Research for AGRI Committee - Implications of Brexit for the EU agri-food sector and the CAP: budgetary, trade and institutional issues

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Research for AGRI Committee - Implications of Brexit for the EU agri-food sector and the CAP: budgetary, trade and institutional issues"

Transcription

1

2

3 DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT Research for AGRI Committee - Implications of Brexit for the EU agri-food sector and the CAP: budgetary, trade and institutional issues WORKSHOP

4 This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development. RESPONSIBLE FOR THE POLICY DEPARTMENT Research manager: Albert Massot Project and publication assistance: Virginija Kelmelytė Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies European Parliament B-1047 Brussels LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE PUBLISHER To contact the Policy Department or to subscribe to its monthly newsletter please write to: Manuscript completed in November European Union, Print ISBN doi: /25019 QK EN-C PDF ISBN doi: / QK EN-N This document is available on the internet at: 3_EN.pdf DISCLAIMER The opinions expressed in this document are the sole responsibility of the author and do not necessarily represent the official position of the European Parliament. Reproduction and translation for non-commercial purposes are authorized, provided the source is acknowledged and the publisher is given prior notice and sent a copy.

5 DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT Research for AGRI Committee - Implications of Brexit for the EU agri-food sector and the CAP: budgetary, trade and institutional issues WORKSHOP Abstract This is the reference document of the Workshop on The Implications of Brexit for the EU agricultural sector and the CAP of 9th November 2017, organised by COMAGRI and the Policy Department B. The purpose of this Workshop was to examine and debate the main budgetary, trade and institutional issues related to the Brexit process at the current state of negotiations. This document is structured in three parts: 1. Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding. 2. EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit 3. Possible transitional arrangements related to agriculture in the light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues November 2017 PE EN

6

7 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies TABLE OF CONTENTS Possible Impact of Brexit on the EU Budget and, in Particular, CAP Funding 5 EU - UK Agricultural Trade: State of Play and Possible Impacts of Brexit 41 Possible Transitional Arrangements Related to Agriculture in the Light of the Future EU - UK Relationship: Institutional Issues 107 3

8 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 4

9 DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT Research for AGRI Committee - Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding STUDY Abstract This note assesses possible consequences of Brexit for the EU budget and the Common Agricultural Policy. It discusses the importance of the Brexit bill and the loss of the British net contribution. Furthermore, it describes how the EU budget and spending on the Common Agricultural Policy can be adjusted to the new situation and estimates how the different options would affect EU Member States and their net balances. IP/B/AGRI/CEI/ October 2017 PE EN

10 This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development. AUTHORS Jacques Delors Institut Berlin: Jörg Haas Notre Europe-Jacques Delors Institute: Eulalia Rubio Research manager: Albert Massot Project and publication assistance: Virginija Kelmelytė Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies, European Parliament LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE PUBLISHER To contact the Policy Department or to subscribe to updates on our work for the AGRI Committee please write to: Manuscript completed in October 2017 European Union, 2017 Please use the following reference to cite this study: Haas J, Rubio E, 2017, Research for AGRI Committee Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding, European Parliament, Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies, Brussels Please use the following reference for in-text citations: Haas, Rubio (2017) DISCLAIMER The opinions expressed in this document are the sole responsibility of the author and do not necessarily represent the official position of the European Parliament. Reproduction and translation for non-commercial purposes are authorized, provided the source is acknowledged and the publisher is given prior notice and sent a copy.

11 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding CONTENTS LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS 9 LIST OF TABLES AND FIGURES 10 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY INTRODUCTION Objectives and methodology Basic features of the EU budgetary system THE IMPACT OF BREXIT ON THE EU BUDGET One-off effects: The Brexit bill Structural effects: The Brexit gap and the different scenarios to adjust to it THE IMPACT OF BREXIT ON THE CAP BUDGET Basic features of the CAP budget How Brexit can alter debates on post-2020 CAP spending Estimating the Brexit effect on the CAP: data and methodology Current CAP net balances Adjusting the CAP to Brexit CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS 37 REFERENCES 39 7

12 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 8

13 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS AMIF CAP COMAGRI EAGF EARDF EIB ESIF ISF MFF OBB OR ORD RAL TFEU TOR Asylum Migration and Integration Fund Common Agriculture Policy Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development European Agriculture Guarantee Fund European Agriculture Rural Development Fund European Investment Bank Europan Structural and Investment Fund Internal Security Fund Multiannual Financial Framework Operating Budgetary Balance Own Resources Own Resources Decision Reste-a-Liquider Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union Traditional Own Resources 9

14 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies LIST OF TABLES Table 1 Main components and relative size of CAP budget LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1 The impact of a 10 billion increase in contributions on Member States net balances 22 Figure 2 Spending cuts in comparison 23 Figure 3 CAP pre-allocations per Member State, (in million, at current prices) 27 Figure 4 Relative importance of pillar 1 and 2 per Member State 27 Figure 5 CAP net balances of EU Member States, average 30 Figure 6 Estimated change in CAP net balances resulting from a 3 billion increase in national contributions 32 Figure 7 Estimated change in CAP net balances resulting from a 3 billion CAP spending cut 33 Figure 8 Estimated change in CAP net balances resulting from a 10 billion CAP spending cut 33 Figure 9 Estimated change in CAP net balances resulting from a 10 billion reduction in CAP pillar 1 spending 34 Figure 10 Estimated change in CAP net balances resulting from a 10 billion reduction in CAP pillar 1 spending (only old Member States) 35 10

15 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This in-depth analysis assesses possible consequences of Brexit for the EU budget and, in particular, the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP). We discuss how the negotiations about the Brexit bill could affect the current and the post-2020 Multiannual Financial Framework (MFF), and CAP spending in particular. We analyse how Brexit affects the EU budget structurally and how the EU can adjust to the expected budget shortfall. We offer a quantitative assessment of the impact of Brexit on CAP net balances, including different adjustment scenarios and estimates of their impact on the remaining Member States. The Brexit bill Negotiations about the so-called Brexit bill or financial settlement will determine the extent to which the UK pays its share of the financial obligations jointly undertaken by EU countries while the UK was member of the EU. At the moment of writing, negotiations on the Brexit financial settlement are in deadlock. The EU has published its position on the matter but the UK has so far refused to detail which obligations it recognises. The implications of the Brexit bill negotiations for CAP spending depend not only on the overall size of the bill agreed but on the type of financial obligation covered. If the UK accepts to contribute to the EU budget until the end of MFF but does not cover RAL pending in 2020, both EARDF and EAGF spending will be preserved until 2020 but negotiations about the next MFF will be complicated by an unexpectedly large amount of RAL. The Brexit gap We estimate that Brexit will leave a permanent shortfall of 10.2 billion per year in the EU budget. This gap has to be filled either through higher national contributions, spending cuts, a combination of both, or the introduction of new Own Resources. According to our calculations, an increase in contributions disproportionally affects some of the EU s largest net contributors such as Germany, The Netherlands and Sweden. In part, this is because they currently benefit from a rebate on the rebate on their contributions that will no longer apply once the UK leaves. Brexit not only increases the financing burden on the EU-27, it also changes how the burden is shared. The Brexit gap can also be addressed by reducing spending. It is, however, important to stress that the required savings are substantial compared to many EU programmes. Therefore, large spending categories like CAP are likely to come under pressure if the EU budget is cut. There is no default method for adapting the current MFF to the departure of a Member State. 11

16 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Brexit and the CAP We estimate that the British net contribution in the field of CAP amounts to 3 billion annually. However, spending cuts after Brexit could exceed that sum if other EU programmes are prioritised. We outline how the CAP can be adjusted to Brexit and what the implications for Member States are: Higher contributions affect today s biggest net contributors the most. If the current CAP spending levels are maintained after Brexit, Member States contributions to the CAP must increase by 3 billion. We estimate that in this scenario, large net recipients like Poland and Greece are almost unaffected. Austria, Germany, The Netherlands and Sweden lose the most in relative and in absolute terms. Generally, net contributors pay for the lion s share of the shortfall, which increases imbalances in the CAP. Reducing CAP spending puts a higher burden of adjustment on CAP net recipients. Our estimates suggest that cutting expenditure by a relatively small amount like 3 billion has a mixed effect. Among the largest losers in this scenario are CAP net contributors like Germany and The Netherlands, but also net recipients like Spain and Poland. If CAP expenditure is cut by 10 billion, net contributors gain. At the same time, the losses of net recipients are significant in this scenario, not only in absolute terms, but also compared to government spending in relatively poor countries like Bulgaria. Conclusions and recommendations There is no pain-free way of adjusting CAP spending to the Brexit gap. However, the budgetary impact of the different reform options is in most cases limited when compared to general government spending. The EU should be careful about linking the agreement on the Brexit bill to an agreement on a future and hypothetical transitional period, as proposed by the UK. Moving to the second phase without any clear agreement on the Brexit bill could enable the UK to use money as a bargaining chip when negotiating the future relationship between the EU and the UK. The EU s first priority in the Brexit bill negotiations should be to minimise the adverse financial impact of Brexit on the current and future MFF. If concessions are needed, they can come from other elements of the deal such as the UK s participation in EU bodies and funds, payment for pensions and other employees benefits or payment for contingent liabilities. Bargaining about budget cuts and contribution increases should not be limited to one spending area, but include the entire system of EU finances. For example, net contributors might be more willing to accept further increases in their payments if the overall budget is reformed. While Brexit can provide the narrative for a profound reform in the architecture of the CAP, aimed not only at reducing overall CAP spending but at rendering CAP more effective and sustainable, a major revision of CAP might not be feasible before 2022 or 2023, with implementation starting in 2024 or

17 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding 1. INTRODUCTION KEY FINDINGS EU expenditure is planned through annual budgets and Multiannual Financial Frameworks (MFF). MFFs are adopted unanimously by the Council whereas annual budgets are subjected to qualified majority voting. Most EU expenditure is entered into the budget through differentiated appropriations. The stock of unpaid commitments at a given point of time is known as RAL or reste-à-liquider. The EU budget is mostly financed by national governments GNI-based contributions. The UK enjoys a permanent rebate on its contribution, granted in the Own Resource Decision (ORD). Austria, Germany, the Netherlands and Sweden have been granted a rebate based on the British rebate Objectives and methodology This in-depth analysis assesses possible consequences of Brexit for the EU budget and, in particular, the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP). It provides input for the workshop Implications of Brexit for the EU agri-food sector and the CAP: budgetary, trade and institutional issues, organised by the Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development (COMAGRI) and the Policy Department B of the European Parliament. The note includes: A discussion of the main issues at stake in the negotiations about the so-called Brexit bill and the implications of different outcomes for the current and post-2020 Multiannual Financial Framework (MFF) and for CAP spending in particular. An analysis how Brexit affects the EU budget structurally and how the EU can adjust to the expected budget shortfall. A quantitative assessment of the impact of Brexit on CAP net balances, including different adjustment scenarios and estimates of their impact on the remaining Member States. We define the net balance as a Member State s VAT- and GNI-based contributions to the EU budget minus total EU spending in the country. We do not take into account Traditional Own Resources (TOR) because they are direct EU revenues that are merely channelled through Member States. Furthermore, unlike the European Commission s operating budgetary balances (which exclude administrative spending), the net balances we report are not supposed to be a measure of fairness, but rather an indicator of Member States material interests. In accordance with the terms of reference provided by the European Parliament, the analysis of the impact of Brexit on CAP spending is based on the current CAP budget for and the institutional framework adopted by the European Institutions concerning the Brexit negotiations. This note does not take a position on the question what the appropriate level of CAP spending is and it does not evaluate possible options for reforming CAP. 13

18 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 1.2. Basic features of the EU budgetary system The EU budget has some particular features that distinguish it from national budgets. A crucial distinctive aspect is the fact that it is expenditure-led (resources are raised to match what is needed to cover the agreed level of EU expenditures). This, together with the fact that the EU budget is mostly financed through Member States direct transfers, explains the existence of various mechanisms and rules aimed at guaranteeing budgetary discipline and ensuring an orderly development of expenditure over time Annual budgets and the Multiannual Financial Frameworks (MFF) EU expenditure is planned through annual budgets and Multiannual Financial Frameworks (MFF) covering a period of at least five years. MFFs are not multi-annual budgets. They do not set actual expenditure figures but provide a framework for financial programming and budgetary discipline that has to be respected by annual budgets. In particular, the MFF sets the maximum annual amount of resources ( ceilings ) that the EU can allocate ( commitments ) to each category of expenditure ( heading ). It also set an overall annual ceiling for payments. The MFF is a legally binding act agreed unanimously by the Council and approved by majority in the European Parliament. It can be amended in response to unforeseen circumstances but any revision of the MFF needs to be adopted following the same procedure. Art of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) also stipulates that, if there is no agreement on the next MFF at the end of the previous financial framework, the ceilings and other provisions in place for the final year of the expiring MFF shall be extended until such time as that act is adopted. Based on the MFF, the EU adopts annual budgets. They are proposed by the Commission and adopted by both the Council and the European Parliament through a procedure which is similar but shorter than the EU s ordinary legislative procedure 1. In particular, the Council adopts annual budgets with a qualified majority (and not with unanimity as is required for the MFF). Annual budgets correspond to the calendar year and must be agreed by the end of the preceding year. If no agreement is reached in time, the previous annual budget is rolled over on a monthly basis (the Commission is authorised to continue equivalent spending on a monthly basis through the system of provisional twelfths ) 2. Annual budgets can be modified through draft amending budgets, which are subject to the same procedures for adoption as the annual budget Differentiated appropriations: commitments and payments EU expenditure is usually expressed in two different figures: commitment appropriations (legal pledges to provide funds, provided that certain conditions are fulfilled) and payment appropriations (cash or bank transfers to the beneficiaries). Annual commitments and payments often differ. This is particularly the case for cohesion programmes, as commitments are entered into the budget during the initial year of implementing the programme and payments are stretched over various years. Differentiated appropriations give rise to 1 See Article 314 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) for a detailed description of the annual EU budgetary procedure. 2 Art 315 TFEU, If, at the beginning of a financial year, the budget has not yet been definitively adopted, a sum equivalent to not more than one twelfth of the budget appropriations for the preceding financial year may be spent each month in respect of any chapter of the budget in accordance with the provisions of the Regulations made pursuant to Article 322; that sum shall not, however, exceed one twelfth of the appropriations provided for in the same chapter of the draft budget. 14

19 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding outstanding commitments (also known by its French acronym RAL 3 ), which is the total amount of appropriations that the EU has committed to pay but not yet paid at a certain point in time. Outstanding commitments represent a budget liability for the EU. It is also important to note that there are a few categories of EU expenditures for which this rule does not apply and commitments and appropriations coincide (non-differentiated appropriations). This is the case in particular for most spending under the European Agriculture Guarantee Fund (EAGF) Own Resources, corrections and the balanced-budget rule The budget of the European Union is financed by so-called Own Resources, other revenue 5 and the surplus carried over from the previous year. Own Resources can be defined as revenue allocated irrevocably to the Union to finance its budget and accruing to it automatically without the need for any subsequent decision by the national authorities 6. There are three main categories of Own Resources: Traditional Own Resources (TOR), which comprise customs duties and agricultural levies collected by Members States on behalf of the EU (13% of total EU revenues in 2015). Member State s VAT-based contributions, derived from the application of a uniform call rate to a notionally harmonized VAT base determined uniformly for the Member States (12% of total EU revenues). Member States GNI-based contributions, resulting from the application of a uniform call rate to total EU GNI, to match the total volume of resources to the total volume of expenditure (69% of total EU revenues). Own Resources are defined and fixed in a Council Decision (the Own Resources Decision ORD) 7. This Decision is conceived in principle to cover the same period as the respective MFF. In practice, however, ORDs do not have an expiration date and continue to be valid until a new decision enters into force. Since ORDs are approved unanimously by all Member States and ratified by all Member States national Parliaments, a long time can pass until a new ORD enters into force. The ORD also includes various provisions granting particular corrections to certain Member States. The most important one is the correction in favour of the United Kingdom, popularly known as the UK rebate. This provision allows the UK to be reimbursed 66 % of the difference between its contribution and what it receives back from the EU budget. The formula to calculate the UK rebate is complex and it has been amended a number of times 8. In particular, in 2007, it was decided that EU structural and cohesion expenditure allocated to new Member States - including spending from the European Agriculture Fund for Rural Development 3 Reste à Liquider. 4 Only a tiny part EAGF expenditures, implemented through direct management (e.g. financing of actions to promote agriculture products and the establishment of agricultural accounting information or survey systems) are entered as differentiated appropriations. See Art. 169 of Regulation No 966/2012 on the financial rules applicable to the general budget of the Union ( Financial Regulation ). 5 Other revenue includes contributions from non-eu countries to certain programmes, interest on late payments, fines, and other diverse items. They represent a minor part of total EU revenues (6.9% in 2015). 6 Monti, Mario et al (2016), Future financing of the EU. Final report and recommendations of the high level group on own resources, Brussels, p Council Decision of 26 May 2014 on the System of Own Resources of the European Union (2014/335/EU, Euratom). 8 The subject is discussed in detail in D Alfonso, Alessandro (2016), The UK 'rebate' on the EU budget. An explanation of the abatement and other correction mechanisms. European Parliamentary Research Service Briefing, February

20 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies (EAFRD) - would be excluded from the calculation of the rebate. This adjustment was meant to ensure that the UK would help finance the costs of EU enlargement. The UK rebate for year N is financed by higher contributions from the remaining EU Member States in year N+1. The additional payments are calculated based on the share they contribute to the EU's GNI-based own resource. However, four countries (Germany, the Netherlands, Austria and Sweden) pay only 25 % of their normal financing share. This correction is popularly known as the rebate on the rebate. The ORD includes several other corrections which only apply for the period In particular, some countries benefit from gross reductions in their GNI-based contributions in specific years 9 and Germany, the Netherlands and Sweden benefit from a lower VAT call rate, which reduces their VAT-based contribution to the EU budget. Finally, it should be noted that the GNI-based own resource plays a special role, not only because of its relative importance (it accounts for almost 70% of the total income) but because it is the EU s residual revenue source. A uniform GNI call rate is fixed each year as part of the budgetary procedure, and it is determined by the additional revenue needed to finance the expenditure not covered by the other resources (VAT-based payments, TOR and other revenue). In this way, the GNI resource ensures that Art. 310 TFEU is respected, which stipulates that revenue and expenditure shown in the budget shall be in balance Ceilings maximum amounts to spend The EU budget is subject to various ceilings. The MFF sets annual ceilings for commitment appropriations under each heading and overall annual ceilings for commitments and payments. The ORD establishes an annual own-resource ceiling for payments, which is the maximum amount of own resources the EU may raise during a year to cover annual appropriations for payments. The MFF establishes annual ceilings on payments both in absolute terms and as a percentage of the EU's estimated GNI. Each year, the Commission recalculates this percentage on the basis of the latest available GNI forecasts and publishes it in the MFF technical adjustment. This serves to check that the EU's total estimated level of payments is below the annual Own Resources ceiling established by the ORD, which is currently fixed at 1.23 % of the EU's GNI. Since the mid-2000s, Member States largest net contributors to the EU budget have insisted on the need to keep the size of the MFF at 1% of EU GNI. This 1% political ceiling, which is usually interpreted as applying to payment appropriations 10, has weighed heavily on the last two MFF negotiations. 9 Art 2.5 Own Resources Decision: For the period only, Denmark, the Netherlands and Sweden shall benefit from gross reductions in their annual GNI-based contribution of EUR 130 million, EUR 695 million and EUR 185 million respectively. Austria shall benefit from a gross reduction in its annual GNI-based contribution of EUR 30 million in 2014, EUR 20 million in 2015 and EUR 10 million in During the MFF negotiations, the 1% GNI position was first interpreted as relating to commitment appropriations and at a later stage in the negotiation to payment appropriations (see European Commission, EU Public Finances, 5 th edition, p.82). In the latest MFF negotiation, the request from Member States net contributors was to stabilise spending in real terms at the 2013 level, which was in practice equivalent to keep payment appropriations at 1% of EU GNI (even if, in the end, pressure to lower payments from some Member States led to the establishment of payment appropriations below the 1% GNI target). 16

21 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding 2. THE IMPACT OF BREXIT ON THE EU BUDGET KEY FINDINGS Brexit could have a number of different budgetary consequences for the EU. Apart from leaving a permanent gap in the EU budget, the departure of the UK may alter the dynamics of budgetary negotiation in the Council. The removal of the UK rebate can also open the door to a reform of the EU s financing system. The implications of the Brexit bill negotiations for CAP spending will depend not only on the overall size of the bill agreed but on the type of financial obligation covered. If the UK accepts to pay its annual contribution to the EU budget until the end of MFF, both EARDF and EAGF spending will be preserved until 2020 but negotiations about the next MFF will become more difficult. Brexit is likely to leave a structural shortfall (or Brexit gap ) of about 10 billion per year in the EU budget that has to be balanced by higher contributions or lower spending. We estimate that an increase in contributions would disproportionally affect some of the EU s largest net contributors such as Germany, The Netherlands and Sweden. In part, this is because they currently benefit from a rebate on the rebate on their contributions that will no longer apply once the UK leaves The Brexit gap can also be addressed by reducing spending. It is, however, important to stress that the required savings are substantial compared to many EU programmes. Therefore, large spending categories like the CAP are likely to come under pressure if the EU budget is cut. There is no default method for adapting the current MFF to the departure of a Member State. Since any modification requires unanimity, it seems possible that the current MFF remains unchanged and the European Commission covers the shortfall by increasing GNI-based contributions if needed. Brexit, if it occurs, affects the EU s public finances in several ways. First, negotiations about the so-called Brexit bill or financial settlement will determine the extent to which the UK pays its share of all financial obligations jointly undertaken by EU countries while the UK was member of the EU (see section 2.1). Second, Brexit will leave a permanent shortfall in the EU budget estimated at 10 billion per year 11. This gap will have to be filled either through increasing Member States GNI-based contributions, spending cuts, a combination of both or the introduction of new Own Resources (section 2.2). Brexit may have further effects on the upcoming MFF: The departure of the UK may change the dynamics of negotiation in the Council. The UK government played a crucial role in the final stage of the last MFF negotiations, forcing a significant reduction in the overall ceiling for payments. Brexit will lead to an increase the size of the EU budget in relative terms (as a % of EU GNI). This is because it reduces EU GNI by approximately 17% (the British economy s relative weight in the EU) but the UK s net contribution is only about 7% of the EU budget due to the rebate it receives. Under these circumstances, maintaining 11 We already estimated a budget gap of 10 billion per year in Haas, J. and Rubio, E. (2017), Brexit and the EU budget: Threat or Opportunity, Jacques Delors Institute, Policy Paper 183, January The paper was based on data, but the inclusion of data for 2016 has not changed this estimate. 17

22 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies the EU budget at 1% of EU GNI (which was the Council s stance in the last two MFF negotiations) appears difficult. Brexit will end the UK correction mechanism and the related rebates. This opens the door for proposals to remove all corrections in the EU financing system 12 and abolish or reform the VAT-based own resource (on which the calculation of the UK rebate is based) One-off effects: The Brexit bill The Brexit bill or financial settlement refers to the expected payment the United Kingdom has to make to the EU to honour its share of the financial commitments jointly undertaken by EU countries while the UK was member of the EU. It does not refer to any potential future payment related to a possible transition period between Brexit and a future EU-UK partnership agreement. The financial settlement is being discussed in the first phase of Brexit negotiations. Following the phased approach the EU requires the UK to recognise the existence of this obligations and expects to reach an agreement on general principles concerning the nature and composition of this payment and the methodology to calculate it. This agreement is one of the conditions for moving to the second phase of the negotiations, in which the future EU-UK relationship and transitional arrangements will be discussed, together with the exact amount of the financial settlement. At the moment of writing, negotiations about the Brexit bill are in deadlock. The EU presented its negotiation position on the financial settlement in a paper published in June , While the Commission s paper does not name a specific figure, the Financial Times estimates that, based on the EU negotiating position, the bill could amount to between 91 and 113 billion, corresponding to a net payment of billion after considering the share of EU spending that flows back to the UK 15. The EU position paper lists the different financial obligations and liabilities to take into account and proposes a methodology to calculate the amounts for the different items and the UK s share of these obligations. According to the EU, the financial settlement should include the payment of financial obligations derived from the EU budget as well as financial obligations related to the settlement of British participation in EU bodies (the European Investment Band, the European Central Bank) or specific EU funds and facilities (such as the European Development Fund, or the Facility for Refugees in Turkey). These latter ones can be technically tricky and complex to define, but the most contested claims are those related to financial commitments derived from the EU budget. Generally, the EU expects the UK to pay for these commitments according to its share in financing the EU budget after the application of the UK rebate, which is approximately 12.5% 16. Taking into account the UK rebate in the calculation of the Brexit bill is logical from 12 European Commission (2017), Reflection paper on the future of EU public finances, COM(2017) 358 of 28 June Monti, Mario et al (2016), op.cit. 14 European Commission Task Force for the preparation and conduct of the negotiations with the United Kingdom under Article 50 EU, Position Paper Essential Principles on Financial Settlement, TF50 (2017), 2/2, 12 June Barker, Alex, Brussels hoists gross Brexit bill to 100bn, Financial Times, 3 May % is the average of UK s net contributions during 2014 and

23 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding a legal point of view, as the right to this rebate is granted in the Own Resource Decision, the same legal act that states the UK s obligation to contribute to the financing of the EU budget. The Commission s paper lists five types of financial commitments derived from the EU budget: 1. Outstanding budgetary commitments or RAL (reste à liquider). The EU expects the UK to cover part of the spending commitments that have been authorised in past EU annual budgets but have not yet been executed at the moment of withdrawal. RAL amounted to billion at the end of Assuming that RAL increases at the end of the MFF, this implies that at least 29.7 billion would have to be paid by the UK at the moment of withdrawal. 2. Financial programming for the period between the withdrawal date and the end of the MFF. The EU also asks the UK to contribute to the payment of EU spending obligations linked to the MFF but not yet committed in an annual EU budget at the moment of withdrawal. This is the most contested claim according to some experts 18. Initially, the Commission s Article 50 Task Force proposed to include only some long-term spending obligations linked to the MFF in the Brexit bill. More specifically, the Commission argued that the UK should contribute to the financing of those spending commitments recognised as EU liabilities in the consolidated accounts of the EU. These are commitments derived from the signature of a contract or grant agreement with a beneficiary, such as a national or regional authority (e.g. the signature of Operational Programmes) or a private promoter (e.g. GALILEO, COPERNICUS or long-term infrastructure projects financed by the Connecting Europe Facility). In 2016, the consolidated accounts of the EU reported 298 billion of such longterm legal commitments (more than 90% of them related to ESIF spending). Assuming the same amount at end-2108, this would imply an amount of approximately 37.2 billion to be paid by the UK. After exchanges with national capitals, the Commission s initial position toughened 19. Various Member States insisted on making the UK liable not only for long-term legal commitments identified in consolidated annual accounts, but for all planned EU spending under the MFF. In practice, this implies asking the UK to maintain its annual net EU budget contribution until the end of MFF (approximately 10 billion per year in net terms 20 ) and cover its share of the RAL on commitments pending in 2020, which is expected to reach 254 billion (British share: 31.7 billion) 21. In total, 51.7 billion would have to be paid by the UK. There are strong legal and political arguments to support the EU position. By adopting the MFF in 2013, the UK government committed to financing the EU s long-term budget for the whole period. Most spending commitments constitute legal obligations for the EU even if they are not part of an annual budget and not included in consolidated accounts, as they derive from EU legal acts setting out the rules and specific amounts allocated to each programme. The UK can counter that the MFF regulation obliges Member States to adjust the MFF in the event of an enlargement (Art. 21) and that thus, 'a contrario, the 17 European Commission, DG budget (2017), Report on budgetary and financial management. Financial year 2016, Brussels. 18 Barker, Alex, FT breakdown: the 100bn Brexit bill, Financial Times, 3 May Barker, Alex, op.cit. 20 Notice that the UK would continue to benefit from all EU spending programmes until the end of MFF. 21 European Commission (2016), Commission Staff Working Document Accompanying the document: Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council, Mid-term review/revision of the multiannual financial framework , An EU budget focused on results, 299 final, Brussels. 19

24 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies remaining EU27 should adjust the MFF ceilings and reform legal acts to reflect the fact that one of the biggest net contributors is leaving. However, enlargement differs from withdrawal in that it is a decision taken by unanimity by all EU Member states, not imposed by one of them to the others. 3. EU liabilities which are not balanced by corresponding assets. The EU also asks the UK to pay its share of EU liabilities that are recorded in the consolidated accounts and are not balanced by corresponding assets, such as pensions and other employee benefits, payables or financial liabilities not derived from EU borrowing. These are relatively minor amounts. In 2016, liabilities from pensions and other employee benefits amounted to 63.8 billion overall (British share: 7.9 billion) and payables amounted to 40 billion (British share: 5 billion). 4. Contingent liabilities. Contingent liabilities are potential liabilities that may or may not fall due depending on the outcome of an uncertain event in the future. They relate mainly to EU guarantees given to the EIB in the context of EFSI, the EIB external lending mandate or other financial instruments ( 25.5 billion in 2016) and EU borrowing to finance financial assistance programmes ( 54.9 billion 2016). There is a discussion on how to include these liabilities in the calculation of the financial settlement. The EU prefers a British lump-sum payment upfront to cover them in case they materialise in the future, and to reimburse the UK over time if they do not. Another option could be to share the costs from contingent liabilities as they arise in future. 5. Specific costs related to the withdrawal process. The EU s paper asks the UK to carry all the specific costs related to the withdrawal process, such as the costs of moving EU agencies located in the UK. As mentioned above, there is still no agreement on the financial settlement. Through different public speeches, members of the UK government have formally recognised that the UK has financial obligations to the EU but there has not been a public statement detailing which obligations it recognises. Recently, Prime Minister Theresa May promised in her Florence speech on September 22 that no EU country will be required to pay more or receive less over the remainder of the current MFF as a result of Brexit. Ms May has not provided an exact figure but her words have been interpreted as an offer amounting to 20 billion 22, which roughly corresponds to the payment of UK s annual net contribution to the EU budget from the expected date of withdrawal (mid- 2019) until The 20 billion offer is seen as insufficient by EU negotiators. It leaves out many of the financial obligations mentioned above (pensions, contingent liabilities) and it does not recognise the payment of a share of RAL pending in It is also worth pointing out that Theresa May s offer has been presented as a sort of implementation payment linked to a two-year transitional period and not as the settlement of past debts. While this is a good strategy to sell the bill to the UK public opinion, the EU should be careful about linking the agreement on the Brexit bill to an agreement about the transition towards a new EU/UK relationship. Moving to the second phase without any clear agreement on the Brexit bill would enable the UK to use money as a bargaining chip. Finally, from the point of view CAP spending, it is not irrelevant which type of financial obligation is covered. If the UK pays its share of the RAL at the moment of withdrawal (in principle, mid- 2019) but does not contribute to the financing of the EU after this date, CAP spending (both pillar 1 and 2) in 2019 and 2020 may be under threat. 22 Parker, G. and Barker, A. Theresa May prepares 20bn EU budget offer, Financial Times, 19 September

25 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding If the UK pays a part of the RAL at the moment of withdrawal as well as a share of outstanding legal commitments recorded in the consolidated accounts of the EU, EARDF funding for 2019 and 2020 will be preserved but EAGF spending will be threatened. Finally, if as seems to be the intention of May - the UK only recognises its duty to maintain the annual contribution to the EU budget for the last two years of the current MFF, both EARDF and EAGF spending will be preserved until 2020 but negotiations about the next MFF will become more difficult. The remaining EU27 will have to assume the UK s roughly 31 billion share of RAL and share the costs among themselves, on top of having to adjust the EU budget to the permanent shortfall left by Brexit (see next section) Structural effects: The Brexit gap and the different scenarios to adjust to it While Brexit may or may not threaten planned spending in the current MFF, it is almost certain that it will have a lasting impact on future MFFs. Since the UK pays more into the EU budget than the EU spends in the UK, Brexit will leave a structural funding gap in the finances of the EU27. The outcome of the Brexit bill negotiations, decisions concerning a possible transitional period and the budgetary arrangements linked to the future EU-UK partnership will determine the size of the gap, but it seems safe to assume that the British net contribution post-brexit will be lower than it is today. Anything else would likely be unacceptable for the UK. The exact size of the gap not only depends on the type of Brexit (soft or hard, clean or transitional), but on several additional factors. For example, the UK s net contribution to the EU budget has been volatile in the past and forecasts by the British Office for Budget Responsibility suggest that it could decrease in 2017, but increase markedly afterwards 23. This would imply a larger budget shortfall. At the same time, Brexit could also lead to new revenue, e.g., from increased customs duties if tariffs are reinstated between the EU-27 and the UK (although this would simultaneously depress trade volumes and the overall effect on national budgets might well be negative) 24. In light of the uncertainties, it seems reasonable to keep matters simple. We assume that the EU will receive no contributions from the UK after Brexit. Consequently, we estimate the Brexit gap by subtracting the revenue raised in the UK from EU spending in the UK. In order to account for yearly fluctuations, we use the average. Over this period, the UK has contributed an average of 17.4 billion annually, around one-eight of the EU s total revenue. Revenue raised via the VAT-based and the GNI-based own resource accounts for 80% of the amount. Customs duties (TOR) collected in the UK, which account for the remaining 20%, are not strictly speaking a part of the British national contribution to the EU budget, but we still include them since they will no longer be collected after Brexit. On the other side of the ledger, the EU spent 7.2 billion annually on programmes in the UK in 2014 and According to these figures, Brexit will leave a structural gap of 10.2 billion per year in the EU budget 25. The EU will have to increase revenue or cut spending to adjust to this gap. 23 Keep, Matthew (2017) : The UK s contribution to the EU budget, House of Commons Library Briefing Paper No. CBP 7886, p Núñez Ferrer, Jorge and Rinaldi, David (2016), The Impact of Brexit on the EU Budget: A non-catastrophic even, CEPS Policy Brief No For further details, see Haas/Rubio

26 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies We estimate the effect of Brexit on Member States by first calculating each country s current net balance (see section 1.1) and then comparing it to the balance that is expected if contributions increase or EU spending decreases. We use the European Commission s operating budgetary balances dataset that records actual revenue and spending (instead of projections) Scenario 1: Higher contributions If spending in the EU-27 is maintained, revenue needs to increase by approximately 10 billion in order to balance the budget. The GNI-based Own Resource is used to raise the additional funds (see section 1.2.3). As a result, wealthier countries can expect to see a larger deterioration of their net balances. In relation to their current contributions, most Member States are evenly affected. They can expect an increase of between five and eight per cent compared to their current gross national contributions (see figure 1). However, Brexit not only increases the financing burden on the EU-27, it also changes how the burden is shared. A disproportionally large increase can be expected for Austria, Germany, The Netherlands and Sweden. This is because of the way the UK rebate is financed today. All Member States contribute to financing the rebate, but the aforementioned countries have secured a rebate on the rebate that limits their contribution (see section 1.2.3). After Brexit, the UK rebate and its associated rebates can no longer apply. A larger portion of revenue is financed according to countries relative wealth (GNI key). This effect alone could redistribute around 1.7 billion (or 15 per capita) from the four former rebate countries to the others. Figure 1: The impact of a 10 billion increase in contributions on Member States net balances. Source: Authors calculations based on European Commission data on expenditure and revenue by Member States (operating budgetary balances), as reported in EU Financial Reports for Note: A Member State s national contribution consists of the revenue generated by the VAT- and the GNI-based Own Resource. 26 For a more detailed description of the data, see section 3.3 and Haas/Rubio

27 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding Scenario 2: Lower spending The Brexit gap can also be addressed by reducing spending. The distributional consequences are likely to be very different from the scenario described above. If contributions remain broadly unchanged (except for the rebates) and spending falls, the net balances of those Member States that receive the most EU funding today deteriorate, while the effect on net contributors is muted. However, beyond these general considerations, the impact depends entirely on how the cuts are distributed between the different budget headings. It is, however, important to stress that the required savings would be substantial compared to many EU programmes. Figure 2 illustrates this point. Since smaller EU programmes would be devastated by deep cuts, large spending areas such as Structural and Investment Funds and the CAP are likely to come under pressure in this scenario. Figure 2: Spending cuts in comparison Source: Authors representation based on European Commission data and Haas, J. and Rubio, E. (2017), Brexit and the EU budget: Threat or Opportunity, Jacques Delors Institute, Policy Paper 183. Even after deep cuts, Brexit increases the relative size of the EU budget slightly, from currently 1% to 1.05% of EU GNI. The increase reflects the fact that the UK contributes more to EU GNI than to the EU budget. Maintaining the current ratio (in line with net contributors traditional request to keep the EU budget at 1% of EU GNI) would require spending cuts around 16 billion per year. However, the situation becomes less problematic if the currently strong economic growth in the EU continues. 23

28 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Scenario 3: No agreement It is worth noting that there is no default method for adapting the current MFF to the departure of a Member State. The MFF regulation for states that the MFF should be adjusted accordingly in case of Treaty change (Art. 20) 27 or enlargement (Art. 19) 28, but says nothing about the unprecedented event of a Member State requesting to withdraw. Even if we assume that Art. 20 is applicable to withdrawals, there is ample room for interpretation what adjusting the MFF means 29. Since any modification requires unanimity, it seems possible that the current MFF remains unchanged and the European Commission covers the shortfall by increasing contributions via the GNI resource if necessary 30. It may also happen that an ad hoc solution is found to fill the gap during the current MFF (e.g. a two-year UK-EU transitional agreement, involving the payment of UK net contributions in 2019 and 2020) but that Member States fail to reach an agreement on the post-2020 MFF. In this case, article of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) stipulates that the ceilings and other provisions in place for the final year of the expiring MFF shall be extended until such time as that act is adopted. In practice, this means that the level of spending for 2020 will be maintained until an agreement on the new MFF is reached Other possible scenarios Apart from the scenarios outlined above, there are other ways to adjust to the Brexit gap. For example, Member States could combine budget cuts and contribution increases. Another option is the introduction of new Own Resources that make up for the budget shortfall. Some options, such as a CO2 levy, might generate revenue without adding to national contributions. The introduction of new Own Resources could be part of a package deal that includes reforms on the expenditure side, as proposed by the report by the High Level Group on Own Resources published in December However, a comprehensive deal of this sort is difficult to envisage by Even if the elimination of the UK rebate opens the door to reforms on the revenue side, the introduction of one or multiple new revenues requires a lot of political bargaining and the approval of new Own Resource Decisions usually takes a long time. The current ORD was proposed by the Commission in September 2011 and was approved almost three years later, in May Assuming that the Commission makes a proposal for a new ORD in spring 2018, Member States will only have one year and a half to negotiate, approve and ratify the new system. 27 Art. 20 of the current MFF regulation: Should a revision of the Treaties with budgetary implications occur between 2014 and 2020, the MFF shall be revised accordingly. 28 Art. 21 of the current MFF regulation: If there is an accession or accessions to the Union between 2014 and 2020, the MFF shall be revised to take account of the expenditure requirements resulting therefrom. 29 An interesting precedent concerning the different interpretations on how to adjust the MFF to changes in EU membership is Croatia s accession in Both the Commission and the European Parliament called for an increase in the overall level of commitments to adapt to the entry of Croatia, but the Council rejected this interpretation and called for redeployments between ceilings to cover any additional expenditure requirements from the accession. In the end, the compromise was to keep the overall ceiling for commitment untouched but increase the annual payment ceilings for 2013 (See European Commission, EU public finance, 5th edition, Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, 2014, pp ). 30 To be precise, revenue can only be increase until the level stated in the Own Resources Decision, which is currently 1.23% of EU GNI. In 2016, revenue from Own Resources stood at only 0.89% of GNI (cf. Amending Budget No. 6, 2016, p. 198). 31 Some could argue that this would in principle reinforce the negotiating position of net recipients vis-a-vis those of net contributors. However, a non-agreement scenario could be also disruptive for net recipients as the stalemate could result in major legal and financial uncertainty and problems with the disbursement of EU spending (see Haas and Rubio, 2017). 32 Monti, Mario et al (2016), op.cit. 24

29 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding 3. THE IMPACT OF BREXIT ON THE CAP BUDGET KEY FINDINGS Whereas the weight of CAP in the EU budget has decreased over time, CAP spending still represents 37.8% of total EU expenditure. Most of it is allocated to direct payments, which make up approximately 70% of the CAP budget and more than a quarter of the EU budget. The CAP in its current form has a large distributional impact. The four largest net recipients of CAP funds in absolute terms are Poland, Greece, Romania and Spain, while Germany and the UK are among the largest net contributors. Brexit will leave a CAP gap worth 3 billion annually, but CAP spending could face larger reductions if other areas of the EU budget are protected from cuts. Increasing Member State s contributions by 3 billion predominantly affects today s largest net contributors and especially Austria, Germany, The Netherlands and Sweden. This adds to imbalances in the CAP. However, the sums involved are rather small compared to government spending. Reducing CAP spending by 3 billion has mixed effects. Among the largest losers in absolute terms are CAP net contributors like Germany and The Netherlands, but also net recipients like Spain and Poland. Reducing CAP spending by 10 billion favours large net contributors. The losses of net recipients are significant not only in absolute terms, but also compared to their government spending in relatively poor countries like Bulgaria, Lithuania and Romania Basic features of the CAP budget The Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) is one of the EU s oldest policies. Established in 1962, CAP has undergone significant changes through a series of reforms since 1992, but its basic 2-pillar architecture remains unchanged. Pillar 1 includes direct payments for farmers and market measures, and it is delivered through the European Agricultural Guarantee Fund (EAGF). Pillar 2 concerns rural development measures under the European Agricultural Fund for Rural Development (EARDF). CAP spending has shrunk over the last decades but it still represents 37.8% of total EU expenditure. Most of it is allocated to direct payments, which make up approximately 70% of the CAP budget and more than a quarter of the EU budget (see table 1). Pillar 2 spending accounts for 8.8% of total EU spending. 25

30 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Table 1. Main components and relative size of CAP budget EUR million (2011 prices) As % of MFF spending CAP budget % Pillar % Of which: direct payments % Pillar % Source: Council Regulation No 1311/2013, EU regulation 73/2009. EU regulation 1307/2013 and EU Regulation 1305/2013 Both direct payments (EAGF) and rural development measures (EARDF) are implemented by national authorities, following the principle of shared management. Direct payments are 100% financed by the EU whereas rural development measures are subjected to co-financing, with different co-financing rates applied depending on the type of rural area for which support is intended and the measures co-financing. CAP commitments under shared management that is, spending for direct payments (EAGF) and for rural development (EARDF) are pre-allocated to Member States at the beginning of the MFF. In particular, the European Council s agreement on the MFF set the overall CAP budget and indicative annual break-downs per Member State, which are later on negotiated with the European Parliament and included in the EAGF and EARDF legal acts. The distribution of CAP spending per Member States takes as basis the amounts received by Member States in the last year of the expiring MFF (and therefore is strongly path dependent), but it is also the outcome of a political bargaining which takes into account other criteria as well as budgetary concessions on other policies. Figure 3 shows CAP pre-allocations per Member State for the period If we look at the distribution of CAP pillar 1 spending by Member State, we can notice that the biggest beneficiaries are Western European countries (France, Germany Spain, Italy). This is partly explained by historical differences as regards to the level of generosity of direct payments per hectare. As part of the MFF agreement, it was convened that Member States differences in direct payments would be gradually reduced between 2015 and 2020 via a process known as external convergence. Through this process, Member States with average direct payments per hectare above the EU average will see their allocation progressively reduced in order to finance the increase in those Member States with an average direct payments below 90 % of the EU average. While the MFF external convergence has entailed a redistribution of EAGF funding, mostly from Eastern to Western European countries, it has not altered the ranking of countries in terms of EAGF allocations. 26

31 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding Figure 3: CAP pre-allocations per Member State, (in million, at current prices) Source: European Commission, DG BUDGET website. Note: Allocations before transfers between pillars. Looking at pillar 2 pre-allocations, the distribution between Member states is more balanced. Following the Commission s proposal, the allocation of rural development funds per Member State was made on the basis of more objective criteria than in the past. There were however a series of discretionary allocations made to 16 different Member States, particularly to compensate some of them for lower pillar 1 allocations due to external convergence. Figure 4 shows the relative importance of pillar 1 and pillar 2 allocations per Member State. It is worth noting that pillar 1 spending tends to be more important in Western European countries. Having said this, there are also important exceptions. For example, the EAGF accounts for less than 60% of total CAP spending in Austria and Portugal. As discussed in section 3, this factor is likely to influence Member States positions with regards to adjusting the CAP to Brexit. Figure 4: Relative importance of pillar 1 and 2 per Member State Source: European Commission, DG BUDGET website. Note: Allocations before transfers between pillars. 27

32 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Finally, it should be taken into account that the current MFF allows Member States to transfer funds between pillars, up to 15% of the original amounts. Those Member States with average direct payments per hectare below 90 % of the EU average are allowed to transfer up to 25% of the support they receive for rural development to Pillar I. So far, 11 countries have used this option to move part of their direct payment allocations to the rural development policy and four Member States (Poland, Hungary, Slovakia and Croatia) have increased their direct payments allocations using part of their rural development funds. The net transfer from pillar 1 to pillar 2 over the period has amounted to around 4 billion How Brexit can alter debates on post-2020 CAP spending CAP spending was already under pressure before the UK decided to leave the EU. During the last MFF negotiations, which took place against the backdrop of budgetary cutbacks, there was a general expectation that the CAP budget would be cut significantly to free up resources for new spending priorities. In the end, there was no dramatic reduction in CAP spending but an agreement to progressively reduce it in real terms 34. During the next round of MFF negotiations, calls for lower CAP spending could become louder. Depending on the strategy chosen to cover the Brexit gap, two different political dynamics could threaten the CAP: If EU spending is reduced to balance the EU budget, the largest spending categories will be especially likely to be targeted. Cutting the CAP by a fifth would be enough to fill the Brexit gap, while even deep spending cuts in the small categories would yield considerably less (see figure 2). If EU Member States decide to increase contributions in order to make up for the Brexit budget gap, existing imbalances between net contributors and net recipients will become further entrenched. Pressure to shift spending to other areas can grow (see figure 6). How exactly these dynamics will impact post-2020 CAP spending is unclear at this stage. CAP could suffer large cuts or be largely spared from the adjustment effort. Importantly, profound changes to the CAP architecture, be it in form of co-financing or new instruments and allocation criteria could contribute to reducing costs. Speculation about introducing co-financing in pillar 1 direct payments has grown after the Commission s reflection paper on the future of the EU finance explicitly mentioned this option 35. According to AGRA Europe estimates, switching to such a system could reduce budgetary expenditure on the CAP by between 7.5 and 13.5 billion a year, depending of the specific design of co-financing rates. Nuñez Ferrer et al even imagine a co-financing system that would save up to 29 billion per year 36. However, so far, most Member States reject the idea Augère-Granier, Marie-Laure and Sgueo, Gianluca (2016), Common Agricultural Policy Pillar II, European Parliamentary Research Service briefing, July See Henke, Roberto et.al. (2015) Jonathan Little et al (2013) and Matthews, Alan (2017). 35 European Commission (2017), Reflection paper on the future of EU public finances, COM(2017) 358 of 28 June Nuñez Ferrer, Jorge et al., (2016), Study on the potential and limitations of reforming the financing of the EU budget, Expertise commissioned by the European Commission on behalf of the High Level Group on Own Resources, Brussels. 37 Ciaran Moran, CAP under pressure as most Member States reject co-financing of direct payments, Independent.ie, 13 october

33 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding Regarding the timing of a major reform, it is true that historically there has been a strong link between MFF negotiations and CAP reforms 38. This link was clear between the last CAP reform in 2013 and the negotiation of the current MFF, and it seems reasonable to expect changes in the CAP design following the adoption of the post-2020 MFF, all the more if the latter decreases the share of CAP spending in the EU budget. However, it is also true that the uncertainty about the budgetary implications of Brexit and the difficult negotiations about the Brexit bill could delay the next MFF compromise. Furthermore, the election of a new European Parliament will interrupt the EU s legislative activity in Consequently, some experts consider that a major revision of CAP will not be possible until 2022 or 2023, with implementation starting in 2024 or Estimating the Brexit effect on the CAP: data and methodology In order to estimate possible effect of Brexit on Member States CAP net balances, we rely on data provided by the European Commission in its overview of operating budgetary balances (OBB) 40. They record revenue as well as executed expenditure by member state. Since revenue as well as spending has shown considerable variance in the past, we use the average for our calculations. There are no official calculations for Member States net balances in specific spending areas because all EU revenue goes into a unitary budget. However, balances can be estimated by comparing a country s share in financing the EU budget to the share of EU funds it receives in a specific area. Or approach can be outlined as follows: First, we calculate each Member State s national contribution (i.e., revenue raised via the VAT- and the GNI-based resource, including rebates) as a share of all national contributions. By multiplying the contribution share with EU-28 spending on CAP, we arrive at an estimated contribution to the CAP. Second, we subtract the funds a Member State receives via the CAP from its estimated contribution. This gives us today s estimated net contribution. Estimating the impact of Brexit on CAP net balances requires a few additional steps: We remove the UK rebate and the so-called rebate on the rebate that mitigates the UK rebate s impact on the contributions of Austria, Germany, the Netherlands and Sweden 41. In order to do so, we estimate a simplified UK rebate based on CAP expenditure, taking into account that spending in new Member States under pillar 2 is excluded from the calculation of the UK rebate 42. We then calculate how much each Member State would have to contribute to financing the rebate under the current rules and how the burden would be shared if a GNI key was used instead. The difference between the two gives us the net impact of the discontinued rebates, which can be negative or positive. We split up the UK s net contribution among Member States. Again, we use the GNIbased resource because it is the EU budget s marginal revenue source. 38 The 1999 Agenda 2000 reform was closely linked to the negotiations of the MFF, just like the last CAP reform in 2013, but this was not the case for the Fischler Reform in 2004 and the CAP the 'Health Check' in Matthews, A.(2017), The budgetary context for the CAP, blog article, CAPreform.eu, September OBB are included as annex in EU annual Financial Reports. 41 How the corrections are calculated is described in great detail in the 2014 Own Resources Decision. 42 For the sake of simplicity, we leave out smaller items in the calculation, such as the United Kingdom s advantage and TOR windfall gains. 29

34 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Finally, we sum up the original CAP contribution, the effect of discontinuing the rebates, and the cost of covering the UK s net contribution. The result is an updated CAP contribution that can be subtracted from the (possibly also updated) CAP spending in a country to arrive at a new net balance. The approach outlined above simulates an increase in contributions that balances the budget shortfall after Brexit. To simulate a budget cut instead, we simply lower CAP spending by the desired amount and compare it to the sum of updated contributions. If spending is lower than revenue, contributions are decreased according to the GNI key until the budget is in balance once again Current CAP net balances Figure 5 shows current CAP net balances. As can be noticed, the CAP has a large distributional impact. The four largest net beneficiaries in absolute terms, namely Poland, Greece, Romania and Spain, together receive transfers worth around 9 billion annually, which translates into positive net balances of between 1.8 and 3.1 billion. On the other side of the spectrum, Germany is by far the largest net contributor, followed by the UK. Their net annual contribution to CAP amounts to 5.1 and 3 billion, respectively. Since 2014, there has been some variance in CAP net balances but no clear trend towards convergence or divergence. Figure 5: CAP net balances of EU Member States, average Source: Authors calculations, based on European Commission data. 30

35 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding 3.5. Adjusting the CAP to Brexit In analogy to the Brexit gap, it is possible to estimate the size of the budget shortfall left by the British departure from the EU. The CAP gap is equal to the British net contribution in the field of CAP, worth around 3 billion annually. However, it does not follow that Brexit will lead to a reduction of CAP spending by this amount. Expenditure could just as well be reduced by 10 billion, or not at all. There is no automatism, the decision is up to the EU institutions and the Member States. Simulating the impact of different reform options on CAP net balances can give us an idea where Member States material interests lie. The scenarios we outline in the following are not reform proposals. Rather, they serve to illustrate the dynamics that follow from the different possible changes to the CAP Scenario 1: the impact of higher contributions If the current CAP spending levels are maintained after Brexit, additional revenue worth 3 billion must be raised to finance them. Assuming that there is no radical change to the EU financing system before 2020, this happens via the GNI-based own resource (see section 1.2.3). As figure 6 shows, adjusting to the CAP gap through higher contributions leads to a worsening net balance in all Member States. However, not all are equally affected. Austria, Germany, The Netherlands and Sweden lose their benefits from the rebate on the rebate (ibid.). Consequently, in this scenario, a country like The Netherlands sees its CAP net balance deteriorate by almost the same absolute amount as Italy, a country whose GNI is three times larger. Whether this represents an unfair additional burden for the former rebate countries or whether today s financing system is unfair to most Member States, is up for debate. More generally, higher contributions magnify the already existing imbalance between CAP net contributors and net recipients. We estimate that Germany s CAP net balance deteriorates to billion in this scenario and even France ends up with a 1.2 billion CAP net deficit. At the same time, the Polish CAP net balance remains almost unchanged at 3 billion. Nevertheless, it is worth noting that the amounts involved represent relatively small shares of government expenditure. Even for the former rebate countries, the change in net balances is limited to around 0.1% of general government spending. 31

36 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Figure 6: Estimated change in CAP net balances resulting from a 3 billion increase in national contributions Source: Authors calculations, based on Eurostat and European Commission data Scenario 2: the impact of CAP spending cuts Reducing spending puts a higher burden of adjustment on net CAP recipients. A 3 billion cut, equivalent to the British CAP net contribution, reduces the Polish and Greek net gains from the CAP by 230 million and 140 million respectively. Some net contributors, like Luxembourg and Belgium, see their CAP net balance improve very slightly, but most are still negatively affected (see figure 7). The mixed result reflects two conflicting effects of Brexit. On the one hand, the EU s CAP expenditure is reduced in all Member States. The higher the amount a country receives at the moment, the larger the negative effect. On the other hand, money is redistributed from former rebate countries to all other Member States (see previous section). For example, German CAP net contributions increase by more than 600 million. In absolute terms, this is especially beneficial for countries that used to finance the bulk of the UK rebate, such as France and Italy. In some cases, the reduced CAP contribution more than makes up for the loss in EU funding. If the entire Brexit gap of 10 billion is financed by cutting CAP expenditure, the roles are almost completely reversed compared to the higher contributions scenario (see figure 8). Large net contributors to the CAP benefit from the reform. For most former rebate countries, the savings from reduced contributions outweigh the loss of EU funds. In contrast, most net recipients pay only slightly less than before, but receive substantially reduced payments. The Polish CAP net balance deteriorates by a fifth, or 680 million. Furthermore, some of the poorest Member States are strongly affected by cuts. For example, in Bulgaria, Lithuania and Romania, the negative impact exceeds 0.7% of government spending. 32

37 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding Figure 7: Estimated change in CAP net balances resulting from a 3 billion CAP spending cut Source: Authors calculations, based on Eurostat and European Commission data. Figure 8: Estimated change in CAP net balances resulting from a 10 billion CAP spending cut Source: Authors calculations, based on Eurostat and European Commission data. 33

38 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies The impact of co-financing and re-balancing the two pillars of the CAP The decision to cut or to maintain overall CAP expenditure has important distributional consequences. They can be modified via changes within the CAP. Changing eligibility criteria or protecting certain elements from cuts can mitigate or exacerbate the consequences of spending cuts. One proposal that has much appeal among experts and researchers is to introduce national co-financing for pillar 1 spending. This is seen as a good measure not only to reduce overall CAP spending, but to give Member States a greater incentive to improve the fairness and cost-effectiveness of direct payments 43. Figure 9 shows the estimated impact of a 10 billion spending cut achieved through the introduction of co-financing rates for direct payments. The results are compared to the reference scenario where the same cut is distributed between pillar 1 and 2. As can be noticed, there is no clear net recipient/net contributor divide. Several net recipients (e.g. Poland, Romania) and some net contributors (e.g. Austria, the Netherlands) are less affected than in the reference scenario. The main losers in this scenario are those countries which are especially dependent on pillar 1 payments (France, Spain). In contrast, countries such as Portugal, Romania or Austria, where pillar 2 represents more than 40% of total CAP allocation (see figure 4) benefit particularly from concentrating cuts on pillar 1. Figure 9: Estimated change in CAP net balances resulting from a 10 billion reduction in CAP pillar 1 spending Source: Authors calculations, based on European Commission data. More sophisticated adjustments could make large reductions in overall CAP expenditure compatible with protecting economically weaker Member States. One option would be to introduce a cohesion-based system of direct payments, with different co-financing rates for applied to Member States according to their levels of per capita GDP 44. A more radical option would be the introduction of co-financing for direct payments only in the old Member States (EU-15), as suggested in a recent Agra article 45. In order to make up for the 10 billion Brexit gap, the EU-15 would have to finance one third of the direct payments out of their own budget. Figure 10 compares the estimated effect of this measure to the reference scenario. The main 43 Matthews, Allan (2016); von Cramon-Taubadel, Stephan et. al (2017). 44 Nuñez Ferrer, Jorge et al. (2016), op.cit 45 Horseman, Chris, Analysis: P1 co-financing could save CAP up to 13.5 billion per year, Agra Europe, 29 June

39 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding losers in this scenario are big EU-15 CAP gross recipients, particularly Spain, France and Germany but also Greece and Ireland. The main beneficiaries are Poland, Romania and the Czech Republic, which see their net balances improve rather than worsen. Figure 10: Estimated change in CAP net balances resulting from a 10 billion reduction in CAP pillar 1 spending (only old Member States) Source: Authors calculations, based on European Commission data. 35

40 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 36

41 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding 4. CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS Brexit has far-reaching consequences for the EU s finances. The departure of the UK may alter the dynamics of budgetary negotiations in the European Council. The end of the UK rebate can also open the door to a more profound reform of the system of Own Resources. The most immediate consequences, however, are those related to the impact of the ongoing Brexit bill negotiations on the current MFF and the expected permanent shortfall that the UK will leave in the EU budget at the moment of withdrawal. How exactly these two factors will affect the current and future MFF and by extension current and future CAP spending depends to large extent on politics. We do not know what the final outcome of the Brexit bill negotiations will be, but it seems clear that they will depend as much on legal as on political arguments. Likewise, Member States and the European Parliament can take different decisions on how to adjust the EU budget to the Brexit gap. Depending on the decisions taken, Brexit can offer an opportunity to reform the spending and the revenue side of the EU s finances or, on the contrary, entrench and deepen existing divides between Member States and further complicate the EU budget with the establishment of additional corrections. In this note, we have summarised the possible financial consequences of Brexit for the EU budget and CAP in particular. The size and nature of the Brexit bill determines whether there will be a gap in the EU s finances before the end of the current MFF and whether the negotiations about the next MFF will be complicated by an unexpectedly large amount of RAL. The loss of the British net contribution to the EU budget leaves a yearly gap that must be filled by cutting expenditure, increasing contributions or finding new revenue sources. We assume that by 2020, no new revenue will come from the introduction of additional own resources or a Single Market membership fee. Consequently, we estimate an overall Brexit gap of 10 billion and a CAP gap of 3 billion. We have outlined two scenarios to adjust to Brexit at the level of the overall EU budget. Both suggest that CAP spending will be affected. Scenario 1: Filling the Brexit gap by increasing Member States national contributions. This especially affects countries that already have a large negative net balance. Some of them, including Germany and The Netherlands, are hit by further contribution increases because rebates related to the British EU membership run out. Consequently, they are likely to push for a restructuring of EU spending. Scenario 2: Reducing expenditure. The precise consequences of this option depend on the distribution of the budget cuts, but 10 billion in savings cannot be achieved by reducing spending on small EU programmes. Attention is therefore likely to turn to the Structural and Investment Funds and the CAP. Furthermore, we have estimated what impact the different options to adjust CAP to Brexit might have on Member States CAP net balances. If the current CAP spending levels are to be maintained after Brexit, an increase of GNI-based contributions worth 3 billion (the equivalent to the British net contribution in the field of CAP) is needed to finance them. This leads to a deterioration of CAP net balances in all Member States, and widens the already existing imbalance between CAP net contributors and net recipients. 37

42 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Reducing the CAP budget by 3 billion has moderate consequences for Member States CAP net balances. However, it seems likely that there will be pressure for deeper cuts if other EU programmes are protected. Adjusting to the Brexit gap only through CAP spending cuts (that is, cutting CAP by 10 billion) benefits CAP net contributors and shifts the burden of adjustment to net recipients. As a result, CAP imbalances shrink, but the cuts are significant, especially for some of the poorer Member States. Concentrating spending cuts on pillar 1 while protecting pillar 2 has been suggested as a way of reducing the costs of the CAP and improving the quality of CAP spending. Our estimates suggest that such a strategy spreads the burden of adjustment between net contributors and net recipients. However, it requires some large gross recipients of CAP funds (particularly France and Spain) to accept a sizable deterioration in their net balances. Our research shows that there is no pain-free path to adjustment. However, it also shows that the financial impact of the different reform options is in most cases limited when compared to general government spending. The challenge for governments mainly consists in communicating to their constituents that a slightly higher net contribution or a lower net benefit helps make the EU budget more efficient and ultimately benefits all EU members. Their case might be more convincing if they simultaneously simplify the EU s revenue system and refocus spending instead of devoting energy on creating new rebate mechanisms. On a more general note, the following recommendations could contribute to mitigating the impact of Brexit on the EU budget and on the CAP: The EU should be careful in linking the agreement on the Brexit bill to an agreement on a future and hypothetical transitional period, as proposed by the UK. Moving to the second phase without any clear agreement on the Brexit bill can offer to the UK the opportunity to use money as a bargaining chip when negotiating the transition to and future EU/UK relation. The EU s priority in the Brexit bill negotiations should be to minimise the adverse financial impact of Brexit in current and future MFF. If concessions are needed, they can come from other elements of the deal such as the UK s participation in EU bodies and funds, payment for pensions and other employees benefits or payment for contingent liabilities. Bargaining about budget cuts and contribution increases should not be limited to one spending area, but include the entire system of EU finances. For example, net contributors might be more willing to accept further increases in their payments if the overall budget was reformed. It is important to start debating contested key concepts (like EU added value ) and potential compromises soon, even if the actual budgetary impact of Brexit could become clear only at a very late stage of the Brexit negotiations. If the preparations for the post-2020 MFF start only in March 2018, there might not be enough time for an ambitious reform and the EU might end up with a system that is barely less complicated than the current one. A unique opportunity to improve the EU s public finances would be wasted. Brexit can provide the narrative for a profound reform in the architecture of CAP, aimed not only at reducing overall CAP spending but at rendering CAP more effective and sustainable. However, a major revision of CAP seems unlikely before 2022 or 2023, with implementation starting in 2024 or

43 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding REFERENCES Augère-Granier, Marie-Laure and Sgueo, Gianluca (2016), Common Agricultural Policy Pillar II, European Parliamentary Research Service briefing Barker, Alex (2017), The 60 billion Brexit bill: How to disentangle Britain from the EU budget, Centre for European Reform, February 2017 Buckwell, A. et al (2017), CAP: Thinking Out of the box: Further modernisation of the CAP why, what and how? The RISE Foundation, Brussels Chomicz, Ewa (2017), EU budget post-brexit: Confronting reality, exploring viable solutions, European Policy Centre, Discussion Paper D Alfonso, Alessandro (2016), The UK 'rebate' on the EU budget. An explanation of the abatement and other correction mechanisms, European Parliamentary Research Service Briefing, February 2016 Darvas, Zsolt et al (2017) Divorce settlement or leaving the club? A breakdown of the Brexit Bill, Bruegel Working Paper, Issue 03 European Commission (2014), EU Public Finances, 5th edition, Brussels European Commission (2015), EU budget 2014 Financial Report, Luxembourg European Commission (2016), Commission Staff Working Document accompanying the communication from the Commission on the mid-term review/revision of the Multiannual Financial Framework , 299 final, Brussels European Commission (2016), EU budget 2015 Financial Report, Luxembourg European Commission (2017), 10th Financial Report from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council on the European Agricultural Guarantee Fund 2016 Financial Year, COM(2017) 456 final, Brussels European Commission (2017), 10th Financial Report from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council on the European Agricultural Fund for Development 2016 Financial Year, COM(2017) 554 final, Brussels European Commission (2017), Reflection paper on the future of EU public finances, COM(2017) 358 of 28 June 2017 European Commission Task Force for the preparation and conduct of the negotiations with the United Kingdom under Article 50 EU, (2017) Position Paper Essential Principles on Financial Settlement, TF50 (2017), 2/2 European Commission, DG budget (2017), Report on budgetary and financial management, financial year 2016, Brussels Haas, J. and Rubio, E. (2017), Brexit and the EU budget: Threat or Opportunity, Jacques Delors Institute, Policy Paper

44 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Henke, Roberto et. al. (2015), Implementation of the first pillar of the CAP in the EU Member States, study requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development Keep, Matthew (2017), Brexit: the exit bill, House of Commons Library Briefing Paper No Keep, Matthew (2017), The UK s contribution to the EU budget, House of Commons Library Briefing Paper No. CBP 7886 Little, Jonathan et al (2013), European Council Conclusions on the Multi-Annual Financial Framework and the CAP, note from the European Parliament, July 2013 Matthews, Alan (2014), The impact of the simultaneous MFF negotiations on the European Parliament s influence on the 2013 CAP reform, European Parliament project The First Cap Reform Under The Ordinary Legislative Procedure: A Political Economy Perspective, Brussels Matthews, Alan (2016), The Future of Direct Payments, Paper Prepared for Workshop on Reflections on the Agricultural Challenges Post 2020 in the EU: Preparing the next CAP Reform. Brussels: European Parliament, Directorate General for Internal Policies Matthews, Alan (2017), The budgetary context for the CAP, blog article, CAPreform.eu Monti, Mario et al (2016), Future financing of the EU. Final report and recommendations of the high level group on own resources, Brussels, December 2016 Núñez Ferrer, Jorge and Rinaldi, David (2016), The Impact of Brexit on the EU Budget: A non-catastrophic even, CEPS Policy Brief No. 347 Núñez Ferrer, Jorge and Rinaldi, David (2016), The Impact of Brexit on the EU Budget: A non-catastrophic even, CEPS Policy Brief No. 347 Roberto Henke et. al. (2015), Implementation of the first pillar of the CAP in the EU Member States, study requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development Von Cramon-Taubadel, S., and Heinemann, F. (2017), The EU s Common Agricultural Policy. Why reform is overdue, Bertelsmann Stiftung, Policy Brief 40

45 DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT Research for AGRI Committee - EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit STUDY Abstract This report analyzes current UK-EU27 agri-food trade, and quantifies the impacts of a return to WTO rules after Brexit. Agri-food trade is likely to decrease steeply, especially for meat and dairy sectors. However, there might be an opportunity for an increase in production in a reduced number of European sectors, such as red meat, cattle or wheat, to replace imports from the UK. More generally, Ireland is likely to be the most negatively impacted country and deserves particular attention during the Brexit process. IP/B/AGRI/IC/ October 2017 PE EN

46 This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development. AUTHORS Centre d Études Prospectives et d Informations Internationales (CEPII): Cecilia BELLORA, Charlotte EMLINGER, Jean FOURÉ, Houssein GUIMBARD Research manager: Albert Massot Project and publication assistance: Virginija Kelmelytė Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies, European Parliament LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE PUBLISHER To contact the Policy Department or to subscribe to updates on our work for the AGRI Committee please write to: Poldep-cohesion@ep.europa.eu Manuscript completed in October 2017 European Union, 2017 Additional materials are available on the website of the CEPII: Please use the following reference to cite this study: Bellora, C., Emlinger, C., Fouré, J. And Guimbard, H. (2017), Research for AGRI Committee, EU UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit, European Parliament, Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies, Brussels Please use the following reference for in-text citations: Bellora et al. (2017) DISCLAIMER The opinions expressed in this document are the sole responsibility of the author and do not necessarily represent the official position of the European Parliament. Reproduction and translation for non-commercial purposes are authorized, provided the source is acknowledged and the publisher is given prior notice and sent a copy.

47 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit BRIEF PROFESSIONAL DESCRIPTION The authors of this document are economists at the CEPII (Centre d Études Prospectives et Informations Internationales, a French research center on international economics). Cecilia BELLORA currently works on international trade policies and on the links between international trade and the environment. She holds a PhD in economics (University of Cergy-Pontoise, France). She previously worked for a think-tank in the field of agricultural development and then at the French National Institute for Agronomic Research (INRA). Charlotte EMLINGER is working on trade analysis with a special focus on agricultural trade and policies. Her main research topics concern quality specialization, the role of intermediaries in trade, and the impact of trade agreements. She's also in charge of the CEPII trade database. She holds a PhD in economics on Montpellier SupAgro-University of Montpellier 1 (France). Jean FOURÉ works on the computable general equilibrium (CGE) model MIRAGE (trade and environment policy analysis) and develops the longterm growth model MaGE (EconMap database). Jean Fouré graduated from the École Polytechnique and the École Nationale de Statistique et de l'administration Économique (ENSAE) in Houssein GUIMBARD holds an MPhil in environmental economics and natural resources (AgroParisTech, Paris, France). He works on CGE models and their application to international trade. His fields of interest are regionalism and trade policies. 43

48 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 44

49 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit CONTENTS LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS 47 LIST OF TABLES 49 LIST OF FIGURES 50 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 51 INTRODUCTION IMPACT ASSESSMENTS OF EXIT FROM EUROPE EUROPEAN UNION AND UNITED KINGDOM BILATERAL TRADE: STATISTICAL OVERVIEW Macro-economic indicators: a marked dissymmetry Trade protection Tariffs: increase to their MFN level Non-tariff measures (NTMs): increase in their trade-restrictiveness Trade flows Main trading sectors potentially impacted: processed food, dairy and meat Main European trading countries: France, Netherlands and the particular case of Ireland High integration of agri-food value chains through trade MODEL AND SCENARIOS Modelling framework Scenarios The WTO scenario Alternative specifications and sensitivity analysis IMPACTS OF A WTO SCENARIO ON THE AGRI-FOOD SECTOR IN THE EUROPEAN UNION A large decrease in EU27-UK agri-food trade flows unevenly distributed across sectors and EU27 countries Strong decrease in EU27 exports to UK, compensated by exports to other countries only in a few sectors EU27 agri-food imports from the UK: same mechanisms as for imports Most impacted EU27 exporters: the Netherlands, France and Ireland Agri-food value-added decreases within the EU27, though exposure of countries is heterogeneous Agri-food value-added in the EU27: large negative impact in Ireland, very limited in other EU27 countries Decomposition of the impacts on value-added in the EU27: losses from the Brexit are only partly compensated by exports to other countries 77 45

50 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 4.3. At the macroeconomic level, the impact on EU27 countries is marginal, except for Ireland CONCLUDING REMARKS 81 REFERENCES 83 ANNEX A: DATA 87 ANNEX B: MODEL DESCRIPTION 89 ANNEX C: ADDITIONAL TABLES 95 ANNEX D: ADDITIONAL TABLES HS6 DETAILS

51 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS AVE Ad Valorem Equivalent BAU Business-as-usual, the reference scenario without trade policy shock CAP Common Agricultural Policy CES Constant Elasticity of Substitution EU European Union EU27 European Union, with 27 Member States (Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Coratia, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden) GDP Gross Domestic Product GTAP Global Trade Analysis Project HS6 United Nations Harmonized System 6-digits classification MAcMap-HS6 Market Access Map HS6 database MIRAGE Modelling International Relationships in Applied General Equilibrium NEC Not Elsewhere Classified NES Not Elsewhere Specified NTM Non-tariff measure SAM Social Accounting Matrix UK United Kingdom WTO World Trade Organization 47

52 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 48

53 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit LIST OF TABLES TABLE 1 Market size, EU27 (and its first ten Member States, by GDP value) and UK (2016) 58 TABLE 2 Trade flows and protection, EU27 UK 59 TABLE 3 Main export destinations, of the EU27 and the UK, total trade 60 TABLE 4 EU27 exports to the UK in agri-food sectors and faced protection 62 TABLE 5 EU27 imports from the UK in agri-food sectors and faced protection 63 TABLE 6 EU27 exports to the UK in agri-food sectors and faced protection, by country (top ten, by protection revenue) 64 TABLE 7 EU27 imports from the UK in agri-food sectors and faced protection, by country (top ten, by protection revenue) 65 TABLE 8 UK value-added in EU27 exports (% of gross export of EU27 countries) 66 TABLE 9 Breakdown of the value-added contained in exports of UK, by origin 67 TABLE 10 Variations in consumption and production price indexes for agri-food goods and all goods in the WTO scenario, TABLE B. 1 Aggregation of regions 90 TABLE B. 2 Aggregation of sectors 92 TABLE B. 3 Reduction in intra-eu trade restrictiveness of NTMs 93 TABLE C. 1 EU sector exports by destination and ranked by largest decrease in exports towards the world, WTO scenario, TABLE C. 2 EU subregions export to UK in Agri-food sectors: aggregate and three sectors with the largest variations, TABLE C. 3 Agri-food value-added in EU regions, in the WTO scenario: aggregate, five most impacted sectors and decomposition of variation, TABLE C. 4 Gross Domestic Product (volume) and variation in

54 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies TABLE D.1 Number of HS6 products, by GTAP sector 101 TABLE D.2 EU27 imports, HS6 level (1/2) 102 TABLE D.3 EU27 imports, HS6 level (2/2) 103 TABLE D.4 EU27 exports, HS6 level (1/2) 104 TABLE D.5 EU27 exports, HS6 level (2/2) 105 LIST OF FIGURES FIGURE 1 Variations in EU27 export volume to the UK, by sector, FIGURE 2 Variations in aggregate EU27 imports volume from the UK, by sector, FIGURE 3 Variations in EU27 agri-food exports to the UK, by country, FIGURE 4 Variations in total agri-food value-added by EU27 country and UK, FIGURE 5 Variations in agri-food value-added volume and decomposition by source in the WTO scenario,

55 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This document first presents the current state of the trade relationship between the European Union (EU27) and the United Kingdom (UK). It then produces a quantitative impact assessment of the UK s withdrawal from the EU27, with a specific focus on agri-food sectors. The main scenario assumes that (i) MFN tariffs will be imposed on bilateral trade in goods between the EU27 and the UK and (ii) the trade-restrictiveness of non-tariff measures will increase. In the absence of a consensual scenario regarding public policies other than those concerning the trade policy mentioned above, the status quo is assumed. In other terms, redistributive policies that could mitigate Brexit s negative impacts are not contemplated in our scenarios and no change in the Common Agricultural Policy is assumed. Results are given by the computable general equilibrium model developed by the CEPII, MIRAGE, and are expressed as a deviation from a baseline, in The key-findings are the following: The relationship between the UK and the EU27 is characterized by a marked dissymmetry. The EU27, as a whole, is a large market (more than 445 million inhabitants and a GDP of USD 13.8 thousand billion in 2016), while the UK is relatively smaller (a population of 65.6 million people and a GDP of USD 2.6 thousand billion). Thus, the EU27 represents a large market and outlet for UK exporters, while the UK is, in comparison, a small market for EU27 (even if it represents the main export destination of some agri-food sectors in given EU27 countries). For these reasons, macroeconomic impacts on the UK are significantly larger (e.g. -2.3% in GDP) than for EU27 (-0.3%). Nevertheless, the UK is currently the second largest EU28 country and is highly integrated with the EU27 in terms of trade and value chains. As a result, all the EU27 countries will be negatively affected by Brexit, the magnitude of the impact increasing with economic proximity to the UK. Ireland in particular (-3.4% in GDP, USD billion), and to a much lesser extent Belgium and Luxembourg (-0.7%) and the Netherlands (-0.5%), are the most affected countries. Agri-food products are less traded than manufactured ones and contribute less in total GDP. They will face however the largest increases in trade protection, both in terms of tariffs and non-tariff measures. Agri-food exports of the EU27 to the UK will decrease by USD 34 billion (62%) and imports by USD 19 billion (with the same relative decrease, 62%). Trade diversion will take place; part of the decrease in exports to the UK will be compensated by an increase in intra-eu27 trade (+1%) as well as in exports to third countries (+0.9%). This is partly explained by a loss of UK s competitiveness, due to higher prices of imported intermediary consumptions. In the end, agri-food exports of the EU27 to the world will decrease by 4.1% (USD -27 billion). The most affected sectors (in value terms) are processed food (USD billion, -4.7%), 46 which is also the most exported (33% of EU27 agri-food exports), white meat (USD -5.2 billion, %) and dairy (USD -4.6 billion, -7%). The Netherlands (USD -6.7 billion, -66%), Ireland (USD -6.5 billion, -71%) and France (USD -4.7 billion, -51%) undergo the largest drops in exports. Agri-food production and value added are also affected by trade with other countries as well as domestic demand. The relative magnitude of each of these effects (bilateral trade with the UK, trade with third countries and domestic demand) varies across countries and sectors and determines Brexit s impact heterogeneity. In the UK, agrifood value-added increases (+2%), mainly because local production partially 46 These numbers correspond to the impacts on the most affected sector producing processed food, identified as Other food in the simulation results. 51

56 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies substitutes imports from the EU27. This takes place at consumers expense since consumption prices increase by 4%. In the EU27 as a whole, agri-food value-added decreases by 0.8%; the increase in exports to third countries and in intra-eu trade do not compensate for the loss of exports to UK. Even if in all EU27 countries, overall agrifood value-added decreases, some sectors like Red meat (+2.1%) and Cattle (+1.3%) in France gain thanks to their capacity to fulfill the domestic demand, replacing imports from the UK. The wheat sector in France is one of the few where value added increases (+1.7%) thanks to an increase in exports to other EU countries. The fall in agri-food value-added is particularly large in Ireland (-16%, with a collapse in white meat, - 58%), because of the decrease in exports to UK but also to general equilibrium effects leading to a strong decrease in domestic demand. Because of its tight relationship with the UK, of all EU27 countries, Ireland is affected the most by Brexit, and not only in agri-food sectors. In relative terms, its GDP decreases even more than UK's GDP (-3.4% vs -2.4%). This is explained by a drop in Irish agri-food exports to the UK and to the rest of the World, including EU27 countries as Irish production relies heavily on imported intermediates from the UK. 52

57 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit INTRODUCTION In March 2017, the United Kingdom (UK) Government notified the European Council of its intention to withdraw from the European Union (EU). Negotiations on the modalities of Brexit have started and should not exceed two years, after which the withdrawal should be effective, as stipulated by the Treaty on European Union. Agri-food sectors do not contribute much to national GDPs or bilateral trade flows (11% of EU27 exports to the UK in value), but the stakes are nevertheless high. The UK is an important destination for EU27 exports with a highly favorable agricultural trade balance with the UK (USD 29 billion).47 Trade protection that could apply on agri-food goods in the absence of a free trade agreement is particularly high (64%, to be compared with 26% before Brexit, taking into accounts both tariffs and NTMs). Furthermore, agricultural production is managed at the European level by the Common Agricultural Policy, which benefits from one of the largest European budgets ( 59 billion per year). This common policy relies partly on UK contributions and constitutes a significant support to farmers revenues. In other words, agriculture and the food industry are an offensive interest for EU27 and an important subject for the UK, which depends on imports from the EU27. The UK negotiating position will therefore depend on the weight it will give to farmers or consumers interests (Grant et al., 2015; Lang, 2016; Potton and Webb, 2017). For the time being, the specific modalities of the post-brexit EU27-UK relationship are unknown. The future of agricultural policies in the UK is naturally one of the main uncertainties. In terms of agri-food trade, which is our main focus, the issues are manifold. We briefly summarize below the main ones: Tariffs: Tariffs between the EU27 and the UK have to be determined during Brexit negotiations. The future of preferential access to third markets is also uncertain for the UK. Molinuevo (2017) suggests that trade agreements signed by the EU that concern only goods will not be binding anymore for the UK. This implies that the UK will have to negotiate its own preferential tariffs. Among these agreements, the EU- Turkey is the most important. The situation of other (mixed) trade agreements signed by the EU is more complex and uncertain. The UK could also negotiate trade agreements with new partners, the United States, for instance. These negotiations could have an impact on EU27 exports to the UK and to third countries, due to trade diversion effects. Tariff Rate Quotas (TRQs): What will happen to European TRQs after Brexit is crucial in relation to agricultural products. The EU27 and the UK have already agreed to divide existing (import) commitments within the WTO based on historical trade flows, since TRQs were negotiated by the European Commission on behalf of all EU member states. The agreement is however likely to be challenged by EU and UK partners. The uncertainty concerns also EU preferential (export) TRQs in third countries that are part of preferential agreements. Since TRQs are not currently allocated by member states (they are allocated on a first-come, first-served basis), the partition of the quotas could be particularly complex (Revells, 2017; Downes, 2017). The size of these TRQs is a major concern both for UK and EU27 farmers, especially in the livestock sector. Non Tariff Measures (NTMs): Currently, the trade restrictiveness of NTMs (e.g. sanitary and phytosanitary standards, technical barriers, certification procedures, etc.) within the EU is fairly limited, since many of these measures are common to all member states. After Brexit, any new NTM adopted without coordination between the EU27 and the UK will probably have a negative impact on bilateral trade. Furthermore, UK s exit from the EU will involve more border and custom controls, increasing in consequence prices of EU exports to the UK and of EU imports from the UK. 47 Average year value over the period

58 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Geographical Indications (GIs): In some sectors (in particular animal productions, wine and spirits, and fruit and vegetables), maintaining protection for food names is an important stake. Exit from the EU could potentially result in loss of protection for food names (or GIs) in the UK, the European 48 and third countries markets that recognize GIs (Roussel and Doherty, 2016). The UK will need to establish its own national approval scheme in order to protect these GIs. In addition to these elements that both the EU27 and the UK will have to manage, issues on rules of origin (RoO) and bargaining power after Brexit will also influence the UK negotiating position: The question of bargaining power is posed both when we consider UK access to EU27 and third countries markets. The UK will not be involved anymore in the negotiations over the definition of new European norms and regulations. However, to lower the trade restrictiveness of future European NTMs, the UK could decide to continue following European standards, loosing part of the benefits of its independence. The UK, a relatively small country, would also lose bargaining power in trade negotiations with third countries, which could potentially take a long time. Rules of Origin: The rules of origin determine where (in which country) a product and its components have to be produced to benefit from preferential tariffs. Even if the EU27 and the UK reach a trade agreement, many products the UK exports to EU27 would not be eligible anymore to preferential access (if value chains remain unchanged), not enough value added being produced in the UK. More generally, compliance with European RoO requirements potentially could entail additional administrative costs for exporting to the EU in general, and particularly in the case of agri-food sectors, which are closely integrated in EU supply chains (Baker and Swales, 2016; UK House of Lords, 2016). The same problem could arise for the EU27, but most likely to a lesser extent. Future negotiations between the EU27 and the UK encompass several different aspects, not exclusively trade related. In order to evaluate possible outcomes, the European Parliament Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development commissioned to the CEPII/CIREM an analysis of the current state of UK - EU27 agri-food trade and the possible impacts of Brexit. Given the high uncertainty on the outcome of trade negotiations, the application of Most Favoured Nation (MFN) tariffs to bilateral trade between the UK and the EU27, as well as an increase in the trade restrictiveness of bilateral NTMs is the scenario retained to evaluate Brexit's impacts. Considering that a sector-by-sector negotiation is excluded, the impact assessment is conducted with a computable general equilibrium model, that accounts for direct trade impacts of the increased trade protection (not only on agri-food sectors but on all goods and services). The model also takes into consideration indirect trade impacts, due, for instance, to trade diversion brought about by changes in relative prices, and for general equilibrium effects triggered by changes in total revenues at the global level. In the following, we first depict the current state of agri-food trade between the UK and the EU27, relative to trade in manufactured goods and to total European trade. Differences across European member states and sectors are stressed. Then, the impacts on trade and valueadded of a scenario in which no trade deal would be reached by the EU27 and the UK are simulated and analyzed, as well as its macroeconomic consequences, taking into account the limitations of the model and the scenario adopted. Finally, a number of policy recommendations are drawn. 48 Products of UK presently enjoying protection in the UE27 include Melton Mowbray pork pies, Cornish pasties, Yorkshire Wensleydale cheese, Welsh beef, Welsh lamb, Armagh bramley apples and Scotch whisky. 54

59 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit 1. IMPACT ASSESSMENTS OF EXIT FROM EUROPE Several studies were conducted before and after the referendum, to evaluate the potential economic impact of Brexit. Ex ante analyses include both academic and non-academic works, and use different approaches. Ottaviano et al. (2014) and Aichele and Felbermayr (2015) use standard quantitative static general equilibrium trade models à la Arkolakis, Costinot and Rodriguez-Clare (2012) based on a gravity model, to estimate the effect on the UK economy of leaving the EU. Ebell et al. (2016) evaluate the long-run macroeconomic impact of Brexit by employing a large scale structural global econometric model (NiGEM), while Brakman et al. (2017), HM Treasury (2016) and Connell et al. (2017) use gravity models to assess the effects on trade of Brexit. Computable general equilibrium models are the most commonly approaches used to predict the effect of Brexit on trade, value added and real income (see, e.g., Booth et al., 2015; Ciuriak et al., 2015; PwC, 2016; Rojas-Romagosa, 2016; Boulanger and Philippidis, 2015), while Davies and Studnicka (2017) and Hosoe (2016) discuss the potential impact of Brexit, employing general equilibrium models accounting for firm heterogeneity à la Melitz (2013). These works vary in their methodological approaches and in terms of scenarios and focus, which makes it difficult to compare their output. Almost all these studies evaluate and compare the impacts of a hard and a soft Brexit (corresponding to a WTO scenario, and a UK-EU FTA in various balances); some focus on the impact of non-tariff measures and dynamic effects (Aichele and Felbermayr, 2015), others focus more on the post-brexit trade policy that the UK should adopt (Ciuriak et al., 2015), or the role of global value chains (Connell et al., 2017). 49 It is important to note that overall, in the available studies, the main focus is the impact of Brexit on the UK economy, with little attention paid to the effects on EU members. The exceptions are Bergin et al. (2016), Barett et al. (2015) and Rojas-Romagosa (2016) which analyze the impact of Brexit on the Netherlands and Ireland. Lawless and Morgenroth (2016) compare trade and tariffs data to discuss the effect of Brexit on EU trade, and using sector level elasticity estimates they compute the tariff-induced price increases and trade reductions that might result from Brexit. In almost all these works, Brexit is shown to have substantial negative impacts, for both the UK and the EU. The impact on British GDP ranges from -7% to -0.1%, depending on the assumptions made and the scenarios considered (see Bush and Matthes, 2016, for a review and a meta-analysis of the macroeconomic impacts of Brexit). All of these studies find that the most negative outcome would result from failure of the UK and the EU27 to negotiate the terms of the UK s exit, i.e., if they are unable to strike a trade agreement and apply WTO tariffs to their bilateral trade. Studies focusing on the agricultural sector are relatively scarce, and essentially, evaluate the impact of Brexit on British agriculture, using descriptive evidence on trade, production and tariffs (Buckwell, 2016; Potton, 2017; Grant et al., 2015; Lang, 2015), or partial equilibrium modeling frameworks as in Davis et al. (2017) and Van Berkum et al. (2016). Davis et al. (2017) illustrate the heterogeneous impacts that Brexit could have on the UK s agricultural sectors. They combine two partial equilibrium models, FAPRI-UK and FAPRI-EU, to examine different trade arrangements and show that imposing WTO tariffs on UK EU bilateral trade would have a significant impact on the UK domestic market, with the magnitude of this impact across sectors depending on the trade balance in each sector. Imposing tariffs on those products that are mostly imported, e.g. dairy, pig and poultry products, by reducing import volumes, would have a positive impact on UK domestic prices, and a resulting positive effect 49 Connell et al. (2017) show that including sector-level input-output linkages in production using WIOD data in gravity estimates increases the losses to the UK induced by Brexit. 55

60 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies on production. Van Berkum et al. (2016), in their study, focus more on the public policies that the UK might adopt to cope with Brexit. Using the AGMEMOD partial equilibrium model, they conduct a sector analysis and assess the impacts on trade and farm incomes according to different UK agricultural policy scenarios. Donnellan and Hanrahan (2016) use the FAPRI- Ireland model to evaluate the potential impact of Brexit. Although their main focus is Ireland, they find notable negative impacts for the EU agri-food sector overall, and in some sectors and member states in particular (beef, dairy and lamb for Ireland, pig and dairy for Denmark, vegetables for the Netherlands and wine for France, Spain and Italy). Baker et al. (2017) also use partial equilibrium model to assess the impact of Brexit on farmers income. They show that farm business income benefits from the Brexit, through higher prices, in the dairy and pig sector. On the other hand, producers of cereals and sheep meat will experience income reduction due to rising costs of trade to export to the EU. This result is consistent with, Freund et al. (2017) who show with the MAGNET CGE model that the impacts of Brexit is negative for UK, with the most pronounced effects in the meat and livestock sectors. Using general Equilibrium models to assess the impact of the Brexit on Agriculture allows to take the budget question into account. This issue is particularly crucial as the exit of UK from the EU will also entail a withdrawal from the CAP that would results in budget saving for UK. Thus, Boulanger and Philippidis (2015) show that these gains exceed trade facilitation costs on agrifood trade. 56

61 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit 2. EUROPEAN UNION AND UNITED KINGDOM BILATERAL TRADE: STATISTICAL OVERVIEW KEY FINDINGS The relationship between the EU27 and the UK is marked by dissymmetry: the EU27 is a large market (445 million inhabitants, GDP of USD 13,800 billion), while the UK is a relatively small country (65.6 million people, GDP of USD 2,600billion). In the absence of any trade agreement stating otherwise, MFN tariffs will apply to bilateral trade flows between the EU27 and the UK, and NTMs will increase in the long term. Protection faced by EU27 exports to UK will be slightly higher than protection faced by UK exports to EU27: MFN of 18.3% and NTMs of 45.4% for EU27 agri-food exports and MFN of 14.2% and NTMs of 39.9% for UK agri-food exports. Agri-food goods represent 11% of bilateral trade flows between the UK and the EU27. The EU27 s trade balance with the UK is positive: USD 47 billion worth of agricultural goods are exported to the UK, compared to USD 18 billion worth of agricultural imports. We rank sectors and countries by trade value weighted by potential protection, to highlight those potentially most impacted by Brexit. The three main EU27 agri-food sectors are processed food, dairy and meat (for both exports to and imports from UK). The EU27 countries that trade the most with the UK and will face the highest protection are France, Netherlands and Ireland. The situation of Ireland deserves particular attention. Its trade with the UK plays an important role, especially imports: 27% of Ireland s European imports are from the UK, and represent 46% of total Irish agri-food imports (compared to 4% on average for other European countries). Disruptions caused by Brexit may have particularly negative impacts on this country because of the large integration of UK products in Ireland s exports Macro-economic indicators: a marked dissymmetry The relationship between the UK and the EU27 is characterized by a marked dissymmetry. The EU27, as a whole, is a large market with more than 445 million inhabitants and GDP of USD 13.8 thousand billion, while the UK is a relatively small country, with a population of 65.6 million people and a GDP of USD 2.6 thousand billion (see Table 1). Thus, the EU represents a very large market and outlet for UK exporters, while the UK, even though integrated with the EU in terms of trade and value chains, and with a large GDP per capita, is a relatively small market for European exporters in comparison. 50 However, among the EU28, the UK is a large country: it is ranked third after Germany and France for number of inhabitants and second after Germany for GDP. Its GDP per capita is among the highest in this group, 33% higher than the EU27 average. This foreshadows large redistributions of economic activity across the EU Sector and country specificities are discussed later but note that UK is nevertheless an important export market for some sectors. For instance, 12% of French exports of vegetables and fruits go to UK (10% for Spanish exports) as well as 14% of French vegetables oils and fats. 57

62 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Table 2: Market size, EU27 (and its first ten Member States, by GDP value) and UK (2016) Country GDP (USD bn) GDP per capita (USD) Population (mn people) United Kingdom 2,619 39, EU27 13,779 30, Germany 3,467 41, France 2,465 36, Italy 1,850 30, Spain 1,232 26, Netherlands , Sweden , Poland , Belgium , Austria , Denmark , Source: World Development Indicators, The World Bank, Authors calculations Trade protection Tariffs: increase to their MFN level Once the UK leaves the EU, if no relevant trade agreement has been signed to the contrary, the MFN tariff will apply to bilateral trade between the UK and the EU27. Although MFN tariffs are the same across all EU countries, faced protection will depend on the trade patterns of each individual trade partner. For instance, a very high tariff imposed on a product that is not traded at all is less restrictive than a lower tariff on a much more traded good. The way applied protection is computed is detailed in Bouët et al. (2008). As a result, the average MFN duty that EU27 could apply to imports from the UK is 18.3% and 3.2% for agricultural and manufactured goods respectively, while EU exports could face respective average tariffs of 14.2% and 2.6% (Table 2). Agricultural products benefits from a higher MFN protection. This reflects the importance of sensitive sectors such as sugar, bovine products (meat and dairy) and animal products more generally (see Tables 4 and 5) Non-tariff measures (NTMs): increase in their trade-restrictiveness NTMs arguably play a dominant role in restraining imports. Table 2 shows that NTMs follow the same general pattern as protection used by European countries, being more restrictive in the case of agricultural goods compared to manufactured products. Thus, EU27 agriculture exports to the UK face average NTMs trade restrictiveness of 26.01% (14.37% for industrial goods), slightly higher than those imposed by the EU27 on UK exports (22.78% and 13.37%, for agriculture and manufactured goods, respectively). 58

63 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit In the absence of any agreement between the EU27 and the UK after Brexit, new technical and non-technical measures applied by the two regions will probably diverge in the mid-term, accounting for different consumer preferences and trade policies. In the short term, certification procedures will be more complex with the end of the common market and antidumping procedures (or other temporary measures) could be applied to bilateral trade flows. This will result in NTMs whose trade restrictiveness will increase over time. It is difficult to quantify the extent of this increase but it is important to take it into account since NTMs represent the main trade protection. Table 2 reports the values used in the simulation exercises for present and 2030 projected trade restrictiveness of NTMs. These values for NTMs trade restrictiveness are documented in Annex B (pre-brexit NTMs) and Section 4.2 (post- Brexit NTMs). Table 3: Trade flows and protection, EU27 UK Trade flows Protection Value (USD million) %of EU trade %of world trade NTMs pre Brexit (%) MFN (%) NTMs post Brexit (%) EU exports Non Agric. goods 305, Agric. goods 47, Total 353, EU imports Non Agric. goods 196, Agric. goods 17, Total 214, Source: Authors calculations based on tariffs from MAcMap-HS6, NTMs from Kee et al. (2009) and trade from BACI (see Annex A for details on data sources). Note: Trade flows are mean values for the period Current tariff protection is not reported since it does not apply. The AVEs of the MFN tariffs refer to Two NTM values are reported, present AVE and projected AVE in the absence of a specific trade agreement when the UK leaves the EU Trade flows The UK is the second largest (after the USA) EU export market (worth USD 353 billion, and 6.9% of EU exports, annual trade flow, average over the period , see Table 3) in trade value; EU trade is mainly among members. At the same time, the EU27 is the UK s largest export market (USD 214 billion and 46% of UK exports). Trade consists mostly of non-agricultural goods (i.e., goods that are not covered by the WTO Agreement on Agriculture 51 ), agri-food representing only 11% of trade flows. This structure of more manufactured goods than agricultural goods is not a specificity of the trade relationship with the UK but reflects a pattern that is common to most developed countries. 51 The exact product coverage is provided in Annex I of the Agreement on Agriculture: 59

64 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies The EU27 s trade balance with the UK is positive for both manufactured and agricultural goods. 52 USD 47 billion worth of agricultural goods are exported to the UK, compared to USD 18 billion worth of agricultural imports. Additionally, the share of exports to the UK in total EU exports is larger than the share of imports, and especially in the case of agricultural goods (8.8% vs. 3.8%); also, the protection applied to exports (44.3% for agriculture) is higher than that imposed on imports (37% for agriculture). The combination of these three elements (positive trade balance, larger trade share, and protection), means that larger impacts can be expected on European exports (producers) compared to European imports (consumers). Table 4: Main export destinations of EU27 and UK, total trade EXPORTER: EU27 EXPORTER: UK IMPORTER VALUE (USD mn) % TOT EXPORTS IMPORTER VALUE (USD mn) % TOT EXPORTS EU27 2,789, EU27 214, UK 353, USA 52, USA 341, Switzerland 25, China 184, China 24, Switzerland 145, Un. Arab Emirates 12, Russia 116, Hong Kong 10, Turkey 86, Canada 7, Japan 67, Saudi Arabia 7, Rep. of Korea 53, Rep. of Korea 6, Norway 52, Japan 6, Source: Authors calculations, using BACI. Note: Trade flows are mean values over the period , for all goods (agri-food and manufacture) Main trading sectors potentially impacted: processed food, dairy and meat. In the context of agriculture, the most traded products between the EU27 and the UK, by value, are processed food products 53, beverages and meat and dairy products. However, to estimate the impact of Brexit, it is relevant to also consider the protection faced by trade flows. Therefore, we sort sectors by trade flow value multiplied by potential ad valorem protection, were MFN and more restrictive NTMs to be applied, resulting in what we describe in what follows as Protection Revenue. We also investigate trade patterns in more depth using information available at the HS6 level (the statistics at HS6 level are presented in Appendix D, see Annex A.4 for details on data sources). 52 For the sake of comparison, total UK trade imbalance amounts to 29 billion per year on average over the period (source: Eurostat) 53 The Other food sector discussed here is unfortunately a residual sector in the original GTAP database, gathering all processed food not classified elsewhere (i.e. different from vegetal oils, processed rice and sugar or dairy products). 60

65 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit Processed food products represent the main export flow to the UK and the most heavily protected amounting to almost USD 17 billion, representing 10% of European food exports (see Table 4). At the HS6 level, the most protected goods which would generate the highest revenue within the processed food sectors are dog and cat food, France is the biggest exporter to the UK (25%) in these sectors, followed by various animal feed preparations (France, 20%). Imports of communion wafers, rice paper and baking materials from Germany (23%) have an export value of over USD 1.5 billion but attract a fairly low MFN tariff of 5.5%. The next export sectors after processed food ranked by protection revenue are Dairy products and Meat products n.e.c. Despite their smaller flows in terms of value, these two sectors are ranked second and third since they would face very high levels of protection, with MFN duty of around 40% and NTMs increasing from 42% to 74% for dairy, and MFN of 22% and NTMs of 43% for meat products. In each of these sectors, exports to UK represent around 10% of total EU exports. In relation to dairy products, Ireland and France are the main exporters of what are likely to be most heavily affected HS6 products, such as cheese, fresh cheese, butter, buttermilk and some processed cheese. The GTAP category Meat Products is a residual category which includes all meat products not included in other GTAP sectors. It thus includes a variety of different products, some of which account for a significant part of European exports, e.g. swine meat, poultry, cuts and offal (frozen and fresh), swine cuts, sausages, meat offal and blood. The main exporters to the UK of these products are Denmark, the Netherlands and Germany. Beverages and tobacco, and Vegetables and fruit are ranked respectively fourth and fifth for the most affected export products. Czech Republic exports one-third of the first HS6 product (cigarettes containing tobacco) in the Beverages and tobacco category. France ranks second accounting for almost 50% of exports of grape wines n.e.s. Netherlands is another important exporter, ranking first for non-alcoholic beverages (excluding vegetable and fruit juices), denatured ethyl alcohol and cigarette-pipe tobacco. Finally, the European trade flows at the HS6 level that will suffer the most in the Vegetables and fruit sector are tomatoes, cucumbers and gherkins, mushrooms, mandarins, clementines and citrus hybrids, cauliflowers and headed broccoli. The Netherlands is an important exporter to the UK of the first two products (48% and 55% of European exports), Ireland is the main exporter of mushrooms (55%) and Spain s exports to the UK of cauliflowers and broccoli amount to 88% and 79% of the total. EU imports from UK follow a similar pattern (see Table 5). The main imported products, by value, are food products and beverages; however, if value is weighted by protection, dairy products, bovine meat and other meat products are among the most heavily affected products, because of the high level of protection they attract. For instance, the AVE protection would be of more than 130% for dairy products if both MFN and NTMs are considered. As already mentioned, the EU27 s reliance on UK imports is less significant than their reliance on exports to the UK: for the first five sectors in Table 5, imports from the UK represent between 8% and 3% of total European imports in the sector considered. Table 7 shows that Ireland will be the most heavily affected country, as discussed more in details in the following section, since it is the main importer of HS6 products within the beverages and tobacco, the dairy and the bovine meat categories In particular, Ireland is the main importer of cigarettes containing tobacco, water and non-alcoholic beverages n.e.s. (beverages and tobacco sector), milk not concentrated, cheese, fresh cheese and powdered milk and cream (dairy sector). In the bovine meat sector, Ireland import almost one-third of UK exports of boneless, fresh or chilled bovine cuts, and France imports 65% of fresh and chilled lamb carcasses and half carcasses. 61

66 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Table 5: EU27 exports to the UK in agri-food sectors and faced protection TRADE PROTECTION SECTOR TRADE VALUE % of EU TRADE NTMs (%, pre Brexit) MFN (%) NTMs (%, post Brexit) PROT. REV. Food products nec 16, ,773 Dairy products 4, ,717 Meat products nec 5, ,808 Beverages and tobacco products 7, ,749 Vegetables fruit nuts 5, ,243 Bovine meat products 1, ,489 Vegetable oils and fats 1, Crops nec 1, Processed rice Bovine cattle, sheep and goats, horses Sugar Animal products nec Cereal grains nec Fishing Wheat Oil seeds Forestry Paddy Rice Sugar cane sugar beet Wool silk worm cocoons Source: Authors calculations based on tariffs from MAcMap-HS6, NTMs from Kee et al. (2009) and trade from BACI. Note: Trade flows are mean values for the period Current tariff protection is not reported since it does not apply. The AVEs of the MFN tariffs refer to Two NTM values are reported, present AVE and projected AVE in the absence of a specific trade agreement when the UK leaves the EU. 62

67 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit Table 6: EU27 imports from the UK in agri-food sectors and faced protection TRADE PROTECTION SECTOR TRADE VALUE % of EU TRADE NTMs (%, pre Brexit) MFN (%) NTMs (%, post Brexit) PROT. REV. Food products nec 6, ,944 Dairy products 1, ,974 Bovine meat products 1, ,127 Meat products nec 1, Beverages and tobacco products 4, Sugar Vegetable oils and fats Vegetables fruit nuts Fishing Bovine cattle sheep and goats horses Animal products nec Crops nec Cereal grains nec Processed rice Oil seeds Wheat Forestry Paddy Rice Sugar cane sugar beet Wool silk worm cocoons Source: Authors calculations based on tariffs from MAcMap-HS6, NTMs from Kee et al. (2009) and trade from BACI. Note: Trade flows are mean values for the period Current tariff protection is not reported since it does not apply. The AVEs of the MFN tariffs refer to Two NTM values are reported, present AVE and projected AVE in the absence of a specific trade agreement when the UK leaves the EU Main European trading countries: France, Netherlands and the particular case of Ireland If we consider total trade rather than just agri-food, the European countries that trade the most with the UK, and which will be most affected by Brexit, are Germany, the Netherlands and France. These countries bilateral trade with the UK represents 50% of total EU27 bilateral exchanges. This ranking is unchanged if we consider exports and imports separately. 63

68 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Ireland is in a particular position as noted above. Ireland is ranked fifth behind Belgium, as a European trading partner of the UK. Ireland s exports to the UK represent some USD 19 billion a year, and it is the seventh European exporter to UK by value, representing around 5% of European exports. In terms of imports, Ireland is more important: it is the fourth most important importer by value (USD 23.4 bn.) and its weight in European imports is larger (11%) than for exports. What is striking is the share of these flows in Ireland s total trade flows: Irish exports to the UK represents 13% of Ireland s total exports (compared to around 4% for the main European exporters to the UK), and 31% of Irish imports come from the UK. In the light of the important role of the UK as a destination market and as a source of imports, the impact of Brexit on Irish trade and the Irish economy will likely be very large. When considering only agri-food trade (see Table 6 and Table 7), France and the Netherlands are the main UK partners, and Ireland replaces Germany in the top three by bilateral trade value. The three main partners account for half of UK imports and exports in the agri-food sectors. Again, trade with the UK is highly important for Ireland, especially imports: 27% of Ireland s European imports are from the UK, and represent 46% of total Irish agri-food imports (compared to 4% on average for other European countries). However, although Irish exports represent 15% of European agri-food exports to UK, they account for less than 5% of total Irish agri-food imports which, nevertheless, is higher than other European countries. Combining country and sector details does not introduce different sectors in the list of top traded goods: the main importers and exporters trade mainly in processed food, dairy and meat products, and beverages and tobacco. The pattern at country level is in line with the pattern in Table 5: trade in dairy and meat products frequently follows trade in beverages for value although the former are likely to be more affected by high protection. Table 7: EU27 exports to the UK in agri-food sectors and faced protection, by country (top ten, by protection revenue) TRADE PROTECTION COUNTRY TRADE VALUE % of EU TRADE % of total agri. exports of the country NTMs (%, pre Brexit) MFN NTMs (%, after Brexit) Netherlands 9, Ireland 6, France 6, Germany 5, Belgium 3, Italy 3, Spain 4, Poland 1, Denmark 1, Portugal Source: Authors calculations based on tariffs from MAcMap-HS6, NTMs from Kee et al. (2009) and trade from BACI. Note: Trade flows are mean values for the period Current tariff protection is not reported since it does not apply. The AVEs of the MFN tariffs refer to Two NTM values are reported, present AVE and projected AVE in the absence of a specific trade agreement when the UK leaves the EU. 64

69 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit Table 8: EU27 imports from the UK in agri-food sectors and faced protection, by country (top ten, by protection revenue) TRADE PROTECTION COUNTRY TRADE VALUE % of EU TRADE % of total agri. exports of the country NTMs (%, pre Brexit) MFN NTMs (%, after Brexit) Ireland France Netherlands Germany Spain Belgium Italy Sweden Denmark Poland Source: Authors calculations based on tariffs from MAcMap-HS6, NTMs from Kee et al. (2009) and trade from BACI. Note: Trade flows are mean values for the period Current tariff protection is not reported since it does not apply. The AVEs of the MFN tariffs refer to Two NTM values are reported, present AVE and projected AVE in the absence of a specific trade agreement when the UK leaves the EU High integration of agri-food value chains through trade The value chains of UK and EU27 agri-food sectors are highly integrated; for instance, almost half of the value-added in UK s food exports that is generated outside the UK, is produced in the EU27, amounting to 12.58% of total exported value-added (Table 9). Due to the difference in the size of the UK and the EU27, the UK s share in European agricultural and agri-food exported value added is lower (1.45% for agriculture, and 2.11% for food in 2011, see Table 8) than the EU27 in the UK s exported value added (10.53% for agriculture and 12.58% for food, see Table 9). The UK s share of value added is slightly higher in European exports of food, beverages and tobacco than of agricultural products since agricultural production is less dependent on inputs than manufacturing. The intensity of the linkages with UK varies across EU countries (Table 8). The UK accounts for a high share of Ireland s export value-added (particularly in relation to the agricultural sector 11.58%), followed by the Netherlands (2.37%), Denmark (2.24%) and Belgium (2.06%). Ireland is also a particular case when considering the evolution in time of the share of value added generated by the UK which is included in its exports: during , Ireland s dependence on imports from the UK s agricultural sector increased (its dependence on agri-food sector decreased slightly) from 8% to 12%, while the dependence of other EU27 countries remained almost constant. 65

70 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies The share of EU27 value added in UK exports is large and increased significantly between 2000 and 2011, evidence of further integration of UK agricultural and agri-food production with EU members (Table 9). These linkages are particularly important with Germany, France and Netherlands, in the case of both agriculture and food products Table 9: UK value-added in EU27 exports (% of gross export of EU27 countries) EXPORTING COUNTRY AGRICULTURE, HUNTING, FORESTRY AND FISHING FOOD PRODUCTS, BEVERAGES AND TOBACCO EU % 1.45% 2.09% 2.11% Netherlands 2.13% 2.37% 2.65% 2.44% France 1.34% 1.16% 1.47% 1.36% Spain 1.07% 1.19% 1.76% 1.90% Germany 1.09% 1.42% 1.16% 1.41% Ireland 7.97% 11.58% 9.33% 8.81% Denmark 1.39% 2.24% 1.71% 2.70% Belgium 2.30% 2.06% 2.80% 2.10% Italy 0.49% 0.58% 0.94% 0.82% Hungary 0.75% 0.92% 0.61% 0.98% Sweden 1.49% 1.20% 1.92% 1.65% Source: OECD-WTO, Trade in Value Added database (2016). Note: EU27 countries are ranked by the value of their imports from UK, in

71 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit Table 10: Breakdown of the value-added contained in exports of the UK, by origin AGRICULTURE, HUNTING, FORESTRY AND FISHING FOOD PRODUCTS, BEVERAGES AND TOBACCO Domestic 85.32% 75.98% 83.05% 73.70% Foreign 14.68% 24.02% 16.95% 26.30% EU % 10.53% 8.73% 12.58% Germany 1.42% 2.09% 1.61% 2.52% Netherlands 1.01% 1.51% 1.25% 1.65% France 1.44% 1.48% 1.63% 1.75% Spain 0.58% 1.02% 0.75% 1.25% Ireland 0.54% 0.87% 0.61% 1.11% Italy 0.68% 0.83% 0.83% 1.07% Belgium 0.44% 0.51% 0.49% 0.57% Sweden 0.30% 0.46% 0.36% 0.46% Denmark 0.21% 0.39% 0.30% 0.47% Poland 0.06% 0.36% 0.07% 0.46% rest of EU 0.64% 1.01% 0.84% 1.27% Source: OECD-WTO, Trade in Value Added database (2016). Note: EU27 countries are ranked by the value of their exports to UK, in

72 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 68

73 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit 3. MODEL AND SCENARIOS SUMMARY OF SCENARIOS FOR BREXIT Return to WTO rules and sensitivity analysis The scenarios in this report include: WTO : Tariffs between the UK and the EU, and between the UK and Turkey, are increased up to their MFN levels. Trade restrictiveness of NTMs is increased at these borders. WTO (Ireland NTM) : In addition to WTO assumptions, this scenario considers that trade between Ireland and the EU is subject to additional friction, in particular because of the disruption caused by transport routes passing through the UK. WTO (Tariff only) : This scenario considers only the increase in bilateral tariffs (and not the trade restrictiveness of NTMs) up to the MFN level between the UK and EU, and between the UK and Turkey Modelling framework The results presented in this impact assessment are based on the MIRAGE model 55, a recursive-dynamic computable general equilibrium model designed for trade policy analysis (Bchir et al., 2002; Decreux and Valin, 2007; Fontagné et al., 2013). The model is shortly described in Annex B and a more thorough documentation is available online. 56 The MIRAGE model is flexible and can be tailored to different policy questions. In the present case, we model the agricultural sectors in as much detail as possible. We include 31 distinct sectors (19 agri-food industries, 14 manufacturing sectors and 8 services sectors) and 35 geographical areas. The EU is split into 11 countries or country groups (Belgium and Luxembourg, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Rest of EU27), the UK and Turkey are treated as separate, and the rest of the world is aggregated on a regional basis. Details are provided in Annex B Scenarios The WTO scenario A return to WTO rules for EU-UK trade means a return to the MFN tariff rate but is likely also to influence the trade restrictiveness of NTMs. Therefore, for the WTO scenario we assume: Tariff rates between the UK and EU, and between the UK and Turkey, are set at their MFN values (see Appendix A for details on data). 57 Trade restrictiveness of NTMs increases for EU-UK and Turkey-UK trade with the result that the UK loses two-thirds of its preferential access to the single market The version used in this study is MIRAGE-e version Environment and energy specific features are not considered in this exercise Molinuevo (2017) analyzes the legal implications of the UK s withdrawal from the EU for third countries. The consequences for bilateral trade agreements are highly uncertain, in many cases requiring amendments to continue to cover trade with the UK. However, there is more certainty in the case of the few bilateral agreements referring only to goods: since they fall within EU exclusive competences, they were negotiated only by the EU, and will cease to apply to the UK on its withdrawal from the EU. The most significant such agreement, on the basis of which we make our assumption for the scenarios, is the agreement with Turkey. In this case, we consider a return to MFN tariffs. Bilateral investment treaties fall into a different category and probably will remain valid also for UK. 58 This assumption is sourced from the literature, e.g. in Ottaviano et al. (2014) or Dhingra et al. (2016a, 2016b). Our approach however differs from these studies in the way we calibrate initial NTMs trade restrictiveness, as detailed in Annex B. 69

74 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies In agri-food sectors, this could result, for instance, from the introduction of different conformity procedures on both sides of the Channel, or divergence in the regulations on substances authorized for inclusion in food products. While tariffs could be increased in the year that Brexit comes into effect (2019 in our simulations), the increase in the trade restrictiveness of NTMs is likely to be gradual: on day 1 after Brexit, all rules in the UK will remain the same as in the EU, and divergences will emerge only in succeeding years as Great Britain and EU27 implement new regulations. A time frame for this is difficult to predict. As a consequence, we introduce tariffs and NTM shocks in 2021, and observe their outcome in The results for the final year of the analysis should be interpreted as long-term outcomes, after all adjustments have taken place, independent of the time horizon, and with no adjustment cost other than the slow adaptation of capital location. In particular, displacement of workers from one sector to the other happens at zero cost. As already mentioned, the only two changes we consider after Brexit are related to tariffs and NTMs. First, this implies that trade policy elements other than tariffs and NTMs are not modified in our scenarios. In particular, we make no assumptions about tariff rate quotas, meaning that there is no reallocation of import or export quotas presently allocated to UK among other EU members, for example. 59 The evolution of these TRQs is important for exporters, particularly in the agri-food sectors but is highly uncertain and may require negotiations with trade partners other than the UK. We do not consider any agreement that the UK or the EU might negotiate between them, or with third parties. Second, the Common Agricultural Policy and other public policies apart from trade policy, are assumed to remain constant at their present level in the UK and the EU. 60 Again, we do not consider any policy that might mitigate the negative impacts we identify (Section 1 refers to analyses available in the literature on possible mitigating policies) Alternative specifications and sensitivity analysis NTMs and the amount they might increase by as a consequence of Brexit, are taken from the literature and are subject to discussion. To cope with this uncertainty, we implemented two sensitivity scenarios. The outcome of these scenarios is not discussed in detail here. However, the results which differ from those from the central scenario are useful to highlight the implications of some of the assumptions we make. The two sensitivity analyses are: WTO (Tariff Only): In this scenario, only the tariffs increase, up to their MFN level taken from the MAcMap-HS6 database (see Tables in Section 2.3). The NTMs do not change compared to the BAU case. This scenario depicts the role played by NTMs (and the value of their estimated trade restrictiveness). WTO (Ireland NTM): As mentioned above, Ireland s trade with the UK follows a specific pattern for several reasons which include geographical proximity. Matthews (2017) suggests that a decrease in trade with the UK would imply higher transport costs for Ireland, with cargoes not fully loaded in both directions, for instance. To account for these specificities, we consider an additional simple scenario similar to the WTO scenario but where Ireland is assumed to face higher AVE for NTMs when trading with the EU. That is, the increase in NTMs will be equal to half of the increase incurred by the UK. 59 More specifically, we assume that TRQs that were not binding in 2013 remain non-binding for both the EU and UK, and binding TRQs remain binding for both the UK and EU. 60 In other words, we assume that after Brexit, the UK (and the EU27) will continue to grant the same subsidies and impose the same constraints as currently. 70

75 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit 4. IMPACTS OF A WTO SCENARIO ON THE AGRI-FOOD SECTOR IN THE EUROPEAN UNION KEY FINDINGS A return to WTO rules would imply significantly less agri-food trade between the EU and UK in both directions (around -62%). Some EU exports almost completely collapse, like those of Rice, White meat, Sugar, Dairy and Red meat (more than -90% in trade). Ireland, the Netherlands and France are the EU27 countries that lose the most in terms of trade. Brexit also implies more room for EU27 products on their domestic markets and other EU27 markets replacing UK products. Nevertheless, this effect fails to compensate the incurred losses in value-added (see footnote 16 for details on valueadded), with the exception of a few sectors, such as Red meat and Cattle in France, or Sugar and Wheat in Spain, in which value-added increases. Brexit could be an opportunity for the UK s agri-food sectors as a whole. Excepted in Ireland, consumers are hardly affected by changes in overall consumption prices or economic activity. To present and discuss the simulation results, this report focuses first on the most direct impacts of Brexit, namely the changes to bilateral trade between the EU27 and the UK, and then studies the more aggregate or indirect impacts (e.g., on total EU27 agri-food value added or gross domestic product). The following tables and figures may include the results of the three scenarios described above but only the WTO scenario is discussed in detail in the text; the other two are cited when highlighting original elements. Most results are presented in percentage deviation from the BAU scenario, in 2030, both in percentage change and in volumes. The variations in volume are actually measured in constant 2011 USD, i.e. at the prices of the initial year A large decrease in EU27-UK agri-food trade flows unevenly distributed across sectors and EU27 countries Strong decrease in EU27 exports to UK, compensated by exports to other countries only in a few sectors As expected, the direct effect of applying WTO rules to European agri-food exports to the UK is large and negative, as shown in Figure 1. These exports decrease by -62% (which corresponds to USD billion - see Table C.1 in Annex C). Depending on the value of MFN and trade restrictiveness of NTMs, impacts vary widely across sectors, from almost unaffected sectors (Fiber crops, Wool, Forestry) to the near complete collapse of trade flows for Rice, White meat, Sugar, Dairy and Red meat, which decrease by more than 90%. The most affected sectors are also the most traded in the BAU, leading to a loss of trade in volume by USD -470 million for White meat, Dairy, Red meat, Sugar and Rice taken together. The least traded sectors before Brexit are the least affected, and their decrease represents a loss in volume more than ten times smaller at USD -34 million for Fiber crops, Wool and Forestry combined. This result is in line with Lawless and Morgenroth (2016) who find similar decreases in EU27 exports to the UK for Sugar, Meat and Dairy. Finally, the largest decrease in volume concerns Other foods (which consists mainly of dog and cat food, Pastry and Orange juice). 71

76 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies In terms of magnitude, it is important to note that if only tariffs increase (WTO (Tariff only) scenario), the impacts of Brexit on EU27-UK trade will be almost halved but the ranking of the sectors at risk remains similar to the ranking in the WTO scenario. A notable exception is Red meat (and to a lesser extent Sugar and Dairy products), for which a tariff-only scenario has almost the same impact as the WTO scenario. This underlines that in these compared to other sectors, protection comes mainly from the MFN tariff, not NTMs. These direct impacts on European agri-food exports to UK are mitigated by increased exports towards all other trade partners (see Table C.1 in Annex C). EU27 products tend to replace former UK exports to the EU27 and to the rest of the World. Indeed, Great Britain will suffer a loss of competitiveness since its imported inputs, which for the most part come from the EU27, become more expensive (UK production prices increase, as already mentioned in Donnellan and Hanrahan, 2016 and depicted in Table 10) ; while at the same time the decreasing UK demand for EU27 goods make some of their prices decrease. However, increased exports to countries other than the UK are not of the same order of magnitude as EU27-UK trade flows, and fail to compensate for the export losses incurred by the EU27 after Brexit. At the sector level, two effects will compete, especially in relation to intra-eu27 trade. On the one hand, as noted above, EU27 exports become more competitive than UK goods, and EU27 countries tend to gain market shares in destination countries (other than the UK). On the other hand, a general equilibrium effect is at play: as described below, on average, EU27 countries become slightly poorer after Brexit, resulting in decreased overall consumption including in intra-eu27 goods. While the first effect dominates in the majority of sectors (i.e., exports to the EU27 and to the rest of the world increase), for Animal products, Cereals, Forestry, the second effect is larger (intra-eu27 exports decrease). This reverse tendency can be explained by the conjunction of two factors: these goods are at the same time not much exported by the UK and less substitutable between origins, leaving no room for trade deviations to the benefit of EU27 countries. At the global level, trade decreases in the majority of sectors, with only a few increasing their exports (Wheat, Forestry, Fiber crops, Wool). Finally, recall that agri-food sectors represent only a small share of EU27 exports. Thus, the impacts are greater on manufacturing and services, especially in terms of volume. 72

77 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit Figure 11: Variations in EU27 export volume to the UK, by sector, 2030 Source: Authors calculations using MIRAGE-e. Percentage changes indicated in boxes relate to the WTO scenario only EU27 agri-food imports from the UK: same mechanisms as for imports The mechanisms at play on EU27 imports from the UK are about the same as for exports. The level of the MFN tariff is the same for both sides at the HS-6 level, and the trade-restrictiveness of NTMs varies very little. In value, the impacts are smaller, as shown in Figure 2, because the UK is not a major exporter of agri-food products. However, the percentage change in trade is comparable, as are the sector rankings. It should be stressed that the UK is more specialized in Red meat exports than the rest of the EU27, and this sector is one of those that faces the largest percentage decrease due to large MFN tariffs and NTMs, hence making the UK proportionally more vulnerable. 73

78 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Figure 12: Variations in aggregate EU27 imports volume from the UK, by sector, 2030 Source: Authors calculations using MIRAGE-e. Variations with respect to the BAU scenario. Percentage changes indicated in boxes refer to the WTO scenario Most impacted EU27 exporters: the Netherlands, France and Ireland Country and region-level impacts, depicted in Figure 3, are driven by the level of initial trade and the export specialization of EU27 countries in their agri-food trade with the UK. The most affected countries by volume are the Netherlands, Ireland and France; the least impacted are Sweden and Portugal. This ranking corresponds to the initial trade integration with the UK: unsurprisingly, the most (resp. least) impacted countries are those with the closest (resp. loosest) ties with the UK in the agri-food sectors. In terms of volume, the largest decreases in exports are experienced by the largest exporters to the UK. The variation in relative impacts (percentage) is more heterogeneous across countries: EU27 countries having exports concentrated in sectors with the largest tariff and NTM increases, such as Ireland or Poland (see Table 6), face a very significant decrease in their exports (around 70%). On the contrary, countries like Spain or France face lower additional barriers on the UK market due to their specialization, their trade flows decrease by around 50%. This result echoes the findings in Lawless and Morgenroth (2016) and Davis et al. (2017); these authors show that the significant concentration of Irish exports to and imports from the UK in a small number of products with potentially high protection, makes Ireland the most affected country in terms of trade. 74

79 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit The most affected sectors in each EU27 region, i.e., those with the largest variations in export volume, are presented in Table C.2 in Annex C. Similar to the EU27 aggregation, each and every trade flow towards the UK decreases with Brexit. The biggest impacts are observed either because the sector was heavily traded so that even a small percentage decrease leads to high losses in volume, for instance, Beverages and Tobacco from France (only 16% decrease in exports but corresponding to USD 0.5 billion); or because the sector was not heavily traded but the trade flow almost disappears, e.g., in the case of White meat exports from Germany which were worth USD 0.5 billion and decrease by 91%. Figure 13: Variations in EU27 agri-food exports to the UK, by country, 2030 Source: Authors calculations using MIRAGE-e. Variations with respect to the BAU scenario. Percentage changes indicated in boxes refer to the WTO scenario Agri-food value-added decreases within the EU27, though exposure of countries is heterogeneous The economic situation in the agri-food sectors is determined only partially by trade. Domestic demand plays a significant role, in particular because domestic production is often consumed mostly locally with only a small share traded. This section examines agri-food value-added and the sources of its variation Formally, value-added gathers payments to production factors, in the agri-food sectors in our case. In our modeling framework it is equivalent to consider value-added or production because they are proportional. However, magnitude in value-added represents more the contribution of each sector to GDP and the potential impacts on consumers revenues. 75

80 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Agri-food value-added in the EU27: large negative impact in Ireland, very limited in other EU27 countries In terms of value-added in the agri-food sectors, Ireland is the most negatively affected European country by Brexit, with a decrease of 16.3% in value added (see Figure 4). This can be explained by the large share of Ireland s production that is exported to the UK, and the high level of dependence of Ireland on intermediates imported from the UK (see Table 8) which is highlighted also in Matthews (2015, 2017). In contrast, the agri-food sectors in the Netherlands and France are less integrated with UK production; thus, despite the large variations in agri-food exports depicted in Figure 3 (-66% and -51.4% respectively), valueadded in agri-food sectors decreases by a lower order of magnitude, i.e., by 2.7% and 0.3% respectively for these countries. The case of the UK is worthy of mention because Brexit would cause British agri-food value-added to increase by 2.1%. The UK s imports from the EU27 will be replaced by domestic production more than by imports from other countries, anyway at the expense of consumers who face higher prices in both cases (domestic or imported), as discussed below. These results hide large heterogeneity among the sectors within each country. Table C.3 in Annex C summarizes the variations in value-added for each country for overall agri-food production, and for the five most affected (positive or negative impact on volume) sectors. Other food seems systematically to be the most negatively affected sector with other sectors at risk varying from one EU27 country to another. In Ireland, Dairy and Cattle are the sectors most at risk (after Other food), and the reduction in their value-added is highly significant compared to the initial size of these sectors (-45% and -26% respectively). 62 In other countries, the magnitude of the impacts is lower compared to the sector size: White meat and Other crops are the most affected sectors in the Netherlands, as are White meat and Dairy for the rest of the EU27, Vegetables and fruits and Dairy in Italy, and Dairy in France. However, a return to WTO rules with Great Britain could represent an opportunity for those sectors where production replaces former imports from the UK, in their domestic markets and/or in other EU27 markets. This applies particularly to Red meat, Wheat and Cattle in France, and Wheat and Sugar in Spain. These results are to be discussed in more detail below. 62 Although taken from a global model not focused specifically on Ireland, this result is in line with the conclusions in Donnellan and Hanrahan (2016) which specifically estimates the impact of Brexit on Irish agriculture. 76

81 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit Figure 14: Variations in total agri-food value-added by EU27 country and UK, 2030 Source: Authors calculations using MIRAGE-e Decomposition of the impacts on value-added in the EU27: losses from the Brexit are only partly compensated by exports to other countries There are three sources of variation in sector value-added within the EU27: first, the volume of exports lost on the UK market; the volume of exports gained on other EU27 markets and other foreign markets, but more marginally, (see above); and more significantly the ability of a given sector, in a given country, to replace UK imports with domestic supply. Figure 5 presents an accounting decomposition of the variation in value-added by source of variation, separating out the value-added used to satisfy domestic demand, and exports to the UK, EU27 and the rest of the world, and other sources. 63 For every country, value-added losses are driven by the direct effect of decreased exports to the UK. Ireland and the Netherlands are the countries where agricultural value added will decrease the most, respectively by 16.3% and 2.7%. In addition, these two countries experience also a pattern which is different from other EU27 countries. Ireland is the only country where WTO rules would imply loss of exports to both the EU27 and the rest of the world and this is due to Ireland s dependency on intermediates from the UK, which implies loss of competitiveness in all export markets. In the Netherlands, exports to the EU27 increase on average although not supply to the domestic market. For other EU27 members, exports to non-uk partners will help to mitigate the losses from the direct 63 In our case, trade restrictiveness of NTMs is represented as an iceberg cost. Iceberg costs imply that part of the production is lost in the trade process. Therefore, increasing trade protection has some particular impacts on production, since new trade barriers are partially paid by production. This effect is added to the more classical price increase due to tariffs. 77

82 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies effect of Brexit but will not compensate for it completely. Interestingly, France, Spain and Germany are the countries where losses in exports to the UK are compensated the most by exports to other EU27 markets and domestic demand. Figure 15: Variations in agri-food value-added volume and decomposition by source in the WTO scenario, 2030 Source: Authors calculations using MIRAGE-e. These results for EU27 agri-food value-added are in fact the aggregation of the different sectors. The last five columns in Table C.3 in Annex C present the same decomposition of value-added variation for the five most impacted sectors (in terms of absolute variation in volume). For almost every sector in every country, the interpretation is similar to the aggregate level: results are driven by the loss of exports to the UK. In some sectors however, a return to WTO rules could represent an opportunity, when domestic demand replaces UK imports in an amount greater than the losses suffered on the UK market, as it is the case for Red meat and Cattle in France or Wheat in Spain. Regarding Red meat and Cattle, this exception can be explained by the high initial specialization of UK in these sectors, leaving room for trade deviation after Brexit. Wheat production increases may also be a consequence of such UK specialization: while beef production increase in many EU27 countries to replace UK products, Wheat is demanded to feed cattle. Besides, Wheat production in France benefits more from opportunities in other EU27 markets than those related to the domestic market. 78

83 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit 4.3. At the macroeconomic level, the impact on EU27 countries is marginal, except for Ireland The evolution of European production prices is driven by different forces. On the one hand, increased prices for intermediate inputs from the UK (due to tariff and NTM increases) tend to increase production prices. On the other hand, the decrease in UK imports reduces demand for EU27 goods, and drives prices down. Table 10 shows that, on average, this second effect dominates in all European countries except Ireland, and production prices decrease. Because of the agri-food production sector in Ireland s high dependence on UK intermediates, the first effect mentioned above prevails and results in increased production prices. Table 11: Variations in consumption and production price indexes for agri-food goods and all goods in the WTO scenario, 2030 REGION CONSUMPTION PRODUCTION AGRI-FOOD TOTAL AGRI-FOOD TOTAL Ireland Sweden France Portugal Belgium and Luxembourg Netherlands Spain Rest of EU Germany Italy Poland UK Source: Authors calculations using MIRAGE-e. Note: Variations are given in percentage with respect to the BAU scenario. The two opposite forces described above also affect consumption prices. Increases in tariffs and trade restrictiveness of NTMs lead directly to an increase in consumption prices, through the prices of imported goods. On the other hand, consumption prices will follow possible decreases in production prices. The overall effect on consumption prices is shown in Table 10. These results contrast with the results for production prices. First, note that the total consumption price index (including non-agri-food goods) decreases in all EU27 countries, Ireland included. Indeed, in the manufacture sectors, EU27 MFN tariffs and NTMs levels are lower, hence, the market effect of decreased overall demand dominates. For four EU27 countries or regions (Poland, Italy, Germany, Rest of EU27) the same mechanism is in operation in agri-food sectors too because none of them is very dependent on imports from the UK. On the contrary, in other EU27 regions, the tariff effect dominates although the impacts are very small (less than 0.1%). However, the high dependency of Ireland on goods from the UK makes consumption prices increase much more (by 5.4%). 79

84 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Finally, although this report focuses on agri-food issues, a detour to overall GDP impacts that could be better evaluated if the industry and services, which represents the majority of economic activity, were represented with more detail is useful to understand general equilibrium effects: Brexit means a small decrease in EU27 purchasing power in general, and this is one of the reasons why domestic and intra-eu27 demand fail to compensate losses suffered on the UK market by EU27 producers. Indeed, Table C.4 in Annex C shows that WTO rules would have a moderate impact on EU27 GDP (-0.3%), and this is the case for most EU27 members (less than a 0.7% decrease). This result is in line with results in the literature, in particular Booth et al. (2015) which finds a 0.33% decrease in GDP in In contrast, Ireland is strongly affected by Brexit, and its GDP decreases by 3.4% and might even reach 9.4% if Brexit affects Ireland s access to EU27 market as in the WTO (Ireland NTM) scenario. Finally, if only tariffs are at stake, all impacts on the EU27 and on the UK will be marginal. 80

85 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit 5. CONCLUDING REMARKS The UK is the second largest EU27 export market (worth USD 353 billion, and 6.9% of EU27 total exports) in trade value; at the same time, the EU27 is the UK s largest export market (USD 214 billion and 46% of the UK exports). Agri-food sectors represent 11% of the bilateral trade and their trade balance is favorable to the EU27. The first three EU27 agri-food sectors, ranked by the traded value weighted by the protection that could be imposed in a WTO scenario, are processed food, dairy and meat (both exports to and imports from UK). The EU27 countries that trade the most with the UK and that will face the highest protection are France, the Netherlands and Ireland. The large market shares and possible protection, combined with specialization patterns, foreshadows heterogeneous impacts across countries and sectors, as well as the redistribution of production across the EU27. Considering the present situation as a starting point, we simulated the impact of the application of MFN tariffs on bilateral trade between the UK and the EU27 combined with a decrease by 2/3s in preferential access of the UK to the EU27 market. These are two crucial traits of the scenario that could occur after Brexit, in the absence of a trade agreement stating otherwise. We do not consider any other change in public policies: the CAP remains unchanged (meaning that EU27 and UK farmers continue to receive the same payments), no policies are implemented to cope with the possible impacts of Brexit and the UK does not sign any new trade agreements. The result of this scenario is a decrease in bilateral EU27-UK trade: in 2030, as compared to a situation in which UK remains an EU member state, EU27 agri-food exports to the UK will decrease by USD 34 billion as will imports by USD 19 billion. The increase in trade among EU27 countries (+1%) and with other regions (+0.9%) does not compensate for the decrease between the EU27 and the UK, and EU27 total exports diminish by 4.1% (USD -28 billion). Despite the sizeable impacts on trade flows, overall agri-food production and value-added fall by a relatively small 0.8%, which corresponds to USD 5.6 billion. Indeed, domestic demand plays a predominant role in agri-food production. Overall impacts on agri-food exports and value added are negative in every EU27 country, but their magnitude varies among them. Ireland, the Netherlands and France loose the largest trade volumes. Impacts are also heterogeneous across sectors: as far as value added is considered at the EU27 level, the most negatively affected sectors (by volume) are processed food (USD billion, -4.7%), white meat (USD -5.2 billion, -10.5%) and dairy (USD -4.6 billion, -7%). Nevertheless, Brexit is an opportunity for a few sectors: for instance, French Red Meat and Cattle respectively increase their value added by 2.1% and 1.3%, replacing former imports from the UK. It is interesting to note that agri-food value added increases in the UK (+2%), domestic production replacing imports from EU27. This is made at the expense of consumers, prices increasing by 4%. Overall GDP, to which agri-food sectors contribute less than manufacture, is slightly negatively affected in all countries apart from Ireland and the UK, where GDP significantly decreases by 3.4% and 2.4%, respectively. The increase in both NTMs and tariffs contribute to these results: impacts are much smaller if only tariffs increase. In the majority of sectors, the increase in NTMs is nearly twice the one in tariffs and drives the impacts on trade. Nevertheless, this is not the case for Red Meat, and to a lesser extent Sugar and Dairy, which are mainly protected by tariffs. Since Red Meat and Dairy are among the most impacted sectors, the decrease in overall EU27 agri-food value added is not much different between our main scenario and a scenario considering only an increase in tariffs (-0.8% vs -0.6%). 81

86 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies It is important to note that all the impacts considered here do not account for adjustment costs. For instance, the reallocation of production factors, with the exception of capital stocks, is made without frictions. Furthermore, the results have to be interpreted as long-term ones, once reallocations are completely done. Expected impacts on Ireland are particularly concerning: Irish GDP loss exceeds the British one. Indeed, Irish agri-food sectors (and more generally the economy as a whole) are highly dependent on trade with the UK, especially on intermediate consumptions imports. As a consequence, Ireland deserves particular attention when considering redistributive policies to mitigate Brexit's negative impacts. More generally, trade policy options to alleviate the negative impacts we report may consist in limiting the increase in protection on EU27-UK bilateral trade for sectors at risk, and addressing trade impacts of NTMs in a potential trade agreement. 82

87 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit REFERENCES Aichele, R. and Felbermayr, G. (2017), Costs and benefits of a United Kingdom exit from the European Union, Ifo Institut, Center for International Economics. Arkolakis, C., Costinot, A. and Rodriguez-Clare, A. (2012), New Trade Models, Same Old Gains? American Economic Review, 102(1), Baker, S. and Swales, D. (2017), Brexit Scenario: an impact assessment, Market Intelligence report, Agriculture & Horticulture Development Board (AHDB). Barrett, A., Bergin, A., FitzGerald, J., Lambert, D., McCoy, D., Morgenroth, E., Siedschlag, I. and Studnicka, Z. (2015), Scoping the Possible Economic Implications of Brexit on Ireland, ESRI research series 48. Bchir, M. H., Decreux, Y., Gurin, J.-L. and Jean, S. (2002), MIRAGE, a computable general equilibrium model for trade policy analysis, CEPII Working Paper, Berden, K. G., Francois, J., Thelle, M., Wymenga, P. and Tamminen, S. (2009), Non-Tariff Measures in EU-US Trade and Investment An Economic Analysis, Ecorys. Bergin, A., Garcia-Rodriguez, A., McInerney, N., Morgenroth, E., and Smith, D. (2016), Modelling the Medium to Long Term Potential Macroeconomic Impact of Brexit on Ireland, ESRI working paper 548. Bouët, A., Decreux, Y., Fontagné, L., Jean, S. and Laborde, D. (2008), Assessing applied protection across the world, Review of International Economics, 16(5), Boulanger, P. and Philippidis, G. (2015), The End of a Romance? A note on the Quantitative Impacts of a Brexit from the EU, Journal of Agricultural Economics, 66(3), Brakman, S., Garretsen, H. and Kohl, T. (2017), Consequences of Brexit and options for a "Global Britain", CESifo Working paper Buckwell, A. (2016), Agricultural implications of Brexit, Worshipful Company of Farmers. Busch, B. and Mattes, J. (2016), Brexit, the economic impact - A meta-analysis, IW Report 10/2016, Cologne Institute for Economic Research. Ciuriak, D., Xiao, J., Ciuriak, N., Dadkhah, A., Lysenki, D. and Narayanan, B. G. (2015), The trade-related impact of a UK exit from the EU single market, Ciuriak Consulting. Connell, W., Simons, W and Vandenbussche, H. (2017), Global Value Chains, Trade Shocks And Jobs: An Application to Brexit, KU Leuven Discussion Paper Davies, R. B. and Studnicka, Z. (2017), The heterogeneous impact of Brexit: early indications from the FTSE, CESifo Working paper Davis, J., Feng, S., Patton, M. and Binfield, J. (2017), Impacts of Alternative Post-Brexit Trade Agreements on UK Agriculture: Sector Analyses using the FAPRI-UK Model, Agri-Food and Biosciences Institute. 83

88 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Decreux, Y. and Valin, H. (2007), Mirage, updated version of the model for trade policy analysis: Focus on agriculture and dynamics, CEPII Working Paper, Dhingra, S., Huang, H., Ottaviano, G., Pessioa, J. P., Sampson, T., Van Reenen, J. (2016a), The costs and benefits of leaving the EU: Trade effects, Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics and Political Science. Dhingra, S., Ottaviano, G., Sampson, T., and Van Reenen, J. (2016b), The consequences of Brexit for UK trade and living standards, Working paper, Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics and Political Science. Disdier, A.-C., Emlinger, C., and Fouré, J. (2016), Interdependencies between atlantic and pacific agreements: Evidence from agri-food sectors, Economic Modelling, 55, Donnellan, T. and Hanrahan, K. (2016), Potential Implications for the Irish Agri-Food Sector, Teagasc Agricultural and Farm Surveys Department. Downes, C. (2017), The post-brexit management of EU agricultural tariff rate quotas, Journal of World Trade, 51(4), forthcoming. Ebell, M., Hurst, I. and Warren, J. (2016), Modelling the long-run economic impact of leaving the European Union, Economic Modelling, 59(C), Fontagné, L., Fouré, J. and Ramos, M. P. (2013), MIRAGE-e: A general equilibrium longterm path of the world economy, CEPII Working Paper, Fontagné, L., Mitaritonna, C. and Signoret, J. E. (2016), Estimated tariff- equivalents of services ntms, CEPII Working Paper, Fouré, J., Bénassy-Quéré, A. and Fontagné, L. (2013), Modelling the world economy at the 2050 horizon, Economics of Transition, 21(4), Freund, F., Banse, M., Ofermann, F., Pelikan, J. and Salamon, P. (2017), The UK after the referendum: Renegotiating tariffs and beyond, GTAP 2017 Conference Paper. Gaulier, G. and Zignago, S. (2010), BACI: International Trade Database at the Product- Level. The Version, CEPII Working Paper, Grant, W., Cardwell, M., Greer, A., Rodgers, C., Smith, F., Swinbank, A., Bromet, C., Cowling, B., Findlay, R. and Jones, H. (2015), The implication of Brexit for UK agriculture, Report for the Yorkshire Agricultural Society. Guimbard, H., Jean, S., Mimouni, M. and Pichot, X. (2012), MacMap-HS6 2007, an exhaustive and consistent measure of applied protection in 2007, International Economics, Q2, p Hosoe, N. (2016), Impact of Brexit: Firm exit and loss of variety, GRIPS Discussion paper 16-14, National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies. Hummels, D. L. and Schaur, G. (2013), Time as a trade barrier, American Economic Review, 103(7),

89 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit Kee, H. L., Nicita, A. and Olarreaga, M. (2008), Import demand elasticities and trade distortions, Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4), Kee, H. L., Nicita, A. and Olarreaga, M. (2009), Estimating trade restrictiveness indices, The Economic Journal, 119(534), Lang, T. and Schoen, V. (2016), Food, the UK and the EU: Brexit or Bremain? IW report 10/2016, Institut der Deutschen Wirtschaft Koln. Lawless, M. and Morgenroth, E. L. (2016), The product and sector level impact of a hard brexit across EU, ESRI Working paper 550. Matthews, A. (2016), The potential implications of a brexit for future EU agri-food policies, EuroChoices, 15(2), Matthews, A. (2017), Brexit impacts on Irish agri-food exports to the UK, EuroChoices, 16(2), Melitz, M. J. (2003), The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity, Econometrica, 71(6), Minor, P. (2013), Time as a Barrier to Trade: A GTAP Database of ad-valorem Trade Time Costs, ImpactECON, LLC. Second Edition. Molinuevo, M. (2017), Brexit - Trade governance and legal implications for third countries, Policy Research Working paper 8010, World Bank, Trade and Competitiveness. Global Practice Group. Ottaviano, G. I., Pessoa, J. P., Sampson, T. and Reenen, J. V. (2014), The costs and benefits of leaving the EU, CFS Working paper Series 472. Potton, E. and Webb, D. (2017), Brexit: Agriculture and Trade, Briefing Paper 7974, UK House of Commons. PwC (2016), Leaving the EU: Implications for the UK economy, PwC. Revell, B. (2017), Brexit and tariff rate quotas on EU imports: a complex problem, EuroChoices, 16(2): Rojas-Romagosa, H., (2016), Trade effects of Brexit for the Netherlands, CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis. Roussel K. and Doherty, M. (2016), The impact of Brexit on protected food names, Market Intelligence report, Agriculture & Horticulture Development Board (AHDB). Ruparel, R., Booth, S. and Scarpetta, V. (2016), Where next? A liberal, free-market guide to Brexit, Report 02/2016, OpenEurope. Treasury, H. (2016), HM Treasury analysis: the long-term economic impact of EU membership and the alternatives, Report, HM Treasury. UK House of Lords (2017a), Brexit: trade in goods, European Committee. 16 th Report of Session , UK Parliament. 85

90 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies UNCTAD (2009), Non-tariff measures: Evidence from Selected Developing Countries and Future Research Agenda, UNCTAD/DITC/TAB/2009/3. Van Berkum, S., Jongeneel, R.A., abd Vrolijk, H., Van Leeuwen, M. and Jager, J. (2016), Implications of a UK exit from the EU for British agriculture, Study for the National Farmers Union (NFU), Warwickshire, UK, LEI, Wageningen. 86

91 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit ANNEX A: DATA This annex briefly describes the databases used for the descriptive analysis and the quantitative assessment in this report. A.1. The BACI database BACI (Gaulier et al. 2010) is a world trade database developed by CEPII. 64 Original data are provided by the United Nations Statistical Division (available from the COMTRADE database). BACI is constructed using an original procedure which for each bilateral trade flow which ensures the consistency between the exporters and importers declarations. This harmonization procedure increases the number of countries for which trade data are available compared to the original data. BACI provides trade bilateral values and quantities for each product as defined in the 6-digit United Nations Harmonized System (hereafter HS6), for more than 200 countries since In this report, we use BACI data from the 1996 revision of the HS6 classification. In what follows, we examine average trade flows during the period (the three most recent years for which BACI data are available) in order to consider a stable reference situation that does not reflect the particular economic situation in a given year. This choice is also motivated by our interest in the long term effects of Brexit. A.2. The MAcMap-HS6 database The MAcMap-HS6 database (Bouët et al. 2008, Guimbard et al. 2012) provides ad valorem equivalents (percentage, AVE) of the tariffs applied by 190 importing countries to 220 exporting countries on 5,113 HS6 products, in 2011 and The database also contains MFN (most favored nation) and bounds tariffs (upper bound tariff for each country, negotiated at WTO ministerial meetings). This database allows detailed tariff scenarios to be calculated. For this purpose, reference groups weighting schemes are used to preserve the heterogeneity of tariffs and to limit the endogeneity bias between trade flows and customs duties. A.3. Non-Tariff Measures Trade protection involves both tariffs and other measures that can limit market access. Nontariff measures (NTMs) are a heterogeneous set of policy measures other than ordinary customs tariffs that can potentially have an economic effect on international trade in goods, changing quantities traded, or prices or both. 65 This is a broad definition, and it is not uncommon for the more detailed classification provided by the MAST group 66 to be considered in order to distinguish among technical measures, non-technical measures and measures applied to exports (the first two categories concern only imports). For instance, some frequently used technical measures include sanitary and phytosanitary measures (e.g., tolerance limits for pesticide residues, or labeling requirements), and pre-shipment inspection obligations. Non-technical measures can include other traditional trade policy instruments such as rules of origin, quotas, price controls etc., and behind-the-border measures such as public procurement and trade-related investment measures. To account for the impact of these three categories of NTMs on goods, in the following we consider their AVE, based on the estimations in Kee et al. (2009). Kee et al. employ a twostep approach: first, they estimate the impact of NTMs on trade flows; second, they calculate the AVE of these impacts (i.e., the duty that would have the same effect on trade flows) using import demand elasticities taken from Kee et al. (2008). They propose AVEs for NTMs imposed by 78 countries on 4,575 products in the HS6 nomenclature. 64 See also 65 UNCTAD/DITC/TAB/2009/3,

92 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Although the focus in this report is on the agri-food sectors, we account also for the possible broader consequences of Brexit on trade policies. In particular, our scenarios consider changes in the non-tariff measures applied to services. We use the MIRAGE model which relies on Fontagné et al. s (2016) data on trade restrictiveness in the services sectors which provide AVEs of restrictions on cross-border trade in services for 118 countries and 9 sectors, using the GTAP database of trade in services for A.4. The GTAP database GTAP 9 67 brings together the social accounting matrices (SAMs) of 140 countries (or groups of countries) covering the world economy, in a 57 sector nomenclature, for the year A SAM is an extension of the input-output tables in national accounts, merged with a trade matrix that links countries. In order to reduce the calculation dimension to a manageable level, the GTAP database is aggregated on its two dimensions (country-sectors). Aggregations are specific to each study; the one used here is presented above in Table B.1 and B.2. The 21 traded GTAP agricultural sectors (raw milk is a non-traded sector) can also be mapped to the HS6 international trade classifications. To maintain consistency between the descriptive analysis of the actual trade statistics (Section 3) and the Brexit impact assessment (Section 5), the report presents trade statistics for GTAP sectors. 68 These statistics are based on aggregating BACI data using the available correspondence tables 69 between GTAP sectors and HS6 products. Table D.1 shows that some sectors contain only a few products (e.g., Processed Rice includes only two HS6 lines, and ) others contain numerous HS6 lines (e.g., among others, Meat products n.e.c. 43, Vegetable, oils and fats 47), while Food products n.e.c. sectors include nearly 250 products. We take advantage of the HS6 dimension of our trade data by identifying the most traded HS6 products in the sectors that will be most affected by the negative impacts of Brexit on trade. Thus, we retain the first five GTAP sectors in Table 4 (exports) and 5 (imports). For each of these sectors, we rank the first five HS6 products in order of importance, based on trade flows weighted by future trade protection. We also identify the countries with the highest level of trade in each of these five HS6 products. Tables D.2 and D.3 report imports and Tables D.4 and D.5 report exports. We comment on the figures wherever necessary. 67 See 68 Complete trade statistics at the HS6 product level are also provided, in the Annex. 69 See: 88

93 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit ANNEX B: MODEL DESCRIPTION B.1. The MIRAGE model The MIRAGE model 70 is a recursive-dynamic computable general equilibrium model designed for trade policy analysis (Bchir et al., 2002; Decreux and Valin, 2007; Fontagné et al., 2013). It relies on the GTAP9 database for social accounting matrices; tariff protection is taken from MAcMap-HS6 database (Guimbard et al., 2012), trade restrictiveness of non-tariff measures is sourced from Kee et al. (2009) for goods, and from Fontagné et al. (2016) for services. Finally, the trade costs related to time delays and delivery uncertainties due to infrastructure and administration problems are from Minor (2013). 71 Supply side On the supply side, each sector in MIRAGE is modeled as a representative firm, whose production function combines value-added and intermediate consumption in fixed shares. Value-added is a bundle of imperfectly substitutable primary factors (capital, skilled and unskilled labor, land and natural resources); intermediates are represented by a bundle of imperfectly substitutable goods. MIRAGE-e assumes full employment of primary factors. Skilled and unskilled labor is perfectly mobile across sectors but immobile across countries while natural resources are sector specific, and land is only (imperfectly) mobile between agricultural sectors. Installed capital is assumed to be immobile (sector-specific) while investments are allocated across sectors according to their rates of return. The overall stock of capital evolves through a combination of capital formation and a 6% constant rate of capital depreciation. Gross investment is determined by combining the saving and current accounts. Finally, while total investment is savings-driven, its allocation is determined by the rate of return from the various activities. Consumers On the demand side, the representative consumer from each country/region maximizes instantaneous utility under a budget constraint. Expenditure is allocated to commodities and services according to a LES-CES (linear expenditure system constant elasticity of substitution) function. This implies that above a minimum consumption of the goods produced by each sector, consumption choices among the goods produced by different sectors are made according to a CES utility function. Trade Within each sector, total demand for each good (final, intermediate and investment) is differentiated by origin. A nested CES function assigns a particular status for domestic products according to the usual Armington hypothesis: consumers and firms choices are biased towards domestic production, and therefore, domestic and foreign goods are imperfectly substitutable according to a CES specification. Business-as-usual (BAU) scenario Before considering counterfactual scenarios, a business-as-usual growth path for the world economy, referred to as the reference simulation (or BAU ), is simulated up to 2030 in our case. In this BAU scenario, the MIRAGE model is calibrated to match the trajectories obtained from the EconMap baseline database (Fouré et al., 2013). More precisely, in the MIRAGE model, total factor productivity is computed in order to allow GDP to match the growth path 70 The version used in this study is MIRAGE-e version Environment and energy specific features are not considered in this exercise. 71 Minor (2013) follows the methodology in Hummels and Schaur (2013). 89

94 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies derived from EconMap, under constraints on population, skilled and unskilled labor, savings and current account evolutions. The model is calibrated on 2011 data, therefore, we update the tariff levels for 2013 to match most recent MAcMap-HS6 data. B.2. Aggregation of regions and sectors for the present study Table B.1: Aggregation of regions MIRAGE region Africa Middle East North Africa GTAP region Bahrain (BHR), Iran Islamic Republic of (IRN), Israel (ISR), Jordan (JOR), Kuwait (KWT), Oman (OMN), Qatar (QAT), Saudi Arabia (SAU), United Arab Emirates (ARE), Rest of Western Asia (XWS) Egypt (EGY), Morocco (MAR), Tunisia (TUN), Rest of North Africa (XNF) SACU Sub-saharan Africa Turkey Asia ASEAN China and Hong-Kong India Japan Korea Rest of Asia Botswana (BWA), Namibia (NAM), South Africa (ZAF), Rest of South African Customs Union (XSC) Benin (BEN), Burkina Faso (BFA), Cameroon (CMR), Cote d'ivoire (CIV), Ghana (GHA), Guinea (GIN), Nigeria (NGA), Senegal (SEN), Togo (TGO), Rest of Western Africa (XWF), Central Africa (XCF), South Central Africa (XAC), Ethiopia (ETH), Kenya (KEN), Madagascar (MDG), Malawi (MWI), Mauritius (MUS), Mozambique (MOZ), Rwanda (RWA), Tanzania United Republic of (TZA), Uganda (UGA), Zambia (ZMB), Zimbabwe (ZWE), Rest of Eastern Africa (XEC) Turkey (TUR) Cambodia (KHM), Indonesia (IDN), Lao People's Democratic Republic (LAO), Malaysia (MYS), Philippines (PHL), Singapore (SGP), Thailand (THA), Viet Nam (VNM), Rest of Southeast Asia (XSE) China (CHN), Hong Kong (HKG) India (IND) Japan (JPN) Korea Republic of (KOR) Mongolia (MNG), Taiwan (TWN), Rest of East Asia (XEA), Brunei Darussalam (BRN), Bangladesh (BGD), Nepal (NPL), Pakistan (PAK), Sri Lanka (LKA), Rest of South Asia (XSA) EU27 Belgium and Luxembourg France Germany Ireland Italy Netherlands Poland Portugal Rest of EU27 Belgium (BEL), Luxembourg (LUX) France (FRA) Germany (DEU) Ireland (IRL) Italy (ITA) Netherlands (NLD) Poland (POL) Portugal (PRT) Austria (AUT), Cyprus (CYP), Czech Republic (CZE), Denmark (DNK), Estonia (EST), Finland (FIN), Greece (GRC), Hungary (HUN), Latvia (LVA), Lithuania (LTU), Malta (MLT), Slovakia (SVK), Slovenia (SVN), Bulgaria (BGR), Croatia (HRV), Romania (ROU) 90

95 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit Spain MIRAGE region Spain (ESP) GTAP region Sweden Sweden (SWE) North America Canada Canada (CAN) Mexico Mexico (MEX) USA Oceania Australia and New Zealand Oceania Rest of Europe United States of America (USA) Australia (AUS), New Zealand (NZL) Rest of Oceania (XOC) CIS countries Belarus (BLR), Ukraine (UKR), Rest of Eastern Europe (XEE), Kazakhstan (KAZ), Tajikistan (TJK), Kyrgyzstan (KGZ), Rest of Former Soviet Union (XSU), Armenia (ARM), Azerbaijan (AZE), Georgia (GEO) EFTA Russia Rest of the World Rest of the World South America Brazil Switzerland (CHE), Norway (NOR), Rest of EFTA (XEF) Russian Federation (RUS) Rest of North America (XNA), Albania (ALB), Rest of Europe (XER), Rest of the World (XTW) Brazil (BRA) Rest of Latin America Rest of Mercosur Bolivia, Plurinational Republic of (BOL), Chile (CHL), Colombia (COL), Ecuador (ECU), Peru (PER), Venezuela (VEN), Rest of South America (XSM), Costa Rica (CRI), Guatemala (GTM), Honduras (HND), Nicaragua (NIC), Panama (PAN), El Salvador (SLV), Rest of Central America (XCA), Dominican Republic (DOM), Jamaica (JAM), Puerto Rico (PRI), Trinidad and Tobago (TTO), Caribbean (XCB) Argentina (ARG), Paraguay (PRY), Uruguay (URY) United Kingdom UK United Kingdom (GBR) 91

96 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Table B.2: Aggregation of sectors MIRAGE sector GTAP sector MIRAGE sector GTAP sector Agriculture Industry Animal products Animal products nec (oap) Chemistry Chemical.rubber.plastic prods (crp) Beverages and Tobacco Beverages and tobacco products (b_t) Electronic Cattle Cattle.sheep.goats.horses (ctl) Energy Electronic equipment (ele) Coal (coa), Oil (oil), Gas (gas), Petroleum. coal products (p_c), Electricity (ely), Gas manufacture. distribution (gdt) Cereals Cereal grains nec (gro) Ferrous Metals Ferrous metals (i_s) Dairy Dairy products (mil) Machinery Machinery and equipment nec (ome) Fiber crops Plant-based fibers (pfb) Metal products Metal products (fmp) Fishing Fishing (fsh) Metals n.e.c. Metals nec (nfm) Forestry Forestry (frs) Minerals Minerals nec (omn), Mineral products nec (nmm) Oil seeds Oil seeds (osd) Other Manufacturing Manufactures nec (omf) Other Crops Crops nec (ocr) Paper Paper products. publishing (ppp) Other food Red Meat Rice Sugar Vegetable oils and fats Vegetables and fruits Wheat White Meat Wool Raw milk (rmk), Food products nec (ofd) Meat: (cmt) cattle.sheep.goats.horse Paddy rice (pdr), Processed rice (pcr) Sugar cane. sugar beet (c_b), Sugar (sgr) Vegetable oils and fats (vol) Vegetables. fruit. nuts (v_f) Wheat (wht) Meat products nec (omt) Wool. silk-worm cocoons (wol) Textile Transport equipment n.e.c. Vehicles and parts Wood Services Business Services Communication Finance Insurance Other Services Public Services Trade Transport Textiles (tex), Wearing apparel (wap), Leather products (lea) Transport equipment nec (otn) Motor vehicles and parts (mvh) Wood products (lum) Business services nec (obs) Communication (cmn) Financial services nec (ofi) Insurance (isr) Water (wtr), Construction (cns), Recreation and other services (ros), Dwellings (dwe) PubAdmin/Defence/Health/Educat (osg) Trade (trd) Transport nec (otp), Sea transport (wtp), Air transport (atp) Note: a Raw milk (rmk) is not aggregated with Dairy Products (mil) because this product is not traded at all and an aggregation would lead to difficulties in interpreting the results. 92

97 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit B.3. Non-tariff measures in the MIRAGE model Estimations of the trade restrictiveness of non-tariff measures for goods are taken from Kee et al (2009). However, rather than being bilateral, these measures are only importer-specific, and cannot represent the preferential access enjoyed by EU countries. To deal with this limitation we adopt a dual strategy. First, we introduce exporter-importer variation during aggregation of NTM trade restrictiveness indices as in Disdier et al. (2016), using reference group weights to aggregate from the HS-6 level to the sector level considered in this study. Second, we adjust the level of trade restrictiveness within the EU: we assume that between EU countries, all the restrictiveness that could have been withdrawn in a potential EU-US trade agreement ( actionable measures) has already been removed, based on the estimates in Berden et al. (2009). The resulting reduction in NTMs trade restrictiveness within the EU, compared to NTMs related to extra-eu trade partners, is presented in Table B.3. In particular, this approach results in NTMs in the agri-food sectors that are, on average, 53% less restrictive within the EU than between EU and non-eu countries. Table B.3: Reduction in intra-eu trade restrictiveness of NTMs Agriculture MIRAGE sector Sector from Berden et al. (2009) Reduction (%) Animal products, Beverages and Tobacco, Cattle, Cereals, Dairy, Fiber crops, Fishing, Forestry, Oil seeds, Other Crops, Other food, Red Meat, Rice, Sugar, Vegetable oils and fats, Vegetables and fruits, Wheat, White Meat, Wool Industry Food & beverages 53.0 Energy, Minerals, Other Manufacturing All Industry 52.0 Transport equipment n.e.c., Vehicles and parts Automobile 48.0 Chemistry Chemicals 63.0 Electronic Electronics 41.0 Machinery Machinery 55.0 Paper Office equipment 52.0 Ferrous Metals, Metal products, Metals n.e.c. Steel 62.0 Textile Textiles 50.0 Wood Wood 60.0 Services Public Services All Services 47.6 Communication Communication 70.0 Finance Financial 49.0 Insurance Insurance 52.0 Business Services, Trade Other business services 51.0 Other Services Personal, recreational services,construction 37.5 Transport Travel services 40.0 Source: Berden et al. (2009) 93

98 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 94

99 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit ANNEX C: ADDITIONAL TABLES Table C.1: EU27 sector exports by destination and ranked by largest decrease in exports towards the world, WTO scenario, 2030 Sector BAU (USD mn) Total World European Union (27) United Kingdom Rest of the World Var. (USD mn) Var. (%) BAU (USD mn) Var. (USD mn) Var. (%) BAU (USD mn) Var. (USD mn) Var. (%) BAU (USD mn) Var. (USD mn) Var. (%) Total Agrifood 672,808 (8%) -27, ,860 (9%) + 3, ,389 (10%) -33, ,558 (6%) + 2, Other food 222,952 (33%) -10, ,501 (33%) + 1, ,019 (35%) -12, ,433 (33%) White Meat 50,286 (7%) -5, ,588 (8%) ,676 (12%) -6, ,022 (5%) Dairy 65,878 (10%) -4, ,954 (11%) ,207 (10%) -4, ,718 (8%) Beverages and Tobacco 104,631 (16%) -1, ,550 (12%) ,931 (16%) -2, ,149 (21%) Vegetables and fruits 46,832 (7%) -1, ,961 (8%) ,768 (9%) -2, ,103 (5%) Red Meat 19,966 (3%) -1, ,322 (4%) ,658 (3%) -1, ,986 (2%) Other Crops 39,425 (6%) ,867 (6%) ,137 (6%) -1, ,420 (6%) Vegetable oils and fats 26,082 (4%) ,186 (4%) ,380 (3%) ,516 (3%) Cattle 5,961 (1%) ,331 (1%) (1%) ,951 (1%) Animal products 20,072 (3%) ,856 (3%) (1%) ,510 (4%) Sugar 8,169 (1%) ,827 (1%) (1%) ,950 (1%) Rice 1,594 (0%) ,153 (0%) (0%) (0%) Cereals 12,265 (2%) ,590 (2%) (1%) ,285 (1%) Fishing 9,419 (1%) ,374 (2%) (1%) ,484 (1%) Oil seeds 8,926 (1%) ,180 (2%) (0%) ,607 (1%) Wool 751 (0%) (0%) (0%) (0%) Fiber crops 574 (0%) (0%) (0%) (0%) Forestry 14,154 (2%) ,255 (2%) (1%) ,625 (3%) Wheat 14,871 (2%) ,155 (2%) (0%) ,503 (3%) Total Industry 5,970,967 (71%) -122, ,145,487 (74%) +58, ,051 (71%) -207, ,447,428 (69%) +27, Total Services 1,718,543 (21%) -4, ,211 (17%) + 2, ,946 (18%) -20, ,386 (25%) +13, Notes: Sectors are ranked by decreasing loss (in value) of total exports to the World. Levels are given in 2011 USD million and percentages. For instance, Other food represents 33% of EU agri-food exports to the world, while EU agri-food exports to the world represent 8% of total EU exports to the world. Variations in USD million and percentage points with respect to the BAU scenario. Source: Authors calculations using MIRAGE-e. 95

100 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Table C.2: Country/Sector Netherlands Total Agri-food White Meat Other food Other Crops Ireland Total Agri-food Other food Dairy Red Meat France Total Agri-food Other food Dairy EU27 subregions export to UK in Agri-food sectors: aggregate and three sectors with the largest variations, 2030 Beverages and Tobacco Rest of EU27 Total Agri-food Other food White Meat Dairy Germany Total Agri-food Other food White Meat Beverages and Tobacco Italy Total Agri-food Other food Dairy BAU WTO WTO (Tariff only) WTO (Ireland NTM) Var. Var. Var. Var. Var. Var. Level (USD mn.) (%) (USD mn.) (%) (USD mn.) (%) 10,104 (23%) 2,289 (23%) 2,854 (28%) 2,339 (23%) 9,145 (22%) 2,377 (26%) 1,529 (17%) 1,271 (14%) 9,180 (12%) 2,694 (29%) 1,169 (13%) 3,430 (37%) 4,685 (7%) 1,716 (37%) 1,071 (23%) 817 (17%) 5,239 (5%) 2,840 (54%) 533 (10%) 802 (15%) 4,708 (13%) 1,800 (38%) 349 (7%) -6, , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , ,

101 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit Country/Sector White Meat Belgium and Luxembourg Total Agri-food Other food Dairy White Meat Spain Total Agri-food Vegetables and fruits Other food Vegetable oils and fats Poland Total Agri-food Other food White Meat Dairy Sweden Total Agri-food Other food Beverages and Tobacco Fishing Portugal Total Agri-food Other food White Meat Beverages and Tobacco BAU WTO WTO (Tariff only) WTO (Ireland NTM) Var. Var. Var. Var. Var. Var. Level (USD mn.) (%) (USD mn.) (%) (USD mn.) (%) 319 (7%) 3,957 (8%) 2,182 (55%) 361 (9%) 282 (7%) 4,336 (10%) 1,664 (38%) 1,155 (27%) 230 (5%) 1,747 (8%) 960 (55%) 353 (20%) 111 (6%) 793 (4%) 259 (33%) 175 (22%) 239 (30%) 498 (8%) 182 (37%) 63 (13%) 147 (29%) , , , , , , , , , , Note: Levels are given in million 2011 USD, Variations in percentage points. BAU percentages for Total Agri-food are percentages of total exports to the UK, while for sectors it represents the percentage within agri-food exports. Source: Authors calculations using MIRAGE-e. 97

102 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Table C.3: Agri-food value-added in EU27 regions, in the WTO scenario: aggregate, five most impacted sectors and decomposition of variation, 2030 Country/Sector European Union (27) BAU WTO VA decomposition Var (USD Dom. Exp. to Exp. to Exp. to Level Var (%) mn.) demand UK EU Row 98 Iceberg cost Total Agri-food 736,581-5, , Other food 254,129-2, , Vegetables and fruits 67, , White Meat 34, Dairy 42, Animal products 48, Ireland Total Agri-food 10,596-1, Other food 5, Dairy Cattle White Meat Red Meat Netherlands Total Agri-food 46,458-1, , Other food 17, White Meat 1, Other Crops 8, Vegetables and fruits Beverages and Tobacco Rest of EU27 4, , Total Agri-food 156, Other food 42, White Meat 7, Dairy 10, Animal products 13, Forestry 15, Italy Total Agri-food 86, Other food 26, Vegetables and fruits 16, Dairy 4, White Meat 2, Animal products 4,

103 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit Country/Sector France BAU WTO VA decomposition Var (USD Dom. Exp. to Exp. to Exp. to Level Var (%) mn.) demand UK EU Row 99 Iceberg cost Total Agri-food 149, , Other food 61, Dairy 9, Cattle 5, Wheat 4, Red Meat 6, Germany Total Agri-food 94, Other food 42, Animal products 6, Beverages and Tobacco Vegetables and fruits 9, , White Meat 3, Spain Total Agri-food 81, Vegetables and fruits 11, Other food 22, Rice Sugar Wheat 1, Belgium and Luxembourg Total Agri-food 21, Other food 7, Beverages and Tobacco 4, Animal products White Meat Red Meat Poland Total Agri-food 55, Other food 18, White Meat 4, Vegetables and fruits 4, Animal products 5, Forestry 2, Portugal Total Agri-food 13,

104 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Country/Sector BAU WTO VA decomposition Var (USD Dom. Exp. to Exp. to Exp. to Level Var (%) mn.) demand UK EU Row Iceberg cost Other food 3, White Meat Vegetables and fruits Beverages and Tobacco 1, , Animal products Sweden Total Agri-food 21, Forestry 7, Beverages and Tobacco 1, Dairy Red Meat Other food 6, Note: Levels and decomposition are given in million USD, Variations in percentage points. Source: Authors calculations using MIRAGE-e. Table C.4: Gross Domestic Product (volume) and variation in 2030 Region BAU Level Var. ($ bn.) WTO Var. (%) WTO (Tariff only) Var. ($ Var. bn.) (%) WTO (Ireland NTM) Var. ($ Var. bn.) (%) EU27 20, Germany 4, France 3, Rest of EU27 3, Italy 2, Spain 1, Netherlands 1, Poland 1, Sweden Belgium and Luxembourg Ireland Portugal UK 3, Rest of the World 102, Note: Levels are given in billion 2011 USD, Variations in billion 2011 USD and percentage points. Source: Authors calculations using MIRAGE-e. 100

105 EU - UK agricultural trade: state of play and possible impacts of Brexit ANNEX D: ADDITIONAL TABLES HS6 DETAILS Table D.1: Number of HS6 products, by GTAP sector GTAP sectors Number of HS6 products Animal products n.e.c. (oap) 48 Beverages and tobacco products (b_t) 31 Bovine, cattle, sheep, and goats horses (ctl) 8 Bovine meat products (cmt) 30 Cereal grains n.e.c. (gro) 10 Crops n.e.c. (ocr) 63 Dairy products (mil) 24 Fishing (fsh) 41 Food products n.e.c. (ofd) 248 Forestry (frs) 25 Meat products n.e.c.(omt) 43 Oil seeds (osd) 16 Paddy Rice (pdr) 2 Plant based fibers (pfb) 8 Processed rice (pcr) 2 Sugar (sgr) 7 Sugar cane and sugar beet (c_b) 2 Vegetable oils and fats (vol) 47 Vegetables, fruit and nuts (v_f) 89 Wheat (wht) 2 Wool, silk, worm cocoons (wol) 6 Sources: GTAP, United Nations HS6 classification (revision 1996), Authors calculations. 101

106 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Table D.2: EU27 imports, HS6 level (1/2) GTAP HS6 LABEL MFN IMPORTS FROM UK (1) IMPORTS FROM ROW (2) % MAIN IMPORTER FROM UK VALUE OF IMPORTS Dog or cat food (retail) ,593 7 Germany Animal feed preparations n.e.s ,563 7 Ireland 163 Food products n.e.c Cereal foods obtained by swelling, roasting of cereal , Ireland Wheat or meslin flour Ireland Communion wafers, rice paper, bakers wares n.e.s ,814 7 Ireland Milk not concentrated nor sweetened 1-6% fat ,868 6 Ireland 228 Dairy products Cheese except fresh, grated, processed or blue-veined Fresh cheese, unfermented whey cheese, curd ,291 3 Ireland ,385 4 Ireland Butter ,818 3 France Milk and cream powder unsweetened > 1.5% fat Belgium Bovine cuts boneless, fresh or chilled ,681 5 Ireland 90 Bovine meat products Lamb carcasses and half carcasses, fresh or chilled Bovine cuts boneless, frozen France ,823 4 Ireland Bovine carcasses and ,771 4 Netherlands

107 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding half carcasses, fresh or chilled Bovine cuts bone in, fresh or chilled ,238 2 Netherlands 30 Source: MAcMap-HS6 (2013) and BACI (Average flow ), Trade data expresses in millions of USD, MFN tariffs are expressed in percentage and aggregated MAcMap-HS6 s weighting schemes. Authors calculations. Table D.3: EU27 imports, HS6 level (2/2) GTAP HS6 LABEL MFN IMPORTS FROM UK (1) IMPORTS FROM ROW (2) % MAIN IMPORTER FROM UK VALUE OF IMPORT S Fowls, cuts & offal, frozen ,147 7 Ireland Swine cuts, fresh or chilled, n.e.s ,614 3 Poland 77 Meat products n.e.c Fowls, cuts & offal, fresh or chilled Swine meat, salted/dried/smo ked not ham/shoulder/b elly ,556 5 Ireland ,246 4 Ireland Bovine meat, offal n.e.s., not livers, prepared/preser ved Ireland Cigarette or pipe tobacco and tobacco substitute mixes ,920 6 Germany Cigarettes containing tobacco ,568 2 Ireland 31 Beverages and tobacco products Undenatured ethyl alcohol > 80% by volume Beverage waters, sweetened or flavoured ,568 9 Netherlands ,267 9 Ireland Non-alcoholic beverages n.e.s., except fruit, vegetable juices ,784 4 Ireland 32 Source: MAcMap-HS6 (2013) and BACI (Average flow ), Trade data expresses in millions of USD, MFN tariffs are expressed in percentage and aggregated MAcMap-HS6 s weighting schemes. Authors calculations. 103

108 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Table D.4: EU27 exports, HS6 level (1/2) GTAP HS6 LABEL MFN EXPORTS TO UK (1) EXPORTS TO ROW (2) % MAIN EXPORTER TO UK VALUE OF EXPORTS Dog or cat food (retail) , France Animal feed preparations n.e.s ,718 5 France 71 Food products n.e.c Communion wafers, rice paper, bakers wares n.e.s ,597 10, Germany Orange juice, not fermented, spirited, or frozen , Belgium Glucose, glucose syrup < 20% fructose ,381 9 Belgium Cheese except fresh, grated, processed or blueveined ,150 14,745 8 Ireland 426 Dairy products Fresh cheese, unfermented whey cheese, curd , France Butter ,578 9 Ireland Buttermilk, curdled milk, cream, kephir, etc , France Cheese processed, not grated or powdered , Ireland Swine meat, salted/dried/smoked not ham/shoulder/belly , Denmark 320 Meat products n.e.c Fowls, cuts & offal, frozen Swine cuts, fresh or chilled, n.e.s , Netherlands , Germany Fowls, cuts & offal, fresh or chilled , Netherlands Sausages, similar products of meat, meat offal & blood , Germany 173 Source: MAcMap-HS6 (2013) and BACI (Average flow ), Trade data expresses in millions of USD, MFN tariffs are expressed in percentage and aggregated MAcMap-HS6 s weighting schemes. Authors calculations. 104

109 Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding Table D.5: EU27 exports, HS6 level (2/2) GTAP HS6 LABEL MFN EXPORTS TO UK (1) EXPORTS TO ROW (2) % MAIN EXPORTER TO UK VALUE OF EXPORTS Cigarettes containing tobacco ,840 3 Czech Republic Grape wines n.e.s., fortified wine or must, pack < 2l 4.3 2,310 16, France 1,038 Beverages and tobacco products Nonalcoholic beverages n.e.s., except fruit, vegetable juices , Netherlands Undenatured ethyl alcohol > 80% by volume , Netherlands Cigarette or pipe tobacco and tobacco substitute mixes ,473 4 Netherlands Tomatoes, fresh or chilled , Netherlands Cucumbers and gherkins, fresh or chilled , Netherlands 98 Vegetables, fruit and nuts Mushrooms, fresh or chilled Mandarin, clementine & citrus hybrids, fresh or dried , Ireland ,147 9 Spain Cauliflowers and headed broccoli, fresh or chilled Spain 149 Source: MAcMap-HS6 (2013) and BACI (Average flow ), Trade data expresses in millions of USD, MFN tariffs are expressed in percentage and aggregated MAcMap-HS6 s weighting schemes. Authors calculations. 105

110 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 106

111 DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT Research for AGRI Committee - Possible transitional arrangements related to agriculture in the light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues STUDY Abstract There is the potential for severe disruption of agri-food trade between the UK and the EU27 as the UK prepares to leave the EU. This study reviews the additional trade costs that might arise and how they might be avoided under alternative future trade arrangements. The role of a transitional period in order to avoid a cliff-edge for trade is examined. Options under the Common Agricultural Policy to address the negative consequences of Brexit for agricultural markets are discussed. IP/B/AGRI/CEI/ /C5/SC2 October 2017 PE EN

112 This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development. AUTHOR Alan Matthews Research manager: Albert Massot Project and publication assistance: Virginija Kelmelytė Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies, European Parliament LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE PUBLISHER To contact the Policy Department or to subscribe to updates on our work for the AGRI Committee please write to: Manuscript completed in October 2017 European Union, 2017 Please use the following reference to cite this study: Matthews, A., 2017, Research for AGRI Committee Possible transitional arrangements related to agriculture in the light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues, European Parliament, Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies, Brussels Please use the following reference for in-text citations: Matthews, A. (2017) DISCLAIMER The opinions expressed in this document are the sole responsibility of the author and do not necessarily represent the official position of the European Parliament. Reproduction and translation for non-commercial purposes are authorized, provided the source is acknowledged and the publisher is given prior notice and sent a copy.

113 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues BRIEF PROFESSIONAL DESCRIPTION Alan Matthews is Professor Emeritus of European Agricultural Policy at Trinity College, Dublin, Ireland. His research interests include the areas of agricultural policy and modelling, applied trade policy and WTO rules affecting agriculture and food security. He has published widely and has undertaken commissioned studies for the European Commission, the European Parliament, the Food and Agricultural Organisation of the United Nations and the OECD in these areas. He is a past-president of the European Association of Agricultural Economists and is currently a member of Ireland s Climate Change Advisory Council. He is a regular contributor to the blog capreform.eu on issues relating to the EU s Common Agricultural Policy. 109

114 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 110

115 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues CONTENTS LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS 113 LIST OF TABLES 115 LIST OF FIGURES 115 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY INTRODUCTION Purpose of the study Article The UK position on the long-term trade relationship The EU27 position on the long-term trade relationship THE ISSUES AT STAKE FOR AGRI-FOOD TRADE Trade terms in the no deal scenario Specific issues facing Ireland Trade arrangements to avoid or mitigate trade costs Models of the future relationship The WTO dimension of UK withdrawal AVOIDING A CLIFF EDGE FOR AGRI-FOOD TRADE The need for transition arrangements Views of the parties on transition Extending the date for Brexit beyond 29 March Extending the EU acquis to a non-member EFTA/EEA membership as an interim arrangement A temporary customs union as an interim arrangement A free trade agreement as an interim arrangement Rescheduling the phasing of Article 50 negotiations PROTECTING AGRICULTURAL INTERESTS FOLLOWING BREXIT Support in the case of market disturbance Support for adjustment Strengthened promotion policy Improved access to third country markets TRQs for UK-EU27 trade 192 REFERENCES 195 ANNEX 1. EXAMPLES OF CUSTOMS CLEARANCE COSTS

116 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 112

117 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS ACAA AEO AEOC AEOS AGRI AGRIFISH AVE BCP BIP BTAMS CAP CDS CET CFP CHED CITES CJEU DPE CETA CVED DCFTA EAFRD ECMT EEA EGF EIB EU FTA GATT HACCP HGV Agreement on Conformity Assessment and Acceptance of Industrial Products Authorised Economic Operator Authorised Economic Operator for customs simplification Authorised Economic Operator for security and safety Agriculture and Rural Development Committee Agricultural and Fisheries Council Ad Valorem Equivalent Border Control Point Border Inspection Point Bound Total Aggregate Measurement of Support Common Agricultural Policy Customs Declaration Service Common External Tariff Common Fisheries Policy Common Health Entry Document Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora Court of Justice of the European Union Designated Point of Entry EU-Canada Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement Common Veterinary Entry Document Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Area European Fund for Rural Development European Conference of Ministers for Transport European Economic Area European Globalisation Fund European Investment Bank European Union Free Trade Area General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade Hazard Analysis and Critical Control Point Heavy Goods Vehicle 113

118 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies HMRC IMSOC MFF MFN MRA NAO OECD PEM PSE RDP ROOs SAD SPS TARIC TEU TFEU TIR TRQ UCC UK WTO Her Majesty s Revenue and Customs Integrated Management System for Official Controls Multi-annual Financial Framework Most Favoured Nation Mutual Recognition Agreement National Audit Office Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Pan-Euro-Mediterranean preferential rules of origin Producer Support Estimate Rural Development Programme Rules of Origin Single Administrative Document Sanitary and Phytosanitary Standards Integrated Tariff of the European Union Treaty of the European Union Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union Transports Internationaux Routiers, International Road Transport Tariff Rate Quota Union Customs Code United Kingdom World Trade Organisation 114

119 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues LIST OF TABLES Table 1 Timeline of events around the UK withdrawal from the EU 130 Table 2 EU's applied MFN tariff summary, Table 3 Examples of customs and other controls in international trade 136 Table 4 Topics and actions for support in the 2017 Work Programme for information and promotion measures for agricultural products 190 LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1 Impact of UK referendum result on value of sterling 123 Figure 2 Gap between EU and world market prices 135 Figure 3 Alternative post-brexit trade scenarios beyond WTO terms 142 Figure 4 Main elements of different EU trade arrangements 151 Figure 5 Annual lorry traffic and EU share of trade for selected major UK ports in

120 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 116

121 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Introduction On 29 March 2017 the United Kingdom (UK) notified the President of the European Council of its intention to withdraw from the European Union (EU). Article 50 of the Treaty of the European Union sets out the procedures to be followed when a Member State wishes to leave the EU. The UK has set out its ambition for a bold and ambitious free trade agreement with the EU, while respecting its four red lines of ending the jurisdiction of the European Court of Justice, controlling immigration from the EU, ending most contributions to the EU budget, and being able to strike trade deals with third countries. The EU has set out its position through the European Council (Art. 50) guidelines, the Council s negotiating directives and resolutions of the European Parliament, emphasising that a nonmember of the Union, that does not live up to the same obligations as a member, cannot have the same rights and enjoy the same benefits as a member. It also set out a phased approach to the withdrawal negotiations in which progress must be made on three key withdrawal issues before it will give a mandate to move to the second phase of negotiations on the future relationship. Withdrawal negotiations began on 22 June 2017 but the European Council (Art. 50) decided on 20 October 2017 that insufficient progress had been made in the first phase of the negotiations to justify preparing a mandate for the second phase. However, it invited the Council (Art. 50) and the Union negotiator to start internal preparatory discussions in relation to the framework for the future relationship and on transitional arrangements, with a view to being able to move to the second phase of the negotiations in December The issues at stake for agri-food trade In the absence of a future trade agreement tariffs would be re-imposed on bilateral UK-EU27 trade. The tariffs applicable to UK exports would be those in the EU s Common External Tariff (CET). The tariffs applicable to EU exports are not yet known, but at least initially may be kept at the CET level. Even apart from the imposition of tariffs, the UK would be a less attractive market for EU exporters because exporters would lose the preferential trade transfers they currently earn on sales to the UK market. These represent the difference between the price paid by UK consumers for EU27 exports behind the EU tariff wall and the price EU exporters would receive if the products were sold instead at world market prices. Customs clearance costs would be an additional cost for firms exporting or importing from the UK. These costs would be increased for certain agricultural and food products because of the need for additional border checks to ensure compliance with EU27 food safety, plant and animal health regulations. In the absence of an agreement covering road transport services, hauliers travelling between the UK and EU27 could face additional costs because of the need to secure licences with individual Member States. Ireland faces particular issues in the event of a hard Brexit because of the importance of the UK land bridge for the transport of agri-food products to and from the EU27, and because transport from one location in Ireland to another may in some instances need to travel through Northern Ireland. 117

122 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies A range of potential trade arrangements are available which address one or more of these potential trade costs. However, the current ability to trade frictionlessly between the UK and the EU27 is due to the UK s EU membership and can only be maintained if the UK were to remain a member of the EU. There are a number of models for the future long-term trade relationship between the UK and the EU27. These include the Canada, Turkey, Ukraine, Swiss and Norway models. The UK government has ruled out the Canada, Turkey and Norway models, but it has not defined where it might like to end up between the Ukraine and Swiss models. The EU27, for its part, is unlikely to make the Swiss model available because of its institutional deficiencies, though its attitude to the Ukraine model has not been clarified. The Ukraine model is implemented through an Association Agreement with the EU which has been specifically endorsed by the European Parliament. Avoiding a cliff-edge for agri-food trade Even if the UK and the EU27 were to conclude an agreement on the withdrawal conditions and on the nature of their future relationship by 29 March 2019, traders face a cliff-edge situation because of the lack of preparedness of customs administrations and other relevant authorities on both sides to manage border controls; the lack of knowledge on the part of the large number of new businesses that will face the need to seek customs clearance for their exports and imports; and the almost certain congestion at major ports of entry and exit because of the extra time required for these controls. Both parties have indicated a willingness to consider a transition period. In this study, the purpose of a transitional period would be to maintain the trade status quo between the UK and the EU27 until the arrangements for the future trade relationship were put in place. Both parties have indicated their red lines regarding matters on which they would insist during a transition period. There is little clarity, however, as to how extensive such a transition arrangement might be and what laws and regulations it would have to cover to ensure that trade, including trade in agri-food products, would continue on the same basis as it does today. One option is that the UK would remain a Member State of the EU for a further time-limited period, either by including a withdrawal date later than 29 March 2019 in the withdrawal agreement or by unanimously agreeing to extend the Art.50 TEU deadline for the negotiations. Another option is that the UK would agree to bind itself to following the relevant Union acquis as a non-member State for a time-limited period after 29 March 2019 while also joining a temporary customs union for this period. Negotiating what would effectively be a complete if temporary trade agreement at the same time as the parties are negotiating a withdrawal agreement and the framework for their future relations may be more than can be achieved in the remaining time available. Fall-back positions which would avoid some but not all of the additional trade costs, such as a temporary customs union on its own or just a free trade agreement in goods, should be considered if it proves impossible to reach an agreement in which the UK remains bound by the relevant Union acquis in the time available. Following the mandate at the October 2017 meeting of the European Council (Art.50), the General Council (Art. 50) and the Union negotiator should seek to rapidly progress preparatory work particularly on models of transitional arrangements. This should help to clarify what might be the minimum requirements to ensure that trade can continue to take place with the UK as it does today for the duration of the transition period, and what the appropriate balance 118

123 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues of rights and obligations might be during this period. Specific issues for consideration will include whether UK membership of the CAP and the Common Fisheries Policy (CFP) will be deemed necessary as a prerequisite for continued free trade in agricultural and fishery products during the transition period, as well as arrangements to ensure the continued protection of Geographical Indications in the UK. Protecting agricultural interests following Brexit The EU has gained considerable experience in recent years in the management of adverse shocks to agricultural markets which can be drawn upon in designing possible responses to a negative Brexit shock. They include the use of safety-net intervention; targeted aid; mobilisation of the crisis reserve; advancing direct payments; making use of the income stabilisation tool; permitting flexibility in state aids; and facilitating supply management. Farmers and food businesses in the EU27 will need such support to adjust to the structural consequences of a hard Brexit. This might include the provision of adjustment assistance; greater use of financial instruments; a strengthened promotion policy; and improved access to third country markets. A specific market access concern is how UK TRQs will make provision for traditional EU27 export flows, and vice versa for EU27 TRQs. Merely splitting the EU TRQs does not go far enough to protect the interests of EU producers to access the UK market in the event of a hard Brexit. 119

124 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 120

125 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues 1. INTRODUCTION KEY FINDINGS On 29 March 2017 the UK notified the President of the European Council of its intention to withdraw from the European Union (EU). Article 50 of the Treaty of the European Union sets out the procedures to be followed when a Member State wishes to leave the EU. The UK has set out its ambition for a bold and ambitious free trade agreement with the EU, while respecting its four red lines of ending the jurisdiction of the European Court of Justice, controlling immigration from the EU, ending most contributions to the EU budget, and being able to strike trade deals with third countries. The EU has set out its position through the European Council (Art. 50) guidelines, the Council s negotiating directives and resolutions of the European Parliament, emphasising that a non-member of the Union, that does not live up to the same obligations as a member, cannot have the same rights and enjoy the same benefits as a member. It also set out a phased approach to the withdrawal negotiations in which progress must be made on three key withdrawal issues before it will give a mandate to move to the second phase of negotiations on the future relationship. Withdrawal negotiations began on 22 June 2017 but the European Council (Art. 50) decided on 20 October 2017 that insufficient progress had been made in the first phase of the negotiations to justify preparing a mandate for the second phase. However, it invited the Council (Art. 50) and the Union negotiator to start internal preparatory discussions in relation to the framework for the future relationship and on transitional arrangements, with a view to being able to move to the second phase of the negotiations in December The United Kingdom (UK) Prime Minister announced in a letter to the European Council President Donald Tusk dated 29 March 2017 that the UK intended to withdraw from the European Union (EU) in accordance with Article 50(2) of the Treaty on European Union (TEU) (May 2017b).0F72 This letter followed a referendum among the UK electorate on 23 June 2016 on the question Should the United Kingdom remain a member of the European Union or leave the European Union? with the possible responses being either Remain a member of the European Union or Leave the European Union. The Leave response was supported by a narrow majority of 52% compared to 48% for Remain. The Prime Minister s letter did not specify a specific date for this withdrawal. However, in her speech delivered in Florence on 22 September 2017 she made clear that The United Kingdom will cease to be a member of the European Union on 29th March 2019 (May 2017c) Purpose of the study This decision of the UK to exit the EU (Brexit) threatens to unwind over four decades of increasing inter-dependence, including trade inter-dependence, within the framework of the EU. The extent of the possible disruption to existing trade flows will depend, in part, on the 72 Throughout this report, the term European Union or EU is used to refer to the existing Union of 28 Member States. The term EU27 is used to refer to the Union following the departure of the United Kingdom. 121

126 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies nature of any future trade relationship that the UK and the EU27 may agree. Negotiating this relationship is likely to take time and may not be in place before 29 March 2019 which is the end of the two-year time limit specified in Art 50 TEU when withdrawal must take place if there is no agreement on an alternative date. 1F73 This has given rise to discussion about a possible transition period, or implementation period, which would preserve much of the existing Union rules which govern internal trade while applying them to a non-eu state until the future relationship is ready to take effect. Various legal scholars have put forward ideas on how this might be achieved. There remains the possibility that the UK and the EU27 will fail to conclude a withdrawal agreement within the two-year time limit specified in Article 50 TEU. The result would be a disorderly withdrawal in which future trade relations can best be described as a hard Brexit. The withdrawal of the UK from the EU without a trade arrangement in place would lead to huge disruption to UK-EU27 agri-food trade. In 2016, the EU27 exported agrifood products worth 40.3 billion to the UK, while the EU27 imported agri-food products to the value of 16.8 billion from the UK. 2F74 Within the single market and Customs Union, 3F75 this trade takes place seamlessly and without frictions; for example, it allows just-in-time deliveries to supermarkets or to plants for further processing in either party from suppliers in the other party. This trade would be utterly disrupted by a hard Brexit, for three reasons. The first reason is that additional trade costs would apply under a hard Brexit scenario which are described in detail in Chapter 2. They include the levying of tariffs, the costs of customs clearance, and the costs of demonstrating compliance with the other party s regulatory standards. These costs would bear particularly heavily on the agri-food sector because of the generally higher level of agricultural tariffs and the greater need for physical checks when food, and particularly animal products, cross frontiers. The second reason is the lack of preparedness and the potential for huge disruption on both sides of the UK and EU27 border in a hard Brexit scenario. This scenario would require the updating of customs computer systems, the provision of parking space at ports to accommodate the additional delays expected when clearing customs, expansion of the laboratory and other facilities needed at entry points to check goods for compliance with regulatory standards, the recruitment of additional staff to cope with the expected dramatic increase in the workload of border control officials once UK-EU27 trade became external trade, and considerable investment in training the hundreds of thousands of new businesses which would now be involved in extra-eu trade. While businesses would learn in time to cope with many of the additional trade costs that would follow from UK exit from the EU, the requirement to adapt to sudden changes as well as the lack of readiness of the official infrastructure in the event of a hard Brexit would add to short-run disruption. Both sides will lose in this outcome, although the largest costs on the EU27 side will be borne by those Member States with the greatest exposure to UK trade. The third reason is that the economic disruption that would result from a hard Brexit would be likely to lead to a further significant depreciation of the pound sterling relative to the euro and other currencies used in the EU27. When the UK referendum result was announced on 23 June 2016, it led to an immediate 10% drop in the value of sterling which has not been reversed since then (Figure 1). There would be a strong possibility that markets would react in the same way faced with the disruptive impact of a hard Brexit. A further drop 73 The Council negotiating directives specify the withdrawal date as at the latest 30 March 2019 at 00:00 (Brussels time). The withdrawal date is sometimes referred to as Brexit Day in this study. 74 Agri-food trade is defined as trade in the Harmonised System Chapters 01-24, source Eurostat with the EU27 as reporter. 75 For clarity, we refer to the EU Customs Union throughout this paper with initial capital letters, and customs unions generally in lower case. 122

127 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues in the value of sterling would make EU27 exporters to the UK market even less competitive, on top of the additional trade costs including tariffs they would face. A lower value of sterling would reduce the price of UK-sourced food for EU27 importers, but this would only partly offset the higher trade costs they would pay including tariffs in the event of a hard Brexit. Figure 16: Impact of UK referendum result on value of sterling Source: European Central Bank Against this background, this study has three objectives which are developed in the following three chapters. The overall aim is to provide AGRI Committee members with an overview of the institutional choices that could help to avoid the negative outcomes of a hard Brexit for the agri-food sector, while also exploring the instruments available under the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) to mitigate the adverse impacts that may occur as a result of Brexit. Chapter 2 surveys the trade costs that agri-food traders selling into or importing from the UK might face in the event of a hard Brexit. It emphasises how these additional trade costs would bear most heavily on agri-food trade. It also highlights the likelihood of disruption if the UK leaves the EU by 29 March 2019 without an arrangement which largely replicates the existing rules for internal market EU trade. It investigates how different ideal types of trade arrangements might help to avoid some or all of these trade costs. It compares these trade arrangements with examples of current EU trade agreements with third countries. What is increasingly clear is that, even if the withdrawal agreement is successfully concluded prior to 29 March 2019 and depending on the nature of the future trade relationship, not all systems will be in place to facilitate the transition from the current rules applying to UK-EU27 trade to the rules that will apply under the future trade relationship. Again, this is particularly the case for agri-food trade. Chapter 3 sets out the views of both parties on transition arrangements and examines how agri-food trade could be affected by different types of transition arrangement. 123

128 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Any future trade relationship will introduce additional frictions and costs affecting trade flows between the UK and the EU27 compared to the current situation under the Union acquis. There is also the possibility that the withdrawal negotiations will not be successfully concluded, leading to a disorderly Brexit on 29 March Because the agri-food sector is uniquely exposed to these higher trade costs and to the negative shock of a disorderly Brexit, it is prudent to consider how ready the Union is to protect farmers from the immediate impacts of disruption and to assist them to adjust to the new market conditions that will prevail after Brexit. Chapter 4 examines the CAP measures able to support EU farmers and to strengthen agri-export incentives after a hard Brexit Article 50 The procedure for a Member State to leave the European Union is governed by Article 50 in the Treaty of European Union. Relevant extracts include: 2. A Member State which decides to withdraw shall notify the European Council of its intention. In the light of the guidelines provided by the European Council, the Union shall negotiate and conclude an agreement with that State, setting out the arrangements for its withdrawal, taking account of the framework for its future relationship with the Union. That agreement shall be negotiated in accordance with Article 218(3) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union. It shall be concluded on behalf of the Union by the Council, acting by a qualified majority, after obtaining the consent of the European Parliament. 3. The Treaties shall cease to apply to the State in question from the date of entry into force of the withdrawal agreement or, failing that, two years after the notification referred to in paragraph 2, unless the European Council, in agreement with the Member State concerned, unanimously decides to extend this period. There are three things to note about this Article: It sets a time limit of two years following the receipt of the notification to withdraw following which the Treaties would no longer apply to the withdrawing state in the absence of a withdrawal agreement. This period could be shorter if the withdrawal agreement entered into force earlier, or it could be longer if the withdrawal agreement entered into force later, or if there were unanimous agreement by the European Council and the Member State concerned to extend this time limit. The withdrawal agreement is approved by a qualified majority in the European Council (at least 72% of participating Member States (20 out of 27) representing at least 65% of the population of the 27 remaining Member States voting in favour), having first received the consent of the European Parliament. The withdrawal agreement sets out the arrangements for withdrawal of the Member State concerned, taking account of the framework for its future relationship with the Union The UK position on the long-term trade relationship The UK proposal for its future relationship with the EU27 was first set out in the Prime Minister s Lancaster House speech on 17 January 2017 (May 2017a). Its broad outline has remained consistent over time, although critics on the EU side complain that it remains incomplete and imprecise. 124

129 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues In her Lancaster House speech, the Prime Minister set out broad long-term objectives, twelve principles for the negotiations, and four red lines. These were elaborated and, in some cases repeated verbatim, in the UK White Paper The United Kingdom s exit from and new partnership with the European Union published in February 2017 (HM Government 2017d). The UK s broad objectives were defined in the Lancaster House speech as: We will pursue a bold and ambitious free trade agreement with the European Union. This agreement should allow for the freest possible trade in goods and services between Britain and the EU s member states. It should give British companies the maximum freedom to trade with and operate within European markets and let European businesses do the same in Britain. But I want to be clear. What I am proposing cannot mean membership of the single market. European leaders have said many times that membership means accepting the 4 freedoms of goods, capital, services and people. And being out of the EU but a member of the single market would mean complying with the EU s rules and regulations that implement those freedoms, without having a vote on what those rules and regulations are. It would mean accepting a role for the European Court of Justice that would see it still having direct legal authority in our country. That agreement may take in elements of current single market arrangements in certain areas on the export of cars and lorries for example, or the freedom to provide financial services across national borders as it makes no sense to start again from scratch when Britain and the remaining Member States have adhered to the same rules for so many years. A Global Britain must be free to strike trade agreements with countries from outside the European Union too. That means I do not want Britain to be part of the Common Commercial Policy and I do not want us to be bound by the Common External Tariff. These are the elements of the Customs Union that prevent us from striking our own comprehensive trade agreements with other countries. But I do want us to have a customs agreement with the EU. Whether that means we must reach a completely new customs agreement, become an associate member of the Customs Union in some way, or remain a signatory to some elements of it, I hold no preconceived position. I have an open mind on how we do it. It is not the means that matter, but the ends. The key messages in this speech were that the UK would leave the single market, it would leave the Custom Union, but it wished to pursue a bold and ambitious free trade agreement and it held open the possibility that the UK might opt into specific elements of the EU single market. Any such agreement would have to observe the four red lines mentioned in the speech:.. we will take back control of our laws and bring an end to the jurisdiction of the European Court of Justice in Britain... we will ensure we can control immigration to Britain from Europe. We will design our immigration system to ensure that we are able to control the numbers of people who come here from the EU. In future, therefore, the Free Movement Directive will no longer apply and the migration of EU nationals will be subject to UK law. 125

130 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies.. we will not be required to contribute huge sums to the EU budget. There may be some specific European programmes in which we might want to participate. If so, and this will be for us to decide, it is reasonable that we should make an appropriate contribution. But the principle is clear: the days of Britain making vast contributions to the European Union every year will end... [we] must be free to strike trade agreements with countries from outside the European Union too. Also of relevance to future trade arrangements is the UK s position on the border between Northern Ireland and Ireland. This would be the only land border between the UK and the EU27 after Brexit, as the Prime Minister recalled in her Article 50 letter. This letter contained the following commitment: We want to avoid a return to a hard border between our two countries, to be able to maintain the Common Travel Area between us, and to make sure that the UK s withdrawal from the EU does not harm the Republic of Ireland. We also have an important responsibility to make sure that nothing is done to jeopardise the peace process in Northern Ireland, and to continue to uphold the Belfast Agreement. In her Florence speech, the Prime Minister reiterated that the UK will no longer be a member of the EU single market or its Customs Union. She recognised that the single market is built on a balance of rights and obligations and identified as a joint task the need to find a new framework that allows for a close economic partnership but holds those rights and obligations in a new and different balance. She expounded on the nature of the future trade relationship in the following terms: One way of approaching this question is to put forward a stark and unimaginative choice between two models: either something based on European Economic Area membership; or a traditional Free Trade Agreement, such as that the EU has recently negotiated with Canada. I don t believe either of these options would be best for the UK or best for the European Union. European Economic Area membership would mean the UK having to adopt at home - automatically and in their entirety - new EU rules. Rules over which, in future, we will have little influence and no vote. Such a loss of democratic control could not work for the British people. I fear it would inevitably lead to friction and then a damaging re-opening of the nature of our relationship in the near future: the very last thing that anyone on either side of the Channel wants. As for a Canadian style free trade agreement, we should recognise that this is the most advanced free trade agreement the EU has yet concluded and a breakthrough in trade between Canada and the EU. But compared with what exists between Britain and the EU today, it would nevertheless represent such a restriction on our mutual market access that it would benefit neither of our economies. Not only that, it would start from the false premise that there is no pre-existing regulatory relationship between us. And precedent suggests that it could take years to negotiate. 126

131 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues On the crucial issue of how to settle disputes, for example, over regulatory issues, the Prime Minister commented: To make this partnership work, because disagreements inevitably arise, we will need a strong and appropriate dispute resolution mechanism. It is, of course, vital that any agreement reached its specific terms and the principles on which it is based are interpreted in the same way by the European Union and the United Kingdom and we want to discuss how we do that. This could not mean the European Court of Justice or indeed UK courts - being the arbiter of disputes about the implementation of the agreement between the UK and the EU however. It wouldn t be right for one party s court to have jurisdiction over the other. But I am confident we can find an appropriate mechanism for resolving disputes. The speech was more notable for what it ruled out that what it proposed. The Prime Minister ruled out both a model based on the European Economic Area (EEA) and a comprehensive free trade agreement such as the recent agreement with Canada. This implies the UK would like a deal somewhere in between these models. But where in between? She also noted that any trade agreement should implement the joint commitment that we will not accept any physical infrastructure at the border between Northern Ireland and Ireland. However, there remains a lack of precision with regard to the nature of the long-term trade relationship with the EU27 that the UK would like, and how it would avoid physical controls at the border on the island of Ireland The EU27 position on the long-term trade relationship The European Parliament adopted a resolution on 5 April 2017 on negotiations with the United Kingdom following its notification that it intended to withdraw from the European Union. It noted that the UK Prime Minister s letter triggering the Article 50 withdrawal process indicated that the UK s future relationship with the EU will not include membership of the internal market or membership of the customs union (European Parliament 2017). Whereas, nevertheless, continued membership of the United Kingdom of the internal market, the European Economic Area and/or the customs union would have been the optimal solution for both the United Kingdom and the EU-27; whereas this is not possible as long as the United Kingdom Government maintains its objections to the four freedoms and to the jurisdiction of the Court of Justice of the European Union, refuses to make a general contribution to the Union budget, and wants to conduct its own trade policy. The Parliament resolution called for the Article 50 negotiations to begin as soon as possible, and addressed fair treatment for EU27 and UK citizens who will find themselves living in the other party after Brexit, a full settlement of financial obligations, and the need to mitigate the effects of the United Kingdom s withdrawal on the border between Ireland and Northern Ireland. It also set down some conditions of its own regarding the nature of the future relationship: Hopes that under these conditions the European Union and the United Kingdom will establish a future relationship that is fair, as close as possible and balanced in terms of rights and obligations; regrets the decision by the United Kingdom Government not to participate in the internal market, the European Economic Area or the customs union; considers that a state withdrawing from the Union cannot enjoy similar benefits to those enjoyed by a Union Member State, and therefore announces that it will not consent to any agreement that would contradict this; 127

132 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Believes that the future relationship between the European Union and the United Kingdom should be balanced and comprehensive and should serve the interests of the citizens of both parties, and will therefore need sufficient time to be negotiated; stresses that it should cover areas of common interest while respecting the integrity of the European Union s legal order and the fundamental principles and values of the Union, including the integrity of the internal market as well as the decision-making capacity and autonomy of the Union; notes that Article 8 of the Treaty on European Union, as well as Article 217 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, which provides for establishing an association involving reciprocal rights and obligations, common action and special procedures, could provide an appropriate framework for such a future relationship; Stresses that any future agreement between the European Union and the United Kingdom is conditional on the United Kingdom s continued adherence to the standards provided by international obligations, including human rights, and the Union s legislation and policies, in, among others, the fields of the environment, climate change, the fight against tax evasion and avoidance, fair competition, trade and social rights, especially safeguards against social dumping; Opposes any future agreement between the European Union and the United Kingdom that would contain piecemeal or sectorial provisions, including with respect to financial services, providing United Kingdom-based undertakings with preferential access to the internal market and/or the customs union; underlines that after its withdrawal the United Kingdom will fall under the third-country regime provided for in Union legislation. There are four messages which can be taken from these paragraphs including three which might be interpreted as the Parliament s red lines: Points to an association agreement (under Article 217 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, TFEU) as an appropriate framework for the future relationship. Underlines that a state withdrawing from the Union cannot enjoy similar benefits to those enjoyed by a Union Member State.4F76 Wants any future trade agreement to bind the UK to respecting international norms and standards in a range of non-trade policy areas such as environment, climate change, the fight against tax evasion and avoidance, fair competition, and trade and social rights. Opposes piecemeal or sectoral provisions that would give UK businesses preferential access to the single market or customs union. The European Council (Art. 50) issued its guidelines for the negotiations on 29 April 2017 emphasising the need for a phased approach giving priority to an orderly withdrawal.5f77 The guidelines were intended to define the framework for negotiations under Article 50 TEU and set out the overall positions and principles that the Union will pursue throughout the negotiation. It recognised that the guidelines would need to be updated over 76 Note that this phrase goes back to the Interlaken Principles which were announced on May 20, 1987 by Willy de Clercq, then EC Commissioner for External Relations, at a ministerial meeting between the then European Communities (EC) and the European Free Trade Association. They set the principles which the EC would follow in its trade and economic relations with third countries. The Interlaken Principles make clear that the EU will a) prioritise internal integration over relations with non-member states and b) the EU will always safeguard its own decision-making autonomy. The Principles declare that any relationship with the EU must be based on a balance of benefits and obligations. Non-member states will not be able to choose what aspects of EU integration they particularly favour. See Phinnemore, D., Why the UK can t just pick and choose from the EU menu after Brexit, The Conversation, 14 September European Council (Article 50) guidelines on Brexit negotiations, 29 April

133 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues time. The first phase of negotiations would settle the disentanglement of the UK from the EU and from all the rights and obligations the UK derives from commitments undertaken as a Member State. The withdrawal agreement would address, in particular, the UK s long-term financial commitments to the EU as well as reciprocal rights for British and EU citizens. It reiterated its wish to have the UK as a close partner in the future, and noted that Article 50 TEU requires taking account of the framework for its future relationship with the Union in the arrangements for withdrawal. It therefore proposed a second phase of negotiations which would identify an overall understanding of the framework for this future relationship. We stand ready to engage in preliminary and preparatory discussions to this end in the context of negotiations under Article 50 TEU, as soon as the European Council decides that sufficient progress has been made in the first phase towards reaching a satisfactory agreement on the arrangements for an orderly withdrawal. The European Council (Art. 50) guidelines also set down some markers for this future relationship which closely resemble those identified by the European Parliament in its resolution of 5 April In summary: Preserving the integrity of the Single Market excludes participation based on a sectorby-sector approach. A non-member of the Union, that does not live up to the same obligations as a member, cannot have the same rights and enjoy the same benefits as a member. [A future trade agreement] must ensure a level playing field, notably in terms of competition and state aid, and in this regard encompass safeguards against unfair competitive advantages through, inter alia, tax, social, environmental and regulatory measures and practices. In view of the unique circumstances on the island of Ireland, flexible and imaginative solutions will be required, including with the aim of avoiding a hard border, while respecting the integrity of the Union legal order. On 22 May 2017 the Council adopted a set of negotiating directives (Council of the European Union 2017). These cover only the first phase of the negotiations and subsequent sets of negotiating directives are envisaged to address other issues in the negotiations. On 20 October 2017, the European Council (Art.50) met to discuss the progress of the negotiations. It had been anticipated that, if sufficient progress had been achieved in the negotiations to that date, that European Council meeting might agree to move to the second phase, keeping in mind the principle that nothing is agreed until everything is agreed. The European Council noted that progress had been made on some of the issues in the first phase of the negotiations but concluded that, at this time, insufficient progress had been made in the first phase of the negotiations to move on to the second.6f78 Building on the progress made, it called for: work to continue with a view to consolidating the convergence achieved and pursuing negotiations in order to be able to move to the second phase of the negotiations as soon as possible. At its next session in December, the European Council will reassess the state of progress in the negotiations with a view to determining whether sufficient progress has been achieved on each of the three above issues. If so, it will adopt additional guidelines in relation to the framework for the future relationship and on possible transitional arrangements which are in the interest of the Union and comply with the conditions and 78 European Council (Art. 50) conclusions, 20 October

134 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies core principles of the guidelines of 29 April Against this background, the European Council invites the Council (Art. 50) together with the Union negotiator to start internal preparatory discussions. In reporting on the European Council outcome, President Donald Tusk noted that: 7F79 Today the Council has agreed to start internal preparatory discussions in relation to the framework for the future relationship and on transitional arrangements. It is clear that this would not be possible without the new momentum given by the Florence speech of Prime Minister May. I would like to reassure our British friends that in our internal work we will take account of proposals presented there. So the negotiations go on, and we will continue to approach them positively and constructively. And as we are all working actively on a deal, I hope we will be able to move to the second phase of our talks in December. Table 12: Timeline of events around the UK withdrawal from the EU DATE EVENT 23 June 2016 The UK votes to leave the EU 29 March 2017 UK invokes Article 50 5 April 2017 European Parliament adopts resolution on the UK s withdrawal from the EU 29 April 2017 European Council adopts its guidelines for the Brexit negotiations 22 May 2017 EU General Affairs Council authorises opening of negotiations with the UK 8 June 2017 UK General Election 19 June 2017 Negotiations between the UK and the EU begin 20 Oct 2017 European Council (Article 50) Summit Dec 2017 European Council Summit Mar 2018 European Council Summit June 2018 European Council Summit Oct 2018 Dec 2018 European Council Summit European Council Summit 29 Mar 2019 Deadline for UK withdrawal unless an alternative date is agreed May 2019 October 2019 European Parliament elections New Commission takes up office 79 Remarks by President Donald Tusk on the European Council meetings and the Leaders' Agenda, 20 October

135 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues 2. The issues at stake for agri-food trade KEY FINDINGS In the absence of a trade agreement tariffs would be re-imposed on bilateral UK-EU27 trade. The tariffs applicable to UK exports would be those in the EU s Common External Tariff (CET). The tariffs applicable to EU exports to the UK are not yet known, but at least initially may be kept at the CET level. Even apart from the imposition of tariffs, the UK would be a less attractive market for EU agri-food exporters, because intra-eu trade gives exporters higher prices than sales to the rest of the world, described as a preferential trade transfer. Customs clearance costs would be an additional cost for firms exporting to or importing from the UK. These costs are increased for certain agricultural and food products because of the need for additional border checks to ensure compliance with EU food safety, plant and animal health regulations. In the absence of an agreement covering road transport services, hauliers travelling between the UK and EU27 could face additional costs if there is a need to secure licences with individual Member States. Ireland faces particular issues in the event of a hard Brexit because of the importance of the UK land bridge for the transport of agri-food products to and from the EU27, and because transport from one location in Ireland to another may in some instances need to travel through Northern Ireland. A range of potential trade arrangements are available which address one or more of these potential trade costs. However, the current ability to trade frictionlessly between the UK and the EU27 is due to the UK s EU membership and can only be maintained if the UK were to remain a member of the EU. There are a number of models for the future long-term trade relationship between the UK and the EU27. These include the Canada, Turkey, Ukraine, Swiss and Norway models. The UK government has ruled out the Canada, Turkey and Norway models, but it has not defined where it might like to end up between the Ukraine and Swiss models. The EU27, for its part, is unlikely to make the Swiss model available because of its unsatisfactory institutional nature, though its attitude to the Ukraine model as a template for a future UK partnership has not been clarified. The Ukraine model is implemented through an Association Agreement with the EU which is an arrangement that has been specifically endorsed by the European Parliament. This chapter defines the meaning of a hard Brexit by examining the way agri-food trade takes place with countries that the EU does not have a trade agreement with but operates under WTO rules. It identifies the additional costs which food traders in the UK and EU27 would face compared to the way trade takes place today. These include tariffs, customs clearance costs, the loss of preferential trade transfers, costs to show compliance with regulatory standards, and higher costs for transport services. It then discusses how different ideal types of trade arrangement might address these costs. The discussion covers customs agreements, free trade areas, customs unions, regulatory cooperation and regulatory unions. The EU has a wide variety of trade agreements with non-member countries which differ in scope and ambition. The extent to which these actual trade agreements deliver the promised reductions in trade costs is evaluated. 131

136 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 2.1. Trade terms in the no deal scenario Tariffs The most obvious consequence of a hard Brexit would be the re-introduction of tariffs on agrifood trade between the UK and the EU27. The EU s tariffs including on agri-food products would be those set out in the Common External Tariff (CET) which can be accessed via TARIC. 8F80 The UK s tariffs which would apply in the event of a hard Brexit are not yet known. The tariffs the UK could impose ( applied tariffs ) would be limited under WTO rules in two ways: (a) they cannot exceed the maximum tariff levels (called bound tariffs ) contained in the UK s Schedule of Concessions in Goods which has yet to be notified to the WTO, and (b) they cannot discriminate between different import sources (for this reason, these applied tariffs are often referred to as Most Favoured Nation (MFN) tariffs). This means that the UK would have to apply the same tariffs on products imported from the EU27 as from other countries, with the important exception of countries with which it has signed a WTO-compatible preferential trade agreement, preferences granted to developing countries under the WTO Enabling Clause or where a specific waiver has been granted. The UK is a member of the WTO in its own right but its Schedule is currently that notified by the EU. The UK has indicated that it will seek the replicate the bound tariffs in the EU s Schedule of Concessions in Goods when it extracts its own Schedule after Brexit. 9F81 Under a hard Brexit scenario, it would be at liberty to decide what level of applied tariffs it would wish to apply to EU27 imports, provided these met the two WTO restrictions in the previous paragraph. As mentioned, in the EU27 s case, the tariffs that would apply to the UK once it ceased to be an EU member are those set out in the EU s TARIC. The UK has not yet clarified what approach it intends to take to its applied tariffs after Brexit. In its White Paper on future UK trade policy, it stated that The Government intends to introduce legislation that would allow the UK to operate standalone customs and indirect tax regimes as we withdraw from the EU. This will include the power to set customs duties, tariff rate quotas and preferences, as well as wider tariff-related provisions (HM Department of International Trade 2017). However, no indication is given in the White Paper whether the UK intends to change its current tariffs. In the White Paper on the future Customs Bill, the UK government notes that under the new UK standalone customs regime The level of this duty would be decided by the government, and set out in secondary legislation before the UK leaves the EU (HM Treasury 2017). Again, there is neither a commitment to maintaining current tariffs nor any specific proposal to alter them. There have been suggestions that applied tariffs might be reduced on products not produced in the UK (e.g. citrus fruit) or where imported products are an important raw material for a domestic processing industry (e.g. sugar). The UK might also be tempted to simplify some of the highly complex elements of the current EU applied tariff schedule, such as the Meursing formula which sets tariffs for processed foods and the entry price system for certain fruits and vegetables. Other voices outside government have argued in favour of a more wholesale reduction in applied tariffs as part of the move towards a Global Britain strategy. A reduction in applied tariffs might also be seen as a way to mitigate some of the effects of higher food prices on UK consumers due to the additional trade costs and any further depreciation of sterling in the run-up to Brexit Day (alternatively, it would be open to the UK to unilaterally introduce erga omnes tariff rate quotas based on current import quantities to achieve the same objective). In the Trade Policy White Paper, the UK government invited the views of businesses and other stakeholders on, inter alia, an inclusive and transparent trade policy to be 80 TARIC is the integrated Tariff of the European Union, which is a multilingual database in which are integrated all measures relating to EU customs tariff, commercial and agricultural legislation. 81 UK Department for International Trade, Preparing for our Future UK Trade Policy, HMSO, 2017, p

137 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues submitted by early November At this point in time, there remains uncertainty about the level of applied tariffs that would face EU27 exporters in the event of a hard Brexit scenario, but it may be reasonable to assume that, at least initially, the UK will apply the same MFN tariffs as it does today under the EU s CET. Table 13: EU's applied MFN tariff summary, 2016 Number of lines Simple average (%) Tariff range (%) Standard deviation Share of duty-free lines (%) Share of non-ad valorem tariffs (%) Total 9, a HS , a By WTO category WTO agricultural products 2, a Animals and products thereof Dairy products a Fruit, vegetables, and plants Coffee, tea, and cocoa and cocoa preparations Cereals and preparations Oilseeds, fats, oil and their products Sugars and confectionery Beverages, spirits and tobacco Cotton Other agricultural products, n.e.s Notes: a The tariff peak was calculated on a tariff line for which imports in 2015 were 0.1 tonnes. The next tariff peak in the dairy sector was 187.2%. Calculations for averages are based on the national tariff line level (8-digit), excluding in-quota rates. Tariff schedule is based on HS2012. Ad Valorem Equivalents (AVEs) for specific tariffs were estimated based on 2015 import data at the 8-digit tariff from the Eurostat database. If unavailable, the ad valorem part is used for compound and mixed rates. Source: WTO, 2017 The scale of tariffs that would apply if the UK were to adopt the current EU CET is shown in Table 2. The highest average tariffs would be faced by EU27 exports of dairy products, sugars and confectionery, and animal products. The highest peak tariffs are also found in these sectors but also in the category Other agricultural products n.e.s. In defining a hard Brexit, we assume that the UK will continue to apply the EU MFN tariff schedule after Brexit on trade with third countries with which it does not have a Free Trade Agreement (FTA). 133

138 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Loss of preferential trade transfers The loss of preferential trade transfers on EU27 agri-food exports to the UK is not, strictly, a trade cost but it is a consequence of a hard Brexit. Preferential trade transfers arise on agri-food exports to the UK because the UK currently applies the EU s Common External Tariff. This means that UK consumers pay a (somewhat) higher price for foodstuffs imported from the EU27 than they would have to pay if these products were imported from third countries at world market prices. The Customs Union effectively gives a preference to EU exporters in supplying the UK market which is why this trade transfer is called a preferential one. The difference between the price paid by UK consumers behind the EU tariff wall for EU27 exports and the price EU exporters would receive if the products were sold at world market prices is the measure of the preferential trade transfer accruing to EU27 exporters. This preferential trade transfer on exports to the UK market might be eroded in two ways in a hard Brexit. One way would be if the UK decided to lower or eliminate its MFN tariffs on foodstuffs. In the situation of full elimination, EU27 exporters would not face tariffs on exporting to the UK market, but the UK market would be a less attractive one because the price exporters would receive would be lower than they currently earn on these exports. Maintaining tariff-free trade between the UK and the EU27 after Brexit would not avoid the loss of this preferential trade transfer if the UK decided to lower the level of its tariff protection. It would also be possible for EU27 exporters to face both higher tariffs and the loss of the preferential trade transfer. This would occur if the UK applied MFN tariffs to EU27 exports but entered into free trade agreements with third country competitive agricultural exporters which effectively drove down domestic UK food prices to world market levels. This double whammy would be the consequence of the additional discrimination against EU27 exporters in a situation where the UK raised tariffs against EU27 exporters but lowered them against third country competitive agricultural exporters as a result of free trade agreements with these countries. The preferential trade transfer on intra-eu trade has fallen significantly in recent years as EU producer prices have converged on world market prices, in part due to successive CAP reforms, and in part due to the rise in world market prices over the past decade. The left-hand panel in Figure 2 shows that the average difference between EU producer and world market prices has steadily declined but remains positive in recent years. The right-hand panel shows that the remaining gap is largely the result of continued EU protection for a handful of commodities, in particular beef, sugar, poultrymeat and some vegetables. These are the products where EU27 exports to the UK market continue to earn a preferential trade transfer. A corollary of the fall in the preferential trade transfer earned on exports to the UK in recent years is that the potential fall in UK food prices if it were to lower or eliminate its applied tariffs on imported foodstuffs is now much smaller than might have been estimated based on figures from a decade ago. 134

139 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues Figure 17: Gap between EU and world market prices Source: Own calculations based on the OECD Producer Support Estimate (PSE) database. The left hand panel shows the trend in the producer Nominal Protection Coefficient, the right-hand panel uses the consumer Nominal Protection Coefficient. Note that DG AGRI s Key Performance Indicator 2 suggests that the fall in the ratio between EU and world agricultural commodity prices has been even steeper than shown in the OECD database, from almost 40% in 2005 to 6% in 2016 (DG AGRI 2017). There are several world market reference prices in the meat sector. In calculating the EU PSE, the OECD uses the average price of fresh and chilled imports from Australia. If Brazil s export price were used, the Nominal Protection Coefficient shown for beef would be higher Customs clearance Since the Single Market was established on 1 January 1993, goods leaving the UK for elsewhere in the EU, and vice versa, have not been subject to customs checks at frontiers. In the event of a hard Brexit, there will be a requirement for customs clearance. Customs clearance gives rise to two sources of additional costs: the costs of clearance as such, and the time costs of delay while goods are being cleared. While it is possible to minimise these costs (a process called trade facilitation ), it is not possible to avoid them. We consider each of these costs in turn in the context of UK-EU27 agri-food trade in the event of a hard Brexit. Customs processes have a number of different objectives (Table 3). Tariffs. Ensure that any customs duties are paid when goods arrive from third countries and the goods are released either at the border or subsequently (suspended duty), including the administration of tariff preferences, tariff quotas, tariff suspensions, and anti-dumping duties at importation. Tax. Collect import VAT and any excises when goods are released. Documentation. Ensure businesses correctly declare goods for import or export and provide the required documentation, including customs declarations, safety and security information and any licenses required or supporting documentation (such as that required to demonstrate the origin of goods, as may be required under a future free trade agreement between the UK and the EU27); Standards. Ensure that the goods entering comply with relevant safety and environmental standards, with special attention paid to products such as food products, chemicals and electrical equipment. Supply chain security. Security aspects were first introduced in customs legislation in the aftermath of the terrorist attacks in September 2001 in the United States. In 2005 the World Customs Organisation adopted the SAFE Framework of Standards that introduced security measures for supply chains, including the requirement for advanced cargo data notification, security risk assessment and an industry partnership (Authorised Economic Operator) programme. 135

140 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Table 14: Examples of customs and other controls in international trade CONTROLS Revenue collection Safety and security Environment and health Consumer protection Trade policy Source: Grainger, 2015 EXAMPLES OF RELATED ACTIVITY Collection of customs duties, excise duties and other indirect taxes; payment of duties and fees; management of bonds and other financial securities Security and anti-smuggling controls; dangerous goods; vehicle checks; immigration and visa formalities; export licences Phytosanitary, veterinary and hygiene controls; health and safety measures; CITES controls; ships waste Product testing; labelling; conformity checks with marketing standards (e.g. fruits and vegetables) Administration and enforcement of quotas, surveillance measures and quantitative restrictions Under the EU Customs Union, customs policy is the exclusive competence of the EU. The EU Customs Union comprises the 28 EU Member States, with Turkey, San Marino and Andorra also having their own customs unions with the EU. All EU Member States are required to operate customs procedures in accordance with EU legislation (the key legislation being the Union Customs Code). In October 2013, the EU introduced a new Union Customs Code (UCC) (Regulation 952/2013) and Delegated and Implementing Regulations (as amended). This changed a number of the rules and procedures governing the way that customs duties are levied, calculated and collected by EU Member States. Part of these changes is to require that all communications between customs authorities and economic operators must be electronic by December These changes came into force in 2016, with some transition arrangements operating until the end of HOW CUSTOMS CONTROLS WORK IN THE EU Carriers must submit an Entry Summary Declaration via an electronic information system before the arrival of the goods in the EU which is a pre-arrival declaration for risk analysis. A similar declaration (Exit Summary Declaration) is required before the departure of goods out of the EU again to facilitate risk analysis. Traders must lodge a customs declaration form (known as the Single Administrative Document/SAD) for goods imported from and exported to countries outside the EU which requires 54 boxes of information from details of the consignor to the consignee, the product details and tariff details, values, country of origin information, weights and packaging information and terms of trade. Some trusted traders (AEOs) can make simplified declarations at the border and provide a supplementary declaration later. Traders pay any tax and duty which is due on imports. Payment is due on clearance at the border, unless the trader is part of the duty deferment scheme and pays a single sum each month (this facility is subject to provision of a bank guarantee). Importers and exporters can be subject to post clearance audit checks by Customs at any time within the following three or four years. Businesses have to keep customs paperwork for this period. Most goods are cleared for import/export instantly. However, a small sample must be subject to documentary checks by customs (of the order 2-3%) and a smaller sample undergo physical checks as required by the harmonised risk management rules under the UCC (the proportions for certain agri-food products are significantly higher as discussed in the text). 136

141 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues The level of import checks required at borders can be reduced as the result of preauthorisation of traders, advance lodgement of declarations and an extensive system of post-clearance checks, including customs audit, which are carried out at traders premises. Authorised Economic Operators (AEOs) have a special status in the system and under agreed protocols are allowed to operate greatly simplified customs procedures.10f82 While currently AEOs tend to be large firms (which tend to account for the bulk of international trade), the new EU UCC opens the possibility for smaller traders to receive this authorisation. This is scheduled to happen regardless of Brexit, but has obvious implications for how customs procedures might operate with the UK after Brexit Regulatory checks on food products Specific rules apply to the import of food and especially animal products. According to the General Food Law (Regulation 178/2002), food and feed imported into the EU must comply with food law or conditions recognised as equivalent or, where a specific agreement exists, with requirements contained therein (Article 11 - Imports). The regulations differentiate between food of non-animal origin, food of animal origin, and food containing both processed ingredients of animal origin and ingredients of plant origin (composite foods). Depending on the product and where appropriate, imports are required to meet food hygiene standards; other health requirements (e.g. maximum residue levels for pesticides, the use of food additives, flavourings and enzymes, contaminants); product specific requirements (e.g. concerning quick frozen foodstuffs, foodstuffs for particular nutritional purposes, genetically modified organisms or approved residue control plans); plant health requirements; and animal health requirements. Food of non-animal origin. The EU rules on food hygiene require that all food businesses in third countries after primary production wishing to export to the EU must put in place, implement and maintain a procedure based on HACCP principles. 1F83 The competent authorities in the Member States must ensure that foodstuffs imported into the EU are submitted to official controls for the purpose of ensuring that the relevant provisions of the food hygiene rules, including the requirement of putting in place, implementing and maintaining HACCP-based procedures, are observed. Most food of non-animal origin can enter the EU through any entry point and is not subject to specific import conditions, a pre-notification requirement nor certification by the competent authorities of the third country of dispatch. When importing food into the EU responsibility rests with the importer to ensure compliance with the relevant requirements of EU food law or with conditions recognised as equivalent by the EU. Nonetheless, some food of nonanimal origin may be submitted to controls in accordance with a control plan drawn up by the Commission in the light of potential risks. Such controls may be at the point of entry, the point of release for free circulation, the importer s premises, retail outlets etc. The Commission has established a list of food of non-animal origin that, on the basis of known or emerging risks, must be subjected to an increased level of official controls when entering the EU. 82 The EU Authorised Economic Operator (AEO) system permits qualifying companies to undergo streamlined customs procedures under the Union Customs Code. It applies to companies authorised for customs simplification (AEOC) or security or safety (AEOS) or a combination of the two. This is a version of the trusted trader scheme used in other countries and allows importers to fast track customs, reducing the burden of checks, security and taxation requirements for regular importers. SEE DG TAXUD Authorised Economic Operator for more detail. 83 HACCP stands for Hazard Analysis Critical Control Point and is a systematic approach to the identification, evaluation, and control of food safety hazards. 137

142 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Under the currently applicable legislation on trade in plants and plant products (Directive 2000/29/EC),12F84 a phytosanitary certificate from the competent authority in the exporting country is required for plants for planting, cut flowers, and some fruits, vegetables and seeds ( controlled plants ). For non-controlled plants, imports into the EU do not require prior approval or notification, although they are subject to rules on food safety and customs procedures and inspection. 13F85 Under the new Regulation (EU) 2016/2031 which will come into force in December 2019, all living plant material (namely entire plants, fruits, vegetables, cut flowers, seeds, etc.) will require a phytosanitary certificate confirming their compliance with the EU legislation if they are to be imported into the EU. The Commission will adopt within two years a list of plant materials that can be exempted from that certification if they are deemed safe for the EU territory. Once the UK becomes a third country, movement of controlled plants and plant products from the UK to the EU27 (and, under the UK European Union (Withdrawal) Bill, from the EU27 to the UK) will have to be accompanied by a phytosanitary certificate issued by the plant health authority of the country of origin rather than a plant passport. This will involve additional costs for those moving plants and plant materials between the UK and the EU27. Whereas a plant passport can be issued by a private grower or merchant sending material to another Member State (the only proviso is that the issuing business is licensed to do so by the competent authority in the Member State and is subject to regular quality control checks), a phytosanitary certificate has to be issued by the competent authority of the exporting state. Importers of controlled plants and plant products will have to register as an importer and will have to give advance notice of the arrival of consignments. When the consignment arrives at the EU27 (or UK) border, it will have to be inspected to check that it is accompanied by all the required documents, that it contains the plants claimed, and that it is free of pests and diseases. Consignments can only enter through Designated Points of Entry (DPEs). Products of animal origin. Products of animal origin must be presented at an EU approved Border Inspection Post for submission to an import control. Prior notification of the physical arrival of the products in the EU must be provided to the border inspection post of arrival using the Common Veterinary Entry Document (CVED). Consignments will only be accepted if the products are derived from approved third countries, regions thereof and establishments as appropriate and if veterinary checks had favourable results. Health certificates must accompany all animal products when introduced into the EU. These documents must be signed by an official veterinarian of the competent authority of the exporting third country guaranteeing that the conditions for import into the EU have been met. Further random checks may be carried out on the imported product at the final destination. The Official Controls Regulation (Regulation (EC) No 882/2004) provides national authorities and the Commission with the necessary powers to ensure effective enforcement of regulatory requirements, including audit and control powers in the Member States and third countries. It lays down specific rules for official controls on imported products. All products of animal origin are subjected to a documentary check. Most consignments are also subject to an identity check which involves verification that the product, health marks, stamps and other necessary product and or package information conform to the declaration on the health certificates and EU legislation. A percentage of consignments must also be physically checked to see that it is fit for its intended purpose. The physical check may include sampling the product 84 A new plant health Regulation (EU) 2016/2031 on protective measures against pests of plants was adopted on 13 December 2016 but its provisions will not come into force until 13 December 2019 in order to allow sufficient time for the necessary delegated and implementing acts to be adopted and to give time to businesses to prepare for the new rules. For a summary of the changes brought in by the new Regulation, see European Commission Fact Sheet, New Plant Health Regulation: stringent rules for a better protection from plant pests, 13 Dec Details of the EU regulations governing imports of plants & plant products from non-eu countries can be found on the DG SANTE web page Trade in plants & plant products from non-eu countries. 138

143 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues to look for pathogenic micro-organisms or illegal contaminants such as veterinary drugs residues or heavy metals. Commission Decision 94/360/EC prescribes the level of physical checks for certain products. In general, the minimum number of consignments to be subjected to a physical check are 20% for meat, meat products, fish, fishery products, 50% for poultry meat, honey, dairy products and shellfish, and at between 1% and 10% for most products of animal origin that are not intended for human consumption. For certain products where there is a known health risk the Commission may prescribe a higher level of checking which may include compulsory sampling. The EU has negotiated equivalence agreements with New Zealand and Canada and imports from these countries are subject to lower physical checks and in the case of New Zealand the charges levied for imports are at a reduced level. A new Official Controls Regulation (Regulation (EU) 2017/625) which replaces the 2004 legislation entered into force on 27 April The new rules will gradually become applicable with the main application date being 14 December F86 The regulation establishes an integrated approach to import controls by eliminating the current fragmentation of requirements. Common rules will apply to controls carried out at borders on animals, products of animal origin, plants and other products and goods that must be checked before they enter the EU. The import control system will be more risk-based and targeted. Border Control Posts (BCPs) will replace the different Border Inspection Posts (BIPs) and Designated Points of Entry (DPEs) which currently carry out border control tasks. All consignments to be presented at the border control posts will undergo documentary checks. Identity and physical checks will be carried out at a frequency depending on the risk linked to the specific animals or goods. A single standard document, the Common Health Entry Document (CHED), will be used by operators for the prior notification of consignments. It will be transmitted to the border control post through a new integrated computerised system for official controls (Integrated Management System for Official Controls, IMSOC). In dealing with customs, a company can employ a clearance agent or freight forwarder to act as their representative (which is an additional cost), or they can request authorisation to lodge these declarations themselves. In either case, these are additional direct costs of customs clearance. Examples of charges in force are given in Annex 1 of this study Road transport services The importance of haulage services for the transport of goods across customs borders should not be underestimated. One of the main reasons for the often choking congestion that Turkish hauliers face on the Turkey-Bulgaria border is because Turkey does not have an agreement in transport services with the EU. There is a risk of further border delays in the absence of a UK-EU27 deal on the movement of trucks or lorries, vehicle registration, and the ability of drivers who are EU nationals to drive vehicles into the UK and vice versa if a customs border is established after 29 March Bilateral traffic-sharing agreements are the predominant mode of organisation of international road transport. These split the traffic between the two parties to the exclusion of all others and provide a quantitative framework by annually establishing quotas for the number of authorised journeys. One estimate suggests that there are around 1,400 bilateral agreements for the 43 states participating in the European Conference of Ministers for Transport (ECMT), that is some 20 agreements per EU Member State and 30 to 35 agreements for the other member countries (WTO 2010). Under the ECMT model agreement, which is considered broadly representative of existing road transport agreements in Europe, permits are required for many types of traffic (although with exceptions, such as transport of live animals). Quotas are agreed on the number of individual journeys or the number of permits issued (though with 86 The rules for official controls on imported food and feed products are described on this DG SANTE web page. 139

144 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies the important exception that quotas do not generally apply to traffic with perishable goods). Bilateral quotas are always fixed at the same level for both parties. Accordingly, it often happens that, when the two countries are not equally competitive, the quota allocated to the more competitive country is exhausted before the end of the year. In these circumstances, the country that has exhausted its quota tries to obtain an additional quota from its partner. If it is unable to do so or if the additional quota is exhausted in its turn, the goods can still be carried but with additional costs and journey times, either by the less competitive country or by carriers of a third country that has not yet exhausted its quota. International road haulage with HGVs within the EU is authorised by the EU-wide community licence system. Hauliers with a community licence established in any EU Member State are permitted to undertake any international road haulage in the EU - the international road haulage market in the EU is fully liberalised. However, road transport between EU and non-eu countries (third countries) is still largely based on bilateral agreements between individual Member States and third countries. The EU has only agreed open-access road transport deals with those neighbouring EU countries that have committed to observing the rules of the single market including free movement of persons (these are the EEA agreement with Norway, Iceland and Liechtenstein and the agreement on land transport between the EU and Switzerland). In a worst-case scenario, the UK could be required to negotiate lorry quotas with individual EU27 countries and presumably would retaliate with similar quota restrictions on the number of EU27 hauliers that could operate to the UK. 15F Specific issues facing Ireland The particular problems facing Ireland in the event of a hard Brexit have been highlighted in the European Council (Art.50) guidelines, the Council s negotiating directives, the European Parliament resolutions on Brexit, and in the UK government s position and future partnership papers. It is estimated that, in the space of one month 177,000 lorries, 205,000 vans and over 1.8 million cars cross the border between Ireland and Northern Ireland. Each day it is estimated that 30,000 people make the cross-border commute to work. 16F88 Crossborder flows of agricultural products are particularly important. The shared land border between Ireland and Northern Ireland has resulted in the development of a highly integrated agri-food sector, with large volumes of trade annually in live animals, finished products and products requiring further processing. Over 400,000 pigs are exported live from Ireland to Northern Ireland for processing annually, with almost 400,000 lambs imported from Northern Ireland for processing. Over 800m litres of milk are imported from Northern Ireland annually, much of which is processed and exported from Ireland. Overall, in 2015, exports of agricultural products from Ireland to Northern Ireland (including food, drink, forestry and animal byproducts) were 750m, with imports from Northern Ireland of 567m (IFA 2016). A future border between Ireland and Northern Ireland would be most similar to the border with Germany or France and Switzerland in terms of the intensity of traffic across this border. However, while movement of persons across these frontiers takes place without restrictions as all countries are parties to the Schengen Agreement (although where there is a suspicion of irregularities, controls are allowed in all Schengen countries and at the border as well), the movement of goods requires customs clearance and there are dozens of customs posts along the Swiss border with its EU neighbours.17f89 87 For this reason, the UK road haulage industry proposes that the UK and the EU27 would enter into a Land Transport Agreement for international road haulage that maintains the basic structure of the community licence system. See Road Haulage Association, Proposal for a UK-EU Land Transport Agreement, 4 May Gough, A. Plan, act and engage for a better Brexit, InterTrade Ireland. 89 For details see the Swiss Customs Administration web site. 140

145 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues Both the UK and the EU27 have made clear that they do not wish to see a return to a hard border on the island of Ireland. The European Council (Art. 50) guidelines state In view of the unique circumstances on the island of Ireland, flexible and imaginative solutions will be required, including with the aim of avoiding a hard border, while respecting the integrity of the Union legal order. This was repeated in the Council negotiating directives for the first phase of the withdrawal negotiations which stated that Negotiations should in particular aim to avoid the creation of a hard border on the island of Ireland, while respecting the integrity of the Union legal order. The UK has also stated its intention to avoid a hard border in Ireland, most recently in its White Paper on a future Customs Bill (HM Treasury, 2017), and specifically stating its aim to avoid any physical border infrastructure. Whether this objective is possible and how it might be achieved is discussed later in this chapter. Although the ambition to avoid a hard border on the island of Ireland has received most attention, in terms of the volume and value of trade involved a more important issue concerns the implications of Brexit for the Irish land bridge to continental EU markets. After Brexit Ireland will be the only EU country which must access other EU countries in the single market using road freight by passing through a non-eu country.18f90 At present, it is estimated that around two-thirds of Irish exports to the continent move via the UK. 19F91 This involves two ferry crossings (one over the Irish Sea and the other over the Channel between the UK and France, Belgium or the Netherlands) as well as using the UK as a land bridge. Once the UK leaves the EU, there is the possibility that Irish hauliers would be stopped four times for customs clearance on the way to service customers in the rest of the EU (and vice versa for EU hauliers transporting goods from the rest of the EU27 to Ireland). Movements could take place using sealed TIR trucks provided the UK joins the Common Transit Convention as it has indicated it wants to, but international TIR movements provide much less flexibility to hauliers than they currently enjoy under single market rules (see further discussion later in this chapter). The alternative of direct ferry movements between Ireland and France is much less attractive and would be much more costly. A truck takes 10.5 hours to travel between Dublin and Zeebrugge over the UK land bridge: the same journey via Cherbourg would take three times as long.20f92 This problem has been recognised in the Council s negotiating directives which noted that: The [withdrawal] Agreement should also address issues arising from Ireland s unique geographic situation, including transit of goods (to and from Ireland via the United Kingdom). Transit issues will also arise in moving goods from one part of Ireland to another when the shortest route may be through Northern Ireland Trade arrangements to avoid or mitigate trade costs If the UK leaves the EU without a trade agreement (a hard Brexit), traders would be required to absorb all the additional trade costs identified in Section 2.1: customs clearance costs, tariffs, and the costs of complying with and demonstrating that regulatory standards had been met. A trade agreement between the UK and the EU after Brexit would allow some, or even most, of these costs to be avoided. The catch is that avoiding these costs would come with the trade-off of less policy autonomy for the UK. One of the promises 90 There is significant goods traffic from Northern Europe to Italy which passes through Switzerland. Swiss borders are more manageable because of the bilateral agreements between Switzerland and the EU which mean that effectively, if not legally, it is part of the European Economic Area for goods. Greece has a land border with Bulgaria but the majority of its goods exports to the rest of the EU use RoRo services to Italy. This would not be feasible in the case of Ireland for reasons discussed later. 91 The Independent, Majority of exporters travel through Britain to ship goods overseas, 10 March The figure of 80% is quoted in Posaner, J. and Livingstone, E. Brexit burns Ireland s British bridge to EU markets, Politico (Europe edition), 20 July The Irish Department of Transport, Tourism and Sport has commissioned a study into the use of the UK land bridge by Irish importers and exporters. The research is intended to establish the volume of traffic using the UK land bridge at present, the likely consequences that Brexit will have on land bridge usage and the various options to minimise the likely consequences. See Minister s reply to a Dail question, 11 September Posaner and Livingstone, op. cit. 141

146 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies of those campaigning for the UK to leave the EU was to take back control. At the time of writing, the UK government seems undecided as to how much policy autonomy it is prepared to cede in order to achieve almost frictionless trade between the two parties. The choices it faces are discussed in this section and summarised in Figure 3. Trade facilitation refers to steps that the customs and health authorities can take to minimise the checks and the time required to clear goods through customs, while the other scenarios refer to trade agreements with different levels of ambition. Figure 18: Alternative post-brexit trade scenarios beyond WTO terms Barrier Customs agreement Free Trade Area (FTA) FTA+ Customs Union (CU) CU+ Single market (Regulatory Union) Trade facilitation Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Tariffs Not affected Removed Removed Removed Removed Removed Preferential rent Lost Lost Retained Retained Lost Rules of origin Yes Yes No No Yes Customs clearance Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Regulatory controls Yes Reduced Yes Reduced No Source: Own presentation. Note that the single market scenario is assumed not to include a customs union. It should be absolutely clear that the current ability to trade frictionlessly between the UK and the EU27 is due to the UK s membership of the EU and can only be maintained if the UK were to remain a member. As the UK customs future partnership paper admits, any alternatives will increase the burden for business whether by requiring companies to declare goods traded with the EU27 in the case of a streamlined system or by obliging them to track their final destination in a deeper customs partnership with the bloc. If the option of continued UK membership of the EU is off the table, it remains the case that a lot can be done to reduce the additional trade costs that businesses will face through a future long-term trade agreement. Many of the proposals put forward in the UK policy papers are sensible proposals, once it is accepted that they are second-best proposals compared to avoiding the consequences of having to deal with Brexit in the first place, and that they cannot fully replicate the frictionless trade within the single market and the Customs Union. The choice for the EU27 is how far it is ready to go to embrace these proposals, given the red lines set down by the European Council (Art. 50) and the European Parliament, particularly the refusal to extend participation in the single market on a sectorby-sector approach.21f93 If one objective of the UK in withdrawing from the EU is to gain the ability to lower or remove regulatory standards, the EU27 will want to ensure that any proposals to facilitate trade will not undermine EU27 standards. 93 If Canada had approached the EU during the negotiations on the EU-Canada Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA) and offered to align its food safety and animal health regulations precisely with those of the EU in order to facilitate an agreement on regulatory equivalence which would avoid the need for regulatory checks on trade between the two countries, it is interesting to speculate how the EU might have responded to that offer. The United States and Canada signed such an agreement recognising each other s food safety systems as comparable to each other in May 2016 even though there is not full alignment. 142

147 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues Customs agreement The UK has proposed a customs arrangement with the EU27 that facilitates the freest and most frictionless trade in goods possible, and which, crucially, avoids a hard border and any physical border infrastructure on the island of Ireland (HM Government 2017a). The UK published a future partnership paper on customs arrangements in June 2017 in which it put forward two possible models for future customs co-operation to minimise the costs and delays of clearing customs as discussed previously: the streamlined and the partnership models (HM Government 2017b). The highly streamlined customs arrangement between the UK and the EU27 would involve: streamlining and simplifying requirements, leaving as few additional requirements on EU trade as possible. This would aim to: continue some of the existing arrangements between the UK and the EU; put in place new negotiated and potentially unilateral facilitations to reduce and remove barriers to trade; and implement technology-based solutions to make it easier to comply with customs procedures. This approach involves utilising the UK s existing tried and trusted third country processes for UK-EU trade, building on EU and international precedents, and developing new innovative facilitations to deliver as frictionless a customs border as possible. Four examples of simplification are given in the UK customs paper to illustrate how the streamlining model might work. Simplifying requirements to move goods across frontiers, by negotiating a waiver from the requirement to submit Entry and Exit Summary Declarations and by joining the Common Transit Convention which simplifies border crossing for goods in transit. Reducing delays at ports and airports by negotiating mutual recognition of Authorised Economic Operators (AEOs) and implementing bilateral technology-based solutions for roll-on roll-off ports linked to customs declarations and vehicle registration numbers so that vehicles are not required to stop at the border. Addressing the safety and security agenda through replicating existing levels of customs cooperation and data-sharing. Reducing administrative burdens primarily when importing through unilateral measures of simplification and speeding up authorisations. Some of these proposals are already in place for EU trade with other third countries. With Switzerland and Norway the EU concluded bilateral agreements which entered into force on 1 July 2009 that waive the obligation of traders to provide customs with the Summary Declarations prior to import and export in bilateral trade which were introduced to improve safety and security procedures. The EU has also signed agreements on supply chain security with main partner countries that provide the legal basis for mutual recognition of AEOs. Most of those agreements, e.g. with US, China, Japan or Canada, go beyond mutual recognition; they focus on improving supply chain security, joint risk rules, creating joint standards regarding security controls etc. Looking at Norway in greater detail, Norway is not part of the EU s Customs Union and does not apply the EU s common customs rules and tariffs. Norway is, however, involved in the EU s customs cooperation through Protocol 10 of the EEA Agreement. Norway has signed a separate agreement with the EU in order to ensure that customs rules do not hamper trade flows between Norway and the EU. The agreement waives the obligation to provide information for security purposes prior to the import or export of goods to the EU and requires Norway to apply customs security measures that are equivalent to those applied by the EU in 143

148 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies its trade with third countries. This has involved mutual recognition of the Authorised Economic Operator (AEO) certification scheme and of systems of risk analysis and management. As a result of the agreement with the EU, Norway is invited to participate as an observer in several of the comitology committees under the EU s Customs Policy Group. The new customs partnership model with the EU would align the UK s approach to the customs border in a way that removes the need for a UK-EU27 customs border. One potential approach would involve the UK mirroring the EU s requirements for imports from the rest of the world where their final destination is the EU. This is of course unprecedented as an approach and could be challenging to implement and we will look to explore the principles of this with business and the EU. The customs partnership model would involve the UK operating an import regime that aligns precisely with the EU27 s external customs border, for goods that will be consumed in the EU27 market, even if they are part of a supply chain in the UK first. The UK would need to apply the same tariffs as the EU27, and provide the same treatment for rules of origin for those goods arriving in the UK and destined for the EU27. The customs paper admits the need for:..a robust enforcement mechanism that ensured goods which had not complied with the EU s trade policy stayed in the UK. This could involve, for instance, a tracking mechanism, where imports to the UK were tracked until they reached an end user, or a repayment mechanism, where imports to the UK paid whichever was the higher of the UK s or the EU s tariff rates and traders claimed a refund for the difference between the two rates when the goods were sold to an end user in the country charging lower tariffs. Businesses in supply chains would need to be able to track goods or pass the ability to claim a repayment along their supply chain in order to benefit. Much of the early comment on the customs partnership model focused on the higher administrative costs it would imply. Manufacturers and traders would be required to follow imported goods through to the final consumer. In the case of integrated supply chains, it would not only be UK firms that would be required to do this. Indeed, it is striking that the customs position paper only discusses the UK perspective. The biggest weakness of this proposal is that no one is sure how it might work. The paper itself notes: We acknowledge this is an innovative and untested approach that would take time to develop and implement. The Government is keen to explore this approach with businesses and other stakeholders to understand the practical complexities involved in making it work and assess which other approaches could have a similar effect, how they would work in practice and whether they could achieve the Government s objectives. As Mr Jon Thompson, Chief Executive and Permanent Secretary, HM Revenue and Customs, put it in oral evidence to the House of Commons Treasury Select Committee on 14 September 2017:2F94 Let us make this real. You bring something to Felixstowe where the contents need to be split between those that are going to remain in the United Kingdom and those that are going on onward transfer to the European Union. At that point you begin to have dual systems for everything, whereas at the moment you have a single system. Therefore, that requires not only us but everyone who is involved in that supply chain to run multiple systems at the same time, because there may be different tariff regimes. Essentially, the 94 House of Commons Treasury Committee, Oral evidence: Her Majesty's Revenue and Customs Annual Report and Accounts, HC

149 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues new customs partnership means we are running the EU tariff system at the UK border. That is why it is quite innovative and different, and it requires new technology. In summary, trade facilitation measures can do a lot to reduce the time required to cross borders and to make it as easy as possible for traders to manage the necessary paper work (Grainger 2017; Owen, Shepheard, and Stojanovic 2017). However, only in the context of the EU single market and Customs Union can they be fully removed Free trade agreement A free trade agreement (FTA) is the simplest possible improvement on WTO terms. An FTA would reduce or eliminate tariffs on trade in goods between the two parties. It would be notified to the WTO under GATT Article XXIV which permits discriminatory trade arrangements in the case of FTAs and customs unions which cover substantially all trade. Both parties would maintain their autonomy with respect to their trade policy vis a vis third countries, i.e. their applied MFN tariff schedule, the administration of tariff rate quota (TRQ) preferences for agricultural products, the use of trade defence measures such as anti-dumping and countervailing duties, and the ability to enter into separate FTAs with third countries. 23F95 Although FTAs remove one of the additional trade costs that trade on WTO terms would incur, this is at the cost of introducing a further additional cost, namely, the need to check that a traded product seeking to enter the importing country with a preferential duty has actually originated in the exporting country and is not simply a third country s export transhipped through the exporting country in order to benefit from the tariff preference. Rules of origin (ROOs) determine whether a particular import consignment should be treated as originating in the exporting country (and thus eligible for the preferential duty) or originates in some third country and is simply using the exporting country as a country of transit. This requires the product either to be wholly obtained from the territory of the exporting country or to have undergone sufficient working or processing to qualify as originating. The EU tariff schedule uses four different criteria to determine whether sufficient processing has taken place. These are: i) a change of tariff heading (e.g. chocolate spread will originate in the UK if it is made from imported materials of any other heading); ii) a minimum value added (e.g. for passenger cars, the value of all the non-originating materials used to manufacture the car may not exceed 40% of the total value of the product); iii) specific processing or working requirements or iv) a combination of the first three requirements (e.g. in the case of chocolate spreads, an additional requirement is that no more than 30% of the ex-works value of the product can be accounted for by the value of sugar). 24F96 Cumulation is the term used to describe a system that allows originating products of country A to be further processed or added to products originating in country B, just as if they had originated in country B. The resulting product would have the origin of country B. It can only be applied between countries operating with identical origin rules. A UK- EU27 FTA could allow bilateral cumulation, meaning that when a UK car producer imports intermediate parts from the EU to manufacture a car, those intermediate parts will be considered as originating in the UK when calculating the maximum threshold for nonoriginating materials (i.e. 40%, as explained above). The UK could join the Regional Convention on Pan-Euro-Mediterranean preferential rules of origin (PEM). As the Convention is based on a network of FTAs with identical origin protocols, joining it allows parties to apply a principle of diagonal cumulation when determining 95 However, parties to an FTA can agree to jointly negotiate FTAs with third countries, as in the case of the European Free Trade Association (EFTA). Today, EFTA has 27 FTAs covering 38 countries and territories outside the EU. 96 The EU rules on preferential origin arrangements are summarised on the DG TRADE website Common provisions. 145

150 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies the country of origin of goods. Diagonal cumulation would go further than bilateral cumulation in that originating materials from any party to the Convention would be deemed to originate in the UK for the purpose of calculating the origin of a product exported from the UK to the EU27 (or vice versa). Currently, the parties of the Convention include 42 countries: the EU, EFTA states, Faroe Islands, the Republic of Moldova, participants in the Barcelona Process (Algeria, Egypt, Israel, Jordan, Lebanon, Morocco, Palestine, Syria, Tunisia and Turkey), and participants in the EU's Stabilisation and Association Process (Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Montenegro, Serbia and Kosovo). Under EU rules, to claim preferential treatment under an FTA, importers must present a movement certificate known as EUR.1 or, in certain cases, an invoice declaration. A movement certificate EUR.1 will be issued by the customs authorities of the exporting country following requests by exporters, while an invoice declaration can be made by an approved exporter, or by any exporter with a shipment consisting of originating products whose value does not exceed a certain amount. The customs authorities can grant the status of approved exporter to any frequent exporter subject to conditions they consider appropriate; and withdraw it at any time. For goods with low preferential margins or which are parts of complex supply chains, the costs of showing compliance with rules of origin and requesting the tariff preference are often seen as too high to make it worthwhile. The EU is anyway trying to reduce the costs of complying with ROOs by moving away from the use of paper certificates to certify origin to a system of self-certification by exporters. It is phasing in the REX (Registered Exporter) system from 1 January 2017, initially for exporters in developing countries benefiting from the Generalised System of Preferences and later for other FTAs. Exporters in beneficiary countries will be invited to become registered for REX with the national authority of the country in which they are established. Once registered they will be entitled to issue Statements on Origin on their commercial documents such as invoice declarations without any limit on the value of the goods covered. Presumably, REX would be the basis for any system of self-certification for UK exporters following an eventual UK-EU27 FTA (the Canadian CETA is the first FTA to which the REX procedures will apply). There are other drawbacks of FTAs. FTAs only cover goods but not services, and even for goods not all goods may benefit from a preferential duty, and not all preferential duties may be zero. In the case of sensitive products, such as agricultural products, preferential access may be limited to specific volumes of imports under a TRQ (meaning that exports above this volume are required to pay the full MFN applied duty) and may be subject to safeguard clauses permitting the withdrawal of the concession if there is a surge in import volumes. For EU27 agricultural producers, a particular concern with an FTA which gave tarifffree access under all agricultural tariff lines would be the potential for trade displacement. This could occur if the UK were to open up its market to third country produce (e.g. lamb) either by lowering its MFN applied tariffs or by entering into FTAs with third country competitive agricultural exporters. While this third country produce would not receive the benefit of the preferential duty because it does not originate in the UK, the UK could increase its imports from third countries to meet its domestic demand while diverting more of its own production to the higher-priced EU27 market, hence the notion of trade displacement. 25F97 If the UK did not enter a customs union with the EU27 which would avoid this problem, this could lead to pressure from producer groups within the EU27 to limit imports from the UK to the 97 Trade displacement would be perfectly legitimate and can be distinguished from trade deflection, which would be the attempt by third country exporters to use the UK as a back door into the higher-priced EU market. 146

151 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues volumes currently imported using TRQs. If this happened, the UK would be likely to insist on limiting EU exports to its market in return. FTAs also require the maintenance of customs posts at borders even if there is 100% coverage of tariff lines. This is not only because of the need to check rules of origin, but also because of the many other checks that need to be performed at the border, including the payment of appropriate taxes and excises, security and safety checks and compliance with regulatory standards. A customs agreement can help to minimise some of these costs and the time required to cross borders, as discussed above, but they cannot be completely avoided even in an FTA scenario. Avoiding regulatory checks requires a deeper level of integration and is discussed in the next section FTA+ arrangement with regulatory cooperation An FTA could be combined with various forms of regulatory co-operation. Regulatory co-operation is a way of minimising or eliminating regulatory checks at borders. There are different levels of co-operation depending on the degree of integration the trading partners wish to achieve. Regulatory co-operation is usually implemented through Mutual Recognition Agreements (MRAs).26F98 Harmonisation of regulations means that both parties agree to use the same regulatory standards. This is the approach used in the EU s Association Agreements with the three eastern neighbours Ukraine, Georgia and Moldova with respect to technical standards for industrial products. Agreements on Conformity Assessment and Acceptance of Industrial Products (ACAAs) are a specific type of MRA based on the full alignment of the legislative system, including standards, and implementing infrastructure of the country concerned with those of the EU. Recognition of the equivalence of regulations is based on the fact that regulatory goals, e.g., in relation to health and food quality, in practice may be fulfilled by the use of different kinds of measures. This allows trade barriers to be removed and imported products can be accepted on the basis that they fulfil the relevant regulatory objectives even though regulatory differences persist. Equivalence assessment is an obligation since 1995 under the WTO Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Standards (SPS) (Article 4) which requires that Members shall accept measures of other Members as equivalent, even if these measures differ from their own if the exporting Member objectively demonstrates to the importing Member that its measures achieve the importing Member's appropriate level of sanitary or phytosanitary protection. Members shall, upon request, enter into consultations with the aim of achieving agreements on recognition of the equivalence. The EU has negotiated only a small number of MRAs which recognise other countries standards as equivalent. Food trade across the US-Canadian border is facilitated because the U.S. Food and Drug Administration signed an MRA with the Canadian Food Inspection Agency and the Department of Health Canada recognizing each other s food safety systems as comparable to each other. 27F99 Mutual recognition can simply mean that two or more parties mutually accept each other s conformity assessment procedures, i.e., the process by which products are evaluated for compliance with the rules. Traditional MRAs enable the competent authority nominated by one party to certify products for access to the other party s market, according to the other party s standards and legislation. No regulatory 98 Mutual recognition agreements that facilitate access to markets between the EU and non-eu countries should not be confused with the principle of mutual recognition in the EU single market which ensures market access for products that are not subject to EU harmonisation. 99 U.S. Food and Drug Administration, FDA Recognizes Canada as Having a Comparable Food Safety System to the U.S., May

152 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies convergence is implied by a traditional MRA. In other words, there is no implication that the regulations imposed on products by the parties are to be brought into alignment at any stage. The EU has many MRAs in the SPS area under which it agrees to recognise the validity of certificates issued by the competent authority in the exporting country stating compliance with EU standards, in return for the exporting country agreeing to regular auditing of its practices and procedures. The most limited form of regulatory co-operation would be to agree to exchange information on regulatory standards and to provide the opportunity for stakeholders and regulatory authorities in one country to comment on proposed new or revised standards in the other country. Provisions for information exchange and joint activities between regulatory authorities are increasingly included in FTAs. The UK has proposed that the UK and the EU27 should aim at regulatory equivalence on agri-food measures after Brexit (HM Government 2017c). Although this proposal was put forward in the context of avoiding a hard border on the island of Ireland, it would apply to all UK-EU27 trade after Brexit. One option for achieving our objectives could be regulatory equivalence on agri-food measures, where the UK and the EU agree to achieve the same outcome and high standards, with scope for flexibility in relation to the method for achieving this. An agreement on regulatory equivalence for agri-food, including regulatory cooperation and dispute resolution mechanisms, would allow the UK and the EU to manage the process of ensuring ongoing equivalence in regulatory outcomes following the UK s withdrawal from the EU. Providing the UK and the EU could reach a sufficiently deep agreement, this approach could ensure that there would be no requirement for any SPS or related checks for agri-food products at the border between Northern Ireland and Ireland. Regulatory co-operation including the recognition of regulatory equivalence is a useful and effective way of minimising trade barriers due to differences in regulatory standards. The EU has signed MRAs for organic farming standards with a number of countries, as well as MRAs covering SPS measures.28f100 These agreements often require lengthy negotiations, and demonstrating the equivalence of different standards can be difficult. Achieving the degree of regulatory equivalence sought by the UK while still allowing the UK regulatory autonomy in the SPS area would be a difficult balancing act Customs union A customs union represents a higher level of economic integration because, in this arrangement, the parties agree to maintain a common external trade policy vis á vis third countries. Thus, both parties agree to apply the same tariffs, to share the same agricultural TRQs, and to jointly conclude FTAs with third countries. This option further reduces the costs of customs clearance because checks on the origin of goods are no longer necessary imported goods entering either of the parties will have paid the same tariff so there is no danger of transhipment to avoid the payment of a higher duty in one of the partners. However, border checks would still need to be undertaken for regulatory compliance because there is no presumption in a pure customs union model that the participating countries have the same regulatory standards. VAT payments and excise duties would also need to be paid on crossing the frontier. If there were any exceptions of any kind, customs checks would also be required for those goods. Another advantage of a customs union for EU agri-food exporters is that it would retain the residual preferential trade transfers on exports to the UK, to the extent that 100 In addition to SPS provisions in FTAs, DG SANTE has this list of stand-alone Sanitary and Phytosanitary Agreements. 148

153 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues prices paid by consumers within the customs union are higher than world market prices because of the Common External Tariff. This advantage of a customs union to EU exporters would, of course, be seen as a disadvantage by the UK because it would represent a deadweight cost for the UK economy. It would also keep food prices higher in the UK than they might otherwise be if the UK were able to import at world market prices. We have previously noted that the size of this preferential trade transfer is now much smaller than it was in the past. Under the current rules for EU own resources, tariff revenue on imported goods is considered an EU own resource and is paid directly to the EU budget (less an amount equivalent to 25% of the revenue collected which can be retained by the importing country to offset administrative costs). Under a stand-alone customs union between the UK and the EU27, it would be open to each party to decide that tariff revenue collected should remain with the importing country (as is the case with the EU-Turkey customs union) or be divided up in some other proportion. Allowing the UK to keep the tariff revenue collected on imports from outside the EU27 would eliminate the transfer that the UK currently makes when this revenue is transferred to the EU budget. However, the UK would still make a transfer through the preferential trade transfers on imports from the EU27 itself Customs union with regulatory cooperation As with a free trade agreement, it is possible to envisage a customs union combined with elements of regulatory cooperation. From an agri-food perspective, this would again require harmonisation or close equivalence between the food, sanitary and phytosanitary standards in the UK and the EU27. The same concerns as previously discussed would arise: on the UK side, the possible loss of regulatory autonomy; on the EU27 side, the possible dangers of cherry-picking if the UK were to opt for regulatory coherence in some sectors but not in others A regulatory union A regulatory union is one in which both parties agree to align their regulations on a set of common standards. As the EU single market demonstrates, this does not require agreement on a set of harmonised standards. In the single market, there is agreement on a set of high minimum standards and after that the principle of mutual recognition applies. Any product lawfully marketed in one Member State can be sold in another Member State. Member States can introduce higher standards for their own producers, but they cannot exclude the products of other Member States which do not meet those standards provided they are lawfully marketed in the other Member State. Crucial to the operation of a regulatory union is a high level of protection in the basic standards that are common to all, a high degree of trust and confidence in the competence of the other partners to ensure compliance with the rules, as well as a dispute settlement mechanism which ensures consistent policing of those rules. A customs union with full and consistent adoption of the EU regulatory acquis (a regulatory union) would replicate the status quo with respect to trading conditions. However, because the UK would no longer be an EU Member State, it would have lost its ability to influence the shape of EU regulations through its voice in the Council or Ministers and through its MEPs in the European Parliament. Although this option would be very attractive to EU exporters, for obvious reasons, it has no attractions for the UK as it would imply no extension of its regulatory or trade policy autonomy despite the fact that it had exited the EU Northern Ireland Both the UK and the EU27 recognise that avoiding a hard border on the island of Ireland will require flexible and imaginative solutions. The UK government has set out some ideas to avoid a hard border in its Northern Ireland-Ireland position paper ((HM Government 2017c). 149

154 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies This outlines nine principles on which to base a future customs arrangement at the Northern Ireland-Ireland land border. These include aiming to avoid any physical border infrastructure on either side of the border between Northern Ireland and Ireland, but also preventing new barriers to doing business within the UK, including between Northern Ireland and Great Britain. The UK Government insists that the answer to avoiding a hard border between Northern Ireland and Ireland cannot be to impose a new customs border between Northern Ireland and Great Britain. Instead, it points to a number of examples where the EU has set aside its normal regulations and codes set out in EU law in order to recognise the circumstances of certain border areas. Its view is that devising a way forward on the Irish side of the land border will require similar derogations that go beyond current EU frameworks to maintain the absence of a hard border after Brexit. In addition to the trade facilitation measures it proposed under its highly streamlined customs arrangement in its customs position paper, the UK believes it would be necessary to go still further to agree specific facilitations for the Northern Ireland-Ireland land border. The UK has proposed a cross-border trade exemption that acknowledges that many of the movements of goods across the land border are by smaller traders operating in a local economy. They cannot be properly categorised or treated as economically significant international trade. The cross-border trade exemption would ensure that smaller traders could continue to move goods with no new requirements in relation to customs processes at the land border. It estimates that, in 2015, over 80% of north to south trade was carried out by micro, small and medium-sized businesses. For businesses not eligible for an exemption, the UK proposes that administrative processes could be very significantly streamlined, including for trusted traders on either side of the border, which could allow for simplified customs procedures. There has been no formal response as yet to this suggestion from the EU27 side. Guy Verhofstadt, the European Parliament s Brexit coordinator and chair of its Brexit Steering Group, in an address to the Irish Oireachtas noted that most of the people he met along the Irish border believed that the unique solution involved the UK staying in both the single market and the customs union. Acknowledging that the UK has ruled out that option, he observed that the resolution of this border issue is entirely the responsibility of the United Kingdom. It is for them to come up with a workable solution.. [that] doesn't compromise the Irish membership and the integrity of the single market and the customs union. 29F Facilitating the UK land bridge The UK proposes to address the transit of goods to and from Ireland to the rest of the EU via the UK land bridge by joining the Common Transit Convention. This would allow Irish exporters to use the land bridge across the UK to access continental EU markets without having to enter the UK for customs purposes. It could also facilitate the movement of goods from one part of Ireland to another when the quickest route goes through Northern Ireland. In turn, it would allow exports from Northern Ireland to cross through Ireland for onward delivery to markets outside the EU without having first to enter the EU for customs purposes. The Transit Convention also permits the use of the SAD as a transit document to cover movement of goods between the EU and the other signatories and between these signatories themselves. But using the Common Transit Convention is far from frictionless trade. Making use of the transit system incurs administrative and financial costs as well as restrictions on movements.30f102 Transit movements must be declared, accepted and registered before the movement takes place. This includes a deadline for delivering the goods at destination as well as prescribing the route that will be followed by the haulier. The requirement to use sealed 101 Verhofstadt, G., Speech to Members of the Houses of Oireacthas. Dublin, 21 September DG TAXUD has a 674-page document which describes transit procedures in greater detail. 150

155 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues trucks would rule out the possibility of groupage which means logistics firms can off-load pallets or part-loads on their way through the UK which may help to increase capacity utilisation of lorries and thus keep freight rates low. The Transit Convention approach would also not seem appropriate for the movement of goods from one part of Ireland to another where the shortest route was through Northern Ireland and where in most cases the transit journey would be less than one hour Models of the future relationship Different trade arrangements can potentially reduce some or all of the trade frictions that would arise under a hard Brexit with trade on MFN terms. The EU has entered into a wide range of trade arrangements with different countries which differ in their scope and ambition, and which might provide a template for the future trade relationship between the UK and the EU27. Reference is made to different models which are conveniently summarised by association with a country which exemplifies that relationship. A number of possible models are set out in Figure 4. It is suggested that the overall level of integration increases as we move from left to right across the table, but this is not necessarily the case in all dimensions. The discussion highlights in particular the treatment of agri-food trade in these different agreements. It must be stressed that the UK government has explicitly ruled out the Canadian, Turkey and Norway models but they are discussed here for the sake of completeness. Mrs May, in her Florence speech, indicated that no existing EU trade arrangement would suit the UK. This is because (a) of the size and significance of the economic and trade relationships between the two parties (b) the fact that the UK would be negotiating a trade agreement on the basis that it had exactly the same regulatory standards (although this argument overlooks the fact that the argument for withdrawal is that the UK wishes to have the ability to change these standards in the future). The UK s preferred option is a bilateral FTA which gives it most if not all of the benefits of the single market yet which meets the UK s four red lines. The EU s chief negotiator Michel Barnier has ruled out this option on the grounds that third countries cannot have the same rights and benefits, since they are not subject to the same obligations.31f Introductory comments by Michel Barnier, European Commission website, 6 December

156 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Figure 19: Main elements of different EU trade arrangements Element Canada Turkey Ukraine Swiss Norway < Less..Degree of integration.more > Nonagricultural trade with EU Agricultural trade with EU Trade with third countries Regulatory coherence Agricultural policy Freedom of movement Budget contributions Dispute settlement Liberalised for goods plus services commitments Partial liberalisation Liberalised for goods Partial liberalisation On way to being liberalised for goods and services Partial liberalisation Goods and some services liberalised Partial liberalisation Goods and services liberalised Partial liberalisation No impact Turkey must apply EU FTAs No impact No impact No impact Limited Aspiration Aspiration High Complete Unilateral CAP CAP aspiration* Unilateral Unilateral aspiration No No No Yes Yes No No No Yes Yes WTO-like Limited WTO-like Limited Effective Source: Own presentation. * The Georgian DCFTA has no aspiration that Georgia will adopt CAP regulations Canada Traditionally, EU trade agreements were mainly about reducing tariffs on trade in goods. With changes in production processes leading to the emergence of global supply chains, the growth in the importance of services trade and the emergence of new platforms such as the digital economy, other barriers to trade have become more important. As a result, the EU now seeks deeper trade agreements (called Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Agreements) which address a wider range of issues. The objectives were set out in the Commission s Communication Trade, Growth and World Affairs as follows: Cutting tariffs on industrial and agricultural goods is still important, but the brunt of the challenge lies elsewhere. What will make a bigger difference is market access for services and investment, opening public procurement, better agreements on and enforcement of protection of IPR, unrestricted supply of raw materials and energy, and, not in the least, overcoming regulatory barriers including via the promotion of international standards. Through trade, we should also promote the greening of the world economy and decent work (DG TRADE 2010). The Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA) with Canada is a representative example of this type of agreement.32f104 The tariff reduction package is one of the most comprehensive the EU has achieved in the context of an FTA; overall, tariffs for 98.6% of all Canadian tariff lines and 98.7% of all EU tariff lines will ultimately be fully eliminated. For a few sensitive agricultural products, there will be a special treatment based on TRQs or an exclusion from any tariff reduction. This preferential access is without any prejudice to the rules and regulations that the products in question need to satisfy on the respective import market (technical, sanitary or phytosanitary rules for the security and the protection of the consumer, the user or the environment, including food safety and labelling requirements). These rules remain untouched by CETA. 104 This description of CETA provisions is based on DG TRADE, CETA Summary of the final negotiating results,

157 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues On technical barriers to trade, both sides agreed to further strengthen the links and cooperation between their standard setting bodies as well as their testing, certification and accreditation organisations. A separate protocol improves the recognition of conformity assessment between the parties. It provides for a mechanism by which EU certification bodies will be allowed to certify for the Canadian market according to Canadian technical regulations and vice-versa. There is a limited extension of the rights and obligations of the EU and of Canada under the WTO SPS Agreement. As regards meats and meat products, the existing EU- Canada Veterinary Agreement was integrated into CETA. As additional elements of trade facilitation, the parties agreed to simplify the approval process for exporting establishments and work on further elements aimed at minimising trade restrictions in the event of a disease outbreak. In the area of plant health, CETA sets up new procedures that will facilitate the approval process of plants, fruit and vegetables by Canada. Overall, CETA will streamline approval processes and improve predictability of trade in animal and plant products but it does not amend either the European or the Canadian SPS rules. All products need to fully comply with applicable sanitary and phytosanitary standards of the importing Party. CETA represents a minimalist model for future UK-EU27 trade relations. It would enable the elimination of tariffs and mutual recognition for conformity assessment with each other s standards, but many of the additional trade costs identified in a hard Brexit scenario would remain. Dispute settlement is limited to a state-to-state dispute settlement mechanism very similar to the WTO panel procedure Turkey An incomplete customs union between the EU and Turkey was created on 1 January 1996, guaranteeing free circulation of industrial goods and processed agricultural products. Tariffs are eliminated on these covered goods and Turkey agreed to adopt the Union s Common External Tariff. However, both sides can introduce anti-dumping duties on each other and on third countries. The customs union does not deal with agriculture or services and also has some gaps in its coverage of manufactures. It also has a very limited mechanism for dealing with disputes. There is a key asymmetry in the design of the customs union in that the EU is permitted to negotiate FTAs with third countries, but Turkey is not permitted a seat at the negotiations because it is not an EU member. This situation is exacerbated by the fact that Turkey has been unable to obtain the same agreement from trading partners in parallel negotiations. This means that Turkey has to apply external tariffs at the level negotiated by the EU but does not gain reciprocal access to the third country s market in return. This asymmetry is potentially very costly for both parties as it risks the introduction of origin controls, the absence of which is a key source of the benefits from the customs union (World Bank 2014). Although Turkey is not an EU member state, it has the obligation to adopt the EU acquis in areas related to the customs union. This includes rules and regulations in areas such as intellectual and industrial property rights, competition rules, state aid, the custom code and administrative cooperation. The EU agreed to accept without additional conformity assessment checks Turkish goods for which relevant EU legislation had been incorporated, although this did not happen until F105 However, the transposition of new regulations suffers from outdated procedures. The commitment to approximation of laws under the customs union agreement should be seen as part of the more general alignment process as part of Turkey s application for EU membership. Although Turkey has made considerable 105 Holmes, P., Staying in the Customs Union: Neither Soft Nor Simple, 11 July

158 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies strides in implementing the EU food safety, veterinary and plant health acquis, Turkish food exports are not exempt from EU border checks. However, for some products (e.g. fruits and vegetables, dairy) the EU has begun to recognise certificates issued by the Turkish authorities that export produce complies with EU standards on the same basis as for other third countries. Trade in agricultural products is addressed through a bilateral agriculture and fisheries agreement which entered into force in 1998, and which provided for a 22-year period for Turkey to adjust its agricultural policy with a view to adopting, at the end of that period, those measures of the common agricultural policy which must be applied in Turkey if free movement of agricultural products between it and the Community is to be achieved. Pending the fulfilment of these conditions, the EU and Turkey grant each other preferential treatment in agricultural goods and fishery products. The customs union does not cover services, and particularly road transport services. In the EU, bilateral road transport agreements including quota negotiation remain the responsibility of the individual EU Member States. By limiting the number of Turkish-registered vehicles that can carry goods in their territory, EU Member States set limits on Turkish goods that can be transported to the EU by Turkish road transport operators (although they can still be carried by EU road transport operators). This raises costs if the most efficient transport operator can no longer be used. The customs union with Turkey is the only example where the EU has entered into a customs union arrangement with a third country of significant size (the customs unions with Andorra and San Marino are discounted in this respect). It would have limited attractions as a model for UK-EU27 trade relations in the future. The asymmetries in Turkish participation in decisions stem from the initial expectation that the customs union would be a transitional arrangement while Turkey moved towards full EU membership. The agreement goes further than CETA in that it foresees the movement of goods between the two parties not on the basis of originating status but on the fact that they comply with provisions on free circulation. In the case of agrifood products, the requirement for this is that Turkey aligns its food safety, veterinary and plant health legislation with the Union acquis, and that it adopts those elements of the CAP which are necessary to ensure free movement can be achieved. As these requirements are not yet in place, trade liberalisation in agriculture is limited to some preferential concessions. Agri-food products traded between the EU and Turkey must comply with the standard rules for third countries Ukraine The European Parliament in its Brexit resolution of 5 April 2016 specifically noted that an association agreement could be an appropriate model for the future UK-EU27 trade relationship. Provision for Association Agreements is set out in Article 217 TFEU which ordains that the Union shall develop a special relationship with neighbouring countries, aiming to establish an area of prosperity and good neighbourliness, founded on the values of the Union and characterised by close and peaceful relations based on cooperation. In 2014 the EU concluded an association agreement with the Ukraine (along with similar agreements with Georgia and Moldova) which some observers believe could be a useful template for a future UK-EU27 agreement (Duff 2016; Emerson 2017). The Ukraine s association agreement goes beyond a trade agreement only as it provides for future political cooperation in the field of justice and home affairs, foreign, security and defence policies as well as specifying an elaborate institutional architecture. However, at its heart is a Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Agreement in which three of the four principles of freedom of movement are respected. There is mostly tariff free access for goods, passports 154

159 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues for services, and customs cooperation. The movement of labour is subject to work permits against the backdrop of visa liberalisation (Duff, 2016). Trade in agricultural goods has been liberalised, but for sensitive commodities the tariff preferences are limited by TRQs. The agreement also covers agricultural policy, where the parties shall cooperate to promote agricultural and rural policies, in particular through progressive convergence of policies and legislation. The parties agree to support gradual approximation to relevant EU laws and standards, and a list of EU regulations which broadly govern the EU s Common Agricultural Policy is attached. However, no timetables are stipulated for approximation. The view of Emerson and Movchan (2016) is that the overall message is that Ukraine retains much flexibility over how far or how fast to replicate elements of EU farm policy. The companion DCFTA signed with Georgia does not require approximation of EU agricultural policy yet notably provides for full liberalisation of agricultural trade between the two parties. Ukraine will progressively adapt its technical regulations and standards to those of the EU. Future negotiation of an Agreement on Conformity Assessment and Acceptance of Industrial Products (ACAA) will provide that, in the specific sectors, covered trade between the parties will take place under the same conditions as between EU Member States. The main treaty text of each chapter is accompanied by an annex that lists the EU regulations and directives with which Ukraine agrees to comply, mostly taking these laws in their entirety, but in some cases identifying only those articles that apply, or may be excluded (Emerson 2017). DG TRADE estimates that harmonisation and/or mutual recognition of technical standards should cut existing non-tariff barriers in the agri-food sector by half compared to 2004 (DG TRADE 2013). Ukraine is also committed to aligning its SPS and animal welfare legislation with that of the EU. The SPS chapter deals with verification procedures, listing of establishments, levels of checks, and settlement of trade problems. The Agreement did not itself define the list of laws to be approximated, but instead required Ukraine to submit a Comprehensive Strategy for the implementation of EU SPS standards within three months of its entry into force. In February 2016 agreement was reached between Ukraine and the European Commission on the contents of the Comprehensive Strategy, which is a list of roughly 255 EU regulations and directives (Emerson and Movchan 2016). Rules are established for recognising the equivalence of measures taken by Ukraine with those of the EU. The process should be launched by the exporting party based on the objective demonstration of equivalence and the objective assessment of this demonstration by the importing party. Where equivalence is recognised there will be a reduction of physical checks at frontiers and simplified procedures. Dispute settlement follows the state-to-state WTO panel approach but with faster procedures. There is a procedure that obliges the arbitration panel to ask the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU) for a binding preliminary ruling when there is a dispute concerning the interpretation and application of EU law (i.e. EU legislation annexed to the Agreement). This procedure aims to ensure a uniform interpretation and application of the Agreement s annexed EU legislation without jeopardising the exclusive jurisdiction of the CJEU to interpret EU law. The Ukraine model presupposes a high degree of integration, yet allows for flexibility in deciding the areas where common standards would apply, it does not require acceptance of free movement and CJEU rulings do not have direct effect. Unlike the Turkish model, there is no presumption that Ukraine is a candidate country for EU membership. Advocates of this model believe it could be developed as a template for a future UK-EU27 agreement in ways that meet both the UK s and EU27 s red lines. The EU, of course, might look very differently at extending the provisions of the Ukraine DCFTA to a much more developed economy. 155

160 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Switzerland Relations between the EU and Switzerland are based on more than 120 bilateral agreements,34f106 including a free trade agreement in 1972 and two major series of sectoral bilateral agreements that aligned a large portion of Swiss law with that of the EU at the time of signing.35f107 The first set of sectoral agreements (known as Bilaterals I) was signed in 1999 and entered into force in These seven agreements cover the issues of free movement and mutual market opening including in agriculture. These agreements are linked by a guillotine clause meaning that the suspension, denunciation or non-renewal of one agreement causes the whole package to lapse. This became important following the Swiss referendum vote in 2014 to restrict the free movement of persons from the EU. A further set of sectoral agreements (Bilaterals II) was signed in 2004 and entered into force in These agreements extended cooperation on asylum and free travel within the Schengen borders as well as to new areas such as environment and taxation. These agreements give Switzerland effective membership of the EU single market for goods. 36F108 In contrast to the EEA Agreement, the sectoral agreements between Switzerland and the EU do not cover the free movement of services (except for some aspects such as civil aviation and overland transport or direct insurance for damage). In return, the Swiss have agreed to make budgetary transfers to the less prosperous EU Member States as a contribution to the economic and social cohesion of the single market. The bilateral Agreement on Agriculture between Switzerland and the EU, which regulates trade of basic agricultural products, entered into force in Contrary to the FTA for industrial products, this bilateral agreement does not create a free trade area; instead mutual market access is improved by reducing tariffs and non-tariff barriers to trade for products of particular interest to the EU and Switzerland (mainly fruits and vegetables, cheese, and meat specialities).37f109 Switzerland maintains its own trade policy and its ability to enter into FTAs with third countries. Goods passing between Switzerland and the EU must still pass through customs clearance to check that documentation is in order and that the goods are what they say they are. However, the bilateral Agreement on Agriculture simplifies trade in the agricultural sector by reducing or even eliminating non-tariff barriers to trade. Since 2009, Switzerland and the EU have formed a common veterinary area without veterinary controls on animals and products of animal origin (extended in 2012 to Norway and Iceland). Switzerland applies the same controls at its borders as does the EU. Certain technical regulations in the areas of plant health, animal feed, seeds, organic farming, wine and spirits as well as quality norms for fruit and vegetables are mutually recognized as being equivalent. Switzerland has introduced a new General Food Law Revision which came into force on 1 May 2017 and which aligns the majority of Swiss food law with EU food law. From the EU perspective, this arrangement based on a network of bilateral agreements has a number of disadvantages. Unlike the EEA Agreement, the nature of the bilateral agreements with Switzerland is static, given that there are no proper mechanisms to adapt the agreements to evolving EU legislation. EU law is adopted by Switzerland based on the dates of signature 106 For the full list of agreements, see Swiss Confederation, Department for European Affairs, Liste der Abkommen Schweiz - Europäische Union, in Kraft am 1. Januar For a review, see European Parliament, Fact Sheet The European Economic Area (EEA), Switzerland and the North, June Strictly, only EU Member States can be members of the single market. However, the EFTA members of the European Economic Area are also often regarded as members, since they have a level of access to the single market similar to that enjoyed by EU members. Similarly, Switzerland has a high degree of access to the single market in goods without being an EU member (House of Commons International Trade Committee, 2017). 109 Swiss Confederation Federal Office for Agriculture, Agreement on Agriculture. 156

161 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues of the agreements; although in some cases adaptations can be made by Joint Committees. There is also an absence of surveillance and an efficient dispute settlement mechanism. For some agreements, the case law of the CJEU is treated as binding until the date of signature, but not beyond. The EU has therefore insisted that it will not allow Switzerland any further single market access (e.g. as regards electricity) without a framework institutional agreement to resolve these problems. EU-Swiss negotiations for a framework institutional agreement were launched on 22 May F110 Switzerland is resisting EU pressure to agree a framework agreement emphasising that the bilateral path allows the country to prosper while maintaining its independence. 39F111 Negotiations on the framework agreement are continuing. Because of these institutional deficiencies, it is unlikely that the EU would be prepared to govern its future trade relations with the UK under a similar network of bilateral agreements Norway In this family of five models of EU trade relations with non-eu countries, the Norway model represents the model with the greatest degree of integration, although still less than the single market within the EU Customs Union. Norway is an EFTA Member State and a signatory to the European Economic Area agreement with the EU. EEA membership means that there is free trade in goods and services between Norway and the EU with the exception of agricultural trade. However, some liberalisation of agricultural trade has taken place under a separate bilateral agreement between Norway and the EU which was updated and extended in The EEA agreement gives Norway membership of the single market by ensuring that Norway adopts the EU s regulatory acquis. It also incorporates the four freedoms of the internal market (free movement of goods, people, services and capital) and related policies (competition, transport, energy, and economic and monetary cooperation). The agreement includes horizontal policies strictly related to the four freedoms: social policies (including health and safety at work, labour law and the equal treatment of men and women); policies on consumer protection, the environment, statistics and company law; and a number of flanking policies, such as those relating to research and technological development, which are not based on the EU acquis or legally binding acts, but are implemented through cooperation activities.40f112 Norway also makes a budget contribution to economic and social cohesion in the single market through the EEA Financial Mechanism (referred to as EEA Grants and Norway Grants). Apart from excluding agricultural trade liberalisation with the EU, there are a number of EU policy areas which the EEA Agreement does not cover. Norway continues to have its own agricultural and fisheries policies. It is not a member of the EU customs area so it has an independent trade policy (as a member of EFTA, Norway jointly negotiates free trade agreements with third countries with the other EFTA Member States). The EEA agreement does not cover broader co-operation in the areas of foreign and security policy, nor justice and home affairs (although Norway like the other EFTA countries is part of the Schengen area). There are provisions specifying that the EFTA-EEA countries should be involved in preparing EU acts but, although they can make representations, they do not participate in EU decisionmaking. The EEA Joint Committee, composed of representatives of the EU and the three EFTA- EEA states, meets monthly to decide which pieces of EU legislation should be incorporated into the EEA. Legislation is formally incorporated by including the relevant acts in lists of protocols 110 The Council mandate for these negotiations is here. 111 Swiss Confederation, Switzerland s European policy state of play, accessed 20 October European Parliament, Fact Sheet The European Economic Area (EEA), Switzerland and the North, June

162 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies and annexes to the EEA Agreement. Several thousand acts have been incorporated into the EEA Agreement in this way. Once an EU act has been incorporated into the EEA Agreement, it must be transposed into the national legislation of the EFTA-EEA countries (if this is required under their national legislation). This may simply require a governmental decision, or it may require parliamentary approval. Transposition and application are monitored by the EFTA Surveillance Authority and the EFTA Court. The EFTA Court is a key part of the institutional structure. It plays the same role in enforcing the laws regulating the single market for the three EFTA-EEA states as the CJEU does for the EU Member States. The EFTA Court judges are appointed by the EFTA-EEA states. Because the relevant EU laws are transposed into national legislation, individuals and businesses can defend their rights under these laws in national courts. The EFTA Court has a particular role in adjudicating on cases brought by the EFTA Surveillance Authority against a Member State, and actions concerning the settlement of disputes between two or more EFTA states regarding the interpretation or application of the EEA Agreement. It can also issue advisory opinions interpreting the EEA Agreement on the request of a national court of an EFTA-EEA state. The Norway model has the great advantage that it would keep the UK as a member of the single market and thus avoid border controls for regulatory purposes. However, unless at the same time the UK also entered into a customs union with the EU27, border controls would still be required (as they are between Norway and Sweden, and between Germany/France and Switzerland) even if their practical effect could be minimised through a far-reaching customs agreement. The UK government has to date ruled out an EEA-type trade arrangement on the grounds that it would require the UK to transpose EU legislation in which it had no say in deciding into UK law. This would run counter to the objective of Brexit of taking back control The WTO dimension of UK withdrawal Paragraph 13 of the European Council s negotiating guidelines deals broadly with honouring international commitments. Following the withdrawal, the United Kingdom will no longer be covered by agreements concluded by the Union or by Member States acting on its behalf or by the Union and its Member States acting jointly. The Union will continue to have its rights and obligations in relation to international agreements. In this respect, the European Council expects the United Kingdom to honour its share of all international commitments contracted in the context of its EU membership. In such instances, a constructive dialogue with the United Kingdom on a possible common approach towards third country partners, international organisations and conventions concerned should be engaged. From an agri-food perspective, the most significant sharing of international commitments will be the division of the EU s World Trade Organisation (WTO) commitments. The EU s commitments are listed in documents called schedules of concessions, which reflect the specific tariff concessions and other commitments that it has given in the context of WTO negotiations on trade liberalisation. For trade in goods in general, these usually consist of maximum tariff levels which are often referred to as bound tariffs or tariff bindings. In the case of agricultural products, these concessions and commitments also relate to tariff rate quotas, limits on export subsidies, and some kinds of domestic support. The content of the EU schedules has changed over time to take account of successive enlargements as well as different modifications, such as GATT Article XXVIII negotiations or rectification procedures. 158

163 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues The UK is a member of the WTO in its own right, as are all other EU Member States as well as the EU itself. At the moment, the UK s commitments on maximum tariffs, tariff rate quotas, domestic agricultural subsidies and agricultural export subsidies are bundled with the EU s schedule of concessions. Following Brexit, the UK will need to agree its own schedule of concessions with other WTO members. 41F113 This should not be contentious in the case of its commitments on bound tariffs where the general assumption is that the UK will inherit the commitments in the EU schedule (although there will still be issues around the exchange rate to use in converting EU tariffs in euro to UK tariffs in sterling). However, where the EU s commitments consist of quantitative bindings (for example, to import specific amounts of third country lamb under preferential tariffs, or to limit non-exempt domestic support 42F114 to a specific ceiling), the question arises how this shared commitment will be allocated between the UK and the EU27 after Brexit. Two sets of quantitative bindings are scheduled under the WTO Agreement on Agriculture. These are the EU s commitments on limits on agricultural export subsidies and on non-exempt domestic agricultural support. Under the WTO Ministerial Decision on Export Competition adopted at the Nairobi WTO Ministerial Council in December 2015, developed countries including the EU agreed to immediately eliminate their remaining scheduled export subsidy entitlements as of the date of adoption of that Decision. A delay was agreed for processed products, dairy products and pigmeat until the end of 2020 for developed countries that had provided export subsidies for these products in a recent period, provided that the quantities subsidised did not exceed the quantities exported with subsidy in the years and that no export subsidies would be applied either to new products or new markets. The UK might be interested to acquire a share of the EU entitlements to be able to use export subsidies for these products but in any case they would lapse for both the UK and the EU27 by the end of F115 In any case, the EU has already made a voluntary commitment that it will not make further use of agricultural export subsidies, so agreement on an allocation of the EU remaining entitlements should not be difficult. The UK would not be able to make use of any entitlement to export subsidies on the exempted products to subsidise exports of these products to the EU because no subsidies were paid on exports to this market during the base years As any agreement with the UK to share entitlements would reduce the EU27 entitlements by a corresponding amount, an allocation formula based on relative shares of usage in a base period would not likely be opposed by WTO members. Somewhat similar considerations apply in the case of the EU commitments on nonexempt domestic support. The amount of non-exempt support notified by the EU in its latest notification to the WTO for the year amounted to 5.97 billion compared to its non-exempt domestic support ceiling (BTAMS) of billion. 4F116 Because the EU is only using a fraction of its entitlement to non-exempt domestic support, agreement with the UK on sharing the EU entitlement based on relative use in a base period should not be difficult 113 These issues are also discussed in House of Commons International Trade Committee, 2017, Chapter Not all domestic support is disciplined under the WTO Agreement on Agriculture. Support which is covered by Annex 2 (Green Box), Article 6.5 (Blue Box) and de minimis support is exempted from the limit on a developed country s domestic support (called the Bound Total Aggregate Measurement of Support, BTAMS). All other types of support are deemed trade-distorting and must be limited to the country s BTAMS ceiling in its schedule of concessions. Domestic support for WTO notifications is calculated according to procedures set out in Annexes 3 and 4 of the WTO Agreement on Agriculture. 115 The EU Mission to the WTO announced on 6 October 2017 that the EU had just submitted a revised goods schedule to the WTO which includes both the outcome of recent negotiations linked to EU enlargement as well as implementation of the Nairobi Decision. The revised schedule, which is awaiting certification, incorporates the full Nairobi Decision including the exemptions until 2020 into the EU schedule. 116 WTO Notification by the European Union G/AG/N/EU/34, 8 February

164 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies (although there will be knotty technical problems to resolve in deciding on these shares). 45F117 Any proposed allocation is also not likely to meet with opposition from other WTO Members because any scheduled commitment by the UK would lead to a corresponding reduction in the EU s entitlement to provide trade-distorting support in the future (although those countries that were unable to establish a BTAMS ceiling at the time of their accession might object to the UK being able to do so now). Unlike in the case of export subsidies, where all entitlements will anyway lapse less than two years after Brexit, the EU27 should be conscious that the ceiling agreed for the UK will determine its margin for manoeuvre with respect to its future use of trade-distorting support (e.g. its future use of coupled payments). The higher the ceiling allocated to the UK, the greater the potential damage to EU27 producers if the UK were to make full use of its entitlement at some point in the future. The most controversial area in the division of the EU s quantitative WTO commitments concerns its scheduled tariff rate quotas (TRQs) (Downes 2017). These scheduled TRQs arose at the end of the Uruguay Round as a way of preserving and ensuring some minimum access for third countries in the face of tariffication.46f118 Tariffication was the obligation on WTO Members to replace all forms of import barriers (including quotas, import licenses, voluntary export restraints, variable import levies and many others) by tariffs which could then be bound and reduced over time. The fear was that the resulting tariffs might be set so high that very little trade liberalisation might occur. As a result, two types of TRQs were created under the WTO Agreement on Agriculture: minimum access and current access TRQs.47F119 Where there were no significant imports, minimum access TRQs equal to 5% of domestic consumption in the base period had to be established. Where an importer had current imports greater than these minimum amounts, current access TRQs had to be introduced in order to maintain these export opportunities and allow them to increase. Further TRQs have been created subsequently by the EU, for example, to compensate third countries for the loss of market access arising from successive enlargements of the EU, or as part of the resolution of a WTO dispute brought by a third country against the EU. There were 85 TRQs in the EU s initial schedule resulting from the Uruguay Round and this number increased to 93 in 2006, 112 in 2009 and to 119 in 2013 covering meat, cereals, dairy products, fruits and vegetables and more (Matthews, Salvatici, and Scoppola 2016). 48F120 The quotas vary considerably in both size and form. Some provide a zero duty in-quota tariff rate, others have tariffs below the MFN rate. The administration of these TRQs is further complicated because some are pre-allocated to specific exporters (country-specific TRQs) while others are open to any exporter (global TRQs), and often further restricted by elaborate conditions. 117 Brink, L., UK Brexit and WTO farm support limits, capreform.eu, 13 July Scheduled TRQs at the WTO should be distinguished from TRQs introduced as part of the EU s FTAs with third countries. TRQs are often used to provide some concessions to the FTA partner in the case of sensitive products. 119 These provisions are found in the Modalities for the establishment of specific binding commitments under the reform programme circulated by the Chairman of the Market Access Group, WTO MTN.GNG/MA/W/24, 20 December The full list is contained in the EU s Schedule CLXXIII of which the latest version available on the WTO website is dated 1 December See also the latest EU notification of imports under TRQs WTO G/AG/N/EU/37 dated 17 March 2017 which lists each scheduled TRQ, the quota quantity, actual imports and the actual fill rate. The actual use of many of the EU s TRQs as shown by the fill rate varies widely. 160

165 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues The UK and EU27 have jointly written a letter to other WTO Members saying that they will propose a methodology for splitting these TRQs based on relative consumption shares of the TRQ imports over a recent period.49f121 However, a bilateral agreement on sharing out TRQ quantities has a different impact on other WTO Members compared to sharing out export subsidy or domestic support entitlements. TRQs provide market access opportunities to other WTO Members. A letter signed by a number of agricultural exporters in response claims that a division of the existing EU TRQs between the UK and the EU27 would diminish their export opportunities in both quantity and quality terms.50f122 While currently the full volume of a given TRQ can be imported into any Member State, under the proposed approach those volumes would be reduced. Further, any product sent into the UK or EU27 currently enjoys effectively frictionless onward trade into the other party, thanks to EU Customs Union and single market rules. If there are additional trade costs following Brexit, these countries claim this would further diminish the quality of access provided. They also raise the technical problem that using import shares to mirror consumption can give biased results given that product may be imported into a particular country for technical reasons but then sent on to other EU Member States for consumption. These other WTO Members therefore imply that the overall size of the combined TRQs after Brexit should be increased to reflect this diminution of their export opportunities.51f123 In the extreme, the suggestion has been made that the EU27 should maintain the full value of current TRQs and that the UK should, in turn, also schedule TRQs of equal value. Such an outcome would be opposed by UK and EU27 farmers because it would represent additional competition from third country exporters on these markets. This study is not the place to discuss the rights and wrongs of these positions on future scheduled TRQ commitments,52f124 but there are implications for possible transition arrangements particularly in the event of a hard Brexit. In particular, splitting the EU TRQs would mean that the UK TRQs would make no specific provision for existing UK-EU27 trade, and vice versa. This might not have any practical implications if the UK and the EU27 create a bilateral free trade agreement covering agricultural products on Brexit Day. However, this omission has huge implications if tariff barriers are erected. These implications are further explored in Chapter 4. There may also be a need to split TRQs specifically allocated to the EU by other WTO members as part of their commitments, although the number and importance of these TRQs has not been clarified. 121 UK Department of International Trade, UK and EU set out proposals to WTO members for trade post-brexit, 11 October The letter is available on the Financial Times website. 123 To meet this criticism, the UK and the EU27 could enter into their schedules that their TRQs represent a joint obligation to meet their commitments to other WTO Members. 124 See Ungphakorn, P., EU joins UK in post-brexit WTO talks as data emerges as first major hurdle, Agra Europe, 23 Oct 2017 for the most recent account of the TRQ discussions in Geneva at the time of writing this study. 161

166 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 162

167 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues 3. Avoiding a cliff edge for agri-food trade KEY FINDINGS Even if the UK and the EU27 conclude an agreement on the withdrawal conditions and on the nature of their future relationship by 29 March 2019, traders face a cliff-edge situation because of the lack of preparedness of the customs administrations and other relevant authorities on both sides to manage border controls; the lack of knowledge on the part of the large number of new businesses that will face the need to seek customs clearance for their exports and imports; and the almost certain congestion at major ports of entry and exit because of the extra time required for these controls. Both parties have indicated a willingness to consider a transition period. Both parties have also indicated their red lines regarding matters on which they would insist during a transition period. There is little clarity, however, about how extensive such a transition arrangement might be and what laws and regulations it would have to cover to ensure that trade, including trade in agri-food products, would continue on the same basis as it does today. One option is that the UK would remain a Member State of the EU for a further time-limited period, either by including a withdrawal date later than 29 March 2019 in the withdrawal agreement or by unanimously agreeing to extend the Art.50 TEU deadline for the negotiations. Another option is that the UK would agree to bind itself to following the relevant Union acquis as a non-member State for a time-limited period after 29 March 2019 while also joining a temporary customs union for this period. Negotiating what would effectively be a complete if temporary trade agreement at the same time as the parties are negotiating a withdrawal agreement and the framework for their future relations may be more than can be achieved in the remaining time available. Fall-back positions which would avoid some but not all of the additional trade costs, such as a temporary customs union on its own or just a free trade agreement in goods, should be considered if it proves impossible to reach an agreement in which the UK remains bound by the relevant Union acquis in the time available. Following the mandate at the October 2017 meeting of the European Council (Art.50), the General Council (Art. 50) and the Union negotiator should seek to rapidly progress preparatory work particularly on models of transitional arrangements. This should help to clarify what might be the minimum requirements to ensure that trade can continue to take place with the UK as it does today for the duration of the transition period, and what an appropriate balance of rights and obligations might be during this period. Specific issues for consideration will include whether UK membership of the CAP and the Common Fisheries Policy (CFP) will be deemed necessary as a prerequisite for continued free trade in agricultural and fishery products during the transition period, as well as arrangements to ensure the continued protection of Geographical Indications in the UK The previous chapter discussed the nature of the additional trade costs that would face EU agri-food traders in the event that the UK withdrew from the EU in a hard Brexit, and possible long-term trade arrangements between the UK and the EU27 which would help to mitigate some or all of these trade costs. 163

168 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies In this chapter, we assume that the Article 50 TEU negotiations proceed fruitfully and there is an agreement both on the withdrawal conditions and on the nature of the future relationship which is ratified by both parties before March However, if the UK insists that this should be the date of its departure from the EU, it will result in the cliff edge problem that traders would be likely to face considerable disruption immediately after Brexit Day. One reason is that both parties are highly likely not to have agreed and ratified a fully-fledged trade agreement by this date, even if they have reached agreement on an outline or a future framework. A second reason is that market access under the future trade arrangement will inevitably be more restricted than is the case at present. This implies increased administrative formalities when goods cross the UK-EU27 border, as well as the possibility of increased physical checks and associated time delays, and time will be needed to make these arrangements possible. For these reasons, both the EU27 and the UK have recognised the need for a transitional or interim arrangement although there is disagreement about what this might entail and how long it would last. This chapter examines how agri-food trade could be affected by different transition arrangements. There is also the possibility that, after 29 March 2019, trade between the UK and the EU27 could reflect a hard Brexit situation because the withdrawal negotiations break down and the UK exits without a withdrawal agreement. Trade would then take place on MFN terms and, given the likely bad blood between the parties in this outcome, the prospect of a trade agreement would be postponed to some future date. In this situation, the question of negotiating a transitional arrangement does not arise. A transitional arrangement to avoid a hard Brexit is only relevant when the parties either have ratified or are continuing to negotiate their future relationship The need for transition arrangements A key concern for EU27-UK agri-food trade in the event of a hard Brexit, especially for perishable food products, is the prospect of delays at the key cross-channel crossings. The UK, Ireland, France, Belgium and the Netherlands will have to make big investments in customs systems and lorry parks at their ports to cope with the post-brexit surge of customs declarations and consignment checks. There are three main concerns: the ability of customs systems to cope with the dramatic increase in consignments requiring clearance, the huge increase in the number of firms with no previous experience that will now need to access customs clearance procedures, and the prospect of logistical bottlenecks because of the inability of the key cross-channel entry points to cope with the extra time that would be required for customs and health checks. Lack of customs readiness. The specific challenges facing the UK have been well documented, particularly in a recent National Audit Office (NAO) report on implementation of the new UK Customs Declaration Service (CDS) by Her Majesty s Revenue and Customs (HMRC) (National Audit Office 2017). This replacement for the software currently handling customs clearance in the UK was initiated partly in response to the need to upgrade UK customs systems to meet the requirements of the new EU Union Customs Code. It is scheduled to come into force in January 2019 so as to be ready to meet the EU deadline for all customs procedures to be handled electronically after 2020, but the Brexit date at end March 2019 makes delivery of the new system even more time-sensitive. All experience with the introduction of large and complex software systems suggests there will be inevitable teething problems. The NAO report found that HMRC has made progress in designing and developing the new software but that there is still a significant amount of work to complete, and there is a risk that HMRC will not have the full functionality and scope of CDS in place by March 2019 when the UK plans to leave the EU. 164

169 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues Also, the addition of customs clearance requirements for current intra-eu trade would make demands on the CDS system above its design capacity. Currently, there are 141,000 UK traders who make customs declarations for trade outside the EU. HMRC estimate that a further 180,000 traders will make declarations for the first time under the new system, assuming that the UK leaves the customs union. Currently, there are around 55 million declarations per year; this is expected to rise nearly five-fold to 255 million after March 2019 based on current levels of UK/EU27 trade. The current design capacity for the new CDS is to handle 150 million declarations each year, rather than the estimated 255 million. While these are the potential problems that the UK would face, similar challenges face EU27 Member State customs administrations, many of which are also upgrading systems to meet the new UCC requirements. There is virtually no information available on the EU side on its preparedness to deal with exports to the UK or imports from the UK in the event of a hard Brexit.53F125 However, Ireland is expecting the number of customs transactions to increase by a factor of ten.54f126 It is not only customs administrations that will be challenged to cope with UK-EU27 trade after Brexit. Many plant and animal products are only able to enter through designated entry points where physical inspections including laboratory tests can take place. There is very limited capacity to handle all of the additional inspections that would be required if trade between the UK and the EU27 also had to be inspected. For example, neither Calais nor Coquelles, the two main points of entry into France, has a Border Inspection Post for animal products. Lack of business readiness. It is not only the public authorities that need to prepare for a hard Brexit but also private businesses. New systems would have to be installed, and staff would have to be trained. This will be especially important for the many businesses now exporting within the single market that have no experience with customs clearance procedures. As Joe Owen of the Institute for Government in the UK explained: 5F127 Again, the best way to understand timelines for customs is to look at past changes. The EU s Union Customs Code was designed in 2013, introduced across the EU in 2016 and businesses have until 2020 to become compliant. While that seven-year planning horizon could be reduced in the case of Brexit, could you really cut it back to just two years? That is a heroic timeline. Logistical difficulties. Access to the UK market requires goods to be moved through UK ports (including the Channel Tunnel in this designation) and UK access to the EU27 market means moving goods through EU27 ports. The only exception is lorries crossing the only land border between the UK and the EU27 between Northern Ireland and Ireland. As can be seen from Figure 5, there are two main corridors which will be affected by a hard Brexit, the Dover Strait corridor across the Channel and the Dublin corridor across the Irish Sea. Dover is the key artery for UK trade with continental Europe, with over 2.5 million heavy goods vehicles (HGVs) passing through the port each year (10,000 per day) in either direction, and a further 1.6 million freight movements through the Channel Tunnel. 125 Mr Jim Harra, Director General, Customer Strategy and Tax Design, HM Revenue and Customs, Oral evidence: Her Majesty's Revenue and Customs Annual Report and Accounts, HC 314, UK House of Commons Treasury Select Committee, 14 September 2017 stated: But when it comes to post-brexit arrangements, other member states have been clear that that is a matter for the Commission and the Commission s negotiating team to deal with. So we are not having significant discussions with other customs authorities in the EU about what their arrangements will be post-brexit, but clearly, just as there is a task for the UK to deliver, there will be a task for them as well. More insight into their preparedness for that will be very useful to us, but we don t currently have it (italics added). 126 Brexit - Recent Developments and Future Negotiations: Discussion, Evidence by Liam Irwin of the Office of the Revenue Commissioners to the Oireachtas Joint Committee on Finance, Public Expenditure and Reform, and Taoiseach, 16 May Britain s heroic timeline to introduce new customs regime, Financial Times, October 10,

170 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Both Dover and the Channel Tunnel crossings are designed for RoRo traffic (where goods remain on the back of a lorry and are driven on to a ferry or the train for the Channel Tunnel or, in the case of Dover, also for trailer transport (where the trailers are dropped off and picked up on the other side by another haulier). Lorries account for 45% of all non-bulk goods traffic with the EU and trailers for a further 24% (Owen, Shepheard, and Stojanovic 2017). A lorry driver arriving at the port of entry will stop briefly only to show passport and boarding information, and on arrival will be on the motorway within minutes. This compares to lorry loads of goods entering Dover from outside the EU (around 3% of the total) which are subject to checks that take 45 minutes on average (Meaney 2017). Currently, the Channel ports do not have the parking facilities to cope with delays of this magnitude, leading to fears of massive congestion for traffic on the cross-channel and Irish Sea routes. Figure 20: Annual lorry traffic and EU share of trade for selected major UK ports in 2015 Source: Owen et al, 2017, reproduced with permission. 166

171 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues 3.2. Views of the parties on transition Article 50 on transition Article 50(3) TFEU provides for the following arrangements for withdrawal: 3. The Treaties shall cease to apply to the State in question from the date of entry into force of the withdrawal agreement or, failing that, two years after the notification referred to in paragraph 2, unless the European Council, in agreement with the Member State concerned, unanimously decides to extend this period. This Article provides for two possible withdrawal dates but makes no explicit reference to a transition period. If there is a date agreed in the withdrawal agreement, then the UK would remain a full member to that alternative date, and would then cease to be a member altogether (as a curiosum, the exit date could also be before 29 March 2019 if this were agreed as part of the withdrawal agreement). The withdrawal agreement needs only a qualified majority of the EU27 Member States, as well as the approval of the European Parliament. The two-year deadline which expires on 29 March 2019 is a default in the event there is no such agreed date. The second way envisaged by Article 50 TEU of extending the two-year period is for the period to be extended without a withdrawal agreement in order to allow negotiations to continue. This extension would require unanimous support of the EU27 and the UK. Again, the UK would remain a full member of the EU. The new date could be a specific one, or it could be an open extension until further notice. 56F128 In the UK Prime Minister s Florence speech in September 2017, Mrs May appeared to close off these options. In her speech she stated: The United Kingdom will cease to be a member of the European Union on 29th March We will no longer sit at the European Council table or in the Council of Ministers, and we will no longer have Members of the European Parliament. At face value, this implies that the UK is not interested in pursuing a withdrawal agreement that sets a withdrawal date later than 29 March Nor is it interested in trying to persuade the EU to unanimously extend the negotiating period. The speech states that the UK intention is to leave the EU on 29 March EU traders should therefore prepare for a change in trading conditions from that date The EU position on a transition period The European Parliament expressed its view on transition arrangements in its Brexit resolution of 5 April 2017: Believes that transitional arrangements ensuring legal certainty and continuity can only be agreed between the European Union and the United Kingdom if they contain the right balance of rights and obligations for both parties and preserve the integrity of the European Union s legal order, with the Court of Justice of the European Union responsible for settling any legal challenges; believes, moreover, that any such arrangements must also be strictly limited both in time not exceeding three years and in scope, as they can never be a substitute for European Union membership. 128 David Allen Green, The problems of the Brexit transition, Financial Times, 26 September

172 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies The European Council (Art. 50) in its guidelines in April 2017 accepted that transition arrangements could be part of the withdrawal agreement. Having defined what it felt were core principles in the negotiations, it emphasised that The core principles set out above should apply equally to the negotiations on an orderly withdrawal, to any preliminary and preparatory discussions on the framework for a future relationship, and to any form of transitional arrangements. The core principles, in turn, are defined as follows: The desire to have the United Kingdom as a close partner in the future. Any agreement with the United Kingdom will have to be based on a balance of rights and obligations, and ensure a level playing field. Preserving the integrity of the Single Market excludes participation based on a sectorby-sector approach. A non-member of the Union, that does not live up to the same obligations as a member, cannot have the same rights and enjoy the same benefits as a member. The Union will preserve its autonomy as regards its decision-making as well as the role of the Court of Justice of the European Union. In accordance with the principle that nothing is agreed until everything is agreed, individual items cannot be settled separately. The Union will approach the negotiations with unified positions, and will engage with the United Kingdom exclusively through the channels set out in these guidelines and in the negotiating directives. The guidelines went on to specify the following conditions around any transition arrangements. To the extent necessary and legally possible, the negotiations may also seek to determine transition arrangements which are in the interest of the Union and, as appropriate, to provide for bridges towards the foreseeable framework for the future relationship in the light of the progress made. Any such transition arrangements must be clearly defined, limited in time, and subject to effective enforcement mechanisms. Should a time-limited prolongation of Union acquis be considered, this would require existing Union regulatory, budgetary, supervisory, judiciary and enforcement instruments and structures to apply. Based on the guidelines, any transition arrangements would need to fulfil three conditions: they must (a) be clearly defined, (b) limited in time, and (c) subject to effective enforcement mechanisms. Furthermore, a transition which involves a time-limited prolongation of Union acquis would also require existing Union regulatory, budgetary, supervisory, judiciary and enforcement instruments and structures to apply. These conditions were repeated verbatim in the Council s negotiating directives to the EU negotiator Michel Barnier. The European Parliament in its resolution on the state of play of negotiations with the United Kingdom in October 2017 was even more explicit on the conditions that should apply during a transition period: Notes, in line with its resolution of 5 April 2017, that the Prime Minister of the United Kingdom proposed in her speech of 22 September 2017 a time-limited transitional period; such a transition can only happen on the basis of the existing European Union regulatory, budgetary, supervisory, judiciary, enforcement instruments and structures; underlines that such a transitional period, when the United Kingdom is no longer a Member State, can only be the continuation of the whole of the acquis communautaire which entails the full application of the four freedoms (free movement of citizens, capital, services and goods), and that this must take place without any limitation on the free movement of persons by imposing any new conditions; stresses that such a transitional period can only be envisaged 168

173 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues under the full jurisdiction of the Court of Justice of the European Union ( ECJ ); insists that such a transition period can only be agreed provided that a fully-fledged withdrawal agreement covering all the issues pertaining to the United Kingdom s withdrawal is concluded The UK position on a transition period The British government has been clear from the outset that some form of transition period would be desirable if not essential.57f129 The UK Prime Minister, Mrs May, in her Lancaster House speech in January 2017, under the rubric Smooth orderly Brexit, set out the objectives for the transition period. These were repeated verbatim in the subsequent UK White Paper on exit from and new partnership with the European Union published in February But there is one further objective we are setting. For as I have said before it is in no one s interests for there to be a cliff-edge for business or a threat to stability, as we change from our existing relationship to a new partnership with the EU. By this, I do not mean that we will seek some form of unlimited transitional status, in which we find ourselves stuck forever in some kind of permanent political purgatory. That would not be good for Britain, but nor do I believe it would be good for the EU. Instead, I want us to have reached an agreement about our future partnership by the time the 2-year Article 50 process has concluded. From that point onwards, we believe a phased process of implementation, in which both Britain and the EU institutions and member states prepare for the new arrangements that will exist between us will be in our mutual selfinterest. This will give businesses enough time to plan and prepare for those new arrangements. This might be about our immigration controls, customs systems or the way in which we cooperate on criminal justice matters. Or it might be about the future legal and regulatory framework for financial services. For each issue, the time we need to phase-in the new arrangements may differ. Some might be introduced very quickly, some might take longer. And the interim arrangements we rely upon are likely to be a matter of negotiation. But the purpose is clear: we will seek to avoid a disruptive cliff-edge, and we will do everything we can to phase in the new arrangements we require as Britain and the EU move towards our new partnership. In her Article 50 letter to European Council President Donald Tusk on 29 March 2017, the UK Prime Minister wrote: We should work together to minimise disruption and give as much certainty as possible. Investors, businesses and citizens in both the UK and across the remaining 27 member states - and those from third countries around the world - want to be able to plan. In order to avoid any cliff-edge as we move from our current relationship to our future partnership, people and businesses in both the UK and the EU would benefit from implementation periods to adjust in a smooth and orderly way to new arrangements. It would help both sides to minimise unnecessary disruption if we agree this principle early in the process. 129 The UK side has made reference to an implementation period. This assumes that agreement has been reached on the details of the future trade agreement and it is just a question of phasing in these arrangements. It reflects the early belief expressed by UK Government Ministers that it would be a simple matter to agree both the withdrawal arrangements and a future trade agreement and that all of this could be wrapped up within the twoyear period specified in Article 50. Events suggest that these expectations have proved over-optimistic, to put it mildly. 169

174 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies The UK view on an interim arrangement was further developed in the context of future customs arrangements in its position paper on future customs arrangements (HM Government 2017b). However, under either approach [to future customs arrangements], both the UK and EU Member States would benefit from time to fully implement the new customs arrangements, in order to avoid a cliff-edge for businesses and individuals on both sides. The Government believes a model of close association with the EU Customs Union for a time-limited interim period could achieve this. It would help both sides to minimise unnecessary disruption and provide certainty for businesses and individuals if this principle were agreed early in the process. The Government would need to explore the terms of such an interim arrangement with the EU across a number of dimensions. The UK would intend to pursue new trade negotiations with others once we leave the EU, though it would not bring into effect any new arrangements with third countries which were not consistent with the terms of the interim agreement. While the previous references to transition arrangements had simply made the case that such arrangements would be in the mutual interest of both parties, this was the first reference to the concrete form that a transitional arrangement might take. The UK Prime Minister was still hedging her bets (talking about an unspecified model of close association with the EU Customs Union rather than the more straightforward idea of a temporary customs union between the two parties). She also laid down a marker that the UK would intend to enter into negotiations with third countries on possible free trade agreements, although she recognised that these could not be implemented if they were not consistent with the terms of the interim agreement. That the customs paper put emphasis on maintaining a close association with the EU Customs Union but made no reference to regulatory coherence could simply reflect the fact that the paper was focused on customs arrangements. The UK Prime Minister went much further in outlining her views on a transition period in her Florence speech in September 2017: But the fact is that, at that point [i.e. 29 March 2019], neither the UK - nor the EU and its Members States - will be in a position to implement smoothly many of the detailed arrangements that will underpin this new relationship we seek. Neither is the European Union legally able to conclude an agreement with the UK as an external partner while it is itself still part of the European Union. And such an agreement on the future partnership will require the appropriate legal ratification, which would take time. It is also the case that people and businesses both in the UK and in the EU would benefit from a period to adjust to the new arrangements in a smooth and orderly way. As I said in my speech at Lancaster House a period of implementation would be in our mutual interest. That is why I am proposing that there should be such a period after the UK leaves the EU. Clearly people, businesses and public services should only have to plan for one set of changes in the relationship between the UK and the EU. 170

175 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues So during the implementation period access to one another s markets should continue on current terms and Britain also should continue to take part in existing security measures. And I know businesses, in particular, would welcome the certainty this would provide. The framework for this strictly time-limited period, which can be agreed under Article 50, would be the existing structure of EU rules and regulations. How long the period is should be determined simply by how long it will take to prepare and implement the new processes and new systems that will underpin that future partnership. For example, it will take time to put in place the new immigration system required to retake control of the UK s borders. So during the implementation period, people will continue to be able to come and live and work in the UK; but there will be a registration system an essential preparation for the new regime. As of today, these considerations point to an implementation period of around two years. But because I don t believe that either the EU or the British people will want the UK to stay longer in the existing structures than is necessary, we could also agree to bring forward aspects of that future framework such as new dispute resolution mechanisms more quickly if this can be done smoothly. It is clear that what would be most helpful to people and businesses on both sides, who want this process to be smooth and orderly, is for us to agree the detailed arrangements for this implementation period as early as possible. Although we recognise that the EU institutions will need to adopt a formal position. And at the heart of these arrangements, there should be a clear double lock: a guarantee that there will be a period of implementation giving businesses and people alike the certainty that they will be able to prepare for the change; and a guarantee that this implementation period will be time-limited, giving everyone the certainty that this will not go on for ever. These arrangements will create valuable certainty. This speech goes much further in spelling out how the transition/implementation period might work by proposing a time-limited implementation period based on current terms. For the first time the UK has indicated that the transition period should cover rules as well as the customs union. Nonetheless, there is evidence of different views within the UK Conservative Party on some of the details of this transition. In the run up to the Conservative Party conference in October 2017 the UK Foreign Secretary Boris Johnson gave an interview to The Sun newspaper in which he set out four red lines which expanded on the Florence speech.58f130 These were: The transition period post-brexit must be a maximum of 2 years and not a second more. UK must refuse to accept new EU or European Court of Justice (ECJ) rulings during transition. No payments for single market access when transition ends. UK must not agree to shadow EU rules to gain access to market. 130 Newton Dunn,, T., Brexy beast: Boris Johnson reveals his four Brexit red lines for Theresa May, The Sun, 29 September

176 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies On the one hand, the Foreign Secretary appeared to want a stricter time limit for the transition period where the Prime Minister had suggested a period of around two years but in any case based on the length of time needed to put new processes and systems in place. Where the Prime Minister had talked about new dispute settlement mechanisms, the Foreign Secretary was explicit that these should not require acceptance by the UK of CJEU rulings. Where the Prime Minister had talked about accepting EU rules and regulations during the transition, the Foreign Secretary was explicit that the UK should not be required to implement new EU rules and regulations during transition. Many will agree with his position given that the UK will not have any representation on EU decision-making bodies during this period. On the other hand, the Foreign Secretary was clear that the UK should not make payments for single market access when transition ends, leaving open whether he would support budgetary contributions for single market access during the transition. Further details on the UK view of the transition period were provided in the Prime Minister s statement to and in answers to questions in the House of Commons on the Brexit negotiations on 9 October F131 In response to a question to explain how the arrangements she was seeking for the transition differ from being a member of the single market and the Customs Union for the period of the transition the Prime Minister replied: I have to say to the right hon. Gentleman that, as we leave the European Union in March 2019, we will leave full membership of the customs union and full membership of the single market. What we then want is a period of time when practical changes can be made, as we move towards the end state the trade agreement that we will have agreed with the European Union. We have to negotiate for the implementation period what the arrangements would be. We have suggested that that should be a new agreement an agreement that we should be able to operate on the same basis and on the same rules and regulations. The Prime Minister did not make clear in what way a new agreement might differ from membership of the Customs Union and single market while permitting trade to continue on the same basis as when the UK was a member of the Customs Union and single market. In response to a further question to clarify the consistency between being out of the Customs Union and the single market while still trading on the same basis as firms do at the moment, the Prime Minister replied: As of 29 March 2019, we leave the European Union. That means we leave full membership of the customs union and full membership of the single market. during that [implementation] period what we are proposing is that it is in the interests of individuals and businesses on all sides to be able to continue to operate on the same basis as they do today. When asked specifically whether she agreed with the views of the European Parliament in its Brexit resolution of 3 October 2017 that a transition period can happen only on the basis of the existing EU regulatory, budgetary, supervisory, judiciary and enforcement instruments, her response was: That is the view of the European Parliament in its resolution. In my statement and my Florence speech, I put out that we expect that the implementation period will be based on the current rules and regulations, but of course this is part of the negotiation. 131 May, T., UK plans for leaving the EU, Statement to the UK House of Commons, 9 October

177 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues In responding to an invitation to confirm that the rulings of the CJEU would no longer apply in the UK after 29 March 2019, and that any new laws introduced by the EU27 after that date would have no effect until agreed specifically the UK Parliament, the Prime Minister clarified that We will have to negotiate what will operate during the implementation period. Yes, that may mean that we start off with the ECJ still governing the rules we are part of for that period, but we are also clear that we can bring forward discussions and agreements on issues such as a dispute resolution mechanism. If we can bring that forward at an earlier stage, we would wish to do so. This was the first time the UK indicated that it would be willing to accept a role for the CJEU during the transition. On the question regarding the status of legislation that might come into effect during the transition period, the Prime Minister distinguished between legislation which has already been introduced and new legislation that might be proposed during the transition period. With respect to legislative proposals which were brought forward before Brexit Day, she pointed out that the UK would be in a position to make clear in the withdrawal agreement whether that was a regulation it would be willing to sign up to or not. With respect to legislative proposals introduced after Brexit Day but during the transition period, her view was that the EU legislative process moves so slowly that, in practice, this would not be an issue. The UK Prime Minister s Florence speech and statement and replies to the House of Commons gives much more substance to how the UK envisages the transition period and the conditions it is prepared to accept during that period. The following four points can be highlighted as underlying the UK position: During the implementation period access to one another s markets should continue on current terms. The framework during this period would be the existing structure of EU rules and regulations. On the other hand, the Prime Minister is saying that the UK will leave full membership of the customs union and full membership of the single market. It is hard to see these positions as consistent. The customs union case might be reconciled as follows. By joining a temporary customs union with the EU27 for the transition period, the UK would continue to apply the Common Commercial Policy including the CET. But it would use its position as a non-eu Member State to open free trade negotiations with third countries, something it could not do while an EU Member State, while accepting that any agreements could not be implemented until the end of the transition period. The desire to retain the benefits of the single market while leaving the single market is, at face value, more difficult to reconcile. One interpretation might be that the UK would like to take back control immediately of those aspects of the Union acquis which are not essential to the operation of the single market, while being willing to observe the Union acquis which underpins the single market. However, the Florence speech puts down a marker that, while EU27 citizens will continue to be able to come and live and work in the UK, the UK would want to introduce a registration system. While the length of the transition period should be strictly time-limited, the Florence speech leaves open to further negotiations what this length might be. The length should be determined by how long it will take to prepare and implement the new processes and new systems that will underpin the future partnership and the suggestion is made that these considerations point to an implementation period of around two years. The speech also suggests that different aspects of the new arrangements might be phased in at different times, and that some aspects could be introduced earlier than others. New dispute mechanism procedures are specifically highlighted in this context. The UK has accepted that it would be under the jurisdiction of the CJEU during a transition arrangement, something which should facilitate an agreement which would bind the UK to implementing the relevant Union acquis during this period. 173

178 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies While the Florence speech states that the UK would be prepared to accept the EU s rules and regulations during the transition period, it makes no reference to a willingness to make budgetary contributions towards economic and social cohesion in the single market during this period (which would be separate to any financial settlement agreed as part of the withdrawal negotiations) Extending the date for Brexit beyond 29 March 2019 Although the UK government appears to have ruled this out, it is worth considering further the implications of this option given that it is by far the easiest and most obvious way of maintaining the existing trade relationship during the transition period. 60F132 It does this by avoiding the need for a transition period, because the UK would remain a full member of the EU, with the attendant rights and obligations of membership, until a future agreement was ready to be put in place. The UK would continue to accept the four freedoms, decisions of the CJEU would continue to have direct effect in the UK (while also protecting the rights of UK nationals and businesses in other parts of the EU), the UK would continue to have a say on proposed new regulations during this period, and the UK would continue to make budgetary contributions to the EU. In return, trade would continue exactly as it does today. This solution has the great merit that it would avoid Governments and businesses, both in the EU and the UK, having to change processes twice: once to reflect the terms of the transition and again to reflect the terms of the new relationship. It would also avoid the need for any border checks on the Northern Ireland border during the transition period. The first major obstacle to this solution is on the British side. The government would be open to the charge that it had not delivered Brexit. This criticism could be countered if a firm date for Brexit were agreed even if later than 29 March This could be achieved either by concluding a withdrawal agreement before 29 March 2019 which specified an alternative, later, date (which would have to be agreed by a qualified majority of the EU27 Member States and gain the consent of the European Parliament), or by unanimous agreement of the EU27 to extend the period for the withdrawal negotiations to a specific future date. It could be further guaranteed on the UK side by specifying a withdrawal date in the European Union (Withdrawal) Bill or through another Act of Parliament. The next UK general election is scheduled to be held on 5 May 2022 under the Fixed-term Parliaments Act 2011 (an election may be held at an earlier date in the event of an early election motion being passed by a super-majority of two-thirds in the House of Commons, a vote of no confidence in the government or other exceptional circumstances). Thus, the date for UK withdrawal from the EU could be extended by three years beyond 29 March 2019 while still ensuring that the next UK general election would be held when the UK was no longer an EU Member State. The UK Conservative Party would still be able to fight that election on the basis that it had delivered Brexit. From a British perspective, opposition to this solution is more likely to emerge from the internal politics of the UK Conservative Party where one wing seems determined on exit regardless of the economic consequences. Accepting that the UK would remain an EU Member State for, say, a further three years after 29 March 2019 would likely cause equal complications on the EU side. In May 2019 there will be elections to the European Parliament for a five-year period. If the UK were still a Member State it would be entitled to elect MEPs in those elections. The EU is about to embark on the negotiations for its next Multi-Annual Financial Framework (MFF). Indeed, the Commission proposal for the next MFF which was due to be presented before the end of 2017 has already been delayed to the first half of 2018 because of the uncertainty around the 132 See Winters, A., Holmes, P. and Szyszczak, E. Transition made easy, UK Trade Policy Observatory, 26 September

179 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues extent of future UK contributions to the EU budget. Agreeing the MFF is always contentious because there are net contributors to and net beneficiaries from the EU budget. Thus, agreement on both its size and composition involves decisions on the distribution of resources between Member States. The UK is the second largest net contributor to the UK budget so whether it is a Member State or not when the MFF negotiations take place will have a determining impact on the outcome. Nonetheless, a time-limited extension of UK membership would be manageable. The objections from the EU side are more likely to be political rather than practical Extending the EU acquis to a non-member The second option is that when the UK leaves the EU there is agreement to maintain current rules and regulations during a transition period. Some object to the suggestion that one can discuss a transition or implementation period without knowing the final destination. 61F133 This criticism may be valid with respect to the concept of an implementation period, which is premised on the idea that the terms of the future relationship will be fully negotiated by 29 March However, there is no ambiguity around the concept of a transition period which simply aims to maintain trade on the same basis as at present; the only issue is how to achieve this. The UK would no longer be an EU Member State but it would agree to be bound to apply the Union s rules to ensure the continuation of trade on current terms during this period. The EU has opened this option by saying that the Union acquis must apply to the UK during the transition period. The UK has accepted that EU rules and regulations should apply during this period, although with considerable ambiguity around how that would be achieved if the UK were at the same time to leave the single market and the Customs Union. From the perspective of agri-food trade, an extension of the EU acquis, which would also have to include the UK entering into a temporary customs union with the EU, would ensure the continuation of the trade status quo for the duration of the transition period. This solution would also avoid Governments and businesses, both in the EU and the UK, having to change processes twice: once to reflect the terms of the transition and again to reflect the terms of the new relationship. It would also avoid the need for any border checks on the Northern Ireland border during the transition period. There would need to be clarity around how to interpret the meaning of phrases such as a time-limited prolongation of Union acquis (European Council), the continuation of the whole of the acquis communautaire which entails the full application of the four freedoms (European Parliament) and continued access to one another s markets on current terms (UK Prime Minister). For example, does the position of the European Council and European Parliament imply that the UK must continue to operate its agricultural policy under the rules of the Common Agricultural Policy during the transition period? Would the UK have to continue to apply the rules of the Common Fisheries Policy? There are a wide number of Union policies, including energy, climate, science and research, and environment, which are not directly 133 In response to a question following her statement to the House of Commons reporting on the outcome of the European Council meeting October 2017, the Prime Minister stated: the point of the implementation period is to put in place the practical changes necessary to move to the future partnership, and in order to have that you need to know what that future partnership is going to be (Hansard, European Council, 23 October 2017). At face value, this seems to differ from the concept of a transition period put forward by the Prime Minister previously which is intended to maintain trade on current terms. Because it seems more appropriate to put more weight on the message in the considered statements that the Prime Minister has made, and because it is unlikely that the details of the future trade relationship can be agreed by summer of 2018, the transition period concept used in this chapter is that it is intended to maintain the status quo in trade as far as possible. 175

180 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies linked to trade.62f134 While the UK, under its European Union (Withdrawal) Bill, intends to replicate these policies into British law on Brexit Day, would the UK be able to make changes to regulations in these areas during the transition period? The European Parliament has already resolved that any future trade agreement should bind the UK to respecting international norms and standards in a range of non-trade policy areas such as environment, climate change, the fight against tax evasion and avoidance, fair competition, and trade and social rights. Presumably this requirement would also attach to a transition agreement. The UK might argue that, as a non-member State at that point, it should not be restricted in the policies it adopts which are not directly related to trade. At a minimum, it would be necessary to ensure that giving the UK policy autonomy in these areas does not risk that UK producers could be advantaged relative to EU27 producers within the single market during the transition period. As a hypothetical example, if the UK were free to determine its own agricultural policy during the transition period, it could opt to re-introduce a form of the deficiency payments support mechanism that it used prior to its accession to the EU. Deficiency payments are a form of counter-cyclical coupled payments and would not likely be constrained by any Bound Total Aggregate Measurement of Support ceiling that the UK may include in its schedule of WTO concessions. Coupled payments are permitted in the EU under the CAP although they are a voluntary option for Member States and are subject to conditions including a total expenditure ceiling. If UK farmers were able to receive more generous coupled payments during the transition period, EU farmers might view this as unfair competition. Norway is a member of the single market through its EEA membership, and provides support to its farmers at a much higher level than in the EU, but does not enjoy duty-free access for its agricultural exports to the EU. Any greater policy autonomy for the UK during the transition period may need to be accompanied by some agreement on state aid rules including agricultural support policies. However, this option begs the question how the UK can be both outside the EU, as it will be after 29 March 2019 according to the Prime Minister s Florence speech, and also adhere to the Union acquis?63f135 It would not be sufficient just to extend EU law to the UK after Brexit because, after that date, the UK will no longer be an EU member. To take an obvious point, if the UK leaves the EU on 29 March 2019, it will no longer be a member of the Customs Union. Article 28(1) TFEU reads: The Union shall comprise a customs union which shall cover all trade in goods and which shall involve the prohibition between Member States of customs duties on imports and exports and of all charges having equivalent effect, and the adoption of a common customs tariff in their relations with third countries. The UK, as a third country, would clearly not be a member of this EU Customs Union. To remain in a customs union with the EU would require a separate (even if temporary) customs union agreement. 64F136 Any transitional agreement would have to be a trade or association agreement between the UK and the EU27 because the UK, at that point, would be a third country. A mandate would have to be given to allow the Article 50 TEU negotiations to negotiate a transitional trade agreement under Article 207 or a transitional association agreement under Article 217 TFEU (the EEA agreement was negotiated as an association agreement under 134 The distinction is essentially between Union legislation which has relevance to the European Economic Area and legislation which does not, though it must be recognised that the line is not always easy to draw. 135 See Frantziou and Łazowski (2017) on the complications of the transition period although they do not seem to recognise that the UK would be a non-eu third country during this period. 136 See Holmes, P., Staying in the Customs Union: Neither Soft Nor Simple, Scottish Centre on European Relations, 11 July 2017 and Stojanovic, A., Five things to know about a customs union, Institute for Government, 5 July

181 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues Article 217 although it might be hard to justify this route in the case of a transitional agreement). Some legal scholars debate whether such a mandate would be legal until the UK had actually left the EU and become a third country. Negotiating a transitional trade agreement that effectively replicated the Union acquis would in itself be a mammoth task, it could hardly be just cut and paste. The UK and EU will need to design an agreement whereby all EU Regulations and Directives continued to apply in the UK with complete certainty. This includes all the mutual recognition of testing and certification elements of the Single Market and the free mobility of labour.65f137 There is also an international dimension. This option assumes that during the transition period the UK is no longer an EU Member State but would be part of a (temporary) customs union with the EU27. As a part of a customs agreement the UK would be required to adhere to the FTAs entered into by the EU with third countries. While the UK might be very happy to do this, it presumably would require individual negotiations with each FTA partner to revise the agreements to recognise the non-eu status of the UK after 29 March Even if Article 207/217 TFEU negotiations could be managed, the status of such an agreement under EU law is not certain. Because it might cover issues on which EU member states retain competence, national parliaments may have to be involved in ratification of the transition deal on the EU side.6f138 The Commission might provisionally apply those aspects that fell within its sole competence from Brexit Day, but the whole architecture of this construction has a very uncertain feel. For these reasons, there are doubts whether this option (a new transitional trade arrangement to come into effect immediately after March ) is indeed feasible. The UK and the EU27 would be negotiating both a highly complex international agreement and their future relationship at the same time. As Frantziou and Łazowski (2017) observe: A good transitional arrangement would have to resolve so many of the sticking points in the negotiations that it would be almost as difficult to achieve as a permanent arrangement. They conclude that, if most features of membership are maintained in that transition, it would make more sense to extend the two-year period laid down in Article 50 TEU to a more workable timeline for finding a durable solution EFTA/EEA membership as an interim arrangement One possible way in which the UK might be bound by the EU acquis during the transition period would be if it sought temporary membership of EFTA and the EEA. The main argument for this solution is that the EEA is an already existing trade agreement with non-eu countries and thus can provide the appropriate text. It would be similar to the Norway model discussed in Chapter 2, but with the proviso that it would be intended as a temporary solution for the transition period. However, there are formidable scoping, legal and practical problems to adopting this solution. Joining the EEA agreement would maintain tariff-free trade on non-agricultural goods between the UK and the EU27. It would allow continued time-limited membership of the EU single market. But significant adaptation would still be necessary. EEA membership does not involve a customs union with the EU. The EEA states are free to establish their own trade policies with third countries. Border checks are still necessary to check on origin and for tax purposes. Significantly, the EEA does not cover agri-food trade and EEA countries are free to 137 Winters, Holms and Szyszczak, op. cit. 138 Furthermore, any international agreement between the EU and the state which has withdrawn defining their future relationship would require ratification in the remaining Member States, unless the agreement were only to cover matters falling within the exclusive competence of the European Union (Carmona et al, 2017, p. 7). 177

182 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies adopt their own agricultural and fisheries policies. If the UK and the EU27 wished to maintain essentially the same trade relations in the transition period as now, it would be necessary to extend the EEA agreement by adding a temporary customs union as well as a bilateral agricultural agreement maintaining tariff-free trade. Objections to the EEA model as the long-term framework for UK-EU27 trade relations were outlined in the previous chapter. They include the fact that the UK would be required to implement EU rules and regulations over which it had no say, that it requires continued UK budgetary payments to cohesion countries for single market membership, and that it requires acceptance of the four freedoms, including freedom of movement of labour. When viewing the EEA model as a way forward for the transition period, these implications might be possibly acceptable to the UK. But there are other, legal as well as practical, difficulties in the way of this approach. One set of legal arguments revolves around the issue whether the UK would, in fact, remain a member of the EEA even though it had left the EU. The basis for this argument is that the UK (along with all other EU Member States) has separately ratified the EEA agreement. Thus, it would remain a member and remain within the single market unless it formally withdraws from the EEA using the mechanism laid down in Article 127 of the agreement. Litigation was brought in the UK courts to test that very point, but the application for judicial review was considered to be premature. 67F139 Critics of this argument point out that Article 126 of the EEA agreement limits the territorial application of the agreement to the EU and to the participating EFTA states. In short, once the UK leaves the EU and absent any other agreement any attempt to enforce the agreement would encounter significant legal objections in terms of its material and territorial scope.68f140 However, it is argued that it would still be open to the UK to join the EEA which, given Article 126 of the EEA Agreement, would also require it to seek admission first to EFTA. First, note the considerable practical difficulties in this scenario. It would involve the UK (a) seeking membership of EFTA (b) applying to accede to the EEA under the terms laid out in Article 128 of the EEA Agreement (which requires an agreement between the contracting parties and the state joining the agreement and for the agreement to be ratified by the contracting states in accordance with their own procedures). Moreover, to replicate current market access conditions, it would be necessary in addition for the UK (c) to negotiate additional bilateral agreements with the EU to create a temporary customs union as well as continued free trade in agricultural products, all to avoid additional trade costs during a transitional period which one side says would not last longer than two years. The various negotiations leading up to these agreements would all involve points of substance and disagreement which may not simply be resolved by cutting and pasting existing text, for examples, issues around the UK s budget contribution to the EEA Financial Mechanism, whether the UK would be allowed to invoke some of the EEA limits on freedom of movement, increasing the size of the EFTA Court to include a UK judge, etc. As a result, observers such as Jean-Claude Piris, former Director General of the Legal Service to the Council of the EU, have argued that the time this will take and the procedural obstacles to be overcome do not make the EFTA/EEA option a suitable vehicle for a transitional arrangement. 69F Monckton Chambers, Single market challenge: Adrian Yalland and Peter Wilding v SSEU (Article 127 EEA), 23 January Armstrong, K., Staying in the Single Market: Not so EEAsy?, Brexit Time, 8 September Piris, J.-C., Why the UK will not become an EEA member after Brexit, E!Sharp, September

183 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues This view would appear to be shared by the UK. In response to a question whether continuing membership of the single market might be worse than membership of the EU, the Secretary of State for Exiting the EU, David Davis, replied: 70F142 The simple truth is that membership of the European Free Trade Association, for example, which would be one way to retain EEA [European Economic Area] membership, would do exactly that: it would keep us within the acquis, and it would keep us within the requirements of free movement, albeit with some limitations, but none of those have worked so far. In many ways, it is the worst of all outcomes. We did consider it I gave it some considerable thought, maybe as an interim measure but it seemed to me to be more complicated, more difficult and less beneficial than other options (bolding added). Some legal scholars have tried to identify a possible legal pathway using the EFTA/EAA route which, even if convoluted, might be feasible. Armstrong has pointed out that there is nothing in principle to prevent the EFTA Council preparing a decision unanimously approving UK membership of EFTA that would come into force simultaneously with the UK s withdrawal from the EU. At the same time, the UK s accession to the EEA Agreement could be agreed by the EEA Council and signed by the contracting parties ready for formal ratification. Pending ratification, an exchange of letters could secure its provisional application without the hiatus that Piris anticipated.71f143 However, it may not be possible for the UK both to join EFTA (in order to accede to the EEA agreement), and to be in a customs union with the EU. 72F144 Article 56 of the EFTA Convention deals with accession and association. Under Article 56(3), there is an obligation on an acceding state to apply to become a party to the free trade agreements between the Member States on the one hand and third states, unions of states or international organisations on the other. This would mean that the UK would need to apply to join the 27 FTAs that EFTA countries currently have with 38 countries.73f145 But the UK could not apply to join these FTAs if it were at the same time in a customs union with the EU; a customs union with the EU would oblige it instead to be a party to the EU s FTAs with third countries. The conclusion is that, in principle, it is not possible for an EFTA state to also be in a customs union with the EU, unless the EFTA countries were prepared to waive this requirement for a temporary period to facilitate the UK transition out of the EU A temporary customs union as an interim arrangement As noted earlier, the UK proposed in its future customs arrangements partnership paper to assist in transition a new and time-limited customs union between the UK and the EU Customs Union, based on a shared external tariff and without customs processes and duties between the UK and the EU (HM Government 2017b). This temporary customs union would be limited in time, and could be one among a number of interim arrangements. If agreement on an extension of the full Union acquis seems neither feasible nor practical during the Article 50 negotiations, this is a possible fall-back position on which both sides could agree. The benefit of a temporary customs union is that it would avoid the requirement for rules of origin checks on goods traded between the two parties. From the UK s perspective, it might be a way to give it continued market access to the EU s FTA agreements 142 Davis, D., Membership of the European Economic Area, House of Commons Hansard, 7 September Armstrong, K., Staying in the Single Market: Not so EEAsy?, Brexit Time, 8 September Hughes, K., Scotland s EU Single Market Options: Some challenges from the trade side, Centre on Constitutional Change, 15 January EFTA, Global trade relations. 179

184 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies in the absence of grandfathering. From the EU s perspective, EU farmers would continue to benefit from the preferential trade transfer on exports to the UK market. However, a customs union on its own would not avoid the need for border controls. They would need to be re-introduced to implement phytosanitary checks, check tax compliance and enforce transport restrictions. A customs union would not cover trade in services. It would also prevent the UK from implementing its own trade agreements with third countries, although whether it would be able to negotiate these during the transition period would be a matter for the Article 50 negotiations. Whether such a temporary customs union would be inconsistent with WTO rules on customs unions and free trade areas (set out in GATT Article XXIV and its interpretative note and attached Understanding) has been debated. 74F146 Article XXIV makes provision for interim agreements leading to the formation of a customs union or a free trade area and specifies that approval of such interim agreements is dependent on including a plan and schedule for the formation of such customs union or free trade area within a reasonable length of time. The idea here is to cater for agreements which might initially only cover a portion of total trade between the partners, but which to be consistent with WTO rules should eventually cover substantially all trade. A temporary UK-EU customs union would not be an interim agreement in this sense, although it would be intended as a temporary arrangement. It would presumably cover 100% of trade from day 1 (the day after Brexit Day). The fact that the parties intended to replace it with a free trade agreement within a short period of time is irrelevant to its compatibility with WTO rules. One precedent is the customs union entered into by the Czech and Slovak Republics in 1993 following the breakup of Czechoslovakia. The EU made the customs union a condition for transferring Czechoslovakia s associated status with the EU to the successor states, and the customs union was dissolved when both countries acceded to the EU (and the EU Customs Union) in From the agricultural point of view, the main drawback of a temporary customs union is that it would not address regulatory barriers to trade arising from food safety, veterinary and plant health checks. Here the UK has proposed a separate agreement on regulatory equivalence on agri-food measures, where the UK and the EU agree to achieve the same outcome and high standards, with scope for flexibility in relation to the method for achieving this.providing the UK and the EU could reach a sufficiently deep agreement, this approach could ensure that there would be no requirement for any SPS or related checks for agri-food products at the border between Northern Ireland and Ireland. This proposal was put forward as a way of avoiding a hard border on the island of Ireland as part of the long-term relationship. It could equally well be brought forward and included as a part of a transition agreement. However, this solution would seem to be ruled out by the insistence by the European Council in its guidelines and by the European Parliament that the UK would be required to accept the entire Union acquis during the transition period. 75F147 Although an agreement on regulatory equivalence on agri-food measures would avoid the need for a high proportion of customs checks, there would continue to be a need for checks on other products, including sensitive products such as chemicals, electronic goods, toys and 146 This view was expressed in The Economist in its commentary on the customs position paper: Furthermore, the idea of a temporary tariff-free deal is unconvincing: once Britain leaves the EU, non-discrimination rules mean that the two can avoid bilateral tariffs only by scrapping them for all members of the World Trade Organisation. 147 Recall the European Council guidelines that preserving the integrity of the Single Market is an absolute priority. That excludes participation in any agreement with the UK on a sector-by-sector approach. 180

185 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues cosmetics. Therefore, in the context of avoiding a hard border on the island of Ireland, it has been argued that, as well as a customs union with the EU, it would be beneficial if the UK were to remain in the single market at least for goods alone. 76F148 This solution would avoid borders not only on the island of Ireland but for UK-EU27 trade generally, and would enable existing supply chain arrangements linking companies in both the UK and the EU27 to continue unaffected. While the UK might not be happy with this as a long-term solution (it would not give it access to the single market for capital and services), it might be more attractive in the transition period than a simple tariffs-only free trade agreement which would be the likely alternative. While the UK would remain under the jurisdiction of the CJEU as regards trade in goods and would likely be required to make a financial contribution towards economic and social cohesion in the single market, it would be in a position to control immigration and it would avoid the cliff-edge scenario of full border controls after 29 March 2019 which it is highly unlikely to be able to manage A free trade agreement as an interim arrangement The most minimal step to avoid a hard Brexit outcome after Brexit Day would be for the UK and the EU27 to agree to establish a tariffs-only FTA, with the proviso that the two sides would continue to discuss how to deepen and extend that FTA in the future to include elements of regulatory cooperation at a later stage. A bilateral FTA could avoid the reintroduction of MFN tariffs on UK-EU27 trade, but it would not avoid the need for extensive customs clearance and health checks and the introduction of rules of origin. While a bilateral FTA with 100% coverage of tariff lines might seem straightforward, given that the UK and the EU27 start from the position where there are no tariffs, no other EU FTA (apart from the Economic Partnership Agreements with developing countries) provides 100% tariff-free access to the EU market for the agricultural sector. Instead, preferences are provided for limited quantities of trade at reduced duties. The more that either party tried to fine-tune a bilateral FTA in this way, the longer the time it would take to negotiate and the greater the risk that it might not be in place on Brexit Day. However, a tariffs-only FTA could be agreed by the Council and Parliament alone, without the need for Member State ratification, because tariff policy is exclusively a Union competence Rescheduling the phasing of Article 50 negotiations Unless agreement to implement a transitional arrangement were reached (or agreement for the UK to remain an EU Member State until the final trade agreement were concluded as in the previous option) at the latest by early 2018 during the Article 50 TEU negotiations, traders would be forced to undertake contingency planning and to invest in new systems and personnel to cope with the increased possibility of a cliff-edge Brexit. The additional uncertainty arising from any further delay would impact negatively on trade flows, including the possibility of adverse exchange rate movements from the perspective of EU exporters. Traders will hesitate to enter into longer-term contracts with customers as long as there continues to be uncertainty about future trade conditions after 29 March The longer the time that it takes to start discussing and to reach agreement on the nature of any transitional period, the less valuable it will be to businesses on either side of the future UK-EU27 border. Uncertainty about the trade arrangements which might be in place following Brexit Day is already having a negative impact on the decision-making of businesses and firms that depend on the UK market, including food firms and farmers, not 148 This suggestion has been made by Kevin O Rourke, What if it was the Europeans picking the cherries?, The Irish Economy, 7 October

186 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies least because of the depreciation of sterling and subsequent exchange rate volatility. 7F149 Note, however, that even quickly reaching an agreement on transitional arrangements would not provide full legal certainty given the EU position that nothing is agreed until everything is agreed. So traders entering commitments in 2018 on the assumption that the terms of any transitional arrangement would apply after 29 March 2019 are making a bet on the successful conclusion of the entire set of negotiations. Under the European Council guidelines, discussions on the next set of negotiating directives cannot start until satisfactory progress has been made on the three issues - citizens rights, the financial settlement, and the Irish border - which make up the first phase of the negotiations. It had been hoped that the European Council meeting in October 2017 might be in a position to confirm that sufficient progress had been made and to issue a new negotiating mandate. The European Council noted that progress had been made on some of the issues in the first phase of the negotiations but concluded that, at this time, insufficient progress had been made in the first phase of the negotiations to move on to the second. Some argue that the current uncertainty works to the benefit of the EU27. The longer it takes for the outlines of a deal to become clear, the greater the uncertainty, and the more likely that UK firms will respond to the possibility of no deal or a bad deal by planning a redirection of investment or even a relocation. For some governments, the prospect of attracting financial firms currently headquartered in London may make this an acceptable risk. Others argue that, because the UK has in relative terms more to lose from a disorderly Brexit than does the EU27, the economic pressure created by the current phasing make it more likely that the UK will come forward with acceptable offers on the three preliminary issues, most notably the financial settlement. If indeed these motives influence the EU negotiating position, they are extremely short-sighted and have the potential to build up much more serious problems in the future. Even though the UK has decided to leave the EU, cooperation between the two parties will be essential in meeting many of the future challenges facing Europe, including security threats, terrorism, migration, climate change and financial stability. Poisoning this relationship in the longer-term by refusing to negotiate in good faith would make a very poor bargain. There are other arguments in favour of a more pro-active negotiating stance by the EU.78F150 The sequencing of the negotiations is not a legal obligation. Nothing in the text of Article 50 TEU forbids discussing the withdrawal arrangement and the future framework simultaneously. The sequencing is a tactical choice of the EU, which suggests it should be assessed on the basis of its benefits and costs. There are costs associated with maintaining the current phasing of the negotiations. In the first phase, the UK is being pressed to make commitments, but it is getting nothing in return. Negotiating the two phases in parallel would allow trade-offs and linkages between issues to be made which would make it easier for the parties to reach a compromise agreement, not least on the question of the Irish border. The European Council itself in its guidelines has said that nothing is agreed until everything is agreed, so it is not the case that the UK could pocket 149 Industry Groups Call for a Clear and Predictable Transitional Arrangement in the Brexit Process, press release from a group of industry associations representing global companies operating in both the UK and the EU27, 11 October It noted that they are increasingly challenged by the regulatory and operational complexities as well as the economic risk associated with Brexit. 150 These arguments were put forward in Delhouse, F., Why the sequencing of the Brexit negotiations should be abandoned, Egmont, 28 September

187 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues concessions made, for example, on the transition period without fully meeting the EU27 s expectations on citizens rights and the financial settlement. Newspaper reports suggest that the EU s negotiator, Michel Barnier, did ask the EU27 to give him a new mandate to discuss transition arrangements at the October summit. In the event, there was at least a blocking minority of countries that were opposed to this.79f151 However, the Council has agreed that internal preparatory discussions in relation to the framework for the future relationship and on transitional arrangements should be started. This is an important signal which should be fully exploited. This study makes the strong recommendation that the European Parliament should use its influence to encourage the Council with the Union negotiator to rapidly bring forward specific proposals for the transition with a view to clarifying what it believes would be the minimum requirements to ensure that trade can continue to take place with the UK as it does today in the single market for the duration of the transition period, and what it sees as the appropriate balance of rights and obligations during this period. Not all of the Union acquis is necessary in this regard. A critical issue here is whether UK membership of the CAP and the Common Fisheries Policy (CFP) will be deemed necessary as a prerequisite for continued free trade in agricultural and fishery products during the transition period. With respect to an obligation to respect CAP legislation, the EU s previous trade agreements are ambiguous. Norway and Switzerland do not respect CAP legislation and do not enjoy fully-liberalised trade in basic agricultural products with the EU. With Turkey and Ukraine there is some presumption that these countries will align their agricultural policies with the CAP and that this will facilitate if not be an actual prerequisite for fully liberal agricultural trade. However, Georgia has fully tariff-free agricultural trade with the EU despite having no intention of adopting the CAP legislation. Even though the FTA agreement with Canada did not fully liberalise agricultural trade, the reason for excluding certain tariff lines was due to the economic sensitivity of the sectors concerned and not because of a demand that Canada should align its agricultural policy with that of the CAP. On the basis of these precedents, an obligation to base its agricultural policy on CAP legislation would not appear to be a requirement either for a future trade arrangement with the UK or for a transition agreement. However, some agreement on state aid rules including agricultural support would be necessary. On the fisheries side, Sobrino Heredia (2017) note that acceptance of the CFP has not been a feature of the EU s FTAs but point out that fisheries governance would require a bilateral fisheries agreement to enable preferential access to waters and resources. Another issue which would require clarification, both in any future trade agreement and in the transition, would be the status of the legal protection for EU27 Geographical Indications (GIs) in the UK (and vice versa). The UK, under the European Union (Withdrawal) Bill, will implement the same legislative framework for GIs as the EU one, but there will still be a need to ensure mutual recognition of protected GIs in each other s jurisdiction. One way to achieve this would be if the UK were to join the Geneva Act of the Lisbon Agreement on Appellations of Origin and Geographical Indications (Matthews, 2015). The preparatory work should also clarify whether these minimum requirements are likely to include areas which fall within the competence of Member States, and thus whether a transition agreement would also have to be ratified by Member States as well as the Council and Parliament. These steps are in the interests of EU27 businesses and consumers as much as they are in the interest of the UK. 151 Brexit: stop the 'games' over the bill and get on with EU deal, says Denmark, The Guardian 8 October Brexit talks stutter, but EU leaders might give May break, Reuters, 9 October

188 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Ultimately, the terms of a withdrawal agreement under Article 50, including any provisions it might contain with respect to transitional trade arrangements, must be ratified by both sides. The EU procedure for ratification requires a qualified majority in the Council and the consent of the European Parliament. In the UK, the Government will bring forward a motion on the final agreement to be voted on by both Houses of Parliament before it is concluded. Any new treaty that the UK would agree with the EU would also be subject to the provisions of the Constitutional Reform and Governance Act 2010 before ratification. However, the European Union (Withdrawal) Bill provides the UK Government with a further limited power to implement the contents of any withdrawal agreement reached with the EU into UK domestic law without delay, where this is necessary to ensure that the UK is ready to begin the new arrangements from the date of exit (UK DExEU 2017). Some legal scholars argue that a further referendum would be required under UK law to approve the agreement if it provides that a EU body or institution can impose a requirement or obligation on the United Kingdom (Kouroutakis 2017). What would happen in the event of a failure to ratify by either side is uncertain, but it would certainly increase the chances that the UK would leave the EU without an agreement and thus a hard Brexit. 184

189 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues 4. Protecting agricultural interests following Brexit KEY FINDINGS The EU has gained considerable experience in recent years in the management of adverse shocks to agricultural markets which can be drawn upon in designing possible responses to a negative Brexit shock. They include the use of safety-net intervention; targeted aid; mobilisation of the crisis reserve; advancing direct payments; making use of the income stabilisation tool; permitting flexibility in state aids; and facilitating supply management. Farmers and food businesses in the EU27 will need support to adjust to the structural consequences of a hard Brexit. This might include the provision of adjustment assistance; greater use of financial instruments; a strengthened promotion policy; and improved access to third country markets. A specific market access concern is how UK TRQs will make provision for traditional EU27 export flows, and vice versa for EU27 TRQs. Merely splitting the EU TRQs does not go far enough to protect the interests of EU producers to access the UK market in the event of a hard Brexit. The focus in this chapter is on possible responses to the negative impacts of a hard Brexit for the EU27 agricultural sector. These negative impacts were described in Chapter 2. They include the re-introduction of tariffs on UK-EU27 agri-food trade, the loss of the preferential trade transfer on sales to the UK market, the additional costs including indirect costs of customs and regulatory checks at borders, the likelihood of immediate supply chain disruptions because the necessary systems will not be up and running, and the potential for a further sharp depreciation in the value of the UK currency. Responses to these negative impacts can take two forms. The first consists of attempts to avoid the worst costs of a hard Brexit by shaping the Article 50 negotiations themselves; this response was examined in Chapter 3. The second response examines the use that might be made of existing or new CAP instruments to help offset the adverse consequences for the EU27 farming sector that might follow from the outcome of the Article 50 TEU negotiations or from a failure to bring these to an agreed conclusion. This is the focus of this chapter. At the time of writing, there is no guarantee that the negotiating outcomes discussed in Chapter 3, which would allow agri-food trade to continue in the same way as now and would avoid the adverse consequences of a cliff-edge Brexit, will be agreed. There is still the possibility that the negotiations could fail to reach agreement, and that the UK would cease to be an EU Member State without any agreement a disorderly Brexit, with all of the disruption to trade that would imply. It is therefore also appropriate to examine the possibilities to use instruments under the CAP to cushion producers from these adverse impacts. As a general point, the relevant instruments to address an adverse shock would be expected to differ depending on the nature of the shock and whether it is expected to be temporary or represents a structural shift in external trading relations. In the case of a temporary shock (such as a drop in market prices due to specific market conditions), the primary focus will be on the safeguarding of producer incomes. For a structural shift, it is more important to emphasise instruments which help farmers to adjust to this change rather than to offset the impact of the change (which has the danger that it fossilises existing production and marketing structures rather than encouraging farmers, processers and traders to begin the necessary adjustments). A hard Brexit is likely to involve both elements. The reintroduction of additional trade costs, a further depreciation of sterling and reduced 185

190 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies attractiveness of the UK market (due to unilateral decisions by the UK to reduce applied tariffs or to enter into free trade agreements with third countries which strongly liberalise agricultural trade) represent a structural change in trading relations which will require adjustment by EU producers. The initial lack of preparedness will, in addition, cause temporary but potentially severe disruption to trade flows and hence producer incomes. Although the displacement of EU27 exports destined for the UK market in the event of a hard Brexit is likely to have a negative effect on prices within the EU27 common market as a whole, some Member States will be more exposed to disruption than others, particularly in the event of a further depreciation of sterling, because a higher share of their agricultural exports and agricultural output is currently sold on the UK market. The uneven distribution of the negative price impacts suggests that general market support instruments may need to be accompanied by more targeted measures in the immediate aftermath of a hard Brexit Support in the case of market disturbance The EU has gained considerable experience in recent years in the management of adverse shocks to agricultural markets, specifically in the context of the response to the Russian embargo on exports of certain EU foods to Russia and to the drop in milk prices in Use of safety-net intervention. The EU has the possibility to acquire stocks into intervention, or to pay firms for private storage, in order to withhold product from the market and to strengthen producer prices. This instrument is most effective when dealing with temporary or cyclical market disruptions when there is a reasonable expectation that market prices will recover within a short period of time. The difficulty with the use of intervention is that the build-up of intervention stocks can act to depress market sentiment and to delay the recovery in market prices, as arguably has been the case following the buildup in skim milk powder intervention stocks in the past few years. It also acts to delay adjustments in production where the shock is likely to be permanent (as would be the case of a hard Brexit) and where there is a need to facilitate and assist farmers to take advantage of alternative opportunities. Targeted aid. During the milk crisis the Commission made available national envelopes to Member States to support the dairy sector, having particular regard to those Member States which had been most affected by market developments. It later introduced a scheme of conditional adjustment aid to be defined and implemented at Member State level using a menu of measures proposed by the Commission (amounting to 350 million that Member States were allowed to match with national funds, thus potentially doubling the level of support being provided to farmers). The principles behind this arrangement targeting of funds to Member States most adversely affected, co-financing between the Union and Member States, and flexibility of Member States to choose from a menu of measures proposed by the Commission - would seem very suited to deal with post-brexit disruption. Mobilisation of the crisis reserve. One of the innovations in the 2013 CAP reform was the creation of a 400 million (in 2011 prices) crisis reserve, which is replenished annually by withholding a fixed percentage of direct payments to farmers in receipt of payments above a certain level. If the reserve is not used in any particular year, that money is added to the direct payments that the affected farmers receive in the following year. To date, it has not been necessary to make use of the crisis reserve because other sources of funding were available within the CAP budget to fund the crisis measures implemented in recent years. There is also reluctance among Agriculture Ministers to trigger payments from the reserve 186

191 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues because it effectively represents a redistribution of payments from one group of farmers to another. Nonetheless, the instrument exists and its use could be justified if there were clear evidence that some groups of farmers in the EU27 are more adversely affected by a hard Brexit than others. Advancing direct payments. The first instalment of direct payments is paid to farmers on 1 December in each year, although under existing rules Member States can pay up to 50% of their direct payments envelope to farmers from 16 October, provided that the necessary controls have been carried out. During the dairy crisis this percentage was increased to 70%. The payment date for area and animal-related payments for rural development (such as agrienvironment, organic farming, areas of natural constraints, animal welfare) can also be brought forward and during the milk crisis a higher percentage of the total payment was allowed to be made in the first payment. These measures can provide some relatively swift, but temporary, relief to farmers cash flow and could be considered again as a possible response to the negative short-term fall-out from a hard Brexit. Income stabilisation tool. Member States/regions already have the option to include an income stabilisation tool in their Rural Development Programmes. This risk management tool supports farmers facing a severe drop in income (minimum 30% loss compared to the three previous years). Only a few Member States have programmed this tool, but it could be introduced by others with the next modification of Rural Development Programmes. Agreement has been reached in the trilogues on the Omnibus Regulation to make the income stabilisation tool a more attractive option. More widespread adoption could provide an additional safety net for farmers in the event of a hard Brexit. Flexibility in state aid rules. Member States have the possibility of providing national funding under the de minimis rules (below for agricultural primary production or for marketing and processing activities over three years). For farm aid, there is a national cap that total de minimis aid cannot exceed 1% of annual output. These rules were relaxed during the milk crisis in two ways. Member States could give aids to farmers voluntarily freezing or reducing production (compared to a reference period) up to per farm per year (without national ceiling) in the form of a grant, loan or guarantee (for the dairy, pig meat and fruit and vegetable sectors). Member States could also introduce a state aid scheme for access to finance to bridge a liquidity gap in the form of loans or guarantees (for the dairy, pig meat and fruit and vegetable sectors). Temporary derogations could again be considered in the context of a hard Brexit, although it would be important to avoid that aids to farmers in one Member State would be at the expense of farmers in another. Both of the recent derogations were justified under Article 107(3) TFEU which permits aid to facilitate the development of certain economic activities or of certain economic areas, where such aid does not adversely affect trading conditions to an extent contrary to the common interest. Member States also have the possibility to provide national aids which meet the criteria set out in the Agricultural Block Exemption Regulation. These generally cover measures which are available within Rural Development Programmes (RDPs) and are cofinanced by the EAFRD (for example, aid for investments, for agri-environment-climate schemes, for organic farming, or for the participation in quality schemes) which can also be nationally financed. Under certain conditions, state aids can also cover promotion, the closure of production capacity and, under strict conditions, rescue and restructuring aid for companies in severe financial difficulties, etc. 187

192 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Supply management. In an early response to the Russian embargo which had a particularly adverse impact on perishable crops such as fruit and vegetables, the Commission provided support for the withdrawal of surplus volumes from the market with a view to providing shortterm relief. Depending on the market situation immediately after Brexit, the introduction of similar measures could be justified on a temporary basis Support for adjustment Provision of adjustment assistance. The EU created in 2007 the European Globalisation Adjustment Fund (EGF) as a flexibility instrument in the EU budget for interventions in case of mass redundancies caused by major changes in global trade. It aims to help dismissed workers find new jobs through a package of tailor-made services. Eligible actions include: tailor-made training; job-search assistance; entrepreneurship promotion; and measures addressing the needs of disadvantaged or older workers. The EGF cannot be used for passive social protection measures such as unemployment allowances or retirement pensions. Nor can it fund the restructuring of a company or a sector. From May 2009 to December 2011, the EGF was also able to support workers who had lost their jobs as a result of the financial and economic crisis. In proposing the continuation of the EGF for the period , the Commission proposed that, under specific conditions, Member States would be able to request funding for agricultural sectors, products or regions significantly affected by new trade agreements to help farmers adapt to a different market situation. The objective would be to assist them to become structurally more competitive or to facilitate their transition to non-agricultural activities. Up to five sixths of the proposed budget could be used to this end. This proposal was rejected by both the Council and the European Parliament. One major objection was the linkage of assistance to the conclusion of trade agreements which could have adverse effects for EU farmers. It was argued that the resources available were totally inadequate relative to the potential costs of trade liberalisation, and that it could act as a figleaf to encourage the Commission to negotiate trade agreements at the expense of the agricultural sector. There was also criticism from workers representatives that the high amount to be reserved for the agricultural sector would reduce the funds available for its original purpose.80f152 Whether the EGF is the right institutional framework or not, making available personalised advice, mentoring and coaching to farmers on their options in the event of a severe drop in market prices due to a loss of access to the UK market, as well as training in entrepreneurship and business creation, could be a useful addition to the policy toolkit to address the impact of a hard Brexit. Already, some farm advisory services provide services of this nature. It could be valuable to extend the remit of the Farm Advisory Service foreseen under the CAP Horizontal Regulation from its current focus on meeting crosscompliance and greening standards to also include socio-economic advice. Greater use of financial instruments. Adjustment measures on farms will require access to capital. Financial instruments aim to create incentives for economic operators to provide finance to final recipients such as farmers. They are intended to address an identified market gap, i.e. areas where banks are unwilling to lend and/or where the private sector is unwilling to invest, for instance in small farms or new agricultural businesses without sufficient credit history or assets as collateral. Their main attraction is that they can leverage additional private resources for investment projects when public funds are limited. The constraint on their use 152 Matthews, A. Farmers and the European Globalisation Adjustment Fund, October 25,

193 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues is that the money is expected to be repaid, so they are only suitable for financially viable projects, i.e. those which are expected to generate enough income or savings to pay back the support received. Financial instruments can take the form of loans, guarantees or equity, and may be managed by national or regional banks, international bodies such as the European Investment Bank or the European Investment Fund, by financial intermediaries, and (for loans and guarantees only) by RDP managing authorities. Loans supported by financial instruments can make finance available to farmers where none is offered commercially (e.g. from banks), or on better terms commercially (e.g. with lower interest rates, longer repayment periods, or with less collateral required). Following the disruption caused by a hard Brexit, there is likely to be an increased demand for this type of finance as farmers seek alternative opportunities and traders seek alternative markets. Additional flexibility in the state aid guidelines may be needed to ensure that financial instruments can be made fully operative for farmers Strengthened promotion policy Information and promotion schemes. Support is available under the CAP through a range of instruments towards the provision of information and promotional actions for agricultural products. Following a debate initiated by a Commission Green Paper in July 2011 and a Commission Communication in March 2012, a new Regulation (EU) No 1144/2014 was adopted and became applicable from 1 December F153 This legislation greatly enhanced the scope of the CAP s promotion policy by expanding the scope of measures, beneficiaries and eligible products that could be funded and by significantly increasing the aid for information and promotional activities from a budget of 61 million in 2013 to 111 million for 2016 and up to 200 million in Among the objectives of this legislation is to help restore normal market conditions in the event of serious market disturbance, loss of consumer confidence or other specific problems. Each year, the Commission defines the strategic priorities for promoting EU farm products and funding criteria in an annual work programme outlining the thematic priorities for support including products and possible markets. Proposals submitted for funding are examined by independent experts, following the award criteria defined in the annual work programme. Following a hard Brexit, there would be a case to target support for promotional activities outside the EU on those products and countries most adversely affected. This might be done by reviewing the thematic priorities for support or by revising the award criteria. Targeting on products is already a feature of the thematic priorities. For example, around nine topics were identified for support in the 2017 Work Programme of which two focused on products that were particularly affected by the Russian embargo (Table 4). The value of this scheme was underlined by the response to the specific priority for milk and pig meat products following the 2016 call, where the budget requested was four times higher than the indicated budget in the annual work programme. The award criteria stated for the 2017 Work Programme covered four elements unequally weighted: Union dimension, technical quality, management quality, and budget and costeffectiveness. It could be decided to add criteria in future Programmes which in some way take account of the vulnerability of different Member States to the adverse impacts of a hard Brexit. 153 More information is provided in the European Parliamentary Research Service Briefing EU agricultural promotion measures, June

194 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Table 15: NO. Topics and actions for support in the 2017 Work Programme for information and promotion measures for agricultural products TOPIC 1 Information provision and promotion programmes aiming at increasing the awareness and recognition of certain Union quality schemes 2 Information provision and promotion programmes aiming at highlighting the specific features of agricultural methods in the Union and the characteristics of European agricultural and food products, and other quality schemes 3 Information provision and promotion programmes targeting one or more of the following countries: China (including Hong-Kong and Macao), Japan, South Korea, Taiwan, south-east Asian region or India 4 Information provision and promotion programmes targeting one or more of the following countries: USA, Canada or Mexico 5 Information provision and promotion programmes targeting one or more of the following countries: USA, Canada or Mexico 6 Information provision and promotion programmes targeting geographical areas other than those included under Topics 3, 4 and 5. 7 Information provision and promotion programmes on milk products, pigmeat products or a combination of those two targeting any third country 8 Information provision and promotion programmes on beef products targeting any third country. A Programmes increasing the awareness of Union sustainable agriculture and the role of the agri-food sector for climate action and the environment Source: Commission Implementing Decision of on the adoption of the work programme for 2017 of information provision and promotion measures concerning agricultural products implemented in the internal market and in third countries, C(2016) Export market credit guarantees. Promoting EU products in overseas markets can help to create a demand, but taking advantage of new outlets and entering new markets takes time and causes great uncertainty and risks. Strengthening promotion policy under the CAP only provides a partial solution to this problem, as it does not cover commercial risks. Often, the private banking sector does not provide coverage of this kind of risk either. Certain Member States have set up export credit insurance systems to support agri-food businesses, but there are no export credit, export credit guarantee or insurance programmes operated at the EU level. An Export Credit Group under the Council reviews the export credit support schemes of Member States to ensure that under the EU's common commercial policy, Member States do not undercut each other internationally and create unfair competition. The Commission, together with the European Investment Bank, have been examining the possible benefit and feasibility of setting-up an export credit guarantee facility at the EIB for agricultural exports to new or risky markets. Commissioner Hogan made reference to the conclusions of their study when reporting to the June 2016 AGRIFISH Council meeting. 82F154 It concluded that an export credit guarantee tool does not offer short term relief to supply in crisis situations. It could possibly support the internationalisation of the EU agri-food sector for those companies and export destinations for which access to trade finance is difficult. However, Member States have been slow in providing a clear economic case to introduce such 154 Hogan, P., Speaking note to AGRIFISH Council (June 27, 2016) in Luxembourg, 27 June

195 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues a tool for agriculture at the EU level. At a meeting of the Special Committee for Agriculture on 20 June 2016, Member States were asked to reply to two questions, on the value added of an EU credit guarantee scheme, and on its operational management. 83F155 To date, it does not appear that the Committee has returned to address this issue. One way to advance this file could be to establish European guidelines on the use of export credits to encourage Member States to provide this kind of tool. Promotion on the internal market. While promoting the export of EU products outside the EU is an obvious response to the loss of access to the UK market in the event of a hard Brexit, the potential to stimulate domestic consumption should not be overlooked. This could be particularly useful in the case of fruit and vegetables where average intake in the EU appears to be below recommended nutritional levels. There may be scope under the School Scheme for Milk, Fruit and Vegetables to increase the offtake of these products under this Scheme Improved access to third country markets Some may draw the conclusion from the experience of the Russian embargo and a hard Brexit, if it occurs, that relying on third country markets is too risky and that the appropriate policy response should be to reduce the dependence of EU producers on third country markets and to concentrate on domestic, or even local, markets. Reducing exports to third country markets would be very counter-productive and would further impoverish the farming community. As it is, the vast majority of farm and food products supplied on the EU market (mostly from domestic production but also from imports) are consumed within the EU. Only 4.2% of agricultural products were exported outside of the EU in 2011, and only 6.9% of food, beverages and tobacco products. 84F156 These are either high value products which are sold at premium prices (e.g. products with a quality mark) or lower-valued products for which there is limited consumer demand within the EU and where overseas markets yield a higher return (e.g. certain poultry parts). If farmers were unable or discouraged from producing these products, and instead had to substitute alternative products which could only be sold on the EU market, the net impact would be lower returns to their labour, capital and land inputs. Indeed, the only way to entirely remove the risk of depending on others is to return to self-sufficient households. Even if this were deemed a practical option, that approach magnifies the risks of depending on own production. Instead, the way to address risk on third country markets is to strengthen the rules governing international trade and to diversify markets to reduce the risks of over-dependence on any one buyer. Free trade agreements. The EU is a strong supporter of the multilateral rules-based system under the governance of WTO rules. The rules governing agricultural trade were strengthened in the WTO Agreement on Agriculture signed at the conclusion of the Uruguay Round of trade negotiations in Although another round of negotiations to further liberalise agricultural trade, inter alia, was launched in Doha in 2001, these negotiations are bogged down and are not likely to result in an agreement to further liberalise market access in the near future. Instead, the EU has sought to open additional market access through bilateral free trade agreements with countries willing to go further in liberalising trade. Notable FTAs recently concluded include those with Korea, Vietnam, Singapore and Canada, while FTAs are under negotiation with the US, Mercosur, Japan and India and are scheduled to start with Australia and New Zealand. Trade agreements only open up market opportunities, these must 155 Summary Record of the 1530th meeting of the Special Committee on Agriculture (SCA) held in Brussels on 20th June Calculated from Eurostat, Input-output tables at current prices, 60 branches, EU aggregates, domain [naio_17_agg_60_r2]. 191

196 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies then be realised by the relevant business actors. Assistance can be provided, and Commissioner Hogan has scheduled a number of promotion visits to third countries where important opportunities exist for EU agriculture and to help open doors for new exports. In many markets, the major barrier to access is not the level of tariffs imposed but non-tariff barriers and, in the case of agricultural and food products, particularly SPS measures. The Commission (DG SANTE, DG AGRI, DG TRADE) has been working for some time to resolve a number of SPS issues with third country partners, with some success. More focus could be brought to this work by drawing up an annual priority list of the trade barriers that the EU hopes to remove. While these efforts should continue, the negotiation of trade agreements and the removal of SPS barriers are lengthy and arduous processes and so these are not a relevant response to the immediate problems likely to be caused by a hard Brexit TRQs for UK-EU27 trade It was argued in Chapter 2 that splitting the EU TRQs between the UK and the EU27 would mean that the UK TRQs would make no specific provision for existing UK-EU27 trade, and vice versa. While this might not have any practical implications if the UK and the EU27 create a bilateral free trade agreement covering agricultural products on Brexit Day, this omission has significant implications for EU producers if tariff barriers are erected. In the case of beef TRQs, for example, virtually all EU TRQ amounts are allocated to specific countries with the small exception of a 1,500t TRQ for frozen edible offal of which 700t is allocated to Argentina and the remaining 800t is available to other countries. There is a pigmeat TRQ of 10,159t with a reduced rate of duty of which 4,624t are allocated to Canada but the EU27 could compete with other countries for the remaining erga omnes quota of 5,535t. Other pigmeat TRQs remain open to any exporter. In the case of the major sheepmeat TRQ of 283,715t, almost all of this is allocated to specific countries (with New Zealand being the largest beneficiary with a quota of 227,854t), leaving only an MFN quota of 200t for which all EU27 exporters would have to compete after a hard Brexit. New Zealand also has a butter TRQ of 74,693t with a very favourable in-quota tariff, while the EU27 would have to compete for the MFN quota of 11,360t with a higher in-quota tariff in the event of a hard Brexit. Two Cheddar cheese quotas allocate 14,711t TRQs to Australia, New Zealand and Canada while the EU27 would have to compete with all other countries for a share of the MFN TRQ of 15,005t. Various EU27 countries have been traditional exporters to the UK market for decades if not longer. When schedules of concessions were being drawn up at the formation of the WTO in 1994, there was no need to create current access TRQs for these exports because, at that time, they had completely unrestricted access to the UK market under EU rules. It would seem odd that the UK would now seek to introduce TRQs in its own schedule of concessions at the WTO to maintain the market access of what were previously third countries, but not to provide TRQs to maintain the access of existing exporters that happen to be now EU27 members. Of course, the UK could make the same argument for EU TRQs for its current exports but, given the balance of agricultural trade between the two parties, an exchange of TRQ concessions of this kind should be welcomed by EU producers. 192

197 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues Is there a case for pursuing such an exchange of TRQ concessions? This is a matter for legal scholars to determine, and the answer may not be straightforward (Downes, 2017 reviews some of the arguments). In principle, the established practice under GATT Article XIII, which deals with quantitative restrictions, is to extrapolate quota shares from a representative period (typically three years) of import data. The relevant requirement in Article XIII(2) is to ensure, in applying import restrictions to any product, that WTO Members shall aim at a distribution of trade in such product approaching as closely as possible the shares which the various contracting parties might be expected to obtain in the absence of such restrictions. As Downes explains, basing new TRQs on existing levels of trade might not be deemed to comply with this requirement given that exports from non-eu exporters were restricted by TRQs while EU suppliers had preferential access. Representing countries with substantial supplying interests within the meaning of Article XIII, the EU27 has the right to make its claims heard when the UK is determining the size and allocation of its agricultural TRQs. Of course, this right cannot be enforced at the expense of the holders of existing TRQ quotas. It would be up to the UK, in consultation with other WTO Members, to reconcile the EU demands as substantial suppliers with those of other third countries (Downes, 2017). The political acceptability to other WTO Members of allowing EU27 access to the UK would probably be dependent on any TRQ access offer by the EU27. While the balance of advantages to the EU27 would need to be further explored, the current bilateral negotiations in Geneva to merely split the EU TRQs do not go far enough to protect the interests of EU producers to access the UK market in the event of a hard Brexit. 193

198 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies 194

199 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues REFERENCES BRC, A Fair Brexit for Consumers: The Customs Roadmap, London: British Retail Consortium. Council of the European Union Directives for the Negotiation of an Agreement with the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland Setting out the Arrangements for Its Withdrawal from the European Union, Annex to the Council Decision Authorising the Opening of Negotiations with the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland for an Agreement Setting out the Arrangements for Its Withdrawal from the European Union, Brussels. DG AGRI Annual Activity Report Brussels: European Commission. DG TRADE Trade, Growth and World Affairs. Trade Policy as a Core Component of the EU s 2020 Strategy. COM(2010)612. Brussels: European Commission EU-Ukraine Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Area. Brussels: European Commission. Downes, C The Post-Brexit Management of EU Agricultural Tariff Rate Quotas, Duff, A After Brexit: Learning to Be Good Neighbours. Commentary 18 November Brussels: European Policy Centre. Emerson, M Stocktaking after Theresa May s Brexit Speech in Florence: Key Point the Transition, Key Omission the Future Relationship. CEPS Policy Insights No Brussels: Centre for European Policy Studies. Emerson, M., and V. Movchan Deepening EU-Ukrainian Relations: What, Why and How? London: Rowman & Littlefield International, Ltd. European Parliament Resolution of 5 April 2017 on Negotiations with the United Kingdom Following Its Notification That It Intends to Withdraw from the European Union. (2017/2593(RSP)). Brussels. Frantziou, E., and A. Łazowski Brexit Transitional Period: The Solution Is Article 50. Brussels: Centre for European Policy Studies. Grainger, A The Role of Border Management in Implementing Trade Policy Goals. In Workshop - Facilitating External Trade via Border Management, by A. Grainger and J. Hintsa. Brussels: European Parliament Policy Department, Directorate- General for External Policies. HM Department of International Trade Preparing for Our Future UK Trade Policy. London: Her Majesty s Stationery Office. HM Government. 2017a. Customs Bill: Legislating for the UK s Future Customs, VAT and Excise Regimes. Cm London: Her Majesty s Stationery Office b. Future Customs Arrangements: A Future Partnership Paper. London c. Northern Ireland and Ireland: Position Paper. London d. The United Kingdom s Exit from and New Partnership with the European Union White Paper. Cm London: Her Majesty s Stationery Office. HM Treasury Customs Bill: Legislating for the UK s Future Customs, VAT and Excise Regimes. Cm London: Her Majesty s Stationery Office. House of Commons International Trade Committee UK Trade Options beyond First Report of Session London: House of Commons. IFA Brexit: The Imperatives for Irish Farmers & the Agri-Food Sector. Dublin: Irish Farmers Association. 195

200 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies Kouroutakis, A Legal Uncertainty Surrounding the Approval of the Brexit Agreement. I-CONect, Blog of the International Journal of Constitutional Law and ConstitutionMaking.Org. June Matthews, A What outcome to expect on Geographical Indications in the TTIP free trade agreement negotiations with the United States?, Paper prepared for the 145th EAAE Seminar Intellectual Property Rights for Geographical Indications: What is at Stake in the TTIP? April 14-15, 2015, Parma, Italy. Matthews, A., L. Salvatici, and M. Scoppola Trade Impacts of the Common Agricultural Policy. IATRC Commissioned Paper 19. Minneapolis: International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium. May, T. 2017a. The Government s Negotiating Objectives for Exiting the EU. Lancaster House, London, January b. Prime Minister s Letter to Donald Tusk Triggering Article 50, March c. Florence Speech: A New Era of Cooperation and Partnership between the UK and the EU. Florence, September Meaney, A Brexit: The Implications for Ports. National Audit Office The Customs Declaration Service. Report by the Comptroller and Auditor General. London: National Audit Office. Owen, J., M. Shepheard, and A. Stojanovic Implementing Brexit: Customs. London: Institute for Government. Sobrino Heredia, J M, 2017, Research for PECH Committee Common Fisheries Policy and BREXIT - Legal framework for governance, European Parliament, Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies, Brussels. UK DExEU Legislating for the United Kingdom s Withdrawal from the European Union. London: Department for Exiting the European Union. World Bank Evaluation of the EU-Turkey Customs Union. Report No TR. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. WTO Road Freight Transport Services: Background Note by the Secretariat. S/C/W/324. Geneva: World Trade Organisation. 196

201 Transitional arrangements related to agriculture in light of the future EU - UK relationship: institutional issues ANNEX 1. EXAMPLES OF CUSTOMS CLEARANCE COSTS Many of the published examples of customs clearance costs refer to clearing sea containers at ports. This is the normal way for food products to arrive from non-eu countries into the EU. Food transport between the UK and the EU27 is more likely to take the form of roll on roll off (RoRo) traffic, and the figures quoted below should be taken as illustrative of the costs that might be incurred. Customs clearance and inspection costs as well as health checks are normally on a per consignment basis and thus do not vary according to the value of the consignment. They have the same effect as a specific tariff in that they bear more heavily on low-value produce than on high-value produce. This should be borne in mind when comparing cost estimates expressed as a percentage of the value of trade. The UK House of Lords Select Committee on the European Union collected evidence on the costs of administering tariff and non-tariff barriers.85f157 The Agricultural and Horticultural Development Board estimated that the transactional costs for customs and health checks between the UK and the EU27 would be in the region of 8% to 10%, and perhaps a bit more than that. The Food and Drink Federation estimated these costs at a further eight per cent, and added that the increase in transactional costs for composite products was likely to be higher. Evidence from an Irish firm of chartered accountants specialising in customs issues was that the cost for customs clearance, either in the payment of a clearance agent or the recruitment of staff in addition to logistics related costs, would be 100 per movement. 86F158 Article 13d of the Plant Health Directive requires Member States to charge for the import inspections required by the Directive. As an example, in the UK three separate fees are paid for each consignment. A document check fee (to cover the cost of checking the consignment s paperwork) amounts to 5.71 ( 6.37). An identity check fee to cover the cost of the inspectors checking the assignment, also amounts to 5.71 ( 6.37) for small consignments (the size of a truck or railway wagon) or ( 12.74) if bigger. A physical inspection fee must also be paid which depends on the type of plant material being imported. Where risk targeted checks have been set for trade in a particular commodity from a particular country, on the basis of the compliance record of that trade, a reduced fee is charged. If the consignment arrives outside normal working hours, a higher fee can be charged. 87F159 As another example, Keurpunkt is an approved inspection site for imported fruits and vegetables at the Port of Antwerp. On its website, it offers administrative and document assistance at a cost of 35/container, physical inspection of potatoes, fruits and vegetables at a cost of 37.50/container plus additional contract costs, and phytosanitary inspection of wood packaging material at 65/container.8F160 Grainger (2017) quotes costs in the range of a few pounds to 25 ( 28) to 50 ( 56) for declaring a sea container; costs can be significantly greater, if further compliance related services are needed. Other direct costs can include inspection fees, demurrage, storage charges, handling charges, laboratory fees, amongst others. He quotes from a previous study 157 House of Lords Select Committee on the European Union, Chapter 6: Costs of administering tariff and non-tariff barriers, Brexit: Trade in Goods, HL Paper 129, London. 158 Lynch, C. Partner in BDO Customs and Trade Practice, Evidence to the Oireacthas Joint Committee on Finance, Public Expenditure and Reform, and Taoiseach inquiry into Brexit: Matters relating to Customs, Trade and Tariffs, 25 May Details of the current UK rules for importing plants and plant products from outside the EU are given on the DEFRA web site

202 Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies he authored which examined the direct compliance costs incurred by businesses when importing meat from non-eu countries into the UK. The costs of mandatory port health controls ranged between 382 ( 450) and 673 ( 793) per container. He notes there are also indirect costs of customs clearance. These tend to be less tangible, but may be much more significant than the direct costs. They include missed business opportunities and failure to take advantage of international trade opportunities, loss of business competitiveness, failure to meet contractual obligations because of delays at ports and borders, and safeguard measures such as by holding additional stock in warehouses and factories to help buffer against unforeseen delays at ports and borders. There will also be cash flow implications arising from changes in VAT legislation. At present, EU importers moving products into the EU from the UK are exempt from having to make upfront payments of import VAT on their goods. This does not apply to goods outside the EU customs area. EU importers must pay import VAT upfront, for example, on goods coming from Turkey, even though it has a customs union relationship with the EU. Although these payments are eventually recoverable, the introduction of import VAT on all goods being imported from the UK could represent a major cash flow burden for importers (BRC, 2017). Importers of EU products into the UK would face a similar burden assuming the UK continues to apply EU rules after Brexit. 198

203

204

Research for AGRI Committee - Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding

Research for AGRI Committee - Possible impact of Brexit on the EU budget and, in particular, CAP funding DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES Policy Department for Structural and Cohesion Policies AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT Workshop on Implications of Brexit for the EU agri-food sector and the

More information

Annual revision of national contributions to the EU budget

Annual revision of national contributions to the EU budget Annual revision of national contributions to the EU budget SUMMARY Briefing November 2014 The annual adjustment of the financing of the EU budget is now in the spotlight. In 2013, around three quarters

More information

With regard to the expenditure side, the following modifications are proposed:

With regard to the expenditure side, the following modifications are proposed: Council of the European Union Brussels, 8 November 2016 (OR. en) 13583/16 BUDGET 29 EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM Subject: Draft amending budget No 4 to the general budget for 2016: Update of appropriations to

More information

DECISIONS. COUNCIL DECISION of 26 May 2014 on the system of own resources of the European Union. (2014/335/EU, Euratom)

DECISIONS. COUNCIL DECISION of 26 May 2014 on the system of own resources of the European Union. (2014/335/EU, Euratom) 7.6.2014 L 168/105 DECISIONS COUNCIL DECISION of 26 May 2014 on the system of own resources of the European Union (2014/335/EU, Euratom) THE COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, Having regard to the Treaty on

More information

A. INTRODUCTION AND FINANCING OF THE GENERAL BUDGET. EXPENDITURE Description Budget Budget Change (%)

A. INTRODUCTION AND FINANCING OF THE GENERAL BUDGET. EXPENDITURE Description Budget Budget Change (%) DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET NO. 2/2018 VOLUME 1 - TOTAL REVENUE A. INTRODUCTION AND FINANCING OF THE GENERAL BUDGET FINANCING OF THE GENERAL BUDGET Appropriations to be covered during the financial year 2018

More information

How the EU Budget has developed and changed in the last 10 years?

How the EU Budget has developed and changed in the last 10 years? IN-DEPTH ANALYSIS for the BUDG committee How the EU Budget has developed and changed in the last 10 years? Budgetary Affairs Policy Department D for Budgetary Affairs Author: Dr Giacomo Benedetto, Jean

More information

Q&A: The EU's high-level group on own resources

Q&A: The EU's high-level group on own resources EUROPEAN COMMISSION MEMO Strasbourg, 25 February 2014 Q&A: The EU's high-level group on own resources The high-level group on own resources has been formally established today by the Presidents of the

More information

ALDE POSITION PAPER ON EU BUDGET POST 2013

ALDE POSITION PAPER ON EU BUDGET POST 2013 ALDE POSITION PAPER ON EU BUDGET POST 2013 1. Background Since 1988, annual EU budgets are based on a Multiannual financial framework (henceforth MFF) agreed between the European Parliament, Council and

More information

12608/14 IS/sh 1 DG G II A

12608/14 IS/sh 1 DG G II A Council of the European Union Brussels, 2 September 2014 (OR. en) 12608/14 BUDGET 16 EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM Subject: Draft budget of the European Union for the financial year 2015: Council position of

More information

The next Multiannual Financial Framework (MFF) and its Flexibility

The next Multiannual Financial Framework (MFF) and its Flexibility IN-DEPTH ANALYSIS requested by the BUDG committee The next Multiannual Financial Framework (MFF) and its Flexibility Budgetary Affairs Policy Department for Budgetary Affairs Directorate General for Internal

More information

DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET N 6 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2014 GENERAL STATEMENT OF REVENUE

DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET N 6 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2014 GENERAL STATEMENT OF REVENUE EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 17.10.2014 COM(2014) 649 final DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET N 6 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2014 GENERAL STATEMENT OF REVENUE STATEMENT OF EXPENDITURE BY SECTION Section III Commission

More information

MID-TERM REVISION OF MFF : BACKGROUND NOTE. Duration of the next MFF

MID-TERM REVISION OF MFF : BACKGROUND NOTE. Duration of the next MFF Briefing MID-TERM REVISION OF MFF 2014-2020: BACKGROUND NOTE The note provides an overview on the options for the duration of the multiannual financial framework (MFF) period after 2020: history, background,

More information

DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET No 5 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2017

DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET No 5 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2017 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 28.7.2017 COM(2017) 485 final DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET No 5 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2017 Providing the financing for the European Fund for Sustainable Development (EFSD) and increasing

More information

DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET No 6 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2018

DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET No 6 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2018 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 12.10.2018 COM(2018) 704 final DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET No 6 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2018 Reduction of payment and commitment appropriations in line with updated forecasts of expenditure

More information

B The EU financial settlement

B The EU financial settlement B The EU financial settlement Introduction B.1 The effects of Brexit on the public finances are likely to be dominated by the indirect effects of changes in trade, migration and other policy regimes on

More information

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 30.1.2019 COM(2019) 64 final 2019/0031 (APP) Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION on measures concerning the implementation and financing of the general budget of the Union in

More information

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 7.12.2018 COM(2018) 817 final 2018/0414 (COD) Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL amending Regulations (EU) No 1305/2013 and (EU) No 1307/2013

More information

13060/17 ADD 1 1 DPG

13060/17 ADD 1 1 DPG Council of the European Union Brussels, 20 October 2017 (OR. en) 13060/17 ADD 1 PV/CONS 52 ECOFIN 806 DRAFT MINUTES Subject: 3563rd meeting of the Council of the European Union (Economic and Financial

More information

6315/18 ML/ab 1 DG G 2A

6315/18 ML/ab 1 DG G 2A Council of the European Union Brussels, 20 February 2018 (OR. en) 6315/18 FIN 139 INST 65 OUTCOME OF PROCEEDINGS From: General Secretariat of the Council To: Delegations No. prev. doc.: 5939/18 FIN 90

More information

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 5.10.2017 COM(2017) 565 final 2017/0247 (COD) Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL amending Regulation (EU) No 1303/2013 as regards the

More information

MFF : BACKGROUND NOTE IN VIEW OF MID-TERM REVIEW/REVISION Specific flexibility - Frontloading of some key programmes

MFF : BACKGROUND NOTE IN VIEW OF MID-TERM REVIEW/REVISION Specific flexibility - Frontloading of some key programmes Briefing MFF 2014-2020: BACKGROUND NOTE IN VIEW OF MID-TERM REVIEW/REVISION Specific flexibility - Frontloading of some key programmes The briefing provides preliminary information of the use of frontloading

More information

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 30.1.2019 COM(2019) 65 final 2019/0030 (COD) Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL laying down provisions for the continuation of ongoing

More information

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 19.12.2018 COM(2018) 892 final 2018/0432 (COD) Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL in order to allow for the continuation of the territorial

More information

Analysing the EU exit charge

Analysing the EU exit charge AN ICAEW BRIEF Analysing the EU exit charge Foreword The financial relationship between the UK and the EU can be difficult to understand. We hope that this ICAEW brief will help make sense of how things

More information

"Discussion circle" on budgetary procedure

Discussion circle on budgetary procedure THE EUROPEAN CONVTION Brussels, 24 March 2003 THE SECRETARIAT CERCLE II Working document 05 "Discussion circle" on budgetary procedure Subject : Proposal of M. David O'Sullivan, alternate member of the

More information

DRAFT REPORT. EN United in diversity EN. European Parliament 2017/2053(INI)

DRAFT REPORT. EN United in diversity EN. European Parliament 2017/2053(INI) European Parliament 2014-2019 Committee on Budgets 2017/2053(INI) 10.1.2018 DRAFT REPORT on reform of the European Union s system of own resources (2017/2053(INI)) Committee on Budgets Co-rapporteurs:

More information

Accounting Officer's Status Report to the European Parliament and the Council 30 June 2015

Accounting Officer's Status Report to the European Parliament and the Council 30 June 2015 Accounting Officer's Status Report to the European Parliament and the Council 30 June 2015 Article 150(4) of the Financial Regulation Page 2 of 10 INDEX 1. Purpose and scope... 3 2. 2014 EU annual accounts

More information

Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION. on the system of own resources of the European Union. (//EC, Euratom) {SEC(2011) 876 final}

Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION. on the system of own resources of the European Union. (//EC, Euratom) {SEC(2011) 876 final} EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 29.6.2011 COM(2011) 510 final 2011/0183 (CNS) Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION on the system of own resources of the European Union (//EC, Euratom) {SEC(2011) 876 final} EXPLANATORY

More information

«Macro-economic Conditionality in Cohesion Policy: Added Value or Unnecessary Burden?»

«Macro-economic Conditionality in Cohesion Policy: Added Value or Unnecessary Burden?» December 2012 «Macro-economic Conditionality in Cohesion Policy: Added Value or Unnecessary Burden?» Roundtable Report Markella Dimitrakopoulou Introduction On 14 November 2012, Egmont Royal Institute

More information

Multiannual Financial Framework : Commission proposal

Multiannual Financial Framework : Commission proposal BRIEFING 221-227 MFF Multiannual Financial Framework 221-227: Commission proposal Initial comparison with the current MFF SUMMARY On 2 May, the Commission presented its proposal for the Multiannual Financial

More information

Quantitative Economics for the Evaluation of the European Policy

Quantitative Economics for the Evaluation of the European Policy Quantitative Economics for the Evaluation of the European Policy Dipartimento di Economia e Management Irene Brunetti Davide Fiaschi Angela Parenti 1 10/11/2015 1 ireneb@ec.unipi.it, davide.fiaschi@unipi.it,

More information

The next Multiannual Financial Framework (MFF) and its Duration

The next Multiannual Financial Framework (MFF) and its Duration IN-DEPTH ANALYSIS requested by the BUDG committee The next Multiannual Financial Framework (MFF) and its Duration Budgetary Affairs Policy Department for Budgetary Affairs Directorate General for Internal

More information

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL AND THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL AND THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 15.9.2017 COM(2017) 473 final COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL AND THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT Technical adjustment of the financial framework for 2018 in line

More information

Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development

Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development EUROPEAN PARLIAMT 2009-2014 Committee on Agriculture and Rural Development 24.7.2013 2013/0117(COD) ***I DRAFT REPORT on the proposal for a regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council laying

More information

The draft general budget of the European Union for 2015 (DB 2015) as proposed by the Commission amounts 1 to:

The draft general budget of the European Union for 2015 (DB 2015) as proposed by the Commission amounts 1 to: Council of the European Union Brussels, 24 July 2014 (OR. en) 11778/14 FIN 478 PE-L 40 NOTE From: Permanent Representatives Committee (Part 2) To: Council Subject: Council position on the draft budget

More information

fwk1420/mff COM Part I en.pdf. 3

fwk1420/mff COM Part I en.pdf. 3 PRZEGLĄD ZACHODNI I, 2013 Sidonia Jędrzejewska Brussels THE POLISH PRESIDENCY AND THE BUDGET OF THE EUROPEAN UNION The Polish Presidency and the Budget of the EU The Polish Presidency was dominated by

More information

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION. laying down the multiannual financial framework for the years

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION. laying down the multiannual financial framework for the years EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 29.6.2011 COM(2011) 398 final 2011/177 (APP) Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION laying down the multiannual financial framework for the years 2014-2020 EN EN EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM

More information

The draft general budget of the European Union for 2018 (DB 2018) as proposed by the European Commission amounts 1 to:

The draft general budget of the European Union for 2018 (DB 2018) as proposed by the European Commission amounts 1 to: Council of the European Union Brussels, 10 July 2017 (OR. en, fr) 10939/1/17 REV 1 NOTE From: To: Budget Committee FIN 447 INST 299 PE-L 32 Permanent Representatives Committee/Council Subject: Draft general

More information

on the MFF Mid-Term Review and Revision

on the MFF Mid-Term Review and Revision EPP Group Position Paper on the MFF Mid-Term Review and Revision EN EPP Group Position Paper on the MFF Mid-Term Review and Revision The purpose of this Position Paper is two-fold: firstly, to identify

More information

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL EN EN EN COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES Brussels, 10.12.2009 COM(2009) 682 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL on the follow-up to 2007 Discharge Decisions (Summary) - Council Recommendations

More information

17145/1/12 REV 1 AR/kg 1 DG G II A

17145/1/12 REV 1 AR/kg 1 DG G II A COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION Brussels, 5 December 2012 17145/1/12 REV 1 FIN 989 PE-L 118 "I/A" ITEM NOTE from : General Secretariat of the Council to : Permanent Representatives Committee/Council No.

More information

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 25.3.2013 COM(2013) 159 final 2013/0087 (COD) Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL on fixing an adjustment rate to direct payments provided

More information

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001 4 The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 200 Tina Winther Frandsen, International Relations INTRODUCTION The EU member states' public finances showed remarkable development during the 990s. In 993, the

More information

Brussels, COM(2015) 451 final. ANNEXES 1 to 4 ANNEXES

Brussels, COM(2015) 451 final. ANNEXES 1 to 4 ANNEXES EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 9.9.2015 COM(2015) 451 final ANNEXES 1 to 4 ANNEXES accompanying the Proposal for a Council decision establishing provisional measures in the area of international protection

More information

Development of the budget of European Union

Development of the budget of European Union Development of the budget of European Union Nordic-Baltic meeting of foreign affairs coordinators Association of Estonian Cities (AEC) Tallinn, 4-5 April 2013 UNO SILBERG, Dr (Econ) uno.silberg@gmail.com

More information

ANNEXES. accompanying the. Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION

ANNEXES. accompanying the. Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 27.5.2015 COM(2015) 286 final ANNEXES 1 to 3 ANNEXES accompanying the Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION establishing provisional measures in the area of international protection

More information

Official Journal of the European Union

Official Journal of the European Union 7.6.2014 L 168/39 COUNCIL REGULATION (EU, Euratom) No 609/2014 of 26 May 2014 on the methods and procedure for making available the traditional, VAT and GNI-based own resources and on the measures to meet

More information

Launching the new and implementing the past Ensuring a seamless transition to the new programmes

Launching the new and implementing the past Ensuring a seamless transition to the new programmes Draft Budget 2014 Launching the new and implementing the past Ensuring a seamless transition to the new programmes Janusz Lewandowski Commissioner for Financial Programming and Budget COBU, 26 June 2013

More information

Active Monitoring and Forecast of Budget Implementation Autumn Information Note

Active Monitoring and Forecast of Budget Implementation Autumn Information Note 11 October INFO()/101 Active Monitoring and of Budget Autumn Information Note Contents 1. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS... 2 2. INTRODUCTION... 3 3. IMPLEMENTATION OF THE BUDGET... 4 3.1. at the end of September...

More information

Analysis of the. budgetary implementation of the European Structural and Investment Funds in Budget

Analysis of the. budgetary implementation of the European Structural and Investment Funds in Budget Analysis of the budgetary implementation of the European Structural and Investment Funds in 2015 Budget May 2016 Cover image: kubais - Fotolia EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE-GENERAL BUDGET Analysis of

More information

The new Own Resources Legislation for the period of the MFF

The new Own Resources Legislation for the period of the MFF The new Own Resources Legislation for the period of the MFF 2014-2020 European Commission Chapter 33: Financial and Budgetary Provisions Explanatory meeting with Serbia Brussels, 27 January 2015 1 Background

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. State Aid Scoreboard. Report on state aid granted by the EU Member States. - Autumn 2012 Update. {SEC(2012) 443 final}

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. State Aid Scoreboard. Report on state aid granted by the EU Member States. - Autumn 2012 Update. {SEC(2012) 443 final} Brussels, 21.12.2012 COM(2012) 778 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION State Aid Scoreboard Report on state aid granted by the EU Member States - Autumn 2012 Update {SEC(2012) 443 final} EN EN REPORT FROM

More information

How is the EU budget distributed?

How is the EU budget distributed? How is the EU budget distributed? A political agreement on the 2014 2020 multiannual financial framework (MFF) among European institutions was reached on 27 June 2013. The leaders of the European Parliament,

More information

Presented jointly by the negotiators of the European Union and the United Kingdom Government.

Presented jointly by the negotiators of the European Union and the United Kingdom Government. 8 December 2017 TF50 (2017) 19 Commission to EU 27 Subject: Joint report from the negotiators of the European Union and the United Kingdom Government on progress during phase 1 of negotiations under Article

More information

The Federal Government's positions on the EU Multiannual Financia! Framework (MFF) post

The Federal Government's positions on the EU Multiannual Financia! Framework (MFF) post Die Bundesregierung Courtesy Translation 25 January 2018 The Federal Government's positions on the EU Multiannual Financia! Framework (MFF) post- 2020 1 Lasting peace and increasing prosperity in Europe

More information

The EU: your questions answered

The EU: your questions answered 1 The EU: your questions answered This booklet gives a brief overview of some of the issues and questions people have raised about the European Union. Many people have said that they don t have enough

More information

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 20.2.2019 C(2019) 1396 final COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION Modification of the calculation method for lump sum payments and daily penalty payments proposed by the Commission

More information

Draft Interinstitutional Agreement

Draft Interinstitutional Agreement EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 29.6.2011 COM(2011) 403 final Draft Interinstitutional Agreement between the European Parliament, the Council and the Commission on cooperation in budgetary matters and on

More information

DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET No 6 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2017

DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET No 6 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2017 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 9.10.2017 COM(2017) 597 final DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET No 6 TO THE GENERAL BUDGET 2017 Reduction of payment and commitment appropriations in line with updated forecasts of expenditure

More information

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 22.5.2018 COM(2018) 312 final 2018/0158 (COD) Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL on the apportionment of tariff rate quotas included in

More information

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 2.5.2018 COM(2018) 326 final 2018/0131 (NLE) Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION on the methods and procedure for making available the Own Resources based on the Common Consolidated

More information

JESSICA JOINT EUROPEAN SUPPORT FOR SUSTAINABLE INVESTMENT IN CITY AREAS JESSICA INSTRUMENTS FOR ENERGY EFFICIENCY IN LITHUANIA FINAL REPORT

JESSICA JOINT EUROPEAN SUPPORT FOR SUSTAINABLE INVESTMENT IN CITY AREAS JESSICA INSTRUMENTS FOR ENERGY EFFICIENCY IN LITHUANIA FINAL REPORT JESSICA JOINT EUROPEAN SUPPORT FOR SUSTAINABLE INVESTMENT IN CITY AREAS JESSICA INSTRUMENTS FOR ENERGY EFFICIENCY IN LITHUANIA FINAL REPORT 17 April 2009 This document has been produced with the financial

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL. on guarantees covered by the general budget Situation at 31 December 2016

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL. on guarantees covered by the general budget Situation at 31 December 2016 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 1.12.2017 COM(2017) 721 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on guarantees covered by the general budget Situation at 31 December 2016

More information

Future of EU finances: reforming how the EU budget operates. Briefing Paper. February 2018

Future of EU finances: reforming how the EU budget operates. Briefing Paper. February 2018 2018 Future of EU finances: reforming how the EU budget operates Briefing Paper February 2018 2 CONTENTS Paragraphs Introduction 1-4 EU value added 5-10 Making EU value added a core objective of the next

More information

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Slovakia. Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Slovakia. Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty EN EN EN COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES Brussels, SEC(2009) 1276 REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Slovakia Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty EN EN 1. THE APPLICATION OF

More information

FINANCING INSTRUMENTS FOR THE EU S TRANSPORT INFRASTRUCTURE

FINANCING INSTRUMENTS FOR THE EU S TRANSPORT INFRASTRUCTURE DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES POLICY DEPARTMENT B: STRUCTURAL AND COHESION POLICIES TRANSPORT AND TOURISM FINANCING INSTRUMENTS FOR THE EU S TRANSPORT INFRASTRUCTURE EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Abstract

More information

Official Journal of the European Union L 144/3

Official Journal of the European Union L 144/3 9.6.2009 Official Journal of the European Union L 144/3 COUNCIL REGULATION (EC) No 473/2009 of 25 May 2009 amending Regulation (EC) No 1698/2005 on support for rural development by the European Agricultural

More information

Active Monitoring and Forecast of Budget Implementation Summer Information Note

Active Monitoring and Forecast of Budget Implementation Summer Information Note 5 July INFO() 67 Active Monitoring and of Budget Summer Information Note Contents 1. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS... 2 2. INTRODUCTION... 3 3. IMPLEMENTATION OF THE BUDGET... 4 3.1. at 15 June... 4 3.2. forecasts...

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL ON BORROWING AND LENDING ACTIVITIES OF THE EUROPEAN UNION IN 2014

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL ON BORROWING AND LENDING ACTIVITIES OF THE EUROPEAN UNION IN 2014 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 10.7.2015 COM(2015) 327 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL ON BORROWING AND LENDING ACTIVITIES OF THE EUROPEAN UNION IN 2014 EN EN

More information

EU budget Financial report. Budget. Job creation. Growth. Security. Research. Innovation. Environment. Skills. Regional development

EU budget Financial report. Budget. Job creation. Growth. Security. Research. Innovation. Environment. Skills. Regional development Job creation Growth Security Research Innovation Environment Skills Regional development Humanitarian aid Health Infrastructure Natural resources Cohesion Energy Education EU budget 2016 Financial report

More information

WORKING DOCUMENT. EN United in diversity EN. European Parliament

WORKING DOCUMENT. EN United in diversity EN. European Parliament European Parliament 2014-2019 Committee on Budgetary Control 24.4.2017 WORKING DOCUMT on ECA Special Report 5/2017 (2016 Discharge): Youth unemployment - have EU policies made a difference? An assessment

More information

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, XXX COM(2018) 398/2 2018/0222 (NLE) Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION amending Council Regulation (EU) 2015/1588 of 13 July 2015 on the application of Articles 107 and 108

More information

Evaluation of the implementation of transparency in CAP beneficiaries

Evaluation of the implementation of transparency in CAP beneficiaries Evaluation of the implementation of transparency in CAP beneficiaries In the years since farmsubsidy.org s early victories in Denmark, the UK, the Netherlands and Sweden, EU member states have come a long

More information

Legal options for an additional EMU fiscal capacity

Legal options for an additional EMU fiscal capacity DIRECTORATE GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES POLICY DEPARTMENT C: CITIZENS' RIGHTS AND CONSTITUTIONAL AFFAIRS CONSTITUTIONAL AFFAIRS Legal options for an additional EMU fiscal capacity NOTE Abstract The establishment

More information

Evaluation questions are shown in blue and will be deleted once we upload the questionnaires

Evaluation questions are shown in blue and will be deleted once we upload the questionnaires COSME Evaluation Survey questionnaire -----For internal use----- Code SO Target group SO10005 SO1 Other organisations Evaluation questions are shown in blue and will be deleted once we upload the questionnaires

More information

Council of the European Union Brussels, 31 May 2017 (OR. en) Mr Jeppe TRANHOLM-MIKKELSEN, Secretary-General of the Council of the European Union

Council of the European Union Brussels, 31 May 2017 (OR. en) Mr Jeppe TRANHOLM-MIKKELSEN, Secretary-General of the Council of the European Union Council of the European Union Brussels, 31 May 2017 (OR. en) 9795/17 FIN 334 COVER NOTE From: date of receipt: 30 May 2017 To: No. Cion doc.: Subject: Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed

More information

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 22 March /12 ADD 1 CADREFIN 160 POLGEN 52. ADDENDUM TO THE NOTE from: Presidency

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 22 March /12 ADD 1 CADREFIN 160 POLGEN 52. ADDENDUM TO THE NOTE from: Presidency COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION Brussels, 22 March 2012 8057/12 ADD 1 CADREFIN 160 POLG 52 ADDDUM TO THE NOTE from: Presidency to: Council Subject: Multiannual Financial Framework (2014-2020) - Sections

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL. on the quality of fiscal data reported by Member States in 2017

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL. on the quality of fiscal data reported by Member States in 2017 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 8.3.2018 COM(2018) 112 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on the quality of fiscal data reported by Member States in 2017 EN EN REPORT

More information

Analysis of the budgetary implementation of the European Structural and Investment Funds in 2014

Analysis of the budgetary implementation of the European Structural and Investment Funds in 2014 Ref. Ares(2015)2276305-01/06/2015 EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE-GENERAL BUDGET Analysis of the budgetary implementation of the European Structural and Investment Funds in 2014 May 2015 NOTE: THE INFORMATION

More information

Council of the European Union Brussels, 24 May 2017 (OR. en) Mr Jeppe TRANHOLM-MIKKELSEN, Secretary-General of the Council of the European Union

Council of the European Union Brussels, 24 May 2017 (OR. en) Mr Jeppe TRANHOLM-MIKKELSEN, Secretary-General of the Council of the European Union Council of the European Union Brussels, 24 May 2017 (OR. en) 9667/17 FIN 328 COVER NOTE From: date of receipt: 24 May 2017 To: No. Cion doc.: Subject: Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed

More information

Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION

Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 24.10.2014 COM(2014) 658 final 2014/0306 (NLE) Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION on the signing and provisional application on behalf of the Union of the Agreement for scientific

More information

Brexit. Triggering Article 50: what now?

Brexit. Triggering Article 50: what now? Brexit Triggering Article 50: what now? www.freshfields.com/brexit 29 March 2017 Triggering Article 50: what now? The UK Prime Minister, Theresa May, has today formally triggered the process of the UK

More information

Quick appraisal of major project. Guidance application: for Member States on Article 41 CPR. Requests for payment

Quick appraisal of major project. Guidance application: for Member States on Article 41 CPR. Requests for payment Quick appraisal of major project Guidance application: for Member States on Article 41 CPR Requests for payment Europe Direct is a service to help you find answers to your questions about the European

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL. on EAGF expenditure. Early Warning System No 4-6/2018

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL. on EAGF expenditure. Early Warning System No 4-6/2018 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 19.7.2018 COM(2018) 554 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on EAGF expenditure Early Warning System No 4-6/2018 EN EN REPORT FROM

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL. on the quality of fiscal data reported by Member States in 2016

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL. on the quality of fiscal data reported by Member States in 2016 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 9.3.2017 COM(2017) 123 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on the quality of fiscal data reported by Member States in 2016 EN EN REPORT

More information

budgetary implementation

budgetary implementation Analysis of the budgetary implementation of the European Structural and Investment Funds in 2016 May 2017 Budget Europe Direct is a service to help you find answers to your questions about the European

More information

PRESS RELEASE. 3044th Council meeting. Economic and Financial Affairs BUDGET. and of the Conciliation Committee session

PRESS RELEASE. 3044th Council meeting. Economic and Financial Affairs BUDGET. and of the Conciliation Committee session COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION PRESS RELEASE 3044th Council meeting 16150/10 PRESSE 298 PR CO 33 Economic and Financial Affairs BUDGET and of the Conciliation Committee session President Melchior WATHELET

More information

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. Analysis of the Draft Budgetary Plan of Lithuania. Accompanying the document COMMISSION OPINION

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. Analysis of the Draft Budgetary Plan of Lithuania. Accompanying the document COMMISSION OPINION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 21.11.2018 SWD(2018) 520 final COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Analysis of the Draft Budgetary Plan of Lithuania Accompanying the document COMMISSION OPINION on the Draft

More information

Recommendations by the Fiscal Advisory Council on Austria s Budget Policy and Budget Financing in 2016

Recommendations by the Fiscal Advisory Council on Austria s Budget Policy and Budget Financing in 2016 Recommendations by the Fiscal Advisory Council on Austria s Budget Policy and Budget Financing in 2016 Adopted at the Fiscal Advisory Council meeting on November 25, 2015 Economic environment In its World

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL ON BORROWING AND LENDING ACTIVITIES OF THE EUROPEAN UNION IN 2013

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL ON BORROWING AND LENDING ACTIVITIES OF THE EUROPEAN UNION IN 2013 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 21.8.2014 COM(2014) 529 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL ON BORROWING AND LENDING ACTIVITIES OF THE EUROPEAN UNION IN 2013 EN EN

More information

Proposal for a COUNCIL IMPLEMENTING DECISION

Proposal for a COUNCIL IMPLEMENTING DECISION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 13.5.2015 COM(2015) 203 final 2015/0106 (NLE) Proposal for a COUNCIL IMPLEMENTING DECISION authorising Denmark to apply, in accordance with Article 19 of Directive 2003/96/EC,

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Denmark. Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Denmark. Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 12.05.2010 SEC(2010) 585 REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Denmark Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Denmark Report prepared

More information

Financial Perspective Inter-Institutional Agreement

Financial Perspective Inter-Institutional Agreement COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION Brussels, 11 April 2006 8350/06 CADREFIN 91 NOTE from : to : Subject : Presidency Coreper Financial Perspective Inter-Institutional Agreement 1. The Presidency submits to

More information

Council of the European Union Brussels, 10 September 2018 (OR. en)

Council of the European Union Brussels, 10 September 2018 (OR. en) Conseil UE Council of the European Union Brussels, 10 September 2018 (OR. en) 11871/18 LIMITE PUBLIC CADREFIN 187 RESPR 25 POLGEN 140 FIN 630 NOTE From: To: Subject: Presidency Permanent Representatives

More information

EU framework programme processes

EU framework programme processes Briefing January 2018 Adoption, implementation, evaluation SUMMARY Over the past 35 years, the European Union ( EU) institutions have adopted eight framework programmes for research. The lifecycles of

More information

ANNUAL REVIEW BY THE COMMISSION. of Member States' Annual Activity Reports on Export Credits in the sense of Regulation (EU) No 1233/2011

ANNUAL REVIEW BY THE COMMISSION. of Member States' Annual Activity Reports on Export Credits in the sense of Regulation (EU) No 1233/2011 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 7.2.2017 COM(2017) 67 final ANNUAL REVIEW BY THE COMMISSION of Member States' Annual Activity Reports on Export Credits in the sense of Regulation (EU) No 1233/2011 EN EN

More information

THE SWEDISH FISCAL POLICY FRAMEWORK

THE SWEDISH FISCAL POLICY FRAMEWORK THE SWEDISH FISCAL POLICY FRAMEWORK Regeringens skrivelse 2017/18:207 Fiscal policy framework Skr. 2017/18:207 The Government presents this Communication to the Riksdag. Stockholm, 12 April 2018 Stefan

More information

The CAP towards 2020: Possible scenarios for the reallocation of the budget for direct payments

The CAP towards 2020: Possible scenarios for the reallocation of the budget for direct payments DIRECTORATE GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES POLICY DEPARTMENT B: STRUCTURAL AND COHESION POLICIES AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT The CAP towards 2020: Possible scenarios for the reallocation of the budget

More information

financial framework EU budget 2014

financial framework EU budget 2014 Multiannual financial framework 2014 2020 EU budget 2014 and The figures Budget Europe Direct is a service to help you find answers to your questions about the European Union. Freephone number (*): 00

More information

EXPENDITURE RULES. Database

EXPENDITURE RULES. Database EXPENDITURE RULES Fiscal (or budgetary) rules regulate the development of public budget deficits and surpluses (see DICE Report 2/2004), without explicit reference to s or revenues. The revenue side is

More information