THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN: CONSTITUTIONAL LIMITS AND THE NEW PUBLIC SPENDING GROWTH RULE

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN: CONSTITUTIONAL LIMITS AND THE NEW PUBLIC SPENDING GROWTH RULE"

Transcription

1 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN: CONSTITUTIONAL LIMITS AND THE NEW PUBLIC SPENDING GROWTH RULE

2 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN: CONSTITUTIONAL LIMITS AND THE NEW PUBLIC SPENDING GROWTH RULE The author of this article is Pablo Hernández de Cos of the Directorate General Economics, Statistics and Research. Introduction In the last two decades the developed countries have significantly modified the framework in which fiscal policy operates. In particular, they have adopted fiscal rules setting explicit caps on the deficit or public debt and/or on certain budgetary items so as to ensure the sustainability of public finances. The empirical evidence available broadly confirms that fiscal rules may prove effective in obtaining and maintaining budgetary discipline [Debrun et al. (2008) and European Commission (2009)]. Moreover, it is found that their presence increases the likelihood of fiscal consolidations being successful, which is particularly important in circumstances such as those at present, in which the deterioration in public finances brought about during the economic crisis must be corrected [IMF (2009)]. The same literature emphasises, however, that the design of fiscal rules largely influences their effectiveness. Aspects such as their definition, control and application mechanisms, and the procedure for correction in the event of deviations, are crucial for attaining the objectives laid down [Bohn and Inman (1996) and Ayusi-i-Casals et al. (2009)]. Establishing fiscal rules that make it obligatory to maintain healthy public finances is all the more important in a monetary union since, as has been seen in the case of the sovereign debt crisis affecting the euro area since early 2010, one member s inappropriate fiscal policies may have adverse repercussions for the other members and generate union-wide tensions. Insofar as the financial markets do not always act as a deterrent to these policies, it becomes necessary to set fiscal controls on the Member States, obliging them to internalise the effect of their decisions on the union as a whole. It is this very reasoning that prompted the inclusion in the Treaty on European Union of limits on the members deficits and public debt, which were complemented by the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP). However, the economic crisis has highlighted the problems of the workings of the SGP, which was incapable of promoting a sustained fiscal consolidation during the economic upturn. This meant that the crisis led to an unprecedented deterioration in most European countries fiscal position and outlook, which in some cases began to be perceived as unsustainable. The economic policy response to the euro area s sovereign debt crisis is far-reaching and includes, among other aspects, a revision of the EU economic governance framework. In addition to the need to create crisis-management mechanisms, the strong interrelatedness of macroeconomic, fiscal and financial problems has revealed the need for wider and more intense economic policy coordination in the monetary union, which has taken specific form in the design of a new framework for the monitoring of macroeconomic imbalances and of competitiveness [ECB (2011) and Caballero et al. (2011)]. On the fiscal front, a reform of the SGP aimed at strengthening its implementation is pending approval. Among other aspects, the reform acknowledges the importance of an appropriate definition of fiscal frameworks not only at the European level, but also at the national level; accordingly, the Member States are asked to meet minimum requirements in respect of their fiscal frameworks so that these may contribute more effectively to attaining budgetary stability. In the same respect, the Euro Plus Pact entered BANCO DE ESPAÑA 3 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

3 into by the euro area Heads of State and Government on March 2011 included the commitment by members to transpose into national legislation the EU budgetary rules established in the SGP. Spain already had budgetary stability legislation (BSL) setting limits on the deficit that all tiers of government may incur. Nonetheless, it has been decided to reinforce this framework further to the approval in September 2011 of a reform of the Constitution that incorporates into the constitutional text the deficit and debt limits set at European level. Previously, in July 2011, a public spending growth rule was introduced for central government and for the biggest municipal councils. Under this rule, the rate of increase of public spending may not annually exceed the economy s nominal medium-term growth rate. This article analyses these changes. The following section briefly describes the reform of the SGP. The third section analyses the constitutional reform. Section 4 describes the spending rule and illustrates its functioning through a simulation of how such a rule would have worked during the expansion period. Section 5 draws conclusions. The reform of the Stability and Growth Pact The framework of fiscal rules in Spain is firstly defined by the content of the constituent Treaty of the European Union and of the SGP. This framework defines quantitative limits on the deficit and public debt, a compliance oversight and control mechanism (which is known as the preventive arm of the SGP) and a procedure so that countries may correct deviations should they arise (the corrective arm of the SGP). As regards the limits, the budget deficit is required not to exceed 3% of GDP, and public debt to remain below 60% of GDP. Further, under the preventive arm, budget balances should be close to equilibrium or in surplus in the medium term, a clause that has been interpreted as the need to attain and maintain a structural budget balance in equilibrium (the so-called medium-term target ). The medium-term targets are specific to each country and depend, among other factors, on the level of public debt, on potential growth and on implicit liabilities, in particular those derived from population ageing on public finances. Currently, for the euro area countries, these targets stand, in respect of the structural budget balance, at between 0.5% of GDP (in Germany, Ireland, the Netherlands and Portugal) and a surplus of 0.5% (in Belgium, Luxembourg and Finland). In Spain s case, according to the methodology for calculating the medium-term targets agreed upon by the Ecofin in July 2009 [European Commission (2010)], the structural deficit may rise to around 0.5%, and the updated Stability Programme set this target as a structural balance in equilibrium (see Table 1). 1 The preventive arm of the SGP comprises the periodic monitoring of national public finances by the Commission and the Council on the basis of the Stability and Convergence Programmes submitted annually by the Member States. Under these oversight arrangements, the attainment of medium-term targets and the pattern of approach to them are evaluated. The corrective arm establishes a so-called excessive deficit procedure for cases in which the margins are exceeded. This includes the setting of timeframes for correction, the failure to comply with which may lead to various reputational or financial sanctions. 1 Each Member State presents its own medium-term budgetary targets in its stability or convergence programme. This may not exceed the target derived from the agreed calculation methodology, and it is assessed by the Ecofin Council. These targets are revised when a significant structural reform is made and, in any event, every four years. BANCO DE ESPAÑA 4 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

4 BUDGET BALANCE AND PUBLIC DEBT IN THE EURO AREA COUNTRIES TABLE 1 % of GDP Medium-term objectives (a) Structural balance Actual balance Public debt Belgium Germany Estonia Ireland Greece Spain France Italy Cyprus Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Austria Portugal Slovenia Slovakia Finland SOURCES: European Commission (2010) and AMECO. a The medium-term objectives are set in structural balance terms. The experience of the past decade has nevertheless revealed problems with the workings of the SGP, which was not capable of promoting the consolidation of public finances during the expansionary phase (see Table 1). The structural deficit in 2007, the year prior to the economic crisis, stood at 1.7% of GDP in the euro area, a very similar figure to that observed in 1999, when the third phase of EMU began, meaning that only five of the countries today making up the euro area had achieved their medium-term targets (Germany, Spain, Cyprus, Luxembourg and Finland). Also in 2007, eight countries had a public debt ratio above 60%. Departing from this starting point, which was subsequently compounded by the impact of the economic crisis on public finances and on growth prospects, there was a highly significant deterioration in the budgetary situation in most European countries during the crisis. Against the background of the ongoing reform of the European governance framework, the strengthening of the SGP is, therefore, of crucial importance [European Commission (2011)]. The reform that is pending approval 2 firstly envisages reinforcing the preventive arm with the inclusion of spending developments in the evaluation of countries compliance with medium-term budgetary targets. As a result, the growth rate of public spending should not exceed medium-term GDP growth unless it is accompanied by discretionary increases in public revenue. It is sought hereby to prevent, as occurred before the crisis in some countries, a highly favourable trend in public revenue, associ- 2 After a series of meetings between May and September 2011, the European Parliament and the Council reached an agreement on 14 September on governance reform. The Parliament plans to adopt this at its plenary session from 26 to 29 September, and the Council intends to do so on 4 October BANCO DE ESPAÑA 5 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

5 SIMULATION OF PUBLIC DEBT DYNAMICS (a) TABLE 2 % of GDP 1998 Debt 2007 Debt Actual Simulation Belgium Germany Estonia Ireland Greece Spain France Italy Cyprus Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Austria Portugal Slovenia Slovakia Finland SOURCES: AMECO and Banco de España. a This table compares the actual debt ratio of the euro area countries in 1998 and 2007 (columns 2 and 3, respectively) with a simulation based on the debt-reduction proposal in the reformed SGP (column 4). In the simulation, a debt ratio greater than the reference value in year t is reduced in t+1 by 1/20th of the difference between its level and 60%. If the annual reduction observed in the debt ratio were greater than 1/20th in a year, the reduction observed in that year would be maintained. ated with exceptional factors such as an excessive growth of financial and real estate assets, from allowing likewise excessive public spending growth. Indeed, it can be verified that strict compliance with this rule would have led to a much healthier situation in most European countries during the decade prior to the economic crisis [Banco de España (2011)]. Secondly, it is sought to strengthen the public debt criterion, given that it had largely been ignored in the past and in light of the absence of quantitative criteria for the evaluation of its rate of reduction. The reform will require Member States with a level of debt of over 60% of GDP to move more quickly towards their medium-term budgetary targets. Further, Member States with debt ratios that exceed the reference value of 60% of GDP will be subject to the application of the excessive deficit procedure, unless the rate of decline of debt over a given period is considered satisfactory. The Commission has proposed using a numerical criterion to evaluate whether a country s public debt ratio is diminishing at a satisfactory rate. In the three years prior to the assessment, the ratio should have fallen on average by one-twentieth of the amount by which it differs from the reference value of 60%. Table 2 presents a simulation of the dynamics of the public debt/gdp ratio between 1998 and 2007 in the euro area countries, under the assumption that this criterion had been applicable. While in terms of the area as a whole the impact would have been limited, its application would have had a very significant effect on the countries with bigger public debt/gdp ratios. Specifically, Greece and Italy would have reduced this ratio to below 100% in 2007, a level close to 20 pp and 10 pp, respectively, below their actual values. In the case of Belgium, however, the simulations show that the effort made was greater than that required by the rule. BANCO DE ESPAÑA 6 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

6 Thirdly, new reporting obligations and new financial sanctions are included for the euro area countries. These will be applicable beforehand and more gradually, and their approval will be more automatic. Finally, national budgetary frameworks should adjust to a set of minimum requirements relating to public accounting and statistics systems, numerical fiscal rules, forecasting systems, effective medium-term budgetary targets, and the coverage of all general government sub-sectors. Beyond these minimum requirements, the use of top-down budgeting processes will also be promoted, along with the role of fiscal councils, which will be entrusted with providing independent analyses, assessments and projections regarding national fiscal policy matters. Along the same lines, the Euro Plus Pact, signed in April 2011 by the euro area Heads of State and Government to strengthen economic policy coordination in favour of competitiveness and convergence, highlights as one of its essential objectives the need for the Member States to transpose the EU budgetary rules laid down in the SGP into national legislation. In this respect, it is stressed that, although the Member States may select the specific national legal instrument used to bring about this transposition, they must ensure this instrument is sufficiently and soundly binding and durable (e.g. a constitutional or framework law). The exact formulation of the rule will also be decided by each country, although budgetary discipline must be ensured both at the national level and at other regional and local levels. It is in this connection that the recent reform of the budgetary framework in Spain is being undertaken. In fact, the national budgetary framework has been defined since 2001 by the BSL, which was subsequently amended in This legislation sets limits on the deficit that all levels of government may incur. Likewise, it details a procedure for setting and monitoring targets, along with the consequences, if any, in the event of non-compliance (see Box 1 on the content of this legislation). The reforms approved in recent months reinforce this framework with the incorporation of the fiscal limits into our Constitution, along with the introduction of a public spending rule linked to medium-term economic growth. These changes are analysed in detail below. The constitutional reform CONTENT The reform enshrines in the Constitution the obligation for all levels of government to adjust their conduct to the principle of budgetary stability. Specifically, it establishes that the State and regional governments may not incur a structural deficit that exceeds the margins, if any, established by the European Union. Local governments, for their part, must keep their budget in balance. In the case of public debt, its weight in relation to GDP may not exceed the reference value established in the Treaty on European Union, i.e. 60%, and absolute priority is granted to the payment of interest charges and of principal on public debt over other budgetary commitments. The limits on the structural deficit and the volume of public debt may only be exceeded in the event of natural disasters, economic recession or exceptional emergency situations beyond the control of the State and which considerably impair the financial situation or the economic or social sustainability of the State. An absolute majority in Parliament would be required in this situation. The details on these exceptions, the way in which deviations should be corrected and the accountability of each level of government should such deviations occur, the definition of the mechanisms providing for compliance with the limit on debt and the methodology for BANCO DE ESPAÑA 7 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

7 BUDGETARY STABILITY LEGISLATION BOX 1 The budgetary stability legislation (BSL) in Spain sets limits on the deficit that may be incurred by all levels of government and publicsector corporate entities. It likewise details a procedure for setting targets and monitoring them, along with the consequences, if any, of these not being met. Specifically, under the BSL, central government and the regional governments are, along with large municipalities at the local government level 1, obliged to submit a public finances outturn that is in balance over the course of the business cycle. If economic growth of less than 2% is projected 2, the deficit these levels of government may incur shall not exceed 1% of GDP 3. If economic growth is between 2% and 3%, general government must show a budget in balance and, if growth exceeds 3%, a surplus must be run. Moreover, an additional 0.5% can be added to these limits to finance increases in investment, including that earmarked for research, development and innovation. 4 All other municipalities should always show a budget in balance or in surplus. The stability target of the Social Security system shall be set having regard to medium- and long-term population and economic developments. Given the high fiscal decentralisation in Spain, in which the regional and local governments are responsible for a large share of public revenue and spending policies, Spanish regulations establish additional requirements for them. In the case of regional governments, the organic law on funding governing them sets limits on their debt capacity. Specifically, it allows regional governments to enter into credit operations maturing at less than one year to cover temporary cash needs but, for operations maturing at over one year, funds must be earmarked exclusively to investment spending and, moreover, the total amount of the annual repayments may not exceed 25% of the regional government s current revenue. As regards credit operations abroad and public debt issues, prior authorisation from the State is required. Similar limits exist in the case of local government. In addition to the extension of the fiscal rules to the lower tiers of government, the BSL has a clause that says that the State shall not take responsibility for the financing of the deficits or public debt of the lower levels of government. This clause, similar to that at the European level, seeks to prevent the cost of inappropriate fiscal behaviour in one region from feeding through to others or to central government, and it is essential so that capital markets maintain a significant disciplining effect on the basis of discrimination between the risk premia on the debt of the different levels of government. Turning to the target-setting procedure, a report is first drawn up assessing the cyclical phase for the following three years. 5 On this basis, the BSL obliges the government to set, first, the budgetary stability target for the three following years in the first half of each year, both for the general government sector as a whole and for each of the agents comprising it 6 ; and, second, the State spending limit. Both must be approved by Parliament. Once approved, the individual fiscal target for each regional government is set by means of bilateral negotiations between the Ministry of Economy and Finance and the representatives of each regional government on the Fiscal and Financial Policy Council. As to the monitoring procedure, the Ministry of Economy and Finance is required to submit a report to the government before 1 October each year on the degree of compliance with the targets, and on real cyclical developments during the year and deviations from the initial forecast. Should a risk of non-compliance be discerned, a warning may be made to the government agent responsible. If such non-compliance involves a bigger-than-targeted deficit, the level of government in question is also required to draw up an economic and financial rebalancing plan over a maximum term of three years. Lastly, it is stipulated that, if a deviation from targets prompts a breach of the SGP, the tier of government involved shall assume the attendant proportion of the responsibilities that should arise from the breach. In addition, in the case of the regional governments and municipalities, compliance shall be taken into account in the State s authorisation of credit operations and debt issues. Specifically, if the failure to meet the stability target takes the form of a greater-thantargeted deficit, all the regional government s debt operations shall require State authorisation. 7 1 Specifically, those that are provincial or regional capitals, or that have a population equal to or higher than 75,000 inhabitants. 2 These growth thresholds that determine the possibility of attaining a budget in deficit, in balance or in surplus are set, for a period of three years, by the Council of Ministers, on the proposal of the Minister of Economy and Finance and further to a report by the Council of Fiscal and Financial Policy of the Regional Governments and the National Local Government Board. 3 Breaking down into a ceiling of 0.2% of GDP for central government, 0.75% of GDP for the regional governments as a whole and 0.05% of GDP for large municipalities. 4 This additional 0.5% of GDP breaks down into 0.2% of GDP for central government, 0.25% of GDP for the regional governments as a whole and 0.05% for the above-mentioned municipalities. 5 This report is drafted by the Ministry of Economy and Finance, following consultation with the National Statistics Institute and with the Banco de España on the cyclical position of the Spanish economy, and taking into account the projections of the European Central Bank and of the European Commission. 6 The Ministry of Economy and Finance is also entrusted with formulating the proposed stability target for the regional governments as a whole and for local governments. This proposal follows prior reports by the Fiscal and Financial Policy Council and the National Local Government Board, respectively, before being approved by the Government. 7 However, if the regional government had submitted the economic and financial plan to the Fiscal and Financial Policy Council and the measures contained therein had been declared suitable by the Council, State authorisation for short-term credit operations that are not deemed to be external financing would not be required. BANCO DE ESPAÑA 8 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

8 LEGAL BASIS OF THE FISCAL RULES (a) TABLE 3 Types of scal rule Spending Revenue Balance Debt Political commitments Coalition agreements Legal International treaties Constitution 4 3 TOTAL SOURCE: IMF (2009), Fiscal rules: Anchoring expectations for sustainable public nances. a The totals for some columns may give rise to a number higher than the total number of countries with rules, since several rues are applied simultaneously in many countries. calculating the structural deficit shall be established in an implementing organic law that shall be approved before 30 June The reform shall enter into force as of the day of its publication in the Official State Gazette, accepting the structural deficit limits, which shall be applicable from ANALYSIS OF THE REFORM Constitutional rank The main novelty of the reform in relation to the pre-existing fiscal framework is the incorporation into the Constitution of the deficit and public debt limits set at the European level. In this respect, the economic literature stresses that a higher legal order may improve the effectiveness of the rule, arguing that this hampers the capacity of the particular government in power to eliminate or amend it, given that this normally requires broader Parliamentary majorities. Moreover, constitutional rank gives the rule supremacy over other legislation drawn up by national parliaments, meaning that such legislation must be drafted in a manner compatible with the fiscal limits included in the rule. The empirical evidence available on this issue is scant and not sufficiently conclusive, given that very few countries have incorporated their fiscal rule into the Constitution (see Table 3). For the EU, Iara and Wolf (2010) find that the greater the rank of the legislation in which fiscal limits are set, the more effective they are. Yet for the United States, in contrast, it does not seem that the incorporation into the Constitution in certain States has given rise to significant effects in terms of budgetary discipline [Hou and Smith (2010)]. 3 In Spain s case, the high degree of fiscal decentralisation prevailing may be an additional argument in favour of constitutional rank, since it makes it easier for the requirement to be made of all levels of government, and in particular the regional and local governments. Indeed, the Spanish constitutional rule covers, as did the budgetary stability legislation, all tiers of government, mentioning explicitly central government, the regional governments and the local governments. 4 3 The evidence for the United States is, in principle, sounder than that available for the EU, since it is based on long periods of time ( ) in which there are more observations with fiscal rules incorporated into the Constitution of the Federated States. 4 In the case of Social Security Funds, the implementing organic law will have to detail what is understood by budgetary stability. It should be recalled that the BSL establishes that the stability target for the Social Security system should be set having regard to medium- and long-term population and economic projections. It would have been an option to include this definition in the Constitution, which would have given constitutional cover to the need to ensure the sustainability of the pensions system in the medium and long term on the basis of the population and macroeconomic projections available. BANCO DE ESPAÑA 9 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

9 The limit on the budget deficit in structural terms As to the choice of the target variable for the rule, the reform refers to the budget deficit in structural terms 5, but it does not set an explicit numerical limit as is the case, for example, in the German constitution, but refers rather to the margins established by the European Union. As indicated in the previous section, the main limit on the structural deficit existing at the European level is that included in the preventive arm of the SGP, which establishes the need to attain the medium-term target, which in Spain s case was defined by the Stability Programme as a structural balance in equilibrium. In any event, the size of this target depends on the level of public debt, potential growth and implicit liabilities. And a structural surplus might indeed be required if the country were to have, for instance, a high public debt/gdp ratio or if medium-and long-term growth prospects were to worsen. The reference to the European Union could be understood along the lines that, were Spain to find itself in these circumstances, the constitutional requirement might come to entail the requirement of a structural surplus. Furthermore, it can add greater flexibility to the setting of targets, aligning them automatically to European agreements. In any event, the political agreement accompanying the constitutional reform establishes that the limits on the structural deficit will be set in an organic law and will be 0.4% of GDP (0.26% corresponding to the State and 0.14% to the regional governments), a figure slightly above the medium-term target set in the Stability Programme, but which observes the figure defined according to the calculation methodology agreed upon. This figure is similar to that set in the reform of the German constitution, which places it at 0.35% of GDP for the annual cyclically adjusted central government deficit, while in the case of the federal Länder, it is 0%. In Spain s case, the setting of the numerical ceiling and its distribution between State and regional government under the law involves allowing these limits to be amended, like any organic law, by an absolute Parliamentary majority, compared with the three-fifths figure that amendment of the Constitution requires. 6 The definition of the limit in respect of the structural deficit adds a practical difficulty, since this variable is not observable and must be estimated. 7 Specifically, the calculation of the structural deficit is obtained as the difference between the observed deficit and the cyclical deficit 8, and the latter is calculated by applying the public revenue and spending elasticities to the deviation, or output gap, between actual GDP and potential or trend GDP. However, estimates of the output gap and of the elasticity of public revenue and spending are not free from controversy, given that there are different methods available in the economic literature that also show different results. The reform stipulates that it will be the implementing organic law that determines the methodology and procedure for the calculation of the structural deficit. It would be advisable to choose a method that were readily replicable and one that could be made available to all analysts. In the case of the German constitutional reform, it was decided, for example, to apply the same method currently used in the European Union, developed jointly by the European Commission and the Member States. In the case of the output gap it should moreover be taken into account that the estimates require macroeconomic projections and are frequently subject to revision following the inclusion of new available information or data arising from forecasting errors, which may also 5 The constitutional text makes no reference to the actual deficit. In any event, the 3% ceiling in the EU Treaty remains applicable. 6 In this respect, the political agreement accompanying the constitutional reform indicates that the limits relating to the structural deficit, and the path for attaining the debt target in 2020, may be subject to revision in 2015 and in 2018, on the initiative of any of the parties subscribing to this agreement. 7 Nor was the arrangement established under the stability law free from problems, given that it necessarily involved setting the thresholds determined by the surplus, equilibrium or deficit requirement. 8 The calculation of the structural balance further requires adjusting the latter for temporary or exceptional factors. BANCO DE ESPAÑA 10 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

10 alter the calculations of the structural deficit. It is therefore necessary to establish the treatment of these revisions. 9 Generally, calculations of the structural deficit should be based on prudent estimates of the economy s potential output growth, estimates that avoid viewing as structural improvements in the budget deficit those that are merely cyclical. The main advantage of using the deficit in structural terms is that it allows the stabilising role of fiscal policy to be maintained (see Chart 1). 10 In fact, the cyclical component of the deficit diminishes (increases) in periods of economic expansion (recession), given that public revenue tends to grow (diminish) and public spending to fall (increase) simply due to the operation of the automatic stabilisers, generating a stabilising effect on the economy. The constitutional limits would allow for countercyclical discretionary fiscal policy conduct, beyond that derived from the automatic stabilisers, but that would call for the attainment of structural surpluses in economic boom times. Setting the limit in terms of the structural deficit offers some advantages over the current BSL, which establishes the need for a surplus, a balanced budget or a deficit in terms of real GDP growth thresholds. In particular, these thresholds create undesirable elements of discontinuity. For instance, a growth forecast of 1.9% enabled a deficit of up to 1% to be budgeted (without including the productive investment deficit), whereas, if growth onetenth of a point higher is projected, a budget in balance would have to be provided for. Furthermore, there was no direct relationship between growth above the threshold set on the amount of the surplus, meaning that it could not be ensured that a continuous period of expansion would materialise in a sizeable surplus (a surplus of 0.1% of GDP was sufficient to comply with the rule). Conversely, the new definition requires that, in times of economic boom, the entire portion relating to the cyclical balance should be saved and this, moreover, will be proportionate to the economic expansion (see Chart 1). Generally, it could be said that the new rule will require higher surpluses than those arising from the BSL in expansion periods. For example, on the basis of an elasticity of the deficit with respect to the output gap of 0.4, in a situation of a positive output gap to an order equivalent to 3% of GDP, the fiscal surplus will have to be at least 0.8%, while in the case of the BSL, a surplus of 0.1% would suffice (provided that real GDP growth exceeded 3%). Moreover, the ceiling of 1.5% for the total deficit under the current BSL is eliminated, giving more headroom in periods of recession. For example, if a negative output gap of 5% of GDP is reached, the new arrangement would allow a deficit of up to 2.4% of GDP. Another difference between the new rule and the BSL is that the new structural limits cannot be altered by the presence of investment spending. There are arguments that warrant leaving public investment outside the definition of the rule (in application of what is known as the golden rule ), which are based above all on the fact that there is evidence showing that this type of expenditure may exert positive effects on growth in the long run. However, 9 In the case of the German constitutional rule, the ex post result of the structural balance is adjusted for the error in the projection of real GDP. In the case of the Swiss constitutional rule, however, when a deviation from the limit in the rule arises as a result of a forecasting error, this is included in full in a notional account. 10 In the case of local governments, the ceiling is set in terms of the observed deficit. This is the criterion that was also adhered to by the BSL, although in this case the biggest municipal councils were actually allowed to run a deficit of 0.5% of GDP when economic growth was less than 2%. Local government revenue may show something of a cyclical response in its behaviour, given that they have a share in State tax revenue (depending on how the latter trends) and, in the case of the large municipalities, a percentage of personal income tax, VAT and excise duties are transferred to them. Accordingly, compliance with the limits set in the Constitution will mean that these municipalities will have to attain a structural surplus in periods of expansion, allowing them to offset the adverse impact on revenue-raising capacity in economic slowdowns, without having to apply compensatory adjustment measures. BANCO DE ESPAÑA 11 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

11 OUTPUT GAP, CYCLICAL BUDGET AND CONSTITUTIONAL RULE CHART % of GDP OUTPUT GAP CYCLICAL BUDGET CONSTITUTIONAL LIMIT ON THE STRUCTURAL BALANCE SOURCE: AMECO. excluding investment spending also poses problems. Firstly, not all investment spending is necessarily productive. Secondly, there is expenditure classified as current that may have even greater effects on long-term productivity (for example, education spending). Further, the accounting distinction between current and capital expenditure is not always easy, whereby excluding investment spending may generate incentives to record current expenditure in this latter group. Indeed, some countries that had golden rules in the past, such as the United Kingdom and Germany, have recently scrapped them. The limit on public debt The reform establishes an explicit limit on public debt, further reinforcing the commitment to budgetary discipline. Public debt is, in fact, the key variable for measuring the sustainability of public finances; and, given that the need to meet the debt criterion in the Stability Pact has in the past been subject to a milder interpretation than in the case of the deficit, the introduction of a constitutional limit may confer operability on the European requirement in Spain s case. Moreover, this prevents those budgetary transactions that are not accounted for in the budget deficit, but which do give rise to an increase in borrowing needs, from remaining outside the scope of the rule. The Constitution further establishes that the procedure for reducing the public debt/gdp ratio if it exceeds the European ceiling will be detailed in the implementing organic law. This procedure should adhere, at least, to the arrangements laid down in the new reform of the Stability Pact for the reduction of excess debt above 60% of GDP. As to the priority given to the payment of the interest and principal on public debt over other expenditure, this may prove particularly significant in circumstances such as the present in which the markets are most sensitive to the possibilities of sovereign debt default. The possibility of deviations from the limits Broadly, establishing exceptions to compliance with fiscal limits is considered to be desirable and can reinforce the credibility of compliance, provided these exceptions are clearly defined. In the case of constitutional reform, the definition of these exceptions and the need for Parliamentary approval of the circumstances giving rise to the exceptionality are very similar, for example, to those of the German constitution, the sole difference being that, in Spain s case, explicit mention is made among the exceptions of economic recession. In this respect, it should be recalled that the Treaty on European Union states that deficits above 3% are not considered excessive provided that the failure to comply is of scant significance, temporary and due to exceptional circumstances, such as a serious economic recession for instance. Following the 2005 reform of the SGP, a serious reces- BANCO DE ESPAÑA 12 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

12 sion is defined as a negative year-on-year growth rate of real GDP or a cumulative loss of output over a prolonged period of very low real GDP growth relative to potential growth. Moreover, it is important that the organic law should make clearly explicit the temporary path that should be followed to place the deficit once more within the established limits, once the deviations have come about. The Spanish constitutional reform does not explicitly consider the treatment of the potential deviations that may come about. In this respect, the German constitutional rule, like Switzerland s, includes in its implementing legislation a mechanism whereby any ex post deviation from the structural balance target (positive or negative) is accumulated in a notional account. In Switzerland s case, the government must take adjustment measures if this account has a negative balance exceeding 6% of expenditure (i.e. around 0.6 pp of GDP), placing it below this limit in the following three years. In Germany s case, adjustment measures must be taken as soon as the notional account reaches 1%, but only if economic conditions allow. 11 Monitoring, control and compliance mechanisms The economic literature stresses that to ensure the success of fiscal rules, it is vital to have the appropriate monitoring and control mechanisms, and the capacity to impose or encourage compliance. In Spain s case, these procedures should also be laid down in the implementing organic law of the constitutional text. In relation to monitoring the rule, it is particularly important that the mechanisms set in place should allow early identification, within the fiscal year, of the risks to meeting the budgetary targets. As to the mechanisms for encouraging or forcing through compliance, the constitutional reform indicates that the implementing organic law should regulate the responsibility of each government level in the event of non-compliance with the budgetary stability targets, which might be interpreted as the possibility of including sanctions. Sanctions are, in fact, a mechanism that could encourage compliance. However, the evidence shows that it is not easy to define them in a manner that makes their application credible, as the case of the SGP demonstrated. In this respect, and as indicated in the second section, the reform of the Pact includes the proposal whereby sanctions should be decided beforehand and more automatically so that their applicability is enhanced. A further instrument that might prove very effective would be clauses providing for the automatic adjustment of specific revenue and expenditure items in the event of the established fiscal targets failing to be met. 12 Transitory period Finally, as regards the entry into force of the rule, the definition of a transitory procedure would be reasonable given the high budget deficit levels prevailing at the time of approval of the constitutional reform. The transitory period is somewhat longer in Spain s case than was set in Germany, at least in the case of central government. That might be warranted by the different starting position in terms of the budget deficit, although the extension to 2020 in the case of limits on the structural deficit might prove more than accommodating. It should be borne in mind that the latest Stability Programme set an overall general government structural deficit of 1.9% in 2014, whereby, if this target is met, attaining a structural deficit of 0.4% in 2020 will entail a limited fiscal effort. 11 The control account may not exceed 1.5% of GDP and, moreover, deviations during the year may not exceed 3% of budgetary revenue. In the year after this increase in the control account of above 1%, the deficit must be reduced by the amount by which it exceeds 1%, but not by an amount in excess of 0.35%. This obligation is only applicable to the years in which there is a positive output gap or the negative output gap is diminishing. 12 The content of single additional provision 2 of the constitutional reform may give rise to the introduction of these mechanisms in the implementing organic law, indicating that this law shall envisage the mechanisms that allow compliance with the debt limit referred to in article BANCO DE ESPAÑA 13 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

13 PUBLIC DEBT SCENARIO CHART 2 80 % of GDP SOURCE: Banco de España. The political agreement accompanying the constitutional reform indicates, moreover, a 60% ceiling on public debt as a target to be met in Chart 2 illustrates how this ratio might be attained on the basis of a series of assumptions. 13 Evidently, under harsher macroeconomic scenarios the fiscal adjustment needed to place public debt at 60% in 2020 will be greater. Even under the macroeconomic scenario simulated, a greater adjustment of the structural deficit, that were to anticipate the time at which the constitutional limit were reached, would allow a swifter reduction in the public debt ratio, meaning that room for manoeuvre would be gained to face potentially adverse situations without the risk of breaching the 60% ceiling again. The new spending rule Before the constitutional reform, in July 2011, a ceiling on public spending growth was introduced into the national budgetary framework with a definition very similar to that included in the preventive arm of the SGP. This spending rule, now in force, is a very useful complement to the constitutional debt and deficit margins. Indeed, the experience in some other developed countries shows that the most successful fiscal frameworks are those that combine the budget deficit rule with explicit limits on public spending [IMF (2009) and Ljungman (2008)]. The usefulness of the latter is that it is directed at the habitual source of budget deficits. Specifically, the ex ante setting of a maximum amount of spending adds discipline to the budgeting for each spending unit, and these units thus have less leeway to exert upward pressure through their individual demands. Moreover, ex post this enables the increase in revenue in better-than-expected cyclical situations to be saved and, if the rule is well-defined and transparent, the spending components that generate deviations can be identified. Defining a spending rule is not, however, free from difficulty and the definition may impair its effectiveness. Specifically, among the different elements that make up its definition, the choice of the variable that acts as a reference for setting boundaries on its permitted course is one of 13 In particular, strict compliance with the macroeconomic and fiscal projections in the latest Stability Programme is assumed. That would entail placing the budget deficit at 2.1% of GDP and the public debt ratio at 68.9% in Subsequently, an annual 0.3% adjustment of the structural deficit is assumed, taking it to 0.4% in 2020 as established by the reform. Under the assumption of a zero contribution to the change in debt of the difference between GDP growth and the implicit interest rate on debt, a deficit-debt adjustment of 0.5% of GDP per annum and a trajectory that would see the output gap close in 2015 to subsequently turn positive and reached 2% in 2020, the public debt/gdp ratio would stand below 60% in BANCO DE ESPAÑA 14 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

14 the most important. In principle, given that public revenue shows approximately unit elasticity with respect to nominal GDP, a growth in spending linked to this variable would ensure, if the starting point is a budgetary position in balance, that this position were maintained in the future. Evidently, if the starting point is a budget deficit, resuming a balanced budget will require spending growth below nominal growth until such equilibrium is attained. However, to avoid procyclical behaviour in public spending, selecting annual GDP growth as a reference should be avoided, replacing it instead with a measure of the economy s potential growth. Under the rule approved in Spain, the annual increase in spending may not exceed the increase in real GDP over the medium term, which is defined, for each year, as the average of the real GDP growth rates envisaged in the Stability Programme for the current year and the three following years and those recorded in the five previous years, i.e. as an average of growth rates over nine years, which may be considered as an approximation to potential growth. 14 In any event, given that the constitutional reform will also require the estimation of this variable for the calculation of the structural deficit, its definition in the spending rule should desirably be compatible with the methodology used in the estimation. As to the nominal component of GDP to be taken as a reference, in principle the annual growth of the GDP deflator could be used. Nonetheless, that might allow very high spending increases as a result of the existence of likewise very high inflation. To avoid this problem, some limit could be set on the increase in the deflator incorporated into the rule (e.g. that compatible with the ECB s definition of price stability). Along the same lines, it has been decided in the case of the rule approved to set growth in the GDP deflator of 1.75% as a reference, which would add a disciplining element to the future course of public spending. The rule likewise states that the permitted growth in spending should be adjusted for the estimated impact of planned discretionary tax measures; as a result, when regulatory changes involving increases (reductions) in revenue are approved, the limit on spending increases (falls) by the equivalent amount. This adjustment is fully warranted in that it accommodates growth in spending to changes in revenue and prevents fiscal imbalances from arising further to the approval, for example, of tax cuts not accompanied by equivalent cuts in spending. However, it should be taken into account that estimating the impact of tax changes on revenue is not straightforward and ex ante estimates may differ greatly from actual results. Accordingly, it would be advisable periodically to conduct an ex post analysis and to adjust spending growth to the potential deviations that may arise. As regards the spending components subject to the limit, it has been decided, firstly, to exclude interest payments, which is justified by the fact that this variable is beyond the control of the fiscal authority, at least in the short run. Further, non-discretionary expenditure on unemployment benefits is excluded, which will prevent any procyclical bias in the application of the rule. 15 However, this exclusion runs the risk of leaving out rises in expenditure derived from a structural increase in unemployment, which will not be corrected with cyclical developments. 14 Some problems may be encountered with this definition. Specifically, the five years backwards that are taken may not be representative of potential growth if a structural change takes place. Moreover, taking projections for the current year and three ahead may cause added problems given that it is a stylised fact in the literature that it is difficult to capture changes in the business cycle. Further, the use of projections may cause some risk of excessive growth in spending if the projections prove optimistic. 15 For instance, in an economic slowdown there would be an increase in spending on unemployment benefits. If the rule is applied to this definition of spending, that would mean that, to ensure compliance, other spending items would have to be adjusted to compensate for the total spending growth exceeding that set in the rule, causing a procyclical bias therein. BANCO DE ESPAÑA 15 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, OCTOBER 2011 THE REFORM OF THE FISCAL FRAMEWORK IN SPAIN

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001 4 The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 200 Tina Winther Frandsen, International Relations INTRODUCTION The EU member states' public finances showed remarkable development during the 990s. In 993, the

More information

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION 2014 DRAFT BUDGETARY PLANS OF THE EURO AREA: OVERALL ASSESSMENT OF THE BUDGETARY SITUATION AND PROSPECTS

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION 2014 DRAFT BUDGETARY PLANS OF THE EURO AREA: OVERALL ASSESSMENT OF THE BUDGETARY SITUATION AND PROSPECTS EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 15.11.2013 COM(2013) 900 final COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION 2014 DRAFT BUDGETARY PLANS OF THE EURO AREA: OVERALL ASSESSMENT OF THE BUDGETARY SITUATION AND PROSPECTS EN

More information

NATIONAL FISCAL GOVERNANCE

NATIONAL FISCAL GOVERNANCE EUROPEAN SEMESTER THEMATIC FACTSHEET NATIONAL FISCAL GOVERNANCE 1. INTRODUCTION The conduct of budgetary policy is the competence of EU Member States. At European level, common commitments have been taken

More information

The role of regional, national and EU budgets in the Economic and Monetary Union

The role of regional, national and EU budgets in the Economic and Monetary Union SPEECH/06/620 Embargo: 16h00 Joaquín Almunia European Commissioner for Economic and Monetary Policy The role of regional, national and EU budgets in the Economic and Monetary Union 5 th Thematic Dialogue

More information

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL. Current state of the excessive deficit procedure in the Member States

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL. Current state of the excessive deficit procedure in the Member States EN EN EN EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 27.1.2011 COM(2011) 22 final COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL Current state of the excessive deficit procedure in the Member States and assessment

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Finland. Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Finland. Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 16.11.2015 COM(2015) 803 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Finland Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty EN EN REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Finland

More information

Kristina Budimir 1 Debt Crisis in the EU Member States and Fiscal Rules

Kristina Budimir 1 Debt Crisis in the EU Member States and Fiscal Rules Kristina Budimir 1 Debt Crisis in the EU Member States and Fiscal Rules The financial turmoil in September 2008 provoked an economic downturn with a sharp slump in production, followed by slow growth resulting

More information

Lecture 15. Fiscal Policy and the Stability Pact

Lecture 15. Fiscal Policy and the Stability Pact Lecture 15 Fiscal Policy and the Stability Pact The Fiscal Policy Instrument In a monetary union, the fiscal instrument assumes greater importance: the only macroeconomic policy instrument left at the

More information

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL. on the effective enforcement of budgetary surveillance in the euro area

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL. on the effective enforcement of budgetary surveillance in the euro area EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 29.9.2010 COM(2010) 524 final 2010/0278 (COD) Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL on the effective enforcement of budgetary surveillance

More information

74 ECB THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE

74 ECB THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE Box 7 THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE This year s European Semester (i.e. the framework for EU policy coordination introduced in 2011) includes, for the first time, the implementation of the

More information

REPORT ON AUSTRIA S COMPLIANCE WITH EU FISCAL RULES

REPORT ON AUSTRIA S COMPLIANCE WITH EU FISCAL RULES REPORT ON AUSTRIA S COMPLIANCE WITH EU FISCAL RULES This report evaluates the update of the federal government s Austrian Stability Programme for the period 2013 to 2018 as at April 2014. It focuses on

More information

EMU G overnance: Governance: Fiscal Fiscal Policy

EMU G overnance: Governance: Fiscal Fiscal Policy EMU Governance: Fiscal Policy Francesco Saraceno MPA - 2012 1 Outline What is Fiscal Policy (trivial) The role of Fiscal Policy (less trivial) Some Definitions i i (boring boring!) Fiscal Policy in the

More information

Opinion of the Monetary Policy Council on the 2014 Draft Budget Act

Opinion of the Monetary Policy Council on the 2014 Draft Budget Act Warsaw, November 19, 2013 Opinion of the Monetary Policy Council on the 2014 Draft Budget Act Fiscal policy is of prime importance to the Monetary Policy Council in terms of ensuring an appropriate coordination

More information

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES. Recommendation for a COUNCIL OPINION

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES. Recommendation for a COUNCIL OPINION EN EN EN COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES Brussels, 19.02.2008 SEC(2008) 221 Recommendation for a COUNCIL OPINION in accordance with the third paragraph of Article 5 of Council Regulation (EC) No

More information

End of year fiscal report. November 2008

End of year fiscal report. November 2008 End of year fiscal report November 2008 End of year fiscal report November 2008 Crown copyright 2008 The text in this document (excluding the Royal Coat of Arms and departmental logos) may be reproduced

More information

Commission takes steps under the excessive deficit procedure for France, Greece, Ireland, Spain and UK; assesses Stability Programme of Cyprus

Commission takes steps under the excessive deficit procedure for France, Greece, Ireland, Spain and UK; assesses Stability Programme of Cyprus IP/09/458 Brussels, 24 March 2009 Commission takes steps under the excessive deficit procedure for France, Greece, Ireland, Spain and UK; assesses Stability Programme of Cyprus Following the assessment,

More information

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL. Assessment of the action taken

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL. Assessment of the action taken EN EN EN EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 15.6.2010 COM(2010) 329 COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL Assessment of the action taken by Belgium, the Czech Republic, Germany, Ireland, Spain, France,

More information

QUARTERLY REPORT ON THE SPANISH ECONOMY 1 OVERVIEW

QUARTERLY REPORT ON THE SPANISH ECONOMY 1 OVERVIEW QUARTERLY REPORT ON THE SPANISH ECONOMY OVERVIEW The first quarter of 3 saw a continuation of the pattern of contraction in economic activity, albeit at a slacker pace than in the final stretch of. On

More information

Testimony before the Non-Standing Committee for the Monitoring and Assessment of the Toledo Pact Agreements

Testimony before the Non-Standing Committee for the Monitoring and Assessment of the Toledo Pact Agreements Madrid, 15 April 2009 Testimony before the Non-Standing Committee for the Monitoring and Assessment of the Toledo Pact Agreements Miguel Fernández Ordóñez Governor Five years since the last assessment

More information

COMMISSION OPINION. of on the Draft Budgetary Plan of Italy and requesting Italy to submit a revised Draft Budgetary Plan

COMMISSION OPINION. of on the Draft Budgetary Plan of Italy and requesting Italy to submit a revised Draft Budgetary Plan EUROPEAN COMMISSION Strasbourg, 23.10.2018 C(2018) 7510 final COMMISSION OPINION of 23.10.2018 on the Draft Budgetary Plan of Italy and requesting Italy to submit a revised Draft Budgetary Plan EN EN COMMISSION

More information

46 ECB FISCAL CHALLENGES FROM POPULATION AGEING: NEW EVIDENCE FOR THE EURO AREA

46 ECB FISCAL CHALLENGES FROM POPULATION AGEING: NEW EVIDENCE FOR THE EURO AREA Box 4 FISCAL CHALLENGES FROM POPULATION AGEING: NEW EVIDENCE FOR THE EURO AREA Ensuring the long-term sustainability of public finances in the euro area and its member countries is a prerequisite for the

More information

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 29.9.2010 COM(2010) 526 final 2010/0280 (COD) Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL amending Regulation (EC) No 1466/97 on the strengthening

More information

EXPENDITURE RULES. Database

EXPENDITURE RULES. Database EXPENDITURE RULES Fiscal (or budgetary) rules regulate the development of public budget deficits and surpluses (see DICE Report 2/2004), without explicit reference to s or revenues. The revenue side is

More information

Previsions Macroeconòmiques. Macroeconomic scenario for the Catalan economy 2017 and June 2017

Previsions Macroeconòmiques. Macroeconomic scenario for the Catalan economy 2017 and June 2017 PM Previsions Macroeconòmiques Macroeconomic scenario for the Catalan economy 2017 and 2018 June 2017 Previsions macroeconòmiques Macroeconomic scenario for the Catalan economy June 2017 ISSN: 2013-2182

More information

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Slovakia. Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Slovakia. Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty EN EN EN COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES Brussels, SEC(2009) 1276 REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Slovakia Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty EN EN 1. THE APPLICATION OF

More information

PUBLIC FINANCE IN THE EU: FROM THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA TO THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT

PUBLIC FINANCE IN THE EU: FROM THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA TO THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT 8 : FROM THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA TO THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT Ing. Zora Komínková, CSc., National Bank of Slovakia With this contribution, we open up a series of articles on public finance

More information

Official Journal of the European Union L 140/11

Official Journal of the European Union L 140/11 27.5.2013 Official Journal of the European Union L 140/11 REGULATION (EU) No 473/2013 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 21 May 2013 on common provisions for monitoring and assessing draft

More information

10: The European Monetary Union. Baldwin&Wyplosz The Economics of European Integration

10: The European Monetary Union. Baldwin&Wyplosz The Economics of European Integration 10: The European Monetary Union The importance of credibility The theory OCA leaves out the issue of credibility in the conduct of monetary policy. Inflation depends on the expectations of economic agents

More information

QUARTERLY REPORT ON THE SPANISH ECONOMY OVERVIEW

QUARTERLY REPORT ON THE SPANISH ECONOMY OVERVIEW QUARTERLY REPORT ON THE SPANISH ECONOMY OVERVIEW During 13 the Spanish economy moved on a gradually improving path that enabled it to exit the contractionary phase dating back to early 11. This came about

More information

Ex-Post Assessment of Compliance. with the Domestic Budgetary Rule in 2016

Ex-Post Assessment of Compliance. with the Domestic Budgetary Rule in 2016 Ex-Post Assessment of Compliance with the Domestic Budgetary Rule in 2016 May 2017 1 Irish Fiscal Advisory Council 2017 This report can be downloaded at www.fiscalcouncil.ie 2 Background The Fiscal Responsibility

More information

Introduction. Key results of the EU s 2018 Ageing Report. Europe. 2 July 2018

Introduction. Key results of the EU s 2018 Ageing Report. Europe. 2 July 2018 Europe 2 July 2018 The EU s 2018 Ageing Report and the outlook for Germany The analysis of the European Union s latest Ageing Report provided in the Finance Ministry s June 2018 monthly report shows that

More information

THE SUSTAINABILITY OF MALTESE GOVERNMENT DEBT: 2018Q1 UPDATE

THE SUSTAINABILITY OF MALTESE GOVERNMENT DEBT: 2018Q1 UPDATE THE SUSTAINABILITY OF MALTESE GOVERNMENT DEBT: 2018Q1 UPDATE Article published in the Annual Report 2017, pp. 69-76 BOX 4: THE SUSTAINABILITY OF MALTESE GOVERNMENT DEBT: 2018Q1 UPDATE 1 The global financial

More information

1. IMF Article IV interim mission to the euro area. Eurogroup The President. Brussels, 13 December To the members of the Eurogroup

1. IMF Article IV interim mission to the euro area. Eurogroup The President. Brussels, 13 December To the members of the Eurogroup Eurogroup The President Brussels, 13 December 2018 ecfin.cef.cpe(2018)7002171 To the members of the Eurogroup Subject: Eurogroup meeting of 3 December 2018 Dear colleagues, I would like to share with you

More information

A review of the surplus target, SOU 2016:67

A review of the surplus target, SOU 2016:67 Summary A review of the surplus target, SOU 2016:67 In Sweden there is broad political consensus on the fiscal policy framework. This consensus is based on experiences from the deep economic crisis in

More information

PUBLIC LIMITE EN COUNCILOF THEEUROPEANUNION. Brusels,9July2012 (OR.en) 12171/12 LIMITE ECOFIN669 UEM252

PUBLIC LIMITE EN COUNCILOF THEEUROPEANUNION. Brusels,9July2012 (OR.en) 12171/12 LIMITE ECOFIN669 UEM252 ConseilUE COUNCILOF THEEUROPEANUNION Brusels,9July2012 (OR.en) 12171/12 PUBLIC LIMITE ECOFIN669 UEM252 LEGISLATIVEACTSANDOTHERINSTRUMENTS Subject: COUNCILRECOMMENDATIONwithaviewtobringinganendtothe situationofanexcesivegovernmentdeficitinspain

More information

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Portugal. Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Portugal. Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES Brussels, 7 October 2009 SEC(2009) 1274 REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Portugal Report prepared in accordance with Article 104(3) of the Treaty 1. THE APPLICATION OF

More information

Recent Developments in fiscal governance in the EU. Lessons from the crisis: from the Six- Pack to the Fiscal Compact

Recent Developments in fiscal governance in the EU. Lessons from the crisis: from the Six- Pack to the Fiscal Compact Recent Developments in fiscal governance in the EU Lessons from the crisis: from the Six- Pack to the Fiscal Compact The Crisis as en eye opener A comprehensive EU response to the crisis More effective

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Denmark. Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Denmark. Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 12.05.2010 SEC(2010) 585 REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Denmark Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Denmark Report prepared

More information

Assessment of the 2018 Stability Programme for. Portugal

Assessment of the 2018 Stability Programme for. Portugal EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE GENERAL ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL AFFAIRS Brussels, 23 May 2018 Assessment of the 2018 Stability Programme for Portugal (Note prepared by DG ECFIN staff) 1 CONTENTS 1. INTRODUCTION...

More information

Testimony by the Governor of the Banco de España before Parliament in relation to the Draft State and Social Security Budget for 2019

Testimony by the Governor of the Banco de España before Parliament in relation to the Draft State and Social Security Budget for 2019 8 January 19 Testimony by the Governor of the Banco de España before Parliament in relation to the Draft State and Social Security Budget for 19 Pablo Hernández de Cos Governor TESTIMONY BY THE GOVERNOR

More information

Fiscal rules in Lithuania

Fiscal rules in Lithuania Fiscal rules in Lithuania Algimantas Rimkūnas Vice Minister, Ministry of Finance of Lithuania 3 June, 2016 Evolution of National and EU Fiscal Regulations Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) Maastricht Treaty

More information

Statistical revisions a European perspective

Statistical revisions a European perspective Statistical revisions a European perspective Gabriel Quirós, Julia Catz, Wim Haine and Nuno Silva 1, 2 1. Introduction Timeliness and reliability are important quality criteria for official statistics,

More information

Revista Economică 69:4 (2017) TOWARDS SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT: REAL CONVERGENCE AND GROWTH IN ROMANIA. Felicia Elisabeta RUGEA 1

Revista Economică 69:4 (2017) TOWARDS SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT: REAL CONVERGENCE AND GROWTH IN ROMANIA. Felicia Elisabeta RUGEA 1 TOWARDS SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT: REAL CONVERGENCE AND GROWTH IN ROMANIA Felicia Elisabeta RUGEA 1 West University of Timișoara Abstract The complexity of the current global economy requires a holistic

More information

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES. Recommendation for a COUNCIL OPINION

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES. Recommendation for a COUNCIL OPINION EN EN EN COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES Brussels, 30 January 2008 SEC(2008) 107 final Recommendation for a COUNCIL OPINION in accordance with the third paragraph of Article 5 of Council Regulation

More information

Chapter 17: Economic and monetary policy The acquis in the area of fiscal policy

Chapter 17: Economic and monetary policy The acquis in the area of fiscal policy Chapter 17: Economic and monetary policy The acquis in the area of fiscal policy Brussels, 2 December 2014 DG ECFIN, Fiscal policy and surveillance 1 European Commission Outline I. Stability and Growth

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Finland. Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Finland. Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 18.5.2016 COM(2016) 292 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Finland Report prepared in accordance with Article 126(3) of the Treaty EN EN REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION Finland Report

More information

Recommendation for a COUNCIL IMPLEMENTING DECISION. imposing a fine on Spain for failure to take effective action to address an excessive deficit

Recommendation for a COUNCIL IMPLEMENTING DECISION. imposing a fine on Spain for failure to take effective action to address an excessive deficit EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 27.7.2016 COM(2016) 517 final Recommendation for a COUNCIL IMPLEMENTING DECISION imposing a fine on Spain for failure to take effective action to address an excessive deficit

More information

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. Analysis of the 2016 Draft Budgetary Plan of GERMANY. Accompanying the document COMMISSION OPINION

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. Analysis of the 2016 Draft Budgetary Plan of GERMANY. Accompanying the document COMMISSION OPINION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 16.11.2015 SWD(2015) 601 final COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Analysis of the 2016 Draft Budgetary Plan of GERMANY Accompanying the document COMMISSION OPINION on the Draft

More information

THE DEFICIT OF THE EU MEMBER STATES IN THE EURO AREA

THE DEFICIT OF THE EU MEMBER STATES IN THE EURO AREA THE DEFICIT OF THE EU MEMBER STATES IN THE EURO AREA PhD. Candidate Adrian AMARIȚA Ministry of Regional Development and Public Administration Abstract The Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance

More information

The Economic Situation of the European Union and the Outlook for

The Economic Situation of the European Union and the Outlook for The Economic Situation of the European Union and the Outlook for 2001-2002 A Report by the EUROFRAME group of Research Institutes for the European Parliament The Institutes involved are Wifo in Austria,

More information

National Audit Office's Fiscal Policy Audit and Monitoring Report on the Parliamentary Term

National Audit Office's Fiscal Policy Audit and Monitoring Report on the Parliamentary Term National Audit Office's Fiscal Policy Audit and Monitoring Report on the 2011 2014 Parliamentary Term NATIONAL AUDIT OFFICE S REPORTS TO PARLIAMENT R 20/2014 vp National Audit Office's Fiscal Policy Audit

More information

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 27.7.2016 SWD(2016) 263 final COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Analysis by the Commission services of the budgetary situation in Spain following the adoption of the COUNCIL

More information

Assessment of the Fulfilment of the Maastricht Convergence Criteria and the Degree of Economic Alignment of the Czech Republic with the Euro Area

Assessment of the Fulfilment of the Maastricht Convergence Criteria and the Degree of Economic Alignment of the Czech Republic with the Euro Area Assessment of the Fulfilment of the Maastricht Convergence Criteria and the Degree of Economic Alignment of the Czech Republic with the Euro Area A joint document of the Ministry of Finance of the Czech

More information

Spring Forecast: slowly recovering from a protracted recession

Spring Forecast: slowly recovering from a protracted recession EUROPEAN COMMISSION Olli REHN Vice-President of the European Commission and member of the Commission responsible for Economic and Monetary Affairs and the Euro Spring Forecast: slowly recovering from a

More information

NOTE General Secretariat of the Council Delegations Subject: Council Opinion on the updated Stability Programme of Germany,

NOTE General Secretariat of the Council Delegations Subject: Council Opinion on the updated Stability Programme of Germany, COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION Brussels, 27 April 2010 9088/10 UEM 142 NOTE From: General Secretariat of the Council To: Delegations Subject: Council Opinion on the updated Stability Programme of Germany,

More information

Recommendation for a COUNCIL DECISION

Recommendation for a COUNCIL DECISION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 27.7.2016 COM(2016) 518 final Recommendation for a COUNCIL DECISION giving notice to Spain to take measures for the deficit reduction judged necessary in order to remedy the

More information

Annual revision of national contributions to the EU budget

Annual revision of national contributions to the EU budget Annual revision of national contributions to the EU budget SUMMARY Briefing November 2014 The annual adjustment of the financing of the EU budget is now in the spotlight. In 2013, around three quarters

More information

THE EU FRAMEWORK FOR FISCAL POLICIES

THE EU FRAMEWORK FOR FISCAL POLICIES THE EU FRAMEWORK FOR FISCAL POLICIES To ensure the stability of the Economic and Monetary Union, the framework for avoiding unsustainable public finances needs to be strong. A reform (part of the Six-Pack

More information

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION. Common principles on national fiscal correction mechanisms

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION. Common principles on national fiscal correction mechanisms EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 20.6.2012 COM(2012) 342 final COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION Common principles on national fiscal correction mechanisms EN EN COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION Common principles

More information

EUROPEA U IO. Brussels, 26 April 2013 (OR. en) 2011/0386 (COD) PE-CO S 6/13 ECOFI 163 UEM 38 CODEC 463 OC 109

EUROPEA U IO. Brussels, 26 April 2013 (OR. en) 2011/0386 (COD) PE-CO S 6/13 ECOFI 163 UEM 38 CODEC 463 OC 109 EUROPEA U IO THE EUROPEA PARLIAMT THE COU CIL Brussels, 26 April 2013 (OR. en) 2011/0386 (COD) PE-CO S 6/13 ECOFI 163 UEM 38 CODEC 463 OC 109 LEGISLATIVE ACTS A D OTHER I STRUMTS Subject: REGULATION OF

More information

Introduction. The Stability and Growth Pact. The Fiscal Compact and Fiscal Policy

Introduction. The Stability and Growth Pact. The Fiscal Compact and Fiscal Policy Introduction The proposed 'Fiscal Compact' Treaty 1 is but a step on the road to fiscal union. It aims to incorporate significant parts, but by no means all, of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) into

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. State Aid Scoreboard. Report on state aid granted by the EU Member States. - Autumn 2012 Update. {SEC(2012) 443 final}

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. State Aid Scoreboard. Report on state aid granted by the EU Member States. - Autumn 2012 Update. {SEC(2012) 443 final} Brussels, 21.12.2012 COM(2012) 778 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION State Aid Scoreboard Report on state aid granted by the EU Member States - Autumn 2012 Update {SEC(2012) 443 final} EN EN REPORT FROM

More information

Institutions for EMU Economic Governance Francesco Saraceno OFCE-Research Center in Economics of Sciences Po Luiss School of European Political Economy Jakarta School of Government and Public Policy Where

More information

Assessment of the 2017 convergence programme for. Bulgaria

Assessment of the 2017 convergence programme for. Bulgaria EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE GENERAL ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL AFFAIRS Brussels, 23 May 2017 Assessment of the 2017 convergence programme for Bulgaria (Note prepared by DG ECFIN staff) 1 CONTENTS 1. INTRODUCTION...

More information

The Spanish banking system: situation and challenges Universidad de Almería, 18 July 2016

The Spanish banking system: situation and challenges Universidad de Almería, 18 July 2016 18.07.2016 The Spanish banking system: situation and challenges Universidad de Almería, 18 July 2016 Luis M. Linde Governor Let me first thank the Universidad de Almería and all the sponsors for their

More information

Council of the European Union Brussels, 29 November 2016 (OR. en)

Council of the European Union Brussels, 29 November 2016 (OR. en) Conseil UE Council of the European Union Brussels, 29 November 2016 (OR. en) PUBLIC 14814/16 LIMITE ECOFIN 1107 UEM 399 COVER NOTE From: To: Subject: General Secretariat of the Council Permanent Representatives

More information

Economic consequences of high public debt and lessons learned from past episodes

Economic consequences of high public debt and lessons learned from past episodes ECB-RESTRICTED Economic consequences of high public debt and lessons learned from past episodes Presented by Cristina Checherita-Westphal Pascal Jacquinot Based on joint work with ESCB WGPF Team ECFIN

More information

Official Journal of the European Union L 306/33

Official Journal of the European Union L 306/33 23.11.2011 Official Journal of the European Union L 306/33 COUNCIL REGULATION (EU) No 1177/2011 of 8 November 2011 amending Regulation (EC) No 1467/97 on speeding up and clarifying the implementation of

More information

Stability and Growth Pact: Implementation of the comply or explain rule (March 2015)

Stability and Growth Pact: Implementation of the comply or explain rule (March 2015) IPOL EGOV DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE SUPPORT UNIT B RIEFING Stability and Growth Pact: Implementation of the comply or explain rule (March 2015) In accordance with Regulation

More information

The Spanish economy: transformation and challenges Spain Investors Day

The Spanish economy: transformation and challenges Spain Investors Day 15.01.2019 The Spanish economy: transformation and challenges Spain Investors Day Pablo Hernández de Cos Governor Let me thank the Governing Board of Spain Investors Day and its chairman, Benito Berceruelo,

More information

Assessment of the Convergence Programme for. the United Kingdom

Assessment of the Convergence Programme for. the United Kingdom EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE GENERAL ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL AFFAIRS Brussels, 23 May 2018 Assessment of the 2017-18 Convergence Programme for the United Kingdom (Note prepared by DG ECFIN staff) 1 CONTENTS

More information

GREEK ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

GREEK ECONOMIC OUTLOOK CENTRE OF PLANNING AND ECONOMIC RESEARCH Issue 27, June 2015 GREEK ECONOMIC OUTLOOK Macroeconomic analysis and projections Public finance Human resources and social policies Development policies and sectors

More information

OVERVIEW. The EU recovery is firming. Table 1: Overview - the winter 2014 forecast Real GDP. Unemployment rate. Inflation. Winter 2014 Winter 2014

OVERVIEW. The EU recovery is firming. Table 1: Overview - the winter 2014 forecast Real GDP. Unemployment rate. Inflation. Winter 2014 Winter 2014 OVERVIEW The EU recovery is firming Europe's economic recovery, which began in the second quarter of 2013, is expected to continue spreading across countries and gaining strength while at the same time

More information

Luis M Linde: The Spanish banking system situation and challenges

Luis M Linde: The Spanish banking system situation and challenges Luis M Linde: The Spanish banking system situation and challenges Speech by Mr Luis M Linde, Governor of the Bank of Spain, at the University of Almeria, Almeria, 18 July 2016. * * * Let me first thank

More information

Overview of EU public finances

Overview of EU public finances 6 volume 17, 12/29B I Overview of EU public finances PRE-CRISIS DEVELOPMENTS Public finance developments in the EU up to 28 can be divided into three stages: In 1997, the Stability and Growth Pact entered

More information

Limited to Cabinets - Embargo until adoption

Limited to Cabinets - Embargo until adoption EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, XXX [ ](2018) XXX draft Limited to Cabinets - Embargo until adoption COMMISSION OPINION of XXX on the updated Draft Budgetary Plan of Spain EN EN GENERAL CONSIDERATIONS COMMISSION

More information

The Coordination of Fiscal Policies in Europe

The Coordination of Fiscal Policies in Europe Gian Paolo Ruggiero Ministry of the Economy and Finance Department of the Treasury The Coordination of Fiscal Policies in Europe Warsaw 21 November 2003 04/12/2003 1 1. A European monetary policy and 12

More information

Chapter 1. Fiscal consolidation targets, plans and measures in OECD countries

Chapter 1. Fiscal consolidation targets, plans and measures in OECD countries 1. FISCAL CONSOLIDATION TARGETS, PLANS AND MEASURES IN OECD COUNTRIES 1 Chapter 1 Fiscal consolidation targets, plans and measures in OECD countries This chapter discusses the consolidation efforts of

More information

A. INTRODUCTION AND FINANCING OF THE GENERAL BUDGET. EXPENDITURE Description Budget Budget Change (%)

A. INTRODUCTION AND FINANCING OF THE GENERAL BUDGET. EXPENDITURE Description Budget Budget Change (%) DRAFT AMENDING BUDGET NO. 2/2018 VOLUME 1 - TOTAL REVENUE A. INTRODUCTION AND FINANCING OF THE GENERAL BUDGET FINANCING OF THE GENERAL BUDGET Appropriations to be covered during the financial year 2018

More information

THE SWEDISH FISCAL POLICY FRAMEWORK

THE SWEDISH FISCAL POLICY FRAMEWORK THE SWEDISH FISCAL POLICY FRAMEWORK Regeringens skrivelse 2017/18:207 Fiscal policy framework Skr. 2017/18:207 The Government presents this Communication to the Riksdag. Stockholm, 12 April 2018 Stefan

More information

ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT FOUNDATION IKV BRIEF 2010 THE DEBT CRISIS IN GREECE AND THE EURO ZONE

ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT FOUNDATION IKV BRIEF 2010 THE DEBT CRISIS IN GREECE AND THE EURO ZONE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT FOUNDATION IKV BRIEF 2010 April 2010 Prepared by: Sema Gençay ÇAPANOĞLU (scapanoglu@ikv.org.tr) THE DEBT CRISIS IN GREECE AND THE EURO ZONE Greece is struggling with the most serious

More information

Fragmentation of the European financial market and the cost of bank financing

Fragmentation of the European financial market and the cost of bank financing Fragmentation of the European financial market and the cost of bank financing Joaquín Maudos 1 European market fragmentation following the crisis has resulted in a widening of borrowing costs across Euro

More information

Opinion of the Monetary Policy Council on the draft Budget Act for the Year 2010

Opinion of the Monetary Policy Council on the draft Budget Act for the Year 2010 N a t i o n a l B a n k o f P o l a n d M o n e t a r y P o l i c y C o u n c i l Warsaw, 27 October 2009 Opinion of the Monetary Policy Council on the draft Budget Act for the Year 2010 The draft Budget

More information

Developments in the economic situation Asociación Española de Directivos, Santa Cruz de Tenerife

Developments in the economic situation Asociación Española de Directivos, Santa Cruz de Tenerife Haga clic aquí para escribir texto. 01.03.2018 Developments in the economic situation Asociación Española de Directivos, Santa Cruz de Tenerife Luis M. Linde Governor Introduction Let me begin by thanking

More information

ECB LTRO Dec Greece program

ECB LTRO Dec Greece program International Monetary Fund June 9, 212 Euro Area Crisis: Still in the Danger Zone */ Emil Stavrev Research Department ( */ Views expressed in this presentation are those of the author and do not necessarily

More information

11244/12 RD/NC/kp DG G1A

11244/12 RD/NC/kp DG G1A COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION Brussels, 6 July 2012 (OR. en) 11244/12 UEM 202 ECOFIN 576 SOC 553 COMPET 421 V 517 EDUC 194 RECH 257 ER 286 LEGISLATIVE ACTS AND OTHER INSTRUMTS Subject: COUNCIL RECOMMDATION

More information

Fiscalgovernance inthe euroarea

Fiscalgovernance inthe euroarea Fiscalgovernance inthe euroarea The perspective of the European Commission Nicolas Carnot Adviser European Commission, DG Economic and Financial Affairs Monetary Commission of the European League of Economic

More information

Growth and inflation in OECD and Sweden 1999 and 2000 forecast Percentage annual change

Growth and inflation in OECD and Sweden 1999 and 2000 forecast Percentage annual change Mr Heikensten talks about the interaction between monetary and fiscal policy and labour market developments Speech by Lars Heikensten, First Deputy Governor of the Sveriges Riksbank, the Swedish central

More information

PUBLIC PROCUREMENT INDICATORS 2011, Brussels, 5 December 2012

PUBLIC PROCUREMENT INDICATORS 2011, Brussels, 5 December 2012 PUBLIC PROCUREMENT INDICATORS 2011, Brussels, 5 December 2012 1. INTRODUCTION This document provides estimates of three indicators of performance in public procurement within the EU. The indicators are

More information

34 th Associates Meeting - Andorra, 25 May Item 5: Evolution of economic governance in the EU

34 th Associates Meeting - Andorra, 25 May Item 5: Evolution of economic governance in the EU 34 th Associates Meeting - Andorra, 25 May 2012 - Item 5: Evolution of economic governance in the EU Plan of the Presentation 1. Fiscal and economic coordination: how did it start? 2. Did it work? 3. Five

More information

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION. Assessment of action taken by Portugal and Spain

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION. Assessment of action taken by Portugal and Spain EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 16.11.2016 COM(2016) 901 final COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION Assessment of action taken by Portugal and Spain in response to the Council decisions of 8 August 2016 giving

More information

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. Analysis of the Draft Budgetary Plan of Lithuania. Accompanying the document COMMISSION OPINION

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. Analysis of the Draft Budgetary Plan of Lithuania. Accompanying the document COMMISSION OPINION EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 21.11.2018 SWD(2018) 520 final COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Analysis of the Draft Budgetary Plan of Lithuania Accompanying the document COMMISSION OPINION on the Draft

More information

ARTICLES A FISCAL COMPACT FOR A STRONGER ECONOMIC AND MONETARY UNION

ARTICLES A FISCAL COMPACT FOR A STRONGER ECONOMIC AND MONETARY UNION ARTICLES A FISCAL COMPACT FOR A STRONGER ECONOMIC AND MONETARY UNION This article reviews and assesses the key elements of the fi scal compact, which as part of the new Treaty on Stability, Coordination

More information

1. Sustainable public finances and structural reforms for growth

1. Sustainable public finances and structural reforms for growth Over the last three years, we have taken unprecedented steps to combat the effects of the world-wide financial crisis, both in the European Union as such and within the euro area. The strategy we have

More information

2018 World Savings Day

2018 World Savings Day ACRI Association of Italian Savings Banks 2018 World Savings Day Address by the Governor of the Bank of Italy Ignazio Visco Rome, 31 October 2018 The protection of savings calls, in the first place, for

More information

5. Compliance with Fiscal Rules: A Preliminary Examination

5. Compliance with Fiscal Rules: A Preliminary Examination 5. Compliance with Fiscal Rules: A Preliminary Examination 5.1 Introduction As part of its mandate under the Fiscal Responsibility Bill (FRB), the Council is required to provide an assessment, at least

More information

Comment on Beetsma, Debrun and Klaassen: Is fiscal policy coordination in EMU desirable? Marco Buti *

Comment on Beetsma, Debrun and Klaassen: Is fiscal policy coordination in EMU desirable? Marco Buti * SWEDISH ECONOMIC POLICY REVIEW 8 (2001) 99-105 Comment on Beetsma, Debrun and Klaassen: Is fiscal policy coordination in EMU desirable? Marco Buti * A classic result in the literature on strategic analysis

More information

BACKGROU D 1 ECO OMIC and FI A CIAL AFFAIRS COU CIL Tuesday 8 July in Brussels

BACKGROU D 1 ECO OMIC and FI A CIAL AFFAIRS COU CIL Tuesday 8 July in Brussels Brussels, 8 July 2008 BACKGROU D 1 ECO OMIC and FI A CIAL AFFAIRS COU CIL Tuesday 8 July in Brussels The Council will be preceded as usual by a meeting of the eurogroup, on Monday 7 July starting at 17.00,

More information

Ranking Country Page. Category 1: Countries with positive CEP Default Index and positive NTE. 1 Estonia 1. 2 Luxembourg 2.

Ranking Country Page. Category 1: Countries with positive CEP Default Index and positive NTE. 1 Estonia 1. 2 Luxembourg 2. Overview: Single Results of Euro Countries Ranking Country Page Category 1: Countries with positive CEP Default Index and positive NTE 1 Estonia 1 2 Luxembourg 2 3 Germany 3 4 Netherlands 4 5 Austria 5

More information

DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES

DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES The euro against major international currencies: During the second quarter of 2000, the US dollar,

More information