BILATERALISM IS GOOD: TRADE BLOCS AND STRATEGIC EXPORT SUBSIDIES

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "BILATERALISM IS GOOD: TRADE BLOCS AND STRATEGIC EXPORT SUBSIDIES"

Transcription

1 Oxford Economic Papers 49 (1997), BILATERALISM IS GOOD: TRADE BLOCS AND STRATEGIC EXPORT SUBSIDIES By DAVID R. COLLIE Cardiff Business School, Aberconway Building, Colum Drive, Cardiff CF1 3EU, UK; This paper considers the effect of exogenous trade bloc enlargement in a multi-country version of the Brander-Spencer export subsidy game. In the single-shot game, it is shown that trade bloc enlargement leads to a reduction in the Nash equilibrium export subsidies and thereby increases the welfare of the exporting countries. Although the welfare of the importing countries decreases, world welfare may increase if the export subsidies are financed by distortionary taxation. When the export subsidy game is infinitely repeated, it is shown that trade bloc enlargement reduces the critical discount factor making it easier to sustain free trade. 1. Introduction DESPITE the successful conclusion of the Uruguay Round and the consequent strengthening of the multilateral trade regime, there is still some concern that increased regional integration may result in the division of the world economy into competing trade blocs. This would, it is often argued, lead to an escalation of trade conflict with the result that trade barriers were increased and world welfare reduced. Krugman (1991) has highlighted this possibility using a simple but provocative model in which non-cooperative tariff-setting results in world welfare being minimised when the world economy is divided into three trade blocs. He employs a conventional trade theory model where tariffs are used to improve the terms of trade, however, this is not the only rationale for trade policy. In oligopolistic industries, Brander and Spencer (1985) have shown that countries can use strategic export subsidies to shift profits from foreign to domestic firms. Although export subsidies are prohibited by the World Trade Organisation (WTO), many industrialised countries use export credits and export credit insurance to give their firms an advantage when exporting capital goods to developing countries 1 This paper looks at how the division of the industrialised countries into trade blocs affects their use of strategic export subsidies in oligopolistic industries. The question has some practical relevance as the creation of the Single European Market in 1992 has led the European Commission to call for the harmonisation of the terms on which EC countries give export credit insurance. 2 1 The history of officially supported export credits is examined in Ray (1995), and he also describes the development of international rules governing their use. 2 Exporters in the EC have argued that the proposed reduction in insurance cover would harm their competitiveness against other OECD exporters when telling capital goods in developing countries, see the Financial Times, 31st January Oxford IMrentty Pros 1997

2 D. COLLIE 505 In Krugman (1991) consumers have Dixit-Stiglitz preferences, and each country is endowed with a unique differentiated product. The countries are divided into symmetric trade blocs that pursue a policy of free trade within the trade bloc but impose a common external tariff on imports from the rest of the world. The trade blocs set their tariffs non-cooperatively with each trade bloc setting its tariff to maximise its welfare given the tariffs set by the other trade blocs; the result is a Nash equilibrium in tariffs. An increase in the size of the symmetric trade blocs increases the market power of each trade bloc, and results in an increase in the Nash equilibrium tariffs. As a result of trade diversion and the higher tariffs, world welfare initially declines as the trade blocs become larger until it reaches a minimum with three trade blocs. A further increase in the size of trade blocs increases world welfare and it is maximised when there is one trade bloc which is equivalent to global free trade. Krugman (1993) shows that the reduction in welfare as trade blocs become larger is mainly due to increased trade diversion rather than the higher Nash equilibrium tariffs. In Bond and Syropoulos (1996) it is shown that the results of Krugman (1991) are not robust to changes in the pattern of comparative advantage. If a reduction in the number of trade blocs makes inter-bloc trade less important then the market power of the trade blocs is reduced and the Nash equilibrium tariffs will fall. This implies that world welfare will be minimised when there are more than three trade blocs. Sinclair and Vines (1994) point out that Krugman (1991) assumes that the trade blocs are customs unions with a common external tariff when many trade blocs are actually free trade areas with each country setting its own tariff on imports from outside the free trade area. As a free trade area becomes larger the market power of a country will be reduced as more of its imports come from within the free trade area, and hence the Nash equilibrium tariffs set by countries will fall. Sinclair and Vines (1994) do not consider how world welfare varies with the number of free trade areas, but trade diversion will still occur as with a customs union. The Nash equilibrium tariff rates calculated by Krugman (1991) are much higher than actual tariff rates, and this may be because trade blocs realise that they are engaged in a repeated game rather than a single-shot game. 3 In an infinitely repeated game more co-operative outcome such as free trade can be sustained by the threat of retaliation with the Nash equilibrium tariffs. Bond and Syropoulos (1995) look at how the formation of trade blocs affects the sustainability of free trade in an infinitely repeated version of the Bond and Syropoulos (1996) model. They show that as trade blocs become larger the incentives to deviate from free trade become larger and this makes it more difficult to sustain free trade. Bagwell and Staiger (1994) consider how the announcement of a customs union affects tariff setting in an infinitely repeated game. They show that there will be a honeymoon period with lower tariffs after 3 The tariff rates ralrnint«h by Krugman (1991) are broadly consistent with the Smoot-Hawley tariff rates when trade policy was set non-cooperatively.

3 506 BILATERALISM IS GOOD the customs union is announced, but this may be followed by higher tariffs after the customs union is implemented. In all of these models tariffs are used to improve the terms of trade, but the new trade theory has provided a rationale for strategic trade policies in oligopolistic industries. When domestic and foreign firms compete in the domestic market, Brander and Spencer (1984) have shown that a tariff can be used to extract rent from the foreign firms and to shift profits to domestic firms. In Brander and Spencer (1985), where a domestic and a foreign firm compete as Cournot duopolists in a third market, it was shown that the domestic country can gain by using a profit-shifting export subsidy but if both countries use export subsidies then welfare in the Nash equilibrium, assuming symmetry, will be lower than under free trade. In an infinitely repeated version of the export subsidy game, Collie (1993) has shown that free trade can be sustained by the threat of retaliation with the Nash equilibrium export subsidies provided the countries are similar and the discount factor is sufficiently high. There has been no attempt to look at trade bloc formation in models of strategic trade policy apart from the brief analysis in Sinclair and Vines (1994). They extend the Brander and Spencer (1984) model to consider the effect of trade bloc formation on the Nash equilibrium tariffs. For customs unions their results are ambiguous tariffs initially increase then fall as customs unions become larger whereas for free trade areas they unambiguously show that tariffs fall as the free trade areas become larger. Sinclair and Vines (1994) do not consider the welfare effects of trade bloc formation. This paper looks at how the exogenous formation of the industrialised countries into symmetric trade blocs affects their use of strategic export subsidies in oligopolistic industries. The model presented is a multi-country extension of the Brander and Spencer (1985) export subsidy game where the industrialised countries export to countries in the rest of the world. The paper begins by looking at the Nash equilibrium of the single-shot export subsidy game, and then considers the sustainability of free trade in the infinitely repeated export subsidy game. In the single-shot game, the Nash equilibrium export subsidies are derived as functions of the number of countries in each trade bloc, and it is shown that export subsidies are reduced as trade blocs become larger. This is because trade bloc enlargement reduces the effectiveness of export subsidies. The reduction in the Nash equilibrium export subsidies by all the trade blocs leads to an increase in the welfare of all the industrialised countries. Obviously, the terms of trade of the importing countries will deteriorate so reducing their welfare but, surprisingly, world welfare may increase if the export subsidies are financed by distortionary taxation as in Neary (1994). This provides an economic rationale based upon worldwide efficiency for the WTO prohibition of export subsidies. 4 In the infinitely repeated export subsidy 4 An alternative rationale for the WTO prohibition of export subsidies is suggested by Bagwell and Staiger (1996). In their model, export subsidies serve to co-ordinate the entry decisions of firms and the prohibition of export subsidies may increase welfare if the co-ordination provided by export subsidies does more to prevent entry than to promote entry.

4 D. COLLIE 507 game, free trade can be sustained by the threat of retaliation with the Nash equilibrium export subsidies if the discount factor of the trade blocs exceeds the critical value. The critical discount factor is such that the instantaneous gain from unilaterally using an export subsidy is just equal to the present discounted value of the losses from retaliation. As trade blocs become larger the instantaneous gain from unilaterally using an export subsidy decreases because export subsidies become less effective, but the losses from retaliation also decrease because of the increase in Nash equilibrium welfare. It turns out that the overall effect of trade bloc enlargement is to reduce the critical discount factor making it easier to sustain free trade. 2. The model The model is a multi-country version of the Brander and Spencer (1985) analysis of profit-shifting export subsidies based upon Collie (1993), and as in Krugman (1991) some special assumptions will be employed to yield a tractable model. The model is partial equilibrium and only analyses the effect of trade bloc enlargement on the oligopolistic industry located in the industrialised countries. All the output of the oligopolistic industry is assumed to be exported to countries in the rest of the world, hence the model concentrates upon the profit-shifting effect and ignores the usual trade diverting effect of trade bloc enlargement. 5 The model is symmetric, all the industrialised countries are assumed to be identical, and all the trade blocs are of equal size, hence it can be analysed by considering a representative trade bloc. The simplest possible functional forms, linear demand and constant marginal cost, will be used to allow explicit solutions to be obtained for welfare as a function of the number of countries in each trade bloc. This assumption is necessary, in particular to analyse the sustainability of free trade in an infinitely repeated game. Therefore the model is not general; however, the lack of generality can be justified by the possibly counter-intuitive results obtained about trade bloc enlargement. In each of the N industrialised countries there is a single firm with constant marginal cost c that exports its output to the rest of the world where it engages in Cournot competition with the other firms from the industrialised countries. 6 The N industrialised countries are divided into B symmetric trade blocs with M 3 Incorporating demand in the industrialised countries into the model, would introduce the possibility of the trade blocs setting tariffs on imports from other trade blocs and then trade bloc enlargement would affect the Nash equilibrium tariffs as in Sinclair and Vines (1994). However, the assumptions of segmented markets and constant marginal cost allows the export markets in the rest of the world to be analysed independently of the markets in the industrialised countries. The total welfare effect of trade bloc enlargement would include the effect of tariff-setting in the industrialised markets as well as the effect of export-subsidy-setting in the rest of the world. Combining these two effects is beyond the scope of this paper. 'The assumption that there is a singlefirmin each country is not restrictive since a country with n firms is equivalent to a trade bloc of n countries each with a singlefirm;hence, the results would continue to hold if there were n firms in each country.

5 508 BILATERALISM IS GOOD countries in each trade bloc; thus M = N/B. Since the model is concerned with strategic interaction between trade blocs there must be at least two trade blocs, and obviously the number of trade blocs cannot exceed the number of countries; hence 2 < B < N and 1 < M < N/2. Each trade bloc is assumed to use an export subsidy to maximise the welfare of the countries in the trade bloc given the export subsidies set by the other trade blocs. With the assumption of symmetry, the model can be analysed by considering a representative trade bloc and treating the other (B - 1) trade blocs as one aggregate trade bloc with (N - M) countries. The representative trade bloc sets an export subsidy e t and its firms each export output x h while the other (B-l) trade blocs set an export subsidy e and their firms each export output x. The price of the exported good in the rest of the world is given by the linear inverse demand function P = a-0x (1) where X Mx t + (N M)x is total sales in the export market. The profits of a firm in the representative trade bloc and the profits of a firm in the other (B 1) trade blocs are, respectively 7T, = (P - C + e^xf n=(p-c + e)x (2) At a Cournot equilibrium the firms independently and simultaneously choose their outputs to maximise profits given the export subsidies set by the trade blocs. Since demand is linear there exists a unique Cournot equilibrium. Assuming that allfirmsexport positive quantities, thefirstorder conditions for a Cournot equilibrium are dni/dx, = P + x,p' -c + e t = 0 &n/dx = P + 5cP'-c + e = 0 (3) Using the inverse demand function (1) and noting that X = Mx t + (N - M)x, these first order conditions can be solved to yield explicit solutions for the Cournot equilibrium quantities x, = {a - c + (N - M + \)e t - (N - M)e}/{N + l)/3 (M+l)e}/(n+l)P (4) The output of a firm in the representative trade bloc is increasing in the export subsidy given by therepresentative trade bloc and decreasing in the export subsidy given by the other trade blocs. The output of a firm in the other trade blocs is decreasing in the export subsidy given by the representative trade bloc and increasing in the export subsidy given by the other trade blocs. Substituting the Cournot equilibrium quantities (4) into the inverse demand function (1) and subtracting marginal cost c yields the price-cost margin P-c = {a-c-me,-{n-m)e}/{n+l) (5)

6 D. COLLIE 509 The price-cost margin of all firms is decreasing in the export subsidies given by the representative trade bloc and all the other trade blocs. Since all output is exported to the rest of the world, the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc is given by the profits of its firm less the cost of the export subsidy payments. To capture the fact that the government revenue to pay the export subsidy will typically be raised by distortionary taxation, the opportunity cost of government revenue will be allowed to exceed unity as in Neary (1994). Hence, the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc is given by: W ( iti Xe t x ( = (P c)x t (A \)e t Xi where A is the opportunity cost of government revenue and the term (A 1 )e<jc/ represents the deadweight loss due to the distortionary taxation, which will be zero if lump-sum taxes are feasible, A = I. 7 Thus, using (4) and (5), the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc is W, = [a-c-{{\- l)(n + 1) + M}e, - (N - M)e) x{a-c+(n-m+ l)et - (N - M)e}/(N + \) 2 0 (6) An export subsidy given by the representative trade bloc has three effects on the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc. Firstly, the positive profit-shifting effect: the export subsidy shifts profits to the firms in the representative trade bloc by increasing their output and reducing the output of firms in the other trade blocs. This profit-shifting effect is a purely beggar-my-neighbour effect since the firms in the representative trade bloc gain market share at the expense of firms in the other trade blocs. Secondly, the negative terms of trade effect: the export subsidy worsens the terms of trade since it increases total output and hence reduces the price-cost margin of firms in the representative trade bloc. Thirdly, the negative distortionary taxation effect: the deadweight loss from taxation will increase when the export subsidy is financed by distortionary taxation, A > 1. An export subsidy given by other trade blocs has a negative effect on the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc since it reduces the output and the price-cost margin of firms in the representative trade bloc. 3. Nash equilibrium in export subsidies In this section trade blocs are assumed to behave in a non-cooperative manner when setting export subsidies which leads to an export subsidy war that can be modelled as the Nash equilibrium of the single-shot export subsidy game. Having obtained an expression for the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc in the previous section, it can now be used to derive the Nash equilibrium of the export subsidy game. Then, the effect of 7 Alternatively, A may reflect purely distributional considerations or the fact that the domestic firm U partly owned by foreign shareholders; see Neary (1994, p. 200).

7 510 BILATERALISM IS GOOD trade bloc enlargement on the Nash equilibrium export subsidies and the welfare of the industrialised countries can be analysed. In the Nash equilibrium in export subsidies, each trade bloc sets its export subsidy to maximise the welfare of the countries in the trade bloc given the export subsidies set by the other trade blocs. 8 Since all countries are identical there will be no conflict over income distribution within the trade bloc when setting the optimal export subsidy. The representative trade bloc maximises (6) with respect to e t which yields the first order condition l \E{a-c-(N-M)e}-Ge i ]=0 (7) de, (AT+1) 2 /? where E = 2(N - M + 1) - X(N + 1) and G = 2{N-M+ 1){(A - l)(n + 1) + M} > 0 As the model is symmetric it has a symmetric Nash equilibrium where all trade blocs set the same export subsidy e N, where the superscript N denotes the Nash equilibrium. Substituting e t = e e* 1 into (7) and solving for the Nash equilibrium export subsidy yields where e N = (a - c)e/a (8) A = (N - M)E + G = X(N+l) + (N-M+ \){\{N + 1) - 2} > 0 Clearly, the Nash equilibrium export subsidy is positive if E is positive, and this will be the case if the opportunity cost of government revenue is less than the critical value X E = 2(N - M + l)/(n + 1) > 1. This critical value, shown in Fig. 1, always exceeds unity for M ^ N/2 and is linearly decreasing in the number of countries in each trade bloc. Thus, the Nash equilibrium export subsidy is more likely to be positive, the lower is the opportunity cost of government revenue and the fewer countries there are in each trade bloc. 9 There are export subsidies in the Nash equilibrium in regions A and B of Fig. 1 and export taxes in region C. When lump-sum taxes are feasible, A = 1, the Nash equilibrium export subsidy is always positive. 10 Since the purpose of this paper is to analyse profit-shifting export subsidies, it will be assumed henceforth that A < A* (E > 0) so that trade blocs set positive export subsidies in the Nash equilibrium. To see how the Nash equilibrium export subsidy varies with the size of the trade bloc differentiate (8) with s Obviously, if export subsidies are set by the individual countries rather than the trade blocs then trade bloc formation will have no effect on the Nash equilibrium export subsidies. 9 This result is consistent with the optimal export subsidy under oligopoly in Dixit (1984) where lamp-sum taxes are implicitly assumed and with the optimal export subsidy under duopoly in Neary (1994) where distortionary taxation is assumed. 10 Obviously, if there was only one trade bloc consisting of the N industrialised countries then its optimal policy would be an export tax to improve the terms of trade. This would maximise the welfare of the N industrialised exporting countries.

8 D. COLLIE 511 7N tf + \ \ Opportunity cost of government revenue >l \ (^ C: Export taxes y+2 i j A: Export subsidies ^v... *,. \ B-Export subsidies e" >0. -jj^<0 \ l L M Number of countriesra eich trade bloc M Fio. 1. Critical values of the opportunity cost of government revenue respect to the number of countries in each trade bloc M With A < A, the Nash equilibrium export subsidy is positive and decreasing in the number of countries in each trade bloc. 11 This leads to the following proposition: Proposition 1 Trade bloc enlargement (an increase in the number of countries in each symmetric trade bloc) leads to a reduction in the Nash equilibrium export subsidy. The increase in the number of countries in each trade bloc affects the Nash equilibrium export subsidy set by the representative trade bloc in two ways: Firstly, the profit-shifting effect of the export subsidy is reduced since the export subsidy has less effect on the output of the firms in the representative trade bloc; dx t /de t = (N - M + \)/(N + \)0 from (4). This is because there (9) "As the number of countries in each trade bloc increases, it becomes more likely that there will be export taxes in the Nash equilibrium and these export taxes would be increasing in the number of countries in each trade bloc.

9 512 BILATERALISM IS GOOD are fewer firms outside the trade bloc who will reduce output in response to the export subsidy and more firms inside the trade bloc who will increase output. Secondly, tfie terms of trade effect of the export subsidy is increased since the export subsidy has a larger effect on price; dp/de t = -M/(N + 1) from (5). This is because there are more firms in the trade bloc being given the export subsidy, and hence the price reduction will be larger. Both of these effects reduce the size of the export subsidy set by the representative trade bloc, and since the model is symmetric these effects will be common to all the trade blocs. Thus, the Nash equilibrium export subsidies set by the trade blocs will decrease as the number of countries in each trade bloc increases. As trade blocs become larger and their share of the world market increases, the incentive to use profitshifting export subsidies is reduced. 12 To evaluate how Nash equilibrium welfare of the industrialised (exporting) countries varies with the size of the trade blocs, substitute e t = e = ^ into (6) which yields W N = \ 2 {a - c) 2 G/2(3A 2 (10) Differentiating Nash equilibrium welfare, W N, with respect to the number of countries in each trade bloc, M, yields ^ * 00 This is clearly positive which leads to the following proposition: Proposition 2 Trade bloc enlargement (an increase in the number of countries in each symmetric trade bloc) leads to an increase in the Nash equilibrium welfare of all the industrialised countries. As the number of countries in each trade bloc increases the effectiveness of export subsidies is reduced, and the Nash equilibrium export subsidies set by trade blocs are reduced. Since the model is symmetric there is a reduction of all export subsidies by an equal amount which consequently has no effect on the market shares of firms, but there is an increase in the market price as all the export subsidies are reduced. The welfare of all the industrialised countries is increased since there is an improvement in the terms of trade but no change in the market share of each country's firm. Obviously, the higher price will worsen the terms of trade of the importing countries and reduce their welfare. Assuming that preferences are quasi-linear, the welfare of the importing countries in the rest of the world is given by consumer surplus V = f (a - 0Z) dz - PX = 0X 2 /2 (12) Jo 12 Thi* is the opposite of what happens with the conventional optimum tariffs in Knigman (1991).

10 D. COLLIE 513 Substituting e t e = e^ into (4) and using X Mx ( + (N - M)x yields the welfare of the rest of the world in the Nash equilibrium in export subsidies Differentiating with respect to the number of countries in each trade bloc yields 8V S _-A 3 (a-c) 2 -N 2 (N+l)(N-M+l)<0 (14) DM As the number of countries in each trade bloc increases and Nash equilibrium export subsidies are reduced, the terms of trade of the importing countries are worsened and their welfare falls. To evaluate world-wide efficiency, define world welfare in the Nash equilibrium as the sum of consumer surplus in the rest of the world and the welfare of the N industrialised countries: SI? = V N + NW N. Thus, using (11) and (14), the effect of an increase in the number of countries in each trade bloc on world welfare is The sign of this expression depends upon the term in square brackets and this will be positive if the opportunity cost of government revenue exceeds the critical value A n = N(N -M+ 1)/{N(N - M + 1) - M) > 1 where X n < X E for M < N/2. This critical value, shown in Fig. 1, is greater than unity and increasing in the number of countries in each trade bloc. In region A of Fig. 1 there are export subsidies in the Nash equilibrium and world welfare is increasing in the number of countries in each trade bloc; in region B there are export subsidies and world welfare is decreasing; and in region C there are export taxes and world welfare is increasing. This leads to the following proposition: Proposition 3 Trade bloc enlargement (an increase in the number of countries in each symmetric trade bloc) leads to a reduction in consumer surplus in the rest of the world but will increase world welfare if A ^ A n. When export subsidies are financed by lump-sum taxes, A = 1, trade bloc enlargement leads to lower Nash equilibrium export subsidies which reduces world welfare since the output of the oligopolistic industry contracts increasing the deadweight loss from oligopoly. If export subsidies are financed by distortionary taxation then there is a reduction in the deadweight loss from taxation as export subsidies are reduced as well as the increase in the deadweight loss from oligopoly. When the opportunity cost of government revenue is sufficiently large, A > A n, the reduction in the deadweight loss from taxation outweighs the increase in the deadweight loss from oligopoly and the reduction in export subsidies increases world welfare. Thus, distortionary taxation may (15)

11 514 BILATERALISM IS GOOD provide a rationale based upon worldwide efficiency for the multilateral WTO agreement that prohibits export subsidies. Rather than assume Cournot competition, it could be assumed that all the firms in each trade bloc collude so that there is effectively only one firm in each trade bloc. Then, in contrast to proposition one, trade bloc enlargement leads to an increase in the Nash equilibrium export subsidies until there are only a few trade blocs when they start to decrease. However, as in Proposition 2, trade bloc enlargement results in an increase in the welfare of the industrialised countries since total industry output contracts despite the higher export subsidies. Hence, there is a reduction in the welfare of the importing countries and also world welfare since export subsidies increase as industry output contracts. 4. The sustainabillty of free trade In the single-shot game of the previous section, free trade is not sustainable and the only possible outcome is the Nash equilibrium in which all trade blocs give export subsidies to their firms. To avoid such subsidy wars, in the case of export credits, the industrialised countries of the OECD have reached an agreement which aims 'to provide the institutional framework for an orderly export credit market and thus to prevent an export credit race in which exporting countries compete on the basis of who grants the most favourable financing'. 13 In game theory, it is well known that if a game is infinitely repeated then more co-operative outcomes can be sustained. The perfect folk theorem states that, if agents are sufficiently patient, then any individually rational outcome can be a perfect equilibrium of an infinitely repeated game. Since the purpose of the OECD agreement is to limit export subsidies rather than attempting to maximise the welfare of the OECD countries by imposing export taxes, it seems reasonable to look at free trade as a possible co-operative outcome. Collie (1993) analyses the sustainabilty of free trade in the Brander and Spencer (1985) model of profit-shifting export subsidies using the trigger strategy suggested by Friedman (1971). This section will look at possibility of sustaining free trade as the perfect equilibrium of an infinitely repeated version of the single-shot game analysed in the previous section using trigger strategies as in Collie (1993). The strategy of each trade bloc is to play free trade until any other trade bloc deviates by using an export subsidy, and thereafter to revert to using the Nash equilibrium export subsidy. If all trade blocs pursue a policy of free trade, e/ = e = 0, then from (6) the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc is W F = (a-c) 2 /l3(n+l) 2 (16) 13 Quoted from the OECD (1990, p. 7) which details the Arrangement on Guidelines for Officially Supported Export Credits. Most OECD countries participate in this Arrangement which came into force in 1978 and sets minimum interest rates for export credits thus limiting the implicit subsidy. Participants are allowed to match any deviations from the Arrangement by other countries.

12 D. COLLIE 515 where the superscript F denotes free trade. Given the symmetry of the model, welfare is higher under free trade than in the Nash equilibrium as can be seen by subtracting (10) from (16) which yields 0 (17) where H X(N + 1) 2 > 0. This is clearly positive since the assumption that the Nash equilibrium export subsidies are positive implies that E is positive. 14 When all other trade blocs pursue a policy of free trade, the representative trade bloc will have an incentive to deviate from free trade and unilaterally use a profit-shifting export subsidy. The optimal unilateral export subsidy is given by maximising welfare (6), with e = 0, which yields the first order condition ^P = T- [E(a - c) - Ge,\ =0 (18) de ( (N+\) 2 0 [ K J ' Hence, solving for the optimal export subsidy when the representative trade bloc unilaterally deviates from free trade yields e = (a - c)e/g > 0 (19) where the superscript D denotes deviation from free trade. Differentiating (19) it can be shown that the optimal unilateral export subsidy for the trade bloc is decreasing in the number of countries in each trade bloc, de D /dm < 0, since export subsidies become less effective as the number of countries in each trade bloc becomes larger. Substituting the optimal export subsidy into welfare (6) yields the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc when it deviates from free trade W D = X 2 (a - c) 2 /20G (20) Differentiating (20) it can be shown that the welfare of a country in a trade bloc that deviates from free trade is decreasing in the number of countries in each trade bloc, dw D /8M < 0. Obviously, welfare is higher when the representative trade bloc deviates from free trade than under free trade, as can be seen by subtracting (16) from (20). Also, welfare is higher when the representative trade bloc deviates from free trade than in the Nash equilibrium, as can be seen by subtracting (10) from (20). These subtractions yield 2p(N+l) 2 G 14 If there were export taxes in the Nash equilibrium then welfare in the Nash equilibrium would be higher than welfare under free trade so attempting to sustain free trade would be pointless and impossible.

13 516 BILATERALISM IS GOOD Number of countriej in each trade bloc M Fio. 2. Incentives to deviate from free trade Once the representative trade bloc has deviated from free trade, the other trade blocs will retaliate by setting the Nash equilibrium export subsidy, e", forever afterwards. Faced with the Nash equilibrium export subsidies being set by the other trade blocs, the optimal response of therepresentativetrade bloc is to use its Nash equilibrium export subsidy, e N, and hence the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc will be as in the Nash equilibrium, W N, forever afterwards. Figure 2 shows W F, W N, and W D a& functions of the number of countries in each trade bloc. Assuming that the other trade blocs use the trigger strategy, if the representative trade bloc deviates from free trade by using an export subsidy e then the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc in that period will be W D, but thereafter the other trade blocs will retaliate and the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc will be W N forever afterwards. Whereas, if it does not deviate and pursues a policy of free trade then the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc will be W F in every period. Therefore, using the trigger strategy will be an optimal response for the representative trade bloc to the trigger strategy of the other trade blocs if the present discounted value of the welfare of a country in the representative trade bloc from free trade exceeds that from deviation and the resulting retaliation

14 D. COLLIE 517 -L-W F^W +-^-zw N =>(W D -W r )^-^-JW F -W N ) (22) 1 o 1 o 1 6 where 6 is the discount factor which is between zero and one, 0 < 5 < 1, and will be assumed to be the same for all trade blocs. As the model is symmetric, all trade blocs are in the same situation. The trigger strategy will be optimal for all trade blocs if the discount factor exceeds the critical value, 6*, where the instantaneous gain from unilaterally using an export subsidy is just equal to the present discounted value of the losses from retaliation. Using (21) in (22), the critical discount factor is W D -W F EA 2 (23) where tf = {N-M)(N+l) 2 (A + G) > 0. The critical discount factor is clearly positive, but by subtracting the critical discount factor from unity it can be shown that 0 (24) Hence, the critical discount factor is between zero and one, 0 < S* < 1. Free trade is sustainable as a perfect equilibrium of the infinitely repeated game if the discount factor of the trade blocs is greater than the critical value, 6^6*. Obviously, the lower is the critical discount factor then the easier it is to sustain free trade. To see how the critical discount factor varies as the number of countries in each trade bloc changes, differentiate (23) with respect to M which yields &?_ = A(rt + 1) ^ _ M) {2GH + 2(N-M)A + E} + HA(A + G)}<0 As the denominator is clearly positive, the sign of the derivative depends upon the terms in square brackets which are all positive; hence, the derivative is negative which leads to the following proposition: Proposition 4 Trade bloc enlargement (an increase in the number of countries in each symmetric trade bloc) leads to a reduction in the critical discount factor making it easier to sustain free trade. Looking at Fig. 2 it can be seen that trade bloc enlargement has two effects on the critical discount factor firstly, the instantaneous gain from unilaterally using an export subsidy is reduced since the welfare of a country in a trade bloc that deviates from free trade is decreasing in the number of countries in each trade bloc, dw D /dm < 0. This will reduce the incentive to deviate from free trade and make the critical discount factor smaller. Secondly, the losses from retaliation are reduced since Nash equilibrium welfare is increasing in the number of firms in each trade bloc, dw N /dm > 0. This will increase the (25)

15 518 BILATERALISM IS GOOD incentive to deviate from free trade and make the critical discount factor larger. It turns out that the first effect dominates the second effect so that the incentives to deviate from free trade become smaller as trade blocs become larger; hence, the critical discount factor becomes smaller and it becomes easier to sustain free trade. 15 Rather than an agreement to sustain free trade, the trade blocs could agree to set export taxes to maximise their joint welfare. Provided the discount factor was sufficiently high, such an agreement could be sustained by the threat of retaliation with the Nash equilibrium export subsidies. Obviously, it will be more difficult to sustain the joint welfare maximising export taxes rather than free trade as the critical discount factor will be higher. As above, it can be shown that trade bloc enlargement leads to a reduction in the critical discount factor making it easier to sustain the joint welfare maximising export taxes. 5. Conclusions This paper has analysed the effect of exogenous trade bloc enlargement in a multi-country extension of the Brander and Spencer (1985) model of profitshifting export subsidies. In the single-shot export subsidy game, trade bloc enlargement was shown to reduce the effectiveness of export subsidies with the result'that trade blocs set lower export subsidies in the Nash equilibrium. The lower export subsidies set by the trade blocs increased the welfare of the industrialised (exporting) countries while reducing the welfare of the importing countries. Surprisingly, it was shown that trade bloc enlargement may result in an increase in world welfare if export subsidies are financed by distortionary taxation. In the infinitely repeated game, trade bloc enlargement was shown to reduce the critical discount factor making it easier to sustain free trade (or the joint welfare maximising export taxes). Thus, in contrast to Krugman (1991), bilateralism is good for the industrialised countries and may be good for world welfare. In conventional models where trade policy is used to improve the terms of trade, such as Krugman (1991), trade bloc enlargement increases the market power of trade blocs thereby increasing the incentive to use trade policy; whereas in this strategic trade policy model, trade bloc enlargement reduces the incentive to use profit-shifting trade policy. Thus, trade bloc enlargement provides an example where the new trade theory yields the opposite conclusion to that obtained from conventional trade theory. This analysis also suggests that small trade blocs (or countries) will have the greatest incentive to use strategic trade policy whereas large trade blocs (or countries) will have the greatest incentive to use trade policy to improve their terms of trade. This implies that small countries, such as Korea and Taiwan, are more likely to use strategic trade policy than a large country like the United States. "This is the opposite of what happens in Bond and Syropoulos (1995) in a conventional model where trade blocs use optimum tariffs to improve their terms of trade.

16 D. COLLIE 519 This model also indirectly casts some light on multilateral agreements to limit or prohibit export subsidies. It was shown that reducing export subsidies will increase the welfare of the industrialised countries and this obviously provides a rationale for the OECD agreement to limit export credits given by the industrialised countries on exports to the developing countries. However, intuition suggests that reducing export subsidies in an oligopolistic industry will increase the deadweight loss from oligopoly and reduce world welfare since the gain to the exporting countries is outweighed by the loss to the importing countries; hence, it is argued that strategic trade policy does not provide a rationale for worldwide agreements to prohibit export subsidies. In this model, it was shown that reducing export subsidies may increase world welfare if export subsidies are financed by distortionary taxation since then the increase in the deadweight loss from oligopoly may be outweighed by the reduction in the deadweight loss from taxation. Thus, distortionary taxation provides a rationale based upon worldwide efficiency for the multilateral WTO agreement that prohibits export subsidies. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Earlier versions of this paper were presented to seminars at Cardiff Business School and the University of Warwick, and at the 1996 European Economic Association Congress in Istanbul. I would like to thank the participants for their comments. It has been greatly improved by the insightful comments and suggestions made by two anonymous referees for which I am extremely grateful. I am solely responsible for any errors that remain. REFERENCES BAGWELL, K. and STAIGER, R. W. (1994). 'Multilateral Tariff Co-operation During the Formation of Customs Unions', NBER Working Paper No. 4543, Cambridge, MA. BAGWELL, K. and STAIGER, R. W. (1996). 'Strategic Export Subsidies and Reciprocal Trade Agreements: the Natural Monopoly Case', NBER Working Paper No. 5574, Cambridge, MA. BRANDER, J. A. and SPENCER, B. J. (1984). Tariff Protection and Imperfect Competition', in H. Kicrzkowski (ed.), Monopolistic Competition and International Trade, Oxford University Press, Oxford. BRANDER, J. A. and SPENCER, B. J. (1985). 'Export Subsidies and International Market Share Rivalry', Journal of International Economics, 18, BOND, E. W. and SYROPOULOS, C. (1995). Trading Blocs and the Sustainabflity of Inter-Regional Co-operation', in M. Canzoneri, W. Ethier, and V. Grilli (eds), The New Transatlantic Economy, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. BOND, E. W. and SYROPOULOS, C. (1996). The Size of Trading Blocs: Market Power and World Welfare Effects', Journal of International Economics, 40, COLLIE, D. R. (1993). 'Profit-Shifting Export Subsidies and the Sustainability of Free Trade', Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 40, DDCTT, A. K. (1984). 'International Trade Policy for Oligopolistic Industries', Economic Journal, 94 (supplement), FRIEDMAN, J. W. (1971). 'A Non-Cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames', Review of Economic Studies, 38, KRUGMAN, P. R. (1991). 'Is Bilateralism BadT in E. Helpman and A. Razin (eds), International Trade and Trade Policy, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

17 520 BILATERALISM IS GOOD KJLUOHAN, P. R. (1993). 'Regionalism versus Multilateralism: Analytical Notes' in J. Dc Melo and A. Panagariya (eds), New Dimensions in Regional Integration, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. NBARY, J. P. (1994). 'Cost Asymmetries in International Subsidy Games: Should Governments Help Winners or Losers?*, Journal of International Economics, 37, OECD (1990). The Export Credit Financing Systems in OECD Member Countries, Fourth Edition, Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris. RAY, J. E. (1995). Managing Official Export Credits: the Quest for a Global Regime, Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC. SINCLAIR, P. J. N. and VINES, D. (1994). 'Do Fewer, Larger Trade Blocs Imply Greater Protection?: The good news and bad news about regional trading blocs'. International Economics Study Group Meeting, London.

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly Roger Clarke Cardiff University David Collie Cardiff University Abstract This article analyses export taxes in a Bertrand duopoly with product differentiation, where

More information

Overview Basic analysis Strategic trade policy Further topics. Overview

Overview Basic analysis Strategic trade policy Further topics. Overview Robert Stehrer Version: June 19, 2013 Overview Tariffs Specific tariffs Ad valorem tariffs Non-tariff barriers Import quotas (Voluntary) Export restraints Local content requirements Subsidies Other Export

More information

Product Differentiation, the Volume of Trade and. Profits under Cournot and Bertrand Duopoly *

Product Differentiation, the Volume of Trade and. Profits under Cournot and Bertrand Duopoly * Product Differentiation, the olume of Trade and Profits under ournot and ertrand Duopoly * David R. ollie ardiff usiness School, ardiff University, ardiff, F10 3EU, United Kingdom; Email: ollie@cardiff.ac.uk

More information

Prohibiting State Aid in an Integrated Market:

Prohibiting State Aid in an Integrated Market: Prohibiting tate Aid in an Integrated Market: ournot and ertrand Oligopolies with Differentiated Products* David R ollie ardiff usiness chool, ardiff University Aberconway uilding, olum Drive ardiff F10

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

SHORTER PAPERS. Tariffs versus Quotas under Market Price Uncertainty. Hung-Yi Chen and Hong Hwang. 1 Introduction

SHORTER PAPERS. Tariffs versus Quotas under Market Price Uncertainty. Hung-Yi Chen and Hong Hwang. 1 Introduction SHORTER PAPERS Tariffs versus Quotas under Market Price Uncertainty Hung-Yi Chen and Hong Hwang Soochow University, Taipei; National Taiwan University and Academia Sinica, Taipei Abstract: This paper compares

More information

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, vol. 25, nº 4 (100), pp. 391-395 October-December/2005 Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare YU-TER WANG* Using a simple Cournot duopoly model, this

More information

Profit tax and tariff under international oligopoly

Profit tax and tariff under international oligopoly International Review of Economics and Finance 8 (1999) 317 326 Profit tax and tariff under international oligopoly Amar K. Parai* Department of Economics, State University of New York, Fredonia, NY 14063,

More information

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms 17 RESEARCH ARTICE Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between irms Yordying Supasri and Makoto Tawada* Abstract This paper examines optimal trade policies

More information

University of Warwick institutional repository: A Thesis Submitted for the Degree of PhD at the University of Warwick

University of Warwick institutional repository:   A Thesis Submitted for the Degree of PhD at the University of Warwick University of Warwick institutional repository: http://go.warwick.ac.uk/wrap A Thesis Submitted for the Degree of PhD at the University of Warwick http://go.warwick.ac.uk/wrap/4014 This thesis is made

More information

Welfare in a Unionized Bertrand Duopoly. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* and Sudeshna C. Bandyopadhyay

Welfare in a Unionized Bertrand Duopoly. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* and Sudeshna C. Bandyopadhyay Welfare in a Unionized Bertrand Duopoly Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* and Sudeshna C. Bandyopadhyay Department of Economics, West Virginia University, Morgantown, WV-26506-6025. November, 2000 Abstract This paper

More information

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies? Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies? Moonsung Kang Division of International Studies Korea University Seoul, Republic of Korea mkang@korea.ac.kr Abstract

More information

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY Once there is imperfect competition in trade models, what happens if trade policies are introduced? A literature has grown up around this, often described as strategic

More information

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games Game Theory Wolfgang Frimmel Repeated Games 1 / 41 Recap: SPNE The solution concept for dynamic games with complete information is the subgame perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE) Selten (1965): A strategy

More information

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model Volume 29 Issue 1 Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model Kojun Hamada Faculty of Economics Niigata University Abstract This paper examines which of the Stackelberg

More information

Export Subsidies and Oligopoly with Switching Costs

Export Subsidies and Oligopoly with Switching Costs Export Subsidies and Oligopoly with Switching Costs Theodore To September 1993 Abstract I examine export policy using a two-period model of oligopolistic competition with switching costs. A switching costs

More information

Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies, The Netherlands. Working Paper 99.12

Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies, The Netherlands. Working Paper 99.12 WORKING PAPERS Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies, The Netherlands Working Paper 99.12 "Subsidy and Entry: Role of licensing" by A. Mukherjee (EelS) October 1999 Subsidy and EntlY: Role of Licensing

More information

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key EconS 44 Strategy and Game Theory Homework #5 Answer Key Exercise #1 Collusion among N doctors Consider an infinitely repeated game, in which there are nn 3 doctors, who have created a partnership. In

More information

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Managerial Economics November 16, 2012 Prof. Dr. Sebastian Rausch Centre for Energy Policy and Economics Department of Management, Technology and Economics ETH Zürich

More information

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions Open economies review 14: 5 9, 2003 c 2003 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in The Netherlands. Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions TORU KIKUCHI kikuchi@econ.kobe-u.ac.jp Graduate School of Economics,

More information

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, the University of Tokyo and Noriaki Matsushima Graduate School of Business Administration, Kobe

More information

STRATEGIC TRADE POLICY ANDr-RETALIATIOMi. Export Subsidies and Countervailing Tariffs. David Robert Collie. London School of Economics

STRATEGIC TRADE POLICY ANDr-RETALIATIOMi. Export Subsidies and Countervailing Tariffs. David Robert Collie. London School of Economics STRATEGIC TRADE POLICY ANDr-RETALIATIOMi Export Subsidies and Countervailing Tariffs David Robert Collie London School of Economics Thesis submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy 1 UMI Number:

More information

Does a Bilateral FTA Become a Building Bloc for Free Trade?

Does a Bilateral FTA Become a Building Bloc for Free Trade? Does a Bilateral FTA Become a Building Bloc for Free Trade? Ryoichi Nomura y Takao Ohkawa z Makoto Okamura x Makoto Tawada { July 31, 2008 Abstract This paper examines whether a formation of bilateral

More information

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis EC 202 Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I George Symeonidis Oligopoly When only a small number of firms compete in the same market, each firm has some market power. Moreover, their interactions cannot be ignored.

More information

Export restrictions on non renewable resources used as intermediate consumption in oligopolistic industries

Export restrictions on non renewable resources used as intermediate consumption in oligopolistic industries Export restrictions on non renewable resources used as intermediate consumption in oligopolistic industries Antoine Bouët, David Laborde and Véronique Robichaud August 2, 2011 Abstract We build a dynamic

More information

Sanna-Randaccio LECTURE 22 : NON TARIFF BARRIERS

Sanna-Randaccio LECTURE 22 : NON TARIFF BARRIERS Sanna-Randaccio LECTURE : NON TARIFF BARRIERS IMPORT QUOTA DEF Partial euilibrium effects Import uota versus tariff (perfect competition) Import uota versus tariff (monopoly) Tariffication in the Uruguay

More information

Tari s, Taxes and Foreign Direct Investment

Tari s, Taxes and Foreign Direct Investment Tari s, Taxes and Foreign Direct Investment Koo Woong Park 1 BK1 PostDoc School of Economics Seoul National University E-mail: kwpark@snu.ac.kr Version: 4 November 00 [ABSTRACT] We study tax (and tari

More information

Repeated Games. September 3, Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality. Finitely Repeated Games. Infinitely Repeated Games

Repeated Games. September 3, Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality. Finitely Repeated Games. Infinitely Repeated Games Repeated Games Frédéric KOESSLER September 3, 2007 1/ Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality Finitely Repeated Games Infinitely Repeated Games Automaton Representation of Strategies The One-Shot

More information

WTO E-Learning. WTO E-Learning Copyright August The WTO and Trade Economics: Theory and Policy

WTO E-Learning. WTO E-Learning Copyright August The WTO and Trade Economics: Theory and Policy WTO E-Learning WTO E-Learning Copyright August 2012 The WTO and Trade Economics: Theory and Policy 1 Introduction This is a multimedia course on The WTO and Trade Economics: Theory and Policy. The course

More information

Bilateral trade agreements and the feasibility of multilateral free trade. Kamal Saggi (SMU) and Halis M. Yildiz (Ryerson University)

Bilateral trade agreements and the feasibility of multilateral free trade. Kamal Saggi (SMU) and Halis M. Yildiz (Ryerson University) Bilateral trade agreements and the feasibility of multilateral free trade Kamal Saggi (SMU) and Halis M. Yildiz (Ryerson University) 1 1. Introduction By permitting countries to form free trade agreements

More information

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercise - Quantity competition 1 Take firm 1 s perspective Total revenue is R(q 1 = (4 q 1 q q 1 and, hence, marginal revenue is MR 1 (q 1 = 4 q 1 q Marginal cost is MC

More information

ECON 442: Quantitative Trade Models. Jack Rossbach

ECON 442: Quantitative Trade Models. Jack Rossbach ECON 442: Quantitative Trade Models Jack Rossbach Instruments of Trade Policy Many instruments available to affect international trade flows and prices. Non-exhaustive list: Tariffs: Taxes on Imports.

More information

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich 1 Motivation How does an industry with successive oligopolies work? How do upstream

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model Economics Letters 60 (998) 55 6 Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model X. Henry Wang* Department of Economics, University of Missouri, Columbia, MO 65, USA Received 6 February 997; accepted

More information

Tourism and welfare enhancing export subsidies

Tourism and welfare enhancing export subsidies Tourism and welfare enhancing export subsidies Brian Copeland* Department of Economics University of British Columbia Preliminary and Incomplete Draft July 14, 2010 Email: copeland@econ.ubc.ca Address:

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

The WTO: Economic Underpinnings

The WTO: Economic Underpinnings W T O l e a r n i n g m o d u l e s The WTO: Economic Underpinnings Roberta Piermartini Economic Research and Statistics Division WTO (Version 1 st March 2007) Copyright WTO 2005-2006 1 List of slides

More information

Free entry and social efficiency in an open economy. Arghya Ghosh, Jonathan Lim, and Hodaka Morita

Free entry and social efficiency in an open economy. Arghya Ghosh, Jonathan Lim, and Hodaka Morita Free entry and social efficiency in an open economy Arghya Ghosh, Jonathan Lim, and Hodaka Morita Extended Abstract Is free entry desirable for social efficiency? While this important question has been

More information

International Trade

International Trade 4.58 International Trade Class notes on 5/6/03 Trade Policy Literature Key questions:. Why are countries protectionist? Can protectionism ever be optimal? Can e explain ho trade policies vary across countries,

More information

Strategic Trade Policy under Isoelastic Demand and Asymmetric Production Costs

Strategic Trade Policy under Isoelastic Demand and Asymmetric Production Costs Strategic Trade Policy under Isoelastic Demand and Asymmetric Production Costs Akio Matsumoto 1 Department of Economics Chuo University Nobuko Serizawa 2 Department of Economics Niigata University June

More information

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market Arijit Mukherjee University of Nottingham and The Leverhulme Centre for Research in Globalisation and Economic

More information

Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly. Abstract Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly Kangsik Choi Graduate School of International Studies. Pusan National University Abstract This paper investigates the simultaneous-move games

More information

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions Journal of Economics and Management, 2018, Vol. 14, No. 1, 1-31 License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions Masahiko Hattori Faculty

More information

Estimating Trade Restrictiveness Indices

Estimating Trade Restrictiveness Indices Estimating Trade Restrictiveness Indices The World Bank - DECRG-Trade SUMMARY The World Bank Development Economics Research Group -Trade - has developed a series of indices of trade restrictiveness covering

More information

Sheffield Economic Research Paper Series. SERP Number:

Sheffield Economic Research Paper Series. SERP Number: Sheffield Economic Research Paper Series SERP Number: 2009013 ISSN 1749-8368 Tim James and Jolian McHardy Department of Economics, College of Business, Arizona State University, USA Department of Economics,

More information

Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination

Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination By POL ANTRÀS AND ROBERT W. STAIGER The terms-of-trade theory of trade agreements holds that governments are attracted to trade agreements as a means

More information

Environmental Regulations, International Trade and Strategic Behavior

Environmental Regulations, International Trade and Strategic Behavior Environmental Regulations, International Trade and Strategic Behavior Savas Alpay 1, a and S. Cem Karaman b a Department of Economics, Bilkent University, Bilkent, 06533 Ankara, Turkey b Department of

More information

Export Subsidies versus Export Quotas with Incompletely Informed Policy Makers

Export Subsidies versus Export Quotas with Incompletely Informed Policy Makers Export Subsidies versus Export Quotas with Incompletely Informed Policy Makers Jota Ishikawa Faculty of Economics Hitotsubashi University Tomohiro Kuroda Faculty of Economics Hitotsubashi University February

More information

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I)

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I) 14.581 Week 13 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 13) Trade Policy Theory (I) Spring 2013 1 / 29 Trade Policy Literature A Brief Overview Key questions:

More information

Economic Integration, Trade Diversion, and Welfare Change

Economic Integration, Trade Diversion, and Welfare Change Economic Integration, Trade Diversion, and Welfare Change Juyoung Cheong and Kar-yiu Wong University of Washington November 30, 2007 (Version 1.1. Comments Most Welcome) Abstract This paper examines how

More information

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership Attila Tasnádi Department of Mathematics, Budapest University of Economic Sciences and Public Administration, H-1093 Budapest, Fővám tér 8, Hungary

More information

Economics 452 International Trade Theory and Policy Fall 2014

Economics 452 International Trade Theory and Policy Fall 2014 blue A FINAL EXAM Economics 452 International Trade Theory and Policy Fall 2014 FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT 1. Although the richest OECD countries historically have been the biggest recipients of inward

More information

Market Access and the Reform of State Trading Enterprises

Market Access and the Reform of State Trading Enterprises Market Access and the Reform of State Trading Enterprises Steve McCorriston University of Exeter and Donald MacLaren University of Melbourne April 005 A contributed paper presented at the 8 th Annual Conference

More information

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key EconS 44 Strategy and Game Theory Homework #5 Answer Key Exercise #1 Collusion among N doctors Consider an infinitely repeated game, in which there are nn 3 doctors, who have created a partnership. In

More information

WHEN THE THREAT IS STRONGER THAN THE EXECUTION: TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND WELFARE UNDER OLIGOPOLY

WHEN THE THREAT IS STRONGER THAN THE EXECUTION: TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND WELFARE UNDER OLIGOPOLY WHEN THE THREAT IS STRONGER THAN THE EXECUTION: TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND WELFARE UNDER OLIGOPOLY Dermot Leahy Maynooth University J. Peter Neary University of Oxford, December 31, 2015 CEPR and CESifo

More information

Social Optimality in the Two-Party Case

Social Optimality in the Two-Party Case Web App p.1 Web Appendix for Daughety and Reinganum, Markets, Torts and Social Inefficiency The Rand Journal of Economics, 37(2), Summer 2006, pp. 300-23. ***** Please note the following two typos in the

More information

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form Chapter 6 Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form 1 Market game: one seller and one buyer 2 players, a buyer and a seller Buyer receives red card Ace=11, King = Queen = Jack = 10, 9,, 2 Number represents

More information

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by Ioannis Pinopoulos 1 May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract A well-known result in oligopoly theory regarding one-tier industries is that the

More information

Antidumping Regulation and the Byrd Amendment: Does Revenue Redistribution Dissuade Dumping?

Antidumping Regulation and the Byrd Amendment: Does Revenue Redistribution Dissuade Dumping? Antidumping Regulation and the Byrd Amendment: Does Revenue Redistribution Dissuade Dumping? Rod Falvey a and Sarut Wittayarungruangsri b a University of Nottingham b Fiscal Policy Research Institute,

More information

Antidumping Protection and R&D Investment *

Antidumping Protection and R&D Investment * Antidumping Protection and R&D Investment * Xiwang Gao and Kaz Miyagiwa Emory University This version, September 03, 2003 Abstract In recent years, use of antidumping protection has spread throughout the

More information

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION A10282W1 FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION Preliminary Examination for Philosophy, Politics and Economics Preliminary Examination for Economics and Management Preliminary Examination for History and Economics SECOND

More information

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma Recap Last class (September 20, 2016) Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma Today (October 13, 2016) Finitely

More information

Free-Trade Areas and Welfare: An Equilibrium Analysis. Sang-Seung Yi* This version: April 21, Abstract

Free-Trade Areas and Welfare: An Equilibrium Analysis. Sang-Seung Yi* This version: April 21, Abstract Free-Trade Areas and Welfare: An Equilibrium Analysis Sang-Seung Yi* This version: April 21, 1998 Abstract This paper examines the welfare effects of the formation of a free-trade area (a set of countries

More information

Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets

Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets 経済研究 ( 明治学院大学 ) 第 155 号 2018 年 Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets Jinryo TAKASAKI I Introduction Many governments have been attempting to make public sectors more efficient. Some socialistic

More information

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers Chapter : Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers Learning Objectives Students should learn to:. Extend the reaction function ideas developed in the Cournot duopoly model to a model of sequential behavior

More information

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition Kai Hao Yang /2/207 In this lecture, we will apply the concepts in game theory to study oligopoly. In short, unlike

More information

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach Toyokazu Naito and Stephen Polasky* Oregon State University Address: Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics Oregon

More information

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. 1 Oligopoly The key feature of the oligopoly (and to some extent, the monopolistically competitive market) market structure is that one rm

More information

ECON 4415: International Economics. Autumn Karen Helene Ulltveit-Moe. Lecture 8: TRADE AND OLIGOPOLY

ECON 4415: International Economics. Autumn Karen Helene Ulltveit-Moe. Lecture 8: TRADE AND OLIGOPOLY ECON 4415: International Economics Autumn 2006 Karen Helene Ulltveit-Moe Lecture 8: TRADE AND OLIGOPOLY 1 Imperfect competition, and reciprocal dumping "The segmented market perception": each firm perceives

More information

Discussion Papers. Andreas Haufler and Michael Pflüger. International Commodity Taxation under Monopolistic Competition

Discussion Papers. Andreas Haufler and Michael Pflüger. International Commodity Taxation under Monopolistic Competition Discussion Papers Andreas Haufler and Michael Pflüger International Commodity Taxation under Monopolistic Competition Berlin, March 2003 Opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author and do

More information

the Gain on Home A Note Bias and Tel: +27 Working April 2016

the Gain on Home A Note Bias and Tel: +27 Working April 2016 University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series A Note on Home Bias and the Gain from Non-Preferential Taxation Kaushal Kishore University of Pretoria Working Paper: 206-32 April 206

More information

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions ECO 300 Fall 2005 November 22 OLIGOPOLY PART 2 PRISONER S DILEMMA Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, 481-2 Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions X = 12 2 P + P, X = 12 2 P + P 1 1 2 2 2 1

More information

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS ECO410H: Practice Questions SOLUTIONS 1. (a) The unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is s = (M, M). (b) The unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is s = (R4, C3). (c) The two Nash equilibria are

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104 Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104 Problem Set 1 1. Each of n farmers can costlessly produce as much wheat as she chooses. Suppose that the kth farmer produces W k, so that the total amount of what produced

More information

1of 23. Learning Objectives

1of 23. Learning Objectives Learning Objectives 1. Describe the various situations in which a country may rationally choose to protect some industries. 2. List the most common fallacious arguments in favour of protection. 3. Explain

More information

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly Chapter 13 Application: Implicit Cartels This chapter discusses many important subgame-perfect equilibrium strategies in optimal cartel, using the linear Cournot oligopoly as the stage game. For game theory

More information

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry Lin, Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 7(2), December 2014, 17-31 17 Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically

More information

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley Michael P. Devereux Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation This version: September 3, 2014 Abstract

More information

Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy with Endogenous Labor Supply * 1

Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy with Endogenous Labor Supply * 1 Volume 22, Number 1, June 1997 Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy with Endogenous Labor Supply * 1 Michael Ka-yiu Fung ** 2and Jinli Zeng ***M Utilizing a two-sector general equilibrium model with endogenous

More information

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains Maria-Augusta Miceli University of Rome Sapienza Claudia Nardone University of Rome Sapienza October 8, 06 Abstract We here want to analyze how the imperfect competition

More information

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly Prerequisites Almost essential Monopoly Useful, but optional Game Theory: Strategy and Equilibrium DUOPOLY MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell 1 Overview Duopoly Background How the basic

More information

Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price

Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price Vol. 7, 2013-6 February 20, 2013 http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2013-6 Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price Henrik Vetter Abstract A digressive tax such as a variable rate

More information

CEMARE Research Paper 167. Fishery share systems and ITQ markets: who should pay for quota? A Hatcher CEMARE

CEMARE Research Paper 167. Fishery share systems and ITQ markets: who should pay for quota? A Hatcher CEMARE CEMARE Research Paper 167 Fishery share systems and ITQ markets: who should pay for quota? A Hatcher CEMARE University of Portsmouth St. George s Building 141 High Street Portsmouth PO1 2HY United Kingdom

More information

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location This Version: 9 May 006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location Nathaniel P.S. Cook Abstract This paper examines

More information

Trade negotiations when market access matters

Trade negotiations when market access matters Trade negotiations when market access matters Monika Mrázová, University of Oxford Preliminary draft, November 28, 2008 Abstract This paper analyses trade negotiations in an oligopolistic setting that

More information

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. (a) The monopolist solves: The first order condition is max Π(Q) = Q(a bq) cq. Q a Q c = 0, or equivalently, Q = a c, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated

More information

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS 2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS JEL Classification: H21,H3,H41,H43 Keywords: Second best, excess burden, public input. Remarks 1. A version of this chapter has been accepted

More information

Antidumping, Price Undertaking and Technology Transfer

Antidumping, Price Undertaking and Technology Transfer Antidumping, Price Undertaking and Technology Transfer Cheng-Hau Peng Department of Economics, Fu-Jen Catholic University Hong Hwang Department of Economics, National Taiwan University and RCHSS, Academia

More information

Chapter 9 Nontariff Barriers and the New Protectionism

Chapter 9 Nontariff Barriers and the New Protectionism Chapter 9 Nontariff Barriers and the New Protectionism Nontariff barriers to trade (NTBS) are now perhaps as much as ten times more restrictive of international trade than tariffs. Walters and Blake, The

More information

Switching Costs and the foreign Firm s Entry

Switching Costs and the foreign Firm s Entry MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Switching Costs and the foreign Firm s Entry Toru Kikuchi 2008 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/8093/ MPRA Paper No. 8093, posted 4. April 2008 06:34 UTC Switching

More information

Insurance and Monopoly Power in a Mixed Private/Public Hospital System. Donald J. Wright

Insurance and Monopoly Power in a Mixed Private/Public Hospital System. Donald J. Wright Insurance and Monopoly Power in a Mixed Private/Public Hospital System Donald J. Wright December 2004 Abstract Consumers, when ill, often have the choice of being treated for free in a public hospital

More information

3. Trade and Development

3. Trade and Development Trade and Development Table of Contents 3. Trade and Development the arguments a) Effects of an import tariff b) Effects of an export subsidy c) Arguments for trade policy 164 a) Effects of an import tariff

More information

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly Volume 9, Issue Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo Daisuke Shimizu Faculty of Economics, Gakushuin

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

Coordinating tariff reduction and domestic tax reform under imperfect competition Keen, M.; Ligthart, J.E.

Coordinating tariff reduction and domestic tax reform under imperfect competition Keen, M.; Ligthart, J.E. Tilburg University Coordinating tariff reduction and domestic tax reform under imperfect competition Keen, M.; Ligthart, J.E. Published in: Review of International Economics Document version: Peer reviewed

More information

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly Working Paper Series No. 09007(Econ) China Economics and Management Academy China Institute for Advanced Study Central University of Finance and Economics Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective

More information

Discussion Papers. Andreas Haufler and Michael Pflüger. Market structure and the taxation of international trade

Discussion Papers. Andreas Haufler and Michael Pflüger. Market structure and the taxation of international trade Discussion Papers Andreas Haufler and Michael Pflüger Market structure and the taxation of international trade Berlin, September 2003 Opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not

More information

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries Munich Discussion Paper No. 2006-30 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität

More information

International Economics B 6. Applications of international oligopoly models

International Economics B 6. Applications of international oligopoly models .. International Economics B 6. Applications of international oligopoly models Akihiko Yanase (Graduate School of Economics) November 24, 2016 1 / 24 Applications of international oligopoly models Strategic

More information