Financial Contracting Theory Meets the Real World: An Empirical Analysis of Venture Capital Contracts

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Financial Contracting Theory Meets the Real World: An Empirical Analysis of Venture Capital Contracts"

Transcription

1 Preliminary and incomplete Financial Contracting Theory Meets the Real World: An Empirical Analysis of Venture Capital Contracts by Steven N. Kaplan and Per Strömberg* First Draft: March 1999 This Draft: July 1999 Abstract In this paper, we compare the characteristics of real world financial contracts to their counterparts in financial contracting theory. We do so by conducting a detailed study of actual contracts between venture capitalists (VCs) and entrepreneurs. VCs are the real world entities who arguably most closely approximate the investors of theory. (1) The distinguishing characteristic of VC financings is that they allow VCs to separately allocate cash flow rights, voting rights, board rights, liquidation rights, and other control rights. We explicitly measure and report the allocation of these rights. (2) While convertible securities are used most frequently, VCs also implement a similar allocation of rights using combinations of multiple classes of common stock and straight preferred stock. (3) Cash flow rights, voting rights, control rights, and future financings are frequently contingent on observable measures of financial and non-financial performance. These state contingencies are more common in early stage financings. (4) If the company performs poorly, the VCs obtain full control. As company performance improves, the entrepreneur retains / obtains more control rights. If the company performs very well, the VCs retain their cash flow rights, but relinquish most of their control and liquidation rights. The entrepreneur s cash flow rights also increase with firm performance. (5) It is common for VCs to include non-compete and vesting provisions aimed at mitigating the potential hold-up problem between the entrepreneur and the investor. We interpret our results as most consistent with the theoretical work of Aghion and Bolton (1992) and Dewatripont and Tirole (1994). No theory, however, appears to explain the multi-dimensional nature of the allocation of control rights in these financings. * Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago. This research has been supported by the Kauffman Foundation, by the Lynde and Harry Bradley Foundation and the Olin Foundation through grants to the Center for the Study of the Economy and the State, and by the Center For Research in Security Prices. Peter Lang and Konstantin Semyonov provided excellent research assistance. Amar Bhide, Mathias Dewatripont, Ron Gilson, Rick Green, Jeremy Stein, Luigi Zingales and seminar participants at Maryland, NYU, and the Stockholm School of Economics provided helpful comments. We are grateful to the venture capital partnerships for providing data. Ted Meyer was particularly helpful. Address correspondence to Per Stromberg, Graduate School of Business, The University of Chicago, 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, IL or at per.stromberg@gsb.uchicago.edu.

2 1. Introduction. There is a large academic literature in financial contracting theory. The papers in this literature often begin with a situation in which an investor negotiates with an entrepreneur over the financing of a project or company. These theoretical papers typically make a number of different assumptions concerning the nature of these negotiations. These assumptions concern observability of actions, contractibility of actions, the ability to renegotiate, and the nature of information and uncertainty. Given the assumptions and the models, the papers then generate predictions. For example, a key assumption in Hart and Moore (1998) is that firm output is observable by outsiders, but not verifiable. As a result, it is not possible to write contracts on output. Despite the large volume of theory, relatively little empirical work exists that compares the characteristics of real world financial contracts to their counterparts in financial contracting theory. In this paper, we attempt to inform theory by conducting a detailed study of actual contracts between venture capitalists and entrepreneurs. Venture capitalists (VCs) are real world entities who most closely approximate the investors of theory. VCs have strong incentives to maximize value, but, at the same time, receive few or no private benefits of control. In describing these contracts, we consider the appropriateness of different assumptions and predictions in financial contracting theory. In this version of the paper, we study detailed information on thirty venture capital investments in twenty-three portfolio companies by six venture capital firms 1. Future versions of this paper will utilize detailed information on venture capital investments in more than one hundred portfolio companies by at least ten venture capital firms. For each portfolio company 1 We use the terms venture capital firm and venture capital partnership interchangeably.

3 investment, we asked the VC firm to provide the contractual agreements governing each financing round in which the firm participated. We also asked the VC firm to provide the company s business plan, internal analyses evaluating the investment, and information on subsequent performance. We describe the contracts between the portfolio companies / entrepreneurs and the VCs in great detail. We then consider how well these contracts are described by the assumptions and predictions embodied in different financial contracting theories: (1) "traditional" principal agent theories such as Harris and Raviv (1979); (2) control theories in which cash-flows are verifiable but actions are not such as Aghion and Bolton (1992) and Dewatripont and Tirole (1994); (3) stealing theories in which cash-flows are neither observable nor verifiable such as Hart and Moore (1998) and Gale and Hellwig (1982); (4) agency theories in which the inalienability of human capital is paramount such as Hart and Moore (1994); (5) theories of asymmetric information such as Myers and Majluf (1984); and (6) theories specific to venture capital financing. We obtain the following findings. First, a key feature of VC financings is that they allow VCs to separately allocate cash flow rights, voting rights, board rights, liquidation rights, and other control rights. We explicitly measure and report the allocation of these rights. We believe our measurements are more comprehensive and substantially more detailed than those in any previous work. Second, while convertible securities are used most frequently, VCs also implement the same set of rights using combinations of multiple classes of common stock and straight preferred stock.. 2

4 Third, cash flow rights, voting rights, control rights, and future financings are frequently contingent on observable measures of financial and non-financial performance. These state contingencies are more common in early stage financings. Fourth, these rights are allocated such that if the company performs poorly, the VCs obtain full control. As company performance improves, the entrepreneur retains / obtains more control rights. If the company performs very well, the VCs retain their cash flow rights, but relinquish most of their control and liquidation rights. Fifth, we find that it is common for VCs to include non-compete and vesting provisions aimed at mitigating the potential hold-up problem between the entrepreneur and the investor. These provisions are more common in early stage financings where it is more likely that the hold-up problem is more severe. We interpret our results as most consistent with the theoretical work of Aghion and Bolton (1992) and Dewatripont and Tirole (1994). Dewatripont and Tirole (1994), in particular, capture the gradual shift in control rights that we document. No theory, however, appears to explain the multi-dimensional nature of the allocation of control rights in these financings. In comparing financial contracting theories to real world contracts, we believe this paper breaks new ground. In describing venture capital contracts, our paper extends previous work by Sahlman (1990), Gompers (1997), and Black and Gilson (1998). Sahlman (1990) describes the basic deal structures used in venture capital investments and the economic rationales for them. His is the first detailed discussion of these issues that we are aware of. We extend Sahlman (1990) in several ways. First, Sahlman bases his analysis on forty stock-purchase agreements from a broad range of VCs. His analysis, however, is almost entirely qualitative. He does not present any systematic description and analysis of those 3

5 agreements. Second, Sahlman focuses on the typical set of terms and does not report or analyze the broad range of terms and contingencies. This is particularly important for considering the appropriateness of the assumptions and predictions of the theories that distinguish between cash flow rights, control rights, and liquidation rights. 2 The data and approach in this paper are perhaps most closely related to those in Gompers (1997). His paper is similar to ours in that he describes aspects of venture capital contracts. This paper differs, however, in a number of respects. First, Gompers had access to only a subset of the contracts and information that we have analyzed. He does not analyze data on ownership (cash flow rights), voting rights, liquidation rights, or descriptions of the underlying businesses (from the business plans). Second, Gompers selected his sample to consist entirely of investments in convertible preferred stock, therefore, eliminating some of the important variation that we find in these financings. Third, Gompers theoretical and empirical focus is on explaining the use of convertible securities rather than understanding the relationship between venture capital financings and different financial contracting theories. Black and Gilson (1998) consider explanations for the greater vitality of the venture capital market in stock market- versus bank-centered capital markets. In so doing, they describe different aspects of venture capital contracts. They make the argument, which we confirm as important, that automatic conversion provisions provide important non-monetary incentives to entrepreneurs because they transfer control from the VC to the entrepreneur if the entrepreneur performs well. Like Sahlman (1990), however, they do not present any systematic evidence on the contracts themselves. 2 Because much of the new financial contracting theory had yet to be written, it is not surprising that Sahlman (1990) did not address these issues. 4

6 The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the assumptions and predictions of a number of prominent financial contracting theories. Section 3 describes our sample. Section 4 presents our results. Section 5 discusses our results in relation to the assumptions and predictions of existing theories. Section 6 summarizes and discusses our results. 2. Theories In this section, we summarize a number of financial contracting theories. For each theory, we describe the key contracting assumptions and predictions. We group these theories by their general approach. The theories we study are meant to be representative, not exhaustive. More extensive overviews can be found in Allen and Winton (1995) or Harris and Raviv (1992). The security design theories interpret financial contracts as the solution to conflicts of interest or agency problems between investors and the entrepreneur. A conflict exists because the entrepreneur must transfer a portion of the profits generated by the project back to external investors in return for their financing. The entrepreneur will not take the optimal action because he does not get all the monetary benefits from taking that action, while alternative actions give other benefits to the entrepreneur. The different security design theories assume different types of conflicts of interest in choice of actions. These include: (1) not exerting the optimal amount of costly effort; (2) taking actions that yield private benefits rather than monetary benefits; (3) spending resources on perks or stealing; (4) holding up investors by threatening to leave the project. 5

7 2.1 Traditional" principal agent theories The traditional principal-agency approach, pioneered by Holmstrom (1979), assumes that the agent s effort is unobservable to the principal. There exist, however, one or more observable and contractible signals that are correlated with effort. The optimal incentive contract ensures that the agent puts in enough effort by making the agent s compensation dependent on the outcome of the signals. In the context of a financing problem, the signal is typically output or profits. If the agent is risk-neutral, the optimal contract involves making compensation as sensitive as possible to the signals, i.e. as high pay-performance sensitivity as possible. Harris and Raviv (1979) show that with a risk-neutral principal and agent, and no wealth constraints, the optimal financing contract is to give a fixed payment to the investor and make the manager the residual claimant. The problem with this solution, however, is that the entrepreneur is generally wealth constrained, which is why he needs to borrow in the first place. Hence, contracts where the entrepreneur pays the investor in the case of bad outcomes are not feasible. Innes (1990) shows that with a risk-neutral, wealth constrained manager, and the added assumption that payouts to investors and the manager have to be monotone in profits, the optimal contract corresponds to giving the investor a debt claim. The results of this class of models are quite sensitive to a number of alternative assumptions, e.g. the number of actions and signals, and the risk preferences of the agent. With risk-aversion, for example, pay-performance sensitivity will decline with the risk of the firm. One potential limitation of these models is that they are all about cash incentives and compensation. Ownership is relevant only as it affects pure cash-flow rights. To the extent they 6

8 are important, these models cannot explain the allocation of control rights between investors and the entrepreneur such as voting rights, board membership, and liquidation rights. 2.2 "Control theories": cash-flow verifiable but not actions In the traditional principal-agent models, actions are unobservable, but signals such as output or monetary results are contractible. The control theories change these assumptions by assuming that actions are indeed observable, but not verifiable. Output and monetary benefits are contractible. As a result, control rights that determine who chooses which action to take will be important. The control theories build on the incomplete contracting literature, pioneered by Grossman and Hart (1986). Two important papers that take this approach to security design are Aghion and Bolton (1992) and Dewatripont and Tirole (1994). In Aghion and Bolton (1992), the project yields both monetary benefits, i.e. profits, that are verifiable and can be transferred to outside investors, and private benefits or actions that are non-verifiable and only go to the entrepreneur. The magnitude of these benefits, in turn, depends on what (non-verifiable) action that is taken with respect to the project. In order to finance the project, the entrepreneur gives up some of the monetary benefits to investors. This introduces a conflict of interest. If the entrepreneur is in control, he has the incentive to take actions that increase private benefits at the expense of monetary profits. In order to induce the entrepreneur to take the efficient action, the investor has to pay the entrepreneur (i.e. renegotiate the contract), rendering the project less profitable ex ante. As a consequence, the expected monetary profits might decline so much that the project would can no longer be financed. 7

9 To overcome this problem, the entrepreneur can give up control of the project to investors. The investors will then take the action that maximizes monetary profits, making the project more financially viable. The cost of this to the entrepreneur is that the investors do not care at all about his private benefits when choosing their action. Since the entrepreneur is wealth constrained, he will not be able to pay the investor to avoid this ex-post inefficiency and no renegotiation will occur. It is optimal to give as much control to the entrepreneur as possible, given that the investors participation constraint is met. When full entrepreneur control is not feasible, it is optimal to give the investor control in enough states of the world to break even, e.g. in the worst states of the world where profits are likely to be low. Aghion and Bolton (1992) point out that a debt contract that transfers control to investors in default states has this feature. Dewatripont and Tirole (1994) build on Aghion and Bolton (1992) by focusing on the optimal correlation between control rights and cash flow rights. They add a prior effort problem (as in "traditional theories"), and assume that the person in control also will have the choice between two non-verifiable actions a more risky and a less risky one. The entrepreneur always prefers the riskier action (the other one involving for example a partial or total scaling down of operations). The optimal contract calls for providing traditional pay-for-performance incentives to induce high entrepreneurial effort. In addition, however, the probability of the less risky action being taken should increase when performance deteriorates. To achieve this objective, control has to be gradually transferred, as performance deteriorates, to an outside investor who is increasingly less sympathetic to the entrepreneur and increasingly more likely to choose the less risky action. As a result, the party in control should look more and more like a debtholder (because debtholders prefer less risk) when things get worse, while more control should be transferred to the entrepreneur or to an equityholder (because equityholders prefer more risk) as 8

10 performance improves. Dewatripont and Tirole (1994) show that the contract can be implemented either with a single outsider in control with a contingent security, or with contingent control and noncontingent securities. 2.3 Stealing theories : cash flows neither observable nor verifiable One criticism of the control theories see Hart (1995) is that changes in control in those models do not necessarily coincide with default on a contracted payment. Hence, these theories do not explain one of the distinguishing features of real-world debt contracts. These critics argue that it may be more appropriate to assume that not only actions, but also profits and cash flows themselves are non-observable or non-verifiable. As a result, there is no way to stop the entrepreneur from stealing the profits from the venture if he so wishes. There are two main strands to this literature. The first one, the Costly State Verification (CSV) models of Townsend (1979), Gale and Hellwig (1982), and others, assumes that profits are completely unobservable, unless a verification cost is paid. The other strand, represented by Hart and Moore (1998), Bolton and Scharfstein (1990), and Fluck (1998), assumes that profits are observable but not verifiable to outsiders and courts. The resulting optimal contracts are very similar for the two approaches. The optimal financial claim is a debt-like claim in which (1) the entrepreneur promises a fixed payment to the investor; and (2) the investor takes control of the project and liquidates the assets (or, in the CSV-models, pays the verification cost and takes all the remaining profits) if the payment is not made. Fluck (1998) and Myers (1998) show that an equity-like claim can also work in an infinite period setting, where the investors have the right to replace the entrepreneur (in which case they get the value of the firm without the entrepreneur, i.e. the "liquidation value") and will do so whenever the dividend is too low. 9

11 2.4 Inalienability of human capital theories Hart (1995) concedes that the assumption of unlimited stealing opportunities that underlies the models of the previous section might be a bit extreme (p.102). Hart and Moore (1994) relax the stealing assumption, while developing a model that has a similar intuition or prediction. They assume that (1) the firm s value with the entrepreneur exceeds its liquidation value and (2) the entrepreneur / manager cannot commit not to leave firm. Because the firm is worth less without him, the entrepreneur can threaten to leave the firm unless any promised payment is negotiated down closer to the liquidation value. Hence, external financing capacity is limited by the value of the firm's assets without the entrepreneur and by the amount of the going concern value that the investor would be able to capture in a renegotiation. The optimal contract will call for a debt security, where control is transferred to the investor if the promised payment is not fulfilled, in which case the firm is liquidated. The size of the promised debt payment is limited by the liquidation value of the assets and by the relative bargaining power of the investor. 2.5 Asymmetric information theories Finally, there are two other security design approaches in the literature. The first group is the theories that extend Myers and Majluf's (1984) signaling model to a security design setting. These theories assume that the entrepreneur has private information about the quality of the venture. Given the assumption that the entrepreneur designs the security to offer investors (rather than the other way around), and that payoffs have to be monotone, Nachman and Noe (1994) and Duffie and DeMarzo (1999) show that the optimal contract will be debt. The intuition is that in order to minimize the cost of mispricing, the good firms will have an incentive to issue the 10

12 least informationally sensitive security which turns out to be debt. If agents are risk-averse and not wealth constrained, entrepreneurs can also signal higher quality by retaining a larger stake of the firm, as in Leland and Pyle (1977). In these models, the greater the asymmetric information, the greater the stake that will be retained by the entrepreneur. An alternative approach that perhaps is more relevant for venture capital is to assume private information on behalf of the investors rather than the entrepreneurs. Garmaise (1998) develops a model of security design where venture capitalists who have privately observed signals about the project bid for the entrepreneur's venture using different contract provisions. The optimal strategy for the venture capitalist involves offering to take a debt claim when the private signal is low, and an equity claim when the private signal is high. 2.6 Venture capital-specific theories In recent years, a number of theories have been proposed that specifically address venture capital contracting. Most of these theories have aimed at explaining the use of convertible securities in these financings (based on the results in Sahlman (1990). Berglof (1994) introduces one of the first theories of venture capital contracting. In this paper, the financial contract is designed to maximize the ex ante expected value in a future sale of the firm to new buyer. In his set-up, cash-flows are observable but not verifiable (as in Hart and Moore (1998)); the entrepreneur derives non-transferable private benefits; and the future buyer can expropriate some of the assets in the bad state after having acquired control of the firm (at the expense of any minority shareholders). Control rights determine who will bargain with the future buyer, while cash flow rights determine how much of the future buyer s productivity gain will pass on to the holder. The optimal contract resembles a convertible security in the 11

13 sense that it gives the entrepreneur control in good state, with the venture capitalist getting all cash-flow rights, and the venture capitalist control in the bad state as well as cash-flow rights. Giving control rights to the entrepreneur in the good state enables him to get fully compensated for his private benefits in the bargaining with the future buyer in this state. Giving the venture capitalist control in the bad state allows him to get compensated for being diluted by the new buyer after the sale. Cornelli and Yosha (1998) provide a theory of convertibles and staged financings. In their paper, the entrepreneur can engage in short-term signal manipulation, making short-term profits seeming higher than they actually are. When financing is staged, the entrepreneur has an incentive to manipulate profits in order to make the firm look good enough for the venture capitalist to finance the next round. The model shows that with a properly designed convertible security, the entrepreneur no longer has an incentive to manipulate. This is achieved by giving the VC more of the cash flow rights upon conversion, the better the signal. Repullo and Suarez (1999) solve for the optimal security design in a setting where both the venture capitalist and the entrepreneur have to provide unobservable effort. In their model, the project needs financing in two stages, start-up and expansion. All (positive) cash flows occur after the expansion stage. At startup, the project s profitability is unknown. At expansion, the profitability is known, but not verifiable so that the initial contract cannot be written contingent on that profitability. VC effort is valuable only in the second period and the second period payoffs are dependent on the effort that the VC and the entrepreneur provide. In the optimal contract in their model, the first period investors who might not be the VC receive a payoff of zero if profitability is low and a fixed fraction of the firm if profitability is high. The authors argue that this is consistent with the use of convertible debt in early-stage 12

14 venture financings. When the potential profitability is verifiable and can be contracted on, Repullo and Suarez find that the VCs finance the second stage if the signal is high enough and receive a fixed percentage of the company s equity. Hellman (1998) also focuses on a case where the venture capitalist has to be provided optimal incentives to provide effort. Similar to the set-up of Aghion and Bolton (1991), the project yields verifiable monetary benefits that can be pledged to investors and nonverifiable private benefits that accrue only to the entrepreneur. In addition, at an intermediate stage, the venture capitalist can engage in a costly search to replace the original entrepreneur with a new manager who might add more value. The original entrepreneur will not leave voluntarily, however, because he loses his private benefits. Hence, in order to replace the entrepreneur, the venture capitalist has to have full control rights. The optimal financing contract calls for: (1) giving the entrepreneur all equity compensation which increases his effort and decreases his resistance towards replacement; and (2) giving the venture capitalist control if the benefits from replacing management are high enough. 2.7 Assumptions and Predictions Exhibits 1 and 2 summarize the assumptions and predictions of the different theories. 3. Sample In this preliminary version of the paper, we analyze thirty VC investments in twentythree portfolio companies by six venture capital partnerships. In future versions of this paper, we will analyze investments more than one hundred portfolio companies by at least twelve venture capital partnerships. 13

15 3.1 Description To obtain this sample, we asked each VC to provide detailed information on as many of their portfolio company investments as they were willing to provide. For each of these companies, we asked the VC to provide the term sheet as well as the stock purchase and security purchase agreements for each financing round in which they participated. These documents typically include the financing terms, the firm s equity ownership investors, founders, management, etc. and any contingencies to future financing. We also asked the VC to provide (if available) the portfolio company s business plan at the time of the financing, the VC s internal analysis of the investment, and the subsequent portfolio company financial performance. Finally, we also requested that the VC provide the private placement memoranda / offering documents for the funds that they have managed over the sample period. With these data, we will be able to construct cross-sectional tests as well as to test for any portfolio company selection bias. Table 1 presents summary information for our sample. As mentioned above, panel A indicates that we have thirty investments in twenty-three portfolio companies by six VC firms. Thirteen of these investments are seed or start-up rounds. I.e., the firms receiving financing either had just begun operating or were not yet operating. The remaining investments are later stage rounds in which the firms were already operating. We have the contractual documents for all thirty investments; business plans for twelve; and some internal VC description of the investment for twelve. Panel B shows that all but two of the financing rounds were completed between 1996 and We view the young age of the sample as positive for two reasons. First, our findings will 14

16 reflect current practice in venture capital financing. Second, it is unlikely that the VCs selected many of these the companies based on the final outcome because the final outcome of many of those investments is still unresolved. Panel C shows that the portfolio companies were provided by six venture capital firms with no more than seven of the twenty-three from any one VC. Panel C also indicates that future versions of this paper will incorporate a substantially larger and richer data set that will allow for more cross-sectional analysis as well as more general conclusions. We possess (but have not yet analyzed) data on investments in more than 100 portfolio companies by twelve venture capital firms. Finally, Panel D indicates the amounts of the sample financings. The VCs committed a median of $5 million in equity in each financing round. (This amount is the total for all VCs investing in the round.) The VCs actually disbursed a median $3.8 million at the time the round closed. The mean amounts are somewhat higher than the medians because of two or three relatively large financing commitments. 3.2 Sample selection issues In this section, we discuss potential selection issues concerning our sample. Our sample of portfolio companies and financings is not a random sample in that we obtained the data from six (and ultimately twelve) venture capital firms with whom we have a relationship. We do not believe that this selection is of much concern to our results because we are not attempting to measure performance. Rather, we are attempting to characterize what contracts look like in general and, perhaps more importantly, what contracts are possible. The financings in our sample certainly show what contracts are possible. 15

17 The contracts also represent financings by more than the six VC firms that provided data. The twenty-three companies in our current sample received VC financing from twenty-four additional VC firms either in the financing round in our sample or in other financing rounds. A total of thirty different VC firms, therefore, invested under the terms of the contracts in our sample. This suggests that the financings in our sample are likely to be representative of VC contracts in general. The more likely bias in our sample is that we have selected VC firms (or have chosen to give us data) that are better than average and that the contracts in our sample may be above average in some sense. If this is so, we believe this strengthens our results because we are more likely to have identified sophisticated, value maximizing principals. In future versions of this paper, we expect to be able to test for VC quality effects by comparing the contracts to measures of VC performance. 4. Results In this section, we describe the contracts between the portfolio companies / entrepreneurs and the VCs in great detail. We first describe the securities issued. We then describe how these contracts allocate cash-flow rights, voting rights, board rights, and liquidation rights. Last, we consider in more detail the contingencies involved in allocating those rights. In the analysis, we distinguish between early stage financings and later stage financings. Early stage financings are financing rounds that provide seed or start-up financing. These financing rounds occur, respectively, before the company has been formed and in the first year of a company s existence. 3 Later stage rounds are all other rounds. This distinction is an 3 See Sahlman (1990). 16

18 interesting one because uncertainty about viability, inalienability, and verifiability of the company should be greater in early stage than in later stage rounds. This will be important in distinguishing among financial contracting theories. In future versions of this paper, we also will distinguish whether a round is the first one in which the company utilizes VC funding. This distinction is an interesting one because asymmetric information between the VC and the founders should be greater in the first VC round than in subsequent rounds. Again, this will be important in distinguishing among financial contracting theories. 4.1 Securities Panel D of table 1 reports the types of securities used in the thirty financing rounds. Consistent with Sahlman (1990) and Gompers (1997), convertible preferred stock is the most commonly used security, appearing in twenty-five of thirty financing rounds. Panel D also indicates, however, that VC financings do not always use convertible preferred stock. In fact, three of the thirty financing rounds (and three of the twenty-three portfolio companies) do not use any form of convertible security. Instead, they use multiple classes of stock or a combination of straight preferred and common stock. While the VC financings utilize different types of securities, the financings are similar in that they allow for different allocations of cash flow, voting, board, and liquidation rights. For example, in the financing that uses multiple classes of common stock, the VCs receive a different class of common stock than the founders who receive two classes of common stock. The VC class of common stock has voting, board, and liquidation rights that are different from the founder classes of common stock. The cash flow rights of the classes of common stock also 17

19 differ in that the two classes of founders stock vest under different conditions than the VC class (which vest immediately). 4.2 Cash flow rights Table 2 presents our results on cash flow rights. By cash flow rights, we mean the fraction of a portfolio company s equity value that different investors and management have a claim to. Measuring cash flow rights is not trivial, however, because many of the cash flow rights accorded to founders and management are contingent either on subsequent performance (through performance vesting) or on remaining with the company (through time vesting). Table 2, therefore, present three measures of cash flow rights. The first minimum VC ownership measures cash flow rights under the assumption that management meets all performance and time vesting milestones or contingencies. The second maximum founder and employees vesting measures cash flow rights under the assumption that all non-performance / time-vesting stock and options vest. The third maximum VC ownership measures cash flow rights if management does not meet any performance or time vesting milestones. Under each of the three measures, VC%, founders% and other% are, respectively, the percentage of cash flow rights owned by the venture capitalists, the founders, and others. Founders include the founding management team. Others include employees and previous non-vc investors. Panel A indicates that the VC controls roughly half the cash flow rights on average; founders roughly one-third; and others roughly one-sixth. These amounts should be of great interest to practitioners and academics. It suggests that substantial equity ownership on the part of founders / managers is desirable. On the other hand, it also indicates that founders / managers give up a large fraction of ownership. 18

20 Panels B, C, and D indicate that founders retain significantly larger ownership stakes in later stage financings compared to early stage ones. We suspect that this result is a function of the fact that founders of companies that receive VC funding for the first time in a later stage retain more equity ownership than founder of companies that receive VC funding for the first time in an early stage. Table 2 indicates that there are substantial state-contingencies built into the cash flow rights. The VC stake is a median of 7.9% lower (average of 11.5%) lower under full vesting and good performance compared to the minimum vesting, bad performance state. For early-stage companies, the average and median are roughly 18%. The state-contingency (i.e. the use of performance benchmarks and vesting) is significantly higher (at the 2.5% level) in earlier stage financings compared to later stage ones. This is consistent with the traditional principal-agent theories, because agency problems are presumably higher for earlier-stage companies. Payperformance sensitivities, therefore, should be greater for these companies. This is what we observe. 4.3 Voting rights Table 3 reports post-round voting rights. Voting rights measure the percentage of votes that investors and management have to effect corporate decisions. Most decisions are based on majority rule. As such, voting rights provide one measure of control rights. Board rights, described in the next section, provide another. In table 3, minimum (maximum) VC votes represents the minimum (maximum) votes the venture capitalists control based on subsequent management performance and stock vesting milestones or contingencies. % VC, % Founder, and % Neither control are, respectively, the 19

21 percentage of instances in which voting control is held by the venture capitalists, the founders, or neither. Switch in control indicates the percentage of instances in which voting control can switch based on subsequent performance. Table 3 indicates that VCs have a voting majority in 60% of all financings in the minimum contingency case. VCs control a majority of votes in 77% of the early stage financings (in the minimum contingency case) versus 47% for later stage financings. In the maximum VC vote contingency cases, VCs control a voting majority in 75% of the financings comprised of 92% of early stage and 65% of later stage rounds. The differences between early and later stage rounds are statistically significant at the 10% level. These results indicate that we do observe state-contingent control rights (i.e. not only in case of default on a debt payment), consistent with Aghion and Bolton. In 16% of the financings, in fact, we see voting control switching depending on state-contingencies. 4.4 Board rights Board rights and board seats also have a large effect on the rights to control corporate decisions. While they tend to be related to voting rights, they need not be identical. We distinguish between normal board rights that reflect the board rights or composition at the completion of the financing from adverse state board rights that reflect board rights or composition if the portfolio company performs poorly or reaches an adverse state. We distinguish between three kinds of board members VCs, founders, and outsiders. VC seats are board seats that are reserved for or controlled by venture capitalists. Founder seats are board seats that are reserved for or controlled by the founders / entrepreneurs. Outsider seats 20

22 are board seats that are to be filled by individuals mutually agreed upon by the VCs and the founders / entrepreneurs. Table 4 reports the board results. The boards have an average of 6.3 members and a median of 5 members. These boards are appreciably smaller than those of public companies. 4 Overall, the VC has the majority of the board seats in 40% of the cases, the founder in 20% of the cases, and neither in 40% of the cases. Interestingly, the VCs are less likely to have board control than they are to have voting control. VC board control is somewhat more common for early-stage financings compared to later stage, although the differences are not statistically significant. State-contingent board provisions (i.e. the VC gets full control of the board in the bad state) are present in about a quarter of the cases. This provides another important example of state-contingent control rights. 4.5 Liquidation rights Much of the theoretical security design literature stresses the importance of liquidation rights. Being able to liquidate, or threaten to liquidate, the firm s assets if the firm defaults is often seen to be the main way for an investor to ensure repayment. Table 5 describes the liquidation rights in our venture capital financings. VC financings utilize two types of liquidation rights. The first type consists of the rights a VC has in liquidation or bankruptcy i.e., seniority rights. The second type consists of the rights a VC has to force the company to repay or liquidate the VCs investment In all our financings, the venture capitalist has seniority in case of liquidation or bankruptcy. The liquidation rights, on average, equal the amount of funds that the venture 4 For example, see Yermack (1998) or Gertner and Kaplan (1996). 21

23 capitalist has invested (excluding cumulative dividends, as discussed below). In this sense, the importance of liquidation rights is supported in the data. The venture capitalist does not always hold the most senior claim, however. Claims senior (typically debt) or at par with the venture capitalist average 41% of the investment of the venture capitalist. Such claims are significantly more common for later stage financings than for seed and start-up financings. This is mainly due to the fact that debt is more common in later stages compared to earlier ones. Even though all financings give liquidation rights to the venture capitalists, there are some cross-sectional differences in how strong these are for different deals. One common way of making the liquidation rights stronger is by giving the investor cumulative preferred dividends. Even though these are dividends, and strictly speaking do not have to be paid out, they will accumulate and be added to the liquidation claim. Cumulative preferred dividends are present in 62% of our cases. They are slightly more common in early stage financings, although not significantly so. Optional redemption and put provisions also are commonly used to strengthen the liquidation rights of the venture capitalist's investment. These provisions give the venture capitalist the right after some period time to demand that the firm redeems the venture capitalists claim, typically at liquidation value (or occasionally, at the maximum of the liquidation value and "fair market value"). This is very similar to the right to repayment of principal at the maturity of a debt claim. Without this provision, the liquidation right loses much of its bite because there are no other contracted payments to the venture capitalist that the firm could default on. Optional redemption or put provisions are present in 86% of our financings, and are slightly, but not significantly more common for early stage companies. The maturity of these provisions averages 5.4 years. 22

24 Finally, 31% of our contracts give liquidation (or redemption) rights for other events than default. The most common practice is to give the right to redeem at liquidation value at a sale, merger or IPO, as an alternative to converting the claim to equity if the share price is too low. A small number of contracts, however, give redemption rights at other events, such as upon the termination of the firm's founder. 4.6 Contingencies As mentioned previously, different theories make different assumptions concerning what it is and is not possible to write contracts on. For example, it is common among some financial contracting theorists to assume that firm output is observable by outsiders, but not verifiable. For example, Hart and Moore (1998) assume that the entrepreneur and outside investors can observe firm output, but they cannot write contracts on that output because courts cannot verify the firm output. As a result, it is not possible to write contracts on output. In this section, we report the extent to which contracts between venture capitalists and entrepreneurs are written contingent on subsequent output, performance, or actions. We also detail the types of output that such contracts are written on. Table 6 reports specific examples of contingencies in the VC financings in our sample. Panel A shows that one-third of the financing rounds include provisions that are contingent on subsequent financial performance. In one financing round, the VCs contractually obtain voting control from the entrepreneur if the firm s EBIT -- earnings before interest and taxes -- falls below a mutually agreed upon amount. In another financing round, VCs obtain board control if a firm s net worth falls below a threshold. Net worth, in this instance, is a measure of a company s cumulative cash flow. These examples indicate that VCs are able to write (and presumably 23

25 enforce) contracts in which control rights are contingent on subsequent output quite independently of cash flow rights. Panel B shows that thirty percent of the financing rounds include provisions that are contingent on subsequent non-financial performance. In one instance, share vesting is contingent on product functionality or performance. In several others, vesting is contingent on FDA or patent approvals. The disbursal of committed funding also can be contingent on non-financial performance. For example, one financing was contingent on successfully completing clinical tests. Panel C reports that over one-third of the financing rounds include contingencies based on certain actions being taken. For example, in different rounds, the disbursal of committed funding is contingent on hiring new executives, developing new facilities, and completing a new business plan. Presumably, these actions are both observable and verifiable. Finally, panel D indicates that contingencies based on the sale of securities are included in thirty percent of the financings. In particular, ownership and vesting are commonly linked to a subsequent initial public offering or sale of the company. Overall, table 6 generates two strong results. First, investors (VCs) commonly write (and presumably enforce) contracts in which control rights are contingent on subsequent measures of financial and non-financial performance or output. Second, there is a great deal of variation in the contingencies in these contracts. The contingencies appear to be related to the performance measure that is most important to the investors and the company. Table 7 quantifies the qualitative information on contingencies in table 6. Panel A indicates the contingencies based on subsequent financial or non-financial performance, actions, or sales of securities are used in sixty percent of the financings. Interestingly, state contingent 24

26 contracting is more common (although not significantly so) in early stage financings than in later stage one. Table 7 also indicates that 40% of the sample financings themselves are partially contingent on the attainment of some milestone. In these financing, the VCs provide only a portion of the total funding commitment at the closing or signing of the financing. Additional funding is provided contingent on subsequent performance and actions. In two financings, the VC provided only 5% of its total commitment at closing with the rest being contingent. 4.7 Other terms VC financings include a number of additional terms and conditions. Bartlett (1995) and Levin (1998) detail many of these. In this section, we describe several of the terms and conditions that we believe are relevant to the financial contracting theories Vesting and non-compete clauses The inalienability of human capital theories of Hart and Moore (1994) assume that the entrepreneur cannot contractually commit to stay with the firm. Even though it is not possible to write enforceable contracts that force the entrepreneur to stay with a firm, there are contractual provisions that make it more costly for the entrepreneur to leave. In real-world contracts, two methods are commonly used to make it costly for the entrepreneur to leave the firm. First, the entrepreneur s shares can vest over time. This means that the company receives or can buy back any unvested shares for some low value if the entrepreneur leaves. The earlier the entrepreneur leaves, the more shares are still unvested. Second, the VCs can require the entrepreneur to sign a non-compete contract with the firm that prohibits him from working for 25

27 another firm in the same industry for some period of time in case he leaves. Both of these provisions improve the bargaining power of the VCs if the entrepreneur tries to hold up the VC. Table 8 shows that the VC financings in our sample commonly utilize both founder vesting and non-compete clauses. Non-compete clauses are used in 60% of the portfolio companies while founder vesting is in just fewer than half of the financing rounds. Moreover, both vesting and non-compete clauses are used significantly more frequently in early stage financings than in later stage ones. For seed and start-up firms, vesting is present in 70% of all cases and non-compete clauses in 80% of the cases, while for later stage companies the corresponding numbers are 25% and 40%, respectively. If we exclude California companies, where non-compete clauses are arguably not enforceable (see Gilson, 1998), non-compete clauses are used in 90% of all start-up financings. Hence, for early stage firms, where it is more likely that the entrepreneur is crucial for the firm s operations and the potential hold-up problem is more severe, the contracts practically always include contractual provisions mitigating entrepreneurial hold-up Automatic conversion It is common for securities in venture capital financings to include automatic conversion provisions. Under these provisions, the security held by the venture capitalists convertible preferred stock, convertible debt, or a class of common stock automatically converts into common stock under certain conditions. These conditions generally, although not exclusively, relate to an initial public offering (IPO) and require the IPO to exceed a designated common stock price, dollar amount of proceeds, and / or market capitalization for the company. 26

The Center for Research in Security Prices Working Paper No. 513 March 2000

The Center for Research in Security Prices Working Paper No. 513 March 2000 The Center for Research in Security Prices Working Paper No. 513 March 2000 University of Chicago Graduate School of Business Financial Contracting Theory Meets the Real World: An Empirical Analysis of

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FINANCIAL CONTRACTING THEORY MEETS THE REAL WORLD: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF VENTURE CAPITAL CONTRACTS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FINANCIAL CONTRACTING THEORY MEETS THE REAL WORLD: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF VENTURE CAPITAL CONTRACTS NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FINANCIAL CONTRACTING THEORY MEETS THE REAL WORLD: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF VENTURE CAPITAL CONTRACTS Steven N. Kaplan Per Strömberg Working Paper 7660 http://www.nber.org/papers/w7660

More information

Financial Contracting Theory Meets the Real World: An Empirical Analysis of Venture Capital Contracts

Financial Contracting Theory Meets the Real World: An Empirical Analysis of Venture Capital Contracts Financial Contracting Theory Meets the Real World: An Empirical Analysis of Venture Capital Contracts by Steven N. Kaplan and Per Strömberg* First Draft: March 1999 This Draft: February 2002 Abstract We

More information

Characteristics, Contracts, and Actions: Evidence From Venture Capitalist Analyses

Characteristics, Contracts, and Actions: Evidence From Venture Capitalist Analyses Preliminary. Characteristics, Contracts, and Actions: Evidence From Venture Capitalist Analyses by Steven N. Kaplan and Per Strömberg* First Draft: August 2000 This Draft: December 2001 Abstract We consider

More information

The Center for Research in Security Prices Working Paper No. 536 January 2002

The Center for Research in Security Prices Working Paper No. 536 January 2002 The Center for Research in Security Prices Working Paper No. 536 January 2002 University of Chicago Graduate School of Business Characteristics, Contracts and Actions: Evidence From Venture Capitalist

More information

Where do securities come from

Where do securities come from Where do securities come from We view it as natural to trade common stocks WHY? Coase s policemen Pricing Assumptions on market trading? Predictions? Partial Equilibrium or GE economies (risk spanning)

More information

Angels, Venture Capitalists, and Entrepreneurs: A Dynamic Model of Private Equity Financing

Angels, Venture Capitalists, and Entrepreneurs: A Dynamic Model of Private Equity Financing Angels, Venture Capitalists, and Entrepreneurs: A Dynamic Model of Private Equity Financing Thomas J Chemmanur* and Zhaohui Chen** Oct., 31, 2001 *Finance department, Carroll school of management, Boston

More information

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure Corporate Financial Management Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure As we discussed in previous lectures, two extreme results, namely the irrelevance of capital structure and 100 percent

More information

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Online Appendix for Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Giacomo Rodano Bank of Italy Nicolas Serrano-Velarde Bocconi University December 23, 2014 Emanuele Tarantino University of Mannheim 1 1 Reorganization,

More information

Convertible Securities and Venture Capital Finance

Convertible Securities and Venture Capital Finance Convertible Securities and Venture Capital Finance Klaus M. Schmidt University of Munich, CESifo and CEPR This version: March 21, 2002 Abstract: This paper offers a new explanation for the prevalent use

More information

Venture Capitalists versus Angels: The Dynamics of. Private Firm Financing Contracts

Venture Capitalists versus Angels: The Dynamics of. Private Firm Financing Contracts Venture Capitalists versus Angels: The Dynamics of Private Firm Financing Contracts Thomas J Chemmanur Carroll School of Management Boston College Zhaohui Chen McIntire School of Commerce University of

More information

Venture Capitalists versus Angels: The Dynamics of Private Firm Financing Contracts

Venture Capitalists versus Angels: The Dynamics of Private Firm Financing Contracts Venture Capitalists versus Angels: The Dynamics of Private Firm Financing Contracts Thomas J Chemmanur* and Zhaohui Chen** March, 2006 *Professor of Finance, Carroll School of Management, Boston College,

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

Control rights in venturecontracts

Control rights in venturecontracts Control rights in venturecontracts and convertible securities. Klaas Schouten ANR 978012 Bachelor Thesis August 2007 Tilburg University Department of Finance Supervisor: I. Loncarski Bachelor Thesis 2

More information

Rethinking Incomplete Contracts

Rethinking Incomplete Contracts Rethinking Incomplete Contracts By Oliver Hart Chicago November, 2010 It is generally accepted that the contracts that parties even sophisticated ones -- write are often significantly incomplete. Some

More information

OWNERSHIP AND RESIDUAL RIGHTS OF CONTROL Ownership is usually considered the best way to incentivize economic agents:

OWNERSHIP AND RESIDUAL RIGHTS OF CONTROL Ownership is usually considered the best way to incentivize economic agents: OWNERSHIP AND RESIDUAL RIGHTS OF CONTROL Ownership is usually considered the best way to incentivize economic agents: To create To protect To increase The value of their own assets 1 How can ownership

More information

Financial Contracting with Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard

Financial Contracting with Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard Financial Contracting with Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard Mark Wahrenburg 1 1 University of Cologne, Albertus Magnus Platz, 5093 Köln, Germany. Abstract This paper studies the problem of a bank which

More information

Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin. The allocation of authority under limited liability

Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin. The allocation of authority under limited liability Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin Nr. 2005/25 VOLKSWIRTSCHAFTLICHE REIHE The allocation of authority under limited liability Kerstin Puschke ISBN

More information

Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics

Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics Fisher College of Business Working Paper Series Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics Changing the Nexus: The Evolution and Renegotiation of Venture Capital Contracts Ola Bengtsson,

More information

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński Decision Making in Manufacturing and Services Vol. 9 2015 No. 1 pp. 79 88 Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment Andrzej Paliński Abstract. This paper presents a model of bank-loan repayment as

More information

Angels, Venture Capitalists, and Entrepreneurs: A Dynamic Model of Private Equity Financing

Angels, Venture Capitalists, and Entrepreneurs: A Dynamic Model of Private Equity Financing Angels, Venture Capitalists, and Entrepreneurs: A Dynamic Model of Private Equity Financing Thomas J Chemmanur* and Zhaohui Chen** First Version: October, 2001 Current Version: October, 2003 *Associate

More information

Convertibles and Milestones in Staged Financing

Convertibles and Milestones in Staged Financing Convertibles and Milestones in Staged Financing Lanfang Wang 1 and Susheng Wang 2 June 2008 Abstract: This paper investigates a popular financing strategy whereby the manager of a firm uses convertibles

More information

Moral hazard, hold-up, and the optimal allocation of control rights

Moral hazard, hold-up, and the optimal allocation of control rights RAND Journal of Economics Vol. 42, No. 4, Winter 2011 pp. 705 728 Moral hazard, hold-up, and the optimal allocation of control rights Vijay Yerramilli I examine the optimal allocation of control rights

More information

Lecture 1: Introduction, Optimal financing contracts, Debt

Lecture 1: Introduction, Optimal financing contracts, Debt Corporate finance theory studies how firms are financed (public and private debt, equity, retained earnings); Jensen and Meckling (1976) introduced agency costs in corporate finance theory (not only the

More information

FIN CORPORATE FINANCE Spring Office: CBA 6.246, Phone: ,

FIN CORPORATE FINANCE Spring Office: CBA 6.246, Phone: , FIN 395.5 CORPORATE FINANCE Spring 2018 Instructor: Aydoğan Altı Office: CBA 6.246, Phone: 232-9374, Email: aydogan.alti@mccombs.utexas.edu Office Hours: Wednesdays 1:00 pm to 2:00 pm Course Description

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Preferred Stock in Venture Capital Financing

Preferred Stock in Venture Capital Financing Preferred Stock in Venture Capital Financing Filippo Ippolito May 23, 2007 Abstract We develop a model in which cash-constrained entrepreneurs seek a venture capitalist (VC) to finance their firm. Costly

More information

Entrepreneurial Finance and Private Equity Business Rosenwald 425 Fall 2003 (773) Course Introduction / Outline

Entrepreneurial Finance and Private Equity Business Rosenwald 425 Fall 2003 (773) Course Introduction / Outline University of Chicago Graduate School of Business Entrepreneurial Finance and Private Equity Steven Kaplan Business 34101 Rosenwald 425 Fall 2003 (773) 702-4513 Course Introduction / Outline A. REQUIRED

More information

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM Course content Why do firms exist? And why do some firms cease to exist? How are firms financed? How are firms managed? These questions are analysed by using various models

More information

A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds

A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds Dawei Fang Centre for Finance, Gothenburg University Abstract: We take a portfolio approach, based on simple agency conflicts between

More information

POSTURING IN VENTURE CAPITAL. Naveen Khanna and Richmond D. Mathews. February 25, 2013

POSTURING IN VENTURE CAPITAL. Naveen Khanna and Richmond D. Mathews. February 25, 2013 POSTURING IN VENTURE CAPITAL Naveen Khanna and Richmond D. Mathews February 25, 2013 Abstract. We show how a VC s need to posture in later financing rounds solves the commitment problem inherent in stage

More information

FINANCIAL CONTRACTING. Oliver Hart* was of course extremely excited. Then I looked at the list of previous speakers and a sense of

FINANCIAL CONTRACTING. Oliver Hart* was of course extremely excited. Then I looked at the list of previous speakers and a sense of October 2000 FINANCIAL CONTRACTING by Oliver Hart* It is a great honor to give the Nancy Schwartz lecture. When Ehud Kalai first asked me, I was of course extremely excited. Then I looked at the list of

More information

FINANCIAL CONTRACTING. Oliver Hart. Discussion Paper No /2001. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138

FINANCIAL CONTRACTING. Oliver Hart. Discussion Paper No /2001. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138 ISSN 1045-6333 FINANCIAL CONTRACTING Oliver Hart Discussion Paper No. 327 5/2001 Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138 The Center for Law, Economics, and Business is supported by a grant from the John

More information

Private Equity Lecture 3: Selection & monitoring of investments

Private Equity Lecture 3: Selection & monitoring of investments MSc in Investment Management Private Equity Lecture 3: Selection & monitoring of investments Course leader: Prof. Robert Cressy 1 Learning objectives To become familiar with a significant real-world US

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights? Leonardo Felli 15 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5 Property Rights Theory The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights? For an answer we need to distinguish

More information

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Corporate Control Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Managerial Discipline and Takeovers Managers often don t maximize the value of the firm; either because they are not capable

More information

Optimizing Entrepreneurial Ventures

Optimizing Entrepreneurial Ventures Master of Science Finance & Strategic Management Master Thesis October 7 th, 2015 Optimizing Entrepreneurial Ventures A theoretical approach Author: Niclas Baaring Herstal Supervisor: Peter Ove Christensen,

More information

SIMULATION RESULTS RELATIVE GENEROSITY. Chapter Three

SIMULATION RESULTS RELATIVE GENEROSITY. Chapter Three Chapter Three SIMULATION RESULTS This chapter summarizes our simulation results. We first discuss which system is more generous in terms of providing greater ACOL values or expected net lifetime wealth,

More information

Economics and Finance,

Economics and Finance, Economics and Finance, 2014-15 Lecture 5 - Corporate finance under asymmetric information: Moral hazard and access to external finance Luca Deidda UNISS, DiSEA, CRENoS October 2014 Luca Deidda (UNISS,

More information

An Analysis of the ESOP Protection Trust

An Analysis of the ESOP Protection Trust An Analysis of the ESOP Protection Trust Report prepared by: Francesco Bova 1 March 21 st, 2016 Abstract Using data from publicly-traded firms that have an ESOP, I assess the likelihood that: (1) a firm

More information

CONTRACT THEORY. Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

CONTRACT THEORY. Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England r CONTRACT THEORY Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England Preface xv 1 Introduction 1 1.1 Optimal Employment Contracts without Uncertainty, Hidden

More information

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know?

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? Preliminary Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? by Robert Harris*, Tim Jenkinson** and Steven N. Kaplan*** This Draft: September 9, 2011 Abstract We present time series evidence on the performance

More information

Rural Financial Intermediaries

Rural Financial Intermediaries Rural Financial Intermediaries 1. Limited Liability, Collateral and Its Substitutes 1 A striking empirical fact about the operation of rural financial markets is how markedly the conditions of access can

More information

Grandstanding and Venture Capital Firms in Newly Established IPO Markets

Grandstanding and Venture Capital Firms in Newly Established IPO Markets The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance Volume 9 Issue 3 Fall 2004 Article 7 December 2004 Grandstanding and Venture Capital Firms in Newly Established IPO Markets Nobuhiko Hibara University of Saskatchewan

More information

Portfolio Rebalancing:

Portfolio Rebalancing: Portfolio Rebalancing: A Guide For Institutional Investors May 2012 PREPARED BY Nat Kellogg, CFA Associate Director of Research Eric Przybylinski, CAIA Senior Research Analyst Abstract Failure to rebalance

More information

Bankruptcy, Warrants, and State-Contingent Changes in the Ownership of Control*

Bankruptcy, Warrants, and State-Contingent Changes in the Ownership of Control* JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 6, 347 379 (1997) ARTICLE NO. JF970225 Bankruptcy, Warrants, and State-Contingent Changes in the Ownership of Control* Avner Kalay Tel Aviv University, Tel Aviv, Israel,

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

The Role of the Value Added by the Venture Capitalists in Timing and Extent of IPOs

The Role of the Value Added by the Venture Capitalists in Timing and Extent of IPOs No. 2003/25 The Role of the Value Added by the Venture Capitalists in Timing and Extent of IPOs Tereza Tykvová Center for Financial Studies an der Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universität Taunusanlage 6 D-60329

More information

Relationship Between Capital Structure and Firm Performance, Evidence From Growth Enterprise Market in China

Relationship Between Capital Structure and Firm Performance, Evidence From Growth Enterprise Market in China Management Science and Engineering Vol. 9, No. 1, 2015, pp. 45-49 DOI: 10.3968/6322 ISSN 1913-0341 [Print] ISSN 1913-035X [Online] www.cscanada.net www.cscanada.org Relationship Between Capital Structure

More information

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision Modern Applied Science; Vol. 9, No. 4; 2015 ISSN 1913-1844 E-ISSN 1913-1852 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision Seok Weon Lee 1 1 Division

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES VENTURE CAPITAL CONTRACTING AND SYNDICATION: AN EXPERIMENT IN COMPUTATIONAL CORPORATE FINANCE

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES VENTURE CAPITAL CONTRACTING AND SYNDICATION: AN EXPERIMENT IN COMPUTATIONAL CORPORATE FINANCE NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES VENTURE CAPITAL CONTRACTING AND SYNDICATION: AN EXPERIMENT IN COMPUTATIONAL CORPORATE FINANCE Zsuzsanna Fluck Kedran Garrison Stewart C. Myers Working Paper 624 http://www.nber.org/papers/w624

More information

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility and Coordination Failures What makes financial systems fragile? What causes crises

More information

Online Payday Loan Payments

Online Payday Loan Payments April 2016 EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:01 a.m., April 20, 2016 Online Payday Loan Payments Table of contents Table of contents... 1 1. Introduction... 2 2. Data... 5 3. Re-presentments... 8 3.1 Payment Request

More information

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Appendices A A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Given the structure of venture capital financing just described, the potential mechanisms by which shocks might propagate across companies in

More information

Triparty Contracts in Long Term Financing

Triparty Contracts in Long Term Financing Antonio Mello and Erwan Quintin Wisconsin School of Business September 21, 2016 Mezzanine Finance Mezzanine financing is basically debt capital that gives the lender the rights to convert to an ownership

More information

Venture Capital Financing with Staged Investment, Agency Conflicts and Asymmetric Beliefs. Yahel Giat

Venture Capital Financing with Staged Investment, Agency Conflicts and Asymmetric Beliefs. Yahel Giat Venture Capital Financing with Staged Investment, Agency Conflicts and Asymmetric Beliefs A Thesis Presented to The Academic Faculty by Yahel Giat In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree

More information

An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting

An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting Ph.D. Seminar in Corporate Finance Lecture 4 An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting (Aghion-Bolton, Review of Economic Studies, 1982) S. Viswanathan The paper analyzes capital structure

More information

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Coase (1937) If the market is an efficient method of resource allocation, as argued by neoclassical economics, then why do so many transactions

More information

Venture Capital Contracts: Part II Entrepreneurial Finance - Spring Antoinette Schoar

Venture Capital Contracts: Part II Entrepreneurial Finance - Spring Antoinette Schoar Venture Capital Contracts: Part II Key Terms of VC Contracts Anti-Dilution Provisions Covenants/ Control Terms o Voting Rights/Board representation o Protective Provisions o Registration Rights Employee

More information

Working Paper October Book Review of

Working Paper October Book Review of Working Paper 04-06 October 2004 Book Review of Credit Risk: Pricing, Measurement, and Management by Darrell Duffie and Kenneth J. Singleton 2003, Princeton University Press, 396 pages Reviewer: Georges

More information

Problems with seniority based pay and possible solutions. Difficulties that arise and how to incentivize firm and worker towards the right incentives

Problems with seniority based pay and possible solutions. Difficulties that arise and how to incentivize firm and worker towards the right incentives Problems with seniority based pay and possible solutions Difficulties that arise and how to incentivize firm and worker towards the right incentives Master s Thesis Laurens Lennard Schiebroek Student number:

More information

Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse

Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse Tano Santos Columbia University Financial intermediaries, such as banks, perform many roles: they screen risks, evaluate and fund worthy

More information

Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings

Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings WORKING PAPER Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings Jeremy Burke, Angela A. Hung, and Jill E. Luoto RAND Labor & Population WR-1162 January 2017 This paper series made possible by the NIA funded

More information

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW. Contracts. I.1 Bargain Theory. I.2 Damages Part 1. I.3 Reliance

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW. Contracts. I.1 Bargain Theory. I.2 Damages Part 1. I.3 Reliance ECON 522 - DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW I Contracts When we were studying property law we were looking at situations in which the exchange of goods/services takes place at the time of trade, but sometimes

More information

Table of Contents Private Equity Glossary... 5

Table of Contents Private Equity Glossary... 5 Private Equity Glossary Sales Training Team November 5, 2010 Table of Contents 01 - Private Equity Glossary... 5 Acquisition... 5 Acquisition Finance... 5 Advisory Board... 5 Alternative Assets... 5 Angel

More information

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2018 1 / 36 Coase (1937) If the market is an efficient method of resource allocation, as argued by neoclassical economics, then why do so many transactions

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW DO LEGAL DIFFERENCES AND LEARNING AFFECT FINANCIAL CONTRACTS? Steven Kaplan Frederic Martel Per Stromberg

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW DO LEGAL DIFFERENCES AND LEARNING AFFECT FINANCIAL CONTRACTS? Steven Kaplan Frederic Martel Per Stromberg NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW DO LEGAL DIFFERENCES AND LEARNING AFFECT FINANCIAL CONTRACTS? Steven Kaplan Frederic Martel Per Stromberg Working Paper 10097 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10097 NATIONAL BUREAU

More information

The Making of a Winning Term Sheet: Understanding What Founders Want

The Making of a Winning Term Sheet: Understanding What Founders Want The Making of a Winning Term Sheet: Understanding What Founders Want Part II. Vesting Acceleration, Reallocation of Founder s Stock, Option Pool Dilution and Founder Liquidity By Jonathan D. Gworek mbbp.com

More information

Choice of financing by independent or bankaffiliated

Choice of financing by independent or bankaffiliated Choice of financing by independent or bankaffiliated venture capital firm by Guillaume Andrieu CRG, IAE-University of Toulouse 1 January 008 Abstract This article studies to what extend the affiliation

More information

Some Puzzles. Stock Splits

Some Puzzles. Stock Splits Some Puzzles Stock Splits When stock splits are announced, stock prices go up by 2-3 percent. Some of this is explained by the fact that stock splits are often accompanied by an increase in dividends.

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6. Separation of Ownership and Control

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6. Separation of Ownership and Control Leonardo Felli 16 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6 Separation of Ownership and Control The definition of ownership considered is limited to an environment in which the whole ownership

More information

JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING

JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING Our investment philosophy is built upon over 30 years of groundbreaking equity research. Many of the concepts derived from that research have now become

More information

Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1]

Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1] The Determinants of Capital Structure in Stock Exchange Listed Non Financial Firms in Pakistan By Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1] and Attaullah Shah 2[2] 1[1] Professor & Dean Faculty of Business Administration

More information

SUMMARY OF THEORIES IN CAPITAL STRUCTURE DECISIONS

SUMMARY OF THEORIES IN CAPITAL STRUCTURE DECISIONS SUMMARY OF THEORIES IN CAPITAL STRUCTURE DECISIONS Herczeg Adrienn University of Debrecen Centre of Agricultural Sciences Faculty of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development herczega@agr.unideb.hu

More information

Basic Assumptions (1)

Basic Assumptions (1) Basic Assumptions (1) An entrepreneur (borrower). An investment project requiring fixed investment I. The entrepreneur has cash on hand (or liquid securities) A < I. To implement the project the entrepreneur

More information

When times are mysterious serious numbers are eager to please. Musician, Paul Simon, in the lyrics to his song When Numbers Get Serious

When times are mysterious serious numbers are eager to please. Musician, Paul Simon, in the lyrics to his song When Numbers Get Serious CASE: E-95 DATE: 03/14/01 (REV D 04/20/06) A NOTE ON VALUATION OF VENTURE CAPITAL DEALS When times are mysterious serious numbers are eager to please. Musician, Paul Simon, in the lyrics to his song When

More information

DETERMINANTS OF DEBT CAPACITY. 1st set of transparencies. Tunis, May Jean TIROLE

DETERMINANTS OF DEBT CAPACITY. 1st set of transparencies. Tunis, May Jean TIROLE DETERMINANTS OF DEBT CAPACITY 1st set of transparencies Tunis, May 2005 Jean TIROLE I. INTRODUCTION Adam Smith (1776) - Berle-Means (1932) Agency problem Principal outsiders/investors/lenders Agent insiders/managers/entrepreneur

More information

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Those taking the FINAL have THREE hours Part A (Glaeser): 55

More information

Maximizing the value of distressed assets: Bankruptcy law and the efficient reorganization of firms

Maximizing the value of distressed assets: Bankruptcy law and the efficient reorganization of firms Maximizing the value of distressed assets: Bankruptcy law and the efficient reorganization of firms by David C. Smith* and Per Strömberg** First Draft: October 2003 This Draft: March 2004 Abstract We argue

More information

American Law & Economics Association Annual Meetings

American Law & Economics Association Annual Meetings American Law & Economics Association Annual Meetings Year 2004 Paper 34 Staging of Venture Financing, Investor Opportunism, and Patent Law Jochen Bigus University of Osnabrück This working paper site is

More information

Peer Monitoring and Venture Capital Expertise: Theory and Evidence on Syndicate Formation and the Dynamics of VC Interactions

Peer Monitoring and Venture Capital Expertise: Theory and Evidence on Syndicate Formation and the Dynamics of VC Interactions Peer Monitoring and Venture Capital Expertise: Theory and Evidence on Syndicate Formation and the Dynamics of VC Interactions Thomas J. Chemmanur* and Xuan Tian** Current Version: March 2009 *Professor

More information

EX-ANTE EFFICIENCY OF BANKRUPTCY PROCEDURES. Leonardo Felli. October, 1996

EX-ANTE EFFICIENCY OF BANKRUPTCY PROCEDURES. Leonardo Felli. October, 1996 EX-ANTE EFFICIENCY OF BANKRUPTCY PROCEDURES Francesca Cornelli (London Business School) Leonardo Felli (London School of Economics) October, 1996 Abstract. This paper suggests a framework to analyze the

More information

CHAPTER 3 INVESTMENT STRATEGY AND VENTURE CAPITAL

CHAPTER 3 INVESTMENT STRATEGY AND VENTURE CAPITAL CHAPTER 3 INVESTMENT STRATEGY AND VENTURE CAPITAL This chapter provides a basic explanation of what is an investment strategy as well as a comprehensive background of the concept of venture capital and

More information

Appendix 6-B THE FIFO/LIFO CHOICE: EMPIRICAL STUDIES

Appendix 6-B THE FIFO/LIFO CHOICE: EMPIRICAL STUDIES Appendix 6-B THE FIFO/LIFO CHOICE: EMPIRICAL STUDIES As noted in the chapter, the LIFO to FIFO choice provides an ideal research topic as the choice has 1. conflicting income and cash flow (tax effect)

More information

CHAPTER 17 INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT. by Alistair Byrne, PhD, CFA

CHAPTER 17 INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT. by Alistair Byrne, PhD, CFA CHAPTER 17 INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT by Alistair Byrne, PhD, CFA LEARNING OUTCOMES After completing this chapter, you should be able to do the following: a Describe systematic risk and specific risk; b Describe

More information

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector Bengt Holmstrom and Jean Tirole April 3, 2017 Holmstrom and Tirole Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector April 3, 2017

More information

MODELING AN EXIT STRATEGY FOR ISLAMIC VENTURE CAPITAL FINANCE

MODELING AN EXIT STRATEGY FOR ISLAMIC VENTURE CAPITAL FINANCE MODELING AN EXIT STRATEGY FOR ISLAMIC VENTURE CAITAL FINANCE Tariqullah Khan and Boulem BenDjilali Without clear exit routes, venture capital cannot be provided efficiently. In this paper, we present an

More information

Has Persistence Persisted in Private Equity? Evidence From Buyout and Venture Capital Funds

Has Persistence Persisted in Private Equity? Evidence From Buyout and Venture Capital Funds Has Persistence Persisted in Private Equity? Evidence From Buyout and Venture Capital s Robert S. Harris*, Tim Jenkinson**, Steven N. Kaplan*** and Ruediger Stucke**** Abstract The conventional wisdom

More information

Design and Renegotiation of Debt Covenants

Design and Renegotiation of Debt Covenants Design and Renegotiation of Debt Covenants Nicolae Garleanu Jeffrey Zwiebel October, 2003 Abstract We analyze the design and renegotiation of covenants in debt contracts as a particular example of the

More information

A Back-up Quarterback View of Mezzanine Finance

A Back-up Quarterback View of Mezzanine Finance A Back-up Quarterback View of Mezzanine Finance Antonio Mello and Erwan Quintin Wisconsin School of Business August 14, 2015 Mezzanine Finance Mezzanine financing is basically debt capital that gives the

More information

Optimal Dynamic Contracts in Financial Intermediation: With an Application to Venture Capital Financing

Optimal Dynamic Contracts in Financial Intermediation: With an Application to Venture Capital Financing Optimal Dynamic Contracts in Financial Intermediation: With an Application to Venture Capital Financing Igor Salitskiy November 14, 2013 Abstract This paper extends the costly state verication model from

More information

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan; University of New Orleans ScholarWorks@UNO Department of Economics and Finance Working Papers, 1991-2006 Department of Economics and Finance 1-1-2006 Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using

More information

Financial Infos. Issue (26) Venture Capital. The venture capitalist provides

Financial Infos. Issue (26) Venture Capital. The venture capitalist provides Venture Capital Financial Infos Issue (26) Venture capital is financing that investors provide to startup companies and small businesses that are believed to have longterm growth potential. For startups

More information

Managerial Overconfidence, Moral Hazard Problems, and

Managerial Overconfidence, Moral Hazard Problems, and Managerial Overconfidence, Moral Hazard Problems, and Excessive Life-cycle Debt Sensitivity. Richard Fairchild, School of Management, University of Bath, UK March 27 th, 2009 Abstract We analyse the effects

More information

Appendix CA-15. Central Bank of Bahrain Rulebook. Volume 1: Conventional Banks

Appendix CA-15. Central Bank of Bahrain Rulebook. Volume 1: Conventional Banks Appendix CA-15 Supervisory Framework for the Use of Backtesting in Conjunction with the Internal Models Approach to Market Risk Capital Requirements I. Introduction 1. This Appendix presents the framework

More information

This short article examines the

This short article examines the WEIDONG TIAN is a professor of finance and distinguished professor in risk management and insurance the University of North Carolina at Charlotte in Charlotte, NC. wtian1@uncc.edu Contingent Capital as

More information

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation Afrasiab Mirza Department of Economics University of Birmingham a.mirza@bham.ac.uk Frank Strobel Department of Economics University of Birmingham f.strobel@bham.ac.uk

More information

The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1

The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1 Preservation The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1 Kenneth R. Spong Senior Policy Economist, Banking Studies and Structure, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Richard J. Sullivan Senior

More information

Protecting the Legal Interests of Founders in a Startup Emerging Technology Company

Protecting the Legal Interests of Founders in a Startup Emerging Technology Company Protecting the Legal Interests of Founders in a Startup Emerging Technology Company By Jonathan D. Gworek MORSE BARNES -BROWN PENDLETON PC The law firm built for business. SM mbbp.com Business Technology

More information

Dynamic Smart Beta Investing Relative Risk Control and Tactical Bets, Making the Most of Smart Betas

Dynamic Smart Beta Investing Relative Risk Control and Tactical Bets, Making the Most of Smart Betas Dynamic Smart Beta Investing Relative Risk Control and Tactical Bets, Making the Most of Smart Betas Koris International June 2014 Emilien Audeguil Research & Development ORIAS n 13000579 (www.orias.fr).

More information