THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS. This Version: 14 September 2008

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS. This Version: 14 September 2008"

Transcription

1 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS KENNETH R. AHERN UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN ROSS SCHOOL OF BUSINESS Abstract Why are repeat acquirers early abnormal returns higher than those from later acquisitions? This paper argues that acquirers minimize integration and transaction costs by choosing an optimal target size. As acquirers get larger, they optimally choose targets of larger absolute size, but smaller relative size, leading to declining returns. Using a panel dataset of repeat acquirers over two decades, empirical tests support this argument. In contrast, I find no support for alternative explanations of declining returns based on hubris and diminishing opportunity sets, and only weak support for agency explanations. In addition, using new econometric techniques, I reject the popular theory that declining returns result from market anticipation of later deals. This Version: 14 September 2008 JEL Classification: G30, G32, G34 Keywords: Mergers and acquisitions, repeat acquirers, corporate governance, agency, hubris This paper is an extension of chapter two of my doctoral dissertation completed at UCLA. I am extremely grateful to Antonio Bernardo, Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, and J. Fred Weston for advice and support. I also especially thank David Robinson, Karin Thorburn, Roni Michaely, and Katrina Ellis. Comments provided by Raffaella Giacomini, Marc Martos-Vila, MP Narayanan, Han Kim, Geoffrey Tate, Uday Rajan, Mike Stegemoller, Liu Yang, and seminar participants at the 2008 AFA Annual Meeting, 2006 FMA Annual Meeting, the 2006 US and European FMA Doctoral Seminars, the Anderson School at UCLA, UCLA Department of Economics IO Workshop, London Business School, Penn State, the University of British Columbia, Virginia Tech, Michigan, Purdue, Maryland, and Vanderbilt improved this paper significantly. I gratefully acknowledge the financial support from the Research Program on Takeovers, Restructuring, and Governance at the Anderson School, UCLA. Please direct correspondence to Kenneth R. Ahern, Ross School of Business, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor MI Telephone: (734) Fax: (734) kenahern@umich.edu.

2 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS Abstract Why are repeat acquirers early abnormal returns higher than those from later acquisitions? This paper argues that acquirers minimize integration and transaction costs by choosing an optimal target size. As acquirers get larger, they optimally choose targets of larger absolute size, but smaller relative size, leading to declining returns. Using a panel dataset of repeat acquirers over two decades, empirical tests support this argument. In contrast, I find no support for alternative explanations of declining returns based on hubris and diminishing opportunity sets, and only weak support for agency explanations. In addition, using new econometric techniques, I reject the popular theory that declining returns result from market anticipation of later deals. JEL Classification: G30, G32, G34 Keywords: Mergers and acquisitions, repeat acquirers, corporate governance, agency, hubris

3 1. Introduction The vast majority of research on mergers and acquisitions assumes M&As are singular firm events. Yet in a sample of 12,942 mergers from 1980 to 2004, I find that only 38% of deals are made by first-time acquirers. Furthermore, the most active ten percent of the firms in the sample account for 35% of all deals. Repeat acquirers are the norm, not the exception. The few studies that account for repeat acquisitions find that a firm s announcement returns decline substantially over subsequent deals (Fuller, Netter, and Stegemoller, 2002; Aktas, de Bodt, and Roll, 2007b). In my sample, acquirers have an average three-day abnormal announcement return of 3.19% on the first deal, declining to -0.11% for fifth and later deals. This paper empirically addresses the question raised by this pattern: Why do repeat acquirers have declining returns? Whereas academic studies have concentrated on strategic fit and over-payment as key determinants of merger success, consulting firms and the business press have emphasized the role of target size on the costs of due diligence and integration strategies. For example, the 2002 merger of equals between Hewlett-Packard and Compaq was widely presumed to be doomed to failure at its announcement. However, 16 months after the merger, costs had been reduced by $3.5 billion, roughly 5%. By 2005, HP s stock had risen 46% compared to rival Dell s rise of 2% and IBM s decline of 23%. Compaq s CFO, Jeff Clarke, attributed the merger s success to careful integration, stating, We believe this was the most thoroughly planned merger in history (Harris, 2003, 2006). In contrast, poor integration led to high profile failures in the ATT-NCR and Daimler-Chrysler mergers, even though the economic motivations for the deals were clear. Though research has found that firm size affects acquirer returns, it is still not understood what drives this result (Moeller, Schlingemann, and Stulz, 2004). In this paper, I argue that returns decline by deal order because the costs of M&As increase as acquirers get larger. I develop a simple model to illustrate my hypothesis. I assume that transaction costs depend upon target size and integration costs are determined by relative size. Acquirers choose an optimal target to maximize profits taking these costs into consideration. Because larger targets incur greater integration costs, acquirers have an incentive to buy small targets. However, targets that are too small do not provide enough value to offset the search and transaction costs of the acquisition. Thus both the absolute and relative size of a target 1

4 2 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS influence the acquirer s outcome. The model predicts that larger firms will optimally choose larger targets, though both relative size and returns exhibit a hump-shaped pattern. Above a critical size, as acquirers get larger they optimally buy targets of decreasing relative size, though increasing absolute size, leading to declining returns. Since firms grow through acquisitions, firms later in a deal sequence are larger than firms earlier in a sequence. Thus the model predicts a pattern of declining returns to repeat acquirers even when firms are maximizing profit. My empirical tests support this argument. Nonparametric kernel regressions reveal a positive relationship between the absolute sizes of the acquirer and the target as well as a hump-shaped pattern of both returns and relative size as a function of acquirer size. The data confirm that acquirers get larger over deal sequences and since most first-time acquirers are large enough to be on the declining side of the hump-shaped pattern of returns, later deals generate lower average returns than do earlier deals. In addition, by analyzing the relationship between transaction size and advisor fees, I find evidence supporting the assumption that transaction costs increase with the size of the target. I also find that the relative size of target to acquirer is positively related to integration costs, proxied by industry-relatedness and geographic distance between bidder and target. Next, I use a large panel dataset of repeat acquirers to test the predictions of the cost minimization hypothesis directly against three alternative explanations: agency, hubris, and diminishing opportunity sets. The agency hypothesis predicts that management interests become less aligned with shareholder interests as a firm matures. Thus later deals may be made to generate private managerial benefits, not shareholder wealth gains (Moeller, Schlingemann, and Stulz, 2004). The hubris hypothesis predicts that early success leads to managerial overconfidence and thus overbidding in later deals (Aktas, de Bodt, and Roll, 2007a). Finally, the opportunity set hypothesis predicts that the best targets are acquired first and worse targets later (Klasa and Stegemoller, 2007). I test these hypotheses by first identifying the cross-sectional determinants of abnormal returns for a fixed deal number. Then I determine if these factors are changing systematically over a deal sequence. Both conditions are necessary to explain significant declines in returns. I measure agency using the Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003) g index of managerial entrenchment

5 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS 3 and outside monitoring by independent blockholders. Hubris is measured by premiums paid, and opportunity sets are measured by an acquirer s market-to-book ratio, Tobin s q, and prior year returns. Regression analysis supports the cost minimization hypothesis. Controlling for a host of factors, the absolute and relative sizes of the target affect returns in the cross-section and also change systematically over deal sequences. In contrast, I find only weak support for the agency theory, and none for hubris and opportunity set explanations. Agency variables affect cross-sectional returns, but vary only slightly across deal sequences. In contrast, premiums and growth option proxies change substantially over deal sequences, but do not affect returns in the cross-section. The above results rely on independent cross-sectional and longitudinal tests. In contrast, the dynamic process of market anticipation of future deals at the announcement of earlier deals could explain declining returns as well: when later deals are announced there is no stock price effect because the value of the deal has already been capitalized. Though anticipation is widely cited 1, prior direct tests find mixed results, suffer from small samples, and do not account for the dynamic endogeneity between the likelihood of future deals and current returns (Schipper and Thompson, 1983; Asquith, Bruner, and Mullins, Jr., 1983). To verify the robustness of my results to an anticipation effect, I conduct a series of novel empirical tests designed to overcome limitations of prior studies. First, to address endogeneity, I estimate a simultaneous equations model of the interaction between current M&A returns and the likelihood of future deals. I find that markets do not capitalize the expected value of later deals at the announcements of earlier acquisitions. Though repeat acquirers have higher first announcement returns than firms that do not make subsequent acquisitions, these higher returns are not related to the likelihood of future acquisitions. Second, in a new econometric approach, I use quantile regression to identify the effect that deal order has on information revealed by an announcement. If markets anticipate future mergers, less information will be revealed at the announcement of later deals compared to earlier deals. I find that information, 1 Fuller, Netter, and Stegemoller (2002, p. 1764) assume that markets anticipate mergers for repeat acquirers, allowing them to control for much of the information about bidder characteristics contained in the returns at the announcement of the takeover. Other recent empirical studies that refer to anticipation as a possible effect on acquirer returns include Song and Walkling (2000), Wulf (2004), Bhagat, Dong, Hirshleifer, and Noah (2005), and Song and Walkling (2008).

6 4 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS as measured by the dispersion in returns for a cross section of acquisitions, controlling for other factors, is constant for the first six deals in a sequence, contrary to the anticipation theory and the assumptions made in prior studies. These results are robust to restricting the analysis to cases where anticipation is most likely, namely samples of large transactions and of the most frequent acquirers. Thus I find no evidence supporting anticipation using two independent and unique empirical tests. These results are relevant in their own right, but also validate my main results. Prior research has investigated other issues concerned with repeat acquirers. Loderer and Martin (1990) is perhaps the earliest paper to recognize that firms make multiple acquisitions. More recently, Fuller, Netter, and Stegemoller (2002) examines repeat acquirers to investigate how the public status of the target affects acquirer returns. Moeller, Schlingemann, and Stulz (2005) notes that large loss deals are usually made by a repeat acquirer following a series of successful deals, and Song and Walkling (2008) investigates the anticipation of future acquisitions following industry shocks. To the best of my knowledge, the only other paper to attempt to directly understand why returns decline is Aktas, de Bodt, and Roll (2007a). They posit that a self-interested manager learns through repeat acquisitions to increase premiums in order to capture larger private benefits, which leads to declining returns. More generally, my results contribute to a growing body of research that is concerned with corporate decisions in a dynamic, rather than static setting. See for example Leary and Roberts (2005) on dynamic capital structure, Helwege, Pirinsky, and Stulz (2007) on the evolution of insider ownership, and DeMarzo and Fishman (2007) on the dynamic interaction between agency conflicts and investment. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the theoretical model of M&A cost minimization. The data are described in Section 3. Empirical tests of the cost minimization hypothesis and alternative theories are described in Section 4. Section 5 presents tests of market anticipation. Section 6 concludes.

7 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS 5 2. The cost minimization hypothesis In this section I present a simple model where acquirers maximize profit by choosing an optimal target size given transaction and integration costs. The model generates empirically testable predictions about the relations between acquirer and target size and returns. First I discuss how integration and transaction costs are related to target size. Though acquiring larger targets might generate more synergies, transaction costs are certainly higher. Larger targets require greater costs of due diligence, valuation analysis, and more complex financing. Consistent with this argument, a positive relation between advisory fees and transaction size has been documented by McLaughlin (1990, 1992) and Ma (2006). This means that bidders have an incentive to purchase small firms to reduce costs. However, targets that are very small may not provide enough value to offset the search and transaction costs of the acquisition. Anecdotal evidence supports this idea. In the 1984 Berkshire Hathaway Chairman s Letter to Shareholders, Warren Buffet details the qualities of an attractive takeover candidate. The first requirement is (1) large purchases (at least $5 million of after-tax earnings). In 1985, the size requirement was listed as $10 million in earnings (Buffet, 1984; Buffet, 1985). Clearly the actual size of a large acquisition depends on the size of the acquirer. This implies that the relative size of target to acquirer is an important decision criteria as well. In particular, integration is likely to be more costly when the target is large relative to the acquirer. Though there is no direct empirical evidence on integration costs, it is commonly accepted that mergers-of-equals produce greater post-merger frictions, compared to mergers where the acquirer dominates the target. These relations between target size and costs imply that even if there is a strong economic motivation for a deal, the successful realization of net gains will depend upon target size. I next present a simple model of M&As where acquirers trade off these types of costs and choose targets based on size in order to maximize their profits. I assume that benefits from a merger are linearly increasing in target size, T, at constant rate β. Benefits here are the synergies from the deal net of the purchase price. If the marginal benefits were decreasing in target size, as might be expected, the qualitative results of this model would remain, so linearity is assumed for convenience. Transaction costs are denoted g(t) and integration costs are denoted h(t/a),

8 6 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS where A is the acquirer size. Thus transaction costs are a function of absolute target size, and integration costs are a function of relative size as argued above. Search costs are fixed and denoted F. It is plausible that search costs decrease with target size, since smaller firms are less visible. However, this assumption would strengthen the qualitative results of the analysis, so fixed search costs are assumed for simplicity. The acquiring firm chooses target size T = T to maximize absolute profit: π(t(a),a) = βt F g(t) h(t/a) (1) I assume that costs increase monotonically, g (T) > 0 and h (T/A) > 0. The returns are defined as profit scaled by acquirer size, R(T(A),A) = π A. The following two propositions define how the shape of the cost curves lead to changes in the optimal target size and relative size derived from maximizing the firm s objective function in Equation 1. Proposition 1. If T A h (T/A) h (T/A) < 1, then T (A) > 0. Proposition 2. If g (T) > h (T/A) A, then T A (A) < 0. All proofs are in Appendix A. Proposition 1 states that if integration costs are not too concave, than the optimal target size will increase monotonically as acquirer size gets larger. Thus larger acquirers optimally choose larger targets. 2 Proposition 2 states that the optimal size of the target grows at a slower rate than acquirer size when the change in the marginal transaction cost is greater than the marginal integration cost. Intuitively, as acquirers get larger, the optimal relative size of target to acquirer will decrease if transaction costs are increasing faster than integration costs. For a fixed target size, integration costs will fall less for a large acquirer than for a small acquirer for the same increase in acquirer size. For size increases in small acquirers, the optimal relative value of target to acquirer may actually increase until the transaction costs outweigh the integration costs. Proposition 2 also implies that transaction costs must be strictly convex for relative size to decrease with acquirer size because h (T/A) > 0 2 One can interpret the necessary degree of convexity by noting that T A h (T/A) h (T/A) is the same form as the relative risk aversion coefficient for utility functions. For values of this coefficient between zero and one, costs are concave, but the maximization problem will still lead to increasing target size as acquirers get larger. Thus the shape of the integration cost curve is not restricted to convexity for this result.

9 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS 7 by assumption. This restriction is plausible given that convex transaction costs have been documented for activities less complex than mergers, notably the issuance of new securities (Altinkiliç and Hansen, 2000). The third proposition gives the necessary condition for returns to decrease as a function of acquirer size. Proposition 3. If T A h (T/A) A < π A = R(A), then R (A) < 0. This proposition states that when the marginal cost of integration scaled by the relative size of target to acquirer is less than the return, then returns are declining in A. In other words, an increase in acquirer size will lead to a less than proportional increase in profits when the savings from reduced integration costs are not large. Thus, as in Proposition 2, the same increase in size for a small acquirer, will lead to higher returns than for a large acquirer, because the marginal reduction in integration costs is larger for the small firm. Conversely, since the marginal benefit of reduced integration costs to large firms is small, returns will be lower for larger acquirers. To illustrate the implications of the general model I solve for the optimal target size, relative value, and returns using the following specification: π(t,a) = βt F 0.5δT 2 0.5γ (T/A) 2 (2) where the parameters β, δ, and γ measure the intensity of net synergy, transaction costs, and integration costs, respectively. The profit function is concave and the first-order condition yields an optimal target size T and relative size T A as follows: T = A2 β A 2 δ + γ (3) T A = Aβ A 2 δ + γ (4) The conditions of Proposition 1 and 2 are satisfied because both cost functions are strictly convex. Thus the optimal target size, T, is increasing in the acquirer size A for all A, but the optimal relative size decreases as acquirers get larger only after acquirers reach a certain critical

10 8 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS size where increases in transaction costs outweigh increases in integration costs. Substituting the optimal T in the profit equation yields, and the returns from the acquisition are, π(t (A),A) = A 2 β 2 2(A 2 δ + γ) F (5) R(T (A),A) = π A = Aβ 2 2(A 2 δ + γ) F A. (6) To illustrate the results of this model, I plot the optimal target size, relative size, and return as functions of acquirer size in Figure 1. Parameter values are β = 1, F = 0.5, δ = 0.1, and γ = 5. Since γ measures the integration cost based on relative size and δ measures the transaction cost based on the absolute size, γ is much larger than δ. Figure 1 shows that as acquirers get larger they optimally choose larger targets though of decreasing relative size. The relative size and returns depend upon the size of the acquirer in similar ways. When acquirers are small, the integration costs are large relative to the transaction costs. As the acquirer size increases, the savings from the integration costs more than offset the additional transaction costs and so returns and relative size increase. At a critical point, the transaction costs overcome the integration costs and increasing acquirer size leads to decreasing returns and relative size. In summary, under the following assumptions, 1. Acquirers maximize profits by choosing an optimal target size. 2. Transaction costs are increasing in the absolute size of the target. 3. Integration costs are increasing in relative size and are not too concave. the model generates the following empirically testable predictions, 1. Target size grows monotonically with acquirer size. 2. Relative size and returns follow a hump-shaped pattern, increasing for small acquirers and decreasing for acquirers larger than a critical size. The implication for repeat acquirers is that if there is a positive relationship between deal order and acquirer size, as would be expected, this model predicts that we will observe that returns

11 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS 9 decline over a deal sequence for large enough firms even when firms are maximizing profit from acquisitions. 3. Data and methodology To test theories of repeat acquirers it would be ideal to have returns data and complete acquisition histories of all acquiring firms. However, comprehensive merger data begins in 1980 and returns data are only available for public firms. Thus to produce the most complete acquisition histories I limit my sample to firms that publicly list after This may produce two types of bias. First, firms may have extensive acquisition histories as private firms that would not be captured in my data. However, it is likely that acquisitive private firms also will be acquisitive public firms and this bias will affect all firms equally. Second, the post-1980 listing restriction may bias my sample toward firms in certain industries. I address this problem below and find little bias. The following presents a detailed description of the data. The sample data are taken from Securities Data Corporations s (SDC) U.S. Mergers and Acquisitions database. Only acquisitions worth at least $1 million announced between 01/01/1980 and 12/23/2004 that were completed within 1,000 days are included in the sample. 3 Because repeat acquirers may be more likely to acquire many small firms, rather than fewer large firms, no restriction is placed on the relative value of the target to the acquirer as is commonly done in prior studies. Also, acquirers have to own less than 50% of the target before the acquisition, and 100% after the acquisition. This prevents the inclusion of repeat partial acquisitions of the same target. Acquirers have to be public firms with data available on the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) and CompuStat databases. Targets are restricted to public, private, or subsidiaries of a public or private firm. Also, multiple acquisition announcements by the same firm within five days of each other are excluded. Finally, as noted above, to ensure acquisition deal histories are correctly measured, I exclude all acquirers that were listed on CRSP before 01/01/1980. This exclusion is not typically done in prior research on multiple acquirers but provides a solid benchmark from which to order 3 I restrict attention to completed deals because data on incomplete deals will likely be biased toward public targets. However, only using completed deals may lead to a misproportional small number of hostile deals, since hostile deals are more likely to fail (Walkling, 1985).

12 10 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS acquisitions. Of course acquisition histories are still likely to be incomplete as pre-ipo firms make acquisitions. However, if no benchmark is used, acquisition data limitations will lead to a downward bias in the measurement of acquisition experience for older firms. Using this restriction also avoids defining the beginning of a merger program by an arbitrary no-acquisition hiatus of between two and eight years, as is commonly done in prior studies (Loderer and Martin, 1990; Conn, Cosh, Guest, and Hughes, 2004). This sampling procedure produces 12,942 acquisitions made by 4,879 acquirers. The prototypical repeat acquirer, Cisco Systems, completed 50 acquisitions, the largest number in the sample, though the average firm completed 2.7 deals over the sample 15-year period. If a 1% relative value restriction had been placed on the sample, Cisco would only have 10 deals in the sample. A 5% cutoff would have left only one deal in the sample for Cisco. Thus, imposing relative value restrictions may alter the sample significantly. Table 1 presents a summary description of the sample by year. Total deals peaked in 1997 with 1,437 announcements, though total transaction value peaked in 2000 with $615,382 million. The median transaction value for all years is $25.38 million, considerably less than the average value of $571 million, reflecting the positive skewness of the distribution of transaction values. Though I limit the sample to firms not listed before 1980, the distribution of deals by industry shifts only slightly toward high-technology industries. In a sample where acquirers are not restricted to being listed after 1980, using the 49 Fama French Industry Classifications, 4 banking accounts for the largest number of deals without restricting acquirer listing dates (13.9% of all deals). Computer software (9.9%), business services (6.9%), electronic equipment (5.8%), and communication (5.5%) round out the top five industries which together account for 42% of all deals in the unrestricted sample. The top five industries for the sample used in this paper, where acquirers must be first listed after 1980, are software (13.9%), banking (10.8%), business services (8.6%), communication (6.5%), and electronic equipment (6.2%), totalling 46% of all deals. Thus the industry clustering in merger activity reported in prior work is confirmed here, and relatively unchanged by my sample restrictions (Mitchell and Mulherin, 1996; Harford, 2005). This suggests that the 1980 listing requirement will not produce extensive bias in my results. 4 Generously provided on Kenneth French s Web site. library.html

13 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS 11 Because prior acquisitions may affect any event study prediction method which estimates abnormal returns using firm historical returns, I calculate abnormal returns using a marketadjusted model with the equally weighted CRSP index as a market proxy. For each day in the event period, market returns are subtracted from firm returns (Brown and Warner, 1985). Cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) are computed over the five days surrounding the announcement because the announcement dates listed on SDC are not always accurate, especially for the small deals in my sample. Significance tests of CARs are conducted with a sign test (Corrado and Zivney, 1992). Table 2 reports CARs grouped by total number of deals in a firm s series, acquisition order in series, and target organizational status. There are 2,212 firms that made only one acquisition in the sample period, while there are 503 with over five acquisitions. These 503 firms account for 10% of all firms in the sample, but complete 35% of all the deals. The average CAR for all firms and all deals is a significant 1.98%. Subsidiary targets yield higher returns (3.09%) than do private targets (2.30%), which yield higher returns than public targets, which are statistically negative (-0.86%). Consistent with prior studies, CARs are declining with deal order, regardless of target status. Public targets yield an insignificant 0.35% for first deals declining to a significant 2.06% for sixth and later deals. First acquisitions of private targets generate 3.39%, declining to 0.72% for sixth and later deals. 5 The sample sizes reported for each CAR in Table 2 also reflect that the type of target is changing with deal order. For the first through third deals, roughly 16% are public targets, 55% are private, and 29% are subsidiaries. For fourth and higher deals, public targets become more prevalent, increasing to 25% of the sample for the sixth or later deals, while private targets decrease to 48%. Subsidiary targets first increase to 33% then decline to 27% for the later deals. This supports the idea that changing firm characteristics may explain part of the decline in abnormal returns with deal order. 5 In unreported calculations, average (median) abnormal dollar returns are $19.5 million ($0.4 million) in 2005 dollars, consistent with the same calculations in Moeller, Schlingemann, and Stulz (2004). However, the abnormal dollar returns do not exhibit a strong pattern of decline over deals, as do the equally weighted abnormal returns. Nevertheless, I replaced CARs with dollar returns in all of the following analyses as a robustness check and found no qualitative difference in the results.

14 12 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS 4. Empirical tests of the cost minimization hypothesis To test the cost minimization hypothesis, I first empirically examine the plausibility of its assumptions and then compare the model predictions to the data. The model assumes that transaction costs affect the absolute size of the target, whereas integration costs affect the relative size. To measure transaction costs I retrieve the total acquirer financial advisor fees and the number of acquirer advisors per deal from SDC. Larger deals are predicted to have larger transaction costs. To proxy for integration costs I record whether the target and bidder are in the same Fama French 49 industry classification. Second, I calculate the geographic distance between the location of bidder and target headquarters measured at the zipcode level. 6 I hypothesize that targets that are in different industries and located farther away from the acquirer will have greater frictions and thus higher integration costs. To test the relationship between these cost measures and target size, I run log-log regressions to estimate elasticities between the variables. These results are presented in Table 3. This analysis should not be interpreted as causal evidence. Instead the results record whether larger transactions are associated with higher costs, controlling for other factors. First, a 1% increase in acquirer size is associated with a 0.78% increase in the transaction size and a 0.63% decrease in the relative size of target to acquirer. This result is consistent with model prediction 1. Second, larger deals are associated with larger transaction costs measured both by total fees and by the number of advisers. Higher fees are also associated with deals of larger relative values. Finally, the proxies for integration costs are positively related to relative value. Higher relative values are associated with higher integration costs as measured by distance and industry-relatedness. These results provide credibility to model assumptions 2 and 3 on the relationships between costs and target sizes. Assumption 1 states that firms maximize profits. The plausibility of this assumption is directly tested against other alternative motives for M&As in later analyses. Next, I estimate the model predictions about the relationship between firm size and returns. Econometrically, I want to estimate E(X Acquirer Size), where X is either returns, target size, or relative size. Since the model makes distinctly non-linear predictions, I do not impose 6 The zipcode is taken from SDC. Using the US Census Bureau s database of zipcode longitudes and latitudes, I calculate the surface distance in statute miles.

15 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS 13 a functional form on this expectation, but instead use nonparametric kernel regression to plot the relationships. 7 These estimated expectations are plotted in Figure 2 along with scatterplots of the data. The kernel regression estimates closely follow the model s predictions. This evidence is particularly strong because the unique hump-shaped pattern predicted by the model is replicated in the data. In particular, both returns and relative size increase over a range of small acquirer values and then decrease toward zero. Moreover, consistent with the model, the marginal change in relative value is much larger than the marginal change in returns for increases in acquirer size. Finally, transaction size is also increasing in acquirer size, as predicted. This evidence shows that returns are related to acquirer and target sizes. Thus, if acquirers are getting larger with subsequent deals, than returns will decline over deal sequences. Though the nonparametric estimations are strong evidence in support of the cost minimization hypothesis, they do not control for other factors that may explain declining returns. In particular, the cost minimization hypothesis assumes firms are maximizing profits by choosing an optimal target size. Alternative theories of M&As include agency, hubris, and diminishing opportunity sets. The next set of tests explicitly controls for a host of variables and investigates these alternative theories Tests of the alternative theories To test the alternative theories, I first identify the factors that significantly affect returns in the cross-section and then test whether these factors are changing over deal sequences. Only factors that both explain cross-sectional variation and that vary systematically over a deal sequence can explain the pattern of declining returns. In contrast to the efficiency-based size effect in my model, Moeller, Schlingemann, and Stulz (2004) hypothesize that the size effect reported in their study is likely due to agency problems of larger firms, though they provide no formal tests. I test this hypothesis directly by including measures of internal monitoring and managerial entrenchment/antitakeover provisions 7 In particular I use the leave-one-out Nadaraya-Watson estimator with a Gaussian kernel. Cross-validation is performed by minimizing the estimated prediction error in order to find the optimal bandwidth. See Härdle (1990) for more details on kernel regression estimates.

16 14 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS in regressions on acquirer returns. As a measure of internal monitoring I use the number of non-officer directors that are blockholders in the firm. These data on 1,913 firms over come from the Blockholders database maintained by Wharton Research Data Services (WRDS) and described in Dlugosz, Fahlenbrach, Gompers, and Metrick (2006). Entrenchment is measured using the Gompers-Ishii-Metrick (GIM) governance index of the data in the Investor Responsibility Research Center s (IRRC) Governance database. This data set provides data on 24 antitakeover provisions, such as staggered boards, poison pills, and others, for a sample of predominately large firms for selected years starting in For further information see Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003). The agency theory hypothesizes that more non-officer director blockholders will be associated with higher returns and more antitakeover provisions will be associated with lower returns. Since internal monitoring and the market for corporate control may be substitutes, I also look at the interaction between the two. To investigate hubris, I look at premiums paid by the acquirer. Premiums are defined as the transaction value from SDC divided by the market value of the target 50 trading days before the announcement date. The relation between premiums and CARs is not well defined. The learning model of Aktas, de Bodt, and Roll (2007a) states that higher premiums drive down abnormal returns from acquisitions made later in a deal sequence. However, in contrast to this theory, it is possible that high premiums may indicate the possibility of high synergies between bidder and target, which could lead to higher abnormal returns. Finally, to test the diminishing opportunity set theory, I would like to be able to measure the number and quality of remaining targets for a given acquirer. However, I am unaware of any direct measure of these factors. Instead, I use acquirer book-to-market, Tobin s q, and prior year returns as proxies of opportunity sets. These variables have been used in other studies to measure growth options, and I assume that a component of these growth option measures includes acquisition options (Billett, King, and Mauer, 2007). Table 4 presents firm fixed effect regressions designed to test the cost minimization hypothesis against the alternative explanations. The first column regresses the five-day CAR on acquirer, target, and deal characteristics, controlling for unobserved firm heterogeneity and time effects. First, deal number is not significantly related to abnormal returns. This means that other

17 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS 15 determinants of returns must be changing over time to explain declining returns. Moreover, experience does not appear to influence merger returns. Second, acquirer size is negatively and significantly related to CARs, consistent with the cost minimization hypothesis, but also with hubris and agency. In addition deals/year is also negatively related to CARs, though time elapsed since the prior deal is positively related. Firms that make many acquisitions quickly have lower CARs than firms that do not. Song and Walkling (2008) use this as evidence of market anticipation of later deals. A short duration between deals may instead be related to the indigestion hypothesis of Conn, Cosh, Guest, and Hughes (2004), where integration between the target and bidder is hampered by a subsequent acquisition. Moreover, in various explicit tests reported in Section 5, I do not find support for anticipation as a determinant of returns. Third, the results in Table 4 show that public targets and particularly those purchased with stock, generate significantly lower returns, consistent with the liquidity premium shown in Officer (2007). All these results are consistent with prior studies (Fuller, Netter, and Stegemoller, 2002; Moeller, Schlingemann, and Stulz, 2004). Finally, note that relative value is positive and significant at the 10.4% level, though transaction value is insignificant. Next, I include the variables measuring agency costs in column (2) under the Governance heading in Table 4. Outside director blockholders is significant and positive as hypothesized, the entrenchment index is negative, but not significant, and the interaction term is significantly negative. The negative sign of the interaction term indicates that the benefit of internal monitoring is eroded with more entrenchment provisions. These results are consistent with Masulis, Wang, and Xie (2007) who show greater shareholder control is positively related to acquirer returns in a static cross-section analysis. Also of note is that the inclusion of these agency variables does not change the insignificant acquirer size effect between regressions (1) and (2). This does not support an agency explanation of the size effect as suggested in Moeller, Schlingemann, and Stulz (2004), but neither is it convincing evidence against this hypothesis, since the firms with observed agency variables tend to be much larger than those firms omitted from the IRRC database. This size constraint on the sample also affects the estimated effect of the relative value on the CARs. Since larger firms have lower CARs, larger relative sizes decrease

18 16 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS the returns, as opposed to the positive relationship found in the full sample where returns are higher on average. Next, I test the hubris story, where I restrict my sample to acquisitions of public targets in order to calculate premiums. The results in column (2) under the Public Targets heading in Table 4 suggest that there is no relationship between premiums and CARs. However, target size has a significant negative relation to acquirer CARs, consistent with the cost minimization hypothesis. In unreported tests, for robustness I also include the number of bidders in a takeover contest and find no qualitative differences in the results. Finally, none of the acquirer opportunity set measures are significant in any specification in Table 4. This suggests that diminishing opportunity sets do not explain declining acquirer returns either. In summary, though no evidence is found to support the hubris or opportunity set hypotheses, the above results show that both target size and more managerial entrenchment with less oversight significantly reduces acquirer returns in the cross-section. Other factors also explain announcement returns. Public targets generate lower returns, as does using all stock financing. Both relative value and the number of years since the last acquisition have a positive effect in the large sample, but a negative effect in the public target samples. However, to explain declining acquirer returns, it is not enough that a variable affects CARs in the cross-section alone. It also must be the case that the level of the variable changes systematically over deal sequences. To determine which of these variables are consistently changing over deal number, I calculate means and medians of firm and deal characteristics by deal number for all firms in the sample as well as slope coefficients for both a linear and squared term similar to the procedure in Aktas, de Bodt, and Roll (2007b). These results, presented in Table 5, provide more evidence in support of the cost minimization hypothesis. Average acquirer size continues to grow over subsequent acquisitions, but the average relative size of the target declines at a declining rate over deal sequences. Thus later deals are dominated by acquisitions of large targets, though of a small relative size. Because relatively smaller targets create smaller abnormal returns, acquirer returns are decreasing over deal sequences. In summary, the empirical relation between costs and sizes, the nonlinear kernel regression results, and the longitudinal decline in relative value

19 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS 17 and increase in target absolute size support the basic assumptions and predictions of the cost minimization hypothesis. Returning to the results in Table 5, agency problems appear to have a weak negative relation to declining acquisition returns. First, though the number of outside director blockholders is significantly related to CARs, they are unchanging over deal sequences, a surprising result considering the large increase in the average acquirer size. Second, though managers are significantly more entrenched in later deals than in earlier deals in a statistical sense, the actual change in the average number of antitakeover provisions over the first ten deals is very small. Since these entrenchment changes only affect returns significantly in the interaction with the outside director monitoring variable, the final effect of increased entrenchment on CARs is very small. For robustness, other measures of agency might have been used, but they would likely suffer from the same time invariance. For example, inside ownership may affect merger returns, but both Zhou (2001) and McConnell, Servaes, and Lins (2007) report that inside ownership changes are extremely small over time within the same firm. Sample attrition may explain the deal-series variation if the firms completing later deals are significantly different than those completing earlier deals. To account for this potential bias, in unreported tests I examine deal-series variation using only observations from the 503 acquirers with more than five deals in the sample. The results are unchanged using this smaller sample. In addition, I control for firm fixed effects by looking at within-firm changes in variables over deal numbers and find results that are qualitatively the same as those presented above. In summary, returns decline because acquirers get larger and the relative size of targets to acquirers gets smaller. This pattern is shown to be consistent with a firm s objective to minimize the costs of M&As, after controlling for variables related to agency, hubris, and opportunity set theories. 5. Theory and prior evidence of market anticipation of mergers Though the above results are consistent with the cost minimization hypothesis, if investors anticipate later deals at the announcement of earlier deals, the empirical patterns of the returns to repeat acquirers could also be the consequence of an entirely different effect which would

20 18 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS not be detected in the above analyses. Schipper and Thompson (1983) propose a capitalization theory where markets reflect the entire benefit of an acquisition sequence in the first announcement of the program. Later acquisition returns only reflect surprises, which are zero on average. A related signaling theory proposed in Asquith, Bruner, and Mullins, Jr. (1983) suggests that each acquisition announcement provides less information to the market about the true value of the firm than the preceding announcement. Since the signaling theory is equivalent to the capitalization theory with uncertainty, I group them together in a theory called the anticipation theory. This theory predicts that acquisition returns will be declining as uncertainty is resolved, and later deals will reflect less new information. Since the dynamic effect of anticipation could distort any cross-sectional theory explaining declining returns, it is crucial that we determine its effect, if any Capitalization theory There is an endogenous relationship between current returns and future expected returns. A high first deal return of a repeat acquirer may simply reflect a survival bias, where a successful firm will continue to make acquisitions, rather than reflect the present value of future deals, as suggested by the anticipation theory. To explicitly control for this endogeneity problem, I use a simultaneous equations framework with panel data which allows me to control for the likelihood of future acquisition activity at the current deal. I define the following simultaneous equations model, CAR ia = α 1 EV F ia + X 1ia β 1 + c 1i + u ia a = 1,...,A (7) EV F ia = α 2 CAR ia + X 2ia β 2 + c 2i + v ia a = 1,...,A (8) where EV F = Expected Value of Future Deals a = Order number of acquisition.

21 THE RETURNS TO REPEAT ACQUIRERS 19 This model allows for a simultaneous relationship between the present CAR and the expected value of future acquisitions. The c 1i and c 2i terms capture assumed time-invariant unobserved firm heterogeneity that may affect returns and the value of future deals. This would include such attributes as corporate culture and organizational ability. The variables in the X s reflect other explanatory variables in the equations including size, valuation, deal number, and time elapsed between deals. To estimate the expected value of future deals (EV F) I must account for both the probability of completing more deals and the value of the deals. First, even after controlling for numerous factors, cross-sectional studies of returns usually report R 2 measures of less than 10%, indicating that much of the variance in returns is unexplained. Thus, to reduce noise, I assume all firms would realize a common gain if they carried out a future deal. Second, the probability of making a subsequent deal is much higher than the probability of making ten more deals. Compounding probabilities implies that the likelihood of the immediately subsequent deal captures the greatest portion of the uncertainty of future M&A activity. Thus the uncertainty of the value and likelihood of future deals motivates the following simplifying assumption, EV F ia = P ia V a+1 (9) where the value of the future deal, V a+1, is common to all firms, but the probability of making a subsequent deal, P ia, varies by the firm and deal characteristics of the current deal, a. According to the CARs presented above, V a+1 is non-negative on average, and so there should exist a positive relationship between EV F ia and CAR ia in Equations (7) and (8). 8 8 One could argue that the likelihood of a successful deal is inversely related to the value of the deal. Hietala, Kaplan, and Robinson (2003) show that Viacom won the takeover battle for Paramount in 1994, but overpaid substantially. Thus, due to a winner s curse, highest bidders are most likely to succeed in an acquisition, but destroy value. I do not think this is a large concern in my analysis. The probability I measure is the likelihood of making a future acquisition as measured at the time of a current announcement. This incorporates both the likelihood of making an offer and the likelihood of success. Only the second likelihood might be negatively related to deal value and it is arguable less important than the fundamental decision to make an acquisition or not.

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? *

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Thomas Moeller Neeley School of Business Texas Christian University Abstract In a large sample of public-public acquisitions, target

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

The Impact of Mergers and Acquisitions on Corporate Bond Ratings. Qi Chang. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business

The Impact of Mergers and Acquisitions on Corporate Bond Ratings. Qi Chang. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business The Impact of Mergers and Acquisitions on Corporate Bond Ratings Qi Chang A Thesis In The John Molson School of Business Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of

More information

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 6 Number 2 2012 AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University

More information

Wealth Destruction on a Massive Scale? A Study of Acquiring-Firm Returns in the Recent Merger Wave

Wealth Destruction on a Massive Scale? A Study of Acquiring-Firm Returns in the Recent Merger Wave THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LX, NO. 2 APRIL 2005 Wealth Destruction on a Massive Scale? A Study of Acquiring-Firm Returns in the Recent Merger Wave SARA B. MOELLER, FREDERIK P. SCHLINGEMANN, and RENÉ M.STULZ

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. Stulz Working Paper 9523 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9523 NATIONAL

More information

Learning from Repetitive Acquisitions: Evidence from the Time Between Deals

Learning from Repetitive Acquisitions: Evidence from the Time Between Deals Learning from Repetitive Acquisitions: Evidence from the Time Between Deals Nihat Aktas, Eric de Bodt*, and Richard Roll This draft: June 24, 2011 ABSTRACT Repetitive acquisitions involve benefits and

More information

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXVI, NO. 1 MARCH 1991 Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers HENRI SERVAES* ABSTRACT This paper analyzes the relation between takeover gains and the q ratios of targets and

More information

M&A Activity in Europe

M&A Activity in Europe M&A Activity in Europe Cash Reserves, Acquisitions and Shareholder Wealth in Europe Master Thesis in Business Administration at the Department of Banking and Finance Faculty Advisor: PROF. DR. PER ÖSTBERG

More information

BOARD CONNECTIONS AND M&A TRANSACTIONS. Ye Cai. Chapel Hill 2010

BOARD CONNECTIONS AND M&A TRANSACTIONS. Ye Cai. Chapel Hill 2010 BOARD CONNECTIONS AND M&A TRANSACTIONS Ye Cai A dissertation submitted to the faculty of the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor

More information

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract In this paper we study the market reaction to capital expenditure announcements in the backdrop

More information

Firm Locations and Takeover Likelihood *

Firm Locations and Takeover Likelihood * Firm Locations and Takeover Likelihood * Ye Cai Leavey School of Business Santa Clara University Santa Clara, CA 95053 ycai@scu.edu (408) 554-5157 Xuan Tian Kelley School of Business Indiana University

More information

How do serial acquirers choose the method of payment? ANTONIO J. MACIAS Texas Christian University. P. RAGHAVENDRA RAU University of Cambridge

How do serial acquirers choose the method of payment? ANTONIO J. MACIAS Texas Christian University. P. RAGHAVENDRA RAU University of Cambridge How do serial acquirers choose the method of payment? ANTONIO J. MACIAS Texas Christian University P. RAGHAVENDRA RAU University of Cambridge ARIS STOURAITIS Hong Kong Baptist University August 2012 Abstract

More information

The Benefits of Market Timing: Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions

The Benefits of Market Timing: Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions The Benefits of Timing: Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions Evangelos Vagenas-Nanos University of Glasgow, University Avenue, Glasgow, G12 8QQ, UK Email: evangelos.vagenas-nanos@glasgow.ac.uk Abstract

More information

The Impact of Acquisitions on Corporate Bond Ratings

The Impact of Acquisitions on Corporate Bond Ratings The Impact of Acquisitions on Corporate Bond Ratings Qi Chang Department of Finance John Molson School of Business Concordia University Montreal, Qc H3G 1M8, Canada Email: alexismsc2012@gmail.com Harjeet

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Does Size Matter? The Impact of Managerial Incentives and

Does Size Matter? The Impact of Managerial Incentives and Does Size Matter? The Impact of Managerial Incentives and Firm Size on Acquisition Announcement Returns Master Thesis R.M. Jonkman Using 3,042 acquiring firm observations for the period 1993 2007, I find

More information

ESSAYS IN CORPORATE FINANCE. Cong Wang. Dissertation. Submitted to the Faculty of the. Graduate School of Vanderbilt University

ESSAYS IN CORPORATE FINANCE. Cong Wang. Dissertation. Submitted to the Faculty of the. Graduate School of Vanderbilt University ESSAYS IN CORPORATE FINANCE By Cong Wang Dissertation Submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Vanderbilt University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

More information

Shareholder Wealth Effects of M&A Withdrawals

Shareholder Wealth Effects of M&A Withdrawals Shareholder Wealth Effects of M&A Withdrawals Yue Liu * University of Edinburgh Business School, 29 Buccleuch Place, Edinburgh, EH3 8EQ, UK Keywords: Mergers and Acquisitions Withdrawal Abnormal Return

More information

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan; University of New Orleans ScholarWorks@UNO Department of Economics and Finance Working Papers, 1991-2006 Department of Economics and Finance 1-1-2006 Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Miguel Antón, Florian Ederer, Mireia Giné, and Martin Schmalz August 13, 2016 Abstract This internet appendix provides

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Merger Momentum and Investor Sentiment: The Stock Market Reaction to Merger Announcements Richard J. Rosen WP 2004-07 Forthcoming, Journal of Business Merger momentum and

More information

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality DORON NISSIM* Corporate disclosures are an important source of information for investors. Many studies have documented strong price

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

Investment Performance of Common Stock in Relation to their Price-Earnings Ratios: BASU 1977 Extended Analysis

Investment Performance of Common Stock in Relation to their Price-Earnings Ratios: BASU 1977 Extended Analysis Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2015 Investment Performance of Common Stock in Relation to their Price-Earnings Ratios: BASU 1977 Extended

More information

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership Robert C. Hanson Department of Finance and CIS College of Business Eastern Michigan University Ypsilanti, MI 48197 Moon H.

More information

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Manohar Singh The Pennsylvania State University- Abington Reporting a positive relationship between institutional ownership on one hand and capital expenditures

More information

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK Scott J. Wallsten * Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research 579 Serra Mall at Galvez St. Stanford, CA 94305 650-724-4371 wallsten@stanford.edu

More information

Geography and Acquirer Returns

Geography and Acquirer Returns Geography and Acquirer Returns Simi Kedia and Venkatesh Panchapagesan This Draft: September 2004 Preliminary. Comments Welcome. Abstract We find evidence of local bias in the acquisition decisions of U.S

More information

Discussion Paper No. 593

Discussion Paper No. 593 Discussion Paper No. 593 MANAGEMENT OWNERSHIP AND FIRM S VALUE: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS USING PANEL DATA Sang-Mook Lee and Keunkwan Ryu September 2003 The Institute of Social and Economic Research Osaka

More information

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM ) MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM Ersin Güner 559370 Master Finance Supervisor: dr. P.C. (Peter) de Goeij December 2013 Abstract Evidence from the US shows

More information

Acquiring Intangible Assets

Acquiring Intangible Assets Acquiring Intangible Assets Intangible assets are important for corporations and their owners. The book value of intangible assets as a percentage of total assets for all COMPUSTAT firms grew from 6% in

More information

FAMILY OWNERSHIP CONCENTRATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: ARE SHAREHOLDERS REALLY BETTER OFF? Rama Seth IIM Calcutta

FAMILY OWNERSHIP CONCENTRATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: ARE SHAREHOLDERS REALLY BETTER OFF? Rama Seth IIM Calcutta FAMILY OWNERSHIP CONCENTRATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: ARE SHAREHOLDERS REALLY BETTER OFF? Rama Seth IIM Calcutta INTRODUCTION The share of family firms contribution to global GDP is estimated to be in the

More information

MERGER ANNOUNCEMENTS AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: DO MARKETS PREDICT SYNERGETIC GAINS FROM MERGERS PROPERLY?

MERGER ANNOUNCEMENTS AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: DO MARKETS PREDICT SYNERGETIC GAINS FROM MERGERS PROPERLY? MERGER ANNOUNCEMENTS AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: DO MARKETS PREDICT SYNERGETIC GAINS FROM MERGERS PROPERLY? ALOVSAT MUSLUMOV Department of Management, Dogus University. Acıbadem 81010, Istanbul / TURKEY Tel:

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

Does Insider Ownership Matter for Financial Decisions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan

Does Insider Ownership Matter for Financial Decisions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan Does Insider Ownership Matter for Financial Decisions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan Haris Arshad & Attiya Yasmin Javid INTRODUCTION In an emerging economy like Pakistan,

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 5 Number 1 2011 DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN Ming-Hui Wang, Taiwan University of Science and Technology

More information

Motivated Monitors: The Importance of Institutional Investors Portfolio Weights

Motivated Monitors: The Importance of Institutional Investors Portfolio Weights Motivated Monitors: The Importance of Institutional Investors Portfolio Weights March 12, 2013 Eliezer M. Fich LeBow College of Business Drexel University Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA +1-215-895-2304 efich@drexel.edu

More information

Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets:

Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets: Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets: The Débutante Effect * Luyao Pan a Xianming Zhou b Abstract Both theory and economic intuition suggest that newly listed firms differ from seasoned ones as potential

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Anup Agrawal Culverhouse College of Business University of Alabama Tuscaloosa, AL 35487-0224 Jeffrey F. Jaffe Department

More information

The Effects of Uncertainty and Corporate Governance on Firms Demand for Liquidity

The Effects of Uncertainty and Corporate Governance on Firms Demand for Liquidity The Effects of Uncertainty and Corporate Governance on Firms Demand for Liquidity CF Baum, A Chakraborty, L Han, B Liu Boston College, UMass-Boston, Beihang University, Beihang University April 5, 2010

More information

GOVERNANCE PROVISIONS AND MANAGERIAL ENTRENCHMENT: EVIDENCE FROM FORCED CEO TURNOVER OF ACQUIRING FIRMS

GOVERNANCE PROVISIONS AND MANAGERIAL ENTRENCHMENT: EVIDENCE FROM FORCED CEO TURNOVER OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GOVERNANCE PROVISIONS AND MANAGERIAL ENTRENCHMENT: EVIDENCE FROM FORCED CEO TURNOVER OF ACQUIRING FIRMS Tatyana Sokolyk Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming phone: (307) 766-4244 fax:

More information

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know?

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? Preliminary Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? by Robert Harris*, Tim Jenkinson** and Steven N. Kaplan*** This Draft: September 9, 2011 Abstract We present time series evidence on the performance

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO ACQUIRERS WITH MORE UNCERTAIN GROWTH PROSPECTS GAIN LESS FROM ACQUISITIONS?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO ACQUIRERS WITH MORE UNCERTAIN GROWTH PROSPECTS GAIN LESS FROM ACQUISITIONS? NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO ACQUIRERS WITH MORE UNCERTAIN GROWTH PROSPECTS GAIN LESS FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. Stulz Working Paper 10773 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10773

More information

INSIDER OWNERSHIP AND BANK PERFORMANCE: EVIDENCE FROM THE FINANCIAL CRISIS OF

INSIDER OWNERSHIP AND BANK PERFORMANCE: EVIDENCE FROM THE FINANCIAL CRISIS OF INSIDER OWNERSHIP AND BANK PERFORMANCE: EVIDENCE FROM THE FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2007-2009 by Xinliang Wang B.A. (Honours) University of Saskatchewan, 2009 PROJECT SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE

More information

Conflict in Whispers and Analyst Forecasts: Which One Should Be Your Guide?

Conflict in Whispers and Analyst Forecasts: Which One Should Be Your Guide? Abstract Conflict in Whispers and Analyst Forecasts: Which One Should Be Your Guide? Janis K. Zaima and Maretno Agus Harjoto * San Jose State University This study examines the market reaction to conflicts

More information

Why do acquirers switch financial advisors in mergers and acquisitions?

Why do acquirers switch financial advisors in mergers and acquisitions? Why do acquirers switch financial advisors in mergers and acquisitions? Xiaoxiao Yu 1 and Yeqin Zeng 2 1 University of Texas at Arlington 2 University of Reading September 14, 2017 Abstract Using a sample

More information

How Have M&As Changed? Evidence from the Sixth Merger Wave

How Have M&As Changed? Evidence from the Sixth Merger Wave How Have M&As Changed? Evidence from the Sixth Merger Wave G.Alexandridis, C.F. Mavrovitis, and N.G. Travlos* June 2011 We examine the characteristics of the sixth merger wave that started in 2003 and

More information

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity *

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity * Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity * Index Section 1: High bargaining power of the small firm Page 1 Section 2: Analysis of Multiple Small Firms and 1 Large

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Managerial compensation incentives and merger waves

Managerial compensation incentives and merger waves Managerial compensation incentives and merger waves David Hillier a, Patrick McColgan b, Athanasios Tsekeris c Abstract This paper examines the relation between executive compensation incentives and the

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

Do firms have leverage targets? Evidence from acquisitions

Do firms have leverage targets? Evidence from acquisitions Do firms have leverage targets? Evidence from acquisitions Jarrad Harford School of Business Administration University of Washington Seattle, WA 98195 206.543.4796 206.221.6856 (Fax) jarrad@u.washington.edu

More information

Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies

Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies Andrew Ellul 1 Vijay Yerramilli 2 1 Kelley School of Business, Indiana University 2 C. T. Bauer College of Business, University

More information

Payment Method in Mergers and Acquisitions

Payment Method in Mergers and Acquisitions Payment Method in Mergers and Acquisitions A Study on Swedish firm s Domestic and Cross-Border Acquisitions Bachelor Thesis in Financial Economics and Industrial and Financial Management School of Business,

More information

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power? International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 9, No. 9; 2014 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really

More information

Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets:

Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets: Newly Listed Firms as Acquisition Targets: The Débutant Effect of IPOs * Luyao Pan a Xianming Zhou b February 18, 2015 Abstract Both theory and economic intuition suggest that newly listed firms differ

More information

Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation

Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Wharton Research Scholars Wharton School 4-2011 Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation Peter Maa University of Pennsylvania Follow this and

More information

Is Ownership Really Endogenous?

Is Ownership Really Endogenous? Is Ownership Really Endogenous? Klaus Gugler * and Jürgen Weigand ** * (Corresponding author) University of Vienna, Department of Economics, Bruennerstrasse 72, 1210 Vienna, Austria; email: klaus.gugler@univie.ac.at;

More information

Essays on labor power and agency problem :values of cash holdings and capital expenditures, and accounting earnings informativeness

Essays on labor power and agency problem :values of cash holdings and capital expenditures, and accounting earnings informativeness Hong Kong Baptist University HKBU Institutional Repository Open Access Theses and Dissertations Electronic Theses and Dissertations 8-14-2015 Essays on labor power and agency problem :values of cash holdings

More information

Tests of the influence of a firm s post-ipo age on the decision to initiate a cash dividend

Tests of the influence of a firm s post-ipo age on the decision to initiate a cash dividend Tests of the influence of a firm s post-ipo age on the decision to initiate a cash dividend Dan Dhaliwal Eller School of Business Department of Accounting University of Arizona Tucson, Arizona 85721 Oliver

More information

THE LONG-RUN PERFORMANCE OF HOSTILE TAKEOVERS: U.K. EVIDENCE. ESRC Centre for Business Research, University of Cambridge Working Paper No.

THE LONG-RUN PERFORMANCE OF HOSTILE TAKEOVERS: U.K. EVIDENCE. ESRC Centre for Business Research, University of Cambridge Working Paper No. THE LONG-RUN PERFORMANCE OF HOSTILE TAKEOVERS: U.K. EVIDENCE ESRC Centre for Business Research, University of Cambridge Working Paper No. 215 By Andy Cosh ESRC Centre for Business Research University of

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision Modern Applied Science; Vol. 9, No. 4; 2015 ISSN 1913-1844 E-ISSN 1913-1852 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision Seok Weon Lee 1 1 Division

More information

Internet Appendix to Does Policy Uncertainty Affect Mergers and Acquisitions?

Internet Appendix to Does Policy Uncertainty Affect Mergers and Acquisitions? Internet Appendix to Does Policy Uncertainty Affect Mergers and Acquisitions? Alice Bonaime Huseyin Gulen Mihai Ion March 23, 2018 Eller College of Management, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ 85721.

More information

Corporate Governance, Product Market Competition, and Payout Policy *

Corporate Governance, Product Market Competition, and Payout Policy * Seoul Journal of Business Volume 20, Number 1 (June 2014) Corporate Governance, Product Market Competition, and Payout Policy * HEE SUB BYUN **1) Korea Deposit Insurance Corporation Seoul, Korea JI HYE

More information

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default Trends and Issues October 2018 Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default Chester S. Spatt, Carnegie Mellon University and TIAA Institute Fellow 1. Introduction An

More information

The Effects of Ownership Concentration and Identity on Investment Performance: An. International Comparison *

The Effects of Ownership Concentration and Identity on Investment Performance: An. International Comparison * The Effects of Ownership Concentration and Identity on Investment Performance: An International Comparison * Klaus Gugler, Dennis C. Mueller and B. Burcin Yurtoglu University of Vienna, Department of Economics

More information

The impact of large acquisitions on the share price and operating financial performance of acquiring companies listed on the JSE

The impact of large acquisitions on the share price and operating financial performance of acquiring companies listed on the JSE on CJB the Smit JSE and MJD Ward* The impact of large acquisitions on the share price and operating financial performance of acquiring companies listed 1. INTRODUCTION * A KPMG survey in London found that

More information

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva* The Role of Credit Ratings in the Dynamic Tradeoff Model Viktoriya Staneva* This study examines what costs and benefits of debt are most important to the determination of the optimal capital structure.

More information

CEO Centrality. NELLCO Legal Scholarship Repository NELLCO. Lucian Bebchuk Harvard Law School. Martijn Cremers. Urs Peyer

CEO Centrality. NELLCO Legal Scholarship Repository NELLCO. Lucian Bebchuk Harvard Law School. Martijn Cremers. Urs Peyer NELLCO NELLCO Legal Scholarship Repository Harvard Law School John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business Discussion Paper Series Harvard Law School 11-6-2007 CEO Centrality Lucian Bebchuk Harvard

More information

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance.

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Guillermo Acuña, Jean P. Sepulveda, and Marcos Vergara December 2014 Working Paper 03 Ownership Concentration

More information

The Lifecycle of Firm Takeover Defenses

The Lifecycle of Firm Takeover Defenses The Lifecycle of Firm Takeover Defenses William C. Johnson Jonathan M. Karpoff Sangho Yi Sawyer Business School Foster School of Business Sogang Business School Suffolk University University of Washington

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck

More information

Ownership Dynamics. How ownership changes hands over time and the determinants of these changes. BI NORWEGIAN BUSINESS SCHOOL Master Thesis

Ownership Dynamics. How ownership changes hands over time and the determinants of these changes. BI NORWEGIAN BUSINESS SCHOOL Master Thesis BI NORWEGIAN BUSINESS SCHOOL Master Thesis Ownership Dynamics How ownership changes hands over time and the determinants of these changes Students: Diana Cristina Iancu Georgiana Radulescu Study Programme:

More information

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance.

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. RESEARCH STATEMENT Heather Tookes, May 2013 OVERVIEW My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. Much of my work focuses on understanding the ways in which capital market

More information

Pay for Performance? CEO Compensation and Acquirer Returns in BHCs

Pay for Performance? CEO Compensation and Acquirer Returns in BHCs Pay for Performance? CEO Compensation and Acquirer Returns in BHCs Kristina Minnick Bentley College Haluk Unal University of Maryland Liu Yang University of California at Los Angeles We examine how managerial

More information

An empirical examination of White Knight Corporate Takeovers: Performances and Motivations. Xing Chen. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business

An empirical examination of White Knight Corporate Takeovers: Performances and Motivations. Xing Chen. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business An empirical examination of White Knight Corporate Takeovers: Performances and Motivations Xing Chen A Thesis in The John Molson School of Business Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS, DIVERSIFICATION, AND THE FIRM S LIFECYCLE. Asli M. Arikan René M. Stulz

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS, DIVERSIFICATION, AND THE FIRM S LIFECYCLE. Asli M. Arikan René M. Stulz NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS, DIVERSIFICATION, AND THE FIRM S LIFECYCLE Asli M. Arikan René M. Stulz Working Paper 17463 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17463 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Management Ownership and Dividend Policy: The Role of Managerial Overconfidence

Management Ownership and Dividend Policy: The Role of Managerial Overconfidence 1 Management Ownership and Dividend Policy: The Role of Managerial Overconfidence Cheng-Shou Lu * Associate Professor, Department of Wealth and Taxation Management National Kaohsiung University of Applied

More information

The Tangible Value of Experiential Learning in M&A New Evidence from Takeover of Experienced Deal-Makers

The Tangible Value of Experiential Learning in M&A New Evidence from Takeover of Experienced Deal-Makers The Tangible Value of Experiential Learning in M&A New Evidence from Takeover of Experienced Deal-Makers Dr. Indrajeet Mohite* Abstract Organisational learning theory predicts that firms and their top

More information

Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta

Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta 26 June 2013 Contents 1. Preparation of this report... 1 2. Executive summary... 2 3. Issue and evaluation approach... 4 4. Data... 6

More information

Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation

Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation University of Massachusetts Boston From the SelectedWorks of Atreya Chakraborty January 1, 2010 Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation

More information

When do banks listen to their analysts? Evidence from mergers and acquisitions

When do banks listen to their analysts? Evidence from mergers and acquisitions When do banks listen to their analysts? Evidence from mergers and acquisitions David Haushalter Penn State University E-mail: gdh12@psu.edu Phone: (814) 865-7969 Michelle Lowry Penn State University E-mail:

More information

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem Jin Yong Jung We analyze how the wealth of an agent and its distribution affect the profit of the principal by considering the simple

More information

How Have M&As Changed? Evidence from the Sixth Merger Wave

How Have M&As Changed? Evidence from the Sixth Merger Wave How Have M&As Changed? Evidence from the Sixth Merger Wave G.Alexandridis, C.F. Mavrovitis, and N.G. Travlos* October 2010 We examine the characteristics of the sixth merger wave that started in 2003 and

More information

Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns

Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2014 Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns Courtney D. Winn Utah State University Follow this

More information

Can the Source of Cash Accumulation Alter the Agency Problem of Excess Cash Holdings? Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions ABSTRACT

Can the Source of Cash Accumulation Alter the Agency Problem of Excess Cash Holdings? Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions ABSTRACT Can the Source of Cash Accumulation Alter the Agency Problem of Excess Cash Holdings? Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions ABSTRACT This study argues that the source of cash accumulation can distinguish

More information

Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings

Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings Zhenxu Tong University of Exeter* Paper Number: 08/03 First Draft: June 2007 This Draft: February 2008 Abstract This paper studies how firm

More information

THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN

THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2001 THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage Jin-Chuan Duan * and Yun Li (First draft: April 12, 2006) (This version: May 16, 2006) Abstract This paper identifies a key cause for the documented diversification

More information

Do Value-added Real Estate Investments Add Value? * September 1, Abstract

Do Value-added Real Estate Investments Add Value? * September 1, Abstract Do Value-added Real Estate Investments Add Value? * Liang Peng and Thomas G. Thibodeau September 1, 2013 Abstract Not really. This paper compares the unlevered returns on value added and core investments

More information