Public Goods in Federal Systems

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Public Goods in Federal Systems"

Transcription

1 Public Goods in Federal Systems Catherine Hafer Department of Politics, New York University Dimitri Landa Department of Politics, New York University Abstract We study a politico-economic model of federations with both federal and supplemental regional provision of a local (impure) public good with spillover effects. Regional differences in average income levels and externalities of provision induce differences in preferences over federal and regional levels of provision. Although the voters preferences are not single-peaked, we provide sufficient conditions for the existence of a voting equilibrium and characterize its properties under alternative federal institutional arrangements. The voting equilibrium is unique but displays markedly different substantive characteristics under different conditions on parameters. We show that the inter-regional redistributive tensions present in federations lead to differences in regional preferences over federal institutions and may help to explain otherwise puzzling patterns in state support for federal programs.

2 Introduction The issue of the composition and structure of political unions or federations is as timely as it has ever been, with the expansion of the European Union leading to some of the most heated debates in European politics in the last decade. In many cases of political unions, the joint action of the members is a function of distinctly political phenomena, such as the perception of a common military threat or the political salience of domestic ethnic groups with cultural or historic affinities for neighboring states. The unions that lead to the creation of common political institutions charged with the implementation of common economic policies are, however, rarely products of political calculations alone (see, e.g., Inman and Rubinfeld 1998, Emerson et al for the EU, and Hardin 1999, Ch. 3, for the US), and call for the analysis of distinctly political-economic mechanisms of their formation, maintenance, and internal organization. The present paper analyzes one such mechanism by considering the political and economic incentives within federal structures with public good provision on both local and federal levels and spillover effects between regions - features that often characterize contemporary federal systems. Although such systems rarely have institutional provisions that explicitly authorize the duplication of services or public goods on the federal and the local levels, in practice, public goods provided at the two levels of government are often de facto substitutes, with fiscal federalism emerging less as a constitutional and juridical reality and more as a dynamic economic one. Sometimes the substitution effect is immediate and direct, as with the financing of the creation of new stem-cell lines in the US, which, before President Bush s ban, was done with federal money, but has now been picked up by the state of California. At other times, federal and regional/state programs may have different explicit targets, e.g., different categories of the population, but their substantive closeness gives rise to explicit budgetary fungeability - as with the US federal Medicaid spending on retirees, which is used by state health care facilities to help offset their overall operating expenses (Hernandez 2005). With many other spending programs, there is what may be called article-byarticle substitutability, whereby, within a given policy area there is a division of responsibilities 1

3 between the state and the federal governments, but a drop in spending by one level on an article within its purview, leads another level to pick up the slack by spending more on articles within its own budgetary purview. A prominent example of such a policy area is higher education financing, where the US federal government is typically understood to be responsible for the provision of low-interest student loans and faculty research funds, and state governments finance faculty and staff salaries and the physical plants of state universities. Other policy areas exhibiting substantial substitutability in the US and other federal states include highway construction, environmental regulation, etc., and in these and other policy areas mentioned, this substitutability is best thought of as a feature of what are, in effect, dual-provision fiscal federal mechanisms. Although the latter point is less true of the EU, whose budget is still rather small relative to those of its wealthiest member-states, the range of policy areas in which the substantive policy control is, effectively, shared by the EU and its members is long and growing, including a number of economic policy areas, most notably monetary policy, agriculture and fisheries, etc., with respect to which the EU is more and more resembling a federal state with a robust policy-making and implementing apparatus (Alesina and Wacziarg 1999). In analyzing such dual-provision systems, our model of federations could be seen as combining some of the key elements of two approaches to analyzing the political economy of federations, which have been the focus of the existing analyses and which may be referred to as the scale and the spillover mechanisms. The first of these, requiring more explicit cooperation among members, posits federal structures as outcomes of the economies of scale, which make it profitable for states to join forces in the selection of policy because the returns to joint economic action exceed the sum of the returns to the independent actions by the members (see Alesina, Perotti, and Spolaore (1995), and Bolton, Roland, and Spolaore (1996) for surveys of some of the models analyzing this mechanism). Examples of models that explore this mechanism include Casella (1992) and Alesina and Spolaore (1997), which focus on the scale effects of trade and Persson and Tabellini (1996a and b), which draws on the scale effects of risk sharing. Difficulties in enforcing agreements on which such unions are based are considered in Bednar (2001) and De Figuiredo and Weingast (2001). The second political-economic mechanism prominent in the extant work focuses on the possi- 2

4 bility of members enjoying spillovers in the provision of local public goods in the federation. Less explicitly cooperative than the first mechanism, the spillover mechanism more immediately lends itself to the analysis of the distributive properties of policy-making in federations, which are, arguably, the central source of tension in this conception of federalism. Papers exploring various elements of this mechanism include Cremer and Palfrey (2002), who analyze the distributive effects of unfunded federal mandates, and Alesina et al. (2005), who consider the possibility of supplementing local provision at the federal level. Like Alesina et al., we analyze a model with dual (federal and regional) provision and interregional spillovers, but unlike in their model, the presenceofincomeheterogeneityplaysacentral role in our causal account of the distributive effects of federal politics. Empirically, that heterogeneity is, indeed, substantial: in the US, the highest state-level median household income is nearly twice the lowest, and the highest national GDP per person in the EU (measured at PPP) is nearly three and a half times the lowest. Rather than assuming primitive differences in regional demands for public goods, we induce these differences endogenously from the interaction between the relevant spillover factors and the differences in regional incomes, which enables us to develop predictions in terms of these empirically obervable regional characteristics. 1 Our model also offers a framework for analyzing a wide range of different types of dual-provision mechanisms, including the previously unexplored and both theoretically and empirically important cases in which federal provision may exploit economies of scale in production, as well as the case in which federal provision is equivalent to the equal division of federal revenues among the member regions, who then produce the public good locally just as they would using locally raised revenue (as in Alesina et al. 2005). 1 Our basic setup is also related to Epple and Romano s (2003) model of collective public good provision with supplemental voluntary provision, which could be re-interpreted as a model of federation in which the federal and local means of provision are identical and in which the public good is a pure one. The model presented here is complicated not only by impure public goods and technological differences between the federal and local means of provision, but also by the fact that local provision must be determined by a collective choice rather than by an individual one. 3

5 We show that, in the presence of income heterogeneity across regions, the dual structure of public good provision induces redistributive tensions within the federation, with significant empirical and theoretical implications for our understanding of federal politics. Our key technical results characterize and provide sufficient conditions for the existence of a voting equilibrium with public good provision at two levels of government. Substantively, we show that the presence of spillovers in dual-provision federations results in political conflicts between the region-members of the federation and between the federal and the regional levels of government. These conflicts manifest themselves in regions attempting to increase or decrease the role of the federal government, relative to the regional governments, in order to force other regional governments into making particular political and economic choices. 2 We show that these attempts (1) may help account for the otherwise puzzling empirical patterns in state preferences over federal programs, e.g., opposition from poorer states that are their net beneficiaries and support from wealthier states that effectively subsidize them (Lacy 2004); (2) may give rise to politically potent ends-against-the-middle majority coalitions that often elude directly political explanations; and (3) lead to conflicts over the choices of institutional structures organizing the decision-making in federations, though not necessarily to the instability of collective institutional choice. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the first section to follow we present our results on the existence and properties of equilibrium in federations with joint provision. The next section addresses issues of constitutional variation, including the comparative institutional analysis of political (de-)centralization. It is followed by a brief discussion section and an appendix that gathers the proofs of all the formal propositions in the paper. 2 In explaining the rivalry between the federal and some of the regional governments, this mechanism complements the credit claiming incentives that are highlighted in Bednar (2004) and Volden (2005), though it does suggest that, unlike in the case of credit-claiming, we should not expect this rivalry to be uniform across regions. 4

6 The Model Notation and Primitives The sequence of the game is as follows. First, the citizens of the federal union choose their federally provided level of public good. Then, citizens of each region comprising the union simultaneously choose their respective regional levels of provision. At both levels, decisions are made by majority rule. Following the realization of the federal and the regional provision levels, citizens of the union consume their public and private goods. 3 There are n regions in the union, where n is odd, and let l be the number of regions that choose (by domestic majority) to engage in supplemental local provision. The corresponding sets of member regions are denoted as N and L respectively, with L N. In the interests of tractability, all regions are assumed to have equal populations. 4 Although this assumption may appear restrictive initially, it does not affect the spirit of the substantive results. 5 Let u i j be the utility of agent i in region j. We assume generalized Cobb-Douglas preferences u i j(x i j,y j )=(x i ) a y b j, (1) where y j is the amount of public good enjoyed by each individual in region j and x i j is i s private 3 We comment on both the extension of the results to the case in which a representative federal legislature chooses federal policy and the possibility of reversing the order of provision in the Discussion. 4 It is straightforward, though notationally more cumbersome, to generalize to the case in which regions are of different sizes. We comment further on the possibility of such an extension below. 5 The mobility of voters across regions is beyond the scope of the present paper and is left to the future work extending the model developed here. Not modeling it explicitly here has the advantage of allowing us to evaluate the independent impact of spillovers on federal political economy, as well as to compare our results to the results in other papers that model federal system with spillovers and which, at the moment, do not allow for voter mobility. 5

7 good. This functional form treats public and private goods as essential in some measure and as complements, e.g. as complementary inputs to the productive economic activities of individual agents. Consequently, the agent requires positive amounts of both goods, and the marginal productivity of each input is increasing in the presence of greater amounts of the other. In many cases of public good provision, especially those of large-scale legal, physical, and financial infrastructure, this assumption is particularly plausible and warrants considerable attention in the analysis of political economy of federal unions. Additionally, we use the following notation to denote the corresponding income variables: h i j is the income of agent i in region j; H j = P i h i j is the total income of a generic region j; and H =(H 1,...,H j,...,h n ) is the vector of total regional incomes. H T = P j H j is the total income of the federation. We assume that the private good is numeraire, i.e., the monetary unit. One unit of private good purchases one unit of local public good, that is, one unit of an impure public good that can be enjoyed fully by citizens in the region in which it is provided, but only partly by the citizens of other regions. Let s L < 1 be the proportion of that local public good that citizens of other regions are able to enjoy. The federal-level policy we analyze imposes a uniform tax rate and spends equal amounts (per capita) on the provision of public goods in each region. The benefits from federal provision directed to one region spill over to other regions also at the rate of s L. Hence, a dollar spent on public good provision by the federal government increases the amount of public goodenjoyedinanygivenregionbyγ (1+s L(n 1)) n, where γ is a measure of the relative efficiency of federal provision. If γ < 1, then the federal means of provision is inherently less efficient than the local means of provision, and if γ > 1 then federal provision is more efficient. 6 As noted in the introduction, our assumptions here are flexible enough to cover the cases in which federal provision may exploit economies of scale in production, as well as the case in which federal provision amounts 6 Note that whether or not γ > 1 is distinct from the question of whether membership in the federation is attractive, in part because the existence of spillovers may make it attractive even if γ < 1. 6

8 to the equal division of federal revenues among the member regions, who then produce the public good locally just as they would using locally raised revenue. For notational convenience, we let γ (1+s L(n 1)) n = s F represent the amount of public good enjoyed in a region for each unit the federal government spends on public goods. We thus interpret s F to reflect both the direct impact (from the federal provision for region j) and the indirect impact (via cross-regional spillovers from the federal provision for other regions) of federal provision. Note that s L and s F can be treated as the rates of substitution of the individual s own region s locally provided public good for other regions or federal public goods. We return to the expression of s F in terms of s L below in the evaluation of the conditions that characterize the equilibrium levels of provision. Although, in the interests of brevity, we focus our interpretation of the model on the effects of positive externalities, it is fully consistent with the presence of negative externalities as well. In the latter case, the rationale for the the existence of the federal government may be thought to be the alleviation of such externalities, which is analytically equivalent to the production of positive ones. 7 The federal tax rate is t F and the vector of local tax rates is t = (t 1,t 2,...,t n ), with the understanding that t j,t F [0, 1]. The government faces a balanced budget constraint, so all revenue is invested in public goods at the corresponding level of government. Thus, for individual i in region 7 Suppose that regions produce negative externalities in the form of pollution and that the federal government creates an abatement program to eliminate them. Then the federal government may be thought to be producing a public good, in the form of cleaner air or water, or equivalently it may be thought to be eliminating a negative externality (pollution). If the government action constitutes an actual restriction on some beneficial activity that creates a negative externality as a by-product, then the assumption y j 0 implies that (1) the net benefit of government actions is positive, so that adequate benefits are always provided to compensate for losses, and (2) government abatement programs prevent firms from increasing their rate of pollution in response to government efforts. 7

9 j, X y j = t F H T s F + t j H j + s L t k H k (2) x i j = h i j(1 t F t j ) k L\j The Politico-Economic Equilibrium Our solution concept is subgame-perfect Nash Equilibrium in undominated strategies. More specifically, the equilibrium is characterized as the pair (t F,t ), such that the federal tax rate t F is in the majority rule core of the federation as a whole, given the equilibrium best response of t (t F ), and, for every region j, t j is in the majority rule core of region j, giventf and t j. Solving by backward induction, we first find the induced preferences of a voter in region j over regional tax rates, t j, given her expectations of the other regions simultaneously chosen tax rates, t j, and the known federal tax rate t F. Substituting (2) into (1) yields X u i j(t F,t, ) =((1 t F t j )h i j) a (t F H T s F + t j H j + s L t k H k ) b. (3) k N\j Because both private and public goods are essential, no agent ever prefers to tax away all of her private endowment. She may, however, prefer no supplemental local provision of the public good (t j = 0) if enough public good is provided at the federal level or locally in other districts. To locate any interior solution, we obtain the Kuhn-Tucker conditions, which (combined with the conditions for the corner solution) yield the most preferred local tax rate as a function of the federal tax rate: t j (t F )= 1 a+b " b(1 t F ) a(t F HT H j s F + s L if b(1 t F ) >a(t F HT H j s F + s L 0 otherwise P k N\j P k N\j t k H k H j ) # t k H k H j ) (4) The first thing to note in relation to (4) is that, because voters have identical marginal rates of substitution between private and public goods and the tax is a flat rate on endowment, domestic 8

10 politics (i.e., the politics of determining the supplemental level of public good provided at the local level) is essentially trivial: holding constant the federal tax t F, agents within a region have identical preferences over the internal tax financing the supplemental provision of the public good. Thus the choice of regional tax rate depends on the region s total income, H j, but does not otherwise depend on voter i s income, h i j. For the same reason, the equilibrium local tax rate is robust to the specification of the domestic collective choice rule. This simplicity of the intra-regional politics helps place the inter-regional politics in the spotlight, and will make it easier to see the causes and consequences of disagreements between regions over federal taxation and provision. These disputes will turn on the combination of the redistributive pressures inherent in income heterogeneity across regions and the possibility of free-riding implicit in inter-regional spillovers. We begin our analysis of these effects with two lemmata, which establish the unique relationship between the set of local providers and the federal tax rate that is instrumental in proving the main results of the model. Lemma 1 In any equilibrium, for any pair of regions j and k such that H j <H k,ifregionj provides a positive amount of the public good at the local level, then region k provides a strictly greater amount. Proof See Appendix. Let L(t F ) be the set of members which engage in supplemental local production at federal tax rate t F,i.e.,forwhicht j > 0att F. Let L(t F ) = l(t F ). If we index the regions from richest to poorest, i.e., so that H 1 H 2... H l... H n, the key consequence of this lemma for the present model is that l(t F )mustbethehighestintegersuchthatt l (t F )H l > 0, i.e., it has to be such that both t l (t F )H l > 0andt l+1 (t F )H l+1 = 0 (where the lower bound on tax rate may be P binding). Hence, t j (t F )H j = P t j (t F )H j, and from (4) we can write j N j L X t j (t F )H j = j N = X j L(t F ) t j (t F )H j 1 a + b + as L (l(t F ) 1) (b(1 tf ) X k L(t F ) H k as F t F H T l(t F )). (5) Substituting (5) into (4) and solving for t j (t F )H j at t F such that t j > 0, we get: 9

11 t j(t F )H j = b (1 t F )H j (6) a + b as L 1 a + b + as L (l(t F ) 1) (as F t F H T abs L X + (1 t F ) H k ), a + b as L k L(t F ) where, from the above ordering of H j and (6), l(t F )andl(t F ) are formally defined by the following system of inequalities: (a + b + as L (l(t F ) 1))b(1 t F )H l(t F ) >abs L (1 t F P ) H k +(a + b as L )as F t F H T (a + b + as L (l(t F ) 1))b(1 t F )H l(t F )+1 abs L (1 t F ) k L(t F ) P k L(t F ) H k +(a + b as L )as F t F H T (7) Together (6) and (7) determine the Nash equilibrium in the simultaneous-move local provision game. Lemma 2 For each federal tax rate t F, there is a unique group of regions, L(t F ), that are local providers at that tax rate. Proof See Appendix. By Lemma 1, this group of regions must include the wealthiest l(t F ) regions in the federation. Given this solution to the subgame, we next determine the agents preferences over federal tax rates. These preferences depend critically on the relative merits, from an individual s point of view, of the federal and the local means of provision, taking into account the strategic responses of other regions to changes in each. Two features of voters induced preferences over federal tax rates, each of which is established formally in the appendix, play prominent roles in the characterization of the equilibrium federal tax rate (below). First, we show that voters within a given region j have identical induced preferences over federal tax rates even though they may have different private endowments, and hence different utilities at any given tax rate. In addition to aiding the characterization of the majority rule core, this feature of the model facilitates the extension of the results to both a wider variety of institutions 10

12 for collective choice, including representative government, and the case in which regions differ in their populations. Second, we show that voters in any two regions that do not engage in local provision for some interval of federal tax rates have identical induced preferences over federal tax rates on that interval. Both of these properties are consequences of the fact that the citizens in question enjoy the same spillovers from other regions local provision, the same federal provision of the public good, and the same local provision from their own regional government. Hence, they enjoy the same amount of public good. This induced simplicity of regional politics in the model allows us to focus our attention on the consequences of inter-regional redistributive tensions. Because 0 is a binding lower bound on all local tax rates, the expression for the indirect utility of a voter in region j as a function of federal tax rate, given the equilibrium behavior in the local provision game, is different when some other region k engages in local provision than when it does not. Let l max = L(0) be the number of regions that engage in local provision when there is no federal provision of the public good, i.e. such that H lmax > as L a + b + as L (l max 1) Ã lmax! X H k H lmax +1 (8) 1 The conjunction of Lemmata 1 and 2 implies that the range of t F can be partitioned into [0, ˆt F l max ), [ˆt F l max, ˆt F l max 1 ),...,[ˆt F 1, 1], so that each of these intervals defines a range of tf corresponding to a given value of L. These intervals are bounded by the federal tax rates, ˆt F j (not necessarily optimal, from the perspective of a voter in region j), at which region j ceases local provision, i.e., at which t j (ˆt F j )=0. (For j>l max, t F j = 0.) Substituting t j =0andl = j into (6) and solving for tf ( ˆt F j ), we obtain ˆt F j = (a + b + as L (j 1))H j as L jp, (9) (a + b + as L (j 1))H j +(a + b as L ) a b s jp F H T as L H k 1 H k 1 which j l max is greater than 0. Then, for t F < ˆt F j and t j [0,t j (ˆt F j, )), voters in region j wish to procure more public good through some form of increased taxation. Given this partition of the policy space, we proceed by identifying the extrema on each interval. 11

13 In the presence of spillovers, there may exist multiple local optima, and regions preferences are neither necessarily single-peaked nor necessarily order-restricted. Although this means that we cannot rely immediately on standard theorems for aggregating preferences over t F, we can provide sufficient conditions for the existence of a unique stable outcome of majority rule and characterize that outcome. The next two propositions identify such conditions, and characterize two qualitatively different and mutually exclusive equilibria that obtain when they are satisfied. These equilibria differ dramatically in the composition of the coalitions supporting a greater or lesser degree of federal provision: in the first equilibrium, it is the citizens of the wealthiest regions (whether or not they are wealthy themselves) that prefer greater federal provision in opposition to the poorer regions preference for local provision; in the second equilibrium, the citizens of the wealthiest and sometimes also of the poorest regions prefer local provision, in opposition to the middle-income regions preferences for federal provision. Our sufficiency conditions for the existence of these equilibria identify the preference profiles that are order-restricted, and, as we show in Claim 1 in the Appendix, together they identify all such preference profiles. The restrictions on the preference profiles of the federation they entail are expressed in terms of two functions f(j; a, b, s L,s F,H)andg(j; a, b, s L,s F,H), such that the sign of f( ) determines whether the utilities of the citizens of the jth region are increasing in federal tax rate at a federal tax rate of 0, and the sign of g( ) whether their utilities are decreasing in federal tax rate at the federal tax rate at which that region ceases to provide locally, ˆt F j. We use these functions to establish necessary and sufficient conditions for all voters in regions that are local providers to have monotonic preferences over those federal tax rates at which they would engage in supplemental local provision, and then show that, if the voters have such preferences, the preference profile is order-restricted. In Proposition 1, the relevant ordering is by regional income; however, in Proposition 2, it is not. We characterize both functions explicitly in the Appendix and discuss their responsiveness to changes in parameter values later in this section of the paper. Recall that all citizens of a given region have identical induced preferences over tax rates and that j indexes regions in the descending order of their total (or average) income. Letting m index the median region region in this ordering, we can now formulate the following result: 12

14 Proposition 1 If f(1; a, b, s L,s F,H) > 0, then there exists an equilibrium with the following properties: (1) regions that engage in local provision at t F strictly prefer a higher tax rate, and each region s most-preferred tax rate is one at which it does not engage in local provision; (2) most preferred federal tax rates are weakly increasing in regional income; (3) there exists a Condorcet winner t F, which coincides with the most-preferred federal tax rate of the median income region, i.e., t F = t F m ; (4) the m poorest regions (comprising the majority of member regions of the federation) do not engage in local provision at the equilibrium federal tax rate. Proof See Appendix. Proposition 1 characterizes one set of strategic incentives that heterogenous-income regions face in federal systems with two levels of public good provision. Under the specified conditions, a majority of regions (and so of the citizens of the federation) select a low federal tax rate, anticipating that a minority of wealthier regions will provide additional amounts of the public good. 8 Because members enjoy positive externalities from public goods provided by other regions, free-riding on the provision of the wealthier regions at a lower level of federal provision is sometimes more attractive for the citizens of a poorer regions than is a more efficient level of provision that entails paying a higher federal tax. The properties of the equilibrium characterized in Proposition 1 are consistent with the seemingly puzzling fact that in the United States (poorer) federal units, which would seem to benefit most from redistributive federal programs, tend to oppose the expansion of the federal government, while the states that bankroll the federal programs tend to support it (Lacy 2004). Proposition 1 suggests that when its antecedent condition holds, this fact need not be paradoxical. When the public goods are substitutes, the presence of across-states externalities may make it so that the net 8 A similar logic underlies the equilibrium pattern of provision characterized in Alesina et al. (2005) for regions differing in their primitive taste for the public good, rather than in wealth as in our model. 13

15 receipt of federal funds to finance public good provision, coming at some non-zero price, is in the end worse for some states than free-riding on the spillovers from the public good provision in other states. The poorer (and hence, net federal financing recipient) regions/states object to the increases in federal provision, whereas the wealthier (and hence, net federal taxpayer) regions/states prefer relatively higher levels of federal provision. If so, then the states may be expected to respond precisely in a way consistent with the observed red states / blue states pattern. 9 We next provide another sufficient condition for the existence of the Condorcet winner, under which t F j (t, ) is weakly non-monotonic. Proposition 2 If there exists ˆl l max such that g(j; a, b, s L,s F,H) < 0 for every j ˆl, and,for ˆl <lmax,f(ˆl +1;a, b, s L,s F,H) > 0, then there exists an equilibrium with the following properties: (1) the wealthiest ˆl regions strictly prefer to decrease t F, and have a most-preferred federal tax rate of 0; every other region that engages in local provision at t F strictly prefers to increase it, and its most-preferred tax rate is one at which that region does not engage in local provision; (2) the most-preferred federal tax rate is weakly non-monotonic in regional income, with middle income regions preferring higher tax rates than do wealthier and poorer regions; (3) a unique Condorcet winner t F exists and is (a) 0 if m ˆl,or(b)t F if m>ˆl; m+ˆl (4) the wealthiest ˆl regions engage in local provision at the equilibrium federal tax rate t F. Proof See Appendix. 9 As an empirical matter, this pattern is surely overdetermined by other causal antecedents as well. Our point here is only that that data pattern is consistent with the causal mechanism we expect to be widely operative in federal structures. Moreover, in the context of public good provision accounts, the mechanism we identify is more appealing than those that rely on differences in the demand for public good induced by the differences in production technologies across states. Such differences (which are not modeled in this paper) are likely to work in the opposite direction from that which would be necessary to produce the observed pattern: it is unlikely that poorer states, with, among other things, worse economic infrastructures, have a lower need for the public good component in their production technologies. 14

16 The preference profiles that satisfy the conditions identified in Proposition 2 may give rise to majority coalitions with very different compositions. While some profiles result in an equilibrium in which the voters are divided by differences in regional income - i.e. the richer regions, which favor no federal provision, versus the poorer ones - other profiles produce an equilibrium in which the richest and poorest regions ally against the middle-income regions. In such cases, the rich and the very poor regions prefer little or no federal provision, and the middle-income regions champion higher federal tax rates. To be sure, the rich and the poor regions favor low taxes for different reasons. The citizens of the richer regions oppose the redistributive effects of federal provision. The poorest regions are, in such profiles, so poor relative to the rich regions, and obtain so much public good from the local provision of other regions (in the total absence of federal provision), that their demand for additional private good is greater than their demand for additional public good. This ends-against-the-middle result is the opposite of that of Epple and Romano (2003), in which the rich and poor desire higher taxation than do the middle-income voters. Because in their model, the public good is assumed to be truly global, every agent prefers additional federal provision to her own voluntary (local) provision of the good, since she bears only a fraction of the cost under the former scheme that she bears under the latter, while enjoying access to the same amount of the public good. Hence, in their model, the richest agents always demand high levels of federal taxation. Lower-income agents may demand higher levels of federal provision than middle-income agents, however, producing a coalition of rich and poor in support of higher taxation. By contrast, in the present paper, because the quantity of public good that an agent enjoys depends not only on the resources allocated to its production, but also on the location of its production in the federal system, wealthy regions may experience a decrease in the amount of public good that they enjoy as federal taxation increases. It is also the case that different regions engaging in local provision enjoy different amounts of the public good, giving rise to the possibility that, while some may be harmed by increases in federal provision, other local providers benefit from it. Thus citizens of middle-income regions may prefer higher levels of federal provision than do citizens of the rich and poor regions. 15

17 The Induced Preferences Over Federal Tax Rates: the Intuitive Characterization Figure 1 depicts the indirect utilities u(t F,t (t F )) over federal tax rates for the members of a federation composed of five regions, where the antecedent condition of Proposition 2 holds. Because, as already established, all the citizens of a given region have identical induced preferences over tax rates, we depict the indirect utility of one citizen in each region, with an individual income equal to the region s average per capita income. Without loss of generality, we will refer to the preferences of the citizens of a given region as the region s preferences throughout the following discussion. FIGURE 1 ABOUT HERE Regions 1 and 2, which are the wealthiest members, have strictly decreasing utility. Both 1 and 2 engage in local provision at Region 3 s most-preferred federal tax rate, t F 3. Regions that do not engage in local provision over a given interval of federal tax rates share the same preferences over those tax rates, e.g. regions 1, 2, and 3 all have a maximum at t F 3, and 1 and 2 both have a higher maximum at t F 2, indicating that they both prefer tf 2 to t F 3. Region 3 does not have a maximum at t F 2 because it engages in local provision at that tax rate, t F 2 < ˆt F 3 tf 3. Because regions not engaging in local provision over a given interval of federal tax rates have the same preferences, and because poorer regions stop providing locally at lower tax rates than do richer regions, a poorer region may prefer a lower tax rate than does a richer region, but it will never prefer a higher one. For this reason, most-preferred tax rates are weakly increasing in income among all regions that strictly prefer higher tax rates when they are local providers (i.e. all local providers under the conditions of Proposition 1, and {ˆl +1,...,l max } under the conditions of Proposition 2). Regions that do engage in local provision over a given interval of federal tax rates do not necessarily share the same preferences over those tax rates, however. Although Regions 1, 2, and 3 all engage in local provision on [0, ˆt F 3 ), 3 prefers higher tax rates on this interval, whereas 1 and 2 prefer lower tax rates. This difference is a result of the unequal distribution of wealth and the fact that different local providers enjoy different amounts of public good, insofar as they obtain greater benefit from public goods produced in their own districts (s L < 1). The conditions for the existence of a voting equilibrium in Propositions 1 and 2 are closely 16

18 related. In each case, the relevant conditions are those necessary to guarantee that, in every region, the voters have monotonic preferences on the interval of federal tax rates for which their own region does engage in local provision, [0, ˆt F j ], i.e., each must either strictly prefer higher taxation or lower taxation over those tax rates for which its own region is a local provider. The direct effect of increasing the federal tax rate on the amount of public good j enjoys is positive, but it is offset by all local providers reducing their local provision in response. While the marginal increase in federal provision is constant, the marginal decrease in local provision grows smaller as fewer regions engage in local provision, since regions who have ceased local provision entirely cannot reduce their local provision further in response to increases in federal provision. Thus if, for a citizen of region j, theformereffect dominates the latter effect for some number of local providers, then it does so for fewer local providers as well. Therefore to insure that her consumption is strictly increasing in federal tax rate (for as long region j is a local provider), it is sufficienttoinsurethatitisincreasing on [0, ˆt F l max ), as in Proposition 1. Similarly, to insure that consumption is strictly decreasing in federal tax rate, it is sufficient to insure that it is decreasing on [ˆt F j+1, ˆt F j ), as in Proposition 2. Because the citizens of a richer region pay more than those of a poorer one for a given increase in federal provision, the richer region reduces its local provision more quickly than does the poorer one as the federal tax rate increases. Thus the amount of public good enjoyed, and hence consumption, decreases more quickly or increases more slowly for the richer region. It follows that, given two local providers for whom consumption is decreasing at t F = 0, the consumption of a citizen of the poorer region will reach its minimum at a lower federal tax rate. Thus if the richest region s consumption is increasing on [0, ˆt F l max ), as required in Proposition 1, then all poorer local providers must also have increasing consumption on [0, ˆt F l max ). To insure that consumption is strictly decreasing on [0, ˆt F j ], as for the citizens of the ˆl richest regions in Proposition 2, it is sufficient to require that the citizens of the poorest such region providing locally at t F have decreasing consumption. Because poorer regions stop providing locally before richer regions, as established in Lemma 1, this requirement is equivalent to the statement in Proposition 2. 17

19 Evaluating Sufficiency Conditions To understand the weight of the sufficient conditions in Propositions 1 and 2, note first that the number of regions that provide the public good locally in the absence of federal provision, l max, is independent of the benefits of federal provision, s F. Given this independence, it is evident that f s F > 0and g s F > 0. Consequently, as s F increases, the antecedent of Proposition 1 is more easily, and the antecedent of Proposition 2 less easily, satisfied. Benchmark: pure public good, s L =1 µ lmax a P When s L = 1, then (8) reduces to H lmax > b+al max H k H lmax +1. The conditions for 1 Proposition 1, then, reduce to f(1; s L =1, ) =bs F H T b l max P H k > 0, which is satisfied whenever lmax P H k 1 s F >. Note that this ratio is always less than 1. This means that the wealthy regions H T may prefer federal provision to local provision even when the technology of federal provision is less efficient than that of local provision. The special case in which s F = s L = 1 may be thought to correspond to the world in which federal tax revenue is divided equally amongst the districts to fund the local production of the public good (using the same technology as the one they use for producing a locally financed public good). If s L =1, then f(j; s L =1, ) > 0 reduces to bs F H T b l Pmax H k > 0andg(j; s L =1, ) < 0 1 reduces to bs F H T P b j H k < 0. These conditions are jointly satisfied only if ˆl = l max. It follows 1 that a necessary and sufficient condition for the satisfaction of the conditions for Proposition 2 is g(1; s L =1, ) < 0, which reduces to s F < H 1 < 1. This condition is satisfied when s H T F is relatively small (i.e., federal technology of provision is relatively inefficient) or the wealthiest region controls most of the wealth of the federation. 1 Impurepublicgood,s L < 1 In this, more general, case, it is useful to return to the formulation of s F as a function of s L, s F = γ (1+s L(n 1)) n. Recall that the federal means of provision is inherently less efficient than the local means of provision if and only if γ < 1. (Recall also that the existence of spillovers may make membership in the federation attractive even if γ < 1.) Table 1 below shows the values of γ that 18

20 correspond to different values of the spillover coefficients s L and s F. A line is drawn demarcating the cases in which the federal means of production is more efficient, corresponding roughly to the upper-right portion of the table, and cases in which the local means is more efficient. Because the number of regions engaging in local provision in equilibrium at any given tax rate is defined implicitly by a system of inequalities, it is difficult to obtain comparative statics for f(j, a, b, s L,s F,H)andg(j, a, b, s L,s F,H) analytically for most parameters of the model, and so here we report results of numerical estimations of the determinants of sustaining the existence results in Propositions 1 and 2. For a particular set of parameter values (a = 0.6, b = 0.4, H = (100, 90, 80, 70, 50)) we estimate l max, represented here by superscripts, and the values of f(j, a, b, s L,s F,H)andg(j, a, b, s L,s F,H). The bold-faced cells to the left of the s F =.5 column correspond to cases in which Proposition 2 holds, and the bold-faced values in the cells to the right of it to cases in which Proposition 1 holds. TABLE 1 ABOUT HERE We might expect, absent strategic and redistributive effects, that members would prefer federal provision when it is more efficient, i.e. when γ > 1, and local provision when it is more efficient, i.e. when γ < 1. However, the redistributive features of federal provision and the voluntary nature of local provision complicate the effect of relative technological efficiency on induced preferences in equilibrium. Because a condition of federal provision is that each region enjoys equal amounts of the federally-provided good, and because the regions have unequal wealth, federal provision is redistributive, dampening the richest region s enthusiasm for that means of provision. Redistribution does not explain a second interesting feature of the results, however: satisfaction of the antecedent of Proposition 1 is non-monotonic in γ. For example, although it is satisfied for {s L =.9, s F =.7, γ =.76} and {s L =.9, s F =.9, γ =.98}, itisnotsatisfied for {s L =.7, s F =.7, γ =.92} or for {s L =.5, s F =.5, γ =.83}. Similarly, it is satisfied for {s L =.5, s F =1.5, γ =2.50}, but not satisfied {s L =.3, s F =1.1, γ =2.50}. This non-monotonicity is the result of the voluntary nature of local provision and the strategic response of regions local provision choices to increases in federal provision. While the citizens 19

21 of each local provider may benefit directly from switching to federal provision because it is technologically more efficient sufficiently more efficient to compensate for redistributive effects they suffer indirectly from other regions reducing local provision in response to the increase in federal provision. The condition f(1,a,b,s L,s F,H) > 0issatisfied only if the former effect is greater than the latter. Not all regions are necessarily able to reduce their provision of the public good in response to federal provision, however. When spillovers from local provision are sufficiently large, the poorest regions will not engage in local provision even in the total absence of federal provision, because they consume enough of the public good locally provided in other regions. It follows, then, that they will not be able to respond to increases in federal provision, and thus the net effect of increasing federal taxation on the utility of the richer regions will be greater than it would be if all regions were initially engaged in local provision. For this reason, citizens of richer regions find federal provision more appealing when, ceteris paribus, fewer regions are engaging in local provision, and, as the entries in Table 1 show, the antecedent condition of Proposition 1 is more likely to be satisfied, for a given value of γ, whenl max is lower. Given that redistribution is inherent in federal provision, and given the dependency of the above results on the number of regions that engage in voluntary provision, the satisfaction of the existence conditions also depends on the dispersion of the distribution of regional income. The antecedent of Proposition 2 is more easily satisfied for more dispersed income distributions. The satisfaction of the antecedent condition of Proposition 1 is non-monotonic in the dispersion of the income distribution, however. It is satisfied for sufficiently egalitarian distributions of income because there is little redistribution and little difference in the behavior of the regions in such cases. It is also satisfied for sufficiently inegalitarian distributions, because in such cases the poorer regions do not engage in local provision at any federal tax rate. For intermediate levels of dispersion in the income distribution, the condition is not satisfied because the poorer regions reduction in levels of local provision outweighs the additional direct benefits to the richer regions of federal provision, as discussed above. The effects of increasing the dispersion of the distribution are the same whether the median is less than the mean or vice versa. 20

22 The Effects of Spillovers To determine the effect of introducing positive spillovers into the model of federations with two levels of public good provision, we next provide the properties of the equilibrium in the federation when s L =0. LetH m be the total income in the median region of the income distribution. Then: Proposition 3 In the federation without inter-regional spillovers (s L =0): (1) if s F > Hm H T, then t F = b a+b and the median and all poorer regions choose t j =0; (2) if s F < Hm H T, then t F =0and all regions j choose t j = Proof See Appendix. In the federation without inter-regional spillovers, if s F > H 1, then all citizens of all regions H T prefer pure federal provision, i.e., t F = b a+b and t j = 0, for all j N; ifs F < Hn then all H T, citizens of all regions prefer pure local provision, i.e., t F =0andt j = b a+b, for all j N. The inter-regional disagreement occurs when the efficiency of federal provision is in the middle-range, i.e., when s F ( H n, H H T 1 ). In that case, citizens of some regions prefer federal, and citizens of H T others pure local, provision. Since within each region, voters share induced preferences over t F, the outcome of majority rule in the federation as a whole is identical to the outcome of weighted voting b a+b. among member states, where weights are proportional to states populations. Moreover, since, by assumption, all regions have equal populations, we can, in this and the subsequent results, restrict our attention to simple majority rule among regions. Because the regional preferences are single-peaked, the Condorcet winner always exists, and the prediction is straightforward. We can now ascertain the direct effects of the existence of spillovers in a federal system with joint federal and local provision, by comparing the results of Proposition 3 with those in the model with positive local (inter-regional) spillovers. The following proposition summarizes the salient features of this comparison: Proposition 4 (1) If s F < H m, the presence of local spillovers lowers local provision in the median H T and richer regions, leaving constant the majority s preferences over federal provision. (2) If s F > H m, the presence of local spillovers (weakly) lowers federal provision, leaves local H T provision unchanged for the majority of regions, and (weakly) increases local provision for a minority 21

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice 1. MWG - Decisive Subgroups Recall proposition 21.C.1: (Arrow s Impossibility Theorem) Suppose that the number of alternatives is at least

More information

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A.

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. THE INVISIBLE HAND OF PIRACY: AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE INFORMATION-GOODS SUPPLY CHAIN Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. {antino@iu.edu}

More information

FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE INSTRUMENT TO FINANCE GOVERNMENT. Carlos Maravall Rodríguez 1

FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE INSTRUMENT TO FINANCE GOVERNMENT. Carlos Maravall Rodríguez 1 Working Paper 05-22 Economics Series 13 April 2005 Departamento de Economía Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Calle Madrid, 126 28903 Getafe (Spain) Fax (34) 91 624 98 75 FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE

More information

Bureaucratic Efficiency and Democratic Choice

Bureaucratic Efficiency and Democratic Choice Bureaucratic Efficiency and Democratic Choice Randy Cragun December 12, 2012 Results from comparisons of inequality databases (including the UN-WIDER data) and red tape and corruption indices (such as

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes James E. Anderson February 6, 2009 These notes derive the useful concepts of trade expenditure functions, the closely related trade indirect utility

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours YORK UNIVERSITY Faculty of Graduate Studies Final Examination December 14, 2010 Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics S. Bucovetsky time=2.5 hours Do any 6 of the following 10 questions. All count

More information

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Matthias Doepke UCLA Martin Schneider NYU and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Abstract This paper shows that a zero-sum redistribution

More information

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations? Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 7, 0. Consider an individual faced with two job choices: she can either accept a position with a fixed annual salary of x > 0 which requires L x units of labor

More information

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. You have 3 hours to answer the questions in the final exam. We will collect the exams at 2.30 sharp. Show your work, and good luck! Problem 1. Utility Maximization.

More information

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand Economics 101 Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand 1 Intro First, a note on wealth and endowment. Varian generally uses wealth (m) instead of endowment. Ultimately, these two are equivalent. Given prices p, if

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH http://www.kier.kyoto-u.ac.jp/index.html Discussion Paper No. 657 The Buy Price in Auctions with Discrete Type Distributions Yusuke Inami

More information

Lecture 5: Iterative Combinatorial Auctions

Lecture 5: Iterative Combinatorial Auctions COMS 6998-3: Algorithmic Game Theory October 6, 2008 Lecture 5: Iterative Combinatorial Auctions Lecturer: Sébastien Lahaie Scribe: Sébastien Lahaie In this lecture we examine a procedure that generalizes

More information

Liquidity saving mechanisms

Liquidity saving mechanisms Liquidity saving mechanisms Antoine Martin and James McAndrews Federal Reserve Bank of New York September 2006 Abstract We study the incentives of participants in a real-time gross settlement with and

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Leonardo Felli 7 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Contract Theory has become only recently a subfield of Economics. As the name suggest the main object of the analysis is a contract. Therefore

More information

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 and 2 in the first Blue Book and Problems 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A

More information

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation Reputations arise in situations where there is an element of repetition, and also where coordination between players is possible. One definition of leadership is that

More information

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 24, November 28 Outline 1 Sequential Trade and Arrow Securities 2 Radner Equilibrium 3 Equivalence

More information

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Joan Llull Structural Micro. IDEA PhD Program I. Dynamic Discrete Games with Imperfect Information A. Motivating example: firm entry and

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley Michael P. Devereux Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation This version: September 3, 2014 Abstract

More information

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries BACKGROUND PAPER FOR THE WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2008 Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries Larry Karp The findings, interpretations, and conclusions

More information

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take?

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take? Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take? September 2018 Prepared by the

More information

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence A The infinite horizon model This section defines the equilibrium of the infinity horizon model described in Section III of the paper and characterizes

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game

Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game Parkash Chander * and Myrna Wooders May 1, 2011 Abstract We propose a new concept of core for games in extensive form and label it the γ-core of an extensive

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Are jurisdictions with the median voter and median inequality favored?

Are jurisdictions with the median voter and median inequality favored? Are jurisdictions with the median voter and median inequality favored? Santanu Gupta Institute of Technology and Management Sector 23-A, Gurgaon 2207 Haryana, India email: topigupta@yahoo.com Fax: +9-24-2367488

More information

The Effects of Shareholder Disagreement under Majority Voting

The Effects of Shareholder Disagreement under Majority Voting The Effects of Shareholder Disagreement under Majority Voting Carsten Sprenger International College of Economics and Finance (ICEF), Higher School of Economics, Moscow September, 007 Abstract This paper

More information

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015 Best-Reply Sets Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis This version: May 2015 Introduction The best-reply correspondence of a game the mapping from beliefs over one s opponents actions to

More information

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality Economics 448: Measures of Inequality 6 March 2014 1 2 The context Economic inequality: Preliminary observations 3 Inequality Economic growth affects the level of income, wealth, well being. Also want

More information

Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control (Preliminary and incomplete)

Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control (Preliminary and incomplete) Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control (Preliminary and incomplete) Cristian M. Litan Sorina C. Vâju October 29, 2007 Abstract We provide a model of strategic

More information

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Stephen D. Williamson Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis May 14, 015 1 Introduction When a central bank operates under a floor

More information

Centralized Fiscal Spending by Supranational Unions

Centralized Fiscal Spending by Supranational Unions Centralized Fiscal Spending by Supranational Unions Jenny Simon Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics and CESifo and Justin M. Valasek 1 WZB Berlin First version: June 20, 2012 This version: May

More information

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency Problem Anthony M. Marino Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA 90089-1422 E-mail: amarino@usc.edu May 8,

More information

Do Government Subsidies Increase the Private Supply of Public Goods?

Do Government Subsidies Increase the Private Supply of Public Goods? Do Government Subsidies Increase the Private Supply of Public Goods? by James Andreoni and Ted Bergstrom University of Wisconsin and University of Michigan Current version: preprint, 1995 Abstract. We

More information

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography Increasing Returns and Economic Geography Department of Economics HKUST April 25, 2018 Increasing Returns and Economic Geography 1 / 31 Introduction: From Krugman (1979) to Krugman (1991) The award of

More information

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1 Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose,

More information

A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics

A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics Yong Bao University of California, Riverside Jang-Ting Guo University of California, Riverside October 8, 2002 We would like to

More information

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations Leslie M. Marx Duke University Greg Shaffer University of Rochester December 2006 Abstract When two sellers negotiate terms of trade with a common buyer, the

More information

PUBLIC GOODS AND THE LAW OF 1/n

PUBLIC GOODS AND THE LAW OF 1/n PUBLIC GOODS AND THE LAW OF 1/n David M. Primo Department of Political Science University of Rochester James M. Snyder, Jr. Department of Political Science and Department of Economics Massachusetts Institute

More information

On the Optimality of Financial Repression

On the Optimality of Financial Repression On the Optimality of Financial Repression V.V. Chari, Alessandro Dovis and Patrick Kehoe Conference in honor of Robert E. Lucas Jr, October 2016 Financial Repression Regulation forcing financial institutions

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

ECON 803: MICROECONOMIC THEORY II Arthur J. Robson Fall 2016 Assignment 9 (due in class on November 22)

ECON 803: MICROECONOMIC THEORY II Arthur J. Robson Fall 2016 Assignment 9 (due in class on November 22) ECON 803: MICROECONOMIC THEORY II Arthur J. Robson all 2016 Assignment 9 (due in class on November 22) 1. Critique of subgame perfection. 1 Consider the following three-player sequential game. In the first

More information

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, September 28th, 2016 ANSWER KEY

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, September 28th, 2016 ANSWER KEY Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, September 28th, 2016 ANSWER KEY Instructions. Show all your work clearly and make sure you justify all your answers. 1. Question #1 [10 Points]. Discuss and provide examples

More information

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Class Notes on Chaney (2008) Class Notes on Chaney (2008) (With Krugman and Melitz along the Way) Econ 840-T.Holmes Model of Chaney AER (2008) As a first step, let s write down the elements of the Chaney model. asymmetric countries

More information

Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract

Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract This note shows that a public pension system with a

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy We now proceed to study optimal fiscal policy. We should make clear at the outset what we mean by this. In general, fiscal policy entails the government choosing its spending

More information

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Henrik Horn (Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm) Giovanni Maggi (Princeton University) Robert W. Staiger (Stanford University and

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 9

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 9 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 9 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 24 November 2017 Bargaining Games: Recall Two players, i {A, B} are trying to share a surplus. The size of the surplus is normalized

More information

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Chapter 5 Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Until now we implicitly adopted a view that a Nash equilibrium is a desirable outcome of a strategic game. In this chapter we consider two alternative

More information

Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI

Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI Presented by: Romita Mukherjee February 20, 2008 Basic Principles of International Taxation of Capital Income Residence Principle (1) Place of Residency

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations 19.1: Introduction This chapter is interesting and important. It also helps to answer a question you may well have been asking ever since we studied quasi-linear

More information

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default 0.287/MSOM.070.099ec Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default Robert Swinney Serguei Netessine The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, 904

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE Problem Set 1 These questions will go over basic game-theoretic concepts and some applications. homework is due during class on week 4. This [1] In this problem (see Fudenberg-Tirole

More information

Reputation and Signaling in Asset Sales: Internet Appendix

Reputation and Signaling in Asset Sales: Internet Appendix Reputation and Signaling in Asset Sales: Internet Appendix Barney Hartman-Glaser September 1, 2016 Appendix D. Non-Markov Perfect Equilibrium In this appendix, I consider the game when there is no honest-type

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid September 2015 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model September 2015 1 / 43 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States

Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States Kennesaw State University DigitalCommons@Kennesaw State University Faculty Publications 5-14-2012 Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States Timothy Mathews

More information

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics Spring - 2005 Trade and Development Instructions (For students electing Macro (8701) & New Trade Theory (8702) option) Identify yourself

More information

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility and Coordination Failures What makes financial systems fragile? What causes crises

More information

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015. FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.) Hints for Problem Set 2 1. Consider a zero-sum game, where

More information

MIDTERM ANSWER KEY GAME THEORY, ECON 395

MIDTERM ANSWER KEY GAME THEORY, ECON 395 MIDTERM ANSWER KEY GAME THEORY, ECON 95 SPRING, 006 PROFESSOR A. JOSEPH GUSE () There are positions available with wages w and w. Greta and Mary each simultaneously apply to one of them. If they apply

More information

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma RESEARCH ARTICLE A MODEL OF COMPETITION BETWEEN PERPETUAL SOFTWARE AND SOFTWARE AS A SERVICE Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma School of Information Systems, Singapore Management University, 80 Stanford Road, Singapore

More information

ECON 301: General Equilibrium V (Public Goods) 1. Intermediate Microeconomics II, ECON 301. General Equilibrium V: Public Goods

ECON 301: General Equilibrium V (Public Goods) 1. Intermediate Microeconomics II, ECON 301. General Equilibrium V: Public Goods ECON 301: General Equilibrium V (Public Goods) 1 Intermediate Microeconomics II, ECON 301 General Equilibrium V: Public Goods In our last discussion on externality, we found that as long as property rights

More information

Endogenous Price Leadership and Technological Differences

Endogenous Price Leadership and Technological Differences Endogenous Price Leadership and Technological Differences Maoto Yano Faculty of Economics Keio University Taashi Komatubara Graduate chool of Economics Keio University eptember 3, 2005 Abstract The present

More information

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games Game Theory Wolfgang Frimmel Repeated Games 1 / 41 Recap: SPNE The solution concept for dynamic games with complete information is the subgame perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE) Selten (1965): A strategy

More information

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance September 24 additional problems due Tuesday, Sept. 29: p. 194: 1, 2, 3 0.0.12 Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance Section 9.1 is a lengthy and fact-filled discussion of issues of information

More information

Factors that Affect Fiscal Externalities in an Economic Union

Factors that Affect Fiscal Externalities in an Economic Union Factors that Affect Fiscal Externalities in an Economic Union Timothy J. Goodspeed Hunter College - CUNY Department of Economics 695 Park Avenue New York, NY 10021 USA Telephone: 212-772-5434 Telefax:

More information

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS University of Victoria Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS Martin Farnham Problem Set #5 Note: Answer each question as clearly and concisely as possible. Use of diagrams, where appropriate, is strongly

More information

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Oil Monopoly and the Climate Oil Monopoly the Climate By John Hassler, Per rusell, Conny Olovsson I Introduction This paper takes as given that (i) the burning of fossil fuel increases the carbon dioxide content in the atmosphere,

More information

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2 Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2 Due Tues Oct 3. Question 1 Consider the following model of entry. There are two firms. There are two entry scenarios in each period. With probability only one firm is able

More information

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion?

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion? Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion? Patrick Rey and Michael D. Whinston 1 Introduction In a recent paper, Marx and Shaffer (2007) study a model of vertical contracting between a manufacturer and two

More information

States and Mafias PRELIMINARY. First Version: August 31, 2004 This Version: November 6, Abstract

States and Mafias PRELIMINARY. First Version: August 31, 2004 This Version: November 6, Abstract States and Mafias Ethan Bueno de Mesquita Catherine Hafer PRELIMINARY First Version: August 3, 2004 This Version: November 6, 2004 Abstract We analyze a model of the relationship between a government,

More information

SOCIAL SECURITY: UNIVERSAL VS. EARNINGS DEPENDENT BENEFITS WORKING PAPER SERIES

SOCIAL SECURITY: UNIVERSAL VS. EARNINGS DEPENDENT BENEFITS WORKING PAPER SERIES WORKING PAPER NO. 2011 14 SOCIAL SECURITY: UNIVERSAL VS. EARNINGS DEPENDENT BENEFITS By Jorge Soares WORKING PAPER SERIES The views expressed in the Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and

More information

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation Constantine Angyridis Ryerson University Dept. of Economics Toronto, Canada December 7, 2012 Abstract This paper considers an endogenous growth

More information

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers WP-2013-015 Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers Amit Kumar Maurya and Shubhro Sarkar Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai August 2013 http://www.igidr.ac.in/pdf/publication/wp-2013-015.pdf

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Transport Costs and North-South Trade Transport Costs and North-South Trade Didier Laussel a and Raymond Riezman b a GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II b Department of Economics, University of Iowa Abstract We develop a simple two country

More information

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K Economics 285 Chris Georges Help With Practice Problems 3 Chapter 8: 1. Questions For Review 1,4: Please see text or lecture notes. 2. A note about notation: Mankiw defines k slightly differently in Chs.

More information

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model Volume 29 Issue 1 Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model Kojun Hamada Faculty of Economics Niigata University Abstract This paper examines which of the Stackelberg

More information

Web Appendix: Proofs and extensions.

Web Appendix: Proofs and extensions. B eb Appendix: Proofs and extensions. B.1 Proofs of results about block correlated markets. This subsection provides proofs for Propositions A1, A2, A3 and A4, and the proof of Lemma A1. Proof of Proposition

More information

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Two Period Exchange Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 2 1 Two Period Exchange Economy We shall start our exploration of dynamic economies with

More information

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics Chapter 4 Consumer and Firm Behavior The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization 1 Instructor: Xiaohui Huang Department of Economics University of Virginia 1

More information

CS364A: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture #14: Robust Price-of-Anarchy Bounds in Smooth Games

CS364A: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture #14: Robust Price-of-Anarchy Bounds in Smooth Games CS364A: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture #14: Robust Price-of-Anarchy Bounds in Smooth Games Tim Roughgarden November 6, 013 1 Canonical POA Proofs In Lecture 1 we proved that the price of anarchy (POA)

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 22 COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY Correlated Strategies and Correlated

More information

Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk

Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk Kenneth Mirkin and Marek Pycia June 2015. Preliminary Draft. Abstract We study directed search in a frictional two-sided matching market in which each seller

More information

GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION GEABA DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT

GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION GEABA DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT Tax and Managerial Effects of Transfer Pricing on Capital and Physical Products Oliver Duerr, Thomas Rüffieux Discussion Paper No. 17-19 GERMAN ECONOMIC

More information

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25 Department of Economics Boston College Economics 202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory Midterm Exam Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 203 NAME: The Exam has a total of four (4) problems and

More information

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome.

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome. AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED Alex Gershkov and Flavio Toxvaerd November 2004. Preliminary, comments welcome. Abstract. This paper revisits recent empirical research on buyer credulity

More information

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017 For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market June 017 This appendix contains the proofs and additional analyses that we mention in paper but that

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information