investment,

More information

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth In this chapter we begin our investigation of the determinants of economic growth. We focus primarily on the relationship between savings, investment,

More information

Growth and Ideas. Chad Jones Stanford GSB. October 14, Growth and Ideas p. 1

Growth and Ideas. Chad Jones Stanford GSB. October 14, Growth and Ideas p. 1 Growth and Ideas Chad Jones Stanford GSB October 14, 2015 Growth and Ideas p. 1 U.S. GDP per Person Growth and Ideas p. 2 Why? The average American is 15 times richer today than in 1870. How do we understand

More information

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth J.R. Walker U.W. Madison Econ448: Human Resources and Economic Growth Course Roadmap: Seemingly Random Topics First midterm a week from today. What have we covered

More information

14.05 Intermediate Applied Macroeconomics Exam # 1 Suggested Solutions

14.05 Intermediate Applied Macroeconomics Exam # 1 Suggested Solutions 14.05 Intermediate Applied Macroeconomics Exam # 1 Suggested Solutions October 13, 2005 Professor: Peter Temin TA: Frantisek Ricka José Tessada Question 1 Golden Rule and Consumption in the Solow Model

More information

Economic Growth: Extensions

Economic Growth: Extensions Economic Growth: Extensions 1 Road Map to this Lecture 1. Extensions to the Solow Growth Model 1. Population Growth 2. Technological growth 3. The Golden Rule 2. Endogenous Growth Theory 1. Human capital

More information

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN: IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN: the closed economy Solow model how a country s standard of living depends on its saving and population growth rates how to use the Golden Rule to find the optimal saving

More information

Why thinking about economic growth? Kaldor facts old and new Basic tools and concepts

Why thinking about economic growth? Kaldor facts old and new Basic tools and concepts Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Economic Growth Lecture WS 13/14 1. Motivation and Basic Concepts Why thinking about economic growth? Kaldor facts old and new Basic tools and concepts Why thinking about economic

More information

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996 Economics 200 Macroeconomic Theory Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996 You have 1 hour to complete this exam. Answer any four questions you wish. 1. Suppose that an increase in consumer confidence

More information

Solow instead assumed a standard neo-classical production function with diminishing marginal product for both labor and capital.

Solow instead assumed a standard neo-classical production function with diminishing marginal product for both labor and capital. Module 5 Lecture 34 Topics 5.2 Growth Theory II 5.2.1 Solow Model 5.2 Growth Theory II 5.2.1 Solow Model Robert Solow was quick to recognize that the instability inherent in the Harrod- Domar model is

More information

Class Notes. Intermediate Macroeconomics. Li Gan. Lecture 7: Economic Growth. It is amazing how much we have achieved.

Class Notes. Intermediate Macroeconomics. Li Gan. Lecture 7: Economic Growth. It is amazing how much we have achieved. Class Notes Intermediate Macroeconomics Li Gan Lecture 7: Economic Growth It is amazing how much we have achieved. It is also to know how much difference across countries. Nigeria is only 1/43 of the US.

More information

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 8 - Economic Growth Towson University 1 / 64

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 8 - Economic Growth Towson University 1 / 64 ECON 202 - MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University J.Jung Chapter 8 - Economic Growth Towson University 1 / 64 Disclaimer These lecture notes are customized for the Macroeconomics

More information

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Economics 4353 - Intermediate Macroeconomics Aaron Hedlund University of Missouri Fall 2015 Econ 4353 (University of Missouri) Malthus and Solow Fall 2015 1 / 35 Introduction

More information

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1 Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1 1.1 (from Romer Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 1) Basic properties of growth rates which will be used over and over again. Use the

More information

Road Map to this Lecture

Road Map to this Lecture Economic Growth 1 Road Map to this Lecture 1. Steady State dynamics: 1. Output per capita 2. Capital accumulation 3. Depreciation 4. Steady State 2. The Golden Rule: maximizing welfare 3. Total Factor

More information

Long-term economic growth Growth and factors of production

Long-term economic growth Growth and factors of production Understanding the World Economy Master in Economics and Business Long-term economic growth Growth and factors of production Lecture 2 Nicolas Coeurdacier nicolas.coeurdacier@sciencespo.fr Lecture 2 : Long-term

More information

Long-term economic growth Growth and factors of production

Long-term economic growth Growth and factors of production Understanding the World Economy Master in Economics and Business Long-term economic growth Growth and factors of production Lecture 2 Nicolas Coeurdacier nicolas.coeurdacier@sciencespo.fr Output per capita

More information

Applied Economics. Growth and Convergence 1. Economics Department Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

Applied Economics. Growth and Convergence 1. Economics Department Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Applied Economics Growth and Convergence 1 Economics Department Universidad Carlos III de Madrid 1 Based on Acemoglu (2008) and Barro y Sala-i-Martin (2004) Outline 1 Stylized Facts Cross-Country Dierences

More information

Introduction to economic growth (1)

Introduction to economic growth (1) Introduction to economic growth (1) EKN 325 Manoel Bittencourt University of Pretoria M Bittencourt (University of Pretoria) EKN 325 1 / 32 Introduction In the last century the USA has experienced a tenfold

More information

What we ve learned so far. The Solow Growth Model. Our objectives today 2/11/2009 ECON 206 MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS. Chapter 5 (2 of 2)

What we ve learned so far. The Solow Growth Model. Our objectives today 2/11/2009 ECON 206 MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS. Chapter 5 (2 of 2) ECON 206 MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS What we ve learned so far Roumen Vesselinov Class # 7 The key equations of the Solow Model are these: The production function And the capital accumulation equation How do

More information

Business Cycles II: Theories

Business Cycles II: Theories International Economics and Business Dynamics Class Notes Business Cycles II: Theories Revised: November 23, 2012 Latest version available at http://www.fperri.net/teaching/20205.htm In the previous lecture

More information

The Solow Growth Model. Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017

The Solow Growth Model. Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017 The Solow Growth Model Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017 Solow growth model 2 Builds on the production model by adding a theory of capital accumulation Was developed in the mid-1950s by Robert Solow of

More information

ECONOMIC GROWTH CHAPTER

ECONOMIC GROWTH CHAPTER ECONOMIC GROWTH 17 CHAPTER The Basics of Economic Growth U.S. real GDP per person and the standard of living tripled between 1960 and 2010. We see even more dramatic change in China, where incomes have

More information

ECON 256: Poverty, Growth & Inequality. Jack Rossbach

ECON 256: Poverty, Growth & Inequality. Jack Rossbach ECON 256: Poverty, Growth & Inequality Jack Rossbach What Makes Countries Grow? Common Answers Technological progress Capital accumulation Question: Should countries converge over time? Models of Economic

More information

Growth and Ideas. Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017

Growth and Ideas. Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017 Growth and Ideas Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017 Recap of the Solow model 2 Production function is Cobb-Douglas with constant returns to scale in capital and labour - exponent of 1/3 on K Goods invested

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Intermediate Macroeconomics Intermediate Macroeconomics Lecture 5 - Endogenous growth models Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 February Recap: Why go beyond the Solow model? we looked at the Solow model with technological progress

More information

Chapter 7. Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth (The Very Long Run) CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I. slide 0

Chapter 7. Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth (The Very Long Run) CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I. slide 0 Chapter 7 Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth (The Very Long Run) slide 0 In this chapter, you will learn the closed economy Solow model how a country s standard of living depends

More information

Economic Growth II. macroeconomics. fifth edition. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich Worth Publishers, all rights reserved

Economic Growth II. macroeconomics. fifth edition. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER EIGHT Economic Growth II macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Learning objectives Technological progress

More information

ECON 450 Development Economics

ECON 450 Development Economics ECON 450 Development Economics Classic Theories of Economic Growth and Development The Solow Growth Model University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Summer 2017 Introduction In this lecture we start the

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics: Economic Growth and the Solow Model

Intermediate Macroeconomics: Economic Growth and the Solow Model Intermediate Macroeconomics: Economic Growth and the Solow Model Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2014 1 Introduction We begin the core of the course with a discussion of economic growth. Technically

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Dynamic Macroeconomics Chapter 1 Introduction Dynamic Macroeconomics Prof. George Alogoskoufis Fletcher School, Tufts University and Athens University of Economics and Business 1.1 The Nature and Evolution of Macroeconomics

More information

ECONOMIC GROWTH. Objectives. Transforming People s Lives. Transforming People s Lives. Transforming People s Lives CHAPTER

ECONOMIC GROWTH. Objectives. Transforming People s Lives. Transforming People s Lives. Transforming People s Lives CHAPTER ECONOMIC 30 GROWTH CHAPTER Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to Describe the long-term growth trends in Canada and other countries and regions Identify the main sources of long-term

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics 9. The Solow Model

Advanced Macroeconomics 9. The Solow Model Advanced Macroeconomics 9. The Solow Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2015 Karl Whelan (UCD) The Solow Model Spring 2015 1 / 29 The Solow Model Recall that economic growth can come from

More information

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions. Suppose that a representative consumer receives an endowment of a non-storable consumption good. The endowment evolves exogenously according to ln

More information

? A SIMPLE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH MODEL: THE "AK" MODEL

? A SIMPLE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH MODEL: THE AK MODEL A SIMPLE ENOOGENOUS GROWTH MODEL: THE "AK" MODEL 157 these policies raise the growth rate temporarily as the economy grows to a higher level of the balanced growth path. But in the long run, the growth

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich 9 : Technology, Empirics, and Policy MACROECONOMICS N. Gregory Mankiw Modified for EC 204 by Bob Murphy PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich 2013 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU

More information

3. Which of the following assertions CLEARLY DOES NOT correspond to what you learned in this course?

3. Which of the following assertions CLEARLY DOES NOT correspond to what you learned in this course? ECO2143 Macroeconomic Theory II First mid-term examination: February 4th, 2008 University of Ottawa Professor: Louis Hotte Time allowed: 1h 20min Attention: Not all questionnaires are the same. This is

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy MANKIW. In this chapter, you will learn. Introduction

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy MANKIW. In this chapter, you will learn. Introduction C H A P T E R 8 Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy MACROECONOMICS N. GREGORY MANKIW 2007 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved SIXTH EDITION PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich In this

More information

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model) Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model) This is a model that describes the dynamics of economies in the short run. It has million of critiques, and rightfully so. However, even though

More information

TOPIC 4 Economi G c rowth

TOPIC 4 Economi G c rowth TOPIC 4 Economic Growth Growth Accounting Growth Accounting Equation Y = A F(K,N) (production function). GDP Growth Rate =!Y/Y Growth accounting equation:!y/y =!A/A +! K!K/K +! N!N/N Output, in a country

More information

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth Yulei Luo SEF of HKU October 10, 2013 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ECON2220: Macro Theory October 10, 2013 1 / 34 Chapter Outline Discuss the sources of economic growth and

More information

Macroeconomics Lecture 2: The Solow Growth Model with Technical Progress

Macroeconomics Lecture 2: The Solow Growth Model with Technical Progress Macroeconomics Lecture 2: The Solow Growth Model with Technical Progress Richard G. Pierse 1 Introduction In last week s lecture we considered the basic Solow-Swan growth model (Solow (1956), Swan (1956)).

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Intermediate Macroeconomics Intermediate Macroeconomics Lecture 2 - The Solow Growth Model Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2011 September 14 Reminder from last week The key equation of the Solow model: k(t) = sf (k(t)) }{{} (δ + n)k(t)

More information

Introduction to economic growth (3)

Introduction to economic growth (3) Introduction to economic growth (3) EKN 325 Manoel Bittencourt University of Pretoria M Bittencourt (University of Pretoria) EKN 325 1 / 29 Introduction Neoclassical growth models are descendants of the

More information

3.1 Introduction. 3.2 Growth over the Very Long Run. 3.1 Introduction. Part 2: The Long Run. An Overview of Long-Run Economic Growth

3.1 Introduction. 3.2 Growth over the Very Long Run. 3.1 Introduction. Part 2: The Long Run. An Overview of Long-Run Economic Growth Part 2: The Long Run Media Slides Created By Dave Brown Penn State University 3.1 Introduction In this chapter, we learn: Some tools used to study economic growth, including how to calculate growth rates.

More information

Macroeconomics. Review of Growth Theory Solow and the Rest

Macroeconomics. Review of Growth Theory Solow and the Rest Macroeconomics Review of Growth Theory Solow and the Rest Basic Neoclassical Growth Model K s Y = savings = investment = K production Y = f(l,k) consumption L = n L L exogenous population (labor) growth

More information

Growth. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame. Sims (ND) Growth Fall / 39

Growth. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame. Sims (ND) Growth Fall / 39 Growth Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 Sims (ND) Growth Fall 2012 1 / 39 Economic Growth When economists say growth, typically mean average rate of growth in real GDP per capita over

More information

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model T.Huw Edwards Dept of Economics, Loughborough University and CSGR Warwick UK Tel (44)01509-222718 Fax 01509-223910 T.H.Edwards@lboro.ac.uk

More information

Infrastructure and Urban Primacy: A Theoretical Model. Jinghui Lim 1. Economics Urban Economics Professor Charles Becker December 15, 2005

Infrastructure and Urban Primacy: A Theoretical Model. Jinghui Lim 1. Economics Urban Economics Professor Charles Becker December 15, 2005 Infrastructure and Urban Primacy 1 Infrastructure and Urban Primacy: A Theoretical Model Jinghui Lim 1 Economics 195.53 Urban Economics Professor Charles Becker December 15, 2005 1 Jinghui Lim (jl95@duke.edu)

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid Autumn 2014 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model Autumn 2014 1 / 38 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy We now proceed to study optimal fiscal policy. We should make clear at the outset what we mean by this. In general, fiscal policy entails the government choosing its spending

More information

Chapter 8. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics and Policy 10/6/2010. Introduction. Technological progress in the Solow model

Chapter 8. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics and Policy 10/6/2010. Introduction. Technological progress in the Solow model Chapter 8 : Technology, Empirics and Policy Introduction In the Solow of Chapter 7, the production technology is held constant. income per capita is constant in the steady state. Neither point is true

More information

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy, Tufts University 2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross E212 Macroeconomics Prof. George Alogoskoufis Consumer Spending

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

Chapter 8a: Growth Accounting

Chapter 8a: Growth Accounting Chapter 8a: Growth Accounting his section explains in more detail than chapter 8 the technique called growth accounting which economists use to analyze what determines the growth of income per capita in

More information

Economic Growth C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T. When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to

Economic Growth C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T. When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Economic Growth CHAPTER25 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Define and calculate the economic growth rate, and explain the implications

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid September 2015 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model September 2015 1 / 43 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

The Solow Growth Model

The Solow Growth Model The Solow Growth Model Seyed Ali Madanizadeh Sharif U. of Tech. April 25, 2017 Seyed Ali Madanizadeh Sharif U. of Tech. () The Solow Growth Model April 25, 2017 1 / 46 Economic Growth Facts 1 In the data,

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid Autumn 2014 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model Autumn 2014 1 / 33 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

Chapter 8 Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth

Chapter 8 Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth Chapter 8 Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth Modified by Yun Wang Eco 3203 Intermediate Macroeconomics Florida International University Summer 2017 2016 Worth Publishers, all

More information

Testing the Solow Growth Theory

Testing the Solow Growth Theory Testing the Solow Growth Theory Dilip Mookherjee Ec320 Lecture 4, Boston University Sept 11, 2014 DM (BU) 320 Lect 4 Sept 11, 2014 1 / 25 RECAP OF L3: SIMPLE SOLOW MODEL Solow theory: deviates from HD

More information

Lecture notes 2: Physical Capital, Development and Growth

Lecture notes 2: Physical Capital, Development and Growth Lecture notes 2: Physical Capital, Development and Growth These notes are based on a draft manuscript Economic Growth by David N. Weil. All rights reserved. Lecture notes 2: Physical Capital, Development

More information

004: Macroeconomic Theory

004: Macroeconomic Theory 004: Macroeconomic Theory Lecture 16 Mausumi Das Lecture Notes, DSE October 28, 2014 Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Macro October 28, 2014 1 / 24 Solow Model: Golden Rule & Dynamic Ineffi ciency In the last

More information

The Solow Growth Model

The Solow Growth Model The Solow Growth Model Model Background The Solow growth model is the starting point to determine why growth differs across similar countries it builds on the Cobb-Douglas production model by adding a

More information

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth Yulei Luo Economics, HKU October 19, 2017 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ECON2220: Intermediate Macro October 19, 2017 1 / 32 Chapter Outline Discuss the sources of economic

More information

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section (jwjung@ucdavis.edu) Department of Economics, UC Davis October 27, 2014 Slides revised: October 27, 2014 Outline 1 Announcement 2 Review: Chapter 5

More information

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form Saddle Path Halvor Mehlum Abstract Following up a 50 year old suggestion due to Solow, I show that by including a Ramsey consumer in the Harrod-Domar

More information

READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO

READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO 2050 Dreaming with BRICs: The Path to 2050, by Dominic Wilson and Roopa Purushothaman, reprinted from Global Economics Paper Number 99. Copyright 2003. Reprinted

More information

ECON Chapter 6: Economic growth: The Solow growth model (Part 1)

ECON Chapter 6: Economic growth: The Solow growth model (Part 1) ECON3102-005 Chapter 6: Economic growth: The Solow growth model (Part 1) Neha Bairoliya Spring 2014 Motivations Why do countries grow? Why are there poor countries? Why are there rich countries? Can poor

More information