Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries"

Transcription

1

2 \

3

4 Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries

5 wy HB31.M415 \r\o.%-z\ (7X) working paper department of economics PRIVA TE AND PUBLIC SUPPL Y OF LIQUIDITY Bengt Holmstrom Jean Tirole June 1996 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass

6

7 PRIVA TE AND PUBLIC SUPPL Y OF LIQUIDITY Bengt Holmstrom Jean Tirole June 1996

8 ittute

9 Private and Public Supply of Liquidity Bengt Holmstrom* and Jean Tirole*" First draft : September 21, 1995 This draft : June 17, 1996 We thank Daron Acemoglu, Sudipto Bhattacharya, Olivier Blanchard, Ricardo Caballero, Peter Diamond, Mark Gertler, Oliver Hart, Peter Howitt, Robert Marquez, Rafael Repullo, Jean-Charles Rochet, Julio Rotemberg, Andrei Shleifer, Jeremy Stein, Bob Wilson and Mike Woodford for helpful discussions and comments. This research was supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation. ** Department of Economics, MIT. *" IDEI and GREMAQ (CNRS URA 947), Toulouse, CERAS (CNRS URA 2036), Paris, and MJT.

10 ABSTRACT This paper addresses a basic, yet unresolved question: Do claims on private assets provide sufficient liquidity for an efficient functioning of the productive sector? Or does the State have a role in creating liquidity and regulating it either through adjustments in the stock of government securities or by other means? In our model, firms can meet future liquidity needs in three ways: by issuing new claims and diluting old ones, by obtaining a credit line from a financial intermediary, and by holding claims on other firms. When there is no aggregate uncertainty, we show that these instruments are sufficient for attaining the socially optimal (second-best) contract between investors and firms. Such a contract imposes both a maximum leverage ratio and a liquidity constraint on firms. Intermediaries coordinate the use of liquidity. Without intermediation, scarce liquidity may be wasted and the social optimum may not be attainable. When there is only aggregate uncertainty, the private sector is no longer self-sufficient with regard to liquidity. The government can improve liquidity, by issuing bonds that commit future consumer income. Government bonds command a liquidity premium over private claims. The government should manage the supply of liquidity by loosening liquidity (boosting the value of its securities) when the aggregate liquidity shock is high and tightening liquidity when the shock is low. The paper thus provides a microeconomic rationale for government supplied liquidity as well as for an active government policy.

11 1. Introduction This paper addresses a basic, yet unresolved question: Do private assets provide sufficient liquidity for the efficient functioning of the productive sector? Or does the State have a role in supplying additional liquidity and regulating it through adjustments in the stock of government securities or by other means? These questions presume a demand for liquidity; without demand there is no need to worry about supply. So why do firms demand liquidity? In the standard theory of finance (and in the Arrow-Debreu world of general equilibrium), firms can at any time issue claims up to the full value of their expected returns. They have no reason to hold liquid reserves in order to meet future financing needs, because they can just as well issue new claims as funding needs arise. As long as they use their funds to finance positive net present value projects, such firms will never encounter any liquidity problems. The first step in our analysis then is to build a model in which there is a demand for liquidity, that is, advance financing is essential. For this purpose we use an entrepreneurial model of moral hazard in which the value of external claims are strictly less than the full value of the firm for the standard reason that the entrepreneur must be given a minimum share of the firm in order to be motivated. The wedge between the full value and the external value of the firm limits the firm's ability to raise funds to finance all projects that have positive net present value. In a dynamic setting, this feature implies that liquidity shocks could force the firm to terminate a project mid-stream even though the project has a positive continuation value. To protect itself against such risks, the firm wants to hold liquid reserves either in the form of marketed assets that can be readily sold or by arranging for credit in advance. We study the determinants of the firm's liquidity demand in a simple, dynamic moral hazard model. There are three periods. At date the firm raises funds to invest in a variablesized project that pays off at date 2. At date 1, the firm experiences a liquidity shock. The shock is a random fraction of the date-0 investment and represents the amount of additional investment that must be made to continue the project. 1 If the necessary funds can be raised, The liquidity shock admits several interpretations. It can be a cost overrun on the 1 initial investment. Alternatively, it can represent a shortfall in the date-1 revenue, which could have been used to finance date-1 operating expenses. Or the shock might simply be information about the firm's date-2 returns. The central feature in all these cases is that the 1

12 the project proceeds, delivering a stochastic date-2 return that depends on the entrepreneur's effort. We show that the optimal date-0 contract between the firm and the outside investors limits both the initial investment level and the amount that the firm is allowed to spend on the liquidity shock, both constraints being proportional to the firm's initial assets. Because the firm is credit constrained, the second-best solution trades off the benefits of a higher initial investment against the increased likelihood of having to terminate the project early and see it all go to waste. This solution can be implemented in several ways. One is to give the firm all the necessary funds in advance, but add a liquidity covenant in which the firm promises to set aside a certain amount of funds to cover future liquidity needs. Alternatively, intermediaries could fund future liquidity needs via a credit line. 2 Having established a demand for liquidity, we move on to study its supply by embedding the model of an individual firm in a general equilibrium model with a large number of such firms. Each firm (or intermediary) can issue arbitrary claims contingent on its date-2 financial position and these claims can be freely traded in the market. 3 The government can also supply liquidity by selling securities such as Treasury bonds. There are no other assets that firms and intermediaries can use to transfer wealth from one period to the next. 4 Thus, a firm can meet liquidity needs in four ways: by issuing claims on its own productive assets, by holding claims on other firms, by holding government issued claims, or by using a credit line. Our main interest is in understanding the government's role in supplying and managing liquidity as a function of the severity and nature of the liquidity shocks. We consider two polar cases, one in which the firms' liquidity shocks are independent, so that there is no aggregate uncertainty, and the opposite case in which the firms' liquidity shocks shock affects the firm's net worth, which determines its financing capacity. 2 Our theory is too sparse to distinguish between different financial institutions. When we use language (intermediary, bank, etc) should be interpreted as illustrative of many similar arrangements. that suggests an institutional interpretation, this 3 In contrast to much of the literature, we do not restrict the set of claims that firms can issue, in order to avoid a spurious demand for publicly supplied liquidity. 4 We can allow other assets, such as real estate, as long as their value does not fulfill the private sector's liquidity needs. See the conclusion.

13 are identical. In the absence of aggregate uncertainty, we show that government securities do not add useful liquidity beyond that provided by private claims, nor does the government have any role in managing aggregate liquidity. 5 There is a simple intuition behind the self-sufficiency of the private sector: The date-1 continuation value of the private sector, which is deterministic, must exceed its date-0 value, else it could not have invested at date 0. Therefore the private sector can raise sufficient funds at date 1 by diluting its shareholdings, or equivalently, by leveraging itself up with new debt. However, even though the private sector is self-sufficient in the aggregate, we show that individual firms will in general be unable to satisfy their liquidity needs by holding only private market instruments. One might have thought that it would suffice for each firm to hold a share of the market portfolio, which it could sell when the liquidity shock hits. However, this market solution is in general not efficient, because lucky firms with low liquidity shocks end up holding excess liquidity. Thus, scarce liquidity is wasted. We show that an optimal allocation can always be achieved by intermediaries. Intermediaries hold corporate securities and simultaneously grant credit lines to firms. They take into account the fact that some firms (namely, those with low liquidity needs) will not exhaust their credit lines at date 1. Intermediaries can therefore redistribute excess liquidity to firms that do need extra funds. They act as liquidity pools or insurers in preventing a wasteful accumulation of liquidity by firms that end up being lucky at date 1. Thus, intermediation may strictly dominate financial markets. Note that it is the anonymity of market claims, and not an informational handicap, that explains why financial markets can be inferior to intermediation. The critical feature of the credit line arrangement that yields a productive optimum is that it allows negative net present value investments at date 1. By contrast, claimholders can dispose of negative value claims in an anonymous financial market. In the presence of pure aggregate uncertainty, the earlier argument for why the private sector is self-sufficient breaks down. Now there can be no cross-subsidization, because each firm faces trouble exactly when the other firms do. As the private sector is unable to provide insurance there will be a liquidity shortage whenever the reinvestment need 5 If issued, government securities will carry no premium. 3

14 exceeds the date-1 value of corporate claims. This creates a potential demand for government-provided liquidity. We show that the government can achieve a Pareto improvement by issuing Treasury bonds, and that these bonds can be sold at a liquidity premium. The private sector is willing to purchase low-yielding securities because they serve as an input into the production process. In our risk-neutral model securities with different rates of return co-exist in equilibrium. It is important to point out what the government can achieve that the private sector cannot. In our model, individual investors can refuse to bring in new funds to the corporate sector at date 1, if this is unprofitable. More precisely, we assume that individual investors cannot at date promise to supply new funds at date 1: For example they may pretend at date 1 that they have no new endowment. This assumption is both theoretically and empirically reasonable. In practice individuals can borrow very limited amounts without pledging assets as collateral (as in the case of a mortgage). Because the private sector has no power to audit income and levy taxes, it is unable to check who is lying about endowments at date 1. By contrast, the government has the power to audit incomes and impose nonfinancial penalties (such as jail) to enforce tax payments. It can therefore, on behalf of the consumers, commit new funds at date l. 6 This is what Treasury bonds issued at date achieve. When the government issues securities at a premium and when firms are constrained to issue a single security (equity), a firm has an incentive to free-ride on the liquidity provided by those firms that purchase government securities. The firm can buy their shares instead of government securities. We show that firms respond to the possibility of free riding by issuing multiple securities so as to price discriminate between investors who value liquidity services much (corporations) and those who don't (consumers). Corporate debt is then sold at a liquidity premium relative to equity. However, these outcomes are not socially efficient in that they lead to distorted reinvestments in an effort to economize on the use of government provided liquidity. show that it is more efficient to have the government issue state-contingent bonds, which We supply liquidity only as needed by the private sector. Such bonds have a high value when 6 If our model were one with overlapping generations, the government could commit future consumers as well as current ones.

15 liquidity needs are high and a low value when liquidity needs are low. We interpret statecontingent bonds as a metaphor for an active government policy in which liquidity is made tight when the aggregate liquidity shock is favorable (low) and loose when the aggregate shock is unfavorable (high). Thus, the model offers a rationale, not only for government supplied liquidity, but also for the active management of liquidity by the government. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up a partial equilibrium model of liquidity demanded by a single firm. Section 3 embeds this model in a general equilibrium model without aggregate uncertainty and shows that the private sector is self-sufficient and that intermediaries are used as liquidity pools. Section 4 studies aggregate uncertainty and analyzes the demand for and supply of government securities, including the optimal use of state-contingent bonds. Section 5 relates our results to the literatures on credit rationing, intermediation and government debt. Section 6 concludes with remarks on the key features of the model and suggestions for future research. 2. Exogenous Liquidity Supply 2. 1 The model. This section studies the investment decision of an individual firm. There are three periods, t = 0,1,2 and two types of agents, firms (entrepreneurs) and investors (consumers). There is one (universal) good used both for consumption and investment. All agents are risk neutral with an additively separable utility function over undiscounted consumption streams. For the moment we assume that the good can be stored at a zero rate of return and simply refer to it as "cash". This guarantees that there is no shortage of liquidity. In later sections we will drop this assumption as we are interested in the endogenous supply of liquidity, that is, in how well financial assets can service future funding needs of firms. The firm has access to a stochastic constant-returns-to-scale technology, which for an initial investment I returns RI if the project succeeds and if it fails. The scale of the investment I can be varied freely, subject only to financial constraints. The investment is made at date 0. At date 1, an additional, uncertain amount pi > of cash is needed to finance cost overrruns or date-1 operating expenditures and thus to carry on with the project. The liquidity shock p is distributed according to the cumulative distribution function F, with

16 a density function f. If pi is not paid, the project terminates and yields nothing. If pi is paid, the project continues and its payoff is realized at date 2. Investment is subject to moral hazard in that the firm (entrepreneur) privately chooses the probability p that the project succeeds. The firm can either "behave" or "shirk". If the firm behaves the probability of success is Ph (high), if it shirks the probability of success is pl (l w )» where Ph - Pl Ap > 0. If the firm shirks, it enjoys a private benefit, BI > 0, proportional to the level of its investment I. The firm makes the decision on p after the continuation decision. If the project is abandoned, no decision on p needs to be made. The timing of events is described in Figure 1. DateO Datel Date 2 Continue * X -K- - -*- Financial contract Investment Liquidity shock (pl) Abandon Moral hazard Outcome (Rl or 0) Figure 1 The firm has a date-0 endowment of cash, A, and no endowments at dates 1 and 2. 7 If the firm wants to invest I > A, it will need to raise I - A from outside investors. For the moment, we assume that the initial investment level, the project outcome and the liquidity shock are all verifiable (as we will see, nothing changes if only the entrepreneur observes the liquidity shock). A contract with the investors specifies the amount that the investors will contribute at date 0, the scale I of the project, the contingencies in which the project is continued at date-1, who pays for the liquidity shocks, and finally how the proceeds from the investment are distributed. A key constraint on the contract is that the firm cannot pay out more funds than it has; there is limited liability. It is easy to show that an optimal allocation has the following simple structure. The 7 There is no loss of generality in assuming this. In the presence of a random date-1 revenue stream, the liquidity shock must be thought of as being net of the date-1 revenue.

17 firm invests all its funds initially with the balance of the investment, I - A, paid by the investors. The project is continued if and only if the liquidity shock falls below a threshold p, p < p. Neither the investors nor the firm receive anything if the project fails or is abandoned. If the project succeeds, investors are paid R;I and the firm is paid RJ, where Rj + R f = R. 8 This allocation has three free parameters to be determined: the scale of the project I, the cut-off p, and the investors' share Rj. To make the analysis interesting, we will assume that the project has a positive net present value if the firm is diligent, but not if it shirks: max ff(p)ph R-l-[V(p)dpl >0 >maxjf(p)p L R+B-l-j'pf(p)dp. (1) P Note that the first maximum is achieved by setting p = p t = ph R. That is, net present value is maximized by continuing the project whenever the expected return exceeds the additional need for funding. We will refer to p, as the first-best threshold. We turn to the second-best solution. If the firm continues, it must be given an incentive to be diligent. This requires that (Ap)R f I > BI. (2) As is standard in models with limited liability, the firm must be bribed to be diligent. According to (2), the minimum bribe per unit of investment is Rf = R b = B/Ap. 9 We assume that this minimum is so high that the residual share that can be pledged to investors, R - R b, is insufficient to cover the expected cost of the investors' investment. If the return required by investors is zero, this assumption holds if where F(p)p <l+[v(p)dp for all p, (3) Jo p = ph (R-R b) 8 In this two-outcome world the investors' claim can either be interpreted as debt (the firm must pay back R^I and defaults if it cannot) or as equity (there is no debt and the investors hold an equity share R/R). 9 The minimum payment to the entrepreneur can more broadly be interpreted as a rent shared by all employees of the firm. Without such rents, employees will not work as efficiently.

18 is the date-1 pledgeable per-unit return. Note that condition (3) is equivalent to the condition that some equity is needed to implement the threshold that is most favorable to outside investors : F(Po)Po< 1 + {V(p)dp. Given that the investors' time preference is zero, the return they will require will also be zero as long as they collectively have more cash than demanded by the firms. We will maintain this assumption throughout the paper. With a zero rate of return, and for a given cutoff p, the investors' break-even constraint is F(p) p H (R-R f )I >I-A+I [p f(p)dp. (4) Jo The left-hand side represents the ex ante "pledgable expected income", which must exceed the investors' expected outlays found on the right-hand side. Given (3), we see that the break-even constraint limits the firm's investment to a finite level, which we might term its investment capacity. Because investors break even, the firm's net utility equals the social surplus of the project, namely U(p,I) = [F(p)p,-1- fpf(p)dp] I = m(p)i, (5) Jo where m(p), the term in brackets in (5), represents the marginal return on a unit of initial investment. For a given p, the second-best solution therefore maximizes I, implying, by (4), that it is optimal to set R f = R b. The firm's investment capacity is then where I = k(p)a, (6a) k(p)^^ ppf(p)dp-f(p)p Jo (6b) is the equity multiplier. Maximal leverage is achieved by setting p=p. The equity multiplier can be less than 1 if the expected liquidity demand at date 1 is sufficiently high. In that case I-A < 0. (The total investment, that is, the initial investment plus the expected liquidity payments, will of course exceed the firm's initial cash A.) Unless otherwise

19 specified, we will assume that I-A > 0. That is, that the firm is a net borrower at date (this will be the case if the denominator in (6b) is less than 1 for p = p,). It remains to determine the optimal continuation threshold. Intuition might suggest that it would be optimal to let the firm continue whenever continuation is ex post efficient (p < p,). Indeed, the first-best cut-off p, = ph R maximizes the per-unit profit of investing, m(p). However, at p,, the equity multiplier k(p) is decreasing in p, indicating that one ought to choose a lower treshold than the ex post efficient one. Substituting (6) into (5) and dividing through by F(p), one finds that the optimal (second-best) threshold, p*, minimizes the expected unit cost of total expected investment: p* minimizes l+fvcpjdp ^ * F(p) (7)' It is not difficult to show that the optimal threshold satisfies,0 p (R-R b ) = p < p* < p, = p H R. (8) These bounds can be given a simple economic interpretation. The lower bound is explained by the fact that if p < p, both the firm and the investors prefer to continue with the project ex post. The upper bound is explained by the fact that if p > p the net present value of continuing is negative, in which case an ex post Pareto improvement could be achieved by having investors compensate the firm (which always likes to continue ex post) for abandoning the project. Since transfers from investors to the firm are not constrained by incentive compatibility, both parties would agree to abandon the project given such a liquidity shock. Since k(p ) represents the largest investment scale that the firm can achieve, while p x maximizes the ex post surplus, we see that the second-best solution trades off a larger investment scale at date against fewer liquidations (more investment) at date 1. The firm 10 Note that p* does not depend on either p or p,, so how can (8) hold? The answer is that program (7) gives the optimal cut-off only if (1) and (3) hold. We must have p* > p, else the firm would not be credit constrained at all and condition (3) would be violated. If p* > p,, investment would not be profitable and condition (1) would be violated. Note also that the first-order condition for (7) can be written P*. f'f(p)dp = 1. Jo A mean-preserving spread in the distribution of the liquidity shock therefore decreases

20 cannot freely choose both variables, because by (2) it is limited in its ability to transfer social surplus to investors. Consequently, the firm distributes available funds so that it is credit rationed both ex ante and ex post. For future reference, we record the following result: Lemma 1: // is optimalfor thefirm to adopt a cut-offpolicy in which liquidity needs are met if and only if p < p. (i) The firm's investment capacity I = k(p)a is quasi-concave in p, with a maximum at p=p. (ii) The marginal return on investment m(p) is quasi-concave in p, with a maximum at p =p r (Hi) The firm's expected output (F(p)p,k(p)A) and the value of external claims on this output (F(p)p k(p)a) are quasi-concave in p, with a maximum at the second-best optimum p=p' Implementation of the optimal policy. Suppose the decision to continue the project is left to be negotiated at date 1. In that case, investors would be willing to inject more cash into the project if p < p, but not if liquidity needs exceed p. In the latter case, even if the firm were allowed to dilute the claims of the initial investors by issuing senior securities at date 1, it could not raise enough cash, because the maximal value of the firm's external claims is pj. Thus, to cover the firm's liquidity needs at date 1 when p e (p, p*) one must find a way for investors to commit sufficient funds at date 0. One solution is to give the firm I - A at date and extend it an irrevocable line of credit in the amount p*i to be used for liquidity needs at date 1. Given that the firm cannot consume funds, and always prefers to continue, it will do so as long as the credit line permits. 11 This implements the optimal solution. [Equivalently, the investors can extend an 11 Could the line of credit be renegotiated for mutual advantage once p is realized? The answer is no. If p < p*, then p < ph R and it is ex post efficient to continue so there is no scope for renegotiation. Nor can both parties benefit from an increase in the line of credit when p* < p < ph R. Even though this increase raises total surplus, there is no way to 10

21 irrevocable credit line in the amount (p* -p ) I and grant the firm the right to dilute outside claims as needed to cover the liquidity shock.] In practice, individuals do not grant credit lines, because they cannot commit future income or endowments. Ex post, credit line commitments would be either unprofitable, in which case investors would claim that they have no funds, or be profitable, in which case a commitment was unnecessary. Instead, credit lines are granted by intermediaries such as banks, which can make commitments (both in practice and in our model), assuming of course that they have enough funds to meet later credit needs. This raises the question: How do intermediaries guarantee that their own liquidity needs can be met? In the next section, we show that they can do so by issuing shares that pay off only at date 2. An alternative solution is to give the firm 1(1 +p*) - A at date 1, and require that p*i of this amount is kept in liquid assets. In other words, investors demand that the firm maintains a liquidity ratio equal to p7(l+p*), at least up to date 1. Indeed, a minimum liquidity ratio is a commonly observed debt covenant. As in the case of credit lines, intermediaries are the natural party for overseeing the compliance of such a covenant. It is worth stressing that the partial equilibrium model does not distinguish between a credit line and the hoarding of liquid assets by the firm. But as the next section shows these two methods of providing reserves are no longer equivalent once general equilibrium aspects (namely, that the supply of liquid assets is not unlimited) are brought into consideration. Remark 1: We assumed that the liquidity shock is verifiable. Nothing is altered if only the firm observes the liquidity shock as long as the firm cannot use part of the credit line or its financial assets for consumption at date 1. Given the firm's reserves, it can continue whenever p <p*. If p > p", it cannot continue, since no outsider can be induced to invest in the firm. A rational investor would infer that a firm that tries to raise new funds does so because it has exceeded its reserves and therefore has experienced a shock p > p' > p. Remark 2: If investors cannot control the firm's use of funds, one can show that the firm does not want to distribute the funds between date-0 investment and date-1 investment in accordance with the second-best solution. Either the firm wants to invest less initially in distribute the surplus in a manner that satisfies the investors. 11

22 order to be able to continue in more states at date 1. Or the firm wants to invest excessively at date 0, relying partly on being bailed out by the investors when p < p and there is a cash shortfall (a version of the soft-budget constraint problem). To illustrate the latter possibility, suppose that the firm invests the full amount 1(1 +p*) = I* in illiquid assets. Despite the lack of cash left for reinvestment, the project will often be continued, as the investors have an incentive to rescue the firm as long as p < p. Of course, the investors might want to claim initially that they will not put any more money into the venture, but this is not a credible commitment. Anticipating a "soft budget constraint", the firm may overinvest. Indeed the firm prefers investing I* rather than I if F(p-)p H R b I < F(Po)PhRJ*, or FfcO < F(p )(l+p-). This condition can be satisfied by adjusting B so that p falls just below p'. We summarize this section in: Proposition 1. In the second-best allocation: (i) A firm with initial capital A invests I = k(p')a where k(-) is given by (6b). fti) The project is continued if and only if the liquidity shock falls below the cutoff p\ The cutoff p' lies strictly between the (per-unit-of-invcstment) pledgeable expected return p = ph (R-B/Ap) and the expected return p, = p R. (iii) Neither party is paid anything if the project is terminated or fails. If the project succeeds, the firm is paid (B/Ap)I and the investors (R-B/Ap)I. (iv) This second-best allocation can be implemented by raising (I-A) in externalfundsfor the initial investment and extending the firm a line of credit in the amount p' I to be used for reinvestment. Alternatively, the firm gets (1 + p')l at date with the convenant that it keeps p'l in reserve for reinvestments. 3. Endogenous Liquidity Supply without Aggregate Uncertainty. 3.1 The economy. Next we embed our model in a general equilibrium framework. Our objective is to analyze the endogenous supply of liquidity. To focus on the problem of creating assets that 12

23 can meet the demand for liquidity at date 1, we drop the assumption that there is an exogenously given storage technology. The single consumption good can no longer be stored (there is no longer cash), nor are there any other private assets (like real estate) that can be used to transfer wealth from one period to the next. The only private way to transfer wealth across periods is by buying claims issued by firms. Later on, we will introduce government bonds. There is a continuum of firms with unit mass. Each firm is endowed with the stochastic technology described in section 2. Because of constant returns to scale, there is no loss in assuming that firms have identical endowments; the representative firm is endowed with A units of the good at date and none at dates 1 and 2. As before, consumers and entrepreneurs are risk neutral and do not care about the timing of consumption. Their expected utility for consumption is E[c + c, + cj. Consumers receive per-period endowments that collectively are large enough to finance all required investments and taxes that may be levied. Consumers cannot sell claims on their future endowments, because they can default with impunity. Any assets purchased by the consumers must yield a zero expected return given that their collective endowments exceed investment demand. By contrast, firms may be willing to purchase assets at a premium (a negative return) as long as those assets help them to meet their liquidity needs. Thus, rates of return, to the extent they deviate from zero, will be entirely determined by the productive sector. This is the convenience afforded by a linear preference structure. In this section we will consider the case where liquidity shocks are independent. Because there is a continuum of firms, there is no aggregate uncertainty and F(p) denotes both the ex ante probability that a given firm faces a liquidity shock below p and the realized fraction of firms with liquidity shock below p. The independence assumption and the analysis in section 2 imply that the date-1 funds needed by the productive sector to achieve the productive optimum is the deterministic amount D = [f'"pf(p)dp]i, (9) Jo where I is the representative firm's investment. The two ways of implementing the productive optimum discussed in section 2, an 13

24 irrevocable credit line or a liquidity requirement, both relied on an exogenously supplied liquid asset, cash. With cash no longer available, we are led to investigate whether firms can finance their liquidity needs D by using available market instruments, that is, by issuing additional claims at date 1 or by holding stakes in other firms. 3.2 Financial markets. For the time being, assume that there are no intermediaries. There is only a financial market for claims issued by firms. The financial market is anonymous in that the return on a given claim is independent of who holds it. We first compute the maximum amount that a firm can raise at date 1 by selling new (senior) securities in the financial market. Assuming that the firm is able to continue with the amount thus raised, its market value (the maximum amount it can raise) is ph (R-R b )I = Pol. The market value pqi reflects the fact that the firm must retain the stake RJ as an inside claim in order to behave. Since date-0 investors, those who bought the firm's initial securities, get nothing if the firm cannot meet its liquidity needs, they are willing (ex post) to dilute their claims up to the full amount pqi in order to salvage some of their initial investment. Of course, initial investors take the possibility of dilution into account in the pricing of initial claims. A firm is unable to meet its liquidity needs by issuing new claims whenever the realized liquidity shock p falls in the interval (p,p ]. Can a firm cover the potential shortfall by buying, at date 0, claims issued by other firms and selling these claims at date 1? That is, can the firm assure itself enough liquidity through the financial market? The answer is in general negative. To develop an intuition for why the financial market may be unable to serve the firms' liquidity needs efficiently, let us assume (for illustration only) that all external claims are equity claims and that they are gathered in a single stock index (a mutual fund), which firms can buy. The absence of aggregate shocks implies that S,, the value of the stock index at date 1, is deterministic. Suppose that the productive optimum of section 2 obtains; a firm with liquidity shock p continues if and only if p < p\ Then, a fraction F(p*) of firms will continue at date 1. The total value of external claims on the productive sector at date 1 (and 14

25 date 2) is V, v =F(p *r -\ )p ti. (10) In the absence of credit lines, these external claims need to be diluted by the amount D defined in (9), so, the value S, of the stock index at date 1 is S, = V.-D = [F(p')p -fpf(p)dp]i=i-a. Jo (11) Let us conduct the following thought experiment: Suppose that a fraction a e [0,1) of the stock index is held by the firms themselves. All firms have the same share in the index. At date 1, each firm can then withstand liquidity shocks p satisfying pi<p I + os r (12) For the right-hand side of (12) to be equal to p*i for some a < 1, one must have: p* + f"pf(p)dp<[l + F(p-)]p. (13) Jo Recalling that p* is independent of the extent of moral hazard as measured by B (see (7)), we conclude that for B large enough, that is for p small enough, condition (13) is violated in which case firms are unable to withstand liquidity shocks up to p* by holding the stock index. Intuitively, when the firm's insider share R b is large, an individual firm cannot raise much capital by diluting itself at date 1. Concurrently, the stock index has a low value and the firm cannot raise much by selling the stock index either. Actually, as the next section demonstrates, the issue is not that the stock market delivers too little liquidity in the aggregate. Rather, the ex post distribution of liquid assets is inefficient. The lucky firms (those with liquidity shocks p < p ) hold shares in the stock index, which they do not need. Meanwhile, other firms cannot withstand their larger liquidity shocks because their share in the stock index is confined to be the average share An example may be helpful. Suppose p is uniformly distributed over [0,2] and the parameters are such that p = 1.1 and p, = 3. Then (7) implies p* = 2. The initial 15

26 It is clear that the previous reasoning does not rely on there being a single financial claim (the stock index) that firms can purchase. More generally, S, the difference between the total value of external claims and the aggregate reinvestment cost when the threshold is p* is an upper bound on the combined value of all external date-0 claims on the productive sector. Hence, in the aggregate, the value of the financial claims held by the firms cannot exceed S,. Given that dilution cannot raise more than p 1 per firm, some firms (all firms, if financial claims are uniformly distributed among firms) cannot withstand shocks exceeding p 1 + S,. optimum. To conclude, anonymous financial markets cannot in general implement the productive 3.3 Intermediation. When the financial market fails to supply enough liquidity, the productive optimum can be implemented by introducing an intermediary that offers insurance against liquidity needs by pooling firm risks. The optimal insurance arrangement entails subsidizing firms with a high liquidity demand, allowing them to draw on the market value of firms that experience a low liquidity demand. We first check that there is enough liquidity in the aggregate to implement the secondbest policy. Let all individual firms be pooled together into a single firm, an economy-wide conglomerate. Assuming that the conglomerate follows the second-best policy, where individual firms continue if and only if p < p*, the conglomerate can be sold at date 1 (gross of reinvestments) for the value F(p*)poI. The conglomerate needs to raise D (see (9)) to cover its liquidity needs. Since F(p*)poI - D = S,, which is positive, the conglomerate can raise the necessary funds to implement the second-best policy. It remains to show that an intermediary can make full use of the potential market value of the private sector. There are many equivalent ways in which this can be done. The investment level is I = A/(.9). If A = 9, then I = 10, with outside investors investing 1 and the firm 9. Thus, the outside investors' stake in the stock index is worth 1. But p*-po = -9, implying that there will be realizations of p such that firms will need up to 9 shares of the stock index in order to continue. That is nine times as many shares as each can purchase at date 0. 16

27 simplest is to let the intermediary be a conglomerate as above." At date 0, it issues shares to investors. These shares are claims on the intermediary's financial position at date The intermediary uses the proceeds from its share issue to buy up all the external claims on firms. Firms' securities are priced so that the intermediary breaks even on each firm issue (ex ante). Similarity, the shares of the intermediary are so priced that investors break even. Assuming that the intermediary succeeds in implementing the second-best policy, its shares will now sell for the amount S,, since its market value equals the value of its investment portfolio. The intermediary's net "cash flow" at date is zero, guaranteeing that the arrangement is financially feasible. The intermediary proceeds to grant each firm a credit line equal to p*i. Attached to the credit line is the covenant that a firm cannot issue new claims at date 1. A firm can use all or just a portion of its credit line at date 1. There is no charge for using credit (we will return to this point below). However, the firm has no use for excess credit, since the enterpreneur cannot consume funds and any returns from market assets that the firm might purchase at date 1 will go to the intermediary (except for the portion RJ, which goes to the entrepreneur if the project succeeds). Given the credit line, a firm can continue whenever P ^ P*- The only remaining issue is whether the intermediary can raise enough funds at date 1 to meet its (deterministic) credit obligations D. But this follows immediately from the fact, argued above, that the private sector can in the aggregate raise S, + D > D (assuming I - A > 0). Remark 1: We argued in section 3.1 that the financial market fails to provide adequate liquidity because the value of financial claims held by a firm cannot be contingent on a firm's idiosyncratic liquidity shock. Consequently, firms with low liquidity shocks end up with excessive liquidity, that could be efficiently redistributed to firms with higher liquidity shocks. Such a redistribution however does not occur spontaneously at date 1, since the liquidity-rich firms have no incentives to enter negative NPV arrangements with liquidity- 13 In our model, the number of intermediaries is indeterminate. We will describe the implementation of the second-best solution as if there were a single intermediary. 14 As in Jacklin (1987), it is important to avoid claims that can be redeemed at date 1, since such claims can lead to "bank runs". 17

28 poor ones. One may wonder what it is that an intermediary can do that the financial market cannot do. Intermediation docs not dominate financial markets on informational grounds. Rather, the critical feature of the credit line arrangement that yields a productive optimum is that it allows negative NPV investments at date l. 15 By contrast, claimholders can dispose of negative value claims in an anonymous financial market. Remark 2: Because the private sector is self-sufficient there is no role for government securities. If issued, government securities must yield the market rate of interest, here equal to zero, and they have no impact on the productive sector. Remark 3: Many alternative arrangements involving intermediation are equivalent to the one described above. For instance, the intermediary could be made to resemble a bank by letting firms issue shares directly to investors and having the intermediary hold only firm debt (claims senior to equity). The intermediary could also charge the firm according to the amount of credit used, rather than just an up-front fixed fee. To illustrate, a credit arrangement could call for a repayment of (p/p*) (R-R b )I at date 2 (which can be met, of course, only if the project succeeds) if the firm uses pi (< p*) of credit at date 1. Note that the implied price for credit is below par, as the expected repayment equals (pp<)/p*)i, which is less than pi, the amount of credit used. In fact, because firms are fully diluted when p > p, there is no credit contract that charges an actuarially fair price for all realizations of p. An additional up-front fee must be imposed to cover the intermediary's expected loss. In reality, such fees are common, suggesting that use of credit is indeed underpriced ex post. Variations like these only influence how surplus is redistributed among external claim holders and how initial claims are priced, but they have no effect on real outcomes and therefore we can proceed without pinning down these contractual details. 16 We summarize this section in: Proposition 2. In the absence of aggregate uncertainty: (i) The productive optimum cannot always be achieved through an (anonymous) financial 15 To offset the date-1 loss, the intermediary receives either an upfront commitment fee or securities in the firm at date Monitoring and control right considerations could be introduced to reduce contractual ambiguity, but the implications of such embellishments must await further research. 18

29 market. Ex post, liquidity may be misallocated. (li) The productive optimum can be implcmcmcd (if 1 - A > 0) by relying on private intermediation of credit. Intermediaries act as insurers against liquidity shocks, crosssubsidizing firms. Intermediaries need not observe individual liquidity shocks in order to implement the optimum. fiii) There is no liquidity role for government securities. If issued, such securities must be offered at par (yielding zero interest) and do not affect real allocations. 4. Endogenous Liquidity Supply with Pure Aggregate Uncertainty 4. 1 The demand for government bonds. In the previous section liquidity shocks were independent. We now shift to the other extreme, the case where there is only aggregate uncertainty. All firms experience the same liquidity shock. It is clear that in this case the private sector cannot be self-sufficient. With pure aggregate uncertainty, every firm needs to raise pi at the same time. Since a firm is worth at most pj t0 outsiders at date 1, the aggregate demand for liquidity will exceed the aggregate value of the private sector whenever p < p < p\ Intermediation cannot overcome the problem, because at best it can realize the net ex post value of the productive sector, which in this event is zero. This creates a demand for government supplied liquidity. The government can meet the demand thanks to its assumed ability to commit future consumer endowments via taxation. Suppose the government issues one-period bonds in the amount (p*-p )I at date 0, and sells them at par. We are then back to the environment analyzed in section 2, with government bonds providing a storage facility equivalent to cash. The productive optimum can be achieved by having investors invest (1 +p*)i - A in each firm at date 0, requiring firms to spend (p*-p )I of this amount on the purchase of bonds. 17 Since government bonds, issued at par, lead to the productive optimum, Lemma 1 tells us that the introduction of these bonds raises total output and expected aggregate 17 Alternatively, an intermediary can offer each firm a credit line (p"-p )I, backed by the purchase of an equal amount of government bonds. Firms can raise the missing PqI by issuing new shares. 19

30 investment (the date-0 investment plus the expected value of date-1 reinvestments). Note, however, that the initial level of investment I decreases as firms save more of their resources to cover date-1 liquidity needs. Thus, issuing government bonds crowds out productive investments at date 0, but increases (expected) reinvestments at date 1. We record these results in: Proposition 3. In the presence of aggregate uncertainty: ft) The private sector is not self-sufficient. fti) Assuming that the net social cost of taxation is zero, the government can ensure the productive optimum by issuing a sufficient amount of bonds at the market rate of interest (here, zero) in which case there is no demand for intermediation. ftii) The introduction of government bonds reduces date-0 investments and increases date-1 reinvestments (reduces liquidations). Expected output, aggregate investment and the value of firms all increase. 4.2 The government's objective and liquidity premia. By restricting attention to government securities that yield the market rate of interest, section 4.1 made two implicit assumptions. First, that there is no deadweight loss of taxation. 18 Otherwise, the gain in productive efficiency brought about by the bond issue must be traded off against the change in the deadweight loss of taxation. Second, that the government maximizes the firms' profit subject to the consumers breaking even. If either assumption is violated, the government may want to issue securities at a price q above par (q > 1) per unit of expected return. We refer to q-1 as the liquidity premium. For small premia, there is still a demand for government securities, since the private sector uses them as complementary inputs into the production process. As is well known, credit rationing models raise some difficult conceptual issues for a welfare analysis. A government that aims at maximizing total surplus (consumers' plus producers') would redistribute all endowments to entrepreneurs as one unit of net worth creates more than one unit of output. On the other hand, a government that only represents 18 Or, more generally, the marginal deadweight loss of taxation is the same at all dates, so the date-0 deadweight loss due to the income received by issuing government securities is equal to the date-1 (or date-2) deadweight loss associated with the reimbursement of the public debt. 20

31 , I consumers might confiscate some or all of the entrepreneurs' initial wealth A. Because this conceptual issue is not specific to our model and lies beyond the limited scope of this paper, we will not investigate the effects of alternative assumptions on the government's objective function. Instead, we simply assume that the government arranges for firms to bear the net cost of supplying liquidity, leaving consumers as well off as without government intervention (see, however, the up-coming remark on seignorage). The net tax effect incorporates the benefit of distributing the proceeds from the bond issue at date (or reducing date-0 taxes) and the deadweight loss from taxing consumers to redeem the bonds at date 1. It is apparent that at the social optimum the marginal deadweight loss of taxation must be time increasing. Suppose that the marginal deadweight loss were higher at date than at date 1, say. The government could then issue at date additional one-period bonds at par (at zero rate of interest). The taxpayers would strictly gain; furthermore the firms would be made (at least weakly) better off by the increased supply of liquidity. We conclude that, for the optimal debt policy, q > l The demand for government bonds. Let us for the moment rule out cross-shareholdings and intermediation, and run through the analysis of section 2. 1 to see how firms respond to the presence of a liquidity premium q-1 > 0. For the moment, assume that a firm cannot partially liquidate its investment. (We will later discuss the case of partial liquidation at the firm level.) For a threshold p, the investors' participation constraint becomes F(p)p I >I-A +(j'pf(p)dp)l+(q-l)(p-p )I (14) where use is made of the fact that the maximum dilution at date 1 is p 1, so that (p-p ) in government securities is needed to reach the threshold p. The firm's net utility is now U,(p,q) = m(p,q)k(p,q)a (15). 19 The government cannot gain by reimbursing public debt at date 2, because the deadweight loss of taxation is higher at date 2 than at date 1 by the same reasoning. 21

32 where m(p,q) = F(p)p,-l-J pf(p)dp-(q-l)(p-p ) fi is the modified margin on per-unit-of-investment profit, and k(p,q) = -, 1+ pf(p)dp + (q-l)(p-po)-f(p)p Jo (17) is the modified equity multiplier. The firm chooses the threshold p*(q) to minimize the expected unit cost of effective investment: l+fpf(p)dp+(q-l)(p-p ) (18) p * (q) minimizes ^ F(p) over p >p. As a generalization of condition (8) we get 20 Po<P*(q) + -^rr<pr (19) f(p (q)) We next ask whether this allocation remains an equilibrium when firms are allowed to issue and trade claims in a financial market. First we argue that, if firms are constrained to issue a single security (equity), the equilibrium described above unravels because of freeriding. Suppose that all firms issue shares at date 0. Suppose a contrario that the opening of the financial market does not affect the equilibrium. Shares must then trade at par, else investors would not want to buy them. But then an individual firm could satisfy its liquidity needs more cheaply by buying shares rather than government bonds. To see this, note that the representative firm in the equilibrium without a financial market has an ex post value equal to (p*(q)-p)i > when the liquidity shock p falls in the interval (p,p*(q)]- This value 20 The firm's optimal cut-off, p*(q), need not be monotone in q. The firm may respond to an increase in q by reducing its date-0 investment and raising the date-1 cut-off. On the other hand, if q is high enough, shutting down all demand for bonds, the firm's date-0 investment will be higher than if q were equal to 1 (see Proposition 3). 22

33 stems from the excess amount of bonds it holds. Hence, by holding enough shares in the other firms, an individual firm can accommodate shocks arbitrarily close to p*(q) without paying any liquidity premium. Thus, the equilibrium without cross-shareholdings must unravel once firms are allowed to buy each others' shares. The intuition why the equilibrium breaks down is clear: Liquidity is a public good if the government charges a premium. Each firm therefore wants to free ride on firms that purchase government bonds. Of course, all firms cannot follow the free-rider strategy, since then no firm would buy government bonds and there would be no protection at all against liquidity shocks above p. 4.4 An analysis of the private sector's optimal policy. This section derives the private sector's optimal policy when the government charges a premium. The next section will analyze the implementation of this policy, in particular the private sector's response to the possibility of free-riding. Suppose the private sector buys (p p )I bonds (where I is the investment level of the representative firm) and allocates the funds efficiently at date 1. All firms can withstand the liquidity shock if p < p, but if p > p, some firms must shut down. Instead of shutting down all firms, however, the private sector can resort to partial liquidation at the industry level, allowing a fraction (p ~PoV(p ~Po) of firms to continue (we can assume that the identity of firms that are allowed to continue is drawn randomly). Whether this is optimal depends on how high the liquidity shock is. If p is high enough, it may be better to return the bonds to the investors rather than use the funds for reinvestment. To determine the private sector's optimal policy, let zl be the face value of the bonds that the private sector buys and let X(p,z) be the fraction of firms allowed to continue when the aggregate shock is p. Recalling that entrepreneurs get ph R b = p, - p per unit of investment in case of continuation, an optimal strategy can be found by solving the following program: 23

34 max I X(/>,z)(p,-p )f(p)dp, Jo I,X(0 s.t. (i) lji ) a> X(p,z)p f(p)dp-l[^x(p,z)pf(p)dp + (q-l) (20) (ii) < X(p,z) < min [l, X. I P-P* J Letting 5 be the Lagrangian multiplier for the budget constraint, the optimal choice of X is X(p,z) =. mil '['-. -Pol if p <p > if p >p (21) The choice of z is governed by the first-order condition: r' U*z 3X(p,z) 3z [( Pl -p ) + 5(p -p)]f(p)dp - 5(q-l) = 0. (22) Note that the lower integration bound is p +z due to (21). Also, by (21), the term in brackets in the integrand is non-negative. Therefore, (22) implies that 9X(5,z)/3z > for some values of p, as 5 and (q-1) > 0. In particular, z < p - p so that whenever z + p =, p < p < p, we have < X(p,z) < 1, implying that the private sector uses the option of partial liquidation for these p-values. The reason the private sector resorts to partial liquidation should be clear. If the private sector bought enough bonds to allow all firms to continue whenever p < p, the choice of X would be unconstrained (X would equal or 1). The first-order cost of a reduction in z would then be zero, while the first-order benefit would be q-1 > 0; it would be better to reduce z. Partial liquidation allows the private sector to economize on the use of bonds. Only when bonds carry no opportunity cost ex post (q = 1) will the private sector buy full coverage against adverse liquidity shocks. We summarize the characteristics of the optimal solution in Proposition 4. Ifq > 1, that is, if the net deadweight loss of taxation (which must be nonnegative) is strictly positive, the private sector's optimal solution is characterized by two 24

35 thresholds, p and p, such that: CO Po < P < P < Pi- (ii) The private sector buys zl = (p-po)i > government bonds. (Hi) Allfirms continue if p < p; the fraction (p Po)/(p Po) < 1 offirms continues ifp < p < p; no firms continue if p > p. independently. This solution is more efficient, privately and socially, than when firms act The last inequality in part (i) follows because h represents the marginal value of firm wealth and therefore must be greater than 1. The private sector's solution is better than the solution that individual firms could obtain (as described in section 4.2), because partial liquidation is feasible at the industry level, but not at the firm level. The outcome is also socially more efficient, because consumers are as well off whether firms act alone or collectively. In both cases all the social surplus goes to the entrepreneurs. 21 Note that had partial liquidation been feasible at the firm level, the analysis of section 4.3 would have coincided with that of this section, with the convention that X(p,z) would have denoted the fraction of the individual firm's investment that is not liquidated when the aggregate shock is p. 4.5 Implementing the optimal policy: A rationale for multiple securities. We now turn to the implementation of the optimal policy derived in section 4.4. There are two distinct issues for implementation. First, the private sector's optimal policy involves partial liquidation. If partial liquidation is infeasible at the firm level, it must be performed at the industry level. Financial 21 It is worth noting that the established social value of the private optimum depends on the government's objective function. If the government, instead of letting all the surplus go to the entrepreneurs, chose to maximize its net revenue from selling bonds (that is, consumer surplus), it may well be that restrictions on private arrangements would lead to a higher social utility. The private sector's optimal policy just described has two effects. On one hand it makes bonds more valuable to firms, increasing their demand; on the other hand, it allows firms to bypass the government's mark-up, reducing the demand for bonds. This situation is reminiscent of a government trying to maximize seignorage in a monetary model. Seignorage may be higher if private liquidity creation by way of intermediation and crossshareholdings is restricted. 25

36 markets in general cannot implement the partial liquidation policy described in Proposition 4 iii), since the private sector as a whole would need to buy strictly more than (p-p )I government bonds. There is thus a need for intermediation. Note that the role of the intermediary is here to implement the partial liquidation policy while economizing on expensive government bonds; by contrast in the absence of aggregate liquidity shock, liquid claims commanded no premium and the role of intermediaries was to dispatch liquidity properly among heterogenous firms. When partial liquidation is feasible at the firm level, intermediation no longer plays a role 22 since the individual firm's program coincides with the private sector's. We conclude that under a pure aggregate shock intermediation is necessary only when partial liquidation at the firm level is infeasible. Second, and more interestingly, whether intermediation is used or not, free-riding is an issue and in either case the solution is the issuing of multiple securities. The rationale for multiple securities is a clientele one. Free-riding may arise because firms that buy costly Treasury securities provide socially valuable liquidity to other firms that invest in them. The purchasers of Treasury securities however cannot internalize the value of this liquidity service if they also want to sell shares to consumers, who have no liquidity needs. Indeed shares must be sold at par to consumers, which precludes charging a liquidity premium to corporate purchasers of shares. Because the industry needs outside funding, we conclude that the optimum derived in section 4.4 cannot be achieved if firms issue a single security. In contrast, the use of multiple securities allows the issuer to price discriminate among investors who value liquidity services differently (this point is highly reminiscent of Gorton-Pennacchi (1990)). To illustrate the rationale for multiple securities without needing to introduce intermediaries, let us allow partial liquidation at the firm level. Let us construct an industry equilibrium that yields the same allocation as that obtained from program (20) as described in Proposition 4. In this equilibrium, all firms invest I (the level given in Proposition 4). They all pledge not to finance liquidity shocks exceeding p. A fraction a of the firms, 4 'type- 1 firms", purchase (p-p )I Treasury securities at price q and hold no shares in other firms. At date they issue a) equity, sold at par, and b) short-term (maturing at 22 Of course, when idiosyncratic and aggregate shocks coexist, intermediation again is strictly preferred by firms as scarce liquidity is wasted by financial markets. 26

37 1 date 1) debt with face value (p -p ) I at price q', with the covenants that a) they must fully dilute their equity before selling Treasury securities to finance liquidity needs and b) that they can sell up to (p-p )I Treasury securities to finance their liquidity need when the aggregate shock is p, before servicing the short-term debt. 23 Covenant a) implies that equity in type-1 firms carries no liquidity premium, as it becomes valueless when the aggregate shock exceeds p. Covenant b) implies that the short-term debt is worth (p-p)i at date 1 when the liquidity shock p belongs to the interval [p,p]. The remaining fraction 1-a of the firms, the "type-2 firms", do not purchase Treasury securities, but buy all the short-term debt of type-1 firms. Let a be given by a(p-p) = (l-a)(p-p ). (23) There is no liquidation in any type of firm when p< p. Suppose that p <p < p. Then the value of short-term debt claims held by a representative type-2 firm is equal to a(p-p)i/(l-a) >(p-p )I, and thus type-2 firms can, by selling these debt claims and by diluting their initial investors (to obtain p I), withstand their liquidity shock, pi. On the other hand, type-2 firms are partially liquidated when p E [p,p]. while type-1 firms are not. Type-2 firms can continue to operate a fraction X 2 of their assets, where X 2 pi=x 2 p I + _^_(p-p)i. 1-or That is, they can pledge \p l to new investors and further use the return on short-term debt in type-1 firms. The aggregate (type-1 and type-2 firms) fraction X of assets that are not liquidated is therefore X - or+o-oox, = a+(l-«) - l_l-ap-p J P-Po P-Po 23 The debt contract is contingent on the realization of the aggregate shock for expositional convenience only. Alternatively, type-1 firms can substitute a class of nondilutable long-term (maturing at date 2) senior claim for the short-term debt and dispense with writing a covenant that is contingent on the aggregate shock. 27

38 and coincides with the fraction specified in Proposition 4. Note also that the aggregate demand for Treasury securities is the same as in the intermediated case from Proposition 4ii), as (23) implies that a(p-po) I = - (P Po) L Last, the price of short-term senior debt, q', is set so that firms are indifferent between being a type-1 and a type-2 firm. We thus conclude that the optimal policy is implemented by the issuing of multiple corporate securities when partial liquidation at the firm level is feasible. When partial liquidation at the firm level is infeasible, the optimal policy must be implemented through intermediaries, and these intermediaries must similarly issue multiple securities in order to price discriminate and avoid free-riding State-contingent bonds. While partial liquidation reduces the deadweight loss of taxation and is efficient for the private sector given that the government issues non-contingent bonds, it is not the socially most efficient solution. In this section we show how the government can achieve a better outcome by issuing state-contingent bonds. We begin by characterizing the social optimum when general state-contingent transfers between consumers and producers are allowed. A social plan is defined by (i) the initial level of investment I per firm, and (ii) a state-contingent continuation policy X(p) e [0,1] that determines the fraction of firms that continue when the aggregate liquidity shock is p. The social program is identical to the program studied in section 4.4, with the exception that the transfers are not constrained by an initial purchase of bonds. Formally, the social program solves: max I f X(p)(p,-p )f(p)dp, s.t. (i) <D Iqf X(p)(p -p)f(p)dp > I-A, (24) Jo (ii) < X(p) <1. 28

39 Letting 5 be the Lagiangian multiplier (again, 5 > 1, because it is the shadow value of entrepreneurial wealth), the solution to this program is ri1 if P ^ P#, [0 if p > p\ where p* is defined by ^-TT- <25 > In contrast to the solution in section 4.4, the social optimum specifies either that all firms continue, or no firm continues. The explanation for the difference is that the social program does not have to hoard liquidity (by buying bonds); rather, transfers are provided only as needed. 24 Furthermore, since 5, q > 1, we see that the socially optimal cut-off p* satisfies p < p* < p,. The social optimum X*(p) can be implemented using state-contingent bonds, which pay the holder an amount x(p) as a function of the aggregate shock p. In particular, let the bonds have the following date-1 payoff: x(p) = 1 ' lx*(p)(p-p ), -PoJ if P <P or p > p*, if p <p<p*. Let the date-0 price of these bonds be set so that r\'(p)q(p- P( )f(p)dp. Note that priced this way, bond revenues exactly compensate the consumers for the deadweight loss of taxation when the policy X*(p) is followed. It is straightforward to check that with these payoffs and price, firms can replicate the social optimum, if they so desire, by buying I bonds, where I is the socially optimal level of investment. This amount of bonds enables a firm to continue exactly when the social plan calls for continuation. Also, the firm's budget constraint coincides with the social budget constraint so that the firm can attract the required funds from investors at date Partial liquidation would become relevant only if investors or entrepreneurs were risk averse or if the government could not use state-contingent transfers. 29

40 Can the firm do better by deviating from the socially optimal plan? Suppose there is a better plan for the firm. In this plan, let I be the date-0 investment level, let zl be the amount of state-contingent bonds the firm purchases, and let X(p) be the continuation policy. To be feasible, the plan must satisfy both an ex ante and an ex post budget constraint. The ex ante constraint is I f"x(p)(p -p)f(p)dp -Iz rx'(p)(q-l)(p-p )f(p)dp > I -A. Jo Jo (26) The ex post constraint is < X(p) < min{l,z X*(p)}. (27) Substituting the ex post constraint into the ex ante constraint, it is immediate that it would be feasible for a social planner to replicate the firm's plan. Given that the social objective function coincides with the firm's, the firm's plan cannot be better than the social optimum. Hence, the firm prefers the socially optimal plan. Note that the government need not be concerned by the possibility of free-riding and partial liquidation if bond yields are state contingent, because firms holding bonds do not have excess liquidity when p > p, and therefore other firms cannot free-ride by holding their shares. Remark on seignorage. Suppose that the government aims at maximizing net revenue from issuing government securities, ignoring costs of taxation. Let us compute an upper bound R on the government's net revenue. Let U( = m(p )k(p )A) denote the "autarky utility" of an entrepreneur with assets A, that is the utility she gets when holding no reserves. Clearly, U is a lower bound on entrepreneurial utility. Consider the following program: max R I.MO s.t. (i) lf Jo, X(p)(p 1 -p )f(p)dp > U, (ii) -R-I fx(p)(p -p)f(p)dp >I-A, Jo JO (iii) < X(p) <1. (28) 30

41 Constraint (ii) reflects the fact that investors must break even. Substituting constraint (ii) (which obviously holds with equality) into the objective function, we see that program (28) is the dual of program (24). That is, the social optimum has the same characterization whether the government maximizes entrepreneurial welfare subject to a deadweight loss of taxation or maximizes seignorage. 4.7 An interpretation of state-contingent bonds. The economic rationale for using state-contingent bonds is clear. Bonds that pay a fixed amount will provide excess liquidity in most states at date 1. Firms (or intermediaries) will cash in the bonds that they do not need for reinvestment, forcing the government to tax consumers and implement a wealth transfer that is unnecessary and socially costly (in the deadweight-loss-of-taxation interpretation). While partial liquidation reduces the tax burden, it still leaves slack and also distorts investment and liquidation decisions. The solution that attacks the root cause of the problem is a state-contingent bond, which dispenses liquidity exactly as needed and eliminates all wasteful transfers of wealth. Of course, this solution works ideally only in our idealized model. In reality, statecontingent bonds are not used. The most obvious reason why such bonds are not used is that there is no aggregate, measurable state that unequivocally identifies times when firms should be provided more liquidity. There are other shocks than liquidity shocks that move publicly measured variables, and these shocks may call for very different transfers for similar realizations of the aggregate measures. Macroeconomic policy is not a mechanical exercise, because new, unforeseen contingencies keep appearing. Rather than limiting government policy to bonds that are contingent on a few, foreseeable, and verifiable variables, a discretionary policy may be more desirable (at least if one ignores the political economy of government policy). Thus, we want to view the use of state-contingent bonds as a metaphor for an active government policy rather than as a serious policy instrument in its own right. The value of state-contingent bonds shows that, besides creating liquidity, the government has a potential role in actively managing liquidity. Note that this is true even if private contracts could be indexed on government actions or on the aggregate shock. In our model, optimal liquidity management entails increasing the value ofgovernment 31

42 bonds in times when liquidity needs are high. 25 Since we have assumed that bonds mature at date 1, this is accompanied by a corresponding, immediate increase (decrease) in taxes. It may seem odd that taxes are being raised in adverse liquidity states (recessions), as consumers might simultaneously be experiencing negative demand shocks. But this just underscores the importance of multiple shocks, as discussed above. Our specific result is clearly sensitive to the assumption that there is a single liquidity shock with consumers experiencing no shocks at all. If consumers experience an adverse demand shock that requires resources to be shifted to consumption, then taxation and the value of bonds should be reduced rather than increased, notwithstanding negative liquidity shocks. This does not negate the general logic that state-contingent bonds are of value, that is, an active policy can improve the allocation of resources through wealth transfers. We cannot associate state-contingent bonds with monetary or fiscal policies, since our model does not distinguish between nominal and real claims. But certain analogies can be drawn between the real effects of state-contingent bonds and the alleged effects of fiscal and monetary policies. Note first that we only have a single instrument, corresponding to a case where fiscal and monetary policies are inversely related: when liquidity is tight, fiscal policy is loose and conversely. Some might argue that this is also true in reality, since loose money will either be accompanied by a tight budget, forcing consumers to pay up immediately (as they do in our model), or it imposes an inflation tax, which consumers might anticipate and therefore adjust to immediately, with the same effect as tightening the budget (barring nonlinear taxes). A further parallel is that, in the model, liquidity is tight when the value of bonds are low. Note also that, if one imagined a second generation of entrepreneurs entering at date 1, facing liquidity shocks at date 2, and producing at date 3, then tighter liquidity (lower bond prices) at date 1 would decrease their date 1 investments, and increase their date-2 reinvestments (by Proposition 3), as the cost of carrying liquidity into date 2 would become relatively less expensive. In other words, tighter liquidity at date 1 reduces both reinvestments (of date-0 entrepreneurs) and initial investments (of date-1 entrepreneurs), moving aggregate investment unambigously down at date 1. Again, this conforms with 25 Note that we are not rationalizing continuous government intervention, but rather intervention in severe circumstances. 32

43 standard views on policy effects. Furthermore, in a model with more periods, one could also study bonds with longer maturities. With long-term bonds, wealth transfers between consumers and producers would be accomplished by early redemptions (purchases) of these bonds (adding liquidity) or by issuing new bonds (tightening liquidity). We do not suggest that these parallels can be used to draw strong conclusions about real policies as our model says nothing specifically about monetary or fiscal interventions. Nevertheless, we find it reassuring that one can associate alleged features of real policies with the abstract state-contingent outcomes in the model. Also, the model gives some guidance for government interventions intended to accomplish wealth transfers between the producers and consumers in response to unforeseen, aggregate real shocks. As an illustration, consider the recent collapse of the Soviet Union. In several European countries no attempt was initially made to accommodate this shock (or, if one wants to interpret the central banks' stubborn stance on exchange rates as an active policy, money was made very tight). The result was a massive reduction in entrepreneurial wealth as interest rates soared and asset values plunged. Our analysis supports those who argued that the governments should have responded with policy measures that transferred wealth back to entrepreneurs, by bringing interest rates down. According to received wisdom (and validated by the subsequent events), a reduction in interest rates required a devaluation of the currencies or abandoning fixed exchange rates. In the logic of our model, and we believe in reality, too, such an exchange rate policy should be seen as part of an insurance policy in which the government plays a central role. 5. Relationship to the literature Several papers have relevance for our work, although they do not address in a unified way the main questions we are interested in, namely corporate liquidity needs, the partial self-sufficiency of the private sector, and the foundations for liquidity supply and management by the government. Let us take up these themes in order. 33

44 Corporate liquidity needs By now, there is a very large literature on credit rationing, making the point that investment will be constrained by the firm's net worth (for a survey, see for instance, Bernanke-Gertler-Gilchrist (1994)). Most of this literature does not deal with liquidity demand as such, but rather with the structure of optimal financial contracts, including the decision to liquidate assets in case of financial hardship. Obviously, decisions to liquidate are closely related to decisions to make further investments, as illustrated in Hart (1995). However, the result that firms face a liquidity covenant in the optimal financial contract is to the best of our knowledge new. On the other hand, the result that investors must provide firms with extra cash (or a credit line) ex ante, is reminiscent of Hart and Moore (1989) (see also Hart (1995)), who show that a given class of financial contracts can be improved upon by using a similar arrangement (the optimality of which is not investigated). The fact that real assets serve a dual purpose, as productive inputs as well as collateral for debt, has been exploited in recent papers by Kiyotaki and Moore (1993) and Shleifer and Vishny (1992). Both models are broadly concerned with the general equilibrium implications of wealth constrained financing. The latter model, in particular, shares some features with our model. It has two firms, each facing an idiosyncratic demand shock. Firms may try to piggy-back on each others' investment decisions to generate future income in hard times, not directly through security purchases, as we have it, but rather through the ability to sell assets to the other firm ex post. If the firms' liquidity shocks are not perfectly correlated (so that they are not in default simultaneously), then when one firm experiences a liquidity shock but not the other, it can sell its assets for a higher value than if there were no other informed purchaser of its assets. In effect, the model describes a market mediated, albeit imperfect, way of enhancing firm liquidity. Self-sufficiency and intermediation The study of the demand for consumer liquidity was originated by Bryant (1980) and Diamond and Dybvig (1983). 26 Diamond and Dybvig demonstrate that intermediaries can provide limited insurance by subsidizing consumers with high liquidity needs. Jacklin (1987), however shows that the associated cross-subsidy is infeasible in the presence of financial markets, as those consumers with low liquidity needs can pretend to have high liquidity 26 See also Ramakrishnan and Thakor (1984) and Williamson (1986). 34

45 needs, pocket the subsidy and reinvest it in financial markets. 27 Thus, financial markets in the Diamond-Dybvig framework both reduce welfare and make intermediation useless. By contrast, in our model, intermediaries bring strict improvements despite the existence of financial markets. The main reason for the difference in conclusions is that our firms cannot misuse credit lines. Entrepreneurs cannot divert corporate funds for their own use other than in the limited fashion captured by B. Our results on how the government should manage liquidity obtained in section 4, are also quite different from those in Diamond and Dybvig. In their model, government policy can be made contingent on the macroeconomic shock (the number of withdrawing depositors) while bank contracts with depositors cannot be made contingent on this macroeconomic shock. 28 In our model, government policies do not use more aggregate information than private contracts. Boyd and Prescott (1986), in a related effort to understand the role of intermediation, constructs a model in which financial markets cannot duplicate the services provided by intermediaries. Their model is not about the provision of liquidity as such, but rather about the efficent organization of monitoring. Financial markets are inefficient relative to intermediation, because financial contracts are assumed to be contingent on whether projects are evaluated and also on the outcome of the evaluation. Intermediaries, on the other hand, can offer contracts before an evaluation is made, avoiding the problem of premature information revelation. This seems to be an ad hoc limitation in favor of intermediation. Bhattacharya and Gale (1987) look at a variation of the Diamond-Dybvig model that is closer in structure to ours. In their model there are several banks (corresponding to our firms), which experience idiosyncratic, "sectoral" liquidity shocks that cancel out in the aggregate. The paper characterizes the socially optimal mechanism for sharing risks across banks, noting that this mechanism cannot be implemented through an interbank lending market. Whether a market in bank shares or some other institution could implement the 27 Diamond (1995) shows that intermediaries have a role to play as long as some consumers have imperfect access to financial markets. 28 The subsequent literature on bank runs for the most part assumes independent shocks, as we do in section 3. Hellwig (1994) introduces macroeconomic uncertainty through a date-1 shock on the the short term interest rate between date 1 and date 2, and shows that depositors who withdraw at date 1 must bear some of the aggregate risk. 35

46 social optimum is left open. The authors suggest that a central bank might be the right institution for carrying out interbank risk sharing. Government supplied liquidity The first paper to argue that government debt can improve the intertemporal allocation of investment is by Diamond (1965). In an overlapping generations model he showed that government debt can crowd out private investment, which in the absence of government debt may be excessive. In his model, government bonds provide no liquidity services and are sold at par. Another difference is that in Diamond public debt crowds out private investment while in our paper public debt boosts private investment by providing aggregate liquidity. Models of crossgenerational insurance (Fisher (1983), Pagano (1988) and Gale (1990)), and of asynchronized investment opportunities (Woodford (1990)) are expressely concerned with the role of government debt as a medium of transfer across periods. Woodford's paper is most closely related to ours. In one version of his model, he assumes that individuals periodically receive investment opportunities, which they cannot take advantage of without storing wealth from one period to the next. Government debt is a vehicle for storing wealth. He shows that in a stationary state, the optimal level of government debt should be positive. The role of government debt is thus the same as in our paper. However, Woodford does not consider the possibility that a private market in claims on output could accompush the same as government debt. It appears that it could, because there are no agency costs that would limit the sales of such private claims. In a related vein, Williamson (1992) demonstrates the benefits of fiat money in a model in which adverse selection prevents entrepreneurs from pledging their entire future income. 29 Fiat money plays the role of a store of value (which is the counterpart of government securities in our model, and may have value because Williamson's model is one of overlapping generations). Williamson's focus is distinct from ours; he argues in favor of government securities (in the form of fiat money) and against the trading of private claims. Indeed, Williamson concludes that fiat money has no value if private claims are traded, and that there exists an equilibrium with fiat money that Pareto dominates the purely private 29 On the adverse selection problem and related issues, see also Banerjee-Maskin (1991) and the references in Williamson (1992). For other models on money and government debt, see, for instance, Bewley (1980) and Levine (1991). 36

47 equilibrium as long as agents are prevented from trading private claims. Our conclusions are rather different. Finally, it should be evident that our work has some points of contact with the literature on incomplete markets. Markets in our model are incomplete because individuals cannot borrow against future income and because the value of a firm's claimholdings cannot be contingent on its liquidity shock. The latter problem is effectively dealt with through intermediaries even though the intermediaries do not observe individual liquidity shocks, while the former problem is partly resolved by the government, which creates a new asset that can be used to improve the allocation of investment across periods. The fact that the government can improve on private outcomes by issuing new securities is related to a general result in the incomplete market literature, which states that generically one can add an asset to an incomplete market and make everyone better off (Elul (1995)). Of course, unlike this literature, the source of incompleteness is spelled out in our model. 6. Concluding remarks. Rather than summarize our results, we wish to address some questions that our paper may raise and indicate directions in which the analysis could be extended. 30 First, the questions. What do we mean by liquidity? Liquidity has been given various interpretations in the literature. In models with adverse selection, liquidity is related to the degree of asymmetric information about an asset. Assets about which there is a great deal of asymmetric information are less liquid than assets which everyone knows equally well. Firms can address this illiquidity problem in various ways. For instance, firms can issue claims that place different informational demands on buyers. This is illustrated in the paper by Gorton and Pennacchi (1990), where debt is shown to be informationally less demanding than equity and therefore a firm may be able to raise funds at a lower cost of capital by issuing both We are grateful to Peter Diamond, Peter Howitt and Andrei Shleifer for raising many of these questions. 31 In a related vein, Stein (1995) presents an adverse selection model in which the government can influence the liquidity of bank liabilities by guaranteeing some of the bank debt through deposit insurance. In his model, liquidity coincides with reserves. His paper does not address why the government would like to supply liquidity, nor why it would want to influence liquidity by changing reserve requirements. But his paper, unlike ours, gives one 37

48 In our model of moral hazard, assets are not illiquid because people have different assessments about their value. Rather, claims on firms fall into two categories: insider claims, held by entrepreneurs, and outsider claims, held by investors. Insider claims are completely illiquid in the sense that if the entrepreneur were to sell these claims in the market, the value of them (as well as of the external claims) would drop. External claims, on the other hand, are entirely liquid and can be sold at no discount at all times. Because we have assumed that the value of insider claims exceeds the value of the firm's investment (and therefore, insiders must chip in some of their initial endowment to raise funds), there is a potential shortage of liquid assets. Why do we need an agency model? This question is largely answered by the previous paragraphs. Without an agency problem, all assets would be fully liquid. Firms could sell claims up to the value of their investments at any point in time and could therefore undertake all socially productive investments. It is the inability to transfer all the social surplus to external investors that constrains the firm's financing opportunities. As we have shown, the firm is credit constrained both ex ante and ex post. Therefore, ex post financing is not forthcoming without ex ante commitments. Such commitments require assets that allow the firm to hoard liquidity (and pay for it in advance). This is what creates a demand for liquid assets. What if there were other real private assets in the model? The assumption that there are no other private assets than the investment projects themselves was a simplification. It would be easy to introduce assets like real estate, which could be used to transfer wealth from one period to the next. If there were enough of those assets, they would obviate the need for government securities, but if the aggregate value of the assets fell below the minimum amount of government securities needed to achieve a productive optimum ((/?* - p )I), real assets would merely reduce the demand for government bonds, but they would not eliminate it. 32 Similarity, if the liquidation value of firms were positive rather than zero, this would reduce the demand for government bonds. interpretation of the transmission mechanism of monetary policy. 32 Real estate would in general carry a liquidity premium for the same reason government bonds do in our model. We derive liquidity premia in a simplified setting in Holmstrom-Tirole (1996). It should also be noted that real estate prices are likely to move procyclically, making it a worse instrument than government provided insurance. 38

49 75 the investment-capital ratio realistic? The model implies that government intervention is needed only when the aggregate demand for liquidity exceeds the value of the private sector. This seems grossly at odds with the empirical fact that the market value of the corporate sector is large relative to investment. Part of the explanation has to do with the interpretation of investment. As we already pointed out, in our model reinvestments include all the cash outlays (wages and working capital, for instance) needed to continue the firm, not just investments in physical capital. This figure is surely an order of magnitude larger than measured aggregate investment. Nevertheless, it remains true that the private sector can continue on its own as long as p < p, that is, as long as the value of the initial claimholders' investment has not been driven down to zero. Only when their investment has lost all its value need the government step in. This is an unrealistic feature of the model. It is driven by the equally unrealistic feature that external claims are fully liquid. To the extent that new issues of equity and debt are costly, because of difficulties in valuing these claims correctly, the private sector will run into reinvestment problems before the initial claimholders have lost all of their investment. Similarly, the holdings of monitors Qzrge shareholder, bank, venture capitalist,...) cannot be diluted without generating further incentive problems. 33 Thus, we think of p as the point where the private sector hits a serious debt capacity constraint. Let us finally suggest some extensions of our model. Currently, the link between the producer and the consumer sector is very simple and uninteresting. It would be highly desirable to study a general equilibrium extension that could highlight how consumer and producer shocks would affect the overall economy and feed back on each sector. This might give a more realistic picture of the need for transferring wealth in one direction or the other and therefore on how the government should manage liquidity. In this context, one would also want to be more careful about the deadweight losses caused by taxation and the role played by individual time preferences and risk aversion. Another important extension would introduce more periods into the model, perhaps by overlapping firms as earlier indicated. In such an extension, the government could issue long-term as well as short-term bonds, which would raise questions about managing the 33 Tirole (1994). It is straightforward to add monitors into our model, along the lines of Holmstrdm- 39

50 maturity structure of government debt. While intermediaries play a role in our model, it is a rather passive one. They are merely conduits for forming contracts that are unavailable in a financial market in which anonymous claims on corporate income are traded. In reality, intermediaries play a more active role, monitoring investments and liquidity needs. This role would probably emerge in a multi-period analysis, since one would have to worry about how firms use their excess liquidity. In the present model, excess liquidity was never misused by firms, since they had no use for the extra funds. 40

51 MIT LIBRARIES References Banerjee, A. and E. Maskin (1991) "A Walrasian Theory of Barter and Money: I", mimeo, Harvard University. Bhattacharya, S. and D. Gale (1987), "Preference Shocks, Liquidity, and Central Bank Policy," in New Approaches to Monetary Economics, (eds. W, Barnett and K. Singleton). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bewley, T. (1980), "The Optimum Quantity of Money," in Models ofmonetary Economics, (J.Kareken and N. Wallace, eds.). Minneapolis: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Bryant, J. (1980) "A Model of Reserves, Bank Runs, and Deposit Insurance", Journal of Banking and Finance, 43: Diamond, D. (1995) "Bank Liquidity Creation when Markets are Illiquid", mimeo, University of Chicago. Diamond, D. and P. Dybvig (1983) "Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity", Journal of Political Economy, 91: Diamond, P. (1965) "National Debt in a Neoclassical Growth Model", American Economic Review, 55: Elul, R. (1995), "Welfare Effects of Financial Innovation in Incomplete Markets Economies with Several Consumption Goods, "Journal of Economic Theory, 63(1): Fischer, S. (1983) "Welfare Aspects of Government Issue of Indexed Bonds", in Inflation, Debt, and Indexation, edited by R. Dornbusch and M. Simonsen, Cambridge: MIT Press. Gale, D. (1990) "The Efficient Design of Public Debt", in Public Debt Management: Theory and History, edited by R. Dornbusch and M. Draghi, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Gorton, G. and G. Pennacchi (1990), Journal of Finance, 45: "Financial Intermediaries and Liquidity Creation," Hart, O. (1995) Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hart, O. and J. Moore (1989) "Default and Renegotiation: A Dynamic Model of Debt," Working paper Harvard Business School. 41

52 Hellwig, M. (1994) "Liquidity Provision, Banking, and the Allocation of Interest Rate Risk", European Economic Review, 38 (7): Holmstrom B. and J. Tirole (1994), "Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector, "mimeo, MIT and IDEI. (1996) "Modelling Aggregate Liquidity," American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 86: Jacklin, C. (1987) "Demand Deposits, Trading Restrictions, and Risk Sharing", in Contractual Arrangements for Intertemporal Trade, edited by E. Prescott and N. Wallace, Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Kiyotaki, N. and J. Moore (1993) "Credit Cycles", mimeo, London School of Economics. Pagano, M. (1988) "The Management of Public Debt and Financial Markets", in High Public Debt: The Italian Experience, edited by F. Giavazzi and L. Spaventa, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ramakrishnan, T. and A. Tliakor (1984), "Information Reliability and a Theory of Financial Intermediation," Review of Economic Studies, 51: Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny (1992) "Liquidation Values and Debt Capacity: A Market Equilibrium Approach", Journal of Finance, 47: Stein, J. (1995) "An Adverse Selection Model of Bank Asset and Liability Management with Implications for the Transmission of Monetary Policy", MIT Sloan School mimeo. von Thadden, E. L. (1994) "Optimal Liquidity Provision and Dynamic Incentive Compatibility", mimeo, Universitat Basel. Williamson, S. (1986), "Cosdy Monitoring, Financial Intermediation and Equilibrium Credit Rationing," Journal of Monetary Economics, 18: Williamson, S. (1992) "Laissez-Faire Banking and Circulating Media of Exchange", Journal of Financial Intermediation, 2: Williamson, S. and R. Wright (1994) "Barter and Monetary Exchange under Private Information", American Economic Review, 84: Woodford, M. (1990) "Public debt as Liquidity", American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 80: >22 42

53

54

55

56 Date Due U&*Vg5 3 V 1&199B SEP J Lib-26-67

57

58

Monetary Economics. Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable)

Monetary Economics. Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable) Monetary Economics Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one Chris Edmond 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable) 1 This lecture Main reading: Holmström and Tirole, Inside and outside liquidity, MIT

More information

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector Bengt Holmstrom and Jean Tirole April 3, 2017 Holmstrom and Tirole Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector April 3, 2017

More information

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance (Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha Department of Economics UC Davis Chapter 2. Outside financing: Private benefit and moral hazard V. F. Martins-da-Rocha (UC Davis)

More information

Advanced Financial Economics 2 Financial Contracting

Advanced Financial Economics 2 Financial Contracting Advanced Financial Economics 2 Financial Contracting Prof. Dr. Roman Inderst Part 3 1 / 49 Liquidity, Free Cash Flow, and Risk Management 2 / 49 Main Questions Why do some firms hold liquid assets and

More information

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Online Appendix for Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Giacomo Rodano Bank of Italy Nicolas Serrano-Velarde Bocconi University December 23, 2014 Emanuele Tarantino University of Mannheim 1 1 Reorganization,

More information

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model ECON 4335 Economics of Banking, Fall 2016 Jacopo Bizzotto 1 Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model The model in Diamond and Dybvig (1983) incorporates important features of the real world:

More information

Rural Financial Intermediaries

Rural Financial Intermediaries Rural Financial Intermediaries 1. Limited Liability, Collateral and Its Substitutes 1 A striking empirical fact about the operation of rural financial markets is how markedly the conditions of access can

More information

Basic Assumptions (1)

Basic Assumptions (1) Basic Assumptions (1) An entrepreneur (borrower). An investment project requiring fixed investment I. The entrepreneur has cash on hand (or liquid securities) A < I. To implement the project the entrepreneur

More information

Financial Intermediation and the Supply of Liquidity

Financial Intermediation and the Supply of Liquidity Financial Intermediation and the Supply of Liquidity Jonathan Kreamer University of Maryland, College Park November 11, 2012 1 / 27 Question Growing recognition of the importance of the financial sector.

More information

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Christopher Phelan Working Paper 676 December 2009 Phelan: University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Monetary and Financial Macroeconomics

Monetary and Financial Macroeconomics Monetary and Financial Macroeconomics Hernán D. Seoane Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Introduction Last couple of weeks we introduce banks in our economies Financial intermediation arises naturally when

More information

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I April 2005 PREPARING FOR THE EXAM What models do you need to study? All the models we studied

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

Fire sales, inefficient banking and liquidity ratios

Fire sales, inefficient banking and liquidity ratios Fire sales, inefficient banking and liquidity ratios Axelle Arquié September 1, 215 [Link to the latest version] Abstract In a Diamond and Dybvig setting, I introduce a choice by households between the

More information

Economics and Finance,

Economics and Finance, Economics and Finance, 2014-15 Lecture 5 - Corporate finance under asymmetric information: Moral hazard and access to external finance Luca Deidda UNISS, DiSEA, CRENoS October 2014 Luca Deidda (UNISS,

More information

Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective

Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective Olivier Compte and Philippe Jehiel November 2003 Abstract A principal has to choose among several agents to fulfill a task and then provide

More information

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance (Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha Department of Economics UC Davis Part 6. Lending Relationships and Investor Activism V. F. Martins-da-Rocha (UC Davis) Corporate

More information

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility and Coordination Failures What makes financial systems fragile? What causes crises

More information

Bernanke and Gertler [1989]

Bernanke and Gertler [1989] Bernanke and Gertler [1989] Econ 235, Spring 2013 1 Background: Townsend [1979] An entrepreneur requires x to produce output y f with Ey > x but does not have money, so he needs a lender Once y is realized,

More information

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Economic Theory 14, 247±253 (1999) Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Christopher M. Snyder Department of Economics, George Washington University, 2201 G Street

More information

Principles of Banking (II): Microeconomics of Banking (3) Bank Capital

Principles of Banking (II): Microeconomics of Banking (3) Bank Capital Principles of Banking (II): Microeconomics of Banking (3) Bank Capital Jin Cao (Norges Bank Research, Oslo & CESifo, München) Outline 1 2 3 Disclaimer (If they care about what I say,) the views expressed

More information

Bank Leverage and Social Welfare

Bank Leverage and Social Welfare Bank Leverage and Social Welfare By LAWRENCE CHRISTIANO AND DAISUKE IKEDA We describe a general equilibrium model in which there is a particular agency problem in banks. The agency problem arises because

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore*

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore* Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts by Oliver Hart and John Moore* Since Ronald Coase s famous 1937 article (Coase (1937)), economists have grappled with the question of what characterizes

More information

Macroprudential Bank Capital Regulation in a Competitive Financial System

Macroprudential Bank Capital Regulation in a Competitive Financial System Macroprudential Bank Capital Regulation in a Competitive Financial System Milton Harris, Christian Opp, Marcus Opp Chicago, UPenn, University of California Fall 2015 H 2 O (Chicago, UPenn, UC) Macroprudential

More information

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Corporate Control Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Managerial Discipline and Takeovers Managers often don t maximize the value of the firm; either because they are not capable

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 207 Introduction This note works through some simple two-period consumption-saving problems. In

More information

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin 4.454 - Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin Juan Pablo Xandri Antuna 4/22/20 Setup Continuum of consumers, mass of individuals each endowed with one unit of currency. t = 0; ; 2

More information

Teoria das organizações e contratos

Teoria das organizações e contratos Teoria das organizações e contratos Chapter 5: The Moral Hazard Problem: Applications Mestrado Profissional em Economia 3 o trimestre 2015 EESP (FGV) Teoria das organizações e contratos 3 o trimestre 2015

More information

Public-Private Partnerships for Liquidity Provision

Public-Private Partnerships for Liquidity Provision Public-Private Partnerships for Liquidity Provision Ricardo J. Caballero and Pablo Kurlat March 4, 2009 1 Summary Extreme bouts of uncertainty and fear wreak havoc in financial markets and expose leveraged

More information

Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse

Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse Tano Santos Columbia University Financial intermediaries, such as banks, perform many roles: they screen risks, evaluate and fund worthy

More information

DETERMINANTS OF DEBT CAPACITY. 1st set of transparencies. Tunis, May Jean TIROLE

DETERMINANTS OF DEBT CAPACITY. 1st set of transparencies. Tunis, May Jean TIROLE DETERMINANTS OF DEBT CAPACITY 1st set of transparencies Tunis, May 2005 Jean TIROLE I. INTRODUCTION Adam Smith (1776) - Berle-Means (1932) Agency problem Principal outsiders/investors/lenders Agent insiders/managers/entrepreneur

More information

Monetary Easing and Financial Instability

Monetary Easing and Financial Instability Monetary Easing and Financial Instability Viral Acharya NYU Stern, CEPR and NBER Guillaume Plantin Sciences Po April 22, 2016 Acharya & Plantin Monetary Easing and Financial Instability April 22, 2016

More information

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation May 1, 1997 On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation Yoshitsugu Kanemoto 1 Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo 7-3-1 Hongo, Bunkyo-ku, Tokyo 113 Japan Abstract The most important drawback

More information

Scarce Collateral, the Term Premium, and Quantitative Easing

Scarce Collateral, the Term Premium, and Quantitative Easing Scarce Collateral, the Term Premium, and Quantitative Easing Stephen D. Williamson Washington University in St. Louis Federal Reserve Banks of Richmond and St. Louis April7,2013 Abstract A model of money,

More information

A Solution to Two Paradoxes of International Capital Flows. Jiandong Ju and Shang-Jin Wei. Discussion by Fabio Ghironi

A Solution to Two Paradoxes of International Capital Flows. Jiandong Ju and Shang-Jin Wei. Discussion by Fabio Ghironi A Solution to Two Paradoxes of International Capital Flows Jiandong Ju and Shang-Jin Wei Discussion by Fabio Ghironi NBER Summer Institute International Finance and Macroeconomics Program July 10-14, 2006

More information

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation Main Aims: 1. Study money as a liquid asset. 2. Develop an OLG model in which individuals live for three periods. 3. Analyze two roles of banks: (1.) correcting

More information

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income 1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income Until now, we have assumed that government policy is exogenously given, so the government had a very passive role. Its only concern was balancing the intertemporal budget.

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice 1. MWG - Decisive Subgroups Recall proposition 21.C.1: (Arrow s Impossibility Theorem) Suppose that the number of alternatives is at least

More information

A key characteristic of financial markets is that they are subject to sudden, convulsive changes.

A key characteristic of financial markets is that they are subject to sudden, convulsive changes. 10.6 The Diamond-Dybvig Model A key characteristic of financial markets is that they are subject to sudden, convulsive changes. Such changes happen at both the microeconomic and macroeconomic levels. At

More information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Topic 5: Information Economics 21, Summer 2002 Andreas Bentz Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Introduction

More information

Expensive than Deposits? Preliminary draft

Expensive than Deposits? Preliminary draft Bank Capital Structure Relevance: is Bank Equity more Expensive than Deposits? Swarnava Biswas Kostas Koufopoulos Preliminary draft May 15, 2013 Abstract We propose a model of optimal bank capital structure.

More information

Monetary Easing, Investment and Financial Instability

Monetary Easing, Investment and Financial Instability Monetary Easing, Investment and Financial Instability Viral Acharya 1 Guillaume Plantin 2 1 Reserve Bank of India 2 Sciences Po Acharya and Plantin MEIFI 1 / 37 Introduction Unprecedented monetary easing

More information

Counterparty risk externality: Centralized versus over-the-counter markets. Presentation at Stanford Macro, April 2011

Counterparty risk externality: Centralized versus over-the-counter markets. Presentation at Stanford Macro, April 2011 : Centralized versus over-the-counter markets Viral Acharya Alberto Bisin NYU-Stern, CEPR and NBER NYU and NBER Presentation at Stanford Macro, April 2011 Introduction OTC markets have often been at the

More information

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome.

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome. Moral Hazard Example Well, then says I, what s the use you learning to do right when it s troublesome to do right and ain t no trouble to do wrong, and the wages is just the same? I was stuck. I couldn

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

Where do securities come from

Where do securities come from Where do securities come from We view it as natural to trade common stocks WHY? Coase s policemen Pricing Assumptions on market trading? Predictions? Partial Equilibrium or GE economies (risk spanning)

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/domesticdistortioobhag

More information

Relational Incentive Contracts

Relational Incentive Contracts Relational Incentive Contracts Jonathan Levin May 2006 These notes consider Levin s (2003) paper on relational incentive contracts, which studies how self-enforcing contracts can provide incentives in

More information

LEVERAGE AND LIQUIDITY DRY-UPS: A FRAMEWORK AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. Denis Gromb LBS, LSE and CEPR. Dimitri Vayanos LSE, CEPR and NBER

LEVERAGE AND LIQUIDITY DRY-UPS: A FRAMEWORK AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. Denis Gromb LBS, LSE and CEPR. Dimitri Vayanos LSE, CEPR and NBER LEVERAGE AND LIQUIDITY DRY-UPS: A FRAMEWORK AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS Denis Gromb LBS, LSE and CEPR Dimitri Vayanos LSE, CEPR and NBER June 2008 Gromb-Vayanos 1 INTRODUCTION Some lessons from recent crisis:

More information

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation Afrasiab Mirza Department of Economics University of Birmingham a.mirza@bham.ac.uk Frank Strobel Department of Economics University of Birmingham f.strobel@bham.ac.uk

More information

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Stephen D. Williamson Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis May 14, 015 1 Introduction When a central bank operates under a floor

More information

Moral Hazard, Retrading, Externality, and Its Solution

Moral Hazard, Retrading, Externality, and Its Solution Moral Hazard, Retrading, Externality, and Its Solution Tee Kielnthong a, Robert Townsend b a University of California, Santa Barbara, CA, USA 93117 b Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA,

More information

Macroeconomics and finance

Macroeconomics and finance Macroeconomics and finance 1 1. Temporary equilibrium and the price level [Lectures 11 and 12] 2. Overlapping generations and learning [Lectures 13 and 14] 2.1 The overlapping generations model 2.2 Expectations

More information

MORAL HAZARD PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE

MORAL HAZARD PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE LECTURE 3 LECTURER: DR. KUMAR ANIKET Abstract. Ex ante moral hazard emanates from broadly two types of borrower s actions, project choice and effort choice. In loan contracts,

More information

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification by Lawrence Christiano Incorporating Financial Frictions into a Business Cycle Model General idea: Standard model

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Dynamic Inconsistency and Non-preferential Taxation of Foreign Capital

Dynamic Inconsistency and Non-preferential Taxation of Foreign Capital Dynamic Inconsistency and Non-preferential Taxation of Foreign Capital Kaushal Kishore Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas, USA. Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas, USA June

More information

Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments

Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments 1 Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments David C. Mills, Jr. 1 Federal Reserve Board Washington, DC E-mail: david.c.mills@frb.gov Version: May 004 I explore

More information

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Henrik Horn (Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm) Giovanni Maggi (Princeton University) Robert W. Staiger (Stanford University and

More information

A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds

A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds Dawei Fang Centre for Finance, Gothenburg University Abstract: We take a portfolio approach, based on simple agency conflicts between

More information

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982 Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982 Contribution Integrates domestic and international monetary theory with financial economics to provide a complete theory

More information

Optimal Debt Contracts

Optimal Debt Contracts Optimal Debt Contracts David Andolfatto February 2008 1 Introduction As an introduction, you should read Why is There Debt, by Lacker (1991). As Lackernotes,thestrikingfeatureofadebtcontractisthatdebtpaymentsare

More information

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Sta Report November 2009 Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

On Diamond-Dybvig (1983): A model of liquidity provision

On Diamond-Dybvig (1983): A model of liquidity provision On Diamond-Dybvig (1983): A model of liquidity provision Eloisa Campioni Theory of Banking a.a. 2016-2017 Eloisa Campioni (Theory of Banking) On Diamond-Dybvig (1983): A model of liquidity provision a.a.

More information

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński Decision Making in Manufacturing and Services Vol. 9 2015 No. 1 pp. 79 88 Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment Andrzej Paliński Abstract. This paper presents a model of bank-loan repayment as

More information

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment University of Konstanz Department of Economics Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment Florian Baumann and Tim Friehe Working Paper Series 2011-08 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/workingpaperseries

More information

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983)

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983) BANKING AND FINANCIAL FRAGILITY A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983) Professor Todd Keister Rutgers University May 2017 Objective Want to develop a model to help us understand: why banks and other

More information

Expectations vs. Fundamentals-based Bank Runs: When should bailouts be permitted?

Expectations vs. Fundamentals-based Bank Runs: When should bailouts be permitted? Expectations vs. Fundamentals-based Bank Runs: When should bailouts be permitted? Todd Keister Rutgers University Vijay Narasiman Harvard University October 2014 The question Is it desirable to restrict

More information

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy We now proceed to study optimal fiscal policy. We should make clear at the outset what we mean by this. In general, fiscal policy entails the government choosing its spending

More information

Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending?

Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending? Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending? Christian Ahlin Michigan State University Brian Waters UCLA Anderson Minn Fed/BREAD, October 2012

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 9 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3 Consider now a different cause for the failure of the Coase Theorem: the presence of transaction costs. Of course for this to be an interesting

More information

Capital Adequacy and Liquidity in Banking Dynamics

Capital Adequacy and Liquidity in Banking Dynamics Capital Adequacy and Liquidity in Banking Dynamics Jin Cao Lorán Chollete October 9, 2014 Abstract We present a framework for modelling optimum capital adequacy in a dynamic banking context. We combine

More information

Revision Lecture. MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Revision Lecture. MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I Revision Lecture Topics in Banking and Market Microstructure MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I April 2006 PREPARING FOR THE EXAM ² What do you need to know? All the

More information

The I Theory of Money

The I Theory of Money The I Theory of Money Markus Brunnermeier and Yuliy Sannikov Presented by Felipe Bastos G Silva 09/12/2017 Overview Motivation: A theory of money needs a place for financial intermediaries (inside money

More information

This short article examines the

This short article examines the WEIDONG TIAN is a professor of finance and distinguished professor in risk management and insurance the University of North Carolina at Charlotte in Charlotte, NC. wtian1@uncc.edu Contingent Capital as

More information

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55 Government debt Lecture 9, ECON 4310 Tord Krogh September 10, 2013 Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, 2013 1 / 55 Today s lecture Topics: Basic concepts Tax smoothing Debt crisis Sovereign risk Tord

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2018 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity

Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity Douglas W. Diamond University of Chicago Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis Washington University in Saint Louis August 13, 2015 Diamond,

More information

Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis. Gertler and Kiotaki Professor PengFei Wang Fatemeh KazempourLong

Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis. Gertler and Kiotaki Professor PengFei Wang Fatemeh KazempourLong Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis Gertler and Kiotaki 2009 Professor PengFei Wang Fatemeh KazempourLong 1 Motivation Bernanke, Gilchrist and Gertler (1999) studied great

More information

Public Investment and the Risk Premium for Equity

Public Investment and the Risk Premium for Equity Economica (2003) 70, 1 18 Public Investment and the Risk Premium for Equity By SIMON GRANT{{ and JOHN QUIGGIN{ { Tilburg University { Australian National University Final version received 19 December 2001.

More information

Why are Banks Highly Interconnected?

Why are Banks Highly Interconnected? Why are Banks Highly Interconnected? Alexander David Alfred Lehar University of Calgary Fields Institute - 2013 David and Lehar () Why are Banks Highly Interconnected? Fields Institute - 2013 1 / 35 Positive

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 26 January 2015 Failure of the Coase Theorem Recall that the Coase Theorem implies that two parties, when faced with a potential

More information

Monetary Easing and Financial Instability

Monetary Easing and Financial Instability Monetary Easing and Financial Instability Viral Acharya NYU-Stern, CEPR and NBER Guillaume Plantin Sciences Po September 4, 2015 Acharya & Plantin (2015) Monetary Easing and Financial Instability September

More information

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Problem Set: Contract Theory Problem Set: Contract Theory Problem 1 A risk-neutral principal P hires an agent A, who chooses an effort a 0, which results in gross profit x = a + ε for P, where ε is uniformly distributed on [0, 1].

More information

A Tale of Fire-Sales and Liquidity Hoarding

A Tale of Fire-Sales and Liquidity Hoarding University of Zurich Department of Economics Working Paper Series ISSN 1664-741 (print) ISSN 1664-75X (online) Working Paper No. 139 A Tale of Fire-Sales and Liquidity Hoarding Aleksander Berentsen and

More information

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Davide Porcellacchia 8 February 2017 Abstract The canonical New Keynesian model features a zero lower bound on the interest rate. In the simple setting

More information

Development Microeconomics Tutorial SS 2006 Johannes Metzler Credit Ray Ch.14

Development Microeconomics Tutorial SS 2006 Johannes Metzler Credit Ray Ch.14 Development Microeconomics Tutorial SS 2006 Johannes Metzler Credit Ray Ch.4 Problem n9, Chapter 4. Consider a monopolist lender who lends to borrowers on a repeated basis. the loans are informal and are

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Leonardo Felli 7 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Contract Theory has become only recently a subfield of Economics. As the name suggest the main object of the analysis is a contract. Therefore

More information

Low Interest Rate Policy and Financial Stability

Low Interest Rate Policy and Financial Stability Low Interest Rate Policy and Financial Stability David Andolfatto Fernando Martin Aleksander Berentsen The views expressed here are our own and should not be attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank of St.

More information

Comments on Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy, by Cúrdia and Woodford

Comments on Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy, by Cúrdia and Woodford Comments on Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy, by Cúrdia and Woodford Olivier Blanchard August 2008 Cúrdia and Woodford (CW) have written a topical and important paper. There is no doubt in

More information

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies Harris Schlesinger Department of Finance, University of Alabama, USA Center of Finance & Econometrics, University of Konstanz, Germany E-mail: hschlesi@cba.ua.edu

More information

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and the Real Sector

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and the Real Sector Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and the Real Sector Bengt Holmström and Jean Tirole The Quaterly Journal of Economics, 1997, Vol 52, pages 663-692 Microeconomics of Banking, Freixas and Rochet,

More information

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard. Patrick Legros

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard. Patrick Legros Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard Patrick Legros 1 / 25 Outline Introduction 2 / 25 Outline Introduction A principal-agent model The value of information 3 / 25 Outline Introduction A

More information

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals Donald J. Wright January 2014 VERY PRELIMINARY DRAFT School of Economics, Faculty of Arts and Social Sciences, University of Sydney, NSW, 2006, Australia, Ph:

More information

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser. University of Konstanz Department of Economics Optimal Contracting with Reciprocal Agents in a Competitive Search Model Maria Breitwieser Working Paper Series 2015-16 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/econdoc/working-paper-series/

More information