Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility"

Transcription

1 Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility Francesco Caprioli JOB MARKET PAPER 31 October 2008 Abstract In this paper I investigate the optimal fiscal policy when markets are complete and private agents are learning the tax schedule implemented by the government. The main result is that the government should use fiscal variables to manipulate agents expectations, setting low taxes when agents are pessimistic about future consumption and high taxes when they are optimistic about it. Moreover taxes and debt are very persistent, a salient feature in the data that the complete markets optimal taxation framework with rational expectations cannot fit. JEL Classification: E62, H63, D83. Keywords: Optimal Taxation, Learning, Debt Sustainability. I am heavily indebted to Albert Marcet for his excellent supervision and encouragement. I would like to thank Richard Anton Braun, Omar Licandro, Eva-Carceles Poveda, Jordi Galí, Mark Giannoni, Bruce Preston, Michael Reiter and Thijs Van Rens for their very useful comments and suggestions. I am also grateful to Sofia Bauducco, Filippo Ferroni, Stefano Gnocchi, Antonio Mele and Andrea Tesei for detailed feedbacks, which greatly improved this work. francesco.caprioli@upf.edu. Office: (+34)

2 1 Introduction... there is no reason and no occasion for any American to allow his fears to be aroused or his energy and enterprise to be paralyzed by doubt or uncertainty... It is true that the national debt increased sixteen billion dollars... you will be told that the Government spending program of the past five years did not cause the increase in our national income... But that Government spending acted as a trigger, a trigger to set off private activity.. (Franklin Delano Roosevelt, On the Recession (1938)) Just this week, we learned that retails sales have fallen off a cliff, and so industrial production. All signs point to an economic slump that will be nasty, brutish-and long. How nasty?... the unemployment rate will go above 7 percent, and quite possibly above 8 percent... And how long? It could be very long indeed... there is a lot the federal government can do for the economy... Now it is not the time to worry about the deficit.. (Paul Krugman, (2008)) An important issue in public finance theory is how to collect revenues to pay for government expenditures. When lump-sum taxes are not available, fiscal authorities must resort to taxes which distort people s decisions and move the economy away from the first-best. This is why how to set taxes is of crucial importance. The optimal taxation literature (e.g. Lucas and Stokey (1983), Chari et al. (1994), Chari and Kehoe (1999)answers this question looking for the tax profile which minimises the distortionary costs associated with it. The key insight of this literature is that under complete markets the pay-off of the portfolio of state-contingent bonds works as an insurance device. As a consequence, the tax rate should be smooth and respond very little to shocks. This conclusion has been derived in a framework in which agents fully understand the problem faced by the government. As they know the problem, they know the solution too, so that their expectations about future tax rates are model-consistent. In a sense the assumption of rational expectations is very strong because it endows agents with a huge amount of knowledge about market determined outcomes. In reality this knowledge may not be so deep. 1 Then two questions arise: are the fiscal policy recommendations suggested 1 There is a growing evidence against the assumption of fully rational agents. For example, Poterba (1988) and Parker (1999) find that private consumption does not react in anticipation of future tax changes; Feldman and Katuscak (2008) reject the hypothesis of taxpayers being fully rational and fully informed about the tax system with which they interact. Allen and Carroll (2001) find that it takes a very long time 2

3 by the existing literature still valid when agents do not know the problem faced by the policymakers? If not, what is the optimal fiscal policy when agents are learning it? In this paper I give an answer to these two questions. I consider a closed production economy with no capital and infinitely lived agents, where the only source of uncertainty is given by an exogenous government expenditure shock. The problem of the household is to maximise her lifetime expected utility subject to her flow budget constraint. The only difference between this framework and the standard optimal fiscal policy one is that agents do not know the tax schedule the government is going to implement. Hence, their expectations about their own next period s state-contingent marginal utility of consumption are not model-consistent. Agents act like econometricians and use a weighted average of past values of the contingent marginal utility; given the realisation of the shock, each period they update their belief about the marginal utility of consumption contingent on that specific realisation. The government is benevolent and chooses distortionary taxes on labour income and state-contingent debt to maximise households welfare subject to the feasibility constraint, households optimality conditions and the way in which they update their beliefs. Three are the main results. First, the fiscal policy which is optimal under rational expectations generates a very volatile stream of leisure and consumption when it is implemented in a set-up in which agents are bounded rational. The intuition for this result is that the optimal debt management under rational expectations prescribes volatile bond positions across states of nature. Agents perceive this type of debt management simply as a huge wealth effect and therefore they are willing to adjust private consumption. Under standard assumptions on the agents utility function, this higher volatility reduces welfare. Second, in a bounded rationality setting the government should set fiscal variables to manipulate private agents beliefs. To give an intuition for this result, assume that the government expenditure is constant and that the government has zero initial wealth. Under rational expectations, the optimal fiscal rule prescribes balanced budget: the government sets the tax rate to collect enough revenues to finance expenditure. When agents do not have rational expectations, this fiscal rule is still feasible, but it will imply a much longer time for agents to learn the tax rate than if the government followed an expectation-dependent for each household to understand its own consumption function (or a first-order Taylor approximation of it), even considering some form of social learning. Finally, Adam and Padula (2003) and Forsells and Kenny (2003) conclude for not fully rational inflation expectations, and Robert (1997) analyses the consequences of this result in terms of deflation costs. 3

4 fiscal plan. When agents are pessimistic, (i.e. they expect the one-step-ahead tax rate to be higher than they would expect it to be if they were fully rational), government optimality conditions require current expenditure to be financed mainly through debt: in this way the low current tax rate induces agents to revise downwards their expectations about the next period tax rate. 2 In the long-run the tax rate is higher than in a rational expectations framework because the government has to finance the interest paid on a positive amount of debt. 3 In this sense the initial agents beliefs has an effect on the long-run mean value of the tax rate and debt: the more pessimistic (optimistic) the agents are, the higher is the government debt (wealth) in the long-run. One implication of this result is that the model can help explain the wide dispersion across countries in the level of government debt and tax rate. Third, non-rational expectations influence the amount of tax smoothing the government can achieve. The case-study of a perfectly anticipated war is a clear example of the tension between the two conflicting goals the government wants to achieve, tax smoothing on one side and manipulation of beliefs on the other. Under rational expectations it is optimal for the government to accumulate assets before the war and sell them during the war-time. In this way the tax rate is constant in all periods before and after the war. Differently, in a learning framework pessimistic agents do not trust the promises made by the government, which is forced to lower the tax rate to manipulate agents expectations. As a consequence, the government accumulates less assets (than in a RE framework) before the war and finances the war issuing debt. The tax rate after the big shock is much higher than before. 4 Learning introduces a unit-root behaviour in the tax rate, a salient feature in the data which the standard optimal fiscal policy framework with complete markets cannot explain. 5 This persistence affects the power of some widely used tests to check for market completeness and debt sustainability. In line with Marcet and Scott (2007) we find that looking at the behaviour of debt is a much more reliable way to test the bond market structure than looking at the behaviour of tax rates. Similarly, the standard unit-root test in the debt/gdp 2 One implication of this result is that restricting how much a government can become indebted can delay the learning process. 3 The analysis is symmetric for the case of optimistic agents. 4 Manipulating expectations can explain why a benevolent government should run a deficit during peacetime periods, an implication that the Lucas and Stokey (1983) does not have and for which has been criticized. 5 Aiyagari et al. (2002), Battaglini and Coate (2008), Karantounias et al. (2007) and Svec (2008) are all attempts to achieve this result removing alternative assumptions from the baseline model and introducing either market incompleteness, or a political-economic bargaining equilibrium or fear of misspecification by agents. 4

5 ratio used to discriminate between responsible and non-responsible governments can be misleading, since it may cause a fiscal policy plan to be declared unsustainable when instead it is sustainable by construction. Augmenting this test to include the primary surplus in the regressors is a sharper way to distinguish the optimal and sustainable fiscal policy from an unsustainable policy. Finally, we solve the model when the government expenditure is endogenous. We find that, when agents are pessimistic, the fiscal authority would increase the government expenditure compared to the rational expectations value, financing it through debt. This result is in line with some proposals to deal with the recent distress. Many authors have studied the impact of learning on monetary policy design, either when the central bank follows some ad hoc policy rules (see inter alia Orphanides and Williams (2006), Preston (2005a,b, 2006), Preston and Eusepi (2007b,a)) or when it implements the optimal monetary policy (see inter alia Evans and Honkapohja (2003, 2006), Molnar and Santoro (n.d.)). Perhaps surprisingly, fiscal policy has received much less attention. Evans et al. (2007) study the interest rate dynamic learning path in a non-stochastic economy in which the fiscal authority credibly announces a future change in government purchases. Karantounias et al. (2007) and Svec (2008) study the optimal fiscal policy when agents do not trust the transition probabilities of the public expenditure suggested by their approximating model. Up to my knowledge, this is the first paper studying the influence of learning on fiscal policy design. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 studies the consequences of implementing the bond policy function under rational expectations when agents are learning. Section 3 solves for the optimal fiscal policy under learning. In Section 4 we present some simulation results. Section 5 gives some policy implications. Section 6 deals with the problem of discriminating between a complete markets model with learning and an incomplete markets model with rational expectations. Section 7 focuses on test sustainability and debt limits. In Section 8 we report some stylized facts about fiscal variables and agents sentiment and we use US data in order to test the model. Section 9 concludes. 5

6 2 The Model 2.1 Case 1: Rational expectations by both the government and agents We consider first the case in which both the government and households have rational expectations. We present the same model as in Lucas and Stokey (1983) in which a benevolent government levies a proportional tax rate τ t on labour income and has access to a complete set of one-period state-contingent bonds to cover an exogenous stream of government expenditure shocks. The resource constraint is given by where c t, l t and g t denote respectively private consumption, leisure, and public consumption. c t + g t = 1 l t (1) The representative agent s problem is to maximise his lifetime discounted expected utility E 0 β t u(c t, l t ) (2) t=0 subject to the period-by-period budget constraint b t 1 (g t ) + (1 τ t )(1 l t ) = c t + g t+1 g t b t (g t+1 )p b t(g t+1 ) (3) where β is the discount factor, τ t is the state-contingent labour tax rate and b t (g t+1 ) denotes the amount of bonds issued at time t contingent on period t + 1 government shock at the price p b t (g t+1). vb t g t+1 g b t t (g t+1 )p b t (g t+1) is defined as the value of government debt. The government pursues an optimal taxation approach: given an initial amount of inherited debt, it chooses the sequence of tax rates and state-contingent bonds to maximise consumer welfare. It can be shown that the Ramsey equilibrium satisfies τ t = G(g t, b g 1) t > 0 (4) 6

7 b g t(g t+1 = ḡ) = D(ḡ, b g 1) t > 0 (5) vb g t = V (g t, b g 1) t > 0 (6) The allocation is a time invariant function of the only state variable in this model, g t. The initial holding of government bonds matters for the allocation because it determines the value of the Lagrange multiplier attached to the implementability condition, which can be thought of as the intertemporal consumer budget constraint with both prices and taxes substituted out by the agents optimality conditions. The state-contingent bond holding is a time invariant function and does not depend on the current state of the economy, and the market value of debt is influenced by the current shock only through variations in the state-contingent interest rates. 2.2 Case 2: Rational expectations by the government and learning by the agents We assume now that the government has rational expectations while agents are learning fiscal policy: they have perfect knowledge about their own decision problem, in the sense that they correctly understand their own objective function and constraints, but they do not know the problem that the other agents in the economy, government included, have to solve for. As a consequence, they need to forecast market determined variables, in particular interest rates and tax rates, which are outside of their control although they are relevant to their decision problem. The representative agent s problem is to maximise the lifetime utility Ẽ 0 β t u(c t, l t ) t=0 subject to the flow budget constraint equation (3). Ẽ 0 denotes the agent s subjective expectations. The optimality condition with respect to the state-contingent bond is: p b t(g t+1 ) = β u c,t+1(g t+1 ) u c,t π(g t+1 g t ) (7) 7

8 . where π(g t+1 g t ) is the conditional probability of the government expenditure shock. For simplicity, agents know the distribution of g t.. Combining the optimality conditions with respect to consumption and leisure we get 1 τ t = u l,t u c,t (8) Equation (8) gives the combination of consumption and leisure given the tax rate. It is still open how much the agent consumes and saves: according to the Euler Equation Approach, the optimal consumption choice depends on the forecast of one-step-ahead marginal utility of consumption. Combining the flow budget constraint with equation (7) we get b t 1 u c,t = u c,t (c t (1 l t )(1 τ t )) + β g t+1 g t ũ c,t+1 (g t+1 )b t (g t+1 )π(g t+1 g t ) (9) Given arbitrary beliefs, the current tax rate and the holding of state-contingent bonds issued by the government in the previous period, agents adjust their consumption in order to satisfy equation (9), which gives the optimal consumption rule. We assume that the government implements the policy sequences {b t+j (g t+j+1 )} j=0 coming out of (5). The time-line of the events is the following. At the beginning of period t, agents observe the realisation of the shock g t and the tax rate set by the government at t: using all the information up to t 1, they form their expectations about one-period-ahead state-contingent marginal utility of consumption and decide how much to consume. To close the model it remains to specify the manner in which households form their beliefs. They estimate a theoretical regression using as regressors a constant and the government expenditure shock, which is the only variable appearing in the Minimum State Variable solution of the model under rational expectations. The law of motion of marginal utility of consumption perceived by the agents is given by u c,t = [1; g t 1 ] d t 1 + ǫ t (10) where d t 1 is the coefficient vector of dimension (2 1) and ǫ t is the error term. Since by assumption agents know the probability distribution of g t and observe the realisation of the shock before forming their expectations, forecasts of the endogenous variables 8

9 are given by E t u c,t+j = [1; E t g t+j ] d t 1 = d 0,t 1 + d 1,t 1 ρ j g g t j 1 (11) Equation (11) highlights the fact that, as standard in models of boundedly rational learning, agents are estimating a misspecified model: they believe that the model is stationary, while instead it has time-varying coefficients, whose law of motion is given by d t = d t t V 1 t g t 1 (u c,t x t 1 d t 1) (12) V t = V t t (x t 1x t 1 V t 1) (13) where x t 1 = [1; g t 1 ] and V t 1 is the variance-covariance matrix of the regressors. 6 The question is whether, given a sufficient amount of data, this equilibrium converges to the rational expectations equilibrium. The criterion adopted to judge convergence under a recursive least-squares algorithm is the expectational stability of REE, called E-stability by Evans and Honkapohja (2001). The following proposition holds: Proposition Suppose that the government does not make the fiscal plan contingent on agents beliefs and follows the bond fiscal rule which is optimal under rational expectations. Assume that agents utility is separable into consumption and leisure, logarithmic in consumption and linear in leisure. Assume moreover that the initial bond holding is zero. Then the REE is learnable. Proof. We relegate the proof to the appendix. Even if the fiscal authority does not take into account that agents do not have RE, the allocation would eventually converge to it. If the E-learnability condition would not be satisfied, two things would happen. First, agents would be prone to change their regression scheme; second, it would not make sense to compute log-deviation of the system from a steady state around which there would never be convergence. Even when the rational expectation equilibrium is learnable, along the transition path, the fluctuations in the allocation can be quite large with respect to those under rational expectations. To measure the increase in volatility induced by learning we use numerical methods to simulate the model. The utility function is 6 Alternatively to this scheme, agents can use the constant gain scheme, in which case the term 1 t and (13) is replaced with a constant 0 < γ < 1. In the simulation we consider both cases. in (12) 9

10 2 u(c t, l t ) = c1 σ t 1 σ + log(l t) (14) The government expenditure shock g t is assumed to follow a truncated AR(1) process ḡ, if(1 ρ g )g + ρ g g t 1 + ε g t > ḡ g t = g, if(1 ρ g )g + ρ g g t 1 + ε g t < g (1 ρ g )g + ρ g g t 1 + ε g t, otherwise where ε g t N(0, σ ε g ), g is the steady state value, fixed at 0.1 and ḡ, g equal to g + ( ) t ( ) σ 2 ε g t 1 ρ 2 g and g 2 σ 2 ε g t 1 ρ 2 g respectively. In the baseline parametrisation of the model we set σ ε g = 0.01, σ = 1 and β = t To measure the inefficiency of the fiscal policy plan under RE implemented in a context in which agents expectations are formed using a recursive least-squared algorithm rather than being rational, we consider the ratios of consumption and leisure variance when agents learn and the government implements the optimal bond policy rule under rational expectations over their corresponding values when instead both the agents and the government have rational expectations. Table 1: Relative variance ratio ρ g σ 2 c L σ 2 c RE σ 2 l L σ 2 l RE Table 1 shows these ratios change for different values of the autocorrelation coefficient of the government shock. The values are average across 1000 simulations. Two observations are worth noting. First, learning increases the variance of the allocation at least by around 30 per cent with respect to the rational expectations framework. Second, the higher ρ g, the higher is this relative increase. The intuition for these results hinges on the implication of tax smoothing in terms of bond portfolio management; smooth taxes imply volatile bond positions across states of nature. Since optimal consumption under learning depends on the state-contingent bonds issued in the previous period, agents perceive this kind of debt 10

11 management simply as a huge wealth effect and therefore they are willing to adjust private consumption as a consequence. The higher the autocorrelation coefficient for the government shock, the higher is the variance of the bond positions, which translates into a higher variance for consumption. The main implication of this result is that trying to teach the lesson is not a good policy recipe. Implementing a fiscal policy plan without taking into account the way in which not fully rational agents form their expectations induces a stream of consumption and leisure that is much more volatile than in the case of agents assumed to form modelconsistent expectations. Making the policy plan contingent on agents beliefs is much better, in terms of welfare, than obstinately performing the optimal fiscal policy under the rational expectations paradigm. The analysis also raises some doubts about recent developments in the debt management literature, according to which a government should hold extreme debt positions. The first reason to hold such positions relates to the capability to recover the complete markets outcome; almost every equilibrium allocation under complete markets can be replicated through an appropriate position in non-contingent bonds at different maturities. 7 Since the welfare is higher under complete markets than under incomplete markets, the optimal debt management is the one that allows the complete markets outcome to be reached. Due to the low variability of one-period-ahead bond prices across realisations of shock today, Angeletos (2002) and Buera and Nicolini (2004) show that the government can implement the complete markets allocation holding very extreme positions in bonds with different maturities. The second reason for debt volatility is to make the full commitment solution time consistent. Persson et al. (1987) consider a model with nominal frictions where the government in charge has an incentive to engage in a surprise inflation to erode the nominal inherited debt. The unique maturity structure of debt implementing the full commitment solution requires the government in t to leave to its successor a positive amount of nominal bond holdings. 7 Under incomplete markets with only one period bonds, it is not possible to achieve the complete market solution because the implementability condition is replaced with an infinite sequence of period-by-period budget constraints. Aiyagari et al. (2002) for example show that in case of i.i.d. shock, implementing the complete market solution, which generates i.i.d. primary surplus, would imply an explosive path for debt. 11

12 3 Optimal Fiscal Policy When Agents Are Learning The previous section shows that the optimal fiscal policy under rational expectations can lead to very bad outcomes under learning. This suggests that learning should be incorporated in the design of optimal fiscal policy: in this section we study the problem of a government which internalises the fact that agents do not have rational expectations. The pricing equation (7) expresses the state contingent interest rate as a function of households one-step-ahead expectations about state-contingent marginal utility. Understanding their own maximization problem agents realise that consumption at t + 1 depends on the tax rate the government will set at t + 1. It follows that perfect foresight over statecontingent consumption requires perfect foresight over the state-contingent tax rate, which by itself requires a large amount of information about the market. Actually, to forecast the tax rate each household has to solve for the government problem, which by itself implies the following assumptions: Assumption 1 Every agent knows that other agents have the same preferences and constraints and form expectations the way that he does. Assumption 2 Every agent knows that the no-rational-bubble condition holds for all t and all realisations. lim E tβ j u c,t+j b t+j = 0 (15) j Assumption 3 Every agent knows that the resource constraint holds. Assumption 4 Every agent knows that the government has a technology commitment and behaves as a benevolent social planner. The knowledge beyond these assumptions pertains to the external environment of each agent, and it is not required for his maximisation problem. The first three assumptions are necessary in order to compute the relevant constraints of the government, the implementability condition (Assumptions 1 and 2) and the feasibility condition (Assumption 3), while the last one is necessary to understand the objective function of the government. Therefore, the hypothesis implicit in the rational expectations framework of agents able to form modelconsistent expectations endows them with the knowledge of the function (4), which maps 12

13 realisations of government expenditure into the tax rate. 8 Since we want to analyse situations outside the rational expectations equilibrium, in what follows we assume that Assumptions 1-4 do not belong to the agents information set. As a consequence, the optimality conditions for each agent are summarised by u l,t u c,t = 1 τ t (16) p b t(g t+1 ) = βũc,t+1(g t+1 ) u c,t π(g t+1 g t ) (17) Equation (16) coincides with the intratemporal condition under rational expectations, equation (8), while ũ c,t+1 indicates non-rational expectations over the one-step-ahead statecontingent marginal utility of consumption. For simplicity we assume that the government expenditure shock can take only two realisations, g H and g L. Since in the rational expectations equilibrium the marginal utility of consumption is constant given the realisation of the shock, agents expectations are equal to and their law of motion is give by: Ẽ t u c,t+1 (g t+1 = g H ) = γ H t Ẽ t u c,t+1 (g t+1 = g L ) = γ L t γ i t = { γ i t 1 + α t (u c,t (g t = g i ) γ i t 1), if g t = g i γ i t 1, if g t = g j (18) with i = H, L and where α t follows an exogenous law of motion. Definition 1. A competitive equilibrium with non rational agents is an allocation {c t, l t, g t } t=0, state-contingent beliefs about one-step-ahead marginal utility of consumption {γ i t} t=0 for i = H, L, a price system {p b t } t=0 and a government policy {g t, τ t, b t } t=0 such that (a) given the price system, the beliefs and the government policy the allocation solves the household s problem; (b) given the allocation and the price system the government policy satisfies the sequence of government budget constraint (3); and (c) the goods and the bonds markets clear. 8 The reader might argue that if the government announces the state contingent tax plan, and it is fully credible, then the agents have perfect foresight about state-contingent marginal utility, and we are back to the rational expectations equilibrium. This is true if and only if the agents know the resource constraint: only in this case in fact, given the tax rate in the next period, agents can pin down future consumption from the ratio between marginal utility of leisure and marginal utility of consumption. 13

14 Let x t = [γ H t I(g t+1 = g H ) + γ L t I(g t+1 = g L )] (19) where I is the indicator function and define t A t k=0 x k 1 u c,k (20) The log of A t can be interpreted as the sum of past forecast errors in predicting the marginal utility that agents have made from period 0 to period t. Under rational expectations, this variable is constant and equal to 1, while under learning this is not the case any more, unless the initial beliefs about state contingent marginal utilities are exactly equal to the actual marginal utility. Proposition Assume that for any competitive equilibrium β t A t u c,t 0 a.s. 9 Given b 1, γ 1 H, γl 1, a feasible allocation {c t, l t, g t } t=0 is a competitive equilibrium if and only if the following constraint is satisfied 10 E 0 β t A t (u c,t c t u l,t (1 l t )) = A 0 u c,0 b 1 (21) t=0 with initial condition A 1 = 1 Proof. We relegate the proof to the appendix. With respect to the rational expectations case, there are two new state variables. The first one is the vector of last period beliefs about today s contingent marginal utility. The second one, A t 1, is the product of the ratios until period t 1 between expected marginal utility and actual marginal utility. The recursive formulation for A t is A t = A t 1 γ H t 1I(g t = g H ) + γ L t 1I(g t = g L ) u c,t (22) Definition 2. The government problem under learning is subject to (21), (22), (18) and (1). max {c t,l t,γ H t,γl t,at} t=0 E 0 β t u(c t, l t ) (23) 9 Using the results of Proposition we show that this is actually the case. 10 Because of learning, future endogenous control variables do not appear in the budget constraint at time t, and therefore it is not necessary to summarize all the constraints into the implementability condition. Nevertheless we use the intertemporal budget constraint and not the period-by-period one since in this way do not need to calculate the Lagrange multiplier associated with it. 14 t=0

15 Let g t = (g 0,..., g t ) denote the history of government expenditure. Attach the multipliers, β t π t (g t )λ 1,t (g t ), β t π t (g t )λ 2,t (g t ), β t π t (g t )λ 3,t (g t ) and β t π t (g t )λ 4,t (g t ) to constraints (21), (18) for i = H, L, (1) and to (22). The Lagrangian is L =E 0 β t {u(c t, l t ) + (A t (u c,t c t u l,t (1 l t ))) t=0 + λ 1,t ((γ H t γ H t 1 )I(g t = g L ) + (γ H t (1 α t )γ H t 1 α tu c,t )I(g t = g H )) + λ 2,t ((γ L t γ L t 1 )I(g t = g H ) + (γ L t (1 α t )γ L t 1 α tu c,t )I(g t = g L )) γt 1 H + λ 3,t (1 l t c t g t )} + λ 4,t (A t A I(g t = g H ) + γt 1 L I(g t = g L ) t 1 ) A 0 u c,0 b 1 u c,t Assuming b 1 = 0, the first-order necessary 11 conditions t 0 are: c t : u c,t + A t (u cc,t c t + u c,t ) λ 1,t α t u cc,t I(g t = g H ) λ 2,t α t u cc,t I(g t = g L ) + u cc,t λ 4,t A t 1 γ H t 1 I(g t = g H ) + γ L t 1 I(g t = g L ) u 2 c,t = λ 3,t (24) l t : u l,t + A t (u l,t u ll,t (1 l t )) = λ 3,t (25) γ H t : λ 1,t βe t {λ 1,t+1 I(g t+1 = g L ) + (1 α t+1 )λ 1,t+1 I(g t+1 = g H )+ + λ 4,t+1A t u c,t+1 I(g t+1 = g H )} = 0 (26) 11 As standard in the optimal fiscal policy literature, it is not easy to establish that the feasible set of the Ramsey problem is convex. To overcome this problem we check that the solution to the first-order necessary conditions of the Lagrangian is unique. 15

16 γ L t : λ 2,t βe t {λ 2,t+1 I(g t+1 = g H ) + (1 α t+1 )λ 2,t+1 I(g t+1 = g L )+ + λ 4,t+1A t u c,t+1 I(g t+1 = g L )} = 0 (27) A t : (u c,t c t u l,t (1 l t )) + λ 4,t βe t λ 4,t+1 γ H t I(g t+1 = g H ) + γ L t I(g t+1 = g L ) u c,t+1 (28) From equation (28) λ 4,t = (u c,t c t u l,t (1 l t )) + βe t λ 4,t+1 γ H t I(g t+1 = g H ) + γ L t I(g t+1 = g L ) u c,t+1 (29) Multiplying both sides by A t we get λ 4,t A t = A t (u c,t c t u l,t (1 l t )) + βe t λ 4,t+1 A t γ H t I(g t+1 = g H ) + γ L t I(g t+1 = g L ) u c,t+1 = = A t (u c,t c t u l,t (1 l t )) + βe t λ 4,t+1 A t+1 (30) where the last equality follows from equation (22). Iterating forward we obtain λ 4,t A t = E t β j A t+j (u c,t+j c t+j u l,t+j (1 l t+j )) (31) Inserting (31) into (24) we get j=0 u c,t + A t (u cc,t c t + u c,t ) λ 1,t α t u cc,t I(g t = g H ) λ 2,t α t u cc,t I(g t = g L ) u cc,t E t β j (32) A t+j (u c,t+j c t+j u l,t+j (1 l t+j )) = λ 3,t u c,t j=0 The first term on the left side of equation (32) represents the benefit for the government by increasing consumption by one unit. The second one measures the impact of the implementability constraint on the allocation, weighted by the distortion A t represented by non rational expectations. The third and fourth terms reflect the fact that the government takes 16

17 into account how agents update their expectations on the basis of the current consumption. The last term on the left represents the derivative of all future expected discounted primary surpluses with respect to current consumption. This is because from equation (21) each primary surplus (in terms of marginal utility) at t+j, j 0 is pre-multiplied by the product of past ratios between expected and actual marginal utility. In choosing optimal consumption today, the government is implicitly choosing the factor at which all future primary surpluses are discounted. The term on the right is the shadow value of output. A similar interpretation holds for the optimality condition with respect to leisure. Several comments are necessary. First, the optimal allocation is history-dependent through the presence of A t 1 : differently from Lucas and Stokey (1983), the allocation is not any more a time-invariant function of the current realisation of the government shock only, but depends on what happened in the past. Given the state variables g t, A t 1, the vector of past beliefs γt 1 i, i = H, L and α t 1, the problem becomes recursive and standard solution techniques can be applied. Second, it is simple to show that the optimality condition in a complete markets and rational expectations framework is a very special case of (32). Under rational expectations the following equalities hold γ H t 1 γ L t 1 = u c,t (g t = g H ) t = u c,t (g t = g L ) t which implies that A t = A t 1 = 1 t. The Lagrangian collapses to L =E 0 β t [u(c t, l t ) + (u c,t c t u l,t (1 l t )) + λ 1,t (γt H t=0 γ H t 1) + λ 2,t (γ L t γ L t 1) + λ 3,t (1 l t c t g t )] u c,0 b 1 The first-order conditions with respect to γ H t and γ L t are γ H t : γ L t : λ 1,t = βe t λ 1,t+1 (33) λ 2,t = βe t λ 2,t+1 (34) 17

18 which imply that the only solution is λ 1,t = λ 2,t = 0. Combining the first-order condition with respect to consumption and leisure we get u c,t + (u cc,t c t + u c,t ) = u l,t + (u l,t u ll,t (1 l t )) (35) which is exactly the optimality condition found in a rational expectations framework (see Lucas and Stokey (1983)) in which expectations do not depend on the current consumption level and in which there is no distortion into agents beliefs that the government has to manipulate optimally. Third, using the recursive formulation of A t, the intertemporal budget constraint at t b t 1 A t u c,t = E t β j A t+j (u c,t+j c t+j u l,t+j (1 l t+j )) j=0 and combining (32) and (25) the optimal allocation satisfies the following equations: u c,t + A t (u cc,t (c t b t 1 ) + u c,t ) λ 1,t α t u cc,t I(g t = g H ) λ 2,t α t u cc,t I(g t = g L ) = u l,t + A t (u l,t u ll,t (1 l t )) (36) Equation (36) looks very similar to the first-order condition with respect to consumption in the incomplete market model of Aiyagari et al. (2002). In the two frameworks in fact the excess burden of taxation is not constant, although for different reasons. In the absence of a full set of state-contingent bonds, as in Aiyagari et al. (2002), the excess burden of taxation is time-varying because of the incomplete insurance offered by the financial bonds: since the interest payment on last period debt is fixed across realisations of the current government shock, the government in each period has to adjust the stream of all future taxes to ensure solvency. 12 In a complete markets model with learning, what makes the excess burden of taxation time-varying is the cost of issuing state-contingent debt. Although market completeness implies that in each period the government can fully insure against expenditure shocks, the state contingent interest rates change as time goes by because agents expectations change. When agents stop updating their beliefs because the forecast error is zero, A t+j = A t 1 j 0, and the excess burden of taxation becomes constant again. Equation 32 expresses the actual marginal utility of consumption as a function of agents beliefs about it. Figure 1 shows the T-mapping for a log-log utility function and a given value of A t The left panel displays the actual marginal utility of consumption contingent on 12 In a complete market framework with rational expectations the excess burden of taxation is constant because the variable which adjusts to ensure solvency is the pay-off of the portfolio of contingent bonds. 13 The shape of the mapping is robust to different values of this variable. 18

19 the government expenditure shock being low (average with respect to the expected marginal utility of consumption contingent on the government expenditure shock being high), as a function of the previous period belief, γt 1. L The right panel display the same for the government expenditure shock being high. Since the slope is negative, the E-stability condition is satisfied. Figures 2 and 3 show the tax rate and the state-contingent bond policy functions which guarantee that the convergence between actual and expected marginal utility holds. The tax rate is a decreasing function of the previous period expected marginal utility; symmetrically, the state-contingent bond is an increasing function of it. 3.1 Some examples In order to characterise the optimal fiscal policy in the framework we are studying, in what follows we consider some examples restricting the government expenditure shock to a specific form. Although they are not meant to offer a realistic description of the reality, these examples highlight the large differences in the optimal fiscal plan with and without rational expectations Constant government expenditure shock. Consider the case in which the government expenditure is known to be constant. The policy recipe under rational expectations would be to fix the tax rate at the level to balance the budget every period: since there are no intertemporal distortions to smooth there is no role for debt. With learning, the government problem is L = β t [u(c t, l t ) + A t (u c,t c t u l,t (1 l t )) t=0 + λ 1,t (γ t (1 α t )γ t 1 α t u c,t ) + λ 2,t (1 l t c t g)] A 0 u c,0 b 1 (37) where the notation is the same as before and The optimality conditions t 0 are: A t = A t 1 γ t 1 u c,t (38) u c,t + A t (u cc,t c t + u c,t ) λ 1,t α t u cc,t u cc,t β j A t+j (u c,t+j c t+j u l,t+j (1 l t+j )) = u l,t + A t (u l,t u ll,t (1 l t )) u c,t j=0 (39) 19

20 λ 1,t β(1 α t )λ 1,t+1 + β b t A t = 0 Equation (39) gives the mapping T between agents beliefs about (marginal utility of) consumption and actual (marginal utility of) consumption. In the next proposition we characterise the properties of this mapping. Proposition Let the utility function be u(c t, l t ) = logc t + l t (40) and that the term α t is small enough to be ignored. Then, in the set γ t 1 > 0 the mapping T: R + R + has the following properties: T is increasing and concave. T has one fixed point. The least squares learning converges to it. Proof. We relegate the proof to the appendix. The solid lines in figures 4, 5 and 6 show the optimal fiscal plan under rational expectations. Whereas the dashed lines show the optimal fiscal plan when agents adopt a constant gain algorithm to update their belief while supposing that in the initial period the expected consumption is lower than the actual consumption prevailing at t = In Proposition we have shown that the expected marginal utility converges to actual one. The next proposition characterises this value. Proposition Given an initial value for the government bond holding b 1 the allocation under learning does not converge to the allocation under rational expectations implied by the same initial bond holding, unless agents have the correct initial belief about marginal utility. However, for any initial belief held by agents, γ 1, there exists a b 1 such that lim t c L t (γ 1) = c RE t (b 1 ) (41) Proof. We relegate the proof to the appendix. 14 Since for optimistic agents the evolution of the system is symmetric, we do not report it. 20

21 For any initial belief about the marginal utility of consumption, there is always an initial level of government wealth such that the allocation under learning converges to the one under rational expectations starting with that initial government wealth. Figure 10 shows this relation assuming that in equation (37) b 1 = 0. Given the parameters values used, the solution of the Ramsey problem under rational expectations implies that the marginal utility of consumption is constant and equal to 2.5. For all values of initial belief higher (lower) than this reference value, the learning allocation coincides with the solution of a Ramsey problem in an economy populated by rational agents and endowed with a positive (negative) initial government debt One big shock Consider the case in which expenditure is known to be constant in all periods apart from T, when g T > g t. Under rational expectations the government runs a positive primary surplus from period 0 to T 1, using it to buy bonds. At T the government finances the high public consumption level by selling the accumulated assets and possibly by levying a tax rate on labour income. From period T + 1 onwards the tax rate is just sufficient to cover the expenditure and to service the interest on the bonds issued at T. On the other hand, in an economy populated by pessimistic agents, the government can accumulate less assets because it has to stimulate the economy to manipulate expectations. The big shock at T is financed by increasing debt much more than under rational expectations. Figures 7-9 illustrate the optimal plan under rational expectations (the solid lines) and under learning (the dashed lines), assuming T = 10, g t = 0.1 and g T = Cyclical shocks Suppose that g t = g H t = j H T g t = g L otherwise with j = 1, 2,..., T. H is the length of time over two subsequent bad shocks and T is the H last period in which a bad shock can occur. The rational expectations policy recipe is the same as before: the tax rate is constant in all periods when g t = g L and increases very little when the bad shock hits the economy, due to the assets the government accumulates during the good shock periods. Under learning with pessimistic agents, before the first realisation of the bad shock the tax rate is lower than under RE and increases between any two subsequent 21

22 bad shocks, generating resources devoted to reducing debt, which increases whenever the bad shock occurs. After the last bad realisation of the shock, the tax rate falls and then gradually increases over time to ensure intertemporal solvency Bad shock of unknown duration Suppose that the shock can take two realisations, g L and g H, with the following transition probabilities matrix ( 1 0 P = π H,L π H,H where π i,j is the probability that tomorrow the shock is in state j, being today in state i, with g t = g H at t = 0. This example corresponds to an absorbing Markov chain, where the low realisation of the shock is the absorbing state and the high one is the transient state. Under rational expectations, the government finances the bad shocks partly through taxes and partly by issuing debt. Numerical results, not reported here, confirm the role of fiscal policy as stabiliser of expectations: the accumulation of public debt is higher and longer under learning than under rational expectations, the difference being due to the opportunity of inducing the agents to revise their expectations downwards. 4 Simulation Results In this section we apply numerical methods to compute the Ramsey equilibrium described in the Section 3 when the expenditure shock is correlated. We assume a discount factor equal to 0.95 and a gain parameter equal to The government expenditure shock is a two-state Markov process with values equal to g H = 0.1 and g L = 0.05 and transition probabilities equal to π H,L = π L,H = 0.2, π H,H = π L,L = Table 6 summarises some statistics for the allocation and the fiscal variables under rational expectations. Table 7 summarises the same statistics under learning after convergence of beliefs for initially pessimistic and optimistic agents. Reported values are average across 1000 simulations. 15 The choice of the updating parameter is not easy because it requires a trade-off between filtering noises and tracking structural changes. Milani (2007) estimates a New-Keynesian model with one-period-ahead expectations and finds that the best fitting specification has a gain coefficient in a range between and Orphanides and Williams (2004) find that a value for k in the range fits the expectations data from the Survey of Professional Forecasters better than using higher or lower values. Evans et al. (2007) also use the same value for k. 16 For the case of i.i.d shock case the results are very similar to those with serially correlated shock, and therefore are not reported. ) 22

23 Table 2: Tax smoothing and learning γt 1 L γt 1 H E j β γt 1 L γt 1 H E j β Two points are worth noting. First, if γ 1 i > u c RE(g t=0 = g i ) for i = H, L, in the long run the consumption level under learning is lower than under rational expectations. Since at the beginning consumers were pessimistic, the accumulation of debt necessary to induce them to revise their expectations upwards requires higher taxes in the long run than under rational expectations. Because of this, consumption is lower and leisure is higher (than under rational expectations). The average primary surplus is higher as well. In this sense we can say that beliefs are self-fulfilling in the long run: the lower is the initial expected consumption, the lower the actual consumption after convergence. Exactly the opposite is true with optimistic agents, i.e. when γ 1 i < u c RE(g t=0 = g i ) for i = H, L. Second, the amount of tax smoothing the government can achieve in the long run is influenced by the initial beliefs. Suppose we estimate the following equation τ j t = α j + β j g j t + ǫ t (42) where the index j refers to the simulation. The higher β j, the more the tax rate responds to the government shock, and therefore the lower the tax smoothing. The reference value under RE for E j β j is equal to Table 2 reports the mean β across 1000 simulations as a function of the initial expectations. Table 8 shows the same statistics for the system during the first 30 periods of transition, respectively under RE and under learning for pessimistic agents. All the variables are more volatile before convergence than after convergence. This is due to the fact that before convergence agents expectations and the product of past ratios between what agents 23

24 expected in terms of future consumption and actual realised consumption change over time, and this volatility is added to that of the government shock. Notice that the market value of government debt and the labour tax rate are the most volatile endogenous variables, since they have to adjust to influence agents beliefs. Notice also that tax rate volatility while agents are learning is double that after convergence. As concerns autocorrelation, learning creates persistence in the system, which displays more correlation than after convergence. Importantly, the most autocorrelated variables are the fiscal variables, the market value of debt and the tax rate. The top panel in Fig. 14 displays the persistence of the debt/gdp ratio, the primary surplus/gdp ratio and the government expenditure shock under rational expectations: the bottom panel displays the same variables under learning. In both cases we consider the first 50 periods of simulated data. 17 Although in the model debt is the most persistent variable, it is not as persistent as in the data. Another way to compare persistence under learning and under rational expectations is to look at autoregressions of tax rates in the two frameworks when the shock is i.i.d.. Table 9 shows that while under rational expectations the coefficient on the lagged tax rate is close to zero and not statistically significant, under learning it is high and statistically significant. We conclude this section measuring the goodness of the learning equations used by agents to predict one-step-ahead state-contingent marginal utility of consumption. We use the Epsilon-Delta Rationality criterion (EDR), as formalized in Marcet and Nicolini (1998). Define π ǫ,t P( 1 T T [u c,t γ t 1 ] 2 < 1 T t=0 T [u c,t E t 1 u c,t ] 2 + ǫ) which is a function of ǫ, δ and T. E t 1 u c,t denote the expectations of an agent who knows the whole economic structure of the model. The learning mechanism (18) with α t = α satisfies EDR for (ǫ,δ,t) if π ǫ,t 1 δ. Table 5 shows this π ǫ,t for different values of ǫ (across columns) and T (across rows). Reported values are computed out of 1000 simulations. Since the discount factor is equal to 0.95, each period corresponds to one year. 17 To measure the persistence of a variable, say y, we use the k-variance ratio, defined as t=0 P k y = V ar(y t y t k ) kv ar(y t y t 1 ) 24

Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility

Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility Francesco Caprioli JOB MARKET PAPER 31 October 2008 Abstract In this paper I investigate the optimal fiscal policy when markets are complete and private agents

More information

Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility

Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility Francesco Caprioli 1 1 Universitat Pompeu Fabra Conference - November 2008 Caprioli (UPF) Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility Conference 2008 1 / 42

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Behzad Diba University of Bern April 2012 (Institute) Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background April 2012 1 / 19 Research Areas Research on fiscal policy typically

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first introduce and discuss the intertemporal budget

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Eric Sims University of otre Dame Spring 7 Introduction This set of notes studies fiscal policy in the RBC model. Fiscal policy refers to government

More information

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) Was The New Deal Contractionary? Gauti B. Eggertsson Web Appendix VIII. Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) ProofofProposition3:The social planner s problem at date is X min

More information

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Advanced Macroeconomics II Professor Lorenza Rossi/Jordi Gali T.A. Daniël van Schoot, daniel.vanschoot@upf.edu Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Schedule: 28th of May (seminar 4): Exercises 1, 2 and

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far.

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 The Ramsey Model Lectures 11 to 14 Topics in Macroeconomics November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 Lecture 11, 12, 13 & 14 1/50 Topics in Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model: Introduction 2 Main Ingredients Neoclassical

More information

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far (Incomplete) summary of the course so far Lecture 9a, ECON 4310 Tord Krogh September 16, 2013 Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 16, 2013 1 / 31 Main topics This semester we will go through: Ramsey (check)

More information

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle 1 E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 1 A Lucas Tree Model Consider a pure exchange, representative household economy. Suppose there exists an asset called a tree.

More information

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55 Government debt Lecture 9, ECON 4310 Tord Krogh September 10, 2013 Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, 2013 1 / 55 Today s lecture Topics: Basic concepts Tax smoothing Debt crisis Sovereign risk Tord

More information

The science of monetary policy

The science of monetary policy Macroeconomic dynamics PhD School of Economics, Lectures 2018/19 The science of monetary policy Giovanni Di Bartolomeo giovanni.dibartolomeo@uniroma1.it Doctoral School of Economics Sapienza University

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 207 Introduction This note works through some simple two-period consumption-saving problems. In

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Dynamic Macroeconomics Chapter 1 Introduction Dynamic Macroeconomics Prof. George Alogoskoufis Fletcher School, Tufts University and Athens University of Economics and Business 1.1 The Nature and Evolution of Macroeconomics

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings Econ 20200 - Elements of Economics Analysis 3 (Honors Macroeconomics) Lecturer: Chanont (Big) Banternghansa TA: Jonathan J. Adams Spring 2013 Introduction Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

More information

A simple wealth model

A simple wealth model Quantitative Macroeconomics Raül Santaeulàlia-Llopis, MOVE-UAB and Barcelona GSE Homework 5, due Thu Nov 1 I A simple wealth model Consider the sequential problem of a household that maximizes over streams

More information

Problem set Fall 2012.

Problem set Fall 2012. Problem set 1. 14.461 Fall 2012. Ivan Werning September 13, 2012 References: 1. Ljungqvist L., and Thomas J. Sargent (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, sections 17.2 for Problem 1,2. 2. Werning Ivan

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting Masaru Inaba and Kengo Nutahara Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and

More information

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules WILLIAM A. BRANCH TROY DAVIG BRUCE MCGOUGH Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules This paper examines the implications of forward- and backward-looking monetary policy

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims FINAL EXAM. β t 1 2 φτ2 t subject to (1)

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims FINAL EXAM. β t 1 2 φτ2 t subject to (1) Eco54 Spring 21 C. Sims FINAL EXAM There are three questions that will be equally weighted in grading. Since you may find some questions take longer to answer than others, and partial credit will be given

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research 1. Introduction

More information

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption Notes for Econ22A: Consumption Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas UC Berkeley Fall 215 c Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 215, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. Disclaimer: These notes are riddled with inconsistencies, typos and

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics 6. Rational Expectations and Consumption

Advanced Macroeconomics 6. Rational Expectations and Consumption Advanced Macroeconomics 6. Rational Expectations and Consumption Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2015 Karl Whelan (UCD) Consumption Spring 2015 1 / 22 A Model of Optimising Consumers We will

More information

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Davide Porcellacchia 8 February 2017 Abstract The canonical New Keynesian model features a zero lower bound on the interest rate. In the simple setting

More information

On the Optimality of Financial Repression

On the Optimality of Financial Repression On the Optimality of Financial Repression V.V. Chari, Alessandro Dovis and Patrick Kehoe Conference in honor of Robert E. Lucas Jr, October 2016 Financial Repression Regulation forcing financial institutions

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010 Booms and Busts in Asset Prices Klaus Adam Mannheim University & CEPR Albert Marcet London School of Economics & CEPR May 2010 Adam & Marcet ( Mannheim Booms University and Busts & CEPR London School of

More information

Money in an RBC framework

Money in an RBC framework Money in an RBC framework Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 1 / 36 Money Two basic questions: 1 Modern economies use money. Why? 2 How/why do

More information

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics Chapter 11 AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics The simplest model featuring fully-endogenous exponential per capita growth is what is known as the AK model. Jones

More information

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312/702 Basic New Keynesian Model of Transmission Can be derived from primitives:

More information

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income 1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income Until now, we have assumed that government policy is exogenously given, so the government had a very passive role. Its only concern was balancing the intertemporal budget.

More information

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model Bianca De Paoli November 2008 1 Fiscal Policy in a New Keynesian Model 1.1 Positive analysis: the e ect of scal shocks How do scal shocks a ect in ation?

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

Optimal Taxation and Debt Management without Commitment

Optimal Taxation and Debt Management without Commitment Optimal Taxation and Debt Management without Commitment Davide Debortoli Ricardo Nunes Pierre Yared March 14, 2018 Abstract This paper considers optimal fiscal policy in a deterministic Lucas and Stokey

More information

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux Online Appendix: Non-cooperative Loss Function Section 7 of the text reports the results for

More information

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1.

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1. Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective function max C,K,B t=0 β t C1 γ t 1 γ and faces the constraints at each period

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam MACROECONOMICS Prelim Exam Austin, June 1, 2012 Instructions This is a closed book exam. If you get stuck in one section move to the next one. Do not waste time on sections that you find hard to solve.

More information

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

1 No capital mobility

1 No capital mobility University of British Columbia Department of Economics, International Finance (Econ 556) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout #7 1 1 No capital mobility In the previous lecture we studied the frictionless environment

More information

Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs

Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs Viktor Tsyrennikov Preliminary and Incomplete February 28, 2006 Abstract This works aims analyzes market survival of agents with incorrect beliefs.

More information

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy Johannes Wieland University of California, San Diego and NBER 1. Introduction Markets are incomplete. In recent

More information

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption Problem Set 3 Thomas Philippon April 19, 2002 1 Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption The goal of the question is to derive the formulas on p13 of Topic 2. This is a partial equilibrium analysis

More information

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Chapter 11 AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. In his Chapter 11 Acemoglu discusses simple fully-endogenous growth models in the form of Ramsey-style AK and reduced-form AK models, respectively.

More information

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013 Comprehensive Exam August 19, 2013 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question. Good luck! 1 1 Menu

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES 1. REVIEW: SMALL TAXES SMALL DEADWEIGHT LOSS Static analysis suggests that deadweight loss from taxation at rate τ is 0(τ 2 ) that is, that for small tax rates the

More information

Answers to Problem Set #6 Chapter 14 problems

Answers to Problem Set #6 Chapter 14 problems Answers to Problem Set #6 Chapter 14 problems 1. The five equations that make up the dynamic aggregate demand aggregate supply model can be manipulated to derive long-run values for the variables. In this

More information

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6 Contents 1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) 2 1.1 Question (a).................................................... 2 1.2 Question (b).................................................... 6 2 Countercyclical

More information

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications Econ PhD, UC3M Lecture 9: Data and facts Hernán D. Seoane UC3M Spring, 2016 Today s lecture A look at the data Study what data says about open

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2014 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2014 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Part A (Prof. Laibson): 48 minutes Part B (Prof. Aghion): 48

More information

Topic 4. Introducing investment (and saving) decisions

Topic 4. Introducing investment (and saving) decisions 14.452. Topic 4. Introducing investment (and saving) decisions Olivier Blanchard April 27 Nr. 1 1. Motivation In the benchmark model (and the RBC extension), there was a clear consump tion/saving decision.

More information

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018 Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018 Lecture 8: Safe Asset, Government Debt Pertti University School of Business March 19, 2018 Today Safe Asset, basics Government debt, sustainability, fiscal

More information

Business Cycles II: Theories

Business Cycles II: Theories Macroeconomic Policy Class Notes Business Cycles II: Theories Revised: December 5, 2011 Latest version available at www.fperri.net/teaching/macropolicy.f11htm In class we have explored at length the main

More information

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Asset Prices and Finance Max Gillman Cardi Business School 0 December 200 Gillman (Cardi Business School) Chapter 7 0 December 200 / 38 Chapter 7: Asset Prices and Finance

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Macro II Chapter 5 Macro and Finance 1 Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Main references : - L. Ljundqvist and T. Sargent, Chapter 7 - Mehra and Prescott 1985 JME paper - Jerman 1998 JME paper - J.

More information

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M Macroeconomics MEDEG, UC3M Lecture 5: Consumption Hernán D. Seoane UC3M Spring, 2016 Introduction A key component in NIPA accounts and the households budget constraint is the consumption It represents

More information

Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia?

Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia? Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia? Fiscal Limits and Default Risk Premia for Slovakia Moderné nástroje pre finančnú analýzu a modelovanie Zuzana Múčka June 15, 2015 Introduction Aims

More information

Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective

Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Monetary and Fiscal Policy Issues in General Equilibrium

More information

The test has 13 questions. Answer any four. All questions carry equal (25) marks.

The test has 13 questions. Answer any four. All questions carry equal (25) marks. 2014 Booklet No. TEST CODE: QEB Afternoon Questions: 4 Time: 2 hours Write your Name, Registration Number, Test Code, Question Booklet Number etc. in the appropriate places of the answer booklet. The test

More information

RATIONAL BUBBLES AND LEARNING

RATIONAL BUBBLES AND LEARNING RATIONAL BUBBLES AND LEARNING Rational bubbles arise because of the indeterminate aspect of solutions to rational expectations models, where the process governing stock prices is encapsulated in the Euler

More information

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME P UNISH S AVERS?

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME P UNISH S AVERS? D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME P UNISH S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO Applications of Behavioural Economics and Multiple Equilibrium Models to Macroeconomic Policy Conference July 3, 2017

More information

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3) FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS These notes are missing interpretation of the results, and especially toward the end, skip some steps in the mathematics. But they should be useful

More information

Research Summary and Statement of Research Agenda

Research Summary and Statement of Research Agenda Research Summary and Statement of Research Agenda My research has focused on studying various issues in optimal fiscal and monetary policy using the Ramsey framework, building on the traditions of Lucas

More information

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Postponed exam: ECON4310 Macroeconomic Theory Date of exam: Wednesday, January 11, 2017 Time for exam: 09:00 a.m. 12:00 noon The problem set covers 13 pages (incl.

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ). ECON 8040 Final exam Lastrapes Fall 2007 Answer all eight questions on this exam. 1. Write out a static model of the macroeconomy that is capable of predicting that money is non-neutral. Your model should

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment Chapter 6 Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment In Romer s IS/MP/IA model, we assume prices/inflation adjust imperfectly when output changes. Empirically, there is a negative relationship

More information

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound Robert G. King Boston University and NBER 1. Introduction What should the monetary authority do when prices are

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Homework 3: Asset Pricing Homework 3: Asset Pricing Mohammad Hossein Rahmati November 1, 2018 1. Consider an economy with a single representative consumer who maximize E β t u(c t ) 0 < β < 1, u(c t ) = ln(c t + α) t= The sole

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev Department of Economics, Trinity College, Dublin Policy Institute, Trinity College, Dublin Open Republic

More information

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption Toulouse School of Economics Notes written by Ernesto Pasten (epasten@cict.fr) Slightly re-edited by Frank Portier (fportier@cict.fr) M-TSE. Macro I. 200-20. Chapter 3: Consumption Macroeconomics I Chapter

More information

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods. Introduction In ECON 50, we discussed the structure of two-period dynamic general equilibrium models, some solution methods, and their

More information

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model R. Barrell S.G.Hall 3 And I. Hurst Abstract This paper argues that the dominant practise of evaluating the properties

More information

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION by John B. Taylor Stanford University October 1997 This draft was prepared for the Robert A. Mundell Festschrift Conference, organized by Guillermo

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

Government Policy Response to War-Expenditure Shocks

Government Policy Response to War-Expenditure Shocks Government Policy Response to War-Expenditure Shocks Fernando M. Martin SFU August 12, 2011 Wartime policy in the U.S. Episodes of interest: Civil War World War I World War II Qualitative stylized facts:

More information

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) ....... Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) Rapid Aging and Chinese Pension Reform, June 3, 2014 SHUFE, Shanghai ..... The results in this

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29 Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29 Time-Series Time-series is a sequence fx 1, x 2,..., x T g or fx t g, t = 1,..., T, where t is an index denoting

More information

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Pavel Herber 1 and Daniel Němec 2 1 Masaryk University, Faculty of Economics and Administrations Department of Economics Lipová 41a, 602 00 Brno,

More information

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism Árpád Ábrahám João Brogueira de Sousa Ramon Marimon Lukas Mayr European University Institute and Barcelona GSE - UPF, CEPR & NBER ADEMU Galatina

More information