The Dollar and Real Interest Rates

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Dollar and Real Interest Rates"

Transcription

1 The Dollar and Real Interest Rates The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Published Version Accessed Citable Link Terms of Use Campbell, John Y., and Richard H. Clarida The dollar and real interest rates. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 27: doi: / (87) January 21, :28:50 AM EST This article was downloaded from Harvard University's DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at (Article begins on next page)

2 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DOLLAR AND REAL INTEREST RATES John V. Campbell Richard H. Clarida Working Paper No NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA February 1987 Prepared for the Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy, November 21-22, 1986, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania. This paper was commissioned and the work completed before Clarida assumed his position as Senior Staff Economist at the CEA. The views expressed in this paper should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of members of the Council of Economic Advisers or their staff. We would like to thank John Montgomery, Robin Lumsdaine, and Pradeed Srivastava for their able research assistance, and John Huizinga, Rick Mishkin and members of the MIT macro lunch group for helpful comments. The support of the National Science Foundation, grants SES and SES , is acknowledged with thanks. We are of course responsible for all errors. The research reported here is part of the NBER's research programs in Financial Markets and Monetary Economics and International Studies. Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

3 NBER Working Paper #2151 February 1987 The Dollar and Real Interest Rates ABSTRACT In this paper, we investigate the link between the real foreign exchange value of the dollar and real interest rates since We argue that it is important to consider the possibility that real exchange rate movements reflect movements of the long-run equilibrium exchange rate as well as real interest differentials. We use a state-space approach to estimate the importance of shifts in the long-run equilibrium exchange rate, the persistence of the ex ante short-term real interest differential, and the effect of this differential on the exchange rate. Using U.S., Canadian, British, German and Japanese data from October 1979 to March 1986, we find that movements in the dollar real exchange rate have been dominated by unanticipated shifts in the expected long-run real exchange rate. Ex ante real interest differentials have not been persistent or variable enough to account for a major part of exchange rate variation. We use Mussa's (1984) rational expectations model of the real exchange rate and the current account to interpret our results. John Y. Campbell NBER 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA (617) Richard H. Clarida The Council of Economic Advisers Old Executive Office Building Washington, DC (202)

4 Th Dollar and Real Interest Rates by John Y. Campbell and Richard H. Clarida 1. Introduction The substantial, sustained real appreciation of the dollar during the first half of the 1980's and its subsequent depreciation since February 1985 are perhaps the most debated and discussed macroeconomic events of this decade. According to one influential view (as put forth by Blinder (1986), Branson (1985), Frankel (1985), and Sachs (1985)), the strong dollar of 1980 through early 1985 was the result of a significant shift in the U.S. policy mix toward persistent structural budget deficits and a credible, anti-inflationary monetary stance on the part of the Federal Reserve. Other authors (Obstfeld (1985), Poole (1985), the Council of Economic Advisers (1985,1986)) have linked the real appreciation of the dollar in the years following the recession to the surprising surge in real business fixed investment spending. Still another hypothesis (which has been explored by Frankel (1985)) is that the rise and fall of the dollar resulted from a speculative bubble in the foreign exchange market. The real appreciation of the dollar in coincided with a marked increase in short and long term real interest rates, particularly in the U.S. but also abroad (Blanchard and Summers (1984)). This led to the view, especially popular in the financial press, that "the dollar is strong because U.S. real interest rates are high." Of course, to the extent that a shift in monetary policy was responsible for high real 1

5 interest rates in the U.S. relative to those elsewhere, theory would predict a real appreciation of the dollar - with overshooting - followed by a real depreciation to offset high U.S. real interest rates. However, the dollar consistently appreciated in real terms from 1980 through February This fact, along with the observation that the slowdown in U.S. money growth over the period was in fact moderate compared with that experienced in Japan, Germany, and the United Kingdom, has directed research towards explanations of the sustained real appreciation of the dollar which emphasize real rather than purely monetary factors. Since February 1985, the dollar has depreciated substantially in both nominal and real terms against the currencies of the other G5 countries. The extent of depreciation against the currencies of other major U.S. trading partners - Canada, the Latin American countries, and the NIC's in particular - has been less pronounced, especially in real terms. During this period, there has been a sustained increase in U.S. money growth, a decline in GNP growth, the announcement in September 1985 of an effort by the G5 central banks to bring down the value of the dollar, and Congressional deliberation of a major reform of the tax code. In addition, passage of the Gramm-Rudman legislation in December 1985 committed Congress and the President to a budgetary process which would achieve a balanced Federal budget by Fiscal Against this backdrop, both long and short term interest rates have declined sharply in the U.S. and abroad, as has the the slope of the U.S. term structure. In this paper, we investigate the link between the real foreign exchange value of the dollar and real interest rates since We ask 2

6 how much movement in real exchange rates can be attributed to real interest differentials, and how much is due to shifts in the long-run equilibrium real exchange rate. We begin in Section 2 by analyzing the responses of the real exchange rate, the real interest differential and the long-run equilibrium real exchange rate when there is a shock to autonomous expenditure on domestic goods. As discussed above, this type of shock - in private investment or perhaps government spending - is one possible explanation of the high dollar in the early 1980's. We show that under certain circumstances, a permanent positive shock to spending on domestic goods can lead to a higher real interest rate at home (a negative real interest differential) in the short run, and a real appreciation (a decrease in the real exchange rate, the relative price of imports) in both the short and long run. The shock also generates current account deficits in the short run. Our analysis is important for two reasons. First, it clarifies the way in which spending shocks might account for the experience of the early 1980's. Secondly, the claim is sometimes made that an autonomous increase in spending which, in the short run, worsens the current account must of necessity lead to a long-run real depreciation which generates the trade surpluses required to service the accumulated stock of net foreign debt. Our analysis shows, contrary to this, that the long-run equilibrium exchange rate can move in the same direction as the current exchange rate when there is a spending shock. In Section 3 we discuss the traditional methodology for identifying movements in the long-run equilibrium exchange rate. In general, the difference between the log level of the real exchange rate and its 3

7 expected long-run value depends upon the expected sum of current and all future short-term real interest differentials as well as a risk premium. This relationship is of sufficient generality that it is virtually devoid of empirical content. In particular, in the absence of restrictions on the expected long-run equilibrium real exchange rate and the time series properties of the real interest differential and the risk premium, there is no simple link between the level of the real exchange rate and the ex ante real interest differential. The traditional approach (taken by Frankel (1985), Shafer and Loopesko (1983) and Sachs (1985)) is to assume that the expectations hypothesis of the term-structure holds, and that the cross-currency risk premium is zero. These restrictions imply that the difference between the log of the real exchange rate and its expected long-run level is proportional to the ex ante long-term real interest rate differential. Of course this differential is unobservable, and must be constructed using the longterm nominal differential and a proxy for the expected long-term inflation differential. The problem with this is that it is hard to measure expected long-term inflation rates. We provide evidence that widely cited estimates of the differential between the ex ante long-term real interest rate in the U.S. and the other G7 countries as of February 1985 (the month in which the real value of the dollar peaked) may substantially overstate the absolute value of the true real differential as of that date. If this is true, the estimates understate the extent of long-run equilibrium dollar appreciation. In Section 4 we propose an alternative approach to the problem. We 4

8 develop an econometric framework which can be used to estimate the effect of the ex ante short-term real interest differential on the exchange rate, and the extent to which real exchange rate changes reflect shifts in the expected long-run equilibrium real exchange rate. The framework also provides an estimate of the correlation between innovations in the ex ante real interest differential and the expected long-run exchange rate, and allows for the presence of a time varying risk premium. Our approach may be described as follows. The ex ante short-term real interest differential is unobservable as is the expected long-run real exchange rate. However, the ex post short-term real differential and the current log level of the real exchange rate are observable. We assume that the ex ante short-term real differential is AR(l). This implies that the difference between the current log level of the real exchange rate and its expected long-run level is proportional to the ex ante short-term real interest differential. We also assume that the long-run real exchange rate follows a random walk. With these assumptions, it is possible to estimate a state-space model in which two observable variables, the log level of the real exchange rate and the ex post short-term real interest differential, are an exact linear combination of the unobservable state variables, the ex ante real differential, the expected long-run real exchange rate, and the error in forecasting inflation differentials. The advantage of such a tightly restricted system is that it provides efficient estimates of the minimum set of parameters required to estimate the extent to which fluctuations in the (observable) real exchange rate mirror fluctuations in the (unobservable) ex ante real interest 5

9 differential as opposed to shifts in the (unobservable) expected long-run real exchange rate. By using the short-term real differential we avoid the problem of employing proxies for long-run inflation expectations. The parameter estimates take account of the sampling error associated with estimating the ex ante differential from the ex post differential, and allow for covariance between shifts in the expected long-run real exchange rate and innovations in the ex ante differential. Our basic findings, presented in detail in Section 5, are easily summarized: since 1980, movements in the dollar real exchange rate have been dominated by unanticipated shifts in the expected long-run dollar exchange rate. Ex ante real interest differentials have simply not been persistent enough, and their innovation variance simply not large enough, to account for a substantial fraction of the variation in the dollar real exchange rate over this period. We also find that the covarjance between innovations in real interest differentials and in the long run equilibrium exchange rate has been positive in the period. That is, shocks which have increased real interest rates in the U.S. relative to foreign countries have also appreciated the long-run equilibrium real exchange rate and the current real exchange rate. This is precisely the pattern that we model theoretically in Section 2. In Section 6 we relate our results to other recent empirical research on real exchange rates and interest rates, and we discuss current conjectures about the sources of the real dollar depreciation which has occurred since early

10 2. Autonomous Sendinp Shifts and the Long-Run Real Exchange Rate In the simple textbook Mundell-Flemming world, a permanent autonomous increase in spending on domestic goods results in a permanent decline in the relative price of imports (a permanent real appreciation) and a sustained current account deficit. Current account deficits which result from autonomous expenditure shifts redistribute wealth away from the deficit country to the rest of the world. While the Mundell-Flemming model ignores the effects of this wealth transfer, a number of recent models of current account and exchange rate dynamics imply that the decline in domestic wealth reduces domestic absorption relative to national product, induces a real depreciation with an accompanying real interest differential, and gradually eliminates the current account deficit (see Mussa (1984) for a survey and extension of the literature). It is sometimes claimed that the deterioration of a country's net foreign asset position resulting from an autonomous increase in spending requires a long-run real depreciation which more than offsets the initial real appreciation. The reasoning behind this argument is straightforward: the exchange rate must depreciate in real terms relative to its initial equilibrium to generate the trade-balance surpluses necessary to service the interest payments on the economy's accumulated stock of net foreign debt. To evaluate this claim, we investigate the stationarystate properties of Mussa's (1984) rational expectations model of the current account and the real exchange rate. Consider an open economy which produces a fixed quantity of a tradeable good (the domestic good), consumes the domestic as well as a foreign good, and trades a single real asset (denominated in foreign 7

11 goods) with the rest of the world. The rate of return on this asset, r, is assumed constant and the net stock held by domestic residents, a, may be positive or negative. Foreign residents are willing to exchange foreign goods for real assets at the prevailing rate of return r, but their demand for domestic goods in exchange for foreign goods is less than perfectly elastic with respect to the relative price of foreign goods in terms of domestic goods, the real exchange rate. Let q denote the logarithm of the real exchange rate. Spending on domestic goods by domestic residents depends upon the real exchange rate, the desired level of total spending on both domestic and foreign goods by domestic residents, and an autonomous component of total domestic spending which is assumed to fall exclusively on domestic goods. The sum of the excess demands of domestic and foreign residents for domestic goods (in terms of foreign goods) is assumed to be given by h s(y-x)+q+x; (1) where y is the excess of the desired level of total domestic spending on both domestic and foreign goods over the value of domestically produced goods (both measured in terms of foreign goods), s is the marginal expenditure share of total desired domestic spending which falls on domestic goods, and x is an autonomous component of domestic spending which falls exclusively on domestic goods. An increase in the excess of total desired domestic spending over the value of domestic production increases the excess demand for domestic goods by the share of such spending, s, which falls on domestic goods in the absence of exchange rate changes. A rise in q represents a real exchange rate depreciation (an increase in the relative price of imports) 8

12 which shifts both domestic and foreign spending to domestic goods. Finally, an increase in autonomous spending on domestic goods, x, leaves the difference (y - x) unaffected (because desired total spending increases one for one with autonomous spending) but increases the excess demand for domestic goods. In equilibrium, the sum of the excess demands of domestic and foreign residents for domestic production must equal zero. Setting h 0 in equation (1) and rearranging terms we obtain the following condition for equilibrium in the market for domestic goods: y -v(q + (1 - s)x); (2) where v 1/s. Equation (2) states that, for any given level of autonomous spending, an increase in the desired excess of total domestic spending over the value of domestic product requires a real appreciation of the domestic currency to restore equilibrium in the market for domestic goods. Furthermore, as shown in Mussa (1984, p.29), given the value of y, equilibrium in the domestic goods market implies that the domestic excess demand for foreign goods is zero. The determinants of desired total spending by domestic residents are assumed to be the domestic real interest rate (relative to the world real interest rate), the stock of net foreign assets, the difference between net foreign assets and their target level, and an autonomous component. Specifically, desired saving - the difference between national income (including interest income) and total desired spending - is assumed to be given by ra-y=(r-r)+u(a-a)-x (3) where R is the domestic real interest rate, A is the target level of 9

13 assets, and u is a partial adjustment parameter such that 0 < u < 1. An increase in the domestic real interest rate is assumed to increase desired saving and thus to depress the excess of desired total spending over the value of national product. Similarly, the larger is the difference between actual and target assets, the smaller is desired total spending and the larger is desired saving. Finally, an autonomous increase in desired spending, x, represents an autonomous decrease in desired saving and, if x is permanent, an autonomous decrease in the target level of assets. The domestic real interest rate depends on the world interest rate, r, and the expected rate of change of the relative price of foreign goods E[D(q)J: R = r + se[d(q)]; (4) where D is the forward difference operator. If the relative price of foreign goods in terms of domestic goods is expected to increase, then an asset that pays a rate of return r in foreign goods has a rate of return R in terms of the domestic consumption basket which exceeds r by E[D(q)] weighted by the marginal expenditure share s devoted to domestic goods. As a matter of accounting, the current account surplus corresponds to the rate of accumulation of net foreign assets, and is equal to the excess of national income (including interest income) over total spending by domestic residents. Using the equilibrium condition (2) for the market for domestic product, the accumualtion of net foreign assets can be written D(A) = v(q + (1 - s)x)) + ra. (5) The current account surplus must also, in equilibrium, equal desired 10

14 saving. Substituting (4) into (3) and equating to (5), we obtain v((1 - s)x + q) + ra se[d(q)] + u(a - a) - x. (6) Equations (5) and (6) represent a system of forward looking difference equations which jointly determine the time paths of the real exchange rate, q, and net foreign assets, a, conditional on the initial stock of foreign assets and the expected future path of autonomous spending. The general solution for this model is provided by Mussa, and is investigated further by Mussa and Frenkel (1985). For the special case in which shifts in autonomous spending are expected to be permanent (so that x(t) = E[x(t+j)J x) a number of concrete results are obtained which we now summarize. The first and most basic set of results is that a permanent, autonomous increase in spending on domestic goods induces a jump real appreciation, an increase in real interest rates at home relative to those abroad (a fall in the real interest differential), and a current account deficit. The increase in home real interest rates dampens, but does not reverse, the excess of total spending by domestic residents over national income which is created by the autonomous spending increase. Similarly, the real appreciation shifts a portion of the excess domestic spending toward foreign goods as domestic and foreign residents find foreign substitutes relatively less expensive. In subsequent periods, the excess of total spending by domestic residents over national income (the current account deficit) narrows as the wealth effect of a declining stock of net foreign assets reduces total domestic spending. As spending falls, the home currency depreciates; indeed, it is the expectation of this subsequent 11

15 depreciation which induces the initially high level of domestic real interest rates. A noteworthy feature of the model's rational expectations equilibrium is that the ex ante real interest differential follows an AR(l) process, so that the difference between the current log level of the real exchange rate and its expected long-run equilibrium value is always proportional to the current one-period ex ante real interest differential. We examine an empirical specification of this type in Section 4. Unfortunately, as is so often the case in empirical macroeconomics, this result does not generalize to more general specifications for the forcing variables, in this case autonomous spending. The rational expectations equilibrium paths for the real exchange rate, the real interest differential, and the current account converge to a stationary state in which the real interest differential is zero, the current account is in balance, and the real exchange rate is constant. From equation (3) we see that the stationary-state level of net foreign assets is given by a A - x/u which we shall assume, without any loss of generality, is negative. In the stationary state, the excess of national product over desired spending must be sufficient to service the interest on the accumulated stock of foreign debt. Does this in itself imply that the home currency must depreciate in the long run by more than the initial appreciation? The stationary-state condition for a balanced current account is obtained by substituting a = A - x/u in equation (5) and setting the right-hand-side to zero: -r(a - x/u) = v((l - s)x + q). (7) A bit of algebra reveals that the necessary and sufficient condition for 12

16 a long-run real appreciation in response to a permanent increase in autonomous spending is 1/s > (1 + r/u). (8) Recall that u is the partial adjustment parameter and that r is the world real rate of interest. For plausible parameter values, the ratio r/u is most likely less than 1/4. Thus, a value of s <.8 would insure that the long-run real exchange rate would appreciate in response to a permanent increase in autonomous spending. Equation (8) nicely summarizes the two counteracting influences of a permanent increase in autonomous spending on the long-run real exchange rate. Autonomous spending which falls on domestic goods requires a real appreciation which shifts spending away from domestic goods which are in excess demand. However, permanent increases in autonomous spending can reverse the country's net foreign asset position to that of a substantial net debtor. The interest on this debt must be met by an export surplus which, ceterus paribus, requires a real depreciation which shifts spending towards domestic goods. Thus, the higher the world real interest rate and the smaller the rate at which saving adjusts, the larger is foreign debt and debt service in the stationary-state and the more likely it is that the real exchange rate must depreciate. However, so long as the ratio 1/s exceeds 1 + r/u, this effect is outweighed and the long-run real exchange rate appreciates despite a potentially substantial accumulation of foreign debt in the stationary state. For example, suppose that in the initial stationary state autonomous spending is zero, net foreign assets are positive, and that u.20, r =.04, and s =.80. Consider now a shift in autonomous spending equal to 13

17 initial foreign assets. From equations (7) and (8), we see that in the new stationary state, the long-run equilibrium exchange rate appreciates because (1/.80) > 1 + (.04/.20). Yet, the stock of foreign debt in the new stationary state is four times the stock of foreign assets in the original stationary state (since by assumption x = A and net foreign assets in the new stationary state are given by A - x/u). The above model, while simple, usefully illustrates several key properties of the real exchange rate. First, the current level of the real exchange rate depends upon the expected level of the long-run real exchange rate which is consistent with a balanced current account. Second, autonomous spending disturbances will be expected to shift the long-run real exchange rate. Third, if autonomous spending falls on domestic goods, there is a presumption that the real exchange rate will initially appreciate even if in the long run it must depreciate. Fourth, the fact that the current account deficits associated with an autonomous spending increase can result in a potentially large stock of foreign debt does not necessarily imply that the long run real exchange rate must depreciate relative to its initial equilibrium. In sum, autonomous expenditure shifts will in general change the expected long-run level of the real exchange rate. Shifts in autononmous expenditure which are perceived to be permanent and which fall on domestic goods will induce a real appreciation on impact, and may induce a long-run real appreciation even if the current account adjustment mechanism entails the accumulation of a substantial stock of foreign debt. 14

18 3. Empirical Evidence on the Long Run Real Exchange Rate One influential view of exchange rate behavior in the 1980's stresses the importance of tight monetary policy during This view uses Dornbusch's (1976) overshooting model with sluggish price adjustment to account for both the real dollar appreciation and high U.S. real interest rates in the early 1980's. It gives no important role to shifts in the long-run equilibrium real exchange rate. Sachs (1985) and Frankel (1985) present empirical evidence supporting the notion that very little of the real appreciation of the dollar between 1980 and early 1985 was due to a shift in the expected long-run real exchange rate. Their approach is to use proxies for ex ante real interest differentials on long-term bonds to make inferences about the expected cumulative real appreciation of the dollar over the life of the bonds. If uncovered interest parity holds, then the market's expectation of the cumulative real appreciation of the dollar against a particular foreign currency is just nd ne (r - r ), where n is the number of years until nt t f,n,t us,n,t the bonds mature and is the ex post real yield to maturity on n year bonds denominated in the currency of country j. In practice, the expected real yield differential is unobservable, and a proxy for the average expected annual inflation differential over the n year interval must be subtracted from the nominal yield differential to obtain a proxy for the ex ante real yield differential. Table 1 presents Frankel's (1985) estimates of the ex ante real interest rate differential as of February 1985 on 10 year government bonds in the U.S. and a weighted average of the other G7 countries. Three proxies for the expected annual average inflation rate over the 15

19 next 10 years are used, one year lagged inflation, three year distributed lagged inflation, and a DRI forecast of inflation. As of February 1985, nominal yields in the U.S. were 237 basis points higher than the weighted average of foreign yields, so the nominal yield differential stood at -237 basis points; the estimated real differential ranges from -270 to -346 basis points. Assuming that the market expected the real exchange rate to reach long-run equilibrium within 10 years, the real value of the dollar relative to the other G7 countries as of February 1985 was, according to Frankel's estimates, some 24 to 35% above its long-run real equilibrium. Frankel concludes that, "compared with the 33 percent logarithmic real appreciation that the weighted dollar has experienced relative to its average,... most of the real appreciation is attributable to an increase in the real interest differential. Relatively little seems attributable to a change in the long-run equilibrium exchange rate (Frankel (1985), p.202)." Using a somewhat different proxy - a two-year centered moving average of actual inflation rates - for expected inflation over a ten year period, Sachs (1985) reaches much the same conclusion with regards to the the real overvaluation of the dollar relative to the mark as of the end of These calculations are especially sensitive to errors in the measurement of the expected annual average inflation rate over the life of the bonds. To assess the potential magnitude of this measurement error, we recompute Frankel's estimate of the real long-term interest differential as of February 1985 using Richard Hoey's survey of ten year U.S. inflation expectations of financial market participants as of that date. The results are presented in the bottom row of Table 1. According to 16

20 Hoey's survey, U.S. financial market participants were expecting an average annual inflation rate of 5.49% as February This is 1.33 percentage points higher than Frankel's estimate of expected U.S. inflation using the DRI forecast and 1.95 percantage points higher than his estimate using one-year lagged inflation. The implied ex ante real yield on 10 year U.S. government bonds using the Hoey survey results is 6.21% compared with Frankel's estimates of between 7.54% and 8.16%. How much of a difference does this make in calculating the overvaluation of the dollar as of February 1985? A lower bound on the extent of overvaluation can be obtained by subtracting Frankel's highest estimate of the weighted average foreign real 10 year yield, 5.25%, from the U.S. rate implied by Hoey's estimate and multiplying by 10. The result is an estimated overvaluation of only 9.6% as of February Thus, depending on the measure of inflationary expectations used, the dollar was overvalued in real terms as of February 1985 by less than 10% or more than 30%. The point of these calculations is not to criticize any particular choice of proxies for long-term inflationary expectations, but just to illustrate how sensitive any computation based upon expected long-term real interest rates is to the proxy chosen. Because of this sensitivity, no clear consensus has emerged on the extent of dollar overvaluation in early For example, Obstfeld argued in April 1985 that At present, long-term nominal interest differentials between the U.S. and West Germany are roughly 200 basis points above short-term differentials. Under the expectations theory, this implies an expected rise in the U.S. - West German short-term real interest differential, an expected future increase in relative U.S. inflation, or some of each. Given the probable future evolution of fiscal positions within the OECD, I find the expected 17

21 inflation explanation of the current international term structure most plausible. While the real value of the dollar should be expected to fall, I am not convinced that markets expect it to fall as far as its 1977 level (Obstfeld comment on Sachs (1985)). Clearly there is much to be gained from an alternative way to estimate the long-run equilibrium exchange rate. 4. An Econometric Framework In this section we develop an econometric framework which can be used to estimate and interpret (i) the contemporaneous correlation between the real exchange rate and the ex ante short-term real interest differential; and (ii) the extent to which fluctuations in the real exchange rate reflect shifts in the expected long-run real exchange rate. The framework also provides an estimate of the correlation between innovations in the long-run real exchange rate and in the ex ante shortterm real interest differential. We begin with the following basic relationship: = E[q} + E[d] + k. (9) Here is the natural log of the real exchange rate at the start of period t, defined as the nominal exchange rate divided by the ratio of the U.S. and foreign price levels. When the dollar appreciates in real terms, falls. dt rf - r is the ex post short-term real interest differential, the ex post one-period real interest rate realized on foreign assets in period t, less the ex post one-period real rate on U.S. assets. Finally, kt is a risk premium which separates the expected rate of real appreciation of the dollar from the ex ante real interest 18

22 differential. When 0, equation (9) follows immediately from the logarithmic approximation to the uncovered interest parity condition (Cumby and Obstfeld (1984)). Solving equation (9) forward, we obtain w + E E[d+.] + E E[k.], (10) where w is the limit as i approaches infinity of the expectation at time t of the long-run log real exchange rate. We assume that this limit exists (which requires, for example, that ex post real interest differentials follow a stationary stochastic process with mean zero). Equation (10) expresses the difference between the current and long-run log level of the real exchange rate as the undiscounted sum of current and expected future one-period real interest differentials plus the undiscounted sum of current and expected future risk premia. Absent restrictions on the time series properties of w, Et[dJ, and kt, equation (10) is virtually devoid of empirical content. One approach employed by Shafer and Loopesko (1983) and Sachs (1985) is to assume that is constant, kt 0 for all t, and that a proxy for the ex ante longterm real interest differential, Dt, exactly incorporates the undiscounted sum of current and future short-term real interest differentials. Under these assumptions, the following regression should 2 have an R of 1: = w + (11) As discussed in detail in the previous two sections, it is quite likely that any proxies for expected inflation used to construct the long-term 19

23 real interest differentials are subject to measurement error and perhaps even bias. Furthermore, on both theoretical and empirical grounds, it is desirable to allow for shifts in the expected long-run real exchange rate. If fluctuations in w are correlated with the real differential, then the regression given by equation (11) cannot be used to interpret the correlation between the the real exchange rate and the real interest differential. Our approach is to parameterize the dynamics of the variables in (10), without assuming that they are observable. With parsimony in mind, we impose the following restrictions on the unobservables w, E[d], and the forecast error e d - E[d]: E[d] = pe1[dti] + v (12) v Ae1 + u1 (13) e u2 (14) w1 + u3 (15) E[uukl 0; i,j 1,2,3; k > 1 (16) Equation (12) restricts the ex ante one-period real differential to be a zero mean AR(l) process with parameter p. Equation (13) expresses the innovation to this process from the beginning of period t-1 to the beginning of period t as the sum of two terms, a multiple.x of the inflation surprise realized in period t-l, and an independent error u1. Equation (14) is just the rational expectations restriction that the inflation surprise (the difference between the ex post and ex ante real interest differential) is white noise. Equation (15) imposes the restriction that changes in the expected long-run real exchange rate are 20

24 unforecastable. The innovation in w could in general depend on ei, as the innovation in Et[dt] does, without violating this restriction (since etl is not known until the start of period t). However for simplicity we exclude such a correlation. (When we estimated a model leaving this correlation free, we found little increase in likelihood, and qualitatively similar estimates to those reported.) Finally, equation (16) states that the vector [u1 u2 u3]' is white noise. It should be said at the outset that the motivation for the AR(l) specification for the ex ante real interest differential is its empirical tractability. First, the AR(l) specification implies that the ex post real interest differential is an ARMA(l,l) process. The parameter p is identified from the autocorrelations of the ex post differential alone (it is the rate at which higher-order autocorrelations decay). Second, the AR(l) specification implies that, in the absence of a risk premium (l/(l-p))et[dt] + w. (17) That is, the observable real exchange rate is a simple linear combination of the unobservable ex ante real interest differential and the unobservable expected long-run real exchange rate. The more persistent is the AR(l) process for the ex ante differential, the bigger the effect of the differential on the real exchange rate. The AR(l) specification for the real interest differential can also be motivated theoretically. In a world in which permanent, nominal shocks are predominant, Dornbusch's overshooting analysis implies the relationship given in equation (17). Furthermore, as shown in Section 2, permanent real shocks can lead to the same linear relationship between 21

25 the real exchange rate and the short-term real interest differential. However, if real shocks are predominant, shifts in the expected long run real exchange rate will also account for fluctuations in cl. With this background, consider the following state-space model comprised of two measurement equations q4 = l/(l-p) 0 1 E[d] and three transition equations wt Et[d] p A 0 Et1{diP u1 e ei + u2 w w1 u3 The measurement equations express the vector of two observable variables, the real exchange rate and the ex post real interest differential, as a linear transformation of the vector of three unobservable variables, the ex ante real interest differential, the error in forecasting inflation differentials, and the expected long-run real exchange rate. The transition equations provide the law of motion for the vector of unobservable variables. As discussed above, the vector of disturbances to the transition equations is assumed to be serially uncorrelated. The three errors have standard deviations a1, a2 and a3. The contemporaneous covariances a12 and a23 are zero by the property of rational forecast errors. a13 is the contemporaneous covariance between innovations in the 22

26 expected long-run real exchange rate and innovations, unrelated to inflation surprises, in the ex ante real interest differential; it is left unrestricted. The method of Kalman filtering can be used to estimate the parameters of the state-space model. In the absence of a risk premium, there are only two free parameters in the measurement and transition matrices, p and A. There are four free parameters in the variance-covariance matrix of the transition equation innovations, the three variances and the covariance A number of empirical studies have uncovered a time-varying risk premium in the foreign exchange market (see Cumby (1985) for a useful survey and extension of the literature; see Campbell and Clarida (1987) for a recent investigation of risk premia in Euromarket term structures). Within the context of our state-space framework, it is straightforward to introduce an unobservable time-varying risk premium of the following form: ke[d]. (18) Equation (18) says that the risk premium, which separates the expected rate of real appreciation from the real interest differential in favor of foreign assets, is proportional to the ex ante real differential. As such, it makes no statement about causality, but is merely a (very tight) restriction on the covariance between two endogenous, unobservable variables. Note that in the presence of a risk premium, the ex ante real interest differential is a biased predictor of the expected rate of real depreciation. Substituting (18) into (11), 23

27 - E[q1] ae[dt], (19) where a 1 + k. By assuming that the risk premium is perfectly correlated with the ex ante real interest differential, we maintain the tractability of our approach while allowing the real interest differential to be a biased predictor of the expected rate of change of the real exchange rate. In particular, maintaining our restriction that the real interest differential is AR(1), equation (19) implies = (a/(lp))e[d] + w. (20) The requisite modification to the measurement equation is apparent. 5. Data and Empirical Results Data on one month Eurodeposit rates and spot exchange rates against the dollar were obtained for the U.S., Canada, the United Kingdom, Germany, and Japan from the Harris Bank tape. Consumer price indexes for these countries were obtained from the IFS tape. The sample period studied was November 1979 through March Exchange rates and interest rates were sampled on the last Friday of each month. Real exchange rates were constructed as 1tft"us,t (21) where s is the nominal exchange rate in units of foreign currency per dollar and is the ratio of foreign to U.S. CPI's. Ex post real interest differentials were constructed by subtracting the actual inflation differential (as measured by logarithmic changes in the country 24

28 CPI's) over the following month from nominal one-month interest differential as of the last Friday of the preceding month. All results are reported in units of percent per month at an annualized rate. Table 2 displays some summary statistics for our data over the period 1979: :3. The first four columns describe the Canadian, British, German and Japanese data respectively; the last column describes an average formed using 1980 trade weights (Canada 46.35%, United Kingdom 12.43%, Germany 12.69% and Japan 28.53%). The first two rows of Table 2 give the sample means and standard deviations of real exchange rate changes over the period. The sample means are negative, corresponding to real dollar appreciation, for all countries except Japan. The standard deviation for Canada is about 15% per month at an annualized rate, while for the other countries it exceeds 40%. The next two rows of the table give the same statistics for ex post real interest differentials. Sample means are negative for all countries, indicating that real interest rates were higher on average in the U.S. than abroad. Sample standard deviations range from 3% to 8%. These statistics emphasize that real exchange rate changes have been much more volatile than even ex post real interest differentials. A fortiori, they have been much more volatile than ex ante differentials. If real interest rate movements are to explain exchange rates, they must be highly persistent so that they have a magnified effect on the exchange rate (equation (17)), or there must be a very large risk premium effect (equation (20)). At the bottom of Table 2, the first six autocorrelations of the ex 25

29 post real interest differential are reported. These were computed assuming that the true mean of the real interest differential is zero (as discussed in the previous section, this is an implication of our exchange rate model and is also assumed when we estimate our state-space representation). Similar but slightly smaller numbers are obtained when one assumes that the sample mean differential is the true mean. The largest autocorrelations occur for the German data. These autocorrelations die off smoothly so that the German ex post real interest differential looks much like an AR(l) process with coefficient 0.5 or 0.6. This is striking since we model the ex ante differential as an AR(l) process so we expect to find more complex ARMA(l,l) behavior of the ex post differential. The autocorrelations are smaller for the other countries, starting at 0.25 for the U.K., 0.17 for Canada and 0.03 for Japan. They also have a less regular pattern. In Tables 3-7 we estimate the state space model described in the previous section, for each currency and the trade-weighted average. In each table we report results for a model assuming uncovered interest parity, and for the linear risk premium model of equations (18)-(20). We report the coefficients a, p and ) with asymptotic standard errors, the standard deviations, c2 and of the three error terms, and the correlation a13/c1c3. We also report some implications of these numbers: the fractions of the variance of the ex post real interest differential which are due to the variance of the ex ante differential and the variance of the inflation forecast error; the fractions of the innovation variance of the real exchange rate which are due to the innovation variance of the ex ante differential, the innovation variance of the 26

30 long-run equilibrium real exchange rate and the innovation covariance between these variables; the correlation between real exchange rate innovations and innovations in the ex ante differential and the long-run equilibrium exchange rate; and finally, the correlation between innovations in the ex ante differential and innovations in the long-run equilibrium exchange rate. The most striking feature of the results, which is robust across currencies and the presence of a linear risk premium, is how little of the variance of real exchange rate innovations is accounted for by innovations in the ex ante real interest differential. When uncovered interest parity is assumed, the estimates of the share of the ex ante differential in real exchange rate innovation variance are particularly small: they never exceed 9%, while the long-run equilibrium exchange rate accounts for at least 79% and the covariance between components accounts for the rest of the variance. In the linear risk premium model, the ex ante differential plays a somewhat larger role because the coefficient a is estimated larger than one in absolute value for all countries except Japan. Thus the risk premium amplifies the effect of the differential on the exchange rate. Even in the risk premium model, however, the largest share of the ex ante differential in real exchange rate innovation variance is 42% for the trade-weighted average. The estimates for individual currencies are all less than 27%. The reason why we obtain these results is that we do not estimate enough persistence in the ex ante real interest differential to overcome the low standard deviation of the differential relative to the change in 27

31 the exchange rate. Our estimates of p range from 0.35 to 0.81, and higher estimates tend to be associated with a smaller share of the ex ante differential in the variance of the ex post differential. (The ex ante differential accounts for less than 50% of the variance of the ex post differential except in Germany, where as noted above an AR(l) model rather than an ARMA(l,l) model fits the ex post differential quite well). A second striking feature of our results is that the correlation between innovations in the long-run equilibrium real exchange rate and innovations in the ex ante real interest differential is almost always estimated to be positive. The one exception to this statement is the uncovered interest parity model for Germany, which has a tiny negative correlation of The positive correlation implies that shocks that have caused the expected long-run real exchange rate to appreciate have also increased real interest rates in the U.S. relative to those abroad. As we showed in Section 2, this pattern could result from permanent shocks to the demand for domestic goods. In the uncovered interest parity models, a positive shock to the ex ante real interest differential raises the real exchange rate. In these models, therefore, the correlation between shocks to the long-run exchange rate and the real interest differential increases the variance of real exchange rate innovations. In the linear risk premium models, on the other hand, the coefficient a is estimated to be negative for all currencies except the Canadian dollar and the Japanese yen. A negative a corresponds to a negative coefficient k, of absolute magnitude greater than one, in equation (18). In words, the ex ante real interest differential and the risk premium 28

32 move inversely, and the risk premium has a larger variance. This is consistent with Fama's (1984) findings on the relationship between the nominal forward premium and the risk premium. When c is negative, a positive shock to the real differential causes the real exchange rate to fall, so the correlation between shocks to the long-run exchange rate and the differential reduces the variance of real exchange rate innovations. However the real exchange rate still moves in the same direction as the long-run equilibrium exchange rate in all the models we estimate. Our approach relies on the assumption that the stochastic processes driving interest rates and exchange rates are stable through time. However changes in monetary and fiscal policies will in general alter these processes. Clarida and Friedman (1984) have documented a shift in the process for nominal U.S. Treasury bill rates after October 1979, while Huizinga and Mishkin (1985) have isolated changes in the real interest rate process in the U.S. in October 1979 and October Our sample period starts in October 1979, so the shift at that date does not contaminate our results. The October 1982 change is potentially more of a problem, but when we estimate our model for the trade-weighted average data in the post-october 1982 period, we find similar results to those reported in the tables. The uncovered interest parity model attributes over 95% of the variance of real exchange rate innovations to innovations in the long-run equilibrium rate. In the linear risk premium model, the innovations in the real interest differential and the long-run equilibrium rate are estimated to be almost perfectly correlated. It is well known that real exchange rate changes are largely unpredictable (Cumby and Obstfeld (1984)), and a skeptic may argue that 29

Jeffrey Frankel s chapter is a useful summary and extension of results in

Jeffrey Frankel s chapter is a useful summary and extension of results in Comments Frederic S. Mishkin Jeffrey Frankel s chapter is a useful summary and extension of results in the literature on international capital mobility and crowding-out. He looks at the question of whether

More information

1+R = (1+r)*(1+expected inflation) = r + expected inflation + r*expected inflation +1

1+R = (1+r)*(1+expected inflation) = r + expected inflation + r*expected inflation +1 Expecting a 5% increase in prices, investors require greater nominal returns than real returns. If investors are insensitive to inflation risk, then the nominal return must compensate for expected inflation:

More information

1) Real and Nominal exchange rates are highly positively correlated. 2) Real and nominal exchange rates are well approximated by a random walk.

1) Real and Nominal exchange rates are highly positively correlated. 2) Real and nominal exchange rates are well approximated by a random walk. Stylized Facts Most of the large industrialized countries floated their exchange rates in early 1973, after the demise of the post-war Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates. While there have been

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV John E. Floyd University of Toronto May 10, 2013 Our major task here is to look at the evidence regarding the effects of unanticipated money shocks on real

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

1 trillion units * ($1 per unit) = $500 billion * 2

1 trillion units * ($1 per unit) = $500 billion * 2 Under the strict monetarist view, real interest rates and money supply are assumed to be independent. Under this assumption, inflation does not affect real rates. Nevertheless, nominal rates, R, are obviously

More information

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Properties of the estimated five-factor model Informationin(andnotin)thetermstructure Appendix. Additional results Greg Duffee Johns Hopkins This draft: October 8, Properties of the estimated five-factor model No stationary term structure model is

More information

What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates?

What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates? 1 What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates? This chapter does not provide a definitive or comprehensive definition of FEERs. Many discussions of the concept already exist (e.g., Williamson 1983, 1985,

More information

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities - The models we studied earlier include only real variables and relative prices. We now extend these models to have

More information

III Econometric Policy Evaluation

III Econometric Policy Evaluation III Econometric Policy Evaluation 6 Design of Policy Systems This chapter considers the design of macroeconomic policy systems. Three questions are addressed. First, is a worldwide system of fixed exchange

More information

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION by John B. Taylor Stanford University October 1997 This draft was prepared for the Robert A. Mundell Festschrift Conference, organized by Guillermo

More information

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions. Suppose that a representative consumer receives an endowment of a non-storable consumption good. The endowment evolves exogenously according to ln

More information

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination Carl E. Walsh March 8, 017 Contents 1 Policy Coordination 1 1.1 The Basic Model..................................... 1. Equilibrium with Coordination.............................

More information

Applied Econometrics and International Development. AEID.Vol. 5-3 (2005)

Applied Econometrics and International Development. AEID.Vol. 5-3 (2005) PURCHASING POWER PARITY BASED ON CAPITAL ACCOUNT, EXCHANGE RATE VOLATILITY AND COINTEGRATION: EVIDENCE FROM SOME DEVELOPING COUNTRIES AHMED, Mudabber * Abstract One of the most important and recurrent

More information

IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA?

IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA? IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA? C. Barry Pfitzner, Department of Economics/Business, Randolph-Macon College, Ashland, VA, bpfitzne@rmc.edu ABSTRACT This paper investigates the

More information

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom Gaétan Stephan 1 University of Rennes 1, CREM April 2012 (Preliminary draft) Abstract We model the relation between output

More information

3. Money, Inflation, and Interest Rate Links with Currency Values

3. Money, Inflation, and Interest Rate Links with Currency Values 3. Money, Inflation, and Interest Rate Links with Currency Values Quantity Theory of Money... 1 Real and Nominal Interest Rates - The Impact of Expected Inflation... 4 Currency Values, Inflation, and Purchasing

More information

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth The Fisher Equation and Output Growth A B S T R A C T Although the Fisher equation applies for the case of no output growth, I show that it requires an adjustment to account for non-zero output growth.

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2015 Karl Whelan (UCD) Asset Prices Spring 2015 1 / 43 A New Topic We are now going to switch

More information

8: Relationships among Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates

8: Relationships among Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates 8: Relationships among Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates Infl ation rates and interest rates can have a significant impact on exchange rates (as explained in Chapter 4) and therefore can infl

More information

The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession

The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession Roger E.A. Farmer Department of Economics, UCLA 23 Bunche Hall Box 91 Los Angeles CA 9009-1 rfarmer@econ.ucla.edu Phone: +1 3 2 Fax: +1 3 2 92

More information

Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries

Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/speculativedynam00cutl2 working paper department of economics SPECULATIVE

More information

Portfolio Balance Models of Exchange

Portfolio Balance Models of Exchange Lecture Notes 10 Portfolio Balance Models of Exchange Rate Determination When economists speak of the portfolio balance approach, they are referring to a diverse set of models. There are a few common features,

More information

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1 Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Philippe Bacchetta Eric van Wincoop January 10, 007 1 Prepared for the May 007 issue of the American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings.

More information

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM RAY C. FAIR This paper uses a structural multi-country macroeconometric model to estimate the size of the decrease in transfer payments (or tax

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 202A DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 203 D. Romer FORCES LIMITING THE EXTENT TO WHICH SOPHISTICATED INVESTORS ARE WILLING TO MAKE TRADES THAT MOVE ASSET PRICES BACK TOWARD

More information

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure Comment on Dewachter and Lyrio s "Learning, Macroeconomic Dynamics, and the Term Structure of Interest Rates" 1 by Jordi Galí (CREI, MIT, and NBER) August 2006 The present paper by Dewachter and Lyrio

More information

LOW FREQUENCY MOVEMENTS IN STOCK PRICES: A STATE SPACE DECOMPOSITION REVISED MAY 2001, FORTHCOMING REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

LOW FREQUENCY MOVEMENTS IN STOCK PRICES: A STATE SPACE DECOMPOSITION REVISED MAY 2001, FORTHCOMING REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS LOW FREQUENCY MOVEMENTS IN STOCK PRICES: A STATE SPACE DECOMPOSITION REVISED MAY 2001, FORTHCOMING REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS Nathan S. Balke Mark E. Wohar Research Department Working Paper 0001

More information

Lectures 24 & 25: Determination of exchange rates

Lectures 24 & 25: Determination of exchange rates Lectures 24 & 25: Determination of exchange rates Building blocs - Interest rate parity - Money demand equation - Goods markets Flexible-price version: monetarist/lucas model - derivation - hyperinflation

More information

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve Capacity Utilization As a Real-Time Predictor of Manufacturing Output Evan F. Koenig Research Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve indices

More information

Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach

Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach John T. Harvey Professor of Economics Department of Economics Box 98510 Texas Christian University Fort Worth, Texas 7619 (817)57-730 j.harvey@tcu.edu

More information

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities - The models we studied earlier include only real variables and relative prices. We now extend these models to have

More information

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD European Economic Review 42 (1998) 887 895 The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD Philip R. Lane *, Roberto Perotti Economics Department, Trinity College Dublin, Dublin 2, Ireland Columbia University,

More information

TECHNICAL TRADING AT THE CURRENCY MARKET INCREASES THE OVERSHOOTING EFFECT* MIKAEL BASK

TECHNICAL TRADING AT THE CURRENCY MARKET INCREASES THE OVERSHOOTING EFFECT* MIKAEL BASK Finnish Economic Papers Volume 16 Number 2 Autumn 2003 TECHNICAL TRADING AT THE CURRENCY MARKET INCREASES THE OVERSHOOTING EFFECT* MIKAEL BASK Department of Economics, Umeå University SE-901 87 Umeå, Sweden

More information

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock Binh Le Thanh International University of Japan 15. August 2015 Online

More information

Forecasting Exchange Rates with PPP

Forecasting Exchange Rates with PPP Excess money growth provides a measure of pent up inflation. This measure is useful whenever price controls are in effect, as was true in the U.S. in the 1970's. For PPP to be a useful tool in these cases,

More information

VARIABILITY OF THE INFLATION RATE AND THE FORWARD PREMIUM IN A MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION: THE CASE OF THE GERMAN HYPERINFLATION

VARIABILITY OF THE INFLATION RATE AND THE FORWARD PREMIUM IN A MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION: THE CASE OF THE GERMAN HYPERINFLATION VARIABILITY OF THE INFLATION RATE AND THE FORWARD PREMIUM IN A MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION: THE CASE OF THE GERMAN HYPERINFLATION By: Stuart D. Allen and Donald L. McCrickard Variability of the Inflation Rate

More information

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning Doug Hostland Department of Finance Working Paper * 2001-20 * The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not reflect those of the Department of Finance. A previous version of this

More information

1. The Flexible-Price Monetary Approach Assume uncovered interest rate parity (UIP), which is implied by perfect capital substitutability 1.

1. The Flexible-Price Monetary Approach Assume uncovered interest rate parity (UIP), which is implied by perfect capital substitutability 1. Lecture 2 1. The Flexible-Price Monetary Approach (FPMA) 2. Rational Expectations/Present Value Formulation to the FPMA 3. The Sticky-Price Monetary Approach 4. The Dornbusch Model 1. The Flexible-Price

More information

Intervention in Foreign Exchange Markets

Intervention in Foreign Exchange Markets 830 Intervention in Foreign Exchange Markets A Summary of Ten Staff Studies The staffs of the Federal Reserve System and the U.S. Department of the Treasury have recently completed a set of ten studies

More information

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background 2 Theory 2.1 One Country 2.1.1 Background The theory that has guided the specification of the US model was first presented in Fair (1974) and then in Chapter 3 in Fair (1984). This work stresses three

More information

Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates

Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates Christiano 362, Winter 2003 February 21 Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates 1. Fixed versus flexible exchange rates: overview. Over time, and in different places, countries have adopted a fixed exchange

More information

1 Introduction. Term Paper: The Hall and Taylor Model in Duali 1. Yumin Li 5/8/2012

1 Introduction. Term Paper: The Hall and Taylor Model in Duali 1. Yumin Li 5/8/2012 Term Paper: The Hall and Taylor Model in Duali 1 Yumin Li 5/8/2012 1 Introduction In macroeconomics and policy making arena, it is extremely important to have the ability to manipulate a set of control

More information

Real Exchange Rates Recent US experience. Charles Engel University of Wisconsin

Real Exchange Rates Recent US experience. Charles Engel University of Wisconsin Real Exchange Rates Recent US experience Charles Engel University of Wisconsin US-G7 Real Exchange Rates 160 150 140 130 120 Euro C$ Yen UK 110 100 90 Jul-98 Dec-99 Apr-01 Sep-02 Jan-04 May-05 Oct-06 Feb-08

More information

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies George Alogoskoufis, International Macroeconomics, 2016 Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies Our analysis up to now was related to small open economies, which took developments

More information

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves issn 1936-5330 Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves Brent Bundick Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City First Version: October 2007 This Version: June 2008 RWP 07-08 Abstract Piazzesi and Swanson

More information

New evidence on the effects of US monetary policy on exchange rates

New evidence on the effects of US monetary policy on exchange rates Economics Letters 71 (2001) 255 263 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase New evidence on the effects of US monetary policy on exchange rates a b, * Sarantis Kalyvitis, Alexander Michaelides a University

More information

[Uncovered Interest Rate Parity and Risk Premium]

[Uncovered Interest Rate Parity and Risk Premium] [Uncovered Interest Rate Parity and Risk Premium] 1. Market Efficiency Hypothesis and Uncovered Interest Rate Parity (UIP) A forward exchange rate is a contractual rate established at time t for a transaction

More information

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY Alan J. Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko University of California, Berkeley January 2013 In this paper, we estimate the cross-country spillover effects of government

More information

A Regression Tree Analysis of Real Interest Rate Regime Changes

A Regression Tree Analysis of Real Interest Rate Regime Changes Preliminary and Incomplete Not for circulation A Regression Tree Analysis of Real Interest Rate Regime Changes Marcio G. P. Garcia Depto. de Economica PUC RIO Rua Marques de Sao Vicente, 225 Gavea Rio

More information

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Philippe Bacchetta Study Center Gerzensee University of Lausanne Swiss Finance Institute & CEPR Eric van Wincoop University of Virginia NBER January

More information

Did Wages Reflect Growth in Productivity?

Did Wages Reflect Growth in Productivity? Did Wages Reflect Growth in Productivity? The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Published Version Accessed

More information

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios Amit Goyal Goizueta Business School Emory University Ivo Welch Yale School of Management Yale Economics Department NBER December 16, 2003 Abstract This

More information

Theory of the rate of return

Theory of the rate of return Macroeconomics 2 Short Note 2 06.10.2011. Christian Groth Theory of the rate of return Thisshortnotegivesasummaryofdifferent circumstances that give rise to differences intherateofreturnondifferent assets.

More information

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

CFA Level II - LOS Changes CFA Level II - LOS Changes 2017-2018 Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Topic LOS Level II - 2017 (464 LOS) LOS Level II - 2018 (465 LOS) Compared 1.1.a 1.1.b 1.2.a 1.2.b 1.3.a

More information

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model) Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model) This is a model that describes the dynamics of economies in the short run. It has million of critiques, and rightfully so. However, even though

More information

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Policy Research Working Paper 6525 Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in

More information

Lecture 3, Part 1 (Bubbles, Portfolio Balance Models)

Lecture 3, Part 1 (Bubbles, Portfolio Balance Models) Lecture 3, Part 1 (Bubbles, Portfolio Balance Models) 1. Rational Bubbles in Theory 2. An Early Test for Price Bubbles 3. Meese's Tests Foreign Exchange Bubbles 4. Limitations of Bubble Tests 5. A Simple

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CAN AN INCREASED BUDGET DEFICIT BE CONTRACTIONARY? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. l43)4

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CAN AN INCREASED BUDGET DEFICIT BE CONTRACTIONARY? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. l43)4 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CAN AN INCREASED BUDGET DEFICIT BE CONTRACTIONARY? Martin Feldstein Working Paper No. l43)4 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138

More information

International Macroeconomics

International Macroeconomics Slides for Chapter 3: Theory of Current Account Determination International Macroeconomics Schmitt-Grohé Uribe Woodford Columbia University May 1, 2016 1 Motivation Build a model of an open economy to

More information

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh Volume 29, Issue 3 Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh Yu Hsing Southeastern Louisiana University A. M. M. Jamal Southeastern Louisiana University Wen-jen Hsieh

More information

Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment

Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Jason Beeler and John Y. Campbell October 0 Beeler: Department of Economics, Littauer Center, Harvard University,

More information

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael Discussion Benoît Carmichael The two studies presented in the first session of the conference take quite different approaches to the question of price indexes. On the one hand, Coulombe s study develops

More information

The Goods Market and the Aggregate Expenditures Model

The Goods Market and the Aggregate Expenditures Model The Goods Market and the Aggregate Expenditures Model Chapter 8 The Historical Development of Modern Macroeconomics The Great Depression of the 1930s led to the development of macroeconomics and aggregate

More information

Inter-forecast monetary policy implementation: fixed-instrument versus MCI-based strategies. By Ben Hunt. March 1999

Inter-forecast monetary policy implementation: fixed-instrument versus MCI-based strategies. By Ben Hunt. March 1999 G99/1 monetary policy implementation: fixed- versus MCI-based strategies By Ben Hunt March 1999 Abstract 1 Monetary policy authorities can adjust their at any point in time to achieve their policy objective.

More information

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation ECONOMIC BULLETIN 3/218 ANALYTICAL ARTICLES Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation Ángel Estrada and Francesca Viani 6 September 218 Following

More information

Data Dependence and U.S. Monetary Policy. Remarks by. Richard H. Clarida. Vice Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Data Dependence and U.S. Monetary Policy. Remarks by. Richard H. Clarida. Vice Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System For release on delivery 8:30 a.m. EST November 27, 2018 Data Dependence and U.S. Monetary Policy Remarks by Richard H. Clarida Vice Chairman Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System at The Clearing

More information

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Asset Prices and Monetary Policy Volume Author/Editor: John Y. Campbell, editor Volume Publisher:

More information

Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries

Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries Economics Letters 71 (2001) 197 203 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries Soyoung Kim* Department of Economics, 225b

More information

Chapter 2 Foreign Exchange Parity Relations

Chapter 2 Foreign Exchange Parity Relations Chapter 2 Foreign Exchange Parity Relations Note: In the sixth edition of Global Investments, the exchange rate quotation symbols differ from previous editions. We adopted the convention that the first

More information

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data Nicolas Parent, Financial Markets Department It is now widely recognized that greater transparency facilitates the

More information

Economics 430 Handout on Rational Expectations: Part I. Review of Statistics: Notation and Definitions

Economics 430 Handout on Rational Expectations: Part I. Review of Statistics: Notation and Definitions Economics 430 Chris Georges Handout on Rational Expectations: Part I Review of Statistics: Notation and Definitions Consider two random variables X and Y defined over m distinct possible events. Event

More information

Week 7 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Simulation Methods

Week 7 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Simulation Methods Week 7 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Simulation Methods Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ Christopher Ting : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 November

More information

Business Cycles II: Theories

Business Cycles II: Theories Macroeconomic Policy Class Notes Business Cycles II: Theories Revised: December 5, 2011 Latest version available at www.fperri.net/teaching/macropolicy.f11htm In class we have explored at length the main

More information

Relationships among Exchange Rates, Inflation, and Interest Rates

Relationships among Exchange Rates, Inflation, and Interest Rates Relationships among Exchange Rates, Inflation, and Interest Rates Chapter Objectives To explain the purchasing power parity (PPP) and international Fisher effect (IFE) theories, and their implications

More information

Rational Infinitely-Lived Asset Prices Must be Non-Stationary

Rational Infinitely-Lived Asset Prices Must be Non-Stationary Rational Infinitely-Lived Asset Prices Must be Non-Stationary By Richard Roll Allstate Professor of Finance The Anderson School at UCLA Los Angeles, CA 90095-1481 310-825-6118 rroll@anderson.ucla.edu November

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )] Problem set 1 Answers: 1. (a) The first order conditions are with 1+ 1so 0 ( ) [ 0 ( +1 )] [( +1 )] ( +1 ) Consumption follows a random walk. This is approximately true in many nonlinear models. Now we

More information

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN *

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN * SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN * Abstract - This paper reexamines the results of my 1974 paper on Social Security and saving with the help

More information

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Behzad Diba University of Bern April 2012 (Institute) Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background April 2012 1 / 19 Research Areas Research on fiscal policy typically

More information

14.471: Fall 2012: Recitation 12: Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution (EIS)

14.471: Fall 2012: Recitation 12: Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution (EIS) 14.471: Fall 2012: Recitation 12: Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution (EIS) Daan Struyven December 6, 2012 1 Hall (1987) 1.1 Goal, test and implementation challenges Goal: estimate the EIS σ (the

More information

Jacek Prokop a, *, Ewa Baranowska-Prokop b

Jacek Prokop a, *, Ewa Baranowska-Prokop b Available online at www.sciencedirect.com Procedia Economics and Finance 1 ( 2012 ) 321 329 International Conference On Applied Economics (ICOAE) 2012 The efficiency of foreign borrowing: the case of Poland

More information

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting [Forthcoming, American Economic Review] Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting by Steinar Holden Department of Economics University of Oslo Box 1095 Blindern, 0317 Oslo, Norway email: steinar.holden@econ.uio.no

More information

Petrodollars, the Savings Bust, and the U.S. Current Account Deficit

Petrodollars, the Savings Bust, and the U.S. Current Account Deficit GLOBAL PERSPECTIVES Petrodollars, the Savings Bust, and the U.S. Current Account Deficit March 2007 International finance is a fascinating but challenging subject with many moving Richard H. Clarida Global

More information

Establishing and Maintaining a Firm Nominal Anchor

Establishing and Maintaining a Firm Nominal Anchor Establishing and Maintaining a Firm Nominal Anchor Andrew Levin International Monetary Fund A key practical challenge for monetary policy is to gauge the extent to which the private sector perceives the

More information

Introduction Dickey-Fuller Test Option Pricing Bootstrapping. Simulation Methods. Chapter 13 of Chris Brook s Book.

Introduction Dickey-Fuller Test Option Pricing Bootstrapping. Simulation Methods. Chapter 13 of Chris Brook s Book. Simulation Methods Chapter 13 of Chris Brook s Book Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ Christopher Ting : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 April 26, 2017 Christopher

More information

In understanding the behavior of aggregate demand we must take a close look at its individual components: Figure 1, Aggregate Demand

In understanding the behavior of aggregate demand we must take a close look at its individual components: Figure 1, Aggregate Demand The Digital Economist Lecture 4 -- The Real Economy and Aggregate Demand The concept of aggregate demand is used to understand and measure the ability, and willingness, of individuals and institutions

More information

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence Journal of Money, Investment and Banking ISSN 1450-288X Issue 5 (2008) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2008 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New

More information

REGULATORY CAPITAL ON INSURERS ASSET ALLOCATION & TIME HORIZONS OF THEIR GUARANTEES

REGULATORY CAPITAL ON INSURERS ASSET ALLOCATION & TIME HORIZONS OF THEIR GUARANTEES DAEFI Philippe Trainar May 16, 2006 REGULATORY CAPITAL ON INSURERS ASSET ALLOCATION & TIME HORIZONS OF THEIR GUARANTEES As stressed by recent developments in economic and financial analysis, optimal portfolio

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus) Volume 35, Issue 1 Exchange rate determination in Vietnam Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus) Abstract This study investigates the determinants of the exchange rate in Vietnam and suggests policy

More information

Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are

Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are Anna Naszodi 1 Engel and West (2005) argue that the discount factor, provided it is high enough, can be blamed for the failure of the empirical

More information

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress Order Code RS21409 Updated March 24, 2005 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web The Budget Deficit and the Trade Deficit: What Is Their Relationship? Summary Marc Labonte and Gail Makinen

More information

Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem

Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem Owen Zidar Blanchard and Summers NBER Macro Annual 1986 Macro Lunch January 30, 2013 Owen Zidar (Macro Lunch) Hysteresis January 30, 2013 1 / 47 Questions

More information

IMPACT OF SOME OVERSEAS MONETARY VARIABLES ON INDONESIA: SVAR APPROACH

IMPACT OF SOME OVERSEAS MONETARY VARIABLES ON INDONESIA: SVAR APPROACH DE G DE GRUYTER OPEN IMPACT OF SOME OVERSEAS MONETARY VARIABLES ON INDONESIA: SVAR APPROACH Ahmad Subagyo STIE GICI BUSINESS SCHOOL, INDONESIA Armanto Witjaksono BINA NUSANTARA UNIVERSITY, INDONESIA date

More information

The papers and comments presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of

The papers and comments presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Preface The papers and comments presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis s Tenth Annual Economic Conference are contained in this book. The topic of this conference, held on October 12 13, 1985,

More information

Review of the literature on the comparison

Review of the literature on the comparison Review of the literature on the comparison of price level targeting and inflation targeting Florin V Citu, Economics Department Introduction This paper assesses some of the literature that compares price

More information

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

CFA Level II - LOS Changes CFA Level II - LOS Changes 2018-2019 Topic LOS Level II - 2018 (465 LOS) LOS Level II - 2019 (471 LOS) Compared Ethics 1.1.a describe the six components of the Code of Ethics and the seven Standards of

More information

Discussion of The Role of Expectations in Inflation Dynamics

Discussion of The Role of Expectations in Inflation Dynamics Discussion of The Role of Expectations in Inflation Dynamics James H. Stock Department of Economics, Harvard University and the NBER 1. Introduction Rational expectations are at the heart of the dynamic

More information

ANALYSES OF MODEL DERIVED IS LM,

ANALYSES OF MODEL DERIVED IS LM, ANALYSES OF MODEL DERIVED ISLM, AGGREGATE DEMANDAGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND BP CURVES* The group of the EPA World Model Economic Research Institute Economic Planning Agency * This paper was presented at the

More information