Futures Contracts Rates as Monetary Policy Forecasts

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Futures Contracts Rates as Monetary Policy Forecasts"

Transcription

1 Futures Contracts Rates as Monetary Policy Forecasts by G. Ferrero and A. Nobili Bank of Italy, Economic Research Department (This version: October 2005) JEL classification: E43, E44, E58. Keywords: futures rates, monetary policy, risk-premium. Abstract Many central banks currently use futures contracts rates to assess financial markets expectations about future monetary policy. We provide evidence that futures contracts rates are upward biased forecasts of short-term interest rates. The resulting ex-post excess returns, that are predictable using business cycle indicators, are procyclical in the euro area and countercyclical in the United States. We also show that they embody two different components: the effective ex-ante risk premium required by the investor at the moment of futures price settlement and the ex-post systematic forecast error, which is related to the expectation formation process. We find this second component to be more important in explaining overall excess returns in the euro area, while in the United States the riskpremium dominates. These results have important policy implications for central banks in assessing the efficacy of their communication and transparency of the monetary policy strategy. 1 Introduction As short-term interest rates are to a large extent influenced by monetary authority decisions, financial markets provide useful information regarding expectations of future monetary policy stance. This information plays also an important role for central banks in order to check the efficacy of the communication, as well as the transparency of the strategy. 1 Recent studies for the United States have compared the information content of several financial instruments, finding that yield curves and futures contracts on short-term interest rates are useful predictors of the path of monetary policy decisions both in the short and medium run. 2 Among these, Gurkaynak, Sack and Swanson (2004) showed that federal funds futures rates perform better at shorter forecast horizons, while futures contracts rates on eurodollar deposits are so far the best predictors at forecast horizons over six months. Using asset prices and derivatives to assess future monetary policy has some advantages with respect to other techniques, such as VARs, DSGE models or ARIMAs. First, there is no issue of forecasting model 1 What do markets expect about the future course of monetary policy? The question is important to policymakers, not because we are concerned necessarily that we should meet the market s expectations but as a check on the efficacy of our communication, speech of governor Ben Bernanke at the Society of Analysts for Investments of Chicago held on April 15th See Gurkaynak, Sack and Swanson (2004) and Piazzesi and Swanson (2004a, 2004b). 1

2 selection (e.g. there is no need to fully specify an equilibrium model); second, forecasts are based on real-time rather than revised data; third, under the rational expectations hypothesis market participants use all information available at the moment that the contract is settled. 3 Finally, with respect to other measures of market agents expectations, such as survey data, they are available on a more frequent basis. Nevertheless, some caution is required in evaluating the predictive power of quoted futures rates. Given the aversion to risk of market participants, futures rates will also reflect both a risk and a term premium. Such premia may distort the information embodied in forward rates. A number of papers (e.g. Krueger and Kuttner 1996, Sack 2002 and Durham 2003) provided evidence of such distortions for the United States, showing that short-term interest rates implied in futures contracts are upward biased estimators of ex post realized spot rates. In addition, Piazzesi and Swanson (2004) show, for the US economy, that these positive excess returns are time-varying and predictable by means of business cycle indicators, such as nonfarm payroll employment, yield spreads and corporate bond spreads. These findings are consistent with the failure of the expectations hypothesis in its stronger version, according to which, excess returns should not be predictable. In this paper we provided new evidence on the information content of futures rates for the euro area, allowing for a comparison with the United States. Ex-post excess returns computed on euro area short-term interest rates are found to be positive, time-varying and, differently from the United States, procyclical. Therefore, in the euro area, futures rates adjusted for the time-varying excess return are, on average, better predictors during booms than in recessions, as opposed to the United States. Previous literature on adjusted measures of futures rates, such as Piazzesi and Swanson (2004), uses the label risk premium to refer to predictable excess returns on the short-term interest rate, without taking any particular stance on their structural interpretation. We analyze more in detail ex-post excess returns and show that they can be divided into two components. The first is the ex-ante risk premium required by the investors at the moment of buying or selling the financial contract. The second is the ex-post systematic forecast error, which is independent from the financial instrument considered and provides information about the efficacy of the monetary policy communication and the transparency of policy decisions. Excess returns decomposition has important implications for central banks. Even if futures rates adjusted for both components are the best interest rates forecasts, they do not coincide anymore with financial markets view. In order to correctly assess market expectations about the future path of monetary 3 For example, Krueger e Kuttner (1996) showed that, in the United States, forecasts based on federal funds futures rates are efficent, in the sense that the resulting forecast errors are not significantly correlated with any other variable known to the agents at the moment they establish the futures contract price. 2

3 policy, quoted futures rates should be adjusted only by the risk premium, as the sistematic prediction error reflects part of the expectations formation process. Our empirical analysis shows that both components are predictable and positively correlated with the business cycle in the euro area. Systematic prediction errors are by far more important in explaining overall excess returns at horizons up to one year and a half, even if they tended to decline significantly over recent years. A similar decomposition for the United States leads to opposite results. Both components are found to be predictable and countercyclical, but, risk-premia represent by far the larger fraction of whole ex-post excess returns. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we provide evidence on the size and predictability of ex-post excess returns computed on short-term interest rates futures for the euro area, allowing a comparison with the United States. In section 3 we show how to decompose ex-post realized excess returns, while in section 4 we point out the main implications for central banks. Section 5 presents some concluding remarks. 2 Forecasting excess returns on short-term interest rates 2.1 Constant excess returns In this section we check whether futures contracts rates are unbiased predictors of the euro area short-term interest rates during the period from January 1992 to December We restrict our attention to daily yields on futures contracts traded on the London International Financial Futures Exchange (LIFFE), which have quarterly maturities, extending out to 18 months. In particular, for the pre-emu period ( ), we select contracts based on the spot three-month LIBOR euromark time deposits, while, for the EMU period ( ), we consider contracts based on the spot three-month Euribor. 4 This choice reflects the idea that the corresponding interest rates underlying the contracts basically account for the monetary policy stance in the considered sample period. Therefore, let f (n) t denote the interest rate on a futures contract quoted at quarter t with expiration occurring at quarter t+n. Letalsor t+n denote the corresponding realized spot three-month interest rate prevailing on the day of expiration of the future contract. We define the ex-post excess return realized 4 We focus on the March, June, September and December futures contracts, which are by far the most actively traded. The expiration on these contracts is around the third tuesday of the third month of the indicated quarter. 3

4 from holding the n-quarter-ahead contract to maturity as x (n) t+n = f (n) t r t+n. (1) Under the expectations hypothesis (in its stronger formulation) and under the assumption of a riskneutral representative agent, in absence of arbitrage opportunities, futures rates coincide with the expected future spot interest rates; therefore the realized excess returns are just equal to the forecast errors made by market participants and should be, on average, equal to zero. Figure 1 shows the excess return on futures contracts on 3 month euribor, expiring after 3, 6, 9, 12, 15 and 18 months. The ex-post differences between the implied expected rate and the realized spot interest rate are, on average, positive and increase with the forecast horizon. To check whether the mean excess return has been significantly different from zero and, therefore, to reject the expectation hypothesis in its stronger version, we run the following regressions for the forecast horizons n =3, 6, 9, 12, 15, 18 5 x (n) t+n = α(n) + (n) t+n. (2) We summarize results in Table 1(A). The average ex-post realized excess returns is significantly positive over the considered sample period, ranging from 10 to 120 basis points in the euro area; in addition, longer-horizon contracts have larger excess returns. Buying the four-quarter-ahead contract and holding it to maturity is a strategy that generates an excess return of 70 basis points per year on average, 7 time bigger than buying and holding to maturity the one-quarter-ahead contract. Similar conclusions are reached in the corresponding analysis for the United States, using the eurodollar futures contacts rates traded on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange, which are settle based on the spot three-month LIBOR eurodollar time deposit rate (Figure 2; see also Piazzesi and Swanson, 2004). In order to compare the size of the excess returns, in Table 1(B) we report the results of the regressions (2) for the United States, in the same sample period. Average excess return has been significantly positive and larger than those of the euro area at all forecast horizons considered. Precisely, it has been greater on average by 10 basis points at shorter horizons (up to 6 months) and by 20 basis points at longer ones (from 9 up to 18 quarters). 5 Standard errors are computed by means of the Newey-West heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent procedure, in order to take into account the futures contract overlap. 4

5 2.2 Time varying excess returns We have obtained our previous results under the assumption that excess returns are constant over time. Now we allowexcess returns to be time-varying and check wether they can be predicted by means of business cycle indicators. We run the following regressions x (n) t+n = α (n) + β (n) y (c) t + (n) t+n (3) where y (c) t is the business cycle component of the euro area real GDP growth rates 6. The estimated coefficients for the euro area suggest that excess returns are time-varying and significantly procyclical at forecast horizons longer than six months (Table 2A) 7. Splitting the sample between periods of booms and recessions, we notice that excess returns are about 1.5 to 2.5 times lower in recessions than they are on average in expansions; precisely, in the former case, excess returns are about 16, 42 and 75 basis points, respectively, at the forecast horizons of 6, 12 and 18 months; in the latter, they are about 35, 107 and 184 basis points at the same horizons. On the contrary, for the United States, in the same sample period, excess returns are significantly countercyclical; in recessions they are about 1.5 to 3 times larger than in other periods (see Table 2b). At forecast horizons of 6, 12 and 18 months they are, respectively, about 65, 125 and 160 basis points in recession, while they are about 20, 70 and 125 during expansions. As official real GDP data are frequently revised and usually released with different delays in the two regions, these results may be affected by the differences on the information set available to market participants at the moment that contract prices are settled. Therefore, we investigate the predictability of the excess returns running regressions of the form x (n) t+n = α (n) + β (n) z t + γ (n) f (n) t + (n) t+n (4) where z t is a business cycle proxy known to operators in real time and not subject to ex-post revisions. 8 In particular, we select two different sets of variables: first, we use (one at the time) the year-on-year change 6 The business cycle component is extracted by means of a Band Pass filter a la Baxter and King (1996). We select frequencies between 6 and 40 quarters and set up the control size of symmetric moving average equal to 8. All results outlined in this section are robust to the use of alternative filters, such as a Band-Pass (8,32,8) or a Hodrick-Prescott (1600) one. 7 We notice that the size of the business cycle component of real GDP in the sample period is ranging between 0,1 and 1,8 in economic expansions, while, between -0,1 and -2,1 in recessions. 8 The estimated regressions also include the futures rate itself as additional predictor. It would represent a scale variable, based on the idea that the excess returns are lower when the level of interest rates is lower, and vice versa. Results suggest that this variable is not significant at forecast horizons up to 6 months, while at longer horizons the estimated coefficients are significantly positive. 5

6 of the percentage balances referring to the replies collected in the surveys of the European Commission for the manufacturing industry, consumers, the construction and the retail trade sectors 9.Asallthesedata are not released until the last week of the month, in order to perform predictive regressions in real-time, we use those referring to the second month of the indicated quarter. As an alternative, we use the time series for real GDP growth rate expectations measured by the quarterly Consensus Forecasts survey. These variables, by definition, do not depend on future monetary policy shock realizations, therefore, they can be considered contemporaneously predetermined in the corresponding predictive regressions of type (4), avoiding problems of spurious correlations. 10 In Table 3a we only report the results obtained using as predictive regressor the employment expectations for the months ahead collected in the survey of manifacturing industry, as we find this variable to have the best properties in terms of significance and goodness of fit (higher values for the statistic R 2 ) among the entire set of potential explanatory variables. The slope coefficients confirm the view that the excess returns are positively correlated with the business cycle in the euro area; precisely, they are significantly positive and increase with the forecast horizon. The fitted values imply that estimated excess returns are ranging between 15 and 170 basis points, on average, during expansions, while they are between 5 and 70 basis points during recessions. In particular, at a one-year horizon they are, respectively around 100 and 35 basis points. Similar results are obtained using the other business cycle indicators (see Table A3 of the Appendix). In general, among the entire set of variables, we find confidence indicators collected from the survey in the manifacturing industry, as well as the expectations on future real GDP by Consensus Economics, to be good candidates for excess returns predictive regressions. 11 In Table 3b we report the results of the regression (5) fortheunitedstates,inthesamesampleperiod, using the quarterly year-on-year change in nonfarm payrolls as business cycle indicator, as suggested by Piazzesi and Swanson (2004). 12 The countercyclicity of the U.S. excess return is still confirmed, but, 9 For each survey we consider separately the overall index and the components one by one, because some of them may have better indicator properties than their corresponding overall index. In order to screen a narrower set of variables among the large amount of available survey data, we performed a preliminary cross correlation analysis at business cycle frequencies between each of them and real GDP. This roughly search allowed us to select the leading and coincident indicators and drop the lagging ones. When a variable is found to be leading by n quarters, we compared the results obtained by including this variable as lagged (by up to n lags) or contemporaneous. 10 As suggested by Piazzesi and Swanson (2004) for the United States, we also checked for the predictive power of some term spreads. We find weak leading properties of term spreads for forecasting the euro area short-term interest rates, in line with some previous studies. Davis and Fagan (1997), Berg and Van Bergejik (2000) and Nicoletti-Altimari (2001), found that the slope of the yield curve has no marginal predictive content for output growth and inflation using bivariate regressions. Recently, Nobili (2005) argued that these results still hold in a multivariate context using bayesian VAR models with time-varying coefficients. 11 We also run alternative regressions including simultaneously two or more business cycle indicators as explanatory variables. Results in terms of both goodness of fit are very similar to those obtained using a single regressor and gains in out-of-sample forecast accuracy are tiny or negligible. 12 The authors also provide evidence about the significant predictive power of yield spreads and corporate bond spreads for U.S. excess returns. We do not report results obtained with alternative regressors in order to save space. We only notice 6

7 differently form Piazzesi and Swanson (2004) the magnitude of the slope coefficient increases with the forecast horizon. In recessions excess returns are higher by 1.2 to 1.8 times than in periods of booms. At a one-year horizon they are, respectively, about 100 and 70 basis points. Finally, we check the robustness of our results at shorter horizons (up to 9 quarters ahead) substituting the future-based excess returns with those implicit in the term structure of interest rates, both in euro and dollars. 13 Forward rates may embody different risk premia with respect to futures rates because of the nature of the underlying contracts. As futures contracts are marked to market every day, cash-flow movements connected with payments or withdrawing to reconstituite the collateral margins, may imply a spread between futures and forward rates. The terms of a forward contract are settled exclusively by the two parties, meaning that the buyer of the contract may face off asignificant credit risk; the size of credit risk implied in a futures contract can be supposed to be negligible beacuse of the role of the clearinghouse during the trade. The estimated coefficients are reported in Table A1 and A2 of the Appendix. Ex-post excess returns based on forward rates are still, on average, positive and significanlty different from zero both in the euro area and the United States; in addition, they seem to be higher than their counterparts based on futures rates at all forecast horizons considered. Regressions based on business cycle indicators provide further evidence on the prociclicity of excess returns in the euro area and counterciclicity in the United States. Remarkably, the magnitude of the slope coefficients is close to the one obtained using futures rates. 2.3 Forecasts accuracy In the previous sections we have seen that excess returns are significantly different from zero, time-varying and predictable by means of business cicle indicators. Now, we investigate the gains in out-of-sample forecast accuracy using adjusted futures rates. The design of the experiment is based on rolling endpoint regressions. An initial estimate of excess returns at the different horizons is obtained using the sample period 1992q1-1993q4; we use the estimate to compute a set of out-of-sample forecasts for future interest rates up to 18 months E t (i t+n )=f (n) t E t (bx (n) t+n). (5) that, despite the euro area, expectations on future U.S. real GDP growth rates collected from Consensus Forecasts survey seem to be not a good candidate in the sample period we considered. 13 Precisely, the 3-months forward rate prevailing n-quarters ahead can be computed as fw (n) t = r (n) t r (n 1) t where r (n) t is the yield of a risk-free bond quoted at time t and expiring t + n quarters ahead. Due to the lack in financial markets of bonds expiring from 15 to 18 quarters ahead,we cannot build directly 3-months forward rates prevailing at horizons over 9 quarters. An alternative could be offered by the interpolation method developed by Nelson and Siegel. 7

8 Then, we add a new observation and repeat the forecasting exercise, until the end of the sample period. Overall we collect a set of 44 out-of-sample predictions at each forecast horizon. In Table 4 we report some summary statistics on forecast accuracy, such as the mean error (ME) and the root-mean-squared error (RMSE). We perform a Diebold-Mariano test, in order to check whether the errors obtained under the adjusted predictions are significantly different from their counterparts obtained with unadjusted futures rates. 14 For completeness, we allow a comparison with the forecasting performance of some alternative techniques used in the literature, namely, a random walk, an ARIMA and a Bayesian VAR. 15 For the euro area, unadjusted future rates tend to predict short-term interest rates better than the three alternative competitors only at shorter horizons (up to two quarters ahead), while at longer ones they perform relatively poorly. 16 Constant-adjusted futures rates already produce lower root-mean-squared errors at all forecast horizons, even if the gains in forecast accuracy are small and often not significant. Adjusting futures rates for the business cycle improves further our predictions: the associated squared errors are, on average, lower by an amount that increases with the forecast horizon and ranges between 10 and 45 per cent with respect to unadjusted futures rates. For the United States the picture is similar. Unadjusted futures rates strongly outperform the alternative models up to two quarters ahead but generate larger squared forecast errors at longer horizons. Correcting market forecasts for the predictable components of the excess returns leads to gains in predictive accuracy, which are significantly larger when we adjust for time-varying component (the RMSE is between 20 and 50 per cent lower than under the unadjusted futures rates). Notice that these gains are, on average, larger for the United States than in the euro area, at all forecast horizons. This result may depend on the fact that excess returns are countercyclical in the former and procyclical in the latter. Indeed, during expansions, futures adjusted for the time-varying excess return subtract, in addition to the constant term, a positive component from the quoted future in the euro area, while they add it in the United States. The opposite occurs in recessions: business cycle 14 See Diebold and Mariano (2002). This test statistic is essentially a t-statistic in a regression of the differences in the root-mean-squared errors for two alternative forecasts on a constant term. 15 Specifically, we set trivariate domestic BVAR models comprising the short-term interest rate, the inflation rate (based on the HCPI index for the euro area and the CPI index for the U. S.) and a measure of real economic activity (employment expectations in the manufactoring sector for the euro area and nonfarm payrolls for the U.S.). In order to perform a real-time forecasting exercise, for the last two variables we used their year-on-year changes referring to the second month of the indicated quarter. 16 Notice that, the ARIMA model seems to produce better forecasts than the BVAR. This result in part confirms the view that more sophisticated model are not good candidate forecasts for euro area short-term interest rates. Recently Neri and Secchi (2004) found that the predictions of the euro area short-term interest rates (computed as quarterly averages of daily data) up to four quarters ahead provided by unadjusted futures rates strongly outperform those derived by means of a simple DSGE model and a BVAR-DSGE approach a la Del Negro and Schorfheide (2004). On the contrary, at longer horizons the forecasting performances of these competitor models become very similar and not far from those obtained using a naive random walk. 8

9 adjusted forecasts subtract a negative term from the futures rates in the United States, while they add an equivalent one in the euro area. As a result, squared errors are lower in booms (recessions) than in recessions (booms) in the euro area (United States). Table 5 shows that gains in forecast accuracy in expansion periods in the euro area and in recessions in the United States are on average by about the same amount (respectively 41 and 48 basis points). On the contrary, in periods of expansions in the US and recessions in the euro area - when adjusted forecasts are less accurate in both countries - the corresponding gains are larger in the former. 3 Excess returns decomposition The existing literature on risk-adjusted measures of financial instruments uses the term risk premium to refer to the predictable excess return on the short-term interest rate. In this section we ask whether it is possible to identify the risk premia with the predictable excess returns of the previous sections. We start by assuming that the ex-post excess return realized from holding the n-quarter-ahead contract to maturity can be separated in two different components: x (n) t+n = θ (n) t + σ (n) t+n (6) where and θ (n) t = f (n) t E(i t+n I t ) (7) σ (n) t+n = E (i t+n I t ) i t+n (8) The first, θ (n) t,representstheex-ante risk-premium required by the investors at the moment they settle the futures contract price. It is defined as the difference between the futures contract rate and the market s expectation about future short-term interest rate, conditionally to the information set available to the agents. The second, σ (n) t+n,defined as the difference between the conditional expectation on future rate and the ex-post realized spot rate, represents an ex-post systematic forecast error which is not linked to the nature of the financial contract. The assessment of this second component is a relevant issue in terms of credibility and transparency of the monetary policy. Being this part of the excess return connected to the process of formation of expectations, it is clearly affected by the efficacy of communication and it can represent a measure of how monetary policy decisions are perceived by market agents. 9

10 The main difference between E(i t+n I t ) and f (n) t is that the former is a measure of expectations that is not related directly to any financial contract and therefore should not include neither risk nor liquidity premium. As a proxy for E(i t+n I t ) we use three different measures that can be considered, by definiton, as cleared by the ex-ante risk premium. Precisely, we consider the time series of professional forecasters expectations on future short-term interest rate collected in the survey by Consensus Forecasts, the forecasts obtained with the ARIMA model and those resulting from a BVAR. In Tables 6 we report estimates of the two identified components by running the following regressions σ (n) t+n = α (n) σ + (n) t+n (9) θ (n) t = α (n) θ + η (n) t. Note that, by construction, the sum of the two estimated components, bα (n) σ the same amount of the estimated constant excess return reported in Table 1 (bα (n) ). and bα (n) θ,hastobeby The decompositions implied by the different proxies provide similar results. In the euro area, the computed systematic prediction errors are significant at all forecast horizons and, on average, much larger than the corresponding risk premia. When we use interest rates expectations obtained from Consensus Forecasts, the ex-ante risk premium ranges from 5 to 30 basis points, while the systematic prediction error is between 5 and 95 basis points. Therefore the latter component accounts by about 70 per cent of the overall predictable excess returns, at horizons larger than 3 months. The presence of large systematic prediction errors implies the violation of the rational expectations hypothesis and may be explained with learning phenomena connected to structural changes in the economy, as the process of convergence to EMU. For the United States opposite results arise. Risk premia are significantly positive and much larger than the corresponding systematic errors at all forecast horizons. Precisely, they represent a fraction of overall excess returns, which is decreasing with the forecast horizon and ranges between 90 and 60 per cent. In order to investigate the business cycle properties and the predictability of the two components σ (n) t+n and θ (n) t, we report in Table 7 the estimates of the following regressions σ (n) t+n = α (n) σ θ (n) t = α (n) θ + β (n) σ + β (n) θ 10 z t + γ (n) σ z t + γ (n) θ f (n) t f (n) t + (n) t+n (10) + η (n) t

11 Intheeuroareabothcomponentsareprocyclical. The empirical evidence that the difference between the conditional expectations on future rates and the ex-post realized spot rates is bigger in periods of economic expansions could be interpreted as exuberance phenomena: market agents tend to over-estimate future economic conditions when they face booms and underestimate them in periods of recessions. Precisely, ex-post systematic errors are during expansions higher by an amount ranging between 60 and 70 basis points at horizons over one year. In the United States both risk premia and systematic errors are instead found to be countercyclical, as the overall excess return. 4 Assessing monetary policy expectations Results outlined in the previous section have important implications for the central banks. Even if futures rates adjusted for both the risk premium and the systematic prediction error are the best predictors of future monetary policy decisions, they do not coincide anymore with financial markets expectations. Therefore, the correct assessment of financial markets view about the path of monetary policy should be conducted by policymakers using quoted futures rates adjusted only by risk premia, as systematic forecast errors represent part of agents expectations formation process. The spread between risk-adjusted futures rates and spot interest rates can be considered an ex-post measure of the efficacy of monetary authorities communication, as well as the transparency of their policy strategy. In order to provide some practical examples, we compare the term structure of interest rates implied in adjusted and unadjusted futures rates 17 with the ex-post realized pattern of spot rates over time, on two illustrative dates. In the upper panel of Figure 3 we report euro area short-term interest rates forecasts on September On that date, the spot three-month interest rate was close to 3.75 per cent and the euro area was experiencing an expansion phase. Therefore, according to the quoted futures prices, the short-term interest rates were expected to gradually rise in the subsequent periods, reaching a value of 4.5 per cent. As the ex-post realized spot rate declined at 2.75 per cent, futures based forecasts were very misleading on that date. Notice that both constant-adjusted and overall-adjusted futures rates would have implied more accuarate forecasts, but market agents view about future monetary policy signalled rising interest rates because of the large systematic prediction error. 17 Precisely, using z t and f (n) t as predictive regressors, we derive the implied forecasts on the short-term interest rates as E t (i t+n )=f (n) t (bα (n) OLS + β b (n) OLS z t + bγ (n) OLS f (n) t ). 11

12 On the other hand, the lower panel suggests that, in March 2002, when the United States faced a slowdown of real economic activity, futures rates signaled a gradual and persistent rise of future interest rates over time, by about 100 basis points within one year and a half, while the spot rate pattern was declining. Both constant and overall-djusted futures rates implied stable interest rate, consistently with financial markets expectations. 5 Concluding remarks In this paper, we provided new evidence that futures contracts rates are biased forecasts of future shortterm interest rates. We found large and time-varying excess returns on three-months interest rates futures in the euro area, confirming the results obtained by Piazzesi and Swanson (2004) for the United States. We find that, excess returns are predictable using business cycle indicators avaialble to market participants in real-time, in both regions, but they are procyclical in the euro area and countercyclical in the United States. Therefore, futures rates adjusted for the time-varying excess returns generate lower prediction errors in the euro area during booms and in the United States during recessions. We also showed that ex-post excess returns can be divided into two different components. The first is the effective ex-ante risk premium required by the investors at the moment of buying or selling the financial contract. The second is the ex-post systematic forecast error, which is independent from the financial instrument considered and provides useful information about the efficacy of the monetary policy communication and the transparency of policy decisions. The empirical analysis reveals that both components are predictable and positively correlated with the business cycle in the euro area. Among them, the systematic prediction error was by far more important in explaining overall excess returns, suggesting the presence of both exuberance and lerning phenomena. A similar decomposition for the United States leads, instead, to opposite results. The two identified components are both countercyclical and the risk-premium represents by far the larger fraction of the overall excess return. From the point of view of the central bank, the main implication is that a correct assessement of market agents expectations about the path of monetary policy should be conducted using quoted futures rates adjusted only for the risk premium, as the sistematic prediction error represents part of the expectation formation process. Indeed, futures rates adjusted for both components are better forecasts of future monetary policy actions but they do not coincide anymore with finanacial markets view. 12

13 Table 1 EX-POST CONSTANT EXCESS RETURNS (A) EURO AREA n α (n) 9.8** 24.3** 45.5** 70.8** 96.7** 122.7** (2.5) (2.8) (3.2) (3.4) (3.7) (4.0) R (B) UNITED STATES n α (n) 17.9** 39.5** 63.9** 89.9** 116.3** 138.9** (2.9) (2.9) (2.9) (2.7) (2.7) (2.7) R Notes: the sample period is 1992:1-2004:4. Excess returns are measured in basis points. Estimation by OLS. Newey-West HAC t-statistics are reported in parentheses. denotes significance at 10 per cent confidence level. denotes significance at 5 per cent confidence level. 13

14 EX-POST TIME-VARYING EXCESS RETURNS AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE Table 2 (A) EURO AREA n α (n) 9.7** 24.2** 45.6** 71.5** 97.9** 124.1** (2.6) (2.9) (3.4) (3.8) (4.2) (6.5) β (n) * 36.8** 52.1** 62.5** (0.6) (1.3) (1.8) (2.3) (2.7) (3.5) R (B) UNITED STATES n α (n) 18.9** 41.6** 66.1** 91.5** 116.8** 138.8** (3.3) (3.3) (3.3) (3.0) (2.9) (3.8) β (n) -14.1** -29.5** -38.0** (-2.3) (-2.5) (-2.0) (-1.4) (-0.7) (-0.5) R Notes: the sample period is 1992:1-2004:4. Excess returns are measured in basis points. Estimation by OLS. Newey-West HAC t-statistics are reported in parentheses. denotes significance at 10 per cent confidence level. denotes significance at 5 per cent confidence level. 14

15 Table 3 EX-POST TIME-VARYING EXCESS RETURNS AND BUSINESS CYCLE INDICATORS (A) EURO AREA (employment expectations) n α (n) (0.8) (0.3) (-0.4) (-1.2) (-1.2) (-1.9) β (n) 0.5** 1.2** 1.9** 2.3** 2.5** 2.2** (2.9) (3.9) (4.6) (4.4) (4.0) (4.2) γ (n) * 0.12** 0.26** 0.38** 0.51** (0.8) (1.8) (3.0) (4.2) (3.4) (4.4) R (B) UNITED STATES (nonfarm payrolls) n α (n) -11.7** -60.0** ** ** ** ** (-1.1) (-3.3) (-3.8) (-4.6) (-4.0) (-4.3) β (n) -0.2** -0.6** -0.8** -1.1** -1.2** -1.2** (-4.5) (-7.7) (-9.0) (-9.1) (-7.8) (-7.7) γ (n) 0.2** 0.4** 0.6** 0.9** 1.1** 1.3** (3.6) (6.1) (6.5) (6.9) (5.8) (6.3) R Notes: the sample period is 1992:1-2004:4. Excess returns, nonfarm payroll employment growth and futures rates are measured in basis points. Estimation by OLS. Newey-West HAC t-statistics are reported in parentheses. denotes significance at 10 per cent confidence level. denotes significance at 5 per cent confidence level. 15

16 Table 4a OUT-OF-SAMPLE FORECASTS OF SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES EURO AREA futures rates based unadjusted constant business cycle adjusted adjusted n ME RMSE ME RMSE ME RMSE alternative models based random walk ARIMA BVAR Consensus n ME RMSE ME RMSE ME RMSE ME RMSE Notes: the sample period used for the out-of-sample exercise is 1994:1-2004:4. ME is the Mean Error, RMSE is the Root-Mean-Squared Error, expressed in basis points. and are referred to the results of a Diebold-Mariano test; they denote the rejection of the null hypothesis that there is no difference in the forecasting precision between the indicated model and the unadjusted futures, at a significance level, respectively, of 10 and 5 per cent. 16

17 Table 4b OUT-OF-SAMPLE FORECASTS OF SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES UNITED STATES futures rates based unadjusted constant business cycle adjusted adjusted n ME RMSE ME RMSE ME RMSE alternative models based random walk ARIMA BVAR Consensus n ME RMSE ME RMSE ME RMSE ME RMSE Notes: the sample period used for the out-of-sample exercise is 1994:1-2004:4. ME is the Mean Error, RMSE is the Root-Mean-Squared Error, expressed in basis points. and are referred to the results of a Diebold-Mariano test; they denote the rejection of the null hypothesis that there is no difference in the forecasting precision between the indicated model and the unadjusted futures, at a significance level, respectively, of 10 and 5 per cent. 17

18 Table 5 GAINS IN FORECAST ACCURACY AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE EURO AREA n expansions recessions average UNITED STATES n expansions recessions average Notes: gains in forecast accuracy are computed as the differences in the Root-Mean- Squared Errors between forecasts obtained using business cycle-adjusted futures rates and those using constant-adjusted futures rates (expressed in basis points). 18

19 CONSTANT EXCESS RETURN DECOMPOSITION (A) EURO AREA α (n) θ α (n) σ Table 6 α (n) n ARIMA BVAR Consensus ARIMA BVAR Consensus ** 14.5** ** ** 29.7** 17.6* 24.3** ** 44.8** 35.0** 45.5** ** 59.9* 55.3** 70.8** * 77.1** 73.1* 73.0** 96.7** ** 91.2** 86.2* 94.3** 122.7** α (n) θ (B) UNITED STATES α (n) σ α (n) n ARIMA BVAR Consensus ARIMA BVAR Consensus ** 15.0** 38.7** ** 17.9** ** 34.4** 46.7** ** ** 57.9** 57.3** ** ** 81.7** 66.4** ** ** 105.7** 78.1** ** ** 125.7** 87.2** ** Notes: the sample period is 1992:1-2004:4. Excess returns are measured in basis points. Estimation by OLS. t-test are based on Newey-West HAC t-statistics. denotes significance at 10 per cent confidence level. denotes significanceat5percentconfidence level. 19

20 Table 7a TIME-VARYING EXCESS RETURN DECOMPOSITION - EURO AREA (employment expectations) n α (n) θ (0.8) (0.2) (-0.2) (-0.8) (-0.9) (-1.2) β (n) θ ** 0.9** 1.0** 1.0** 0.8* (1.5) (2.0) (2.0) (2.2) (2.1) (1.9) γ (n) θ * (-0.2) (0.3) (0.7) (1.2) (1.3) (1.9) R n α (n) σ (-0.1) (0.1) (-0.1) (-0.7) (-0.8) (-1.3) β (n) σ ** 1.3** 1.5** 1.4** (0.7) (1.3) (2.3) (2.7) (2.8) (2.7) γ (n) σ ** 0.27** 0.36** (0.6) (0.7) (1.4) (2.5) (2.6) (3.3) R Notes: the sample period is 1992:1-2004:4. Excess returns are measured in basis points. Estimation by OLS. Newey-West HAC t-statistics are reported in parentheses. denotes significance at 10 per cent confidence level. denotes significance at 5 per cent confidence level. 20

21 Table 7b TIME-VARYING EXCESS RETURN DECOMPOSITION - UNITED STATES (nonfarm payrolls) n α (n) θ ** -75.2** ** ** (0.2) (-1.6) (-2.3) (-3.9) (-4.2) (-6.0) β (n) θ * -0.16** -0.18** -0.18** (0.6) (-0.9) (-1.6) (-2.2) (-2.5) (-2.9) γ (n) θ 0.08** 0.17** 0.24** 0.32** 0.39** 0.48** (2.3) (3.7) (4.6) (6.4) (7.3) (9.2) R n α (n) σ * -69.8* ** ** ** (-1.0) (-1.7) (-1.7) (-2.3) (-2.1) (-2.2) β (n) σ -0.26** -0.54** -0.73** -0.95** -1.05** -1.07** (-3.7) (-4.5) (-4.8) (-5.7) (-5.4) (-5.8) γ (n) σ ** 0.39** 0.58** 0.74** 0.80** (1.3) (2.6) (2.9) (3.5) (3.2) (3.5) R Notes: the sample period is 1992:1-2004:4. Excess returns are measured in basis points. Estimation by OLS. Newey-West HAC t-statistics are reported in parentheses. denotes significance at 10 per cent confidence level. denotes significance at 5 per cent confidence level. 21

22 Table A1 EX-POST EXCESS RETURNS BASED ON FORWARD RATES EURO AREA constant business cycle α (n) 14.4** 42.6** 44.4** 14.4** 42.5** 44.5** (4.0) (4.1) (3.0) (4.0) (4.2) (3.4) β (n) ** (0.6) (1.2) (2.5) γ (n) R employment expectations real GDP expectations α (n) (0.5) (-1.1) (-1.1) (1.4) (-0.6) (-0.2) β (n) 0.48** 1.16** 1.89** 9.46** 21.86** 38.92** (2.8) (3.6) (4.6) (2.2) (2.2) (3.3) γ (n) 0.25** 0.14** 0.16** ** 0.12* (1.8) (3.9) (4.2) (1.2) (4.2) (1.8) R Notes: the sample period is 1992:1-2004:4. Excess returns are measured in basis points. Estimation by OLS. Newey-West HAC t-statistics are reported in parentheses. denotes significance at 10 per cent confidence level. denotes significance at 5 per cent confidence level. 22

23 Table A2 EX-POST EXCESS RETURNS BASED ON FORWARD RATES UNITED STATES constant business cycle α (n) 26.7** 51.4** 82.5** 27.9** 53.7** 84.7** (4.1) (3.6) (3.7) (4.7) (4.2) (4.1) β (n) ** -31.7** -37.2** (-2.6) (-2.8) (-2.1) γ (n) R nonfarm payrolls real GDP expectations α (n) ** ** (-1.3) (-3.5) (-4.1) (0.7) (-0.1) (-0.5) β (n) -0.25** -0.61** -0.86** ** ** * (-4.5) (-7.5) (-8.9) (-3.0) (-2.9) (-1.9) γ (n) ** 0.66* 0.05* 0.12** 0.20** (4.1) (6.6) (7.1) (1.8) (2.2) (2.6) R Notes: the sample period is 1992:1-2004:4. Excess returns are measured in basis points. Estimation by OLS. Newey-West HAC t-statistics are reported in parentheses. denotes significance at 10 per cent confidence level. denotes significance at 5 per cent confidence level. 23

24 Table A3 TIME-VARYING EXCESS RETURNS AND BUSINESS CYCLE INDICATORS EURO AREA industrial confidence indicator (export order books) α (n) ** β (n) 0.46** 1.05** 1.63** 2.00** 2.13** 1.94** γ (n) ** 0.24** 0.36** 0.50** R industrial confidence indicator (overall index) α (n) ** β (n) 0.59** 1.33** 2.10** 2.70** 3.07** 3.02** γ (n) ** 0.27** 0.39** 0.52** R consumer confidence indicator (general economic situation over next 12 months) α (n) β (n) 0.43* 1.10** 1.49** 1.78** 1.66** 1.29 γ (n) * 0.22** 0.35** 0.50** R expected real GDP (Consensus Forecasts) α (n) β (n) 7.93* 23.48** 38.10** 46.17** 47.11** 41.43** γ (n) * 0.37** 0.51** R Notes: the sample period is 1992:1-2004:4. Excess returns are measured in basis points. The industrial confidence (both the overall index and the export book level) and the consumer confidence are measured in annual percentage changes based on the original percentage balances. The expected real GDP is the business cycle component of expected year-on-year growth rates, extracted by means of a Band-Pass filter considering cycles between 6 and 40 quarters and a size for the symmetric moving average equal to 8. All the regressors included in the estimated equations are lagged by one quarter. Estimation by OLS. Newey-West HAC t-statistics are reported in parentheses. denotes significance at 10 per cent confidence level. denotes significance at 5 per cent confidence level. 24

25 Ex-post excess returns on euro area futures contracts (basis points) Figure n= n= n= n= n= n=

26 Ex-post excess returns on U.S. futures contracts (basis points) Figure n= n= n= n= n= n=

27 Euro area short-term interest rates forecasts (19th September 1997) Figure unadjusted futures ex-post spot rates constant-adjusted risk-adjusted overall-adjusted 3m 6m 9m 12m 15m 18m United States short-term interest rates forecasts (18th March 2002) unadjusted futures ex-post spot rates constant-adjusted risk-adjusted overall-adjusted 3m 6m 9m 12m 15m 18m References [1] Baxter, M. and R. G. King (1995), Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate Band-Pass Filters for Economic Time Series, NBER Working Paper, No [2] Berk, J. M. and P. Van Bergeijk (2000), Is the Yield Curve a Useful Information Variable for the Eurosystem? European Central Bank, Working Paper Series, No

28 [3] Davis, E. P. and G. Fagan (1997), Are Financial Spreads Useful Indicators of Future Inflation and Output Growth in EU Countries, Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 12, No. 6, pp [4] Del Negro, M. and F. Schorfheide (2004), Priors from General Equilibrium Models for VARs, International Economic Review, Vol. 45, No. 2, pp [5] Diebold, F. X. and R. S. Mariano (2002), Comparing Predictive Accuracy, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 20, No. 1, pp [6] Durham, B. (2003), Estimates of the Term Premium on Near-Dated Federal Funds Futures Contracts, Federal Reserve Board, FED Working Paper, No. 19. [7] Gurkaynak Refet S., Sack B. and E. Swanson (2004), Market-Based Measures of Monetary Policy Expectations, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Monetary Affairs, mimeo. [8] Krueger, J. T. and K. N. Kuttner (1996), The Fed Funds Futures Rate as a Predictor of Federal Reserve Policy, Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 16, No. 8, pp [9] Kuttner, K. N. (2001), Monetary Policy Surprises and Interest Rates: Evidence from the Federal Funds Futures Market, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 47, No. 3, pp [10] Neri, S. and A. Secchi (2005), Bayesian Forecasting Models for the Euro Area: New Evidence on the Information Content of M3, Banca d Italia, mimeo. [11] Nicoletti-Altimari, S. (2001), Does Money Lead Inflation in the Euro Area?, European Central Bank, Working Paper Series, No. 63. [12] Nobili, A. (2005), Forecasting Output Growth and Inflation in the Euro Area: Are Financial Spreads Useful?, Banca d Italia, Temi di Discussione, No [13] Seppala, J. (2004) The Term Structure of Real Interest Rates: Theory and Evidence from UK Index-Linked Bonds, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 51, pp [14] Piazzesi, M. and E. Swanson (2004), Futures Prices as Risk-Adjusted Forecasts of Monetary Policy, NBER Working Paper, No [15] Rudebusch, G. D. (1998), Do Measures of Monetary Policy in a Var Make Sense?, International Economic Review, Vol. 39, No. 4, pp

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves issn 1936-5330 Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves Brent Bundick Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City First Version: October 2007 This Version: June 2008 RWP 07-08 Abstract Piazzesi and Swanson

More information

Macroeconomic announcements and implied volatilities in swaption markets 1

Macroeconomic announcements and implied volatilities in swaption markets 1 Fabio Fornari +41 61 28 846 fabio.fornari @bis.org Macroeconomic announcements and implied volatilities in swaption markets 1 Some of the sharpest movements in the major swap markets take place during

More information

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage: Economics Letters 108 (2010) 167 171 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Economics Letters journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolet Is there a financial accelerator in US banking? Evidence

More information

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Liuren Wu Baruch College, City University of New York Joint work with Jian Hua 6th Annual Conference of the Society for Financial Econometrics June 12-14,

More information

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data Nicolas Parent, Financial Markets Department It is now widely recognized that greater transparency facilitates the

More information

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy This online appendix is divided into four sections. In section A we perform pairwise tests aiming at disentangling

More information

Overseas unspanned factors and domestic bond returns

Overseas unspanned factors and domestic bond returns Overseas unspanned factors and domestic bond returns Andrew Meldrum Bank of England Marek Raczko Bank of England 9 October 2015 Peter Spencer University of York PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract Using

More information

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market? International Review of Finance, 2017 Can Hedge Funds Time the Market? MICHAEL W. BRANDT,FEDERICO NUCERA AND GIORGIO VALENTE Duke University, The Fuqua School of Business, Durham, NC LUISS Guido Carli

More information

Information in Financial Market Indicators: An Overview

Information in Financial Market Indicators: An Overview Information in Financial Market Indicators: An Overview By Gerard O Reilly 1 ABSTRACT Asset prices can provide central banks with valuable information regarding market expectations of macroeconomic variables.

More information

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15 The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15 Jana Hvozdenska Masaryk University Faculty of Economics and Administration, Department of Finance Lipova 41a Brno, 602 00 Czech

More information

Using federal funds futures contracts for monetary policy analysis

Using federal funds futures contracts for monetary policy analysis Using federal funds futures contracts for monetary policy analysis Refet S. Gürkaynak rgurkaynak@frb.gov Division of Monetary Affairs Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 20551

More information

S (17) DOI: Reference: ECOLET 7746

S (17) DOI:   Reference: ECOLET 7746 Accepted Manuscript The time varying effect of monetary policy on stock returns Dennis W. Jansen, Anastasia Zervou PII: S0165-1765(17)30345-2 DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2017.08.022 Reference:

More information

The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy

The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy Alexander Kurov and Raluca Stan * Abstract This paper investigates the impact of US unconventional monetary policy on asset prices at the

More information

Can the Fed Predict the State of the Economy?

Can the Fed Predict the State of the Economy? Can the Fed Predict the State of the Economy? Tara M. Sinclair Department of Economics George Washington University Washington DC 252 tsinc@gwu.edu Fred Joutz Department of Economics George Washington

More information

WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY SURPRISES AND THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS AT THE SHORT END OF THE YIELD CURVE. Selva Demiralp

WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY SURPRISES AND THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS AT THE SHORT END OF THE YIELD CURVE. Selva Demiralp TÜSİAD-KOÇ UNIVERSITY ECONOMIC RESEARCH FORUM WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY SURPRISES AND THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS AT THE SHORT END OF THE YIELD CURVE Selva Demiralp Working Paper 080 February

More information

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Vol., No., Fall 998, pp. 3 Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research David E. Runkle Research Officer Research Department

More information

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops. Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Macroeconomic Models and Forecasts for Austria

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops. Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Macroeconomic Models and Forecasts for Austria Oesterreichische Nationalbank Eurosystem Workshops Proceedings of OeNB Workshops Macroeconomic Models and Forecasts for Austria November 11 to 12, 2004 No. 5 Comment on Evaluating Euro Exchange Rate Predictions

More information

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S.

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S. WestminsterResearch http://www.westminster.ac.uk/westminsterresearch Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S. This is a copy of the final version

More information

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4 Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4.1 Introduction Modelling and predicting financial market volatility has played an important role for market participants as it enables

More information

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael Discussion Benoît Carmichael The two studies presented in the first session of the conference take quite different approaches to the question of price indexes. On the one hand, Coulombe s study develops

More information

Stock market firm-level information and real economic activity

Stock market firm-level information and real economic activity Stock market firm-level information and real economic activity F. di Mauro, F. Fornari, D. Mannucci Presentation at the EFIGE Associate Partner Meeting Milano, 31 March 2011 March 29, 2011 The Great Recession

More information

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( ) Lecture 5 Predictability Traditional Views of Market Efficiency (1960-1970) CAPM is a good measure of risk Returns are close to unpredictable (a) Stock, bond and foreign exchange changes are not predictable

More information

A1. Relating Level and Slope to Expected Inflation and Output Dynamics

A1. Relating Level and Slope to Expected Inflation and Output Dynamics Appendix 1 A1. Relating Level and Slope to Expected Inflation and Output Dynamics This section provides a simple illustrative example to show how the level and slope factors incorporate expectations regarding

More information

Is the market always right?

Is the market always right? Is the market always right? Improving federal funds rate forecasts by adjusting for the term premium AN7/8 Michael Callaghan November 7 Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note Series ISSN 3 555 Reserve

More information

Academic Research Publishing Group

Academic Research Publishing Group Academic Research Publishing Group International Journal of Economics and Financial Research ISSN(e): 2411-9407, ISSN(p): 2413-8533 Vol. 2, No. 8, pp: 155-160, 2016 URL: http://arpgweb.com/?ic=journal&journal=5&info=aims

More information

Iranian Economic Review, Vol.15, No.28, Winter Business Cycle Features in the Iranian Economy. Asghar Shahmoradi Ali Tayebnia Hossein Kavand

Iranian Economic Review, Vol.15, No.28, Winter Business Cycle Features in the Iranian Economy. Asghar Shahmoradi Ali Tayebnia Hossein Kavand Iranian Economic Review, Vol.15, No.28, Winter 2011 Business Cycle Features in the Iranian Economy Asghar Shahmoradi Ali Tayebnia Hossein Kavand Abstract his paper studies the business cycle characteristics

More information

Modeling and Forecasting the Yield Curve

Modeling and Forecasting the Yield Curve Modeling and Forecasting the Yield Curve III. (Unspanned) Macro Risks Michael Bauer Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco April 29, 2014 CES Lectures CESifo Munich The views expressed here are those of

More information

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom Gaétan Stephan 1 University of Rennes 1, CREM April 2012 (Preliminary draft) Abstract We model the relation between output

More information

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models Indian Institute of Management Calcutta Working Paper Series WPS No. 797 March 2017 Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models Vivek Rajvanshi Assistant Professor, Indian Institute of Management

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults March, 2018 Contents 1 1 Robustness Tests The results presented in the main text are robust to the definition of debt repayments, and the

More information

Do ination-linked bonds contain information about future ination?

Do ination-linked bonds contain information about future ination? Do ination-linked bonds contain information about future ination? Jose Valentim Machado Vicente Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho Guillen y Abstract There is a widespread belief that ination-linked bonds are

More information

Can the Fed Predict the State of the Economy?

Can the Fed Predict the State of the Economy? Institute for International Economic Policy Working Paper Series Elliott School of International Affairs The George Washington University Can the Fed Predict the State of the Economy? IIEP WP 28 6 Tara

More information

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios Amit Goyal Goizueta Business School Emory University Ivo Welch Yale School of Management Yale Economics Department NBER December 16, 2003 Abstract This

More information

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Jordi Galí, Mark Gertler and J. David López-Salido Preliminary draft, June 2001 Abstract Galí and Gertler (1999) developed a hybrid

More information

Monetary Policy and Market Interest Rates in Brazil

Monetary Policy and Market Interest Rates in Brazil Monetary Policy and Market Interest Rates in Brazil Ezequiel Cabezon November 14, 2014 Abstract This paper measures the effects of monetary policy on the term structure of the interest rate for Brazil

More information

Overseas unspanned factors and domestic bond returns

Overseas unspanned factors and domestic bond returns Overseas unspanned factors and domestic bond returns Andrew Meldrum Bank of England Marek Raczko Bank of England 19 November 215 Peter Spencer University of York Abstract Using data on government bonds

More information

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation? 2011 年 2 月第十四卷一期 Vol. 14, No. 1, February 2011 Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation? Tao Chen http://cmr.ba.ouhk.edu.hk Web Journal of Chinese Management Review Vol. 14 No 1 1 Does Commodity

More information

Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques

Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques Day 1: Equilibrium Models and the Dynamics of Bond Returns Pietro Veronesi Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago CEPR, NBER Bank

More information

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang Pre-print version: Tang, Tuck Cheong. (00). "Does exchange rate volatility matter for the balancing item of balance of payments accounts in Japan? an empirical note". Rivista internazionale di scienze

More information

Asymmetric Information and the Impact on Interest Rates. Evidence from Forecast Data

Asymmetric Information and the Impact on Interest Rates. Evidence from Forecast Data Asymmetric Information and the Impact on Interest Rates Evidence from Forecast Data Asymmetric Information Hypothesis (AIH) Asserts that the federal reserve possesses private information about the current

More information

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011 Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011 Kurt G. Lunsford University of Wisconsin Madison January 2013 Abstract I propose an augmented version of Okun s law that regresses

More information

Monetary Policy Objectives During the Crisis: An Overview of Selected Southeast European Countries

Monetary Policy Objectives During the Crisis: An Overview of Selected Southeast European Countries Monetary Policy Objectives During the Crisis: An Overview of Selected Southeast European Countries 35 UDK: 338.23:336.74(4-12) DOI: 10.1515/jcbtp-2015-0003 Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice,

More information

Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are

Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are Anna Naszodi 1 Engel and West (2005) argue that the discount factor, provided it is high enough, can be blamed for the failure of the empirical

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow, Co-movements of Shanghai and New York stock prices by time-varying regressions Gregory C Chow a, Changjiang Liu b, Linlin Niu b,c a Department of Economics, Fisher Hall Princeton University, Princeton,

More information

Forecasting Stock Index Futures Price Volatility: Linear vs. Nonlinear Models

Forecasting Stock Index Futures Price Volatility: Linear vs. Nonlinear Models The Financial Review 37 (2002) 93--104 Forecasting Stock Index Futures Price Volatility: Linear vs. Nonlinear Models Mohammad Najand Old Dominion University Abstract The study examines the relative ability

More information

Monetary Policy Tick by Tick

Monetary Policy Tick by Tick Discussion of: Michael Fleming and Monika Piazzesi Monetary Policy Tick by Tick Eric T. Swanson Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Bank of Canada Conference on Fixed Income May 3, 2006 This Paper: Summary

More information

Predicting RMB exchange rate out-ofsample: Can offshore markets beat random walk?

Predicting RMB exchange rate out-ofsample: Can offshore markets beat random walk? Predicting RMB exchange rate out-ofsample: Can offshore markets beat random walk? By Chen Sichong School of Finance, Zhongnan University of Economics and Law Dec 14, 2015 at RIETI, Tokyo, Japan Motivation

More information

STX FACULTY WORKING! PAPER NO An Error-Learning Model of Treasury Bill Future* and Implications for the Expectation Hypothesis. nun.

STX FACULTY WORKING! PAPER NO An Error-Learning Model of Treasury Bill Future* and Implications for the Expectation Hypothesis. nun. 330 3385 1020 COPY 2 STX FACULTY WORKING! PAPER NO. 1020 An Error-Learning Model of Treasury Bill Future* and Implications for the Expectation Hypothesis nun PiS fit &* 01*" srissf College of Commerce

More information

Combining State-Dependent Forecasts of Equity Risk Premium

Combining State-Dependent Forecasts of Equity Risk Premium Combining State-Dependent Forecasts of Equity Risk Premium Daniel de Almeida, Ana-Maria Fuertes and Luiz Koodi Hotta Universidad Carlos III de Madrid September 15, 216 Almeida, Fuertes and Hotta (UC3M)

More information

INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA

INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA CAN MONETARY POLICY IN INDIA FOLLOW INFLATION TARGETING AND ARE THE MONETARY POLICY REACTION FUNCTIONS ASYMMETRIC? Abstract Vineeth Mohandas Department of Economics, Pondicherry

More information

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults João F. Gomes Marco Grotteria Jessica Wachter August, 2017 Contents 1 Robustness Tests 2 1.1 Multivariable Forecasting of Macroeconomic Quantities............

More information

Discussion of Did the Crisis Affect Inflation Expectations?

Discussion of Did the Crisis Affect Inflation Expectations? Discussion of Did the Crisis Affect Inflation Expectations? Shigenori Shiratsuka Bank of Japan 1. Introduction As is currently well recognized, anchoring long-term inflation expectations is a key to successful

More information

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence Journal of Money, Investment and Banking ISSN 1450-288X Issue 5 (2008) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2008 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New

More information

CME Lumber Futures Market: Price Discovery and Forecasting Power. Recent Lumber Futures Prices by Contract

CME Lumber Futures Market: Price Discovery and Forecasting Power. Recent Lumber Futures Prices by Contract NUMERA A N A L Y T I C S Custom Research 1200, McGill College Av. Suite 1000 Montreal, Quebec Canada H3B 4G7 T +1 514.861.8828 F +1 514.861.4863 Prepared by Numera s CME Lumber Futures Market: Price Discovery

More information

RESEARCH PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. GDP Trend Deviations and the Yield Spread: the Case of Five E.U. Countries Periklis Gogas* and Ioannis Pragidis

RESEARCH PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. GDP Trend Deviations and the Yield Spread: the Case of Five E.U. Countries Periklis Gogas* and Ioannis Pragidis 2-2010 2010 GDP Trend Deviations and the Yield Spread: the Case of Five E.U. Countries Periklis Gogas* and Ioannis Pragidis RESEARCH PAPERS IN ECONOMICS 1 Department of International Economic Relations

More information

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note* Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note* Yin-Wong Cheung University of California, U.S.A. Frank Westermann University of Munich, Germany Daily data from the German and

More information

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Has the Inflation Process Changed? Has the Inflation Process Changed? by S. Cecchetti and G. Debelle Discussion by I. Angeloni (ECB) * Cecchetti and Debelle (CD) could hardly have chosen a more relevant and timely topic for their paper.

More information

Optimal Hedge Ratio and Hedging Effectiveness of Stock Index Futures Evidence from India

Optimal Hedge Ratio and Hedging Effectiveness of Stock Index Futures Evidence from India Optimal Hedge Ratio and Hedging Effectiveness of Stock Index Futures Evidence from India Executive Summary In a free capital mobile world with increased volatility, the need for an optimal hedge ratio

More information

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure Comment on Dewachter and Lyrio s "Learning, Macroeconomic Dynamics, and the Term Structure of Interest Rates" 1 by Jordi Galí (CREI, MIT, and NBER) August 2006 The present paper by Dewachter and Lyrio

More information

STRESS TEST ON MARKET RISK: SENSITIVITY OF BANKS BALANCE SHEET STRUCTURE TO INTEREST RATE SHOCKS

STRESS TEST ON MARKET RISK: SENSITIVITY OF BANKS BALANCE SHEET STRUCTURE TO INTEREST RATE SHOCKS STRESS TEST ON MARKET RISK: SENSITIVITY OF BANKS BALANCE SHEET STRUCTURE TO INTEREST RATE SHOCKS Juan F. Martínez S.* Daniel A. Oda Z.** I. INTRODUCTION Stress tests, applied to the banking system, have

More information

Published: Eastern European Economics, Vol. 37, No. 5, September-October 1999, pp

Published: Eastern European Economics, Vol. 37, No. 5, September-October 1999, pp The Term Structure of Interest Rates and Future Inflation Viktor KOTLÁN Published: Eastern European Economics, Vol. 37, No. 5, September-October 1999, pp. 36-51 Expected inflation is a major decision factor

More information

Derivation of zero-beta CAPM: Efficient portfolios

Derivation of zero-beta CAPM: Efficient portfolios Derivation of zero-beta CAPM: Efficient portfolios AssumptionsasCAPM,exceptR f does not exist. Argument which leads to Capital Market Line is invalid. (No straight line through R f, tilted up as far as

More information

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application Russell Cooper, John Haltiwanger and Jonathan Willis January 2005 Abstract This paper studies capital adjustment costs. Our goal here

More information

Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi

Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi Alessandra Vincenzi VR 097844 Marco Novello VR 362520 The paper is focus on This paper deals with the empirical

More information

TESTING THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS ON CORPORATE BOND YIELDS. Samih Antoine Azar *

TESTING THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS ON CORPORATE BOND YIELDS. Samih Antoine Azar * RAE REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS Vol., No. 1-2, (January-December 2010) TESTING THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS ON CORPORATE BOND YIELDS Samih Antoine Azar * Abstract: This paper has the purpose of testing

More information

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications 2013 2013 Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data A. Tsui C.Y. Xu Zhaoyong Zhang Edith Cowan University, zhaoyong.zhang@ecu.edu.au

More information

[Uncovered Interest Rate Parity and Risk Premium]

[Uncovered Interest Rate Parity and Risk Premium] [Uncovered Interest Rate Parity and Risk Premium] 1. Market Efficiency Hypothesis and Uncovered Interest Rate Parity (UIP) A forward exchange rate is a contractual rate established at time t for a transaction

More information

PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION. Modelling and forecasting money demand: divide and conquer

PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION. Modelling and forecasting money demand: divide and conquer PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION Modelling and forecasting money demand: divide and conquer César Carrera Jairo Flores Working Paper No. 91, April 2017 The views expressed in this working paper are those

More information

COINTEGRATION AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: AN APPLICATION TO THE CANADIAN TREASURY BILL MARKET. Soo-Bin Park* Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada K1S 5B6

COINTEGRATION AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: AN APPLICATION TO THE CANADIAN TREASURY BILL MARKET. Soo-Bin Park* Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada K1S 5B6 1 COINTEGRATION AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: AN APPLICATION TO THE CANADIAN TREASURY BILL MARKET Soo-Bin Park* Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada K1S 5B6 Abstract: In this study we examine if the spot and forward

More information

CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY

CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY Chapter Overview This chapter has two major parts: the introduction to the principles of market efficiency and a review of the empirical evidence on efficiency

More information

THE NEW EURO AREA YIELD CURVES

THE NEW EURO AREA YIELD CURVES THE NEW EURO AREA YIELD CURVES Yield describe the relationship between the residual maturity of fi nancial instruments and their associated interest rates. This article describes the various ways of presenting

More information

The Impact of Monetary Policy on Asset Prices 1

The Impact of Monetary Policy on Asset Prices 1 The Impact of Monetary Policy on Asset Prices 1 Roberto Rigobon Sloan School of Management, MIT and NBER Brian Sack Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System January 7, 2004 1 The authors would

More information

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics Eric Zivot April 29, 2013 Lecture Outline The Leverage Effect Asymmetric GARCH Models Forecasts from Asymmetric GARCH Models GARCH Models with

More information

A Markov switching regime model of the South African business cycle

A Markov switching regime model of the South African business cycle A Markov switching regime model of the South African business cycle Elna Moolman Abstract Linear models are incapable of capturing business cycle asymmetries. This has recently spurred interest in non-linear

More information

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk Frank Schorfheide University of Pennsylvania, CEPR, NBER, PIER March 2018 Pushing the Frontier of Central Bank s Macro Modeling Preliminaries This paper

More information

Staff Working Paper No. 709 Overnight index swap market-based measures of monetary policy expectations

Staff Working Paper No. 709 Overnight index swap market-based measures of monetary policy expectations Staff Working Paper No. 709 Overnight index swap market-based measures of monetary policy expectations Simon P Lloyd February 2018 Staff Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and

More information

Shocks vs Structure:

Shocks vs Structure: Shocks vs Structure: Explaining Differences in Exchange Rate Pass-Through Across Countries and Time Kristin Forbes: MIT, NBER & CEPR Ida Hjortsoe: Bank of England& CEPR Tsvetelina Nenova: LBS ECB Conference

More information

Testing for efficient markets

Testing for efficient markets IGIDR, Bombay May 17, 2011 What is market efficiency? A market is efficient if prices contain all information about the value of a stock. An attempt at a more precise definition: an efficient market is

More information

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES Mahir Binici Central Bank of Turkey Istiklal Cad. No:10 Ulus, Ankara/Turkey E-mail: mahir.binici@tcmb.gov.tr

More information

Monetary policy and the yield curve

Monetary policy and the yield curve Monetary policy and the yield curve By Andrew Haldane of the Bank s International Finance Division and Vicky Read of the Bank s Foreign Exchange Division. This article examines and interprets movements

More information

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU Tatjana Dahlhaus Danilo Leiva-Leon November 7, VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper assesses the effect of monetary policy during

More information

University of California Berkeley

University of California Berkeley University of California Berkeley A Comment on The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns : The Statistical Significance of FVIX is Driven by a Single Outlier Robert M. Anderson Stephen W. Bianchi

More information

An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States. by Christopher Phillip Reicher

An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States. by Christopher Phillip Reicher An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States by Christopher Phillip Reicher No. 1705 May 2011 Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Hindenburgufer 66, 24105 Kiel, Germany Kiel Working

More information

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Petra Gerlach-Kristen Hong Kong Institute of Economics and Business Strategy May, Abstract This paper uses unobserved components analysis to estimate

More information

MONETARY POLICY AND THE INVESTMENT COMPANIES

MONETARY POLICY AND THE INVESTMENT COMPANIES MONETARY POLICY AND THE INVESTMENT COMPANIES Syed M. Harun Department of Economics and Finance Texas A&M University Kingsville 700 University Boulevard, MSC 186, Kingsville, TX 78363. Tel: 361-593-3938

More information

Productivity, monetary policy and financial indicators

Productivity, monetary policy and financial indicators Productivity, monetary policy and financial indicators Arturo Estrella Introduction Labour productivity is widely thought to be informative with regard to inflation and it therefore comes up frequently

More information

The Effect of Monetary Policy on Credit Spreads

The Effect of Monetary Policy on Credit Spreads Cahier de recherche/working Paper 10-31 The Effect of Monetary Policy on Credit Spreads Tolga Cenesizoglu Badye Essid Septembre/September 2010 Cenesizoglu: Department of Finance, HEC Montréal and CIRPÉE

More information

A Comparison of Market and Model Forward Rates

A Comparison of Market and Model Forward Rates A Comparison of Market and Model Forward Rates Mayank Nagpal & Adhish Verma M.Sc II May 10, 2010 Mayank nagpal and Adhish Verma are second year students of MS Economics at the Indira Gandhi Institute of

More information

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve Capacity Utilization As a Real-Time Predictor of Manufacturing Output Evan F. Koenig Research Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve indices

More information

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies James Morley University of New South Wales 1. Introduction Garnier, Mertens, and Nelson (this issue, GMN hereafter) conduct model-based trend/cycle decomposition

More information

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHANNES KEPLER UNIVERSITY LINZ Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison by Burkhard Raunig and Johann Scharler* Working Paper

More information

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE Abstract Petr Makovský If there is any market which is said to be effective, this is the the FOREX market. Here we

More information

Business Cycles in Pakistan

Business Cycles in Pakistan International Journal of Business and Social Science Vol. 3 No. 4 [Special Issue - February 212] Abstract Business Cycles in Pakistan Tahir Mahmood Assistant Professor of Economics University of Veterinary

More information

Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018

Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018 Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018 Contents Ray C. Fair 2018 1 Macroeconomic Methodology 4 1.1 The Cowles Commission Approach................. 4 1.2 Macroeconomic Methodology.................... 5 1.3 The

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI

Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI Fifth joint EU/OECD workshop on business and consumer surveys Brussels, 17 18 November 2011 Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI Olivier BIAU

More information

Discussion Paper Series No.196. An Empirical Test of the Efficiency Hypothesis on the Renminbi NDF in Hong Kong Market.

Discussion Paper Series No.196. An Empirical Test of the Efficiency Hypothesis on the Renminbi NDF in Hong Kong Market. Discussion Paper Series No.196 An Empirical Test of the Efficiency Hypothesis on the Renminbi NDF in Hong Kong Market IZAWA Hideki Kobe University November 2006 The Discussion Papers are a series of research

More information

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy.

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy. This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/9880/ Monograph: Gascoigne, J. and Turner, P.

More information